Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

World Development 128 (2020) 104847

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

World Development
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev

International linkages, technology transfer, and the skilled labor wage


share: Evidence from plant-level data in Indonesia
Mahmut Yasar a,⇑, Roderick M. Rejesus b
a
The University of Texas at Arlington, and Emory University, College of Business, Department of Economics, 701 S. West Street, Arlington, TX 76019, United States
b
North Carolina State University, Nelson Hall, 2801 Founders Drive, Raleigh, NC 27695, United States

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This paper examines whether technology transfer through international linkages (such as the importing
Accepted 17 December 2019 of intermediate inputs and foreign direct investments) influences skilled labor wage shares in Indonesian
plants. Using a variety of specifications, estimators, and robustness checks (including Correlated Random
Effects Probit, quantile fixed effects regression, and a moment-based instrumental variable (IV)
JEL classifications: approach), we find that the import of intermediate inputs and foreign direct investment likely facilitate
F14 the transfer of technologies from advanced nations, which then results in skill-biased technological
D24
change and increased relative skilled labor wage share. These results indicate that, contrary to standard
L24
J24
trade theory predictions, international linkages can lead to increased demand for skilled labor and a
J31 potential widening of the skilled-unskilled labor wage gap in Indonesia. Our findings support the theo-
O14 retical explanation provided by Acemoglu (2003). Since firms in developing countries like Indonesia
mainly rely on technologies from advanced nations, trade is likely to increase (rather than decrease)
Keywords: the skilled wage premium.
Skill-biased technological change Ó 2019 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Technology transfer
Correlated Random Effects Probit
Fixed Effects Quantile Regression
Indonesia
Asia

1. Introduction Van Reenen, 1998; Haskel & Heden, 1999; and Hollanders & ter
Weel, 2002).1
Identifying the determinants of the growing demand for skilled Overall, empirical evidence from industrialized/developed
labor (or firms’ so-called ‘‘skill-upgrading” behavior) has been an countries indicates that technological innovation that is biased
important issue in the industrial organization, international trade, toward skilled labor (i.e., high tech capital improvements such as
and labor economics literature over the years, especially in the cur- computers and computer-related technologies) is the most domi-
rent era of increasing global market integration. Ever since nant factor behind the increased demand for skilled labor (espe-
Griliches (1969) seminal work that recognized a positive relation- cially in the 1980s and 1990s). (See Berman et al., 1994; Doms,
ship between skilled labor use and capital deepening (i.e., the Dunne, & Troske, 1997; Betts, 1997; Haskel & Heden, 1999;
‘‘capital-skill complementarity” relationship), a number of
researchers have empirically confirmed this connection and have 1
Understanding the factors that affect firms’ skill-upgrading is important because
sought to find the major factors that explain it (specifically, the fac- it has critical implications for the size of the wage gap between skilled and unskilled
tors that drive increases in skilled labor demand). (See Berman, workers. Increasing demand for skilled labor (as firms use more capital) is typically
Bound, & Griliches, 1994; Autor, Katz, & Kreuger, 1998; Machin & expected to increase the wages of skilled labor and, consequently, result in the
widening of the skilled-unskilled labor wage gap. Therefore, this crucial linkage
between skilled labor demand and the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor
also underpins the significance of the determinants of skilled labor demand because it
may provide policy lessons to help address this wage gap issue. It is important to note,
however, that in this paper we only directly test the effect of factors (e.g.,
international linkages) on skilled labor demand (and not the wage gap per se). The
⇑ Corresponding author. existence of an empirical relationship for the former has implications for the latter,
E-mail addresses: myasar@uta.edu (M. Yasar), rmrejesu@ncsu.edu but the relationship to skilled labor demand does not necessarily mean that the wage
(R.M. Rejesus). gap increases.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2019.104847
0305-750X/Ó 2019 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
2 M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847

Bresnahan, Brynjolfsson, & Hitt, 2002; and Leiponen, 2005). In labor wage gap in developing countries. In contrast, our study is
industrialized nations, these technological improvements have based on several more recent theoretical studies that highlight
been driven by capital growth and are typically associated with potential economic mechanisms through which international link-
in-country research and development (R&D) efforts. ages can influence skill-upgrading in developing countries. Unlike
In developing countries like Indonesia, however, there is very standard trade theory, these new theories suggest that trade leads
limited in-country R&D that can facilitate skill-biased technologi- to higher skilled wage premiums in countries with either abundant
cal change. Yet, at the same time, there are empirical studies that skilled labor or with scarce skilled labor. The skill-upgrading pre-
still suggest these countries are also experiencing an increasing sent in developing countries, however, is due to international link-
demand for skilled labor as capital grows.2 This has led many to ages rather than in-house R&D expansion.
question the narrative that ‘‘skill-biased technological change” is The main objective of this article is to examine whether interna-
the main factor in driving skill-upgrading by firms in developing tional linkages (i.e., through importing of intermediate inputs and
countries. It has been argued that firms in developing countries typ- FDIs) directly affect the skill-upgrading behavior of firms in a par-
ically do not have the level of in-house R&D to produce skill-biased ticular developing country—in this case, Indonesia. We consider
technological innovations (Basant & Fikkert, 1996; Hershberg, this in light of the theoretical predictions from recent literature
Nabeshima, & Yusuf, 2007; Yasßar and Morrison Paul, 2012; Yasar, (highlighted in the next section), which all predict that technology
2013). Hence, it is unlikely that the main source of skill-upgrading transfers have a positive impact on skill-upgrading in the context of
in developing countries is this kind of ‘‘in-county” R&D-based tech- developing countries. We posit that international linkages facilitate
nological change. Instead, such technological changes (and conse- technology transfers, which in turn leads to increased demand for
quent skill upgrading) are more likely to be derived specifically skilled labor (i.e., skill-upgrading). This objective is achieved by uti-
from international linkages (i.e., technology transfer through import- lizing 2001–2007 plant-level manufacturing data from Indonesia
ing intermediate/capital inputs and foreign direct investments and estimating a skilled-labor share equation derived from a cost
(FDIs))—the so-called ‘‘skill enhancing trade” hypothesis (Goldberg function specification (Berman et al., 1994; Siegel, 1997; Paul &
& Pavcnik, 2007). However, the role of international linkages in the Siegel, 2001; Hollanders & ter Weel, 2002). Using a variety of econo-
skill-upgrading of firms or plants in developing countries is not metric estimators and robustness checks that account for potential
empirically well understood and, to the best of our knowledge, no endogeneity from various sources, as well as the fractional nature of
consistent relationship has been found across studies.3 the skilled labor share variable, we find that international linkages
The ‘‘international linkages-skill upgrading” relationship has (such as imports of intermediate inputs and FDIs) are positively and
been explored in previous studies, but the results have been largely significantly associated with the skill-upgrading of plants in
mixed. A paper on Chile by Pavcnik (2003) does not find any Indonesia. We also find heterogeneity in the international linkage
strong, statistically significant relationship between international effect, where firms that use more skilled labor are impacted more
linkages and skilled labor wage shares. Results for Peru from by internationalization than those that use less skilled labor.
Mazumdar and Quispe-Agnoli (2004, 2019) indicate that higher Our study contributes to the literature in several respects. First,
levels of importing (especially of intermediate inputs) statistically we focus on the case of a specific developing country—Indonesia—
decrease (rather than increase) the demand for skilled labor. that, as mentioned above, has a different economic environment
Results from Amiti and Cameron (2012) for Indonesia show that compared to industrialized nations (such that the drivers of skill-
the decrease in input tariffs leads to lower wages for skilled work- upgrading may be different than those in developed countries).
ers relative to the wages of production workers for the firms that Although there have been a number of previous studies that also
import their intermediate inputs. In contrast, evidence from focus on developing countries (Chile, Peru, Turkey, etc.), we argue
Bustos (2011) for Argentina, Demir (2010), Meschi, Taymaz, and that there is heterogeneity in the economic environments (and
Vivarelli (2011), and Turco and Maggioni (2013) for Turkey, and development paths) across developing countries, such that some-
Lee & Wei (2015) for Indonesia all suggest that improved interna- thing could still be learned by specifically examining the Indone-
tional linkages through importing or FDI channels can lead to sian case. In particular, Indonesia’s economic environment is
higher relative skilled labor wage shares (e.g., skill-upgrading). such that it has the following unique characteristics:4 (i) it is a large
The results from these latter studies tend to support the notion middle-income country where trade (specifically manufacturing
that technology transfer is the mechanism through which interna- exports) is a major driver of economic growth, (ii) international trade
tional linkages positively influence skill upgrading. Note, however, was increasingly liberalized in the early 2000s that helped reduce
that the studies above used a variety of different estimation proce- the high costs of doing international business in the country, and
dures (some of which do not properly account for different sources (iii) the preferential trading partners of Indonesia is a mix of both
of endogeneity and/or the typically fractional (non-linear) nature developed (e.g., Japan and Korea) and neighboring developing coun-
of the skilled labor wage share variable). In addition, the time peri- tries (e.g., Philippines, Malaysia, etc.). Therefore, Indonesia is an
ods that the data utilizes (as well as the developing country of interesting case to study the ‘‘skill enhancing trade” hypothesis
interest) also vary widely across studies. These factors may have because it is a large developing country with a sizable labor force
contributed to these largely mixed results. and the share of trade in the country’s income is high. Moreover, ear-
Furthermore, as we discuss in the next section, the previous lier studies that focused on Indonesia also typically used data peri-
firm-level studies highlighted above were largely based on a con- ods from the early 1990s to the early 2000s, and so our use of the
ceptual framework from standard trade theory, which predicts that data from 2001 to 2007 may also generate new, different, and more
trade tends to decrease, rather than increase, the skilled-unskilled accurate insights.5 The economic environment (i.e., industrial trad-
ing mix) and development trajectory of Indonesia in the early
2 1990s is likely different compared to the early to late 2000s. Hence,
By using plant-level data from the Turkish manufacturing industry, for instance,
Yasar and Morrison Paul (2008) find that higher capital machinery intensity and
computer use leads to a greater skilled labor share and wage (i.e. the ‘‘capital-skill or
technology-skill complementary”).
3 4
Using industry-level data from the US, Feenstra and Hanson (2002) indicate that See Takii (2019) for more information.
5
both technological change and international linkages through trade (i.e., specifically, Previous studies that used the Indonesian plant-level data covered the time
importing) are both potential sources of skill-upgrading. Note, however, that the period from 1991 to 2002 (e.g. Amiti & Cameron, 2012) or the 1996 and 2006 census
aforementioned study focuses on an industrialized country (US) context, rather than a years (e.g. Kasahara et al., 2016). Also, Lee and Wie (2015) use aggregate data for two
developing country context. See the preceeding section. periods in the 2000s (with only about 350 observations).
M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847 3

the present study can still serve as a complement to these earlier innovation may thus be a major factor that influences the skill-
studies of internationalization-induced skill-upgrading. upgrading behavior of firms in developing countries like Indonesia.
Second, we use a plant-level data set, in contrast to the much There are a number of recent theoretical studies that suggest
more common aggregate (i.e., industry-level) data used in the liter- potential economic mechanisms for which international linkages
ature. For example, although Lie and Wie (2015) also focus on can influence skill-upgrading in developing countries. However,
Indonesia, they use aggregate industry-level data for about 200 it is important to first point out that standard trade theories (i.e.
five-digit manufacturing industries (e.g., not the data for the manu- Heckscher-Ohlin model) predict that growth in international link-
facturing plants) across only two periods in the 2000s (with about age activities (i.e., through improved trade openness) tend to
350 observations). Inferences from plant-level data can produce decrease, rather than increase, the skilled-unskilled labor wage
very different estimates and insights as compared those that use gap in developing countries.6 This suggests that, based on standard
more aggregate industry-level data. The use of aggregate industry- trade theories, international linkages should not positively influence
level data can mask variation in firm-level characteristics and skill-upgrading in developing countries. However, as explained in
behavior, which can then produce misleading results. Holderness detail below, there are recent studies that explain how these link-
(2016) have shown that using aggregate data to study individual ages can actually increase skill-upgrading (and, potentially, the
firm behavior can distort estimation standard errors, weigh individ- skilled-unskilled wage gap).7
ual firms arbitrarily (depending on the composition of the data used For example, Feenstra and Hanson (1997) provide a conceptual
to aggregate), and often cannot control for all relevant individual framework in which outsourcing by multinational firms from
firm-level determinants. Model assumptions based on individual industrialized nations shifts the production in a developing coun-
firm behavior also sometimes does not hold when using aggregate try toward relatively skill-intensive goods. This drives demand
data. These factors can then easily lead to inaccurate conclusions for skilled labor among the firms in developing countries and in
when using aggregate data. Therefore, our use of plant-level data turn leads to an increase in the relative wages of these skilled
arguably generates more reliable estimates of the individual firm- workers. Since the outsourced inputs are considered unskilled
level skill-upgrading effects of improved international linkages. and labor-intensive in the industrialized countries but relatively
Third, we utilize more recent empirical estimation approaches skill-intensive in developing countries, the skill premium increases
that have not been previously used in earlier studies to address in both countries. Similarly, Feenstra and Hanson (2002) reasoned
inherent limitations of the estimation procedures used before and that the increased use of intermediate goods stemming from the
to producer more accurate estimates of the marginal effects of ‘‘global production sharing” shifts the demand toward skilled labor
international linkage variables on skilled labor wage share. For (in developing countries) and away from the unskilled labor, lead-
example, we use a correlated random effects (CRE) Probit model ing to increased skill premium.
that can simultaneously account for: (1) endogeneity due to poten- Sachs and Shatz (1998) also showed that the wage gap between
tial correlation of time-invariant unobservables (e.g., unobserved skilled and unskilled labor can increase in both developed and devel-
heterogeneity) with observable covariates, and (2) the fractional oping countries following trade liberalization (i.e., as the trade in
nature of the typical skilled labor share outcome of interest intermediate materials increases and international linkages
(Wooldridge, 2016). Earlier studies in the ‘‘skill enhancing trade” improve), suggesting that trade (or international linkages) has a pos-
literature do not address both the fractional nature of the skilled itive effect on skill-upgrading by firms. According to Xu (2003), the
labor share variable and unobserved heterogeneity at the same surge in developing countries’ imports from the industrialized
time, which can lead to misleading inferences. In addition, we uti- nations (i.e., as a result of the trade liberalization) leads to an
lize a recently developed moment-based IV estimator that allows increased demand for skilled workers in those countries. This likely
us to account for endogeneity due to both time-varying and time- leads to a higher cost of skilled labor in the industrialized countries,
invariant unobservables that can be potentially be correlated with and results in an export expansion by the developing countries as
the observable explanatory variables (Lewbel, 2012). Previous stud- well. Consequently, the demand for skilled labor and in turn the
ies typically do not account for endogeneity due to time-varying
unobservables. A two-step quantile fixed effects (FE) approach
6
(Canay, 2011) is also used to explore whether there is heterogeneity The logic of this expected decrease in the skilled-unskilled wage gap from
standard trade theories is as follows, which is explained in various books (see, for
in the effect of international linkages on skilled labor demand
instance, Pugel (2007)). A shift from autarky to free trade changes the prices of the
depending on the firm’s location on the conditional skilled wage traded products. According to the Stolper and Samuelson theorem, a rise in the price
share distribution (e.g., whether the effect of the linkages is differ- of a good increases the return to the factor that is used intensively in the production
ent for firms with lower skilled wage shares vs. firms with greater of that good, and reduces the return to the factor that is not used intensively in the
skilled wage shares). Investigating the impact heterogeneity of production of that good; the scarce factor of production loses and the abundant factor
gains. Thus, when a country moves from autarky to free trade, the prices of the
international linkage variables at different points (or quantiles) of
country’s exports will increase and the prices of its imports will fall. Advanced nations
the skilled wage share distribution is a new and novel contribution have a comparative advantage in producing high-skill-intensive goods (i.e., because
to the literature (i.e., previous literature only focus on the effect at they are rich in capital and skilled labor) and the developing countries have a
the mean). Therefore, the use of these newer estimation methods comparative advantage in producing low-skill-intensive goods (i.e., because they are
abundant in unskilled labor). Thus, for instance, before trade, the prices of machines
on micro-level plant data likely provides better insights and more
(a high-skill-intensive good) are lower in an advanced nation and the price of cloth (a
accurate estimates on how international linkages can affect skill- low-skill-intensive good) is lower in a developing country. When these two countries
upgrading in Indonesia, which can then complement earlier studies start trading, the relative prices of machines will increase in the advanced nation and
on different countries and different time periods. the relative price of cloth will rise in the developing nation. According to standard
trade theories, this will lead to an increase in real return to the factor used intensively
to produce the goods that these countries export and a decrease in the real return to
2. Conceptual framework: international linkages & skill-
the factor used intensively to produce the imported goods. Consequently, the wages
upgrading in developing countries of the unskilled worker will decline in advanced nations and increase in developing
nations. In the developing countries, the abundant factor, low-skilled labor, benefits
As mentioned in the previous section, we posit that the type of from trade. These countries have a comparative advantage in the low-skilled labor-
intensive sector. The additional demand from the developed countries increases the
skill-biased technological change in developing countries is one
prices of these goods, and thus raises the wages of the unskilled workers (lowering
where technology innovation is due to international linkages (e.g., the wage-gap in the developing country). See Fukase (2013) for empirical evidence in
importing and FDIs) rather than ‘‘in-country” or ‘‘within-firm” support of this theory.
R&D investments. This ‘‘international-linkage-driven” technological 7
See Goldberg and Pavcnik (2007) for an excellent review.
4 M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847

wages of skilled labor in all countries are likely to increase. Zhu which is available in Buletin Statistik Bulanan Indikator Ekonomi,
(2004), and Zhu and Trefler (2005) argued that over time, as the pro- or the Monthly Statistical Bulletin of Economic Indicators).8
duction of the unskilled-labor-intensive products moves from Capital input is measured by using the value of capital goods
industrialized to developing nations, the relative demand for skilled (e.g., land, building, machinery and equipment, vehicles, and
labor increases, since the shifted production is still relatively skill- others). These values are missing for 2006. Thus, we obtained the
intensive for the developing countries. This, in turn, leads to capital input for 2006 using the following interpolation. We first
skilled-labor wage premiums in developing countries. obtain the deflated capital stock (K) for plant i in year t from
Beaulieu, Benarroch, and Gaisford (2004) also provide a model K ðt Þ ¼ ½ðK ðt 1 Þ  K ðt0 ÞÞðt  t0 Þ=t 1  t 0  þ K ðt 0 Þ, where t0 and t1 repre-
that incorporates both inter- and intra-industry trade between sent the period before and after t for which the value is available.
the developed and developing countries when analyzing the We then obtain the capital input values for 2006. Our capital input
impact of trade liberalization (or international linkages) on the price deflators are obtained from the webpage of the Bank Indone-
skilled-unskilled labor wage gap impact. The study indicates that sia. The establishment data is a rich unbalanced panel data set from
reduction in trade barriers within the high-tech sectors of two 2001 to 2007 that includes typical balance sheet and income state-
regions would likely increase trade in both, which will then fuel ment information. The data also provides statistics on location
demand for more high-tech products and for the skilled labor to (e.g., province), ownership (e.g., private or state or foreign), wages
produce these products. In this case, real wages in both regions and number of workers by gender and skill level, energy usage
increase for skilled labor but decline for unskilled labor. (fuels and lubricant usage, purchase and sale of electricity), inter-
According to Acemoglu (2002a, 2002b, 2003), trade is likely to national engagement (imported intermediate input share and
increase the relative price of skill-intensive goods in developed export status), and so on.9 Note that we use the employment of pro-
countries. This incentivizes the producers of these goods to upgrade duction and non-production workers to define unskilled and skilled
their skill-complementary technologies. Thus, the resulting skilled- workers, respectively. This is common in most studies. See, for
biased technological change leads to an increased wage differential instance, the papers by Amiti and Konnings (2007) and Amiti and
between the skilled and unskilled labor. The wage gap increases in Cameron (2012) for Indonesia and Pavcnik (2003) for Chile Table A1.
developing countries as well, since they transfer and adapt these The full summary statistics for the variables used in the study
skill-complementary technologies developed in the industrialized are illustrated in Appendix Table 1. We have dropped observations
nations. Moreover, by developing a dynamic model of innovations, with missing and negative values. We have also dropped plants for
Thoenig and Verdier (2003) show that globalization can lead to which data was available only for one year, as we use fixed effect
defensive skill-complementary innovations and can consequently models. The final unbalanced panel data set used for the analysis
increase wage differentials between skilled and unskilled labor in in this article ended up with 56,320 observations for the period
both developed and developing countries. This suggests that skill- 2001–2007 Tables A2 and A3.
upgrading is also likely present in developing countries, but it Our two main variables of interest are the share of imported
may be due to international linkages rather than in-house R&D intermediate inputs and the share of foreign equity, which both
expansion. range from about 0 to 1. The imported intermediate inputs data is
Since developing countries rely on technologies developed collected by using the 10-digit Harmonized System (HS) code for
mainly in the US and other industrialized nations, trade could classifying imported inputs. In the survey, the managers are asked
increase skilled labor demand and potentially increase the wage to list the 10-digit HS code for the imported intermediate input.
inequality in these countries (e.g., rather than reduce the wage However, the researchers are only provided with the aggregate
gap as predicted by standard trade theory). The increase in the value for each plant. The survey question excludes: 1) wrapping,
international engagement that results in the flow of intermediate packing, and binding of finished goods, 2) fuel used, and 3) furniture
products, services, direct investment, and adaption and the appliances. Most plants are domestically owned (91.5%) and do not
upgrading of new technologies leads to a shift in demand toward import any intermediate inputs (81%) Tables A4 and A5.10
skilled labor, raising the relative wages of the skilled workers. As We also present descriptive statistics by ownership status (for-
highlighted by Acemoglu (1998, 1999) the further increase in skills eign vs. domestic) and by import status (importer vs. non-
over time would lead to a persistent, gradual skill-biased techno- importer) in Appendix Tables 2 and 3.11 Simple mean differences
logical change in these countries, stemming from the faster adop- from these tables indicate that foreign-owned firms and importers
tion and upgrade of skill-complementary production, marketing, tend to have higher skilled labor shares. Appendix Table 4 presents
and organization methods. Consequently, demand for skilled labor the average skilled wages share, FORS, and IMPS by industry. Appen-
will increase, potentially leading to a higher skilled labor wage pre- dix Table 5 shows the average skilled wage share by industry, import
mium. All the studies presented above show that improved inter- status, and ownership type. The trends over time of the average
national linkages through trade can positively affect skill- skilled labor wage share (by import status and by foreign ownership)
upgrading in developing countries. This is the main hypothesis are presented in Appendix Figs. 1 and 2. These trends suggest a fairly
we want to empirically test in the present study. stable skilled labor share difference over time (i.e., difference
between importer vs. non-importer and difference between foreign
3. Description of the data vs. domestic) Table A6, Figs. A1 and A2.

The source of the establishment-level (or plant-level) data used


8
in this paper is the Survei Tahunan Perusahaan Industri Pengolahan, We have also used the wholesale price indexes at the five-digit level, which we
which is an annual survey of manufacturing establishments in obtained using unpublished concordance tables from BPS, to deflate the value added.
The results were similar to these obtained by using the two-digit level deflators. Since
Indonesia conducted by Badan Pusat Statistik (BPS). This the indexes at the five-digit level are not available for some sub-industries, we ended
establishment-level production data has been used in various pre- up deflating the value added using the wholesale price indexes (WPIs) at the two-
vious studies (see, for instance, Amiti & Konings, 2007; Blalock & digit level.
9
Gertler, 2004, 2008; Roy & Yasßar, 2015). We, however, manually We updated the province codes using the information at http://www.sta-
toids.com/uid.html.
collected indexes (in 2000 prices) using an unpublished concor- 10
In our analysis, we used both the shares and the dummy variables that represent
dance table from BPS to deflate the value added and inputs. We imported material and foreign equity. The results are similar.
deflated the valued added using Indeks Harga Perdagangan Besar 11
Descriptive statistics on average skilled wage shares by industry are also
(i.e., the wholesale price indexes (WPIs) at the two-digit level, presented in Appendix Tables 4 and 5.
M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847 5

4. Empirical approach tions: Rjbj = 1; Rjbjm = 0; Rmbmj = 0; RjbjY = 0; RjbjT = 0; and Rj-
bjK = 0. The symmetry restriction also requires that bjm = bmj.15
4.1. Deriving the cost share equation specification With all these restrictions, the cost share equation for the
skilled labor input becomes:16
In order to examine the impact of international linkages on  
skill-upgrading, we consider a translog cost function with two vari- Sit ¼ a0 þ a1 lnY it þ a2 lnK it þ a3 ln W SK =W USK þ a4 T it þ v it ð3Þ
it
able inputs (e.g., skilled and unskilled workers), and one quasi-
fixed input (capital). Following standard duality arguments, we where i and t denote the firm and year, respectively; Sit is ratio of skilled
consider a translog form for the short-run variable cost function,12 wages to the sum of the total wage bill; Yit is value added, which is
which does not impose a priori restrictions on the degree of substi- obtained by subtracting the value of materials and electricity used and
tution among the inputs.13 Given that variable cost is defined as: other expenses (e.g., those pertaining to rental payments, taxes, and
VC ¼ W S LS þ W US LUS ; the second-order, twice differentiable, non- donations) from the value of production; K it is the capital stock; W SK is
homothetic, and non-neutral technical change translog variable cost the wage rate for the skilled workers; W USK is the wage rate for the
function in logarithmic terms can be written as, unskilled workers; and T is a proxy for technology or technical change.
X
lnVC it ¼ b0 þ bY lnY it þ bj lnW jit þ bK lnK it þ bT T For the variable T, studies in an industrialized country context
j typically use the share of computer expenditures in total capital
XX expenditures, the research and development expenditures, or the
1
þ 2
þ 1=2 b lnW jit lnW mit
m jm
number of patents granted. As discussed earlier, developing coun-
2bYY ðlnY it Þ j tries likely rely on international linkages that facilitate technology
X
þ 1=2bKK ðlnK it Þ þ
2
bjY lnW jit lnY it þ bYK lnY it lnK it transfer from industrialized nations, rather than investing in their
j own R&D. Thus, in this study T includes variables that represent
X X potential channels of international linkages or technology transfer:
þ bjK lnW jit lnK it þ bKT lnK it T þ bjT lnW jit T the share of imported intermediate inputs (IMPS), and the share of
j j
  foreign equity (FORS).17 Thus, our estimating equation becomes:
þ bYT lnY it T þ 1=2 bTT T 2 þ uit ; ð1Þ  
Sit ¼ b0 þ b1 lnY it þ b2 lnðK=Y Þit þ b3 ln W SK =W USK
it
where j, m = LS and LUS ;i = 1, 2,. . ., N.; t = 1, 2,. . .,T; lnVC it is the natural
X
T 1 X
N1
logarithm of the variable cost; lnWi are the natural logarithms of the þ b4 IMPSit þ b5 FORSit þ kt YDt þ ai FDi þ uit : ð4Þ
variable input prices; lnYit is the natural logarithm of the level of t¼1 i¼1
value added; lnKit is the natural logarithm of the capital input; uit Year dummies, YD, are included to control unobserved time fixed
is the error term; T represents a shift in the production technology effects such as macroeconomic shocks and changes in the institutional
or technical change; and the bs are the parameters to be estimated. environment. Firm dummies (FD) are included to control for fixed
Assuming a competitive input market, and applying Shephard’s effects such as managerial quality, work environment or culture.18
(1953, 1970) lemma, the corresponding cost share equations of the
variable inputs can be obtained as follows:14 15
In order to ensure that the Hessian o2 lnVC/olnWj lnWm is symmetric, the bjm= bmj
W jit X jit W jit X jit @lnVC it restriction is also imposed. For monotonicity, the cost function should be an
Sjit ¼ P ¼ ¼ increasing function of input prices, i.e., olnVC/olnWj >0 and o2 lnVC/olnWj >0, which
j W jit X jit VC it @lnW jit
implies that the cost shares should be positive. In order to ensure concavity in input
X
¼ bj þ bjY lnY it þ bjK lnK it þ bjT T it þ b lnW mit
m jm
ð2Þ prices, the Hessian matrix of the second partial derivatives of the variable cost
function, with respect to input prices, should be negative semi-definite. The variable
where X j is the corresponding input and Si are the shares of the vari- translog cost function can be simplified further by imposing more restrictions on the
able inputs in total variable cost. Note that the difference between parameters to be estimated. For instance, further restrictions can be imposed
depending on whether the production function is expected to be represented by
the share equations from the traditional translog cost function, short-run constant returns to scale (bY=1; biY=0; bYK=0; and bYT=0) or long-run
which is based on the assumption that all inputs are instanta- constant returns to scale (bY+bK=1; bYY+bYK=0 ; bjY+bjK=0; bYK+bKK=0; and bTY+bTK=0).
neously adaptable, and the equations here is that here the capital The long-run constant returns to scale restrictions infer that the variable cost function
input emerge as a level instead of as a price of capital. is homogeneous of degree one in output and quasi-fixed input capital. In addition, a
homothetic production function would imply that bjY =0 (See Brown & Christensen,
It is assumed that this cost function is positive, linearly
1981; Christensen & Greene, 1976).
homogenous and concave in variable input prices, increasing in 16
We estimate the cost share equation with respect to two types of labor (i.e.,
variable input prices and output, and decreasing and convex for production and non-production workers as variable inputs).
17
the quasi-fixed capital input. Given these assumptions, certain According to Solow (1960), technical change is embodied in new investment
restrictions are imposed on the estimated parameters, such as goods. Firms in developing countries transfer embodied technology by importing
intermediate and capital goods or through FDI. Thus, we use two proxies for the
the homogeneity of degree one in input prices (Brown &
technology transfer through international linkages: (1) FDI share, and (2) the share of
Christensen, 1981). For a well-behaved production function, the imported material and capital inputs from the total material input. FDI has been
cost function must be homogeneous of degree one in input prices. considered to be a strong channel for embodied technology transfer as multinational
The linear homogeneity in prices results in the following restric- firms transfer machinery, equipment, and intermediate inputs to their affiliates. Firms
without FDI transfer technologies by importing intermediate and capital inputs,
which embodies the technology.
18
Given that the wage rates in the share equation are endogenous, one typically
follows Machin and Van Reenen (1998) and replaces the wage ratio with industry-by-
time dummies. These dummy variables control for unobservable factors that are
likely to change across industries and time, such as input prices and tariffs. In
12
See Christensen et al. (1973) for a more detailed discussion about the translog addition, province-by-time and time dummy variables can also be used to control for
cost function. time-varying region-specific unobservable factors. Including industry-by-year and
13
Note that the difference between the translog short-run cost function and the region-by-year dummy variables would absorb business cycle shocks which affect
traditional translog cost function is that in the former the quasi-fixed input capital is contemporaneously the skilled share and the covariates, which can potentially bias
included as a quantity level, rather than as a price. results if not accounted for. We followed these strategies in our initial Ordinary Least
14
Applying Shephard’s lemma (1953, 1970), the derivatives of lnVCit, with respect to Squares (OLS) runs and the results are similar to those reported in this article using
@lnVC it
the prices for the variable inputs (@lnW jit
), are equal to the shares of these factors in other estimation approaches. Note that we cannot include industry and region
W jit X jit
variable cost ( VC it
) at the levels of the variable inputs that minimize the variable dummies in any of our ‘‘fixed effects” type estimation strategies (see discussion
cost. below) because they are time-invariant (and are absorbed in the firm fixed effects).
6 M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847

We tested for multicollinearity of the independent variables in to unobserved time-invariant factors (i.e., the potential correlation
equation (6) to make sure that we have proper inferences from the between unobserved firm heterogeneity and observed time-
empirical specification. Variance Inflation Factors (VIFs) are given varying covariates in the model (Wooldridge, 2016)).20 The CRE
in Appendix Table 6. The ‘‘rule of thumb” in the literature is that Probit approach builds on the well-known Mundlak-Chamberlain
a VIF > 10 or a tolerance level < 0.1 is a sign of a serious multi- approach and models firm fixed effects as a linear function of the
collinearity problem. None of the variables used for the analysis firm-level averages of the covariates (Papke & Wooldridge, 2008;
had VIFs greater than 10 or tolerance levels less than 0.1, indicating Wooldridge, 2016).
that multicollinearity is not a threat. For linear models, Mundlak (1978) showed that the traditional
fixed effects model is equivalent to the OLS model that includes the
4.2. Estimation strategy: correlated random effects (CRE) probit averages of the time-varying covariates in addition to the observed
covariates themselves. In other words, the CRE Probit model and
Our main estimation strategy is based on a fractional response the traditional fixed effects model produce identical estimates in
model in an unbalanced panel data context. Given the panel nature the linear panel data context, but produce different results in non-
of our data, we first consider traditional panel data estimation linear panel data specifications. However, the marginal effects and
methods that would allow for unobserved heterogeneity and iden- the standard errors obtained in the CRE Probit approach are more
tify the effects of international linkages on skilled labor share. reliable for nonlinear models like the one in this study (more on
We begin with a traditional panel data random effects (RE) esti- this below). Papke and Wooldridge (2008) control for the potential
mator that produces consistent and efficient estimates only if the correlation between the unobserved factors and time-varying
explanatory variables are not correlated with unobserved time- covariates in fractional response models with balanced panel data
invariant variables (e.g., endogeneity due to unobserved hetero- by including the covariates’ firm-specific means over time. Fur-
geneity). This may not be a valid assumption in our case, as the thermore, Wooldridge (2016) builds on the work of Papke and
unobserved time-invariant factors, such as time-invariant manage- Wooldridge (2008) by estimating fractional response models for
rial quality, are likely to be correlated with the observed time- unbalanced panel data by not only including the time averages of
variant explanatory variables in the model. This assumption is the covariates, but also including variables that represent the num-
relaxed in the traditional panel fixed effects (FE) approach, which ber of years each firm is in the sample.
we also use in this study. This FE approach suffers from the so- More specifically, suppose that we have four time-varying
called ‘‘incidental parameters” problem in estimating nonlinear covariates: x1; x2; x3; and x4: Further, suppose that the mean of these
models, however (i.e., given the fractional (between zero and covariates over time for each firm are: x1 ; x2 ; x3 ; and x4 : In a CRE
one) nature of our dependent variable (see the share equation in Probit framework, we can then run yit on x1; x2; x3; x4: x1 ; x2 ; x3 ; x4 ,
(4))). In addition, the traditional RE and FE estimators also do not year dummies, firm averages of year dummies, industry and region
directly account for the fractional nature of the outcome variable dummies, and proxy variables that represent the total number of
years that each firm has data for in the sample. In this case, the
(e.g., predictions maybe outside the range of zero and one). P
Notwithstanding the shortcomings of these two traditional panel term ai ¼ ðd1 x1 þ d2 x2 þ d3 x3 þ d4 x4 Þ in the CRE Probit approach
data methods, we still utilize the RE and FE methods in this article developed by Papke and Wooldridge (2008) allows for the poten-
as the basis of comparison for the other estimation procedures (see tial correlation between unobserved firm heterogeneity and the
below). time-varying covariates. The inclusion of the firm-specific time
In light of these limitations we primarily utilize the Correlated averages controls for these potential correlations in the case of a
Random Effects (CRE) Probit approach for estimating fractional balanced panel. For an unbalanced panel, variables that represent
response models with unbalanced panel data (see Wooldridge, the number of years each firm is present in the sample also needs
2016). Consider the following ‘‘more compact” representation of to be included in order to control for the unobserved firm hetero-
the share equation: geneity (Wooldridge, 2016). In the present study, we follow the
general specification described above for the CRE Probit approach
EðSit jX it ; ai Þ ¼ GðX it b þ ai Þ; ð5Þ in order to address endogeneity problems associated with the
unobserved heterogeneity issue (e.g., our nonlinear CRE Probit
where the X vector includes the explanatory variables discussed in models include the covariates and their averages, time fixed
the previous section, including the year dummies; ai represents the effects, averages of time fixed effects, industry and region fixed
plant-specific, unobserved, time-invariant characteristics that can effects, and variables that identify the number of total years each
affect the skill-upgrading (and/or the other elements of X); G is a firm is represented in the sample).21
nonlinear link function taking on values strictly between zero and Another advantage of using the CRE Probit in our context is that it
one, for which the standard normal cumulative distribution func- allows us to obtain appropriate and more accurate marginal effects,
tion (Probit link function) is considered. as well as their corresponding standard errors. As highlighted in
Papke and Wooldridge (1996) first introduced a quasi- Wooldridge (2016), when T is small and n is large (as in our case),
maximum likelihood estimator (QMLE) that is appropriate for the the traditional fixed effects estimators does not allow us to predict
fractional model in (5), but only when using cross-sectional data. the appropriate average/marginal effects, as the conditional mean of
This approach is robust to heteroscedasticity, ensures that the pre- the heterogeneity is not taken into consideration. Both traditional
dicted values of the outcome fall in the zero to one interval, allows fixed effects and random effects models require shocks to be inde-
for nonlinear effects, and provides consistent estimates of partial/- pendent over time. This assumption is not required with the CRE
marginal effects.19 Papke and Wooldridge (2008) and Wooldridge model. The CRE approach identifies the marginal effects by allowing
(2016) then extended the QMLE method to panel data by introducing for the serial dependence in the data over time, as long as the num-
the CRE Probit methods for balanced and unbalanced data, respec-
tively. Given that our data is an unbalanced panel, the pertinent esti-
mator in our case is the estimator from Wooldridge (2016). 20
Even if the CRE Probit has a ‘‘random effects” name attached to it (i.e., correlated
Similar to the traditional panel FE model, the CRE Probit ‘‘random effects”), it is unlike the traditional panel data ‘‘random effects” model
approach for unbalanced panel data controls for endogeneity due because the CRE Probit approach can address endogeneity due to unobserved
heterogeneity.
21
In light of this specification that includes averages for each firm, we only keep
19
See Ramalho et al. (2011) for a review. plants that have two or more observations in our analysis.
M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847 7

ber of cross-sectional observations is large enough (i.e., we have a data estimators and the CRE Probit estimator only allow us to
large number of cross sectional observations). examine the impact of international linkage variables on the
In summary, the CRE Probit approach used in this article allows expected (mean) value of the relative demand for skilled labor.
us to address the unobserved heterogeneity problem and does not However, there could be substantial heterogeneity in the condi-
require the shocks to be independent overtime, which then allows tional distribution of the skilled labor share, and it would also be
us to causally identify the parameters associated with our indepen- useful to analyze the impact of international linkages at different
dent variables of interest (e.g., importing of intermediate inputs points of the conditional skilled labor share distribution (aside
and foreign direct investments). from the mean). For example, it would be interesting to see if the
effect of imports and FDI is higher for those plants at the higher
4.3. Robustness check: instrumental variable (IV) based on higher end of the conditional skilled labor share distribution vis-à-vis
moments of data those plants at the lower end. Moreover, results from the quantile
FE regression at the median of the conditional outcome distribu-
Notwithstanding the desirable features of the CRE Probit tion can also serve as a useful robustness check relative to the esti-
approach in our empirical context, it may still be possible that mated ‘‘mean” effects from the RE, FE, and CRE Probit estimators.
there is residual endogeneity due to unobserved time-varying In particular, we use the two-step quantile FE approach devel-
(rather than time-invariant) shocks that can affect both the oped by Canay (2011) where the unobserved fixed effects are elim-
demand for skilled labor and the international involvement of inated using a data transformation approach that treats them as
firms. Although we believe that the main source of endogeneity location shifters. To illustrate this approach, consider another com-
in our context is unobserved heterogeneity (which we address pact notation for equation (4) prior to the first-differencing
through the use of the CRE Probit model), we also used a recently transformation:
developed moment-based instrumental variable (IV) approach (see
Sit ¼ X it bðsÞ þ gi þ lit ðsÞ ð6Þ
Lewbel, 2012) to address the possible endogeneity due to a corre-
lation between time-varying unobservables and the observed where Sit is the skilled wage share as described in equation (4), X it is a
covariates, which further allows us to identify the causal effects vector that includes the explanatory variables discussed in equation
of the international linkage variables on skilled labor demand in (4), bðsÞ is a vector of parameters to be estimated at particular quan-
the presence of this type of endogeneity. The moment-based IV tile s, gi is the unobserved fixed-effect for cross-sectional unit i, and
estimator utilizes heteroscedasticity for the error terms from the lit ðsÞ is the idiosyncratic, time-varying error term at a particular
first-stage regression (e.g., regression of the international linkages quantile s. Given the notation in (6), the first step in the Canay
pffiffiffi
variables to observable covariates) to identify the coefficients of (2011) approach is computing a T -consistent estimator of gi using
the endogenous variables even in the absence of exclusion restric- pffiffiffiffiffiffi
a nT -consistent estimator of b derived from an Ordinary Least
tions or valid instruments. Squares (OLS) regression of the first-differences (i.e., a regression of
In order to implement the Lewbel (2012) technique, we have
DSit on DX it ). The second step then uses gb to calculate b
i
b
S it  Sit  git
specified two auxiliary or first-stage equations: one for FDI and
one for importing. According to Lewbel (2012), our model is iden- and run a quantile regression of bS it on X it to estimate the parameters
tified if the error terms in the first-stage FDI and importing equa- at different quantiles bðsÞ. For proper inference, bootstrapped stan-
tions are heteroscedastic. That is, some of the control variables in dard errors (using 500 replications) are calculated in the second stage.
the first stage are correlated with the variance of the first-stage Using the quantile FE regression approach above allows us to
error terms, but not with the covariance between the error terms control for the endogeneity associated with unobservables that
of these two equations and the error term in the second-stage out- are time invariant (as in the traditional fixed-effects or first-
come equation (equation (4) in the manuscript). Then, the residu- differencing transformation), and at the same time allows us to
als from the first-stage FDI and importing equations multiplied by examine the effect of international linkages at different points in
each of the exogenous covariates in mean-centered form can serve the conditional outcome distribution. Thus, we would have infor-
as valid instruments. We used the Breusch and Pagan (1979) test to mation on whether the impact of international linkages varies
validate the presence of the heteroscedasticity condition required depending on where the firm is in terms of the conditional out-
for the error terms in the first-stage regressions. Note that the first come distribution. Another advantage of the quantile FE regression
stage regressions included the natural log of valued added and the is that estimates are robust to outliers in the outcome variable.
capital – valued added intensity as covariates. As illustrated in
Table 2, the Sargan or Hansen J test of overidentifying restrictions 5. Results
to test for correlation between instruments and error terms vali-
date the use of these instruments (i.e., the P-Value is greater than In Table 1, we first show results from the traditional panel RE
0.10, which means we fail to reject the presence of exogeneity). and FE estimation approaches (see columns 1 and 2). As noted
The results are illustrated in the first column of Table 2. above, these estimation procedures may not provide valid esti-
In summary, the CRE Probit approach allows us to causally iden- mates given the underlying assumptions in each approach (i.e.,
tify effects of international linkages on skilled labor demand if the correlation between the explanatory variables and unobserved
main source of endogeneity is due to unobserved heterogeneity heterogeneity for RE, and the incidental parameters problem for
(e.g., time-invariant unobservables correlated with observed FE). Nonetheless, results from these initial RE and FE runs suggest
covariates). Furthermore, the moment-based IV procedure we use that the importing intensity (as proxied through the IMPS variable)
as a robustness check allows us to address endogeneity due to and FDI (as proxied through the FORS variable) have a strong statis-
the possible correlation between time-varying unobservables and tically significant positive effect on the share of skilled wages to
observed covariates. the sum of the total wage bill (Sit).
Given the limitations of the RE and FE models, we estimated the
4.4. Robustness check: quantile FE regression share equation in (4) using the CRE Probit procedure described in
the previous section and present the estimated marginal effects
In addition to the estimation procedures described in the previ- in the third column of Table 1. The results from the CRE Probit is
ous two sub-sections, we also utilized a quantile FE regression consistent with the RE and FE estimates, where the marginal
approach as a robustness check. Note that the traditional panel effects associated with the IMPS and FORS variables reveal a strong
8 M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847

Table 1 ate import shares or foreign equity shares has a statistically signifi-
Results from the Random Effects (RE), Fixed Effects (FE), and Correlated Random cant positive effect on skilled labor wage share is important in and of
Effects (CRE) Probit Estimation Approaches.
itself given that standard trade theories predict the opposite (e.g.,
(1) (2) (3) international linkages increase unskilled labor wages in developing
Variables RE FE CRE Probit: ME countries and narrows he skilled-unskilled labor wage gap). In addi-
ln Y 0.016*** 0.006*** 0.005*** tion, relative to the standard deviation of the skilled labor share vari-
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) able (which is 0.178 in Appendix Table 1), the magnitude of the
ln (K/Y) 0.013*** 0.008*** 0.007***
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
international linkage effect can arguably still be considered as non-
FORS 0.040*** 0.033*** 0.025*** trivial.
(0.005) (0.008) (0.007) As highlighted earlier, Lee and Wie (2015) use five-digit
IMPS 0.048*** 0.036*** 0.030*** industry-level data (not plant-level data) to examine the impact
(0.006) (0.008) (0.007)
of international linkages on the share of skilled labor in total wage
Constant 0.005 0.144*** –
(0.009) (0.016) – bill. As illustrated in Table 8 in their study, the magnitude of the
import share effect is similar to ours (e.g., around 0.03). The coef-
Total No. of Obs. 56,320 56,320 56,320
Number of Plants 18,559 18,559 18,559 ficient on the foreign equity share, however, is a little different,
as they include the foreign equity share and import share variables
Notes:
separately in their regressions, not simultaneously. Apart from
(1) Robust standard errors in parentheses; ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
(2) RE = random effects, FE = fixed effects, CRE = Correlated Random Effects,
using industry-level data, including these two variables separately
ME = Marginal Effects could lead to omitted variable bias. They also use pooled OLS with
(3) Y = value added, K = capital stock, FORS = share of foreign equity (representing year fixed effects, which is different from our approach. Amiti and
FDI), IMPS = share of imported intermediate inputs. Cameron (2012) use the natural log of the firm-level ratio of the
(4) Year Dummies (YD) are included in all estimation runs (1–3) above. However,
non-production wages to production wages and they also interact
for brevity, the parameter estimates for YD are not reported here, but are available
from the authors upon request. the import share with the five-digit industry-level tariffs. Thus, it is
(5) The results reported in column (3) are the estimated marginal effects (ME) from difficult for us to compare the magnitude of our results with theirs.
the CRE Probit model, which would allow for valid comparisons with the RE and FE As we discuss below, they also predict and confirm that the trade
estimates in columns (1) and (2). The actual coefficient estimates (e.g., not marginal
liberalization lowers the skilled wage premium. Their findings
effects) from the CRE Probit Model are available from the authors upon request.
are the inverse of what we find, and what Lee & Wei find using
industry-level data.23
statistically significant positive sign. This is evidence that interna- Amiti and Cameron (2012) examine the effect of tariff changes
tional linkages through importing intensity and FDIs likely increase or trade liberalization on the wages of production workers relative
relative skilled labor demand (e.g., skill-upgrading) in Indonesia. It to non-production workers.24 Their results show that the decrease
is also important to note that the magnitudes of the estimated in input tariffs leads to lower wages for non-production workers rel-
marginal effects for IMPS and FORS in column (3) are slightly lower ative to those of production workers for the firms that import their
than the magnitudes for the RE and FE estimates in columns (1) intermediate inputs. They interact the import variable with
and (2). This suggests that the RE and FE estimates may be biased industry-level input and output tariff variables and show that at
upwards. the mean of the imported intermediate input share (0.25), a one per-
In terms of magnitudes, the CRE Probit results indicate that a centage point fall in input tariffs decreases the skill premium (the
ten percentage point increase in the import share of intermediate natural log WS/WUS) by 0.45 percentage points. The impact of the
inputs leads to a 0.3 percentage point increase in relative skilled cut in the output tariff, however, is not significant. Amiti and
labor wage share. Similarly, a ten percentage point increase in for- Cameron (2012) offer the following intuition for these findings.
eign equity share leads to a 0.255 percentage point increase in the Importing firms may stop producing skill-intensive inputs ‘‘in-
share of skilled labor wage (vis-à-vis the total wage bill). We can house” and begin importing these inputs (international outsource)
provide further information on the magnitude of the variables by after the tariffs are cut. They may instead become more vertically
using the summary statistics illustrated in Appendix Table 2 and integrated in terms of the production of less-skill intensive produc-
Appendix Table 3. As illustrated in Appendix Table 2, the average tion stages. This will lead to less demand for skilled workers and
value of import share for the foreign-owned firms and domestic higher demand for unskilled workers, and thus a lower skilled wage
firms is 39.3% and 6.2%, respectively, resulting in a difference of premium. They also predict that the cut in input tariffs will result in
33.1%. This indicates that if the domestically owned firms had higher efficiency and profit for the importers, which will then yield
the average import share of the foreign-owned firms, the share of higher demand for both skilled and unskilled workers.
the skilled labor in total wages would increase by 0.9 percentage The theoretical papers we reviewed in the conceptual frame-
points. Similarly, as illustrated in Appendix Table 3, the foreign work section, however, predict the opposite.25 More trade liberal-
equity share for the importers and non-importers is 24.5% and ization or a cut in input tariffs is likely to increase the skill
2.9%, respectively. Thus, if the non-importers had the foreign premium as the intermediate or capital inputs would complement
equity share of the importing firms, the share of the skilled labor skilled labor, create higher demand for skilled workers, and substi-
in total wages would increase by 0.54 percentage points. tute them for unskilled labor. The wage gap is likely to increase since
Note that the magnitude of the estimated IMPS and FORS effects firms transfer and adapt skill-complementary technologies devel-
does not seem to be particularly ‘‘large” given the less than one oped in the industrialized nations. The results from Amiti and
percentage point increase of the skill labor wage share in the sce- Cameron (2012) are consistent with the standard trade theory pre-
narios described above. This suggests that increasing the share of
imported intermediate inputs or the share of foreign equity may
not lead to substantially large increases in the skilled labor wage 23
We included an export dummy in our models, but its coefficient was insignificant
share.22 Nevertheless, the ‘‘directional” result that larger intermedi- and dropping it from the model does not affect the parameter estimates of the other
variables. In other words, it does not lead to omitted variable bias.
24
Another study on Indonesia is from Kasahara et al. (2016), who examine the
22
As noted by a reviewer, given the estimated magnitude of the international impact on the skilled labor demand, not on the wages of the skilled labor. They used
linkage effect, it is possible that substantial technology transfers may not lead to a data for two years: 1996 and 2006.
25
proportionally large increase in skilled labor wages. See Goldberg and Pavcnik (2007) for an excellent review.
M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847 9

Table 2
Robustness Checks: Results from the Moment-based IV Method and the Fixed Effects Quantile Regression (at various quantiles).

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)


Variables Moment-based IV Quantile Regression Estimates (by different quantiles)
0.1 0.25 0.5 0.75 0.90
ln Y 0.00591*** 0.002*** 0.004*** 0.006*** 0.009*** 0.013***
(0.01255) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
ln (K/Y) 0.00728*** 0.003*** 0.004*** 0.008*** 0.010*** 0.014***
(0.00098) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
FORS 0.06371*** 0.025*** 0.026*** 0.033*** 0.031*** 0.057***
(0.01718) (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.008) (0.010)
IMPS 0.03086** 0.033*** 0.042*** 0.036*** 0.035*** 0.040***
(0.01433) (0.009) (0.007) (0.008) (0.008) (0.011)
Constant – 0.106*** 0.148*** 0.144*** 0.128*** 0.219***
– (0.017) (0.015) (0.014) (0.014) (0.015)
Sargan/Hansen J P-Value 0.5516 – – – – –
Cragg-Donald Wald F statistic 386.183 – – – – –
Total No. of Obs. 56,320 56,320 56,320 56,320 56,320 56,320
Number of Plants 18,559 18,559 18,559 18,559 18,559 18,559

Notes:
(1) Robust standard errors in parentheses; ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
(2) Columns (2) to (6) represents the relevant percentiles (and/or quantiles) of the outcome variable for which the quantile regression pertains.
(3) Y = value added, K = capital stock, FORS = share of foreign equity (representing FDI), IMPS = share of imported intermediate inputs.
(4) Year Dummies (YD) are included in all estimation runs (columns 1–6) above. However, for brevity, the parameter estimates for YD are not reported here, but are available
from the authors upon request.

dictions. On the contrary, we find that liberalization (more import of The robustness check results from the quantile FE procedure
intermediate inputs and FDI) can lead to increased demand for are reported in columns (2) to (6) of Table 2 (e.g., for the following
skilled labor and a widening of the skilled-unskilled labor wage quantiles: 0.1, 0.25, 0.5, 0.75, and 0.90). Recall that the quantile FE
gap in Indonesia. Our findings support the theoretical explanation regression was conducted to examine whether the effects of the
provided by Acemoglu (2003), where he concludes that trade leads international linkage variables varies depending on the location
to higher skilled wage premiums in both countries with abundant of the plant in the conditional skilled wage share distribution.
skilled labor and countries with scarce skilled labor. Our empirical We find that the effects of international linkages on the skilled
results and Acemoglu (2003) explanation support the notion that labor wage share are larger for firms at the higher end of the con-
skill-biased technological changes in a developing country like ditional outcome distribution (at the 0.90 quantile). However, the
Indonesia are mainly drawn from advances in industrialized nations, effects at the lower quantiles (e.g., 0.75, median, and quantiles
and the transfer of these technological innovations to developing below the median) tend to have effect magnitudes that are quite
nations are facilitated by international linkages—particularly, similar to the estimated ‘‘mean” effects from the RE, FE, CRE Pro-
through importing and/or FDI. In fact, the studies in other countries bit, and moment-based IV regressions. Hence, the ‘‘median”
document that trade liberalization resulted in higher demand for regression results (0.5 quantile) is generally consistent with the
skilled labor, and thus higher skill premiums or wage inequality in ‘‘mean” effects from the other estimations (with the exception of
various developing countries. For instance, these findings are docu- the FORS variable in the moment-based IV). The main inference
mented by Harrison and Hanson (1999) for Mexico and Chile, that increased international linkages (through the importing of
Gindling and Robbins (2001) for Chile and Costa Rica, Attanasio, intermediate materials and FDI) leads to higher skilled labor
Goldberg, and Pavcnik (2004) for Colombia, and Demir (2010), demand is robust across all estimation procedures used in the
Meschi, Taymaz, and Vivarell (2011), and Turco and Maggioni study.
(2013) for Turkey. Our study complements these studies. Overall, our findings show that international linkages, specifi-
The robustness check results using the moment-based IV and cally through importing and FDIs, play an important role in the
quantile FE regression results are presented in Table 2. The skill-upgrading behavior of firms in Indonesia. These international
moment-based IV results (see column 1) still suggests that the linkages tend to increase skill-upgrading and, consequently, have
international linkage variables have a statistically significant posi- the potential to increase the skilled-unskilled labor wage gap.
tive effect on skilled labor demand. In addition, the magnitude of Although the magnitude of the estimated international linkage
the parameter estimate for IMPS is in line with previous estimates effects is not particularly ‘‘large”, we believe that it is still non-
from the CRE Probit estimator. However, the magnitude of the trivial, and the statistically significant positive relationship
FORS parameter estimate from the moment-based IV estimator between international linkages and skilled labor wage share is
tend to be somewhat higher than the one estimated by the CRE important because it is in contrast to what is predicted by standard
PRobit model. Nonetheless, these moment-based IV results gener- trade theory, where the wage gap between skilled and unskilled
ally support the notion that the main source of endogeneity in our labor is predicted to decrease as a developing country participates
specification may be due to the correlation of unobserved time- more in international trade.
invariant variables and the observed covariates, which is con- It is likely that skill-biased technological change is facilitated
trolled for in the FE and CRE probit regressions. Controlling for by firms’ international linkages (i.e., more importing of intermedi-
endogeneity due to the correlation of unobservable time-varying ate goods and FDIs), such that positive skill-upgrading is revealed
factors and the observed covariates (i.e., through the moment- in the analysis. This suggests that foreign technology transfer
based IV) generate results that does not substantially differ from through imports and FDI may be a more important source of
the main inferences based on the FE and CRE Probit results (with skill-upgrading in developing countries (as compared to in-
the exception of the larger magnitude of the FORS variable). country R&D efforts in industrialized nations). Since firms in
10 M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847

developing countries (like Indonesia) barely conduct their own international linkages—particularly, through importing and/or
R&D, it is likely that technology transfer through importing con- FDI.27 Our study also complements Pavcnik (2003), who highlighted
tacts and through multinational companies (i.e., where they invest FDI as an important source of increased demand for skilled labor in
in local subsidiaries) are the main factors affecting skill- Chile.
upgrading.26 The imitation of technologies from industrialized Studying the determinants of the increasing skilled labor
nations may also be enhanced through these types of international demand in Indonesia and its implications on the wage gap between
linkages. skilled and unskilled workers is of interest not only to the aca-
demic community but also to policy makers. The wage gap is typ-
ically attributed to skill-biased technological change, trade, foreign
6. Conclusions direct investment, and the migration of unskilled workers. In this
study, we show that the increase in skilled labor demand and the
Various studies have explored the relationship between capital potential widening of the wage gap of skilled relative to unskilled
deepening and skilled labor demand (i.e., the capital-skill comple- workers in Indonesia can potentially be linked with the import of
mentarity concept), but the majority of these studies are in the capital inputs and foreign direct investment.28 The technology
context of industrialized countries. The main insight from these transfers through these channels would not only increase the
studies is that skill-biased technological change is the main demand for skilled labor but also enhance their productivity more
determinant of the positive relationship between capital and than that of unskilled labor. This, in turn, can potentially lead to a
skilled-labor demand in these nations. Moreover, the skill-biased larger wage gap between the two groups.
technological change in industrialized nations is typically associ- The firms in developing countries will continue to adopt new
ated with in-country R&D efforts. technologies and demand more skilled workers to stay competi-
However, in developing countries like Indonesia, there are few tive in the global marketplace. Technological change or innovation
in-country R&D efforts that can facilitate skill-biased technological is viewed by these countries as the main source of productivity
change, and yet there are empirical studies in developing coun- growth by endogenous growth theory (Romer, 1990; Lucas,
tries that still suggest an increase in the demand for skilled labor 1988). The sources of innovation are investments in research
(as well as a potential widening of the skilled-unskilled labor wage and development and technology transfer through international
gap) as capital grows. Note, however, that previous empirical stud- linkages from other nations. Note, however, that firms in Indone-
ies in developing countries have shown mixed results in terms of sia mainly rely on the technology and knowledge produced by
the effect of international linkages on skilled labor demand, advanced nations rather than investments in in-house research
depending on the country and the time period considered (i.e., and development. Policy makers in Indonesia should focus on
some show no statistically significant effect, some show a statisti- matching the increase in demand for skilled workers (which is
cally negative effect, and some show a significantly positive associated with technology transfers) with an equivalent increase
effect). In this study, we posit that international linkages, through in the supply of skilled workers, given that transfers, the adoption
imports and FDIs, are the main determinants of this skill-biased of better technologies, and the hiring of more skilled workers are
technological change in Indonesia, and these international link- all essential to stay competitive in an increasingly global economic
ages in turn lead to more skill-upgrading (i.e., a higher demand environment. Increases in skilled labor or human capital would
for skilled labor). Note that this explanation contradicts the stan- not only lead to more technology transfer and adoptions, but also
dard trade theory prediction that trade openness would result in result in investments in in-house research and development, and
increased unskilled labor demand and a potential narrowing of thus more innovation the long run. Hence, one way to potentially
the skilled-unskilled labor wage gap (i.e., see footnote 6 in this narrow the skilled-unskilled labor wage gap is not to pursue poli-
paper). Therefore, it is important to empirically test whether inter- cies that will lead to less technology transfers, but rather to focus
national linkages do lead to increased skill-upgrading in a devel- on policy interventions that can help match the increase in
oping country like Indonesia. This is the main goal of the demand for skilled workers that stems from these transfers with
present study. an increase in the supply of skilled workers (i.e., through educa-
Using plant-level data from Indonesia (and a number of estima- tional interventions that increase worker skills).
tion procedures), we find empirical support for our hypothesis
that international linkages do indeed have a statistically signifi-
cant positive effect on the skill-upgrading of firms (although the Declaration of Competing Interest
magnitude of the effect is not substantially large). Acemoglu
(2003) provides a theoretical explanation for this result, where The authors declare that they have no known competing finan-
he concluded that trade ‘‘induces skill-biased technical change, cre- cial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared
ating a powerful force towards higher skill premia in both skill- to influence the work reported in this paper.
abundant and skill-scarce countries.” Since the firms in Indonesia
mainly rely on the technologies developed in advanced nations,
trade is expected to increase rather than decrease skilled labor
demand and this can potentially widen the skilled-unskilled labor 27
Intermediate material and/or capital imports (see Grossman & Helpman, 1991;
wage gap. Our empirical results and the explanation from
Coe & Helpman, 1995; Eaton & Kortum, 1996; Xu & Wang, 1999; Eaton & Kortum,
Acemoglu (2003) support the notion that skill-biased technologi- 2001; and Keller, 2002a, 2002b; Yasar & Morrison Paul, 2007; Yasar, 2013) as well as
cal changes in a developing country like Indonesia are mainly dri- FDIs (see Blomstrom & Kokko, 1998, Saggi, 1999; Carr et al., 2001; Yasar & Morrison
ven by advances in industrialized nations, and the transfer of these Paul, 2007) have been recognized as the two main channels for firms in developing
technological innovations to developing nations is facilitated by countries to transfer technologies from the advanced nations.
28
As noted in the previous section, although we find a statistically significant
positive relationship between international linkages and skilled labor wage share, we
26
Note that this observation is consistent with the studies of Basant and Fikkert consider the magnitude of the estimated effect as not necessarily ‘‘large” but we still
(1996) and Sharma (2016). Basant and Fikkert (1996) found that the productivity consider the effect magnitude to be ‘‘non-trivial.” Hence, as pointed out by one
impact of foreign technology purchases is much greater than that of firms’ own in- reviewer, it is possible that the consequent wage gap impact may not be ‘‘as large” to
house R&D. In a recent study, Sharma (2016) finds similar results for the Indian firms. be of concern to policy makers. However, we argue that this issue is still of concern to
That is, the productive impact of foreign technology transfer is stronger than that of Indonesian policy makers given the interest in sustaining economic growth through
in-house R&D. trade expansion and having a more equitable wage distribution in the long-term.
M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847 11

Acknowledgements Table A1
Descriptive Statistics for the Full Sample [N = 56,320].

We are indebted to the editor and two anonymous referees for Variables Mean Standard
their valuable suggestions and comments. We also wish to Deviation
acknowledge helpful comments by Benjamin Liebman, Luis Orea, Natural Log of Value Added 13.50 1.972
Lourenco Paz, and participants at the European Workshop on Effi- Natural Log of Capital Stock 13.55 2.029
ciency and Productivity Analysis, Southern Economic Association Share of Foreign Equity 0.0698 0.240
Share of Imported Intermediate Inputs 0.0904 0.240
Conference, Florida International University, and the Oklahoma
Foreign Equity Dummy 0.085 0.279
State University. Import Dummy 0.190 0.393
Share of Skilled Labor in Plant Employment 0.176 0.146
Share of Skilled Labor in Plant Wage Bill 0.236 0.178
Natural Log of Capital Stock / Value Added 0.0456 1.624
Skill Premium (The ratio of Skilled Wage to 2.590 26.54
Unskilled Wage per Worker)
Appendix

Fig. A1.

Fig. A2.
12 M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847

Table A2
Descriptive Statistics by Ownership Type [N = 56,320].

Variables Domestic Firms Foreign Firms Mean Difference


[1] [2] [2]-[1]
Natural Log of Value Added 13.285 15.820 2.535***
(1.827) (1.973)
Natural Log of Capital Stock 13.348 15.672 2.324***
(1.898) (2.162)
Share of Foreign Equity – – –
– –
Share of Imported Intermediate Inputs 0.062 0.393 0.331***
(0.198) (0.391)
Foreign Equity Dummy – – –
– –
Import Dummy 0.146 0.664 0.518***
(0.353) (0.472)
Share of Skilled Labor in Plant Employment 0.172 0.213 0.041***
(0.143) (0.171)
Share of Skilled Labor in Plant Wage Bill 0.227 0.340 0.113***
(0.171) (0.214)
Natural Log of Capital Stock / Value Added 0.064 0.148 0.212***
(1.587) (1.964)
Skill Premium (The ratio of Skilled Wage to Unskilled Wage per Worker) 2.430 4.310 1.880***
(26.966) (21.298)

Notes:
(1) Value in Parentheses are Standard Deviations (SDs).
(2) ***, **, **—statistically significant difference at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels.

Table A3
Descriptive Statistics by Import Status [N = 56,320]

Variables Non-Importer Importer Mean Difference


[1] [2] [2]-[1]
Natural Log of Value Added 13.102 15.198 2.096***
(1.703) (2.126)
Natural Log of Capital Stock 13.168 15.154 1.986***
(1.780) (2.225)
Share of Foreign Equity 0.029 0.245 0.216***
(0.158) (0.398)
Share of Imported Intermediate Inputs – – –
– –
Foreign Equity Dummy 0.035 0.297 0.262***
(0.185) (0.457)
Import Dummy – – –
– –
Share of Skilled Labor in Plant Employment 0.168 0.209 0.041***
(0.141) (0.163)
Share of Skilled Labor in Plant Wage Bill 0.220 0.308 0.088***
(0.168) (0.200)
Natural Log of Capital Stock / Value Added 0.067 0.044 0.023***
(1.567) (1.841)
Skill Premium (The ratio of Skilled Wage to Unskilled Wage per Worker) 2.314 3.768 1.454***
(24.056) (35.167)

Notes:
(1) Value in parentheses are Standard Deviations (SDs).
(2) ***, **, **—statistically significant difference at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels.
M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847 13

Table A4
Average Skilled Wage Share, FORS, and IMPS by Industry.

Skilled Wage Share FORS IMPS


Food products, beverages, and tobacco 0.231 0.026 0.03
Textiles, textile products, leather, and footwear 0.193 0.076 0.111
Wood and products of wood and cork 0.214 0.052 0.016
Pulp, paper, paper products, printing, and publishing 0.292 0.031 0.063
Coke, refined petroleum products, and nuclear fuel 0.311 0.106 0.069
Chemicals excluding pharmaceuticals 0.386 0.157 0.263
Pharmaceuticals 0.444 0.112 0.384
Rubber & plastics products 0.241 0.07 0.121
Other non-metallic mineral products 0.207 0.028 0.068
Iron & steel 0.326 0.185 0.236
Non-ferrous metals 0.297 0.225 0.262
Fabricated metal products, except machinery & equipment 0.26 0.111 0.153
Machinery & equipment 0.311 0.225 0.242
Electrical machinery & apparatuses 0.316 0.272 0.287
Radio, television, & communication equipment 0.265 0.521 0.498
Medical, precision, & optical instruments 0.265 0.143 0.252
Motor vehicles, trailers, & semi-trailers 0.302 0.191 0.232
Building & repairing of ships & boats 0.225 0.038 0.053
Railroad equipment & transport equip 0.26 0.149 0.181
Manufacturing; recycling 0.197 0.078 0.047
Other 0.31 0.126 0.173

Table A5
Average Skilled Wages Share by Industry, Import Status, and Ownership Type.

Importer Non-Importer Foreign Domestic


Food products, beverages, and tobacco 0.308 0.223 0.366 0.226
Textiles, textile products, leather, and footwear 0.216 0.187 0.231 0.19
Wood and products of wood and cork 0.246 0.211 0.291 0.209
Pulp, paper, paper products, printing, and publishing 0.318 0.287 0.357 0.29
Coke, refined petroleum products, and nuclear fuel 0.495 0.279 0.447 0.286
Chemicals excluding pharmaceuticals 0.456 0.324 0.517 0.353
Pharmaceuticals 0.498 0.38 0.65 0.414
Rubber & plastic products 0.276 0.23 0.316 0.234
Other non-metallic mineral products 0.288 0.194 0.373 0.2
Iron & steel 0.347 0.301 0.342 0.321
Non-ferrous metals 0.322 0.276 0.331 0.283
Fabricated metal products, except machinery & equipment 0.338 0.231 0.372 0.243
Machinery & equipment 0.385 0.26 0.402 0.276
Electrical machinery & apparatuses 0.346 0.287 0.336 0.307
Radio, television, & communication equipment 0.281 0.222 0.261 0.27
Medical, precision, & optical instruments 0.263 0.268 0.292 0.261
Motor vehicles, trailers, & semi-trailers 0.365 0.264 0.39 0.272
Building & repairing of ships & boats 0.239 0.224 0.314 0.221
Railroad equipment & transport equip 0.307 0.237 0.354 0.236
Manufacturing; recycling 0.241 0.191 0.272 0.19
Other 0.393 0.267 0.402 0.289

Acemoglu, Daron (1999b). Changes in unemployment and wage inequality: An


Table A6
alternative theory and some evidence. American Economic Review, 89(5),
Multicollinearity Test: Variance Inflation Factors (VIF) and Tolerance. 1259–1278.
Acemoglu, D. (2002b). Technical change, inequality and the labor market. Journal of
Variables Variance Inflation 1/VIF
Economic Literature, XL, 7–72.
Factor (VIF)
Acemoglu, D. (2002a). Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies, 69(4),
Natural Log of Value Added 1.44 0.693 781–809.
Natural Log of Capital Stock/Value Added 1.27 0.787 Acemoglu, D. (2003). Patterns of skill premia. Review of Economic Studies, 70(2),
Share of Foreign Equity 1.24 0.808 199–230.
Share of Imported Intermediate Inputs 1.19 0.841 Acemoglu, D. (1999). Labor- and capital-augmenting technical change. NBER
Working Paper No. 7544.
Mean VIF 1.29 Amiti, M., & Cameron, L. (2012). Trade liberalization and the wage skill premium:
Evidence from Indonesia. Journal of International Economics, 87, 277–287.
Note: The ‘‘rule of thumb” in the literature is that a VIF > 10 or a Tolerance Amiti, M., & Konings, J. (2007). Trade liberalization, intermediate inputs, and
level < 0.1 is a sign of a serious multicollinearity problem. productivity: Evidence from Indonesia. American Economic Review, 97(5),
1611–1638.
Attanasio, O., Goldberg, P., & Pavcnik, N. (2004). Trade reforms and wage inequality
in Colombia. Journal of Development Economics, 74, 331–366.
Autor, D., Katz, L., & Kreuger, A. (1998). Computing inequality: Have computers
References changed the labor market. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 1169–1213.
Basant, R., & Fikkert, B. (1996). The effects of R&D, foreign technology purchase, and
Acemoglu, D. (1998). Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed domestic and international spillovers on productivity in Indian firms. Review of
technical change and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, Economics and Statistics., 78(2), 187–199.
1055–1089.
14 M. Yasar, R.M. Rejesus / World Development 128 (2020) 104847

Beaulieu, E., Benarroch, M., & Gaisford, J. (2004). Trade barriers and wage inequality Lee, J., & Wie, D. (2015). Technological change, skill demand, and wage inequality in
in a North-South model with technology-driven intra-industry trade. Journal of Indonesia. World Development, 67, 238–250.
Development Economics, 75(1), 113–136. Leiponen, A. (2005). Skills and innovation. International Journal of Industrial
Berman, E., Bound, J., & Griliches, Z. (1994). Changes in the demand for skilled Organization, 23, 303–323.
within U.S. manufacturing industries: Evidence from the annual survey of Lewbel, A. (2012). Using heteroscedasticity to identify and estimate mismeasured
manufacturing. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(2), 367–397. and endogenous regressor models. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 30
Betts, J. R. (1997). The skill bias of technological change in Canadian manufacturing (1), 67–80.
industries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(1), 146–150. Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development planning. Journal of
Blalock, G., & Gertler, P. J. (2004). Learning from exporting revisited in a less Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3–42.
developed setting. Journal of Development Economics, 75, 397–416. Machin, S., & Van Reenen, J. (1998). Technology and changes in skill structure:
Blalock, G., & Gertler, P. J. (2008). Welfare gains from foreign direct investment Evidence from seven OECD countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113,
through technology transfer to local suppliers. Journal of International 1215–1244.
Economics, 74, 402–421. Mazumdar, J., & Quispe-Agnoli, M. (2004). Can capital-skill complementarity
Bresnahan, T., Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. (2002). Information technology, workplace explain the rising skill premium in developing countries? Evidence from Peru.
organization, and the demand for skilled labor: Firm level evidence. Quarterly FRB of Atlanta Working Paper No. 2004-11.
Journal of Economics, 117(1), 339–376. Mazumdar, J., & Quispe-Agnoli, M. (2019). Can capital-skill complementarity
Breusch, T., & Pagan, A. (1979). A simple test for heteroscedasticity and random explain the rising skill premium in developing countries? Evidence from Peru
coefficient variation. Econometrica, 47, 1287–1294. in the 1990s. Economia, 42(83), 75–94.
Brown, R. S., & Christensen, L. R. (1981). Estimating elasticities of substitution in a Meschi, E., Taymaz, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2011). Trade, technology and skills: Evidence
model of partial static equilibrium: An application to U.S. agriculture, 1947 to from Turkish microdata. Labour Economics, 18, 60–70.
1974. In E. R. Berndt & B. C. Field (Eds.), Modeling and measuring natural resource Mundlak, Y. (1978). On the pooling of time series and cross section data.
substitution (pp. 209–229). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Econometric, 69–85.
Bustos, P. (2011). Trade liberalization, exports, and technology upgrading: Evidence Papke, L. E., & Wooldridge, J. M. (1996). Econometric methods for fractional
on the impact of MERCOSUR on Argentinean firms. American Economic Review, response variables with an application to 401(k) plan participation rates.
101(1), 304–340. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11(6), 619–632.
Canay, I. A. (2011). A simple approach to quantile regression for panel data. The Papke, L. E., & Wooldridge, J. M. (2008). Panel data methods for fractional response
Econometrics Journal, 14(3), 368–386. variables with an application to test pass rates. Journal of Econometrics, 145,
Carr, D. L., Markusen, J. R., & Maskus, K. E. (2001). Estimating the knowledge-capital 121–133.
model of the multinational enterprise. American Economic Review, 91(3), Paul, C. J. M., & Siegel, D. S. (2001). The impacts of technology, trade, and
693–708. outsourcing on employment and labor composition. Scandinavian Journal of
Christensen, L. R., & Greene, W. H. (1976). Economies of scale in U.S. electric power Economics, 103, 241–264.
generation. Journal of Political Economy, 84, 655–676. Pavcnik, N. (2003). What explains skill upgrading in less developed countries?
Christensen, L. R., Jorgenson, D. W., & Lau, L. J. (1973). Transcendental logarithmic Journal of Development Economics, 71(2), 311–328.
production frontiers. Review of Economics and Statistics, 55, 28–45. Pugel, T. (2007). International economics (13th ed.). New York: McGraw Hill.
Coe, D. T., & Helpman, E. (1995). International R&D spillovers. European Economic Ramalho, E. A., Ramalho, J. J. S., & Murteira, J. M. R. (2011). Alternative estimating
Review, 39, 859–887. and testing empirical strategies for fractional regression models. Journal of
Demir, F. (2010). Exchange rate volatility and employment growth in developing Economic Surveys, 25(1), 19–68.
countries: Evidence from Turkey. World Development, 38, 1127–1140. Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy,
Doms, M., Dunne, T., & Troske, K. R. (1997). Workers, wages and technology. 98, 71–102.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1), 253–290. Roy, J., & Yasßar, M. (2015). Energy efficiency and exporting: Evidence from firm-
Eaton, J., & Kortum, S. (1996). Trade in ideas: Patenting and productivity in the level data. Energy Economics, 52, 127–135.
OECD. Journal of International Economics, 40, 251–278. Sachs, J., & Shatz, H. J. (1998). International trade and wage inequality in the United
Eaton, J., & Kortum, S. (2001). Trade in capital goods. European Economic Review, 45 States: Some new results. In: Imports, exports, and the American worker, Susan
(7), 1195–1235. M. Collins (Ed.). Washington: D.C. Brookings Institution.
Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1997). Foreign direct investment and relative Saggi, K. (1999). Foreign direct investment, licensing, and incentives for innovation.
wages: Evidence from Mexico’s Maquiladoras. Journal of International Review of International Economics, 7, 699–714.
Economics., 42, 371–393. Shephard, R. W. (1953). Cost and production functions. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (2002). Global production sharing and rising University Press.
inequality: A survey of trade and wages. In K. Choi & J. Harrigan (Eds.), Shephard, R. W. (1970). Theory of cost and production functions. Princeton, N.J.:
Handbook of international trade. New York: Blackwell. Princeton University Press.
Fukase, E. (2013). Export liberalization, job creation, and the skill premium: Siegel, D. (1997). The impact of computers on manufacturing productivity growth:
Evidence from the US–Vietnam bilateral trade agreement. World Development, A multiple-indicators, multiple-causes approach. Review of Economics and
41(1), 317–337. Statistics, 79(1), 68–78.
Gindling, T. H., & Robbins, D. (2001). Patterns and sources of changing wage Takii, S. (2019). Imported intermediate inputs and plants’ export dynamics: Evidence
inequality in Chile and Costa Rica during adjustment. World Development, 29(4), from Indonesian plant-product-level data. Working Paper.
725–745. Thoenig, M., & Verdier, T. (2003). A theory of defensive skill-biased innovation and
Goldberg, P. K., & Pavcnik, N. (2007). Distributional effects of globalization in globalization. American Economic Review, 93(3), 709–728.
developing countries. Journal of Economic Literature, XLV, 39–82. Turco, L. A., & Maggioni, D. (2013). Does trade foster employment growth in
Griliches, Z. (1969). Capital-skill complementarity. Review of Economics and emerging markets? Evidence from Turkey. World Development, 52, 1–18.
Statistics, 51(4), 251–266. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.06.003.
Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1991). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Wooldridge, J. M. (2016). Correlated random effects models with unbalanced
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. panels. Journal of Econometrics, 211(1), 137–150.
Harrison, A., & Hanson, G. (1999). Who gains from trade reform? Some remaining Xu, B. (2003). Trade liberalization, wage inequality and endogenously determined
puzzles. Journal of Development Economics, 59, 125–154. nontraded goods. Journal of International Economics, 60(2), 417–431.
Haskel, J., & Heden, Y. (1999). Computers and the demand for skilled labour: Xu, B., & Wang, J. (1999). Capital goods trade and R&D spillovers in the OECD.
Industry and establishment-level panel evidence for the U.K. Economic Journal, Canadian Journal of Economics, 32, 1258–1274.
109, 68–79. Yasar, M. (2013). Imported capital input, absorptive capacity, and firm
Hershberg, E., Nabeshima, K., & Yusuf, S. (2007). Opening the ivory tower to performance: Evidence from firm-level data. Economic Inquiry, 51(1), 88–100.
business: University industry linkages and the development of knowledge- Yasar, M., & Morrison Paul, C. J. (2007). International linkages and productivity at
intensive clusters in Asian cities. World Development, 35(6), 931–940. the plant level: Foreign direct investment, exports, imports and licensing.
Holderness, C. G. (2016). Problems using aggregate data to infer individual Journal of International Economics, 72(1), 373–388.
behavior: Evidence from law, finance, and ownership concentration. Critical Yasar, M., & Morrison Paul, C. J. (2008). Capital-skill complementarity, productivity
Finance Review, 5, 1–40. and wages: Evidence from plant-level data for a developing country. Labour
Hollanders, H., & ter Weel, B. (2002). Technology, knowledge spillovers and changes Economics, 15(1), 1–17.
in employment structure: Evidence from six OECD countries. Labour Economics, Yasßar, M., & Morrison Paul, C. J. (2012). Firm performance and knowledge spillovers
9, 579–599. from academic, industrial and foreign linkages: The case of China”. Journal of
Kasahara, H., Liang, Y., & Rodrigue, J. (2016). Does importing intermediates increase Productivity Analysis, 38(3), 237–253.
the demand for skilled workers? Plant-level evidence from Indonesia. Journal of Zhu, S. C. (2004). Trade, product cycles and inequality within and between
International Economics, 102, 242–261. countries. Canadian Journal of Economics, 37(4), 1042–1060.
Keller, W. (2002a). Geographic localization of international technology diffusion. Zhu, S. C., & Trefler, D. (2005). Trade and inequality in developing countries: A
American Economic Review, 92, 120–142. general equilibrium analysis. Journal of International Economics, 65(1), 21–48.
Keller, W. (2002b). Knowledge spillovers at the World’s technology frontier Working
Paper. Austin: University of Texas.

You might also like