Opinion A Nobel Prize For The Economics of Panic - The New York Times

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 5

Opinion | A Nobel Prize for the Economics of Panic - The New York... https://www.nytimes.com/2022/10/11/opinion/nobel-economics-bern...

https://www.nytimes.com/2022/10/11/opinion/nobel-economics-
bernanke-diamond-dybvig.html

SUBSCRIBER-ONLY NEWSLETTER
Paul Krugman

A Nobel Prize for the Economics of Panic


Oct. 11, 2022, 3:38 p.m. ET

By Paul Krugman
Opinion Columnist

You're reading the Paul Krugman newsletter, for Times subscribers


only.  A guide to U.S. politics and the economy — from the mainstream to
the wonkish. Get it with a Times subscription

Do people still read Rudyard Kipling’s “If”? Even if you haven’t, you probably know
how it begins: “If you can keep your head when all about you are losing theirs …”
Refusing to panic, Kipling asserted, was a great virtue.

But during a bank run, refusing to panic can also be a way to lose all your money.

On Monday, the Nobel Prize in Economics was given to a household name, Ben
Bernanke, and two economists’ economists, Douglas Diamond and Philip Dybvig,
largely for papers they published almost 40 years ago. So let’s talk about their work and
why, unfortunately, it remains all too relevant.

An aside: I sometimes encounter people who insist that the economics prize isn’t a
“real” Nobel, because it’s just an award handed out by some Swedes, unlike the other
prizes, which are … awards handed out by some Swedes. Yes, I may be talking my own
book here, since I got one of these things myself in 2008, but it’s hard to deny the
importance of the economics work the Swedes just honored.

Obviously, Bernanke, Diamond and Dybvig weren’t the first economists to notice that
bank runs happen. But Diamond and Dybvig provided the first really clear analysis of
why they happen — and why, destructive as they are, they can represent rational
behavior on the part of bank depositors. Their analysis was also full of implications for
financial policy. At the same time, Bernanke provided evidence on why bank runs
matter and, although he avoided saying so directly, why Milton Friedman was wrong

1 of 5 12/10/22, 5:23 am
Opinion | A Nobel Prize for the Economics of Panic - The New York... https://www.nytimes.com/2022/10/11/opinion/nobel-economics-bern...

about the causes of the Great Depression.

Diamond and Dybvig offered a stylized but insightful model of what banks do. They
argued that there is always a tension between individuals’ desire for liquidity — ready
access to funds — and the economy’s need to make long-term investments that can’t
easily be converted into cash.

Banks square that circle by taking money from depositors who can withdraw their
funds at will — making those deposits highly liquid — and investing most of that money
in illiquid assets, such as business loans.

So banking is a productive activity that makes the economy richer by reconciling


otherwise incompatible desires for liquidity and productive investment. And it normally
works because only a fraction of a bank’s depositors want to withdraw their funds at
any given time.

This does, however, make banks vulnerable to runs. Suppose that for some reason many
depositors come to believe that many other depositors are about to cash out, and try to
beat the pack by withdrawing their own funds. To meet these demands for liquidity, a
bank will have to sell off its illiquid assets at fire sale prices, and doing so can drive an
institution that should be solvent into bankruptcy. If that happens, people who didn’t
withdraw their funds will be left with nothing. So during a panic, the rational thing to do
is to panic along with everyone else.

There was, of course, a huge wave of banking panics in 1930-31. Many banks failed, and
those that survived made far fewer business loans than before, holding cash instead,
while many families shunned banks altogether, putting their cash in safes or under their
mattresses. The result was a diversion of wealth into unproductive uses. In his 1983
paper, Bernanke offered evidence that this diversion played a large role in driving the
economy into a depression and held back the subsequent recovery.

As I said, this was a tacit rejection of Milton Friedman. In the story told by Friedman
and Anna Schwartz, the banking crisis of the early 1930s was damaging because it led
to a fall in the money supply — currency plus bank deposits. Bernanke asserted that
this was at most only part of the story; his paper was, in fact, titled “Non-Monetary
Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression.”

What can be done to mitigate the risk of self-fulfilling panic? As Diamond and Dybvig
noted, a government backstop — either deposit insurance, the willingness of the central
bank to lend money to troubled banks or both — can short-circuit potential crises.
Indeed, the mere knowledge that a backstop exists can often quell a bank run; no
money need actually change hands.

But providing such a backstop raises the possibility of abuse; banks may take on undue
risks because they know they’ll be bailed out if things go wrong. Case in point: the huge

2 of 5 12/10/22, 5:23 am
Opinion | A Nobel Prize for the Economics of Panic - The New York... https://www.nytimes.com/2022/10/11/opinion/nobel-economics-bern...

costs to taxpayers of bailing out irresponsible players during the savings and loans
crisis in the 1980s. So banks need to be regulated as well as backstopped. As I said, the
Diamond-Dybvig analysis had remarkably large implications for policy.

Another implication of their work, which unfortunately went unheeded for decades, was
that we need to think carefully about what we mean by a “bank.” It doesn’t have to be a
big marble building with rows of tellers. From an economic point of view, banking is any
form of financial intermediation that offers people seemingly liquid assets while using
their wealth to make illiquid investments.

This insight was dramatically validated in the 2008 financial crisis. Conventional banks
were, for the most part, unaffected by the panic; there was no mass exodus from bank
deposits. By the eve of the crisis, however, the financial system relied heavily on
“shadow banking” — banklike activities that didn’t involve standard bank deposits. For
example, many corporations had taken to parking their cash not in deposits but in
“repo” — overnight loans using things like mortgage-backed securities as collateral.
Such arrangements offered a higher yield than conventional deposits. But they had no
safety net, which opened the door to an old-style bank run and financial panic.

And the panic came. The conventionally measured money supply didn’t plunge in 2008
the way it did in the 1930s — but repo and other money-like liabilities of financial
intermediaries did:

The run on shadow banking. FRED

Fortunately, by then Bernanke was chair of the Federal Reserve. He understood what
was going on, and the Fed stepped in on an immense scale to prop up the financial
system.

3 of 5 12/10/22, 5:23 am
Opinion | A Nobel Prize for the Economics of Panic - The New York... https://www.nytimes.com/2022/10/11/opinion/nobel-economics-bern...

Finally, a sort of meta point about the Diamond-Dybvig work: Once you’ve understood
and acknowledged the possibility of self-fulfilling banking crises, you become aware
that similar things can happen elsewhere.

Perhaps the most notable case in relatively recent times was the euro crisis of 2010-12.
Market confidence in the economies of southern Europe collapsed, leading to huge
spreads between the interest rates on, for example, Portuguese bonds and those on
German bonds. The conventional wisdom at the time — especially in Germany — was
that countries were being justifiably punished for taking on excessive debt. But the
Belgian economist Paul De Grauwe argued that what was actually happening was a
self-fulfilling panic — basically a run on the bonds of countries that couldn’t provide a
backstop because they no longer had their own currencies.

Sure enough, when Mario Draghi, the president of the European Central Bank at the
time, finally did provide a backstop in 2012 — he said the magic words “whatever it
takes,” implying that the bank would lend money to the troubled governments if
necessary — the spreads collapsed and the crisis came to an end:

“Whatever it takes” was all it took. FRED

So here’s to a well-deserved Nobel that unfortunately remains relevant.

Quick Hits
The panic in Britain’s bond market is back.

So is the spread in Italy’s.

4 of 5 12/10/22, 5:23 am
Opinion | A Nobel Prize for the Economics of Panic - The New York... https://www.nytimes.com/2022/10/11/opinion/nobel-economics-bern...

Why markets can break down in extreme situations.

Was there a natural gas bubble (ahem)?

Facing the Music

The Fed’s motto during crises?

Paul Krugman has been an Opinion columnist since 2000 and is also a distinguished professor at the City
University of New York Graduate Center. He won the 2008 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his
work on international trade and economic geography. @PaulKrugman

FOR TIMES SUBSCRIBERS

TWICE A WEEK

Paul Krugman
A guide to U.S. politics and the economy — from the mainstream to the
wonkish.

5 of 5 12/10/22, 5:23 am

You might also like