Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 3

Review

Reviewed Work(s): Feminism and Anti-Feminism in Early Economic Thought. by


Michèle A. Pujol
Review by: Marianne A. Ferber
Source: Journal of Economic Literature , Dec., 1993, Vol. 31, No. 4 (Dec., 1993), pp. 1966-
1967
Published by: American Economic Association

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2728335

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Economic
Literature

This content downloaded from


93.180.40.214 on Thu, 09 Jun 2022 20:38:33 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
1966 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXI (December 1993)
cal reason over such complex domains clearly Mill, particularly after he came under the influ-
must take a more contingent form" (p. 16). ence of Harriet Taylor and the early socialists.
Whether one welcomes such complexities in Even Mill, however, considered employment
moral deliberation is in part a matter of tem- of women to be incompatible with marriage,
perament. Those who elect to delve into the especially when it involved work away from
complexities will find this volume of consider- home, and failed to include women in his dis-
able use. cussions of labor market issues, such as mini-
MICHAEL S. MCPHERSON mum wages.
Williams College An extensive analysis of the publications of
the pioneers of neoclassical economics shows
that while they were somewhat more concerned
REFERENCES
with women s issues, their perspective was not
significantly different from that of their prede-
ELSTER, JON. The cement of society: A study of social
order. NY: Cambridge U. Press, 1989. cessors. Nor did they shrink from outrageous
PARFIT, DEREK. Reasons and persons. Oxford: Clar- inconsistencies when these views proved in-
endon Press, 1984. compatible with their theories. A few examples
REGAN, DONALD. Utilitarianism and co-operation.
will suffice to make this point.
Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1980.
SEN, AMARTYA K. "Rational Fools: A Critique of the They tended to favor labor unions as neces-
Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory," Phi- sary in order to achieve "fair" wages for men,
losophy and Public Affairs, 1977, 6(4), pp. 317- but were opposed to organizing women, or to
44.
ensuring equal pay for equal work, ostensibly
on the grounds that only men have to support
dependents (Francis Y. Edgeworth, "Women's
B Methodology and History of Economic Wages in Relation to Economic Welfare,"
Thought Econ. J., Dec. 1923, 33, pp. 487-95). Their
conviction that the "most precious part of the
Feminism and anti-feminism in early economic capital invested in human beings is the result
thought. By MICHELE A. PUJOL. Aldershot, of the care and influence of the mother" was
U.K.: Elgar: distributed in the U.S. by ignored when comparing the value of human
Ashgate, Brookfield, Vt., 1992. Pp. vii, 228. and physical capital (Alfred Marshall, Principles
$49.95. ISBN 1-85278-456-3. of Economics, London: Macmillan, [1890]
This review of the writings of early econo- 1930). And, like the classical economists, they
mists on women s issues is a useful reminder advocated interference with women's choice
of how much we miss by not devoting more between employment and reproductive activi-
attention to the history of thought. Specifically, ties, while all other interventions in the econ-
we learn to what extent widely acclaimed schol- omy were to be strictly confined to instances
ars can go astray when they are unable to rid where private and public costs and benefits of
themselves of the blinders of tradition. We also individual decisions diverged (Arthur C. Pigou,
learn that useful and potentially important in- The Economics of Welfare, London: Macmillan;
sights of authors who are not in the mainstream 2nd ed., 1924).
may be virtually ignored. It was the early feminists, whose work was
As Pujol points out, women do not figure most often disparaged when it was not entirely
prominently in the work of classical economists. ignored, who contributed many innovative
Adam Smith set the tone by largely ignoring ideas that have finally gained currency today.
their contributions in the labor market, and not Such little known writers as Barbara L. S. Bodi-
recognizing their nonmarket work as pro- chon (Women and Work, London: Bosworth
ductive. Ironically, the father of the "invisible & Harrison, 1857), Millicent G. Fawcett
hand" also set the precedent of accepting re- ("Equal Pay for Equal Work," Econ. J., Mar.
strictions on women's entry into the labor force. 1918, 28, pp. 1-6), Ada Heather-Bigg ("The
From then on, economists of this school tended Wife's Contribution to Family Income," Econ.
to subject women to not-so-benign neglect. J., Mar. 1894, 4, pp. 51-58), Eleanor Rathbone
The one notable exception was John Stuart ("The Remuneration of Women's Services,"

This content downloaded from


93.180.40.214 on Thu, 09 Jun 2022 20:38:33 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Book Reviews 1967

Econ. J., Mar. 1917, 27, pp. 55-68), and Wil- what the book is supposed to be about. The
liam Smart (Studies in Economics, London: explanation, no doubt, is that Pujol unquestion-
Macmillan, 1895) deviated from their more cel- ingly links patriarchy and capitalism, as though
ebrated peers by emphasizing the importance neither could exist without the other. This is
of dual labor markets in keeping women's wages by no means self-evident, and detracts from
low. They advocated education and training to the main focus of this otherwise thoughtful and
increase women's productivity, opening up well-documented book.
nontraditional occupations to women in order MARIANNE A. FERBER
to avoid crowding in female fields, and provid- University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign
ing family allowances for women, in recognition
of the value of their contributions in the house- Radical economics. Edited by BRUCE ROBERTS
hold. But their views "failed to acquire even a AND SUSAN FEINER. Recent Economic
semblance of legitimacy within the orthodox Thought Series. Norwell, Mass. and Dor-
economics discourse" (p. 199). drecht: Kluwer Academic, 1992. Pp. vi, 252.
Thus Pujol succeeds in providing strong sup- $57.50. ISBN 0-7923-9178-0. JEL 93-0020
port for her claim that the Radical economics in the United States
emerged in the late 1960s, not initially as a
neoclassical paradigm is based on a point of view theoretical movement, but as a form of disci-
which excludes women from the sphere of eco-
plined outrage at racism, militarism, and the
nomic rationality: they are construed as not be-
longing in the market sphere and as unmotivated vast disparities of wealth, power, and life oppor-
by self-interest. tunities in contemporary capitalist societies.
With the onset of stagflation in the 1970s, radi-
She also extensively documents that cal economists also began exploring the sources
of growth, stagnation, and instability under cap-
their exclusion [of women] from the realm of
italism. Not surprisingly, given these initial
economic rationality yields contradictory situa-
tions. (p. 199) concerns, most radical economists in some form
embraced Marxism as an analytic framework
Most shocking is not merely that thinkers and socialism as a political agenda, even while
widely acclaimed for their objectivity indulged harboring few illusions about the Soviet Union
in biased and normative judgments, but rather and other Communist states.
that they appear to have been totally unaware Over the past 20 years, a major feature of
that they were guilty of such practices. the maturing of radical economics has been the
Along with its considerable virtues this book, deepening of its theoretical foundations. This
however, also has shortcomings. For one, the volume is a survey of the work in various theo-
author goes to extremes in explaining to her retical fields over the past 20 years. It includes
readers what they will be told, then telling six essays in the areas of class analysis, the labor
them, and then explaining what they were told. theory of value, analytic Marxism, Marxist-fem-
This results in a great deal of unnecessary repe- inism, theories of accumulation and crisis, and
tition, aggravated by the tendency to discuss development economics. Each essay is followed
individual publications separately, rather than by a substantial comment by a recognized au-
simply presenting the gist of each scholar's thor in the various specialized fields. The edi-
work, with perhaps some explanation how their tors are associated with the post-modern school
views may have changed over time. Pujol also of radical economics around the journal Re-
has the annoying (though regrettably not un- thinking Marxism, and this approach is dispro-
common) habit of using words that can not be portionately represented. But the volume still
found in the dictionary, such as "caricatural" includes a wide range of authors and spirited
(p. 4) and "revolutioning" (p. 5), to mention debates.
only two examples. Much of the book concentrates on various
Last, but by no means least, we learn almost aspects of the analytics of class exploitation.
as much about the procapitalist views of classi- Within traditional Marxian analysis, Makoto
and neoclassical economists as about their Itoh examines the so-called "transformation
antifeminist convictions, although this is not problem"-the technique through which the

This content downloaded from


93.180.40.214 on Thu, 09 Jun 2022 20:38:33 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like