Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 12

International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

International Review of Financial Analysis

Does cross-border syndication affect venture capital risk and return?☆


Susanne Espenlaub a, Arif Khurshed a, Abdulkadir Mohamed b,⁎
a
Manchester Business School, University of Manchester, Manchester, UK
b
School of Management, University of Liverpool, Liverpool, UK

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Venture capital (VC) cross-border syndication has increased significantly in recent years. This study examines the
Received 19 March 2012 risk and returns of investments of US–European cross-border syndicates in US portfolio companies. We use a
Received in revised form 10 October 2013 large sample of investments across four financing stages, and highlight several noteworthy differences between
Accepted 12 October 2013
cross-border syndicates and previous US-only evidence. By comparison, US–European syndicates are larger than
Available online 21 October 2013
US-only syndicates, involve younger VCs, and focus more on later financing stages. Controlling for sample
JEL classification:
selection bias caused by the endogenous choices of exit route and exit timing, we examine the risk and returns
G24 of investments backed by cross-border syndicates. Consistent with evidence from US-only syndicates, alpha
G32 and beta decrease monotonically from the earliest (start-up) stage to the later stages of financing.
© 2013 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
Keywords:
Venture capital
Cross border
Risk and return
Syndication

1. Introduction of the VC investment (Lerner, 1994). Amit (2002) concludes that


syndication can add value to the investment, based on his finding
In recent years, cross-border venture capital (VC) investments that the more VC firms participate in the financing, the greater are
have increased substantially in terms of the amounts of capital, the overall benefits to backers and entrepreneurs. Recent studies on
numbers of deals and range of industries involved (Guler & Guillen, cross-border syndicates outside the US investigate why VC firms rely on
2010). Typically, in an international VC syndicate, local investors team cross-border syndicates when they internationalize their investments,
up with foreign investors in order to invest in a local entrepreneurial and emphasize the importance of the legal and institutional frameworks
company (Meuleman & Wright, 2011). Cross-border syndication may (Lu & Huang, 2010; Tykvova & Schertler, 2011). Wright, Pruthi, and
provide access to more complementary skills and capabilities than Lockett (2005) examine Asian VC markets and point out that investments
domestic syndicates. VC firms may play an important role in the inter- syndicated between local and foreign VC firms require further study.
nationalization of their portfolio companies through their respective Dimov and Milanov (2009) find that more than 73% of VC invest-
home-country product and capital markets (Tykvova & Schertler, ments in the US are syndicated. To date, little is known about the
2011). During the period from 2000 to 2008, more than one third of prevalence of cross-border syndicates between US VC firms and foreign
portfolio companies globally received financing from foreign VC firms VC providers. Also, to our knowledge, there are no prior studies of the
(Tykvova & Schertler, 2011). Previous studies of VC syndication focus performance of VC investments in US portfolio companies financed by
on motives for syndication, and document that VC firms syndicate in such cross-border syndicates. Prior studies of syndication, both domestic
order to spread the investment risk, including risks due to the illiquidity and cross-border, examine portfolio companies located outside the US. By
contrast, this study analyzes VC investments in US portfolio companies
made by US VCs syndicating with VCs from outside the US (specifically
Europe).
☆ We are grateful to the editor, Brian Lucey and an anonymous referee for suggestions
that significantly improved the paper. We also thank Ranko Jelic, Norman Strong,
Measuring the risk and returns of VC investments is challenging.
Michael Brennan, Murray Dalziel, Olan Henry, Gary Cook, Martin Lozanno, Ning Gao, Valuations of VC investments can only be observed when a portfolio
Pawel Bilinski, Brahim Saadouni and Axel Buchner for their valuable comments and company goes public or is acquired. Those companies within a VC
suggestions. The authors also wish to thank their colleagues at Manchester Business portfolio that manage to go public or are acquired are likely to be a
School, Liverpool University and the participants of the Financial Management Association
select subsample of comparatively good performers. In addition, the
(Denver 2011) for their helpful comments on earlier drafts of this paper.
⁎ Corresponding author. Fax: +44 151 794 2000. timing of exits, and the resulting return observations, are likely to
E-mail addresses: Susanne.Espenlaub@mbs.ac.uk (S. Espenlaub), vary systematically depending on the characteristics of the investment
Arif.Khurshed@mbs.ac.uk (A. Khurshed), Abdulkadir.Mohamed@liv.ac.uk (A. Mohamed). and the portfolio company, and on the nature and success of the VC

1057-5219/$ – see front matter © 2013 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2013.10.003
14 S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24

Table 1
Previous studies of venture capital risk and returns. The table summarizes the findings of the previous studies on venture capital investments. Only the studies by Cochrane (2005) and
Korteweg and Sorensen (2010) evaluate the risk and returns of investment rounds.

Authors Country of venture Sample and period Methodology Returns (Ri) STD (σ) Systematic
capital firm risk (β)

Seppä and Laamanen (2001) US VC fund level (1998–1999) Binomial/OLS model NR NR NR


Chen, Baierl, and Kaplan (2002) US VC fund level (1999) Method of moments 45% all stages 115.6% NR
(repeated sale approach)
Ljungqvist and Richardson (2003) US VC fund level (1981–1993) Proportional hazard model 19.81% all stages 22.29% 1.09 all stages
Woodward (2004) US Company data (1990–2003) Method of moments NR 50% 2.0 all stages
(building an index)
Cochrane (2005) US Company data (1987–2000) Selection bias (maximum likelihood) 71% Start-up 96% 1.1 Start up
65% Early stage 98% 0.9 Early stage
60% Expansion 98% 0.7 Expansion
50% Later stage 99% 0.5 Later stage
Hege et al. (2008) US & Europe Company data (1997–2003) OLS 62% (US) NR NR
106% (EU)
Korteweg and Sorensen (2010)ab US Company data (1985–2005) Selection bias 2246% Seed 117% 0.7414
60.10% Early 134% 2.742
10.9% Late 148% 2.628
85.41% Mezz 135% 5.888

NR: not reported.


a
The returns are annualized and based on Table 8.
b
The standard deviations are annualized and based on Table 5.

investments. For instance, Gompers and Lerner (2000) highlight the 2. Literature review
tendency of VCs to delay the liquidations of poor investments and
the consequent realization and reporting of negative returns. The Sahlman (1990) is a seminal study of the structure of the US VC
resulting sample selection biases with regard to observed exit routes industry and the relationship between investors and VC firms.
and timing is a fundamental problem in evaluating the risk and returns Gompers (1995) investigates the structure of staged VC investments in
of VC investments, and our study seeks to address and control for these the presence of agency and monitoring costs. Hellmann and Puri (2002)
biases. investigate the contributions of VC firms to start-up companies located
We study the risk and returns of syndicated financing rounds in Silicon Valley.
between US and European VC firms in US portfolio companies.1 We Lerner (1994) studies (US-only) VC syndication in biotechnology
focus on portfolio companies that received VC financing from two or entrepreneurial companies and investigates the rationales for syn-
more VC firms, where at least one VC firm is European and at least dication. He finds that experienced VCs syndicate with other experienced
one is based in the US. We chose Europe because it is the second largest backers in early-stage investments, while in later-stage investments ex-
VC industry after the US. US–European cross-border syndicates are an perienced VCs syndicate with both experienced and inexperienced ones.
interesting case whose study minimizes the impact of differences in Lockett and Wright (2001) report that small VC firms have difficulty
legal and institutional settings on cross-border risk and returns. This achieving optimal portfolio diversification, and syndication allows them
facilitates the comparison of our results with those of prior studies of to achieve a well diversified portfolio. According to Arberk, Filatotchev,
the risk-return trade-off of VC investments by US-only VCs and VC and Wright (2006), the fact that VC investments are illiquid and syn-
syndicates (Cochrane, 2005; Korteweg & Sorensen, 2010). dication is used as a risk-sharing mechanism means that studying VC
We document some interesting similarities and differences between syndication is crucial to understanding the activities of VC firms.
US VCs and US–European cross-border syndicates, in terms of the invest- The aim of this study is not to contribute to our understanding of the
ment behavior and performance. Comparable to studies of US VCs, we motives for syndication (Bent, Williams, & Gilber, 2004; Brander, Amit,
find that US–European cross-border syndicates face a monotonically & Antweiler, 2002; Casamatta & Haritchabalet, 2007; Fleming, 2004;
decreasing relationship between both abnormal performance (alpha) Lockett & Wright, 2003). Rather we aim to investigate the risk and
and systematic risk (beta), on the one hand, and the stage of VC financing, returns of US–European cross-border syndicated investments (taking
on the other hand. That is, VC investments in earlier financing stages have the composition of these syndicates as given).
higher abnormal returns and higher systematic risk than corresponding There are a number of studies that examine the risk and returns of
investments in later stages. We document significant evidence of sample VC investments (see Cochrane, 2005; Korteweg & Sorensen, 2010;
selection bias. Nevertheless, our findings on the risk and returns of VC Woodward, 2004), but these studies focus on investments by US-only
investments are remarkably robust across alternative methods of dealing VCs and VC syndicates. As we document below, US VC firms have
with selection bias. been co-investing with European VCs since the late 1980s. Yet, little
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 reviews the is known about the syndicates. To our knowledge, the risk and returns of
literature on the returns of VC investments; Section 3 describes the European VCs co-investing with US players is as yet unexplored. Table 1
motivation, data sources and the methodology employed; Section 4 summarizes the results of previous studies of VC risk and returns. Only
discusses the empirical findings; Section 5 presents the conclusion. Cochrane (2005) and Korteweg and Sorensen (2010) investigate the
risk and returns of VC investments at the level of the individual portfolio
company as opposed to the performance of the VC fund overall.
Seppä and Laamanen (2001) investigate the risk and return profiles
of investments at the VC fund level (correcting for sample selection bias
1
using a binomial model). For a sample of 597 investment rounds
There are a handful of studies of VC returns that analyze the returns at the fund level
rather than the returns of each investment round (Chen et al., 2002; Hege et al., 2008;
between 1998 and 1999, they find that early-stage investments have
Ljungqvist & Richardson, 2003; Woodward, 2004). Typically, there are more financing higher returns and implied volatility than other investment rounds.
rounds than VC funds. Manigart et al. (2002) examine the determinants of VC returns in five
S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24 15

markets: the US, the UK, the Netherlands, Belgium and France from result in a final sample of 26,865 investment rounds made by 2641
1994 to 1997. The authors show that VC firms require higher returns US–European VC syndicates. Of these investments, 6774 result in IPO
for early-stage investments than expansion or later-stage financing. In exits, 13,907 in M&A exits, 2152 in liquidations and 4032 had not
addition to depending on the financing stage, the required returns been exited by the end of the sample period (i.e. 31 December 2010).
depend on the size of the investment and the country of origin of the Our risk-return calculations are based on the subsample of IPOs and
portfolio company. M&As for which realized values are available (not available in the case
Chen, Baierl, and Kaplan (2002) examine the long-term risk and of liquidations and non-exited investments).
return characteristics of VC investments, and their role in long-term
strategic asset allocation. They use 148 VC funds that had liquidated as 3.2. Calculation of holding period returns
of 1999. They report an average arithmetic return of 45%, and a standard
deviation of 115.6%. They conclude that one should only allocate between We compute the holding period return (RT) for each financing round
2% and 9% of a portfolio to VC for the minimum-variance portfolio, due to using the following equation:
the high volatility of VC returns.   
Cochrane (2005) examines the mean, standard deviation, alpha IT It0
RT ¼ −1 where IT ¼ W MT : ð1Þ
(abnormal performance) and beta (systematic risk) of VC investments It0 V t0
in the US. Based on a sample of 16,613 investment rounds between
1987 and 2000, the results show that the expected returns for the first IT is the amount a VC firm receives at the time of exit; It0 is the initial
round are 71%, for the second 65%, for the third round 60% and for the investment in a target company; Vt0 is the value of a portfolio company
fourth round 51%. The betas corresponding to the stages are 1.1, 0.9, immediately after receiving VC funding at t0; W is an adjustment factor
0.7 and 0.5, respectively. Similarly, Korteweg and Sorensen (2010) correcting for changes (dilution) in VC ownership due to changes in
examine the alpha and beta of VC investments in entrepreneurial the portfolio company's valuation across successive investment rounds,
companies. The authors focus on US VC firms and examine the risk as discussed below; MT is the market value of the portfolio company
and returns from 1985 to 2005. Correcting for sample selection bias upon exit. The market value (MT) of the portfolio company is the key
due to the endogenous timing of VC exits (‘dynamic selection bias’), factor in the return calculation, but this information is available only
they find that monthly alphas range from 3.3% to 3.5%, while the betas for IPO and M&A exits.
are more than 1 using the Capital Asset Pricing (CAPM) and three- For investments exited through an IPO, we need to take into account
factor models. the fact that VC backers usually do not sell their entire stake at the time
With the exception of Cochrane (2005) and Korteweg and Sorensen of the IPO (see Cumming, 2008), but instead exit gradually over the first
(2010), previous studies evaluate the risk and returns of VC investments two post-IPO years.2 To account for this, we compute the market value
at the fund level (e.g., Kaplan & Schoar, 2005), often using proprietary of the portfolio company not only at the time of the IPO but also in the
data on the portfolios of companies held by specific VC firms or funds aftermarket up to two years post-IPO. To calculate the market value at
(e.g., Kaplan & Stromberg, 2003, 2004). At the fund level, it is difficult IPO, we multiply the number of shares outstanding after the IPO by
to analyze changes over time and variations across industries, while the IPO offer price. To calculate the aftermarket values, we multiply
our study (along with Cochrane, 2005; Korteweg & Sorensen, 2010) is outstanding shares by the end-of-month share price for each of the
able to examine these aspects using data at the level of the individual 17 months starting from the end of the lock-up agreement (typically
deal (or portfolio company). An added advantage of using deal-level 6 months after the IPO) and ending roughly 24 months after the IPO.
data is that there are many more observations of deals than of VC funds. For each of these 17 months, we compute VC returns adjusting for the
A larger sample improves the reliability of the statistical estimates in different holding periods. Finally, we compute the VC returns on the
our risk-return analysis. investment exited (gradually) through an IPO as the weighted average
This is the first study to examine the risk and returns of co- of one third of the return at the IPO and two thirds of the average
investments by US and European VC firms, as most previous studies monthly returns over the 17-month aftermarket period.3 We apply a
focus on separate samples of either US or European firms. For instance, similar method to the market benchmark to ensure synchronicity in
Hege, Palomino, and Schwienbacher (2008) compare the performance the price observations and the matching of holding periods.
of VC investments between the US and Europe and report internal Note that this adjustment only applies to IPO exits. For M&A exits, we
rates of return (IRR) of 62% for US VCs and 106% for European VCs. assume that the VCs fully realize their investments in a single transaction,
Our analysis sheds light on the differences and similarities between and we use transaction values to calculate the holding period return.
US–European cross-border syndicates and US-only (or European-only) VentureXpert does not provide information on VC holdings in a
VCs and syndicates in terms of their characteristics and performance. portfolio company. We infer VC holdings using an approach similar to
that of Cochrane (2005) and Korteweg and Sorensen (2010). This
3. Data and methodology approach is best explained using an example. Assume that a portfolio
company receives $5 m from a VC firm and is valued at $15 m post-
3.1. Data financing. From these values we can infer that the VC firm owns 33%
of the company. If the company were to receive an additional $15 m
From VentureXpert we extract all investments made during 1985– from a different VC firm and was then valued at $40 m, the second VC
2008 by US–European cross-border syndicates of VC firms, and identify would own 38%, while the first VC's ownership would be reduced to
whether they were exited through an IPO, M&A (including trade sales) 21%.4
or liquidation, or not exited, during 1990–2010. From the database, we
2
collect information on the value of the backed company after receiving We are grateful to the referee for drawing our attention to the limitations of
calculating returns based on IPO prices.
VC financing (post-VC financing value), the country of origin of the VC 3
The weights (1/3, 2/3) are based on the average rate of post-IPO VC exit documented,
firms, the choice of exit route, the number of rounds a portfolio company e.g., by Cumming (2008). For comparison, we report returns calculated (i) on the
received, and the number of VCs in the syndicate. assumption that the entire VC holding is sold through IPO (at the offer price), and
To be included in our sample, a portfolio company should have (ii) on the assumption that it is sold immediately at the end of the lock-up period;
received financing from at least one US and one European VC. Further, see Appendix A for details.
4
Share of the old venture investor I ¼ 0:33ð40
40−15Þ
 100 ¼ 21%: We are aware that
we require that data need to be available on (i) the amount invested some VCs have ‘ratchet agreements’ protecting them from ownership dilution that might
by the VCs, (ii) the post-VC financing company value, and (iii) the arise due to subsequent investment rounds. However, VentureXpert provides no
founding dates of the VCs and the portfolio company. These filter rules information on the type and extent of these agreements for our sample firms.
16 S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24

Finally, we annualize the holding period returns using The conditional probability (P⁎k) is estimated through a multinomial
logit using
1
RAnnual ¼ ð1 þ RT Þ t −1 ð2Þ 
 exp Zγ j
P j InvjExitIPO;M&A;Liq0 n;no exit ¼X : ð7Þ
where t is the period over which investments are held (in years).5 expðZγ k Þ
k

3.3. Sample selection bias Pj is the probability of exit j (or no exit) and is estimated through a
multinomial logit. It is transformed using a polynomial approximation:
In the absence of sample selection bias, systematic risk for a given
 
financing stage can be estimated using the following equation: j nj
λ Pj ¼ λ M j Pj ð8Þ

R j ¼ Xβ j þ ε j ð3Þ
where Mj is a dummy variable that equals one for choice j and zero
otherwise, n is the degree of the polynomial function for Pj. λ(Pj) is a
where Rj is the excess return in stage j, X is the market excess returns, and sample correction term, which depends on the probability Pj and is
βj is the systematic risk in stage j, measuring changes in the investment equivalent to the inverse Mills in the Heckman model. The correction
returns in stage j relative to the market excess returns. function λ() is assumed to have the same form for all financing stages
However, due to the systematic sample selection criterion that invest- that are exited through the IPO route.6
ment returns can only be observed for investments exited through an A consistent estimate of systematic risk for the financing round is
IPO or M&A, the βj estimate is likely to be biased. Therefore, a sample estimated using pooled cross-sectional regression and given by
selection model is required to provide unbiased estimates. If the objective
were to control for the binary outcome of inclusion versus exclusion from 
R j ¼ Xβ j þ λ P j þ ζ j j¼1 ð9Þ
the sample, the Heckman (1979) model would be an appropriate method
by which to control for sample selection bias. However, VC firms do not
face the binary choice of an IPO exit or a non-exit. Instead, they choose where Rj is the excess return for stage j (j = 1 start-up stage, j = 2 early
to exit (or not) through one of several routes, including IPO, M&A or stage, j = 3 expansion stage, and j = 4 the later stage), X contains the
liquidation. This complicates the estimation of βj, as documented in market return, and year and industry dummies. λ(Pj) is the sample
previous studies (Cochrane, 2005, Korteweg & Sorensen, 2010). correction term and includes first- and second-order polynomial
To address the problem of selectivity in the presence of multiple approximations of the probability of an IPO exit.7 Eqs. (7) to (9) are
outcomes, we use a sample selection model proposed by Dahl (2002). estimated simultaneously. We use clustered standard errors to adjust
The model extends the classic Heckman (1979) model in two ways: for the cross-sectional dependence of VC investments.
first, it models various choices as opposed to a single choice in the In addition to adjusting for selection bias due to the choice of exit
selection equation. Second, the probabilities of these choices are route and the availability of data only for IPO and M&A exits (and not
transformed through a polynomial function. for other routes), we also need to address the endogenous nature of
To overcome the issue of exit-route selectivity, we use the Dahl the timing of the VC exit and the resulting idiosyncratic variation in
(2002) model. Consider the following two equations: the holding period across VC investments. In estimating the risk and
returns of VC investments it is clearly essential to control for the fact
R1 ¼ Xβ1 þ μ 1 ð4Þ that VC returns are realized in a discrete and lumpy fashion over widely
varying holding periods.8 To do so, we adopt an approach similar to that
 of Korteweg and Sorensen (2010), who deal with the sample selection
P k ¼ Zγk þ ηk k ¼ 1; 2; …m ð5Þ
bias due to the endogenous timing of observed returns. While they
address this ‘dynamic selection bias’ using Markov Chain Monte Carlo
where Eq. (4) is a linear regression model and Eq. (5) is a probability (or (MCMC) estimation, we estimate an amended Heckman model with
choice) model. R1 is an excess return for stage 1, and the variable X
the first stage involving a duration Cox (1972) model.
contains market excess returns, industry and year dummies. μ1 is the In Stage I of our model, we estimate, using a Cox (1972) model, the
disturbance term of the outcome equation and satisfies E(μ1|X,Z) = 0
time from investment to exit by the VC firms. This allows us to model
and V(μ1|X,Z) = σ2. P*k is the probability of observing no exits through and control for the endogeneity of the exit-timing decision. In Stage II,
IPO, M&A and liquidation. k is a categorical variable and describes m
we estimate the systematic risk by including, in the form of an inverse
choices (m = 1, IPO, m = 2, M&A, m = 3, liquidation and m = 4, no Mill's ratio, the predicted hazard of exit (i.e., the instantaneous prob-
exit). The variable Z contains control variables for the probabilities of
ability of exit at a given point), modeled in Stage I as an additional
exits. These variables include the following: age of VCs, amount invested explanatory variable. This adjusts the estimated systematic risk for the
by VCs, VCs syndicated (measured as the number of VCs in the
dynamic sample selection (due to endogenous timing). A significant
syndicate), age of portfolio companies, number of rounds a portfolio coefficient for the inverse Mill's ratio would indicate the presence of
company has received, financing stage, and year and industry dummies.
dynamic selection bias.9
ηk is the residual of the selection model, independently and identically
distributed (i.i.d.). The stage return (R1) is observed only when the VC 6
Bourguignon, Fournier, and Gurgand (2007) present a survey of the selection bias
investors make an investment and then exit through an IPO. This models available in the literature, including Lee (1983) and Dubin and McFadden
condition is expressed as (1984). Using a Monte Carlo experiment, they conclude that Dahl's model performs better
than both Lee's (1983) and Dubin and McFadden (1984).
   7
Dahl (2002) recommends the transformation of second- or third-order polynomial
P k N Max P k : ð6Þ
K≠1 approximations for the correction term. Using a third-order polynomial function does
not change the results and hence we report the second-order (polynomial function)
results.
8
We are grateful to the referee for drawing our attention to this issue.
5 9
Our estimate of the annualized return is based on valuation estimates of the portfolio The results of our analysis of the risk and returns of VC investments below need to be
company pre-IPO. These estimates are clearly subject to all the biases and inaccuracies interpreted bearing in mind that they are only generalizable to the extent that our
typically arising in valuations, particularly in the context of VC portfolio companies. We methods for correcting the sample selection biases are fully valid. Unfortunately, as the
thank the referee for highlighting this issue and for noting that this is a problem common selection biases outlined above are an inherent feature of any VC dataset, the resulting
to all empirical research into VC. limitations are unavoidable.
S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24 17

3.4. Determinants of the selection equation Table 2


Definition of the variables.

The determinants included in the two steps are motivated as follows: Variables Definition and unit of measurements Data source

(a) VC age: The age of the VC company is measured as the difference Early stage returns Annualized returns for the early stage rounds. VentureXpert
between founding date and investment date. Previous studies Expansion returns Annualized returns for the expansion stage VentureXpert
rounds
(Gompers, 1996; Lee & Wahal, 2004) document that the IPO Later stage returns Annualized returns for the later stage rounds. VentureXpert
exit is an important exit method and that VCs improve their Start-up returns Annualized returns for the start-up rounds. VentureXpert
reputations by exiting through this route. Generally, young VCs Benchmark Is the annualized returns computed from Bloomberg
will rush to exit through an IPO so as to gain a reputation, as returns Morgan
(market Stanley World Capital Index (MSCI). S&P 500
reported by Gompers (1996). Hence, the probability of an exit
returns) and
of this type is influenced by the age of the VCs. MSCI Europe.
(b) Investment size: The size of the VC investment in a portfolio VC-age Age of venture capital firm invested in a portfolio VentureXpert
company is expected to influence the decision to exit the portfolio company and measured in years as the
company. VCs tie up substantial amounts of capital in illiquid difference
between founding date and date of investment.
investments in portfolio companies. The amount of capital FFind1–FFind12 Fama and French industry classification VentureXpert
invested influences the expected value; hence a large invest- Risk free rate Annualized risk free rate DataStream
ment reflects a VC's confidence in the future success of a portfolio Invest size($m) Is the amount invested by venture capital firm in VentureXpert
company. If VCs have any predictive ability, we expect the prob- a given round measured in millions of dollars
Comp age Age of a portfolio company, measured (in years) VentureXpert
ability of a successful exit (through IPO or M&A) to increase with
as the difference between the founding date and
investment size. the date of investment.
(c) Syndication allows VCs to diversify their investment risk. Syndicate Synd (#) Is the number of venture capital firms syndicated VentureXpert
size typically increases as the portfolio company develops and its in financing a portfolio company
need for VC funds increases. Giot and Schwienbacher (2007)
argue that larger syndicates facilitate successful trade-sale and
IPO exits by providing valuable contacts, connections and quality
certification. Hence, we expect VC syndicate size to increase
the probability of exit through M&A or IPO. At the same time,
by less experienced VCs (Lerner, 1994). We find that approximately
larger syndicate size may also increase the probability of
45 to 46% of the investments by our cross-border syndicates are
liquidation. A larger syndicate has greater bargaining power
made at the expansion stage, while start-ups attract the smallest
vis-à-vis the entrepreneur(s) and can exert more pressure
proportion of investments (around 11 to 12%); see also Table 4. By
on the entrepreneur(s) to liquidate an unsuccessful venture
contrast, previous studies on US VCs show a much smaller proportion
(e.g., Sharifzadeh & Walz, 2012).
of expansion-stage investments and a higher proportion of early-stage
(d) Company age: The age of the backed company is measured in
investments. For instance, Cochrane (2005) reports that early-stage
years from founding date to investment date. VCs invest in
investments account for 46% of his sample, compared to 14.7% for
young companies, and their investment decision might be
expansion rounds. Thus, while US VC's investments tend to cluster in
influenced by the characteristics of the backed company. For
early-stage financing, our findings highlight that US–European cross-
instance, a young company with high growth opportunities
border syndicates focus on mature investments, where the risk tends
might be more attractive to VC firms than a mature company
to be lower than in the earlier stages (as we will show below).
with low growth opportunities.
We find that the size of US–European cross-border syndicates (at 10
(e) Market excess return (Rm − Rf) is the main variable of interest,
members for IPOs and 8 for M&As) is around double that reported by
in that its coefficient is interpreted as a measure of systematic
Giot and Schwienbacher (2007) for US-only VC syndicates (5 for IPOs
risk (beta). Like all investors, VC firms are likely to benchmark
and 4 for M&As). The larger syndicate size may be related to the greater
the returns of their investments against market excess returns.
focus of US–European cross-border syndicates on expansion-stage
According to the CAPM, VC backers will require a return that is
investments and the younger average age of the syndicate members
in direct relation to the beta of the investment and to the market
(Lerner, 1994).
return. We use the US risk free rate for US VC firms, while for the
Interestingly, we find that syndicate size is larger for investments
European VC firms we use the average risk free rate of European
that are liquidated (12 members) than for investments exited through
countries in the sample.
other routes. This may be due to the relative inexperience (low average
We use industry and year dummies as additional control variables. age) of the VCs and VC syndicates involved in investments that go on to
Table 2 shows the definitions of the independent variables. be liquidated. Another possible explanation may be that, in particularly
large syndicates, the costs of syndication (e.g. due to free-riding among
4. Descriptive statistics, results and analysis VC members) offset the benefits (in terms of risk sharing, etc.). Free-
riding by self-interested syndicate members may cause each individual
4.1. Descriptive statistics VC to spend too little time and effort on screening and monitoring the
portfolio companies, and this may make liquidation more likely. For a
Table 3 shows the descriptive statistics of the VC and portfolio discussion of the costs and benefits of syndication, see, e.g., Sharifzadeh
company characteristics by exit route. Panel A shows VC-related variables, and Walz (2012).
while Panel B shows portfolio company characteristics. At over 50%, the proportion of investments exited through M&As is
For IPO and M&A exits, we find that the mean age of the VC firms higher than that for all other routes. This is followed by IPOs with
in US–European cross-border syndicates ranges from 21 to 23 years, around 25 to 30% of the investments. Similarly, previous studies (Giot
with the median ranging from 17 to 20 years. For comparison, Giot & Schwienbacher, 2007) document that the M&A route is the most
and Schwienbacher (2007) report for US-only syndicates average common exit method for VCs, followed by IPOs.
ages of 28.8 and 27.6 for IPO and M&A exits, respectively. This may Comparing IPOs and M&As, we find that portfolio companies that are
in part be explained by the greater focus of our cross-border syn- exited through the IPO route tend to receive relatively larger investments
dicates on expansion-stage investments, which tend to be backed than those exited via M&As (the average investment sizes are $5.90 m
18
Table 3
Descriptive statistics by exit route. The table shows the descriptive statistics for the sample (1990–2010) based on the exit method. Panel A shows VC firms' characteristics while Panel B shows the portfolio company statistics. VC-age is the age of
venture capital firm investing in a portfolio company and is measured as the difference between founding date and date of investment (in years). Invest size is the amount invested by venture capital firm in a given round ($m). Synd (#) is the number
of venture capital firms syndicated in financing a portfolio company. Comp age is the age of a portfolio company and is measured as the difference between founding date and date of investment (in years). Start-up, Early, Expansion and Later are
dummy variables taking a value of 1 for each stage and zero otherwise. The industries are dummies based on the Fama and French 12 industry classifications.

S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24


IPO exits M&A exits Un-exited Liquidation exit

Mean Median STD Max Min Mean Median STD Max Min Mean Median STD Max Min Mean Median STD Max Min

Panel A: Venture capital firms characteristics


VC-age 20.670 16.953 16.944 189.069 4.000 22.759 19.912 16.528 192.751 3.000 19.367 17.000 15.147 148.000 0.000 16.162 15.000 14.774 135.000 0.000
Invest size ($m) 5.909 2.532 16.853 620.000 0.300 4.767 2.877 6.706 334.995 0.100 2.959 2.110 2.920 30.500 0.300 2.770 2.000 2.719 30.792 1.000
Synd (#) 10 9 5 35 2 8 7 5 31 2 12 11 6 28 2 12 11 6 33 2

Panel B: Portfolio company characteristics


Comp age 8.392 6.789 8.293 24.340 1.000 9.008 7.690 6.901 20.049 1.000 10.118 9.000 7.419 19.000 2.000 5.720 5.000 3.559 21.000 1.000
Start-ups 0.125 0 0.331 1 0 0.114 0.000 0.317 1.000 0.000 0.057 0.000 0.231 1.000 0.000 0.079 0.000 0.271 1.000 0.000
Early 0.203 0 0.402 1 0 0.254 0.000 0.435 1.000 0.000 0.163 0.000 0.369 1.000 0.000 0.148 0.000 0.355 1.000 0.000
Expansion 0.454 0 0.498 1 0 0.448 0.000 0.497 1.000 0.000 0.506 1.000 0.500 1.000 0.000 0.513 1.000 0.500 1.000 0.000
Later 0.218 0 0.413 1 0 0.184 0.000 0.388 1.000 0.000 0.275 0.000 0.446 1.000 0.000 0.260 0.000 0.439 1.000 0.000
Consumer non-durable 0.010 0 0.099 1 0 0.012 0.000 0.111 1.000 0.000 0.006 0.000 0.074 1.000 0.000 0.001 0.000 0.038 1.000 0.000
Consumer durable 0.006 0 0.078 1 0 0.006 0.000 0.080 1.000 0.000 0.001 0.000 0.022 1.000 0.000 0.011 0.000 0.103 1.000 0.000
Manufacturing 0.026 0 0.159 1 0 0.018 0.000 0.135 1.000 0.000 0.022 0.000 0.146 1.000 0.000 0.017 0.000 0.129 1.000 0.000
Energy, oil & gas 0.003 0 0.056 1 0 0.002 0.000 0.042 1.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.016 1.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
Chemicals and allied products 0.008 0 0.090 1 0 0.003 0.000 0.054 1.000 0.000 0.001 0.000 0.036 1.000 0.000 0.003 0.000 0.053 1.000 0.000
Business equipment 0.463 0 0.499 1 0 0.655 1.000 0.475 1.000 0.000 0.490 0.000 0.500 1.000 0.000 0.558 1.000 0.497 1.000 0.000
Telecom 0.041 0 0.199 1 0 0.035 0.000 0.184 1.000 0.000 0.043 0.000 0.202 1.000 0.000 0.086 0.000 0.280 1.000 0.000
Utilities 0.002 0 0.043 1 0 0.002 0.000 0.045 1.000 0.000 0.005 0.000 0.071 1.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
Wholesale & retail 0.047 0 0.212 1 0 0.035 0.000 0.185 1.000 0.000 0.040 0.000 0.196 1.000 0.000 0.113 0.000 0.317 1.000 0.000
Healthcare 0.251 0 0.433 1 0 0.128 0.000 0.334 1.000 0.000 0.263 0.000 0.440 1.000 0.000 0.100 0.000 0.300 1.000 0.000
Money finance 0.020 0 0.139 1 0 0.019 0.000 0.137 1.000 0.000 0.010 0.000 0.098 1.000 0.000 0.018 0.000 0.132 1.000 0.000
Others 0.123 0 0.328 1 0 0.084 0.000 0.277 1.000 0.000 0.120 0.000 0.325 1.000 0.000 0.094 0.000 0.292 1.000 0.000
No of obs 6774 13,907 4032 2152
S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24 19

Table 4
Descriptive statistics by financing round. The table shows descriptive statistics for the sample (1990–2010) based on financing stage. VC-age is the age of venture capital firm investing in a
portfolio company and is measured as the difference between founding date and date of investment (in years). Invest size is the amount invested by venture capital firm in a given round
($m). Synd (#) is the number of venture capital firms syndicated in financing a portfolio company. Comp age is the age of a portfolio company and is measured as the difference between
founding date and date of investment (in years). IPO is the number of investments exited through IPO route. MA is the number of investments exited through mergers and acquisitions.
Liqu'd is the number of investments exited through liquidation. Private is the number of investments not exited by the end of the sample period. We use Fama and French 12 industry
classifications.

Variable Start-up stage Early stage Expansion stage Later stage

Mean Median STD Mean Median STD Mean Median STD Mean Median STD

VC-age (years) 21.323 18.000 15.848 22.755 20.000 17.292 20.998 18.000 16.553 20.128 17.000 15.403
Invest size ($m) 9.913 2.083 29.406 14.796 3.396 45.651 23.040 5.000 47.869 32.540 6.749 59.392
Synd (#) 8 7 5 8 6 5 9 8 5 11 10 6
Comp age (years) 7.562 6.488 7.061 7.545 6.499 5.742 9.091 7.636 7.554 9.859 8.742 7.739
IPO 0.303 0 0.460 0.236 0 0.425 0.250 0 0.433 0.261 0 0.439
MA 0.556 1 0.497 0.598 1 0.490 0.499 0 0.500 0.448 0 0.497
Liqu'd 0.060 0 0.238 0.054 0 0.226 0.088 0 0.284 0.098 0 0.297
No exit 0.081 0 0.272 0.111 0 0.314 0.163 0 0.369 0.194 0 0.395
Consumer non-durable 0.012 0 0.107 0.008 0 0.089 0.011 0 0.102 0.009 0 0.097
Consumer durable 0.003 0 0.056 0.006 0 0.079 0.007 0 0.085 0.003 0 0.058
Manufacturing 0.022 0 0.147 0.019 0 0.138 0.022 0 0.145 0.020 0 0.139
Energy, oil & gas 0.001 0 0.038 0.001 0 0.032 0.003 0 0.052 0.001 0 0.023
Chemicals and allied products 0.004 0 0.065 0.004 0 0.060 0.006 0 0.075 0.001 0 0.026
Business equipment 0.524 1 0.500 0.594 1 0.491 0.571 1 0.495 0.585 1 0.493
Telecom 0.033 0 0.180 0.040 0 0.196 0.044 0 0.204 0.044 0 0.204
Utilities 0.002 0 0.046 0.001 0 0.032 0.002 0 0.046 0.004 0 0.063
Wholesale & retail 0.045 0 0.208 0.032 0 0.176 0.050 0 0.218 0.048 0 0.213
Healthcare 0.233 0 0.423 0.178 0 0.383 0.163 0 0.370 0.178 0 0.383
Money finance 0.017 0 0.129 0.019 0 0.136 0.018 0 0.134 0.016 0 0.126
Others 0.103 0 0.303 0.097 0 0.296 0.104 0 0.306 0.091 0 0.288
No of obs 2843 5897 12,500 5625

and $4.76 m, respectively). By contrast, companies exited through IPOs the expansion and later stages. Again, as in Giot and Schwienbacher
tend to be younger at the time of investment than those exited through (2007), who report that syndicates are smaller in the start-up and
M&As and those not exited. Companies that are liquidated are the early stages than in the expansion and later stages, we find that syndicate
youngest (at around 5–6 years on average). We find little variation in size rises to 11 in later stages compared to 8 in the earlier stages. On
terms of the investment stages between IPO and M&A exits. average, portfolio companies that have received financing at the start-
As expected, VC investments are clustered in the business equipment up or early stage are younger than those that have received expansion
and healthcare industries, regardless of the exit route. This is consistent and later-stage financing.
with previous studies (Cochrane, 2005; Giot & Schwienbacher, 2007). Cochrane (2005) reports that around 9% of investments with
There are differences in the VC characteristics between investments funding from US VCs in the early and expansion stages are liquidated.
that end up being liquidated and others. The results show that liquidated We find a similar proportion of liquidations among investments backed
investments were backed by young VCs, and generally the portfolio by US–European syndicates in the expansion and later stages. However,
companies too were younger on average than those portfolio com- surprisingly, we find a much lower liquidation rate of only 5 to 6% in the
panies in the sample that were yet to be exited. Nearly half of the start-up and early stages.
liquidated investments are from the expansion-stage round. Giot and In conclusion, our preliminary analysis identifies a number of
Schwienbacher (2007) report similar shares of liquidations between interesting similarities and differences between US VCs and US–
the early and expansion stages. Interestingly, the syndicate size is European cross-border syndicates.
typically larger for liquidated investments than for portfolios exited via
an IPO or M&A. The association between syndicate size and liquidation
suggests that VC syndication is not necessarily good news for a portfolio 4.2. Results and analysis
company, possibly due to free-riding by VC firms resulting in too little
VC screening and monitoring and a greater chance of liquidation. Table 5 provides information on the average annualized returns for
Table 4 shows the characteristics of the VC firms and portfolio VC investments (without correcting for any sample selection biases)
companies by stage of financing. VC experience (as measured by the exited through IPOs and M&As. The IPO figures in Panel A are calculated
average age of the syndicate members) is quite similar across all the so as to account for gradual post-IPO exit by the VC (as outlined in Data
different financing stages, ranging from 21–22 years in the start-up and methodology Section 3.2 above) by basing returns on a weighted
and early stages to 20–21 years in the expansion and later stages. This average of the IPO offer price and aftermarket prices. The returns on
is an interesting observation, as it has previously been found that start- the stock indices shown in Table 5 are calculated based on staggered
up and early-stage rounds are typically financed by experienced VCs, holding periods to match the calculation of the returns on investments
while expansion or later stages are funded by less experienced ones. exited (gradually) through and after IPOs. Panel B shows the returns for
For instance, Lerner (1994) finds that experienced US VCs syndicate investments exited through the M&A route. While Table 5 reports only
only with other experienced VCs in the early-stage round. By contrast, the returns on investments exited through IPOs or M&As, it is reasonable
we find that, among our US–European cross-border syndicates, the to assume that the corresponding returns on the 2152 investments in our
average age of the syndicate members varies little across all the financing sample that were exited by liquidation are −100% in each case.10
stages.
Consistent with Giot and Schwienbacher (2007), we find that the 10
While we do not report a return averaged across all exit routes, such an estimate
size of investment is smaller in the start-up and early stages than in would have to take into account the number of and returns on liquidations.
20 S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24

Table 5 the Dahl model (outlined in Section 3.3).12 Following Cochrane (2005),
IPO/MA annualized returns. The table shows mean, median, standard deviation, maximum we deal with the issue of return skewness, noted above, by calculating
and minimum values of venture capital returns exited through IPO and M&A exits. Returns
are annualized and computed over the period 1990 through 2010 using a weighted
logarithmic returns.
average of IPO and aftermarket prices. The rows entitled ‘Start-up stage’, ‘Early stage’, It is evident from the table that in many exit years the uncorrected
‘Expansion stage’ and ‘Later stage’ show returns for the respective financing stages. returns are higher than the corrected returns. These differences are
‘MSCI World’ is the annualized MSCI world index returns. ‘MSCI Europe’ is the annualized often statistically significant at 5% or higher. VC's returns are positive
MSCI Europe index returns. ‘S&P 500’ is the annualized S&P 500 composite returns. ‘Risk
in the vast majority of exit years and financing rounds. However, the
free’ is the annualized risk-free rate for US and Europe, respectively.
returns are particularly high in the bubble year of 1999. After the
Mean Median STD Max Min credit crisis in 2007–8, returns for the expansion and later stages
Panel A: Annualized returns for IPO exits (corrected for gradual VC exit post-IPO) fell dramatically by around 80% from their average levels in 2006.
Start-up stage 2.532 0.402 7.554 31.148 −0.959 While returns did not decline as much for those investments made in
Early stage 1.632 0.301 6.253 27.597 −0.967 the earlier stages, exit activity declined. In fact, no IPO exits occurred
Expansion stage 1.228 0.146 4.533 24.947 −0.977
for start-up investments during 2008–9.
Later stage 0.987 0.114 3.531 21.871 −0.927
MSCI world 0.116 0.104 0.091 0.311 −0.119 As Table 6 shows, adjusting for selection bias has a major impact on
MSCI Europe 0.121 0.114 0.131 0.398 −0.162 reported returns. From this we conclude that it is important to control
S&P 500 0.141 0.122 0.110 0.370 −0.098 for selection bias when estimating the risk-return trade-off.13 As outlined
FTSE all shares 0.105 0.091 0.108 0.322 −0.134
in Section 3.3, we control for exit-route selection bias using Dahl's (2002)
Risk free rate (US) 0.045 0.049 0.017 0.059 0.000
Risk free rate (Europe) 0.061 0.055 0.019 0.147 0.033 two-stage model. This involves a multinomial logit model in the first
No of obs 6774 stage, predicting the chosen exit route, and in the second stage, a linear
regression of excess return on the VC investment on the market risk
Panel B: Annualized returns for M&A exits
Start-up stage 1.315 0.282 3.241 19.287 −0.921
premium (proxied by the excess return on the S&P 500 index). We
Early stage 1.091 0.228 3.016 18.166 −0.912 calculate both VC and benchmark returns taking into account the fact
Expansion stage 0.669 0.052 2.629 16.194 −0.879 that VCs do not sell all of their holdings at the time of the IPO
Later stage 0.563 0.008 2.428 15.188 −0.795 (i.e. correcting returns for gradual VC exit). Table 7 shows the
MSCI world 0.037 0.045 0.109 0.236 −0.223
estimated parameters of this model. As expected, we find clear evidence
MSCI Europe 0.058 0.071 0.135 0.336 −0.235
S&P 500 0.045 0.042 0.117 0.293 −0.211 of selection bias, as shown by the statistical significance of the estimated
FTSE all shares 0.041 0.047 0.108 0.263 −0.223 selection-bias parameters, λ(P1) and λ(P2).
Risk free rate (US) 0.030 0.033 0.019 0.080 0.000 We find that returns on investments in all stages are positively
Risk free rate (Europe) 0.053 0.055 0.011 0.146 0.033
related to the market benchmark (i.e. they have positive betas that are
No of obs 13,907
statistically significant at 5% or above). As is to be expected, start-up
and early-stage investments have higher systematic risk (higher betas)
than expansion and later-stage investments. The start-up and early-
stage betas of 1.316 and 1.122, respectively, mean that returns on invest-
Comparing Panels A and B, we find that IPO returns are higher than ments made in these stages are expected to change by 1.31 and 1.12%,
M&A returns in each of the four financing stages. This is consistent with respectively, for every one-percent change in the market benchmark
prior studies that document that IPOs are the preferred and most (S&P 500). The betas for expansion and later-stage investments are
profitable form of exit (e.g., Black & Gilson, 1998). 1.079 and 0.797, respectively.
For both IPO and M&A exits, the table shows that expansion and For comparison, Cochrane (2005) reports betas of 1.1 for start-up
later-stage returns are on average lower than start-up and early-stage investments, 0.9 for early-stage, 0.7 for expansion and 0.5 for later-
returns, based on both means and medians returns.11 On invest- stage investments. Both Cochrane's and our results demonstrate that
ments exited through an IPO, VC firms earn median returns of VC investors are exposed to higher systematic risk in earlier stages of
40.2% on investments in the start-up stage, 30.1% in the early stage, financing, and that systematic risk (beta) declines continually, the
14.6% in the expansion stage, and 11.4% in the later stages. The later the stage of investment.
cross-sectional standard deviations (which can be interpreted as This may be due to the difficulty of selling a portfolio company in its
total risk) corresponding to these stage are 755%, 625%, 453% and early phase of development. Previous studies have suggested that the
353%, respectively. higher returns in earlier stages are required to attract and compensate
The corresponding median returns (standard deviations) for the the more experienced VC firms that are more likely than less experienced
M&A exits are 28.2 (324)% in the start-up stage, 22.8 (301)% for the VCs to invest in these riskier stages. In line with Cochrane (2005), we find
early stage, 5.2 (262)% for the expansion stage, and 0.8 (242)% for the higher risk and returns in earlier stages, but we find little variation in the
later stages. level of experience of US–European cross-border syndicates across
For both IPO and M&A exits, total risk decreases significantly from financing stages (see Table 4).
the start-up to the later stages of financing. This is to be expected as Abnormal performance, as measured by the coefficient of the constant
portfolio companies mature from earlier to later stages (see Table 4), in our second-stage regression, is shown in Panel B of Table 7. This
reducing the level of risk and thus the expected return. measure is the so-called alpha. We estimate alpha as 41.6%, 35.2%,
As noted above, the returns shown in Table 5 are not corrected for 28.1%, and 23.5% for the start-up, early, expansion and later stages,
sample selection bias. Table 6 examines the impact of controlling for respectively. Similar to beta, we find alpha to decline monotonically, the
exit-route selection bias on returns. By year of (IPO) exit, it shows the later the financing stage. This is comparable to Cochrane, who reports
VC returns on investments exited through an IPO with and without alphas of 71% for start-up, 65% for early, 60% for expansion, and 50% for
correction for sample selection bias. The returns are corrected using later-stage investments.

12
The Dahl method (similar to the method used by Cochrane) gives us estimates of the
mean of the (logarithmic) return. For comparison, we focus similarly on the means (rather
11
The following discussion focuses on median returns. A large difference between mean than the medians) of the uncorrected returns.
13
and median values suggests that returns are skewed and driven by a few investments with In interpreting the figures in Table 6, it is important to bear in mind that they may still
very high returns. Skewness is to be expected for VC investments, where a few deals provide a biased estimate of the typical return on a VC investment. The returns reported
typically provide very high returns to compensate for large numbers of unsuccessful and here are only representative to the extent that our correction for sample selection bias is
liquidated investments. We thank the anonymous referee for highlighting this issue. valid.
Table 6
Venture capital returns corrected for (exit-route) sample-selection bias. The table shows the descriptive statistics of annualized log returns for the Start-up stage, Early, Expansion and Later stage round based on the subsample of investments exited
through an IPO. The statistics are tabulated by the year of IPO. We report both corrected and uncorrected returns for sample selection bias. The corrected returns for sample selection bias are estimated using Dahl (2002) semi-parametric
method. T-test shows if the difference in means between corrected and un-corrected returns is statistically significant.

S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24


Start-up returns Early stage returns Expansion stage returns Later stage returns

Un-corrected Corrected Un-corrected Corrected Un-corrected Corrected Un-corrected Corrected

IPO-year Mean Std Mean STD T-test Mean Std Mean STD T-test Mean Std Mean STD T-test Mean Std Mean STD T-test

1990 −0.834 1.081 −0.250 0.893 −3.623 0.204 0.575 0.281 0.620 −0.789 −0.295 1.005 0.261 0.564 −4.334 0.169 0.235 0.253 0.383 −1.656
1991 0.046 0.098 0.452 0.899 −4.988 0.570 0.750 0.582 0.725 −0.100 0.023 0.090 0.298 0.200 −11.611 0.457 0.375 0.326 0.261 2.522
1992 −0.344 0.910 −0.404 0.682 0.457 0.273 0.593 0.415 0.391 −1.767 −0.010 0.080 0.029 0.059 −3.352 0.328 0.417 0.378 0.307 −0.856
1993 0.083 0.998 0.453 0.748 −2.601 0.326 0.443 0.366 0.482 −0.539 0.037 0.779 0.157 0.051 −1.771 0.387 0.524 0.278 0.259 1.705
1994 −0.175 1.088 −0.483 0.705 2.101 0.274 0.581 0.326 0.718 −0.492 0.158 0.225 0.130 0.217 0.769 0.480 0.457 0.349 0.304 2.107
1995 0.496 0.921 0.436 0.692 0.455 0.482 0.623 0.480 0.643 0.021 0.420 0.795 0.518 0.750 −0.783 0.434 0.330 0.574 0.228 −3.074
1996 0.293 0.952 0.577 0.881 −1.898 0.625 0.737 0.640 0.134 −0.218 0.213 0.839 0.521 0.538 −2.734 0.402 0.727 0.484 0.401 −0.892
1997 0.111 0.905 0.645 0.678 −4.131 0.547 0.720 0.623 0.438 −0.798 0.420 0.576 0.707 0.636 −2.905 0.320 0.582 0.382 0.268 −0.897
1998 0.709 0.796 0.788 0.979 −0.544 0.895 0.962 0.836 0.665 0.443 0.602 0.784 0.749 0.679 −1.236 – – – – –
1999 0.895 1.031 1.010 1.076 −0.671 1.175 0.859 1.113 0.774 0.466 1.084 1.161 1.001 1.278 0.418 0.692 0.722 0.705 0.823 −0.106
2000 0.299 0.458 0.649 0.836 −3.319 0.242 0.864 0.716 0.637 −3.868 0.258 0.531 0.169 0.201 1.487 0.220 0.379 0.125 0.157 2.160
2001 0.137 0.342 0.840 0.700 −8.269 0.573 0.854 0.770 0.689 −1.568 0.004 0.009 0.037 0.091 −3.946 0.292 0.611 0.376 0.317 −1.113
2002 −0.323 0.731 −0.355 0.548 0.308 0.213 0.120 0.451 0.767 −3.280 −0.128 0.258 −0.119 0.172 −0.253 0.023 0.061 0.047 0.040 −2.823
2003 0.337 0.870 0.674 0.653 −2.705 0.451 0.391 0.426 0.230 0.482 0.263 0.305 0.438 0.240 −3.941 0.215 0.302 0.301 0.196 −2.100
2004 0.218 0.685 0.519 0.403 −3.399 0.503 0.369 0.527 0.305 −0.444 0.302 0.523 0.458 0.430 −2.013 0.264 0.245 0.402 0.245 −3.436
2005 0.186 0.782 0.453 0.586 −2.391 0.463 0.498 0.491 0.401 −0.371 0.100 0.173 0.288 0.393 −4.051 0.044 0.052 0.179 0.126 −9.238
2006 0.218 0.670 0.405 0.502 −1.958 0.370 0.374 0.396 0.282 −0.488 0.263 0.522 0.422 0.290 −2.400 0.209 0.209 0.423 0.299 −5.151
2007 0.003 0.094 0.436 0.234 −16.154 0.107 0.089 0.046 0.039 5.827 0.256 0.495 0.496 0.399 −3.286 0.261 0.346 0.424 0.105 −4.448
2008 – – – – – 0.053 0.373 0.228 0.304 −3.156 0.038 0.168 0.126 0.106 −3.952 0.051 0.038 0.045 0.073 0.660
2009 – – – – – 0.057 0.166 0.239 0.133 −7.465 0.043 0.375 0.047 1.915 −0.023 0.062 0.075 0.056 0.060 0.583
2010 0.388 0.351 0.449 0.753 −0.677 0.068 0.211 0.233 0.101 −6.486 0.066 0.051 0.090 0.077 −2.283 0.033 0.046 0.062 0.095 −2.516
No of obs 858 1389 3068 1459

21
22 S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24

Table 7
Risk-return estimation allowing for gradual post-IPO disinvestment by VCs. The estimation of Stage 1 in Panel A uses the full sample, while Stage 2 in Panel B uses only investments exited
through IPOs. Returns in Panel B are based on a weighted average of the IPO offer price and post-IPO market prices, as described in Section 3.2. The coefficients are estimated using Dahl's
(2002) semi-parametric method. We use clustered standard errors as opposed to robust standard errors allowing for cross sectional dependence of the returns. Market is the excess market
returns using MSCI Europe and S&P 500. The correction terms in the Dahl (2002) model are transformed using first and second order polynomial approximations. *** Significant at 1%, **
significant at 5% and * significant at 10%.

Panel A: Stage I selection equation

Variables IPO exits M&A exits Liquidation exits

Coeff Odds Coeff Odds Coeff Odds

VC-age 0.032*** 1.033 0.040*** 1.041 −0.007*** 0.993


Invest size 0.014*** 1.014 −0.015*** 0.985 −0.004 0.996
Synd 0.058*** 1.060 0.020*** 1.020 0.023*** 1.023
Comp-age 0.008** 1.008 −0.024*** 0.976 −0.256*** 0.774
Start-up −0.672*** 0.511 −1.144*** 0.319 0.266** 1.305
Early −0.609*** 0.544 −0.441*** 0.643 −0.388*** 0.678
Expansion −0.220*** 0.803 −0.171*** 0.843 0.105** 1.111
Cons 3.866*** 4.035*** 1.041 1.859*** 6.417
Industry & year Yes Yes Yes
Pseudo R2 0.317
No of obs 26,865

Panel B: Stage II outcome equation

Variables Start-up Early stage Expansion stage Later stage

Coeff P-values Coeff P-values Coeff P-values Coeff P-values

Constant 0.416*** 0.000 0.352*** 0.000 0.281** 0.028 0.235*** 0.004


Market 1.316*** 0.000 1.122*** 0.000 1.079*** 0.000 0.797** 0.033
λ(P1) −0.688* 0.089 −0.461** 0.430 −0.421* 0.096 −0.368* 0.086
λ(P2) 0.326 0.257 0.257* 0.085 0.068 0.897 0.189 0.272
Industry Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.161 0.221 0.181 0.137
No of obs 858 1389 3068 1459

To address the dynamic selection bias that is due to the endogenous We find clear evidence of sample selection bias, as evidenced by the
timing of VC exits, we use a Heckman-type two-stage model (outlined statistical significance of the coefficient of the selectivity parameter (the
in Section 3.3), where the selection equation is estimated using a Cox inverse Mill's ratio), in all stages except the start-up stage. Taking account
(1972) duration model. Table 8 shows the results. of the bias, we find results on the risk and returns of VC investments that

Table 8
Cox estimation model. As in Table 7, the estimation of Stage 1 in Panel A uses the full sample, while Stage 2 in Panel B uses only investments exited through IPOs; returns in Panel B are
based on a weighted average of the IPO offer price and post-IPO market prices, as described in Section 3.2. The coefficients are estimated using Heckman with Cox model (proportional
hazard). We use clustered standard errors as opposed to robust standard errors allowing for cross sectional dependence of the returns. Market is the excess market returns using MSCI
Europe and S&P 500. *** Significant at 1%, ** significant at 5% and * significant at 10%.

Panel A: Stage I selection equation

Variable Coeff Hazard ratio

VC-age 0.008*** 1.008


Invest-size 0.005*** 1.005
Synd 0.005*** 1.005
Comp-age 0.086*** 1.090
Start-up −0.357*** 0.700
Early −0.662*** 0.516
Expansion −0.377** 0.686
Industry & year Yes
Pseudo R2 0.387
No of obs 26,865

Panel B: Stage II outcome equation

Variables Start-up Early stage Expansion stage Later stage

Coeff P-values Coeff P-values Coeff P-values Coeff P-values

Constant 0.457*** 0.000 0.418*** 0.000 0.273** 0.028 0.212*** 0.004


Market 1.403*** 0.000 1.2143*** 0.000 1.102*** 0.000 0.868** 0.033
Inv. mills 0.031 0.563 −0.297*** 0.000 −0.419*** 0.000 0.235*** 0.000
Industry Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.163 0.224 0.189 0.141
No of obs 858 1389 3068 1459
S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24 23

are remarkably robust. The results for alpha (abnormal performance) and
Mean Median STD Max Min
beta (systematic risk) adjusted for dynamic selection bias (in Table 8) are
Panel A: Annualized returns for 100% IPO exits
remarkably similar to those adjusted for exit-route selection bias
Start-up stage 2.056 0.544 9.139 51.267 −0.901
(in Table 7). While the start-up and early stages have higher alphas in Early stage 3.058 0.596 11.156 57.267 −0.910
the dynamic selection model than in the exit-route selection Expansion stage 4.594 0.367 16.017 61.267 −0.951
model (46 and 42% compared to 42 and 35%, respectively), the Later stage 6.338 0.491 18.772 77.267 −0.931
reverse holds for the expansion and later stages (27 and 21% MSCI world 0.101 0.093 0.088 0.296 −0.118
MSCI Europe 0.101 0.099 0.120 0.385 −0.157
compared to 28 and 24%, respectively). Nevertheless, both models
S&P 500 0.122 0.116 0.101 0.360 −0.093
indicate clearly that abnormal performance is lower, the later the FTSE all shares 0.081 0.090 0.092 0.305 −0.122
stage of financing. Risk free rate (US) 0.043 0.048 0.016 0.079 0.000
In terms of the systematic risk, measured by beta, we similarly Risk free rate (Europe) 0.061 0.055 0.019 0.147 0.033
No of obs 6774
find that both selection models show beta to drop continually from
the start-up stage to the later stage. The estimated betas are between Panel B: Annualized returns for post-IPO exits at the end of the IPO lock-up period
3 and 10% higher in the dynamic selection model than in the exit- Start-up stage 2.367 0.376 7.063 29.123 −0.897
route (Dahl) selection model. The beta for the start-up stage is Early stage 1.611 0.297 6.173 27.244 −0.955
Expansion stage 1.192 0.142 4.402 24.224 −0.949
1.316 in the exit-route model compared to 1.403 in the dynamic Later stage 0.965 0.111 3.453 21.390 −0.907
selection model. The later-stage beta is around 40% lower than the MSCI world 0.115 0.103 0.090 0.307 −0.118
start-up beta, at 0.797 in the exit route model and 0.868 in the MSCI Europe 0.119 0.112 0.129 0.391 −0.159
dynamic selection model. S&P 500 0.140 0.121 0.109 0.367 −0.097
FTSE all shares 0.104 0.090 0.107 0.319 −0.133
Risk free rate (US) 0.045 0.049 0.017 0.058 0.000
5. Conclusion Risk free rate (Europe) 0.060 0.054 0.019 0.144 0.032
No of obs 6774
This study examines exit choices and the risk and returns of invest-
ments backed by US–European cross-border syndicates. We control for
gradual VC exit, post-IPO, and two types of sample selection bias: one
due to the endogenous choice of exit route, and another due to the References
endogenous timing of exits.
Overall, our study highlights some interesting similarities and Amit, B. (2002). Syndication among venture capitalists: When and with whom. Research
in Finance, 19, 285–321.
differences between US VCs and US–European cross-border syn-
Arberk, M., Filatotchev, I., & Wright, M. (2006). Venture capitalists, syndication and
dicates, in terms of investment behavior and performance. We find governance in initial public offerings. Small Business Economics, 26, 337–350.
that, compared to US VCs, US–European syndicates on average Bent, N., Williams, K., & Gilber, E. (2004). The syndication of private equity investments in
South Africa. Journal of Business Managements, 35, 39–48.
comprise younger VCs investing relatively more in later stages of
Black, S., & Gilson, J. (1998). VC and the structure of capital markets: Banks versus stock
financing. Also, the size of the US–European cross-border syndicates markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 47, 243–277.
is double than that of US VC syndicates, exhibiting a higher tendency Bourguignon, F., Fournier, M., & Gurgand, M. (2007). Selection bias corrections based on
to spread investment risk. The level of experience of the US– the multinomial logit model: Monte Carlo comparisons. Journal of Economic Surveys,
21, 175–205.
European syndicates tends to vary little across financing stages, in Brander, J., Amit, R., & Antweiler, W. (2002). Venture capital syndication: Improved venture
contrast to US-only syndicates where earlier stages attract more selection vs. the value added hypothesis. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy,
experienced VCs. 11, 423–452.
Casamatta, C., & Haritchabalet, C. (2007). Experience, screening and syndication in
For our sample of US–European cross-border syndicates, we find venture capital investments. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 16(3), 368–398.
a monotonically decreasing relationship between both abnormal per- Chen, P., Baierl, T., & Kaplan, P. (2002). Venture capital and its role in strategic
formance (alpha) and systematic risk (beta), on the one hand, and the asset allocation. Journal of Portfolio Management, 28, 83–90.
Cochrane, J. (2005). The risk and return of venture capital. Journal of Financial Economics,
stage of VC financing, on the other hand. These findings are broadly in 75, 3–52.
line with those of Cochrane (2005) for US VCs. We document significant Cox, D. (1972). Regression models and life-tables. Journal of Statistics Society, 34, 187–220.
evidence of sample selection bias. Nevertheless, our findings on the Cumming, D. (2008). Contracts and exits in venture capital finance. Review of Financial
Studies, 21, 1947–1982.
risk and returns of VC investments are robust to controlling for two
Dahl, G. (2002). Mobility and the returns to education: Testing Roy model with multiple
alternative sources of sample selection bias. Our results are broadly markets. Econometrica, 70, 2364–2420.
comparable to those reported by Cochrane (2005) for investments Dimov, D., & Milanov, H. (2009). The interplay of need and opportunity in venture capital
investment syndication. Journal of Business Venturing, 25, 331–348.
by US VCs.
Dubin, J., & McFadden, D. (1984). An econometric analysis of residential electric appliance
holdings and consumption. Econometrica, 52, 345–362.
Appendix A Fleming, G. (2004). Venture capital returns in Australia. Venture Capital, 6, 23–45.
Giot, P., & Schwienbacher, A. (2007). IPOs, trade sales and liquidation: Modelling venture
capital exits using exits using survival analysis. Journal of Banking & Finance, 31, 697–702.
This table complements the results presented in Table 5. It shows Gompers, P. (1995). Optimal investment, monitoring and the staging of venture capital.
mean, median, standard deviation, maximum and minimum values of Journal of Finance, 50, 1461–1489.
venture capital returns exited through IPO exits. As in Table 5, returns Gompers, P. (1996). Grandstanding in the venture capital industry. Journal of Financial
Economics, 42, 133–156.
are annualized and computed over the period 1990 through 2010. Gompers, P., & Lerner, J. (2000). Money chasing deals? The impact of fund inflows on
Unlike in Table 5, Panel A of this table reports returns calculated on private equity valuations. Journal of Financial Economics, 55, 281–325.
the assumption that the 100% of the VC holding is sold through the Guler, I., & Guillen, F. (2010). Institutions and the internationalization of US venture
capital firms. Journal of International Business Studies, 41, 185–205.
IPO (at the offer price); while Panel B reports the corresponding Heckman, J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47, 153–161.
returns on the assumption that the VC holding is sold immediately Hege, U., Palomino, F., & Schwienbacher, A. (2008). Venture capital performance: The
at the end of the IPO lock-up period. The rows entitled ‘Start-up disparity between Europe and the United States. Working paper.
Hellmann, T., & Puri, M. (2002). Venture capital and the professionalization of start-up
stage’, ‘Early stage’, ‘Expansion stage’ and ‘Later stage’ show returns
firms: Empirical evidence. Journal of Finance, 57, 169–197.
for the respective financing stages. ‘MSCI World’ is the annualized Kaplan, S., & Schoar, A. (2005). Private equity performance: Returns, persistent, and
MSCI world index returns. ‘MSCI Europe’ is the annualized MSCI capital flows. Journal of Finance, 60, 1791–1823.
Kaplan, S., & Stromberg, P. (2003). Financial contracting theory meets the real world: An
Europe index returns. ‘S&P 500’ is the annualized S&P 500
empirical analysis of venture capital contracts. Review of Economic Studies, 70, 281–316.
composite returns. ‘Risk free’ is the annualized risk-free rate for Kaplan, S., & Stromberg, P. (2004). Characteristics, contracts and actions: Evidence from
US and Europe, respectively. venture capitalists analyses. Journal of Finance, 59, 2173–2206.
24 S. Espenlaub et al. / International Review of Financial Analysis 31 (2014) 13–24

Korteweg, A., & Sorensen, M. (2010). Risk and return characteristics of venture Manigart, S., Waele, K., Wright, M., Robbie, K., Desbrieres, P., Sapienz, H., et al. (2002).
capital backed entrepreneurial companies. Review of Financial Studies, 10, Determinants of required return in venture capital investments: A five-country
3738–3772. study. Journal of Business Venturing, 17, 291–312.
Lee, L. (1983). Generalized econometric models with selectivity. Econometrica, 5, Meuleman, M., & Wright, M. (2011). Cross-border private equity syndication: Institutional
507–512. context and learning. Journal of Business Venturing, 26, 35–48.
Lee, M., & Wahal, S. (2004). Grandstanding, certification and the underpricing of venture Sahlman, W. (1990). The structure and governance of venture capital organization.
capital backed IPOs. Journal of Financial Economics, 73, 375–407. Journal of Financial Economic, 27, 473–524.
Lerner, J. (1994). The syndication of venture capital investments. Financial Management, 23, Seppä, T., & Laamanen, T. (2001). Valuation of venture capital investments: Empirical
17–22. evidence. R&D Management, 31, 215–231.
Ljungqvist, A., & Richardson, M. (2003). The cash flow, return and risk characteristics of Sharifzadeh, A., & Walz, U. (2012). Syndication of venture capital investments, governance
private equity. Stern University working paper 9454. and contract design. In D. Cumming (Ed.), The Oxford handbook of venture capital.
Lockett, A., & Wright, M. (2001). The syndication of venture capital investments. The Oxford University Press.
International Journal of Management Science, 29, 375–390. Tykvova, T., & Schertler, A. (2011). Venture capital and internationalization. International
Lockett, A., & Wright, M. (2003). The structure and management of alliances: Business Review, 20, 423–439.
Syndication in the venture capital industry. Journal of Management Studies, 40, Woodward, S. (2004). Measuring risk and performance of private equity. Sand Hill working
2073–2102. paper.
Lu, Q., & Huang, P. (2010). The impact of liability of foreignness on international Wright, M., Pruthi, S., & Lockett, A. (2005). International venture capital research: From
venture capital firms in Singapore. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 27, cross country comparison to crossing countries. International Journal of Management
81–91. Review, 7, 135–166.

You might also like