Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 12

World Development Vol. 40, No. 9, pp.

1798–1809, 2012
Ó 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2012.04.026

The Institutional Reforms Debate and FDI Flows to the


MENA Region: The “Best” Ensemble
WASSEEM MICHEL MINA *
United Arab Emirates University, United Arab Emirates
Summary. — This paper empirically examines the theoretical debate on the adoption of a best approach to reforming institutions iden-
tified by Rodrik (2008) in the context of property rights protection and FDI flows to eight MENA countries. The first best approach
comprises strengthening domestic institutional functions only, while the second best comprises in addition entering into force bilateral
investment treaties and the interaction between functions and treaties. Empirically both approaches to reducing investment expropria-
tion risk encourage FDI flows. The positive effect of the second best approach depends on the success of the first best approach, sug-
gesting the two approaches are complementary.
Ó 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — institutional reforms, property rights protection, FDI, MENA, first best, second best

1. INTRODUCTION given the globalization that has occurred in the past quarter-
century and the growing importance of markets in resource
Institutions are defined as the set of rules governing human allocation and the conduct of economic activity. The intensifi-
behavior (North, 1991). They include both formal and infor- cation of globalization and development of markets have
mal rules. Formal rules are legal in nature and include consti- necessitated the adoption of common institutional functions
tutions, laws, and regulations created and enforced by the and standards, similar to the adoption of a common language
government in response to individuals’ needs to organize inter- in communications, which facilitate trade and capital mobility.
actions in society. Informal rules are social in nature and in- However, the adoption of an orthodox approach for institu-
clude traditions and customs influenced by cultures and tional reform does not take into account a country’s unique
beliefs. circumstances and the interaction of institutions within the
Institutions play an important role in supporting markets country. This view is supported by Rodrik (2008) who argues
and transactions by protecting property rights, enforcing con- that institutional reforms promoted by the World Bank, the
tracts, and facilitating collective action to provide physical and IMF or the WTO, to name three examples, presume the exis-
organizational infrastructure (Dixit, 2009). They create order, tence of a unique set of appropriate institutional arrangements
reduce uncertainty in the exchange of goods and capital, and to which it is “inherently desirable” that countries conform.
help to determine transaction and production costs; thus, He also warns that the convergence to a first best practice does
institutions determine the feasibility and profitability of engag- not “consider potential interactions with institutional features
ing in economic activity (North, 1991). elsewhere in the system” and advocates instead for institu-
Among the positive effects of good institutions is the promo- tional reforms based on the theory of the second best. 3
tion of a country’s integration into the world economy Acting along the lines of the theory of the second best, many
(Rodrik, 2008). The flow of capital constitutes one important governments have strengthened PRP through bilateral invest-
integration channel. As other studies have shown, Property ment treaties that act as complements or substitutes to their
Rights Protection (PRP) encourages capital flows and pro- domestic institutional functions. A bilateral investment treaty
vides incentives for investment and capital exchange. is an international legal instrument between two contracting
In the examination of the influence of domestic institutions
on capital flows, empirical studies have focused mostly on
domestic PRP institutional functions. 1, 2 These studies have * The author would like to thank three anonymous reviewers, Paul
used indicators of the quality of institutional functions, which Alagidede, Luc Christiaensen, Alisa DiCaprio, Suut Dogruel, Imed Drine,
assess a country’s actual performance against industrialized Augustin Fosu, Abdulnasser Hatemi, Magda Kandil, Jorge Martinez-
countries’ first best performance. Vazquez, Wim Naude, Jeffrey Nugent, Aleksander Surdej, and participants
This assessment approach has been adopted despite diverg- at the Nordic Conference on Development Economics (2010), the African
ing social and political norms between developing and emerg- Econometric Society’s 15th Annual Conference on Econometric Modeling
ing market economies and developed economies. This for Africa (2010), the Third Summer Research Day of the Faculty of
approach implies that institutional reforms should bring the Business and Economics at the United Arab Emirates University (2010),
performance of domestic institutional functions in developing and the Middle East Economic Association Meetings (2011) for useful
and emerging market economies in line with that of developed comments and suggestions. The author would also like to thank Lay Poh
countries. It may also imply that developing and emerging Allonen and Ahmed Taha for excellent library services. Part of this research
market economies should adopt an orthodox approach to was conducted while the author was a UNU-WIDER visiting scholar in
reforming domestic institutions that is believed to achieve summer 2009. The financial support of the Faculty of Business and
the first best, a point that is discussed further below. Economics at the United Arab Emirates University (through Summer
The comparison of a country’s institutional performance Research Grant Program) is gratefully acknowledged. Final revision
against industrialized countries’ first best is understandable accepted: November 9, 2011.
1798
THE INSTITUTIONAL REFORMS DEBATE AND FDI FLOWS TO THE MENA REGION: THE “BEST” ENSEMBLE 1799

countries that establishes clear, simple, enforceable, and reci- investment is more sensitive to institutional function quality
procal rules for foreign investment protection from govern- than FDI; and (d) the influence of domestic institutional func-
ment expropriation. A treaty identifies the circumstances tions on FDI has been examined in different regions from a
under which expropriation can take place and the associated geographical perspective with the exception of the MENA re-
compensation standards, and it establishes dispute settlement gion. The first and fourth findings are of special importance
mechanisms that facilitate foreign investment in the presence and relevance to this paper; the first finding lends major sup-
of imperfect domestic PRP institutional functions. port to the first best approach to institutional reforms typically
This paper explores the policy debate underlying institutional heralded by international organizations, such as the World
reforms that is reflected implicitly in the assessment of institu- Bank and the IMF, and the fourth finding identifies geograph-
tional functions quality and explicitly in Rodrik’s (2008) views ical gap in literature coverage, which this paper attempts to
on second best institutions and explores that debate in the con- fill.
text of the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) region. In In the second strand in the literature, the influence of bilat-
particular, this paper empirically examines the influence on eral investment treaties on FDI, 6 I find: (a) the influence of
Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) flows to MENA countries bilateral investment treaties depends on the degree of govern-
of the second best approach for PRP, which is comprised of ment commitment to PRP and is surprisingly not always posi-
bilateral investment treaties, domestic institutional functions, tive; (b) domestic institutional functions can complement or
and the interaction between them. The paper uses treaties en- substitute for bilateral investment treaties in attracting FDI;
tered into force with high-income OECD countries, which con- and, (c) the impact of bilateral investment treaties tends to
stitute about one-third of the treaties entered into force by eight diminish as the number of contracted treaties increases glob-
high- and middle-income MENA countries, comprising Alge- ally. Although some of these studies have explored the nature
ria, Egypt, Jordan, Lebanon, Libya, Morocco, Syria, and Tuni- of the relationship between bilateral investment treaties and
sia. domestic institutional functions, whether as complements
The paper uses panel data for the period of 1992–2008 and or substitutes, 7 the perspective of institutional reforms is
adopts two estimation methodologies to ensure robustness. explicitly lacking, with the exception of Hallward-Driemeier
The first is the Random and Fixed-Effects (RE/FE) dynamic (2003). 8 Two policy questions motivate and underlie the
panel regression model, which takes into account nonstation- hypotheses examined in this paper: should countries strengthen
arity, endogeneity, heteroskedasticity, autocorrelation, and PRP by reforming domestic PRP institutional functions
cross-panel correlation. The second is the dynamic panel alone—a first best approach—or, should they both reform
Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) model, along the domestic institutional functions and contract bilateral invest-
lines of Arellano and Bond (1991), which accounts for poten- ment treaties—a second best approach?
tial endogeneity. Both methodologies support the first and sec- In the third strand, on the determinants of FDI in the
ond best approaches to reducing the risk of investment MENA region, 9 I find that natural resources and human cap-
expropriation to encourage FDI flows. The GMM methodol- ital discourage FDI flows in GCC countries while institutional
ogy supports the second best approach of enhancing govern- quality, trade openness, and infrastructure development
ment stability to encourage FDI flows. encourage FDI flows. In MENA countries I find more gener-
The paper contributes to the literature of development eco- ally that (a) market potential encourages FDI, (b) evidence on
nomics and economic policy literature in two respects. First, in economic growth is inconclusive, and (c) the level and stability
examining the debate on institutional reform to strengthen of institutional quality positively influence FDI. The concept
PRP, the paper stresses that the issue is not whether but that institutional quality influences FDI in the MENA region
how to undertake institutional reform. Second, to the best of is of particular importance to this research and supports the
our knowledge, this paper is the first in the empirical literature first best approach.
to model first and second best approaches to institutional re-
forms and to apply the results in the context of international
capital flows. 3. FDI, BILATERAL INVESTMENT TREATIES
The paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 summarizes the AND INSTITUTIONAL FUNCTIONS IN THE MENA
findings of the empirical literature; Section 3 discusses the per- REGION
formance of domestic institutional functions, the proliferation
of bilateral investment treaties, and FDI development in the FDI flows have varied across the MENA region as Table 1
MENA region; Section 4 discusses the empirical model and shows. 10 Egypt has attracted the highest average level of FDI
the testable hypotheses; Section 5 discusses the data challenges flows during the period of 1990–2008, amounting to about
and the resulting modeling approach; Section 6 discusses the $2.6 billion and has also accumulated the highest average level
empirical issues and estimation methodology; Section 7 dis- of FDI stocks, amounting to $22.6 billion. In contrast, Syria
cusses the empirical results; and, Section 8 provides the con- has attracted the lowest average level of less than half a billion
clusion. dollars.
With FDI expressed in per capita terms or relative to GDP,
different countries appear to be the primary FDI recipients
2. EMPIRICAL LITERATURE: WHAT ARE during that period. Lebanon had the highest per capita aver-
THE FINDINGS? ages with flows and stocks amounting to about $323 and
$1720 per capita, respectively. Lebanon had the highest aver-
In previous work I survey three strands in the empirical cap- age FDI flow relative to GDP (6%), and Tunisia had the high-
ital flows literature that are relevant to this paper. 4 In the first est FDI stock (62%).
strand, the influence of domestic institutional functions on The eight MENA countries have entered into force approx-
capital flows, 5 I find that: (a) the quality of domestic institu- imately 230 treaties as Table 1 shows, about one-third of
tional functions positively influences capital flows; (b) better which are with high-income OECD countries. Egypt entered
institutional function quality tilts a country’s capital structure into force the largest number of treaties (64), followed by
toward equity and away from debt; (c) a country’s portfolio Lebanon (36), and Morocco (35). Libya entered into force
1800 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 1. FDI, bilateral investment treaties, and other indicators in MENA countries (1990–2008) (period average)
FDI flows FDI stocks Treaties Other indicators
Net Per capita % GDP Net Per capita % GDP All OECD OIL LABOR TRADE INFLATION
Algeria 680.9 21 0.8 4838.1 152.5 6.2 15 6 1616.3 6596.7 57.4 11.0
Egypt 2596.0 34.2 2.5 22568.9 313.5 25.6 64 12 806.8 2654.4 52.0 8.9
Jordan 642.8 119 4.9 5289.9 1019.1 46.2 28 10 (0.0) 5464.9 127.1 4.7
Lebanon 1269.6 322.6 6.1 6842.8 1717.7 31.5 36 14 0.1 10973.8 69.0 15.0
Libya 648.2 105.9 1.1 1965.8 338.7 3.8 8 3 1526.1 15273.4 68.4 3.3
Morocco 1146.8 39.4 2.3 13249.9 450.8 25.1 35 13 2.5 3736.5 62.6 3.3
Syria 352.7 18.8 1.2 7289.1 443.8 38 20 5 513.3 3011.3 67.8 6.7
Tunisia 841.1 86.4 3.4 13903.9 1454.4 61.9 25 11 87.7 6040.1 95.0 4.1
Notes: Treaties are counted as of June 2008. World Bank’s 2005 income classification is used in classifying countries. The units for OIL, LABOR, TRADE,
and INFLATION are in thousands of barrels per day, constant 2005 US$, percent of GDP, and percent, respectively. Appendix A to this paper provides
data sources for the different variables.

the least number (8) mainly due to the international embargo bureaucracy quality was poor, however, reaching approxi-
that had been in effect until the first half of the 2000s. Lebanon mately 58% and 47% of the OECD averages, respectively.
ratified the largest number of treaties with OECD countries Comparing political to PRP institutional functions, the
(14), followed by Morocco (13), Egypt (12), and Tunisia (11). average performance of the former fared better than that of
To understand the MENA region’s FDI performance and the latter. The MENA region showed better government sta-
the proliferation of bilateral investment treaties, we need to as- bility than OECD countries, outperforming them by 12%. Per-
sess the performance of domestic institutional functions at the formance related to ethnic tensions, external conflict, and
regional and country levels. We therefore compare the domes- internal conflict amounted to 92%, 90%, and 82% of the
tic institutional function performance, both PRP and political, OECD averages, respectively. The worst performance, how-
to that of (24) OECD countries using the International Coun- ever, was on democratic accountability, amounting to approx-
try Risk Guide’s (ICRG) political risk components. 11 The per- imately 46% of the OECD average.
iod under investigation is 1990–2008 during which bilateral As we would like to evaluate the domestic PRP performance
investment treaties proliferated in the MENA region. of Egypt, Lebanon, and Tunisia in particular, we compare the
Table 2 shows that, contrary to common perception, the MENA countries’ performance in Table 2. Tunisia’s average
MENA countries’ average performance with respect to the performance ranks first on law and order and bureaucracy
risk of investment expropriation (labeled “investment profile”) quality, second on investment profile and government stabil-
and law and order is not far from the OECD average perfor- ity, but fifth on corruption. Compared to Tunisia, Lebanon’s
mance. The average performance of the MENA countries on performance lies on the other extreme; it performed worst with
risk of investment expropriation amounted to approximately respect to corruption and government stability, second to
80% of the OECD average performance, while law and order worst on investment profile, and fifth on law and order and
amounted to 72%. The performance on corruption and bureaucracy quality.

Table 2. Domestic institutional functions in MENA (1990–2008) (period average)


Function Property rights protection Political
IP C L&O BQ GS ET IC EC MP RP DA
Regional level
Max Institutional Score 12 6 6 4 12 6 12 12 6 6 6
MENA 7.23 2.77 4 1.79 9.2 4.56 9.11 9.96 3.03 3.51 2.64
OECD 9.09 4.77 5.57 3.78 8.25 4.97 11.1 11.04 5.77 5.62 5.73
MENA–OECD ratio 0.795 0.581 0.718 0.474 1.115 0.918 0.821 0.902 0.525 0.625 0.461
Country level
Algeria 6.8 2.3 2.4 1.8 8.3 3.1 5.7 10.4 1.1 1.2 3.2
Egypt 7 2.2 3.6 2 9.2 5.4 8.4 10.1 3.0 2.5 2.8
Jordan 7.8 3.4 4 2.2 9.2 4.7 9.4 10.3 4.6 3.3 4.0
Lebanon 6.6 1.5 3.6 1.5 7.7 4.4 7.8 6.3 2.7 2.6 4.1
Libya 7.4 3 4 1.3 8.8 4.2 9.6 9.4 2.8 4.1 1.4
Morocco 8 3 5 2 9.6 4.7 9.4 9.9 3.9 4.1 3.3
Syria 5.6 2.8 4.5 1.3 9.8 5.0 10.7 8.9 2.0 4.6 1.4
Tunisia 7.9 2.6 4.5 2 9.6 4.9 10.7 10.7 3.9 4.8 2.3
Notes: “IP,” “C,” “L&O,” “BQ,” “GS,” “ET,” “IC,” “EC,” “MP,” “RP” and “DA” are investment profile, corruption, law and order, bureaucracy
quality, government stability, ethnic tensions, internal conflict, external conflict, military in politics, religion in politics, and democratic accountability,
respectively. A higher score indicates a lower risk. The list of OECD countries is based on the World Bank’s 2005 income classification. It comprises 24
countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Korea, Luxembourg,
Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, and United States. Source: Author calculations based on
ICRG data.
THE INSTITUTIONAL REFORMS DEBATE AND FDI FLOWS TO THE MENA REGION: THE “BEST” ENSEMBLE 1801

One important observation emerges from the assessment of BIT bilateral investment treaty entered into force, BIT-
institutional function performance at the regional and country INSTITFN is an interaction term between the natural loga-
levels. Although investment expropriation risk is believed to rithm of domestic PRP institutional function on the one
be the main reason for signing bilateral investment treaties, hand and bilateral investment treaties on the other, OIL is
there are other institutional functions, such as corruption oil production, PRICE is oil price, LABOR is labor productiv-
and bureaucracy quality, which may be associated with sign- ity, TRADE is trade openness, INFLATION is inflation rate,
ing bilateral investment treaties and should be considered WFDIFLOWS is world FDI flows, and e is an error term. 14
when assessing institutional reforms. The average total PRP The subscripts i, t, and l are country, time, and lag indicators
country performance for Lebanon, which is ranked last in with i = 1, . . . , N; t = 1, . . . , T; and l = 1,. . ., T  1. The
the region, appears to support this observation. model is double logarithmic except for BIT and BIT-
Finally, in looking beyond domestic institutional perfor- INSTITFN. Appendix A to this paper provides more informa-
mance and bilateral investment treaties, we see that common tion on variable definition and data sources.
characteristics of high FDI countries are their relatively low The decision to use FDI flows as opposed to FDI stock per
oil production and high trade openness. Oil production is capita is based on the presence of unit roots in the time series,
moderate in Egypt, nonexistent in Lebanon, and limited in as discussed further in Section 6. We expressed FDI flows in
Tunisia, as Table 1 shows. On the other hand, trade openness per capita terms, rather than relative to GDP, in order to
is highest in Lebanon and Tunisia, with trade accounting for account for PRP influence on FDI flows directly and not
approximately 70% and 95% of GDP, respectively. on FDI’s relative weight in the host country. This is similar
to the strategies used by Hallward-Driemeier (2003) and
Neumayer and Spess (2005).
4. EMPIRICAL MODEL AND TESTABLE HYPOTHESES The inclusion of the lagged dependent variable, FDIit-l, in
the empirical model serves two purposes. First, it accounts
(a) Empirical model for the persistence in FDI flows, especially when FDI is related
to natural resources; natural resources require flows of foreign
Gravity models have been increasingly used in empirical investment over time. Second, it mitigates the likely upward
studies to explore bilateral FDI flows, such as Bellack, Leibr- bias in the influence of bilateral investment treaties and
echt, and Riedl (2008), Bevan and Estrin (2004), Desbordes domestic PRP institutional functions on FDI. This bias likely
and Vicard (2009), Frenkel, Funke, and Stadtmann (2004), results from the lack of bilateral FDI data and the consequent
Hallward-Driemeier (2003), and Wei (2000). However, in the modeling of bilateral investment treaties as discussed in the
absence of data on bilateral FDI flows for MENA countries, next section. We expect its coefficient to be positive.
it is infeasible to adopt a typical gravity model. INSTITFN is domestic PRP institutional function. Because
We should note, however, that gravity models in essence PRP is a multidimensional process, we model PRP using four
constitute an extension of the location advantage hypothesis ICRG political risk components: investment profile, corrup-
of Dunning’s (1981) Ownership–Location–Internalization tion, law and order, and bureaucracy quality. These four func-
(OLI) paradigm. The location advantage hypothesis argues tions are outcomes of the legal and judicial systems and
that location advantages have to exist in the host market for government bureaucracy and are essential to PRP. The invest-
a multinational corporation to invest in the location. These ment profile refers to the risk of investment expropriation, prof-
advantages include natural and human resource endowments, its repatriation, and payment delays, which clearly influence
market size and potential, the degree of economic develop- PRP. Corruption is a threat to PRP as it enables people to as-
ment, the degree of openness of the economy, macroeconomic sume positions of power through patronage rather than ability.
stability, and PRP. Patronage threatens the rights of foreign investors because it
Of the many location advantages that characterize the facilitates government expropriation of investment or can cause
MENA region, natural resource endowments are of particular direct conflicts with patrons and investors. Law and order refers
importance because, in the MENA region, it is believed that to the strength and impartiality of the legal system as well as the
natural resource endowments, which include oil and natural popular observance of the law. Quality of bureaucracy refers to
gas reserves, attract resource-seeking FDI. Resource-rich whether the bureaucracy continues to function without drastic
MENA countries include Algeria and Libya, which are changes in policy when there is a change in government leader-
rich in both oil and natural gas reserves, and Egypt, which ship. Higher scores indicate better performance. 15 A positive
is rich in natural gas reserves. In addition some MENA coun- coefficient for each of these functions is expected, and an
tries enjoy a large population size, which is potentially a improvement in the performance of each of these functions is
human resource endowment when combined with education expected to be associated with more FDI flows.
and training. 12, 13 The respective population sizes of Egypt, In addition to the four PRP institutional functions, we also
Algeria, and Morocco are approximately 84 million, 35 mil- add government stability, which is a political institutional
lion, and 32 million in 2010. We account for natural resource function based on the correlation between FDI, the different
endowments and human capital in the empirical model. domestic institutional coefficients, and bilateral investment
The empirical model expresses FDI as: treaties. 16 Government stability refers to the ability of the
government to carry out its declared program(s) and remain
FDI it ¼ b0 þ b1 FDI itl þ b2 INSTITFN it þ b3 BIT it in office. A positive coefficient of government stability is also
þ b4 BITINSTITFN it þ b5 OILit þ b6 PRICEit expected.
BIT is the annual number of bilateral investment treaties en-
þ b7 LABORit þ b8 TRADEit þ b9 INFLATION it tered into force. We use bilateral investment treaties entered
þ b10 WFDIFLOWS it þ it ð1Þ into force as opposed to signed treaties to account for the
actual commitment to PRP by MENA countries. Treaties
Here, FDI is FDI flows per capita, FDIit-l lagged dependent protect and promote foreign investments, compensate for
variable, INSTITFN domestic PRP institutional function, losses, and create mechanisms for dispute settlements between
1802 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

contracting parties. Therefore, the coefficient of BIT is ex- 5. DATA AND MODELING APPROACH
pected to be positive.
BITINSTITFN is an interaction term that models the policy (a) Data and issues
interaction between domestic institutional functions and bilat-
eral investment treaties. A positive coefficient indicates that FDI data are obtained from UNCTAD’s FDI online data-
bilateral investment treaties complement domestic institu- base. Because of the variation in FDI flows per capita across
tional functions; a negative coefficient indicates substitution. countries, we take the natural logarithm as stated in the empir-
OIL and PRICE are the oil production and price variables, ical model. To get around zero and negative values of FDI
respectively. OIL is measured in thousands of barrels per day. flows, we use the same approach adopted by Blonigen and
PRICE is the crude oil price measured as the price of Saudi Davies (2004) and Neumayer and Spess (2005) as discussed in
Arabian Light 34 in US$ per barrel. Because oil production re- Kerner (2009). If the value of FDI flows is zero, we add one dol-
quires capital and technology, we expect OIL coefficient to be lar and take the natural logarithm, which results in a value of
positive. Similarly higher oil prices encourage the supply of oil, zero. If the value of FDI flows is negative, we take the negative
at least up to the limit enforced in OPEC countries; thus, we of the natural logarithm of the absolute value of FDI flows. The
expect a positive PRICE coefficient. 17 same approach is used with INSTITFN and OIL. Data on bilat-
We include LABOR to account for the productivity of hu- eral investment treaties are also obtained from UNCTAD’s
man capital in MENA countries. The more educated the labor FDI online database. We select the high-income OECD partner
force, the more productive it is. We measure labor productiv- countries for each of the MENA countries.
ity as real GDP per person employed. 18 We would expect a
positive coefficient reflecting the positive productivity influ- (b) Modeling approach
ence on FDI in MENA countries.
TRADE is the degree of trade openness of the economy. It is The lack of bilateral FDI flows data has constituted an
measured as the sum of exports and imports as a percentage of empirical challenge for this study. Unlike previous studies,
GDP. An open economy is conducive for FDI flows; FDI which used bilateral FDI flows data and adopted gravity mod-
flows toward the tradable sector with potential foreign ex- els, this study uses aggregate-level FDI data. The unavailabil-
change earnings. Thus, we expect a positive coefficient. ity of bilateral FDI data has affected the modeling approach of
INFLATION is a proxy for macroeconomic stability in the bilateral investment treaties; thus, we must use a count of the
economy. It is measured by the inflation rate based on either number of treaties entered into force.
the consumer price index or the GDP deflator. A higher infla- This approach has its pros and cons. It is a simple and
tion rate is an indicator of lower macroeconomic stability and straightforward solution to the absence of bilateral FDI data.
real incomes. It therefore discourages market-seeking, but not However, it may result in an upward BIT coefficient bias if
necessarily resource-seeking, FDI flows. A negative coefficient there are positive FDI flows from countries with which treaties
is expected. have been signed but not entered into force or with which
We include WFDIFLOWS to account for the business cycle there are no treaties. Second, the adopted modeling approach,
in the global economy. It is measured as world FDI inflows in which is based on the number of treaties that each country en-
millions of US$. MENA countries are likely to obtain more ters into force, implies that treaties are weighted equally in
FDI flows with the expansion of the world economy and the terms of promoting and protecting foreign investment.
increase in global FDI flows; thus, a positive coefficient is ex- This assumption is not totally unrealistic from empirical and
pected. legal perspectives. Although in principle the number of bilat-
eral investment treaties is related to the size of economy and
(b) Testable hypotheses should be weighted accordingly, the correlation coefficients
of GDP, population size, labor force, and natural resources
We use the above empirical model to test whether a second are small. 19 Additionally, the number of OECD countries lim-
best approach, as opposed to a first best approach, to PRP its the number of treaties that MENA countries can enter into
institutional reform has a positive influence on attracting force. Further, from a legal perspective, the assumption is not
FDI flows to MENA countries. As mentioned in the introduc- unrealistic given the tendency in many cases for countries to
tion, a first best approach comprises reforms to PRP domestic adopt bilateral investment treaties as models with standard-
institutional functions only, whereas a second best approach ized articles and clauses and to broadly define investment in
comprises reforms to domestic PRP institutional functions in such a way that reflects the interest in protecting and encour-
addition to entering into force bilateral investment treaties, aging foreign investment in all its forms, present and
and the interaction between the two. future. 20, 21
(i) First hypothesis:
A first best approach to PRP institutional reform has a po-
sitive influence on FDI flows to MENA countries. 6. EMPIRICAL ISSUES AND ESTIMATION
METHODOLOGY
H0 : b2 6 0
H1 : b2 > 0 In constructing the empirical model, a number of issues
should be considered: nonstationarity, endogeneity, heteroge-
neity, and serial correlation. 22 We address these issues by
(i) Second hypothesis:
adopting RE/FE and GMM estimators.
A second best approach to PRP institutional reform has a
positive influence on FDI flows to MENA countries.
(a) Nonstationarity
H0 : b2 6 0; b3 6 0; b4 6 0
In the presence of nonstationarity, we could end up with
H1 : b2 > 0; b3 > 0; b4 > 0 spurious regressions. Therefore, to detect nonstationarity, we
THE INSTITUTIONAL REFORMS DEBATE AND FDI FLOWS TO THE MENA REGION: THE “BEST” ENSEMBLE 1803

use a battery of panel unit root tests. The first test is the Levin, country effect, li , in addition to a disturbance term mi;t . The
Lin, and Chu (LLC) unit root test, which assumes identical lagged dependent variable is correlated with the country effect
first-order autoregressive coefficients across countries. The test li and thus the error term li þ mi;t . To eliminate the unobserv-
involves the following regression equation: able country effect, the GMM estimator takes the first differ-
ence:
X
k
Dy it ¼ ai þ ci y it1 þ aj Dy itj þ eit ð2Þ Dy i;t ¼ aDy i;t1 þ b0 DX i;t þ Dmi;t ð4Þ
j¼1
Although the unobservable country effect is eliminated with
The subscripts i and t are country and time indicators with differencing, an endogenous bias may still arise from the cor-
i = 1, . . . , N and t = 1, . . . ,T. The null hypothesis H0: ci ¼ relation between the lagged difference of the dependent vari-
c ¼ 0; 8 i against the alternative hypothesis H1: c1 ¼ c2 ¼ able and the error term. In this case we use instrumental
   ¼ cN < 0; 8i: variables. The difference GMM estimator uses the lagged levels
We also use the Im, Pesaran, and Shin (IPS) W-stat and the of the explanatory variables as instruments on two conditions:
Augmented Dickey Fuller–Fisher Chi-squared tests, which al- that the error term of the differenced equation is not serially
low the first-order autoregressive coefficients to vary across correlated and that the lagged levels of the explanatory vari-
countries under the alternative hypothesis H1: ci < 0; 8i. 23 ables are weakly exogenous. We write the moment conditions
as follows:
(b) Endogeneity
E½y i;ts ðmi;t  mi;t1 Þ ¼ 0 for s P 2; t ¼ 3; . . . ; T ð5Þ
Endogeneity is defined in terms of the correlation between
the explanatory variables and the error term. It results in E½X i;ts ðmi;t  mi;t1 Þ ¼ 0 for s P 2; t ¼ 3; . . . ; T ð6Þ
inconsistent Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) estimates. Endoge-
neity may result from unobservable country-specific effects, To ensure that these moment conditions are satisfied, we test
simultaneity, and variable omission. the lack of second-order serial correlation and use a Sargan
In panel data, endogeneity may result from the presence of test of over-identifying restrictions to test for instrument valid-
time-invariant, unobservable, country-specific effects. Such ity.
unobservable effects result in a correlation between the explan-
atory variables or lagged dependent variable and the error (c) Heterogeneity and serial correlation
term. In the presence of unobservable country-specific effects,
one can adopt Fixed Effects (FE) or Random Effects (RE) esti- The performance of MENA countries is heterogeneous with
mators. If the individual country effects are assumed to be a respect to FDI inflows, domestic institutional functions, and
fixed constant over time and can be estimated, then one can the number of bilateral investment treaties entered into force,
adopt the fixed effects estimator. Alternatively, if they are as- as well as the natural and human resource endowments, as dis-
sumed to be randomly distributed, then one can adopt a RE cussed in Section 3. This is likely to generate heteroskedasticity
estimator. To confirm the selection of one type of model over in the error term. In the presence of heteroskedasticity, coeffi-
the other, we use a Hausman specification test. cient estimates are consistent but inefficient, and their standard
Endogeneity may also result from simultaneity, variable errors will be biased and result in inference problems. We con-
omission, and measurement error. Simultaneity arises from duct a Wald test for panel heterogeneity on the empirical mod-
the reverse causality between FDI inflows on the one hand els containing a stationary time series, and the lagged
and bilateral investment treaties entered into force and domes- explanatory variables that the Granger-causality tests detected
tic institutional functions on the other. In dealing with simul- were endogenous.
taneity, we conduct a Granger-causality test on the stationary In the presence of serial correlation, coefficient estimates are
time series to identify whether FDI Granger causes INSTI- consistent but inefficient, and the standard errors are biased.
TFN, BIT, or any of the explanatory variables. If we identify To detect the presence of serial correlation, we conduct a test
any reverse causality, we lag that explanatory variable. for serial correlation in the idiosyncratic errors of a linear pa-
Lagging the explanatory variable is one way to deal with nel-data model as demonstrated by Wooldridge (2002). Final-
endogeneity, as Neumayer and Spess (2005) and Tobin and ly, we test whether the panels are correlated or independent of
Rose-Ackerman (2006) have shown. each other using the Breusch–Pagan LM test of independence.
Variable omission can be associated with unobservable
country-specific effects such as the strength of a MENA coun-
try’s relations with a bilateral investment treaty partner or 7. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
with variables that can influence FDI flows but cannot be in-
cluded in the empirical model due to data unavailability, such We report the panel unit root test results in Table 3. The re-
as the ownership advantages of foreign corporations. sults indicate that FDI is stationary in the level. We also see
In facing this and other sources of endogeneity, we adopt a that not all domestic institutional functions INSTITFN are
dynamic panel GMM approach in estimating the empirical stationary in the levels. Corruption, law and order, and gov-
model given in Eqn. (1) following Arellano and Bond ernment stability are stationary in level. However, for invest-
(1991). To explain the GMM estimator, consider the following ment profile and bureaucracy quality, the LLC test indicates
empirical model: their stationarity based on a rejection of the null hypothesis
of a common unit root in the panel of eight countries. IPS
y i;t ¼ ay i;t1 þ b0 X i;t þ li þ mi;t i ¼ 1; . . . ; N t ¼ 1; . . . ; T and ADF-Fisher tests, on the other hand, fail to reject the null
ð3Þ hypothesis of individual unit roots. However, the three tests
do indicate the stationarity of the two series in difference form.
where yi,t is the dependent variable and Xi,t is the vector of We therefore use these two variables in difference form. 24 The
explanatory variables, and the subscripts i and t denote coun- stationarity results of WFDIFLOWS are similar to those of
try and time periods. The error term comprises unobservable the investment profile and bureaucracy quality. BIT and the
1804 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 3. Panel unit root tests


Variable (log) Variable form LLC IPS ADF-Fisher Decision
FDI Level 11.344a 3.504a 34.016a Stationary
INSTITFN
Investment profile Level 2.483a .890 18.254 Mixed
Difference 7.783a 5.505a 58.647a Stationary
Corruption Level 19.454a 7.897a 23.246c Stationary
Law and order Level 7.742a 6.330a 65.190a Stationary
Bureaucratic quality Level 2.360a .763 11.501 Mixed
Difference 2.820a 2.424a 12.986a Stationary
Government stability Level .8.791a 5.410a 55.388a Stationary
BIT Level 7.185a 6.024a 58.498a Stationary
BITINSTITFN
Investment profile Level 2.660a 2.623a 29.447a Stationary
Corruption Level 3.732a 3.032a 30.400a Stationary
Law and order Level 2.553a 2.762a 30.574a Stationary
Bureaucratic quality Level 1.386c 1.933b 20.825c Stationary
Government stability Level 2.461a 2.651a 29.579a Stationary
OIL Level .474 1.439 13.69 Nonstationary
Difference 6.223a 5.297a 52.034a Stationary
PRICE Level 11.534 8.559 0.012 Nonstationary
Difference 12.421a 9.539a 97.011a Stationary
LABOR Level 2.636 4.73 7.426 Nonstationary
Difference 10.344a 8.058a 77.353a Stationary
TRADE Level 1.493 2.174 10.604 Nonstationary
Difference 6.981a 5.189a 55.009a Stationary
INFLATION Level 0.882 0.605 15.335 Nonstationary
Difference 13.042a 10.816a 104.52a Stationary
WFDIFLOWS Level 2.061b 0.599 12.512 Mixed
Difference 1.539c 4.052a 43.080a Stationary
Notes: LLC tests for common unit root, while IPS and ADF-Fisher test for individual unit roots. Panel unit root tests include individual intercept,
respectively. BITINSTITFN is in level.
a
Significance at p < 0.01 level.
b
Significance at p < 0.05 level.
c
Significance at p < 0.1.

interaction terms are stationary in level. The remaining Table 4. Granger causality test results
explanatory variables OIL, PRICE, LABOR, TRADE, and Variable Variable form Test statistic
INFLATION are stationary in difference form.
INSTITFN
We report in Table 4 the results of the Granger-causality
Investment profile Level 0.927
tests assessing whether FDI Granger-causes INSTITFN, Investment profile Difference 0.071c
BIT, or any of the explanatory variables. The results are re- Corruption Level 0.43
ported for one lag. Test statistics indicate the rejection of the Law and order Level 0.256
null hypothesis of FDI not Granger-causing investment pro- Bureaucracy quality Level 0.033b
file, government stability, BIT, PRICE, LABOR, and INFLA- Bureaucratic quality Difference 0.572
TION. Test statistics also indicate the rejection of the null for Government stability Level 0.035b
the interaction terms, except for that between bilateral invest- BIT Level 0.031b
ment treaties and corruption. Accordingly, we lag these vari- BITINSTITFN
ables twice in the empirical model. Investment profile Level 5.391b
In Table 5, we report the results of heteroskedasticity, serial Corruption Level 1.008
correlation, and panel independence. The results of the Wald Law and order Level 4.974b
test for panel heterogeneity indicate that the null hypothesis Bureaucratic quality Level 7.338a
of homoskedasticity is rejected at the 1% level. The results Government stability Level 4.825b
of the Wooldridge test of serial correlation indicate the rejec- OIL Difference 0.816
tion of the null hypothesis of no serial correlation at the 1% PRICE Difference 0.047b
level. Finally, the results of the Breusch–Pagan LM test of LABOR Difference 0.014b
independence also indicate the rejection of independence at TRADE Difference 0.367
the 10% level. INFLATION Difference 0.038b
When the Hausman specification tests recommend the adop- WFDIFLOWS Difference 0.331
tion of the RE model in most specifications, we adopt the fea- Notes: Null hypothesis: FDI does not Granger-cause the explanatory
sible Generalized Least Squares (GLS) estimation variable. Granger causality test results are reported for one lag. Variable
methodology. We also take into account the results of heter- form, whether level or difference, is based on the panel unit root tests
oskedasticity, serial correlation, and panel independence tests. reported in Table 3. p values reported in test statistic.
a
When Hausman specification tests suggest the adoption of an Significance at p < 0.01 level.
b
FE model, we report the robust estimates. Significance at p < 0.05 level.
c
Significance at p < 0.1 level.
THE INSTITUTIONAL REFORMS DEBATE AND FDI FLOWS TO THE MENA REGION: THE “BEST” ENSEMBLE 1805

Table 5. Diagnostic tests The first lag of the dependent variable has a positive, and
INSTITFN Homoskedasticitya Serial Independencec mostly unitary, influence on FDI flows, which implies the per-
correlationb sistence of FDI flows to the region. As column 1 suggests, a
1% increase in the last period’s FDI flows increases current
Investment profile 0.000 0.000 0.088
FDI flows by 0.92%.
Corruption 0.000 0.000 0.093
Among the different domestic institutional functions that
Law and order 0.000 0.000 0.08
influence FDI flows, a lessening in the risk of investment expro-
Bureaucratic quality 0.000 0.000 0.086
priation and improvement in government stability have a posi-
Government stability 0.000 0.000 0.037
tive influence, while an improvement in corruption (i.e., less
Notes: Test statistics are reported for models containing the domestic corruption) has a surprisingly negative influence. As the invest-
institutional function in the first column. ment profile is in difference form, a 1% improvement in the
a
Modified Wald test for groupwise heteroskedasticity; the null hypothesis
growth rate of the investment profile results in an increase in
is homoskedasticity.
b
Wooldridge tests for autocorrelation in panel data; the null hypothesis is FDI flows of 0.7%. This positive influence holds regardless of
that no autocorrelation exists. the inclusion of the interaction term in the model. Government
c
Breusch–Pagan LM test of independence of cross-section residuals; the stability on the other hand has a striking but nonrobust posi-
null hypothesis is independence. p values reported. tive influence on FDI flows. With government stability in level
rather in difference, an improvement in government stability by
1% results in an increase in FDI flows of more than 3%. How-
(a) RE and FE estimates ever, this positive influence becomes statistically insignificant
when the interaction term is included in the model.
Table 6 reports the RE and FE estimates. Unless otherwise In contrast to investment profile and government stability, a
noted in the column heading, the RE estimates are reported. decrease in corruption has a surprisingly negative and robust

Table 6. Institutional functions, bilateral investment treaties, and FDI flows to nonGCC countries—RE (FGLS) and FE estimation (based on common and
individual panel unit roots and Granger-causality test statistics). Dependent variable: log of FDI inflows per capita
Variables (form) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)
IP IP+ C C/FE C+ L&O L&O+ BQ BQ+ GS/FE GS+/FE
FDI (L) 0.918a 0.909a 0.848a 0.541a 0.851a 0.893a 0.845a 0.891a 0.867a 0.509a 0.505a
(0.059) (0.060) (0.062) (0.173) (0.064) (0.061) (0.068) (0.063) (0.064) (0.157) (0.153)
FDI (L2) 0.141b 0.139b 0.124b 0.038 0.122b 0.124b 0.082 0.115c 0.097 0.047 0.071
(0.056) (0.058) (0.059) (0.145) (0.062) (0.059) (0.067) (0.062) (0.063) (0.141) (0.136)
INSTITFN (*) 0.700b 0.695c 0.699a 1.761b 0.782a 0.069 0.156 0.034 0.041 3.151b 2.245
(0.356) (0.370) (0.133) (0.708) (0.143) (0.371) (0.435) (0.388) (0.399) (1.388) (1.480)
BIT (L2) 0.142a 0.462 0.113b 0.054 0.124b 0.136b 0.274 0.131b 0.035 0.028 3.430
(0.055) (0.675) (0.052) (0.115) (0.054) (0.056) (0.529) (0.058) (0.205) (0.128) (3.842)
BITINSTITFN (**) 0.165 0.152b 0.264 0.292 1.496
(0.332) (0.065) (0.347) (0.304) (1.672)
OIL (D) 0.154 0.144 0.102 0.008 0.161 0.100 0.100 0.099 0.092 0.037 0.070
(0.131) (0.135) (0.135) (0.210) (0.151) (0.134) (0.153) (0.135) (0.139) (0.207) (0.217)
PRICE (L2.D) 0.530a 0.603a 0.262b 0.239 0.302b 0.398a 0.356b 0.399a 0.405b 0.502 0.487
(0.136) (0.152) (0.134) (0.343) (0.135) (0.136) (0.160) (0.153) (0.159) (0.363) (0.367)
LABOR (L2.D) 3.636a 3.888a 6.415a 3.241 6.305a 4.338a 4.382a 4.481a 4.139a 1.972 1.490
(1.319) (1.421) (1.138) (2.966) (1.240) (1.263) (1.289) (1.256) (1.323) (2.844) (3.034)
TRADE (D) 2.933a 2.913a 2.283a 2.749 2.415a 2.686a 2.962a 2.538a 2.385a 2.148 2.474
(0.545) (0.570) (0.518) (1.943) (0.544) (0.542) (0.558) (0.549) (0.568) (1.800) (1.654)
INFLATION (L2.D) 0.154b 0.158b 0.048 0.006 0.054 0.150b 0.145c 0.155b 0.144c 0.075 0.102
(0.074) (0.078) (0.070) (0.144) (0.072) (0.074) (0.077) (0.076) (0.077) (0.157) (0.165)
WFDIFLOWS (D) 0.268 0.218 0.269 0.726 0.412b 0.275 0.412c 0.264 0.300 0.916 0.893
(0.182) (0.195) (0.168) (0.560) (0.178) (0.185) (0.220) (0.198) (0.212) (0.599) (0.586)
Constant 0.607a 0.636a 1.412a 2.842b 1.380a 0.750 0.880 0.637a 0.666a 5.522b 3.541
(0.147) (0.151) (0.220) (1.163) (0.232) (0.631) (0.697) (0.138) (0.143) (2.704) (3.059)
Observations 120 120 120 120 120 120 120 120 120 120 120
R-squared 0.644 0.648 0.654
Wald test v2 756.51a 687.1a 942.4a 11.66a 995.34a 793.6a 576.9a 803.32a 786.62a 9.99a 10.24a
t statistic
H0: b2 6 0 1.966b 1.878b 5.256 2.487 5.469 0.186 0.359 0.088 0.103 2.270a 1.517c
H0: b2 + b3 + b4 6 0 1.835b 3.352 0.305 0.515 0.101
Notes: “IP,” “C,” “L&O,” “BQ,” and “GS” are investment profile, corruption, law and order, bureaucracy quality, and government stability, respectively.
+ indicates the inclusion of BITINSTIFN in the regression model. L, L2, and D refer to the first lag, second lag, and difference, respectively. RE (FGLS)
estimation is used unless otherwise noted. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. Heteroskedasticity and within (panel specific AR1) and across
correlations are accounted for. The one-sided critical t values at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels for df = 120 are 2.358, 1.658, and 1.289, respectively.
*
The second lags of the difference of IP and BQ are used, while for GS the second lag is used. BIT is the annual number of bilateral investment treaties.
**
The second lags of the interaction term with IP, L&O, BQ, and GS are used.
a
Significance at p < 0.01 level.
b
Significance at p < 0.05 level.
c
Significance at p < 0.1 level.
1806 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

influence. As the RE and FE estimates show in columns 3, 4, ens. In other words, there is institutional complementarity be-
and 5, an improvement or lessening in corruption by 1% de- tween corruption and bilateral investment treaties.
creases FDI flows by approximately 0.7% and 1.8% and by Finally LABOR, TRADE, and PRICE have positive and
approximately 0.8% when an interaction term is included in statistically significant coefficients suggesting that more labor
the empirical model. This result may suggest that less corrup- productivity, trade openness, and higher oil prices result in
tion is associated with better economic policies, which pro- more FDI flows. The LABOR and TRADE coefficients are
mote more domestic savings and investment and reduce the largest, suggesting that labor productivity and trade open-
reliance on foreign capital. The influence of law and order ness are the most influential FDI drivers in MENA countries.
and bureaucracy quality is statistically insignificant.
The influence of bilateral investment treaties seems mixed, (b) GMM estimates
however the statistically significant influence is positive. This
positive influence is observed in some of the specifications Given the nature of the difference GMM estimator, and to
containing investment profile, corruption, and law and or- examine the influence of the annual number of bilateral invest-
der. Bilateral investment treaties with OECD countries can ment treaties, we include in the estimation the total (cumula-
therefore be considered useful in the promotion of FDI tive) number of bilateral investment treaties. Additionally, in
flows. all specifications, we fail to reject the null hypotheses of the
The interaction between bilateral investment treaties and Sargan over-identification and serial correlation tests and con-
domestic institutional functions is statistically insignificant, clude that instruments are not correlated with the residuals,
with the exception of the interaction with corruption. Such and errors in first difference regression exhibit no second-order
interaction is positive and statistically significant at the 5% le- serial correlation.
vel. This suggests that bilateral investment treaties increase GMM estimates are mostly similar to the RE/FE estimates.
FDI flows per capita as corruption in MENA countries less- We should keep in mind that the dependent variable is now the
Table 7. Institutional functions, bilateral investment treaties, and FDI flows to nonGCC countries—GMM estimation. Dependent variable: log of FDI inflows
per capita
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
IP IP+ C C+ L&O L&O+ BQ BQ+ GS GS+
FDI (L.D) 0.327a 0.313a 0.362a 0.362a 0.379a 0.355a 0.349a 0.342a 0.350a 0.343a
(0.107) (0.111) (0.101) (0.103) (0.093) (0.092) (0.074) (0.083) (0.101) (0.104)
FDI (L2.D) 0.126 0.125 0.125 0.113 0.141 0.120 0.075 0.058 0.166 0.155
(0.149) (0.135) (0.175) (0.177) (0.184) (0.179) (0.230) (0.211) (0.153) (0.150)
INSTITFN (D) 2.911a 4.089a 0.735 0.498 0.248 0.210 1.707 2.484 4.332b 6.253a
(0.700) (0.848) (0.658) (0.614) (0.623) (0.582) (1.334) (1.548) (2.027) (2.402)
BIT (D) 0.073 0.941a 0.043 0.000 0.043 0.432a 0.110 0.307a 0.022 1.038b
(0.058) (0.236) (0.067) (0.083) (0.071) (0.098) (0.088) (0.115) (0.072) (0.436)
BITINSTITFN (D) 0.471a 0.120b 0.329a 0.608a 0.474b
(0.107) (0.060) (0.086) (0.201) (0.196)
OIL (D) 0.173 0.301b 0.437b 0.560b 0.352b 0.407a 0.495c 0.565b 0.349b 0.380b
(0.173) (0.152) (0.185) (0.222) (0.165) (0.126) (0.260) (0.252) (0.176) (0.162)
PRICE (D) 0.955a 0.991a 0.483a 0.383b 0.484a 0.445a 0.473b 0.492b 0.981a 0.830b
(0.237) (0.194) (0.174) (0.158) (0.164) (0.156) (0.187) (0.215) (0.361) (0.367)
LABOR (D) 0.369 0.337 1.062 0.559 1.761 0.920 1.124 0.694 2.087 0.137
(1.485) (1.224) (1.760) (2.070) (1.286) (1.456) (1.808) (1.684) (1.787) (2.107)
TRADE (D) 2.844b 3.375a 2.571 2.918 2.361 2.698 2.983c 3.107b 2.632c 2.829b
(1.370) (1.071) (1.768) (1.857) (1.834) (1.774) (1.738) (1.391) (1.487) (1.395)
INFLATION (D) 0.254b 0.253b 0.253b 0.212b 0.267b 0.259b 0.244a 0.331a 0.115b 0.070
(0.100) (0.113) (0.107) (0.098) (0.104) (0.110) (0.071) (0.102) (0.050) (0.058)
WFDIFLOWS (D) 0.219 0.362 0.414 0.509 0.309 0.386 0.266 0.259 0.090 0.226
(0.414) (0.435) (0.477) (0.498) (0.430) (0.403) (0.473) (0.444) (0.379) (0.428)
Constant 0.050 0.125 0.004 0.004 0.063 0.040 0.097 0.064 0.046 0.057
(0.123) (0.113) (0.161) (0.161) (0.126) (0.125) (0.137) (0.125) (0.137) (0.135)
Observations 136 136 136 136 136 136 136 136 136 136
Wald test v2 89.7a 260.28a 159.2a 60.63a 267.91a 182.8a 738.9a 638.7a 110.3a 153.4a
Sargan test v2 143.66 140.32 139.8 138.7 140.4 140.2 138.55 134.8 134.4 128.2
Serial correlation test (p values) 0.429 0.445 0.437 0.426 0.439 0.426 0.38 0.371 0.575 0.61
t statistic
H0: b2 6 0 4.159a 4.822a 1.117 0.811 0.398 0.361 1.280 1.605 2.137b 2.603a
H0: b2 + b3 + b4 6 0 4.803a 0.998 0.550 1.521 2.602a
Notes: “IP,” “C,” “L&O,” “BQ,” and “GS” are investment profile, corruption, law and order, bureaucracy quality, and government stability, respectively.
+ indicates the inclusion of BITINSTIFN in the regression model, respectively. One-step GMM estimator results are reported. Robust standard errors are
in parentheses. L, L2, and D refer to the first lag, second lag, and difference, respectively. BIT is the cumulative rather than the annual number of bilateral
investment treaties entered into force. H0 for Sargan over-identification test: instruments not correlated with residuals. H0 for serial correlation test: errors
in first-difference regression exhibit no second-order serial correlation. The one-sided critical t values at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels for df = 120 are 2.358,
1.658, and 1.289, respectively.
a
Significance at p < 0.01 level.
b
Significance at p < 0.05 level.
c
Significance at p < 0.1 level.
THE INSTITUTIONAL REFORMS DEBATE AND FDI FLOWS TO THE MENA REGION: THE “BEST” ENSEMBLE 1807

growth rate of FDI flows. The lagged growth rate has a posi- 8. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
tive influence on the current growth rate, suggesting the persis-
tence of growth rates. In this research we explore how MENA countries can ap-
The risk of investment expropriation and government stabil- proach institutional reforms that strengthen PRP. A first best
ity positively influence FDI flows, as Table 7 shows. An approach is to strengthen their domestic institutional func-
improvement in the growth rate of investment profile by 1%, re- tions to approach the performance of industrialized countries.
sults in a tripling or quadrupling of the growth rate of FDI flows, Alternatively, countries may elect to sign and enter into force
with an even higher magnitude for government stability. The po- bilateral investment treaties in tandem with improving their
sitive influence of bilateral investment treaties is observed in institutional functions—a second best approach.
some of the specifications containing investment profile, law We examine this institutional reform debate in the context
and order, bureaucracy quality, and government stability. of FDI flows to MENA countries. The results confirm that
The coefficients of the interaction terms between bilateral reducing the risk of investment expropriation and improving
investment treaties and domestic institutional functions are government stability have a positive influence on FDI flows
negative in all specifications. Thus, the dynamic panel GMM to MENA countries.
estimator suggests that bilateral investment treaties are substi- The results also confirm the joint positive influence of
tutes for domestic institutional functions in MENA countries. domestically reducing the risk of investment expropriation
Similar to most OIL estimates obtained in the RE/FE mod- and entering into force bilateral investment treaties with
el, OIL coefficients are positive, but are statistically significant OECD countries. However, the interaction between domestic
and with much higher magnitude. PRICE coefficients are also institutional strengthening and entering into force bilateral
much higher than the RE/FE estimates. TRADE coefficients investment treaties to strengthen PRP has a negative influence
are similarly positive and statistically significant. on FDI flows.
Unlike the RE/FE estimates, LABOR coefficients are statis- The policy implications of the results of this paper are
tically insignificant in all specifications. Also INFLATION important. First, to continue attracting FDI flows, MENA
coefficients are negative and suggest that the growth in infla- countries need to protect investors and enhance government
tion rate discourages the growth rate in FDI flows. stability. Government expropriation of foreign investment cre-
ates uncertainty about the return on investment and deters
(c) Institutional reform hypotheses investment. Similarly, government instability generates uncer-
tainty about the economic and political principles of the coun-
The two hypotheses regarding a first best or a second best try, which essentially govern foreign investments.
approach to PRP institutional reforms can now be tested Second, when the attempt to strengthen domestic institu-
based on the estimates obtained under both methodologies tional functions is fraught with challenges and/or MENA gov-
in Tables 6 and 7. Both methodologies reject the null hypoth- ernments wish to speed reforms and send strong signals about
esis that a first best approach to reducing the risk of invest- their commitment to PRP, it is beneficial to sign and enter into
ment expropriation and government stability has no force bilateral investment treaties. However, the influence of
influence on FDI flows to MENA countries; the strengthening bilateral investment treaties is not as strong as that of domestic
of these two domestic PRP institutional functions has a posi- institutional strengthening. The adoption of a second best ap-
tive influence on FDI flows. Both methodologies also reject proach to strengthening PRP encourages FDI flows, but its suc-
the null hypothesis that a second best approach to reducing cess or positive influence is dependent on the success of the first
the risk of investment expropriation has no influence; PRP best approach. The reform of domestic institutional functions is
can be strengthened by entering into force bilateral investment inevitable for the success of bilateral investment treaties.
treaties with OECD countries in addition to increasing inves- Finally, the question of whether MENA countries should
tor protection domestically. adopt a first or a second best approach to institutional reforms
The GMM estimates reject the null hypothesis that a second is a mere theoretical question. The empirical results indicate
best approach to enhancing government stability has no influ- that the success of the second best approach is dependent on
ence on FDI flows. FE estimates do not reject this null hypoth- the success of the first best approach, thus the two bests be-
esis. come an ensemble.

NOTES

1. By PRP institutional functions we refer to the outcomes of domestic costly to use, and potentially corruptible. In response, firms resort to
institutions, mainly the legal and judicial systems and the government relational contracting as an alternative, building long-term relationships
bureaucracy, which influence the PRP process. Examples of these with each other and sustaining cooperation through repeated interaction.
functions are the issuance of laws, the enforcement of laws, contracts Long term relational contracting is regarded as (better) informal substitute
and order, the restriction of government’s power to expropriate and to the (weak) formal PRP institutions.
extract rents, and the control of corruption.

4. For the sake of brevity, we focus on the main messages of the


2. See, for example, Alfaro, Kalemli-Ozcan, and Volosovych (2008),
literature and leave the literature survey to Mina (2010, 2011).
Asiedu (2006), Busse and Hefeker (2007), Daude and Fratzscher (2008),
Daude and Stein (2007), Du, Lu, and Tao (2008), Faria and Mauro
(2009), Kraay and Nehru (2006), Lane (2004), Mina (2006), Mina and 5. Findings are based on the surveys of Alfaro et al. (2008), Asiedu
Martinez-Vazquez (2006), Mishra and Daly (2007), Naude and Krugell (2006), Busse and Hefeker (2007), Daude and Fratzscher (2008), Daude
(2007), and Wei (2000). and Stein (2007), Du et al. (2008), Faria and Mauro (2009), Kraay and
Nehru (2006), Lane (2004), Mina (2006), Mina and Martinez-Vazquez
3. Using Ghana and Vietnam as examples, Rodrik (2008) argues that (2006), Naude and Krugell (2007), Mishra and Daly (2007), and Wei
despite the presence of commercial laws, courts are highly inefficient, (2000).
1808 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

6. Findings are based on the surveys of Desbordes and Vicard (2009), 26% in 2003, amounting to about two-thirds of the average for the
Egger and Pfaffermayr (2004), Egger and Merlo (2007), Hallward- other two regions.
Driemeier (2003), Kerner (2009), Mina (2009), Neumayer and Spess
(2005), Tobin and Rose-Ackerman (2006), and UNCTAD (1998). 13. In addition, large population size drives market-seeking FDI.

7. This relationship has been examined in Desbordes and Vicard (2009), 14. We should note that because of a high correlation coefficient of
Hallward-Driemeier (2003), Mina (2009), and Neumayer and Spess approximately 0.9 between oil production and domestic market size for
(2005). the sample countries, as measured by either nominal or real GDP, we
decided to omit the latter.
8. Hallward-Driemeier (2003) finds that bilateral investment treaties are
more effective in higher institutional quality settings and where institutions 15. The maximum score for each of these indices is provided in Table 2.
are already being strengthened. She argues that, “This undermines a central
rational for some of the less developed countries that enter into these 16. Correlation coefficients are available from the author.
agreements hoping to bypass the need to strengthen property rights and
institutions more generally. Put differently, if host countries are committed
17. Mina (2007) discusses the possibility of negative oil price influence on
to trying to attract more FDI, BITs have not provided a short-cut from the
FDI flows in GCC countries.
need to implement broader reforms of domestic institutions” (italics added;
pp. 21–22).
18. Bellack et al. (2008) use unit labor costs and labor productivity in
examining the influence of labor costs on FDI flows to Central and
9. Findings are based on Chan and Gemayel (2004), Hisarciklilar,
Eastern European countries.
Kayam, and Kayalica (2007), Kamaly (2002), Onyeiwu (2003), and Mina
(2007).
19. The correlation coefficients are 0.071 for real GDP, 0.254 for
population, 0.288 for labor force, 0.152 for oil production, and 0.407
10. A table that shows the growth in the (5-year) average level of FDI in
for oil revenues relative to GDP.
1980–2008 is available from the author. The growth in FDI over time
obliges the empirical methodology to consider its nonstationarity, as
discussed further in Section 5. 20. For more discussion of this issue, see OECD (2006).

11. A higher score indicates a lower risk. More information on the 21. See Legum (2005).
political risk components is provided in Section 4.
22. See Baltagi (2005) for a discussion of these issues.
12. World Bank (2008) argues that the average level of education,
and thus the level of human capital, is low in MENA relative to East 23. For a discussion of panel unit root tests, see Barbieri (2009) and Lee
Asia and Latin America. The average gross enrollment rate in and Chang (2009).
secondary education amounted to 75% in 2003 in MENA, compared
to 78% and 90% for East Asia and Latin America. Similarly, the 24. Based on the mixed results, we also included these two variables in
average gross enrollment rate in higher education in MENA was only level form in our estimation. The results are available by request.

REFERENCES

Alfaro, L., Kalemli-Ozcan, S., & Volosovych, V. (2008). Why doesn’t Chan, K. K., & Gemayel, E. R. (2004). Risk instability and the pattern of
capital flow from rich to poor countries? An empirical investigation. foreign direct investment in the Middle East and North Africa region.
Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(2), 347–368. IMF Working Paper, WP/04/139.
Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel Daude, C., & Fratzscher, M. (2008). The pecking order of cross-
data: Monte Carlo evidence with an application for employment border investment. Journal of International Economics, 74(1),
equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–297. 94–119.
Asiedu, E. (2006). Foreign direct investment in Africa: The role of natural Daude, C., & Stein, E. (2007). The quality of institutions and foreign
resources, market size, government policy, institutions and political direct investment. Economics and Politics, 19(3), 317–344.
instability. World Economy, 29(1), 63–77. Desbordes, R., & Vicard, V. (2009). Foreign direct investment and
Baltagi, B. (2005). Econometric analysis of panel data. New York: John bilateral investment treaties: An international political perspective.
Wiley & Sons. Journal of Comparative Economics, 37(3), 372–386.
Barbieri, L. (2009). Panel unit root tests under cross-sectional dependence: Dixit, A. (2009). Governance institutions and economic activity. American
An overview. Journal of Statistics: Advances in Theory and Applica- Economic Review, 99(1), 5–24.
tions, 1(2). Du, J., Lu, Y., & Tao, Z. (2008). Economic institutions and FDI location
Bellack, C., Leibrecht, M., & Riedl, A. (2008). Labour costs and FDI choice: Evidence from US multinationals in China. Journal of
flows into Central and Eastern European countries: A survey of the Comparative Economics, 36(3), 412–429.
literature and empirical evidence. Structural Change and Economic Dunning, J. (1981). International production and the multinational enter-
Dynamics, 19(1), 17–37. prise. London: Allen & Unwin.
Bevan, A. A., & Estrin, S. (2004). The determinants of foreign direct Egger, P., & Merlo, V. (2007). The impact of bilateral investment treaties
investment into European transition economies. Journal of Compara- on FDI dynamics. World Economy, 30(10), 1536–1549.
tive Economics, 32(4), 775–787. Egger, P., & Pfaffermayr, M. (2004). The impact of bilateral investment
Blonigen, B. A., & Davies, R. B. (2004). The effects of bilateral tax treaties treaties on foreign direct investment. Journal of Comparative Econom-
on US FDI activity. International Tax and Public Finance, 11(5), ics, 32(4), 788–804.
601–622. Faria, A., & Mauro, P. (2009). Institutions and the external capital
Busse, M., & Hefeker, C. (2007). Political risk, institutions and foreign direct structure of countries. Journal of International Money and Finance,
investment. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(2), 397–415. 28(3), 367–391.
THE INSTITUTIONAL REFORMS DEBATE AND FDI FLOWS TO THE MENA REGION: THE “BEST” ENSEMBLE 1809

Frenkel, M., Funke, K., & Stadtmann, G. (2004). A panel analysis of Mina, W., & Martinez-Vazquez, J. (2006). Contract enforcement, insti-
bilateral FDI flows to emerging economies. Economic Systems, 28(3), tutional stability and the level and maturity of international lending.
281–300. International Studies Program Working Paper No. 06-17.
Hallward-Driemeier, M. (2003). Do bilateral investment treaties attract Mishra, A., & Daly, K. (2007). Effect of quality of institutions on outward
FDI? Only a bit . . . and they could bite. World Bank Policy Research foreign direct investment. Journal of International Trade and Economic
Working Paper 3121. Washington, DC. Development, 16(2), 231–244.
Hisarciklilar, M., Kayam, S. S., & Kayalica, O. (2007). Locational drivers Naude, W. A., & Krugell, W. F. (2007). Investigating geography and
of FDI in MENA countries: A spatial attempt. Munich Personal institutions as determinants of foreign direct investment in Africa using
RePEc Archive (MPRA) Paper No. 2085. panel data. Applied Economics, 39(10–12), 1223–1233.
Kamaly, A. (2002). Evaluation of FDI flows into the MENA region. Neumayer, E., & Spess, L. (2005). Do bilateral investment treaties increase
Department of Economics, American University in Cairo, Mimeo. foreign direct investment to developing countries?. World Development,
Kerner, A. (2009). Why should I believe you? The costs and consequences 33(10), 1567–1585.
of bilateral investment treaties. International Studies Quarterly, 53(1), North, D. C. (1991). Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1),
73–102. 97–112.
Kraay, A., & Nehru, V. (2006). When is external debt sustainable?. World OECD (2006). International investment perspectives 2006. OECD Publish-
Bank Economic Review, 20(3), 341–365. ing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/iip-2006-en.
Lane, P. R. (2004). Empirical perspectives on long-term external debt. Onyeiwu, S. (2003). Analysis of FDI flows to developing countries: Is the
Topics in Macroeconomics, 4(1), 1–21, Available from http://www.be- MENA region different? Paper presented at ERF’s 10th Annual
press.com/bejm/topics/vol4/iss1/art1. Conference, Marrakech, Morocco.
Lee, C.-C., & Chang, C.-P. (2009). FDI, financial development, and Rodrik, D. (2008). Second-best institutions. American Economic Review:
economic growth: International evidence. Journal of Applied Econom- Papers & Proceedings, 98(2), 100–104.
ics, 12(2), 249–271. Tobin, J., & Rose-Ackerman, S. (2006). When BITs have similar bite: The
Legum, B. (2005). Defining investment and investor: Who is entitled to political economic environment for bilateral investment treaties. Yale
claim? Symposium on making the most of international investment Law School, November.
agreements: A common agenda, OECD, Paris. UNCTAD (1998). Bilateral investment treaties in the mid-1990s. Geneva:
Mina, W. (2006). Does contract enforcement matter for international United Nations.
lending?. Applied Economics Letters, 13(6), 359–364. Wei, S.-J. (2000). How taxing is corruption on international investors?.
Mina, W. (2007). The location determinants of FDI in the GCC countries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(1), 1–11.
Journal of Multinational Financial Management, 17(4), 336–348. Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel
Mina, W. (2009). External commitment mechanisms, institutions, and data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
FDI in GCC countries. Journal of International Financial Markets, World Bank (2008). The road not traveled: Education reform in the Middle
Institutions & Money, 19(2), 371–386. East and North Africa. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Mina, W. (2010). Institutional reforms debate and FDI flows to MENA
region: Does one “best” fit all? International Studies Program Working
Paper No. 10-34.
Mina, W. M. (2011). Institutional reforms debate and FDI flows to APPENDIX A
MENA region: Does one “best” fit all? UNU-WIDER Working Paper
No. 2011/50. See Table 8.

Table 8. Variables, definitions, and data sources


Variable Definition Source
FDI FDI annual flows per capita in US$ (in log form) UNCTAD’s FDI online database
BIT Annual number of bilateral investment treaties entered Author’s calculation based on UNCTAD’s bilateral
into force investment treaties online database (as of June 1, 2008)
INSTITFN Domestic PRP institutional functions. These are (a) ICRG political risk index
investment profile, (b) corruption, (c) law and order, and
(d) bureaucracy quality (in log form)
BITINSTITFN Interaction term between BIT and INSTITFN constructed Author’s calculation
as the product of INSTITFN (in log form) and BIT
OIL Oil production in thousands of barrels per day (in log Energy Information Administration
form)
PRICE Crude oil price measured by the price of Saudi Arabian Energy Information Administration
Light 34 in US$/barrel (in log form)
LABOR Real GDP per person employed (in log form) Author’s calculation based on UNCTAD’s bilateral
investment treaties online and World Development Indicators
databases
TRADE Sum of exports and imports as a percentage of GDP (in World Bank’s World Development Indicators
log form)
INFLATION Inflation rate in percentage (in log form). Rate is World Bank’s World Development Indicators
calculated based on the consumer price index, except for
Oman and UAE where it is based on GDP deflator
WFDIFLOWS World FDI inflows in millions of US$ (in log form) Author’s calculation based on UNCTAD’s bilateral
investment treaties online database

You might also like