Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

PART 2

Market economics

37
CHAPTER 2.1

economics of the
Minerals industry
Phillip C.F. Crowson

Mining is like any other economic activity in that its contribu- degree of processing before it can be sold. In some instances
tion to the gross domestic product (GDP) is measured by its that may be no more than simple washing and sorting, but, at
value added—that is, its worth based on the sum of wages, sal- the other extreme, complex metallurgical or chemical process-
aries, rent, royalties, direct taxes, interest payments, and gross ing may be necessary. Mineral producers aim to maximize the
profits involved in producing its final products. However, its profitability of their operations and will balance the costs of
modest share of the global gross product greatly understates additional processing against any advantages gained from
its importance. Like other primary industries, it produces the selling higher-value products.
raw materials that form the essential basis of all other eco-
nomic activities. Mineral products perform the same function DeMAnD
for the global economy as the vitamins and trace elements in Few mineral products are demanded for their intrinsic worth
the human diet. Without their continuing supply, economic but instead for their various properties. Most are intermedi-
activity would gradually wither and die. ate goods used as raw materials or processing aids for more
finished products. The main exceptions are precious gems and
BounDARieS precious metals in some but not all of their uses. Whereas each
The minerals industry embraces a wide range of different mineral has a specific set of properties, whether physical or
products with differing methods and structures of production chemical, few of those properties are unique to any one min-
and with diverse markets. Its boundaries are conventionally eral product. End users of the finished product may be com-
defined to exclude petroleum, natural gas, and water, although pletely unaware of what minerals are used in its manufacture
hard-rock mineral fuels such as coal and uranium are included. and are merely interested in whether the product meets their
Distinctions are also drawn between mining and quarrying for needs satisfactorily. In short, demand for minerals is derived
sand, gravel, and construction materials, although those share from demand for finished products, and in many instances the
the characteristics of other mineral products. The downstream minerals used account for a relatively small proportion of the
boundaries of the industry are imprecise as it merges, in many product’s total cost.
instances, into processing and manufacturing industry. That is This derived nature of demand means that it is difficult
especially true of some industrial minerals, particularly those for producers of many mineral products to differentiate their
used in chemical manufacture, but it also applies to metallic material from that of other suppliers, except concerning its
minerals. inherent properties. While the properties of a specific min-
Where the division is made is largely one of convention. eral product may make it ideally suited for some end uses,
The production of pig iron and steel, for example, is regarded most uses will normally have substitutes of varying degrees of
as manufacturing, so the boundary with mining is the output effectiveness. The fertilizer minerals are a partial exception in
of iron ore. For copper the division is less clear-cut, with some that regard, because growing plants require potash, phosphate,
mines producing copper metal on-site and others selling ores and nitrogen in varying combinations, but even the consump-
and concentrates. Conventionally primary nonferrous met- tion of fertilizers is dictated by the demand for agricultural
als are grouped as mineral products, but their semifabricated products and by farmers’ cost structures. Demand for mineral
shapes and wrought products are grouped as manufactures. products is always at the mercy of fashion, of technological
That raises questions about a metal like aluminum, for which changes in end-use markets, of governmental regulations,
the major input is not the mineral raw material but energy. and, above all, of relative prices. These characteristics are not
Mines produce ores rather than finished salable products. unique to mineral products but set them apart from the general
With few exceptions, most run-of-mine output requires some run of manufactures.

Phillip C.F. Crowson, Hon. Prof. & Professorial Research Fellow, Centre for Energy, Petroleum & Mineral Law & Policy, University of Dundee, Scotland

39
40 SMe Mining engineering handbook

Substitution and Prices to be less materials intensive than those purchased at lower
That substitutes exist for most mineral products in many of levels of income. Consequently, the economy’s IU of min-
their uses circumscribes their producers’ market power. A eral product per unit of GDP will eventually peak and then
marked shift in a product’s relative price will impact the size fall back. Although its absolute demand for mineral products
of its market. Some substitution may be straightforward, as may continue growing with expanding per capita incomes, a
in the use of different minerals as fillers or extenders in the point may be reached where even that ceases to rise and even
plastics industry, or of different materials in the manufacture weakens.
of refractories. Sometimes the most effective substitutes are Smaller economies with limited populations and/or inher-
abstinence, as in a farmer’s decision not to apply phosphate to ent geographical disadvantages may never develop their own
his fields one year, or a change in processing technology, such materials-based manufacturing industries but continue to rely
as heat treatment to replace the addition of alloying elements. on imports. This means their IU of many mineral products will
It will often involve process adaptations or investment in new never rise substantially, regardless of the levels of their per
technology and equipment. In those cases substitution will be capita incomes. By contrast, some economies may develop
spread over a period, rather than instantaneously, but when it large export-oriented manufacturing capabilities so that their
has occurred, it is unlikely to be reversed quickly. Changes in apparent IU not only rises rapidly but also reaches atypi-
relative prices often drive irreversible technological change. cally high levels. Densely populated countries with limited
Often demand for a specific mineral product will be land area will have different consumption patterns than more
affected not by changes in its own relative price but by the sparsely populated bigger countries, even at similar levels of
prices of the products in which it is incorporated or used in per capita income. In short, each country’s IU of mineral prod-
processing. For example, the demand for fillers and coating ucts depends on far more than per capita incomes alone, but
clays is driven by changing demands for paper, and for zinc in those provide the main impetus for change.
galvanizing by markets for steel products. Changes in end uses The basic pattern of changing intensities over time as
and in consumers’ spending patterns, driven by demographic incomes rise can be traced in the historical experience of the
and technical change, and sometimes merely by fashion, can mature industrial economies and is still being written in the
open up new markets for individual minerals and wipe out newly industrializing and developing countries. Continuing
existing markets. technological change, both in products and production pro-
cesses, and shifts in relative prices, especially of energy, mean
Markets for Mineral Products that newly industrializing countries do not slavishly follow
Most types of economic activity, including trade and services, the path of their predecessors. Each country will naturally
depend on mineral products, but their use is biased toward the adopt the cheapest and most effective set of technological
goods-producing sectors. Demand for many mineral products, options available, which will probably, but not necessarily, be
and for metals in particular, is heavily reliant on construction, less materials intensive. Global demand reflects both the sum
capital goods industries, and the manufacture of vehicles and total of the component economies’ varying patterns of IU and
consumer durable goods. Because these markets are responsive their GDP rates of growth. To the extent that some of the final
to changes in expectations and to movements in interest rates, output of the rapidly growing economies, such as China and
they are typically the most volatile segments of overall expen- India, is based on exports to the mature economies, their ris-
diture. Even where mineral products are used for processing or ing demands for materials will be partly at the expense of the
in goods for immediate consumption, their demand can fluctu- mature economies rather than merely additional to them.
ate by far more than overall economic activity and is at the
mercy of variations in work in progress and in the holding of Demand, Supply, and Prices
inventories of all types throughout the production chain—from Since production is relatively slow to react to swings in
mine to final consumer. In general, therefore, demand for min- demand and tends to be more stable in the short run, supply
eral products is more volatile than economic activity, as mea- and demand are seldom in precise balance. There is normally
sured by changes in industrial production or GDP. a dynamic equilibrium over time, with capacity moving in
step with demand, but market balances can quickly veer from
Demand, incomes, and intensity of use shortage to excess with little warning. The consequence is
Typically an economy’s demand for goods rises with per cap- volatile prices for most mineral products. In some instances,
ita incomes. When these are near subsistence levels, and only a buildup or reduction of inventories can cushion the immedi-
the most basic needs can be satisfied, the usage of minerals ate impact, but many products are not amenable to large-scale
per unit of output tends to be low. Initially, many of the needs stockpiling. Producers are therefore forced to reduce their
for mineral products will be met by imports of finished goods output when demand falls, but they can seldom react quickly
rather than by domestic manufacture. As per capita incomes enough when demand surges. Even the mere existence of
rise, the demand for more sophisticated products will also accumulated inventories can adversely affect expectations and
expand, thereby raising the economy’s intensity of mineral depress prices.
use per unit of output. Rapidly growing demands for invest-
ment in modern infrastructure of all types will further boost Demand and Recycling
the intensity of use (IU). The demand for mineral products, Quite apart from changes in inventories, supplies of many
and especially for the building blocks of steel, cement, and mineral products are not met by newly mined material. Even
construction materials, will tend to increase far more rapidly some of the minerals used as processing aids may be recycla-
than the GDP. Eventually, the nation’s basic infrastructure will ble, although most are dissipated in use. Where mineral prod-
be developed and individuals will devote an ever increasing ucts are processed into capital goods and consumer durables
proportion of their growing incomes to services of all types they become part of the global capital stock and potentially
rather than to products. The goods that are purchased will tend available for recycling when the goods are scrapped. Products
economics of the Minerals industry 41

used in packaging can also be recycled. The extent to which ore and Waste
recycling supplements primary production depends on the The product of all mines is ore. Even where it is mined under-
nature of the original end uses, the lives of the finished goods, ground from rich veins or seams, its extraction will neces-
the available technology, and governmental regulation. It is sarily require the removal of waste rock. Historically, miners
also governed by the rate of demand growth. Even in mature followed the often narrow veins using muscle power to extract
markets, recycling alone cannot meet new demand, but its the ore with pick and shovel, and the amount of waste was
ability to satisfy part of that demand does constrain the com- kept to an absolute minimum. With the introduction of ever
mercial freedom of the mining industry. Much recycled mate- more complex machinery and equipment, mines produce a
rial will be supplied for environmental reasons as a result of greater proportion of waste. The underground workings now
governmental regulation or fiscal incentives. Its supply is thus have to be large enough to provide access for and to accom-
fairly insensitive to price, a contrast to the supply of newly modate modern equipment. Open-pit mines have to remove
mined material. any overburden and sufficient surrounding rock to ensure the
stability of the pit walls. The deeper the mine, the greater the
SuPPly volume of waste removed.
Attention is normally focused on minerals supply, and in par- In most instances, the run-of-mine product requires treat-
ticular on its nonrenewable nature and site specificity. These ment and upgrading before it can be profitably sold. Even coal
are extremely important but over a rather longer time span may require washing. Most industrial minerals are subjected
than the immediate characteristics of supply and demand. to a variety of physical or chemical processes in order to maxi-
It is often overlooked that the mining industry exists solely mize their market value. Metallic ores usually contain only
because there is a demand for its products rather than because modest proportions of commercially valuable products whose
ore deposits exist. Unless there are potential end uses for the extraction generates large amounts of tailings. Today a typical
products of their exploitation, ore deposits would be not much mine covers a much larger land area than it did in the 19th
more than interesting geological phenomena. or early 20th century, and it alters the landscape irreversibly.
That makes the mine a much less desirable neighbor than in
geographical location earlier times, to the extent that local communities are often
It is a truism that viable deposits of most minerals are not unwilling to trade the environmental and social costs for the
scattered evenly across the globe but that their geographical benefits. Even so, mining of all forms accounts for a modest
distribution is uneven. The lower a mineral element’s crustal proportion of the earth’s surface.
abundance, and the higher the concentration factor required
for economic mining, the scarcer and less evenly spread geo- Depletion and Transport
graphically it becomes. In sharp contrast to manufacturing The mining industry’s substantial need for supplies of energy,
and to mineral processing, the location of mines is dictated power, and water—both in the extraction of raw ore and in
by a combination of geology and geography. Yet the contrast its subsequent processing—partly governs its location. These
can be overstated because the existence of known ore deposits requirements certainly help dictate the form in which mineral
does not necessarily guarantee that they will be mined. That products are transported and the nature and extent of upgrad-
will depend on a wide range of technical, economic, social, ing on the mine site. So too, crucially, does the availability of
environmental, and political factors. transport. Indeed, there has been an almost symbiotic relation-
Mining is not the only type of economic activity whose ship between the development of transport systems and the
location is geographically predetermined. Others include, for mining industry.
example, certain forms of agriculture, the generation of hydro- That relationship has been fostered by the main charac-
electric power, and even tourism. It is, however, unquestion- teristic of the mining industry: its dependence on the extrac-
able that mining can only occur where mineral deposits exist, tion of nonrenewable resources. Individual ore deposits are
often in places that are remote and inhospitable. Historically, strictly finite, either because they are physically bounded or
mining was regarded in nearly all locations as having a prior because the costs of extracting the remaining ore become
claim on land use and taking precedence over alternative uses, prohibitive. Naturally, any society will first exploit the most
almost regardless of where the mineral deposits were located. accessible and easily worked ore deposits. As these become
That is increasingly less likely today, with mining having to worked out, it will develop technologies to extract more ore
compete with other potential uses. This applies not just near from the existing workings, whether by going deeper or by
urban centers in densely populated countries but also in popu- process innovations. These productivity improvements will
lated regions where the preservation of the natural landscape be accompanied by a search for new ore deposits, which will
may take precedence over any form of development. probably be increasingly distant from population centers and
All forms of mining involve some, often irreversible, dis- their markets. Hence, the imperative is to improve transport
turbance to the physical landscape. When today’s advanced links and reduce transport costs in order to enable the develop-
economy countries were industrializing and needed minerals ment of more distant mines at acceptable costs.
both as raw materials for industry and to create infrastructure, Mineral deposits will only be exploited if the mines based
such disturbance was accepted as an unavoidable consequence on them can profitably ship their products to the marketplace.
of accessing mineral wealth. Moreover, mines tended to be rel- With relatively few exceptions, mines are primarily developed
atively small and not too obtrusive on the landscape. Metallic with the expectation of earning profits, over and above their
minerals were largely extracted from underground workings, operators’ capital costs. If they are persistently unprofitable,
which produced limited amounts of waste. By contrast, much they will close down, even if the underlying mineral deposits
modern mining is carried out on a large scale, often through are not depleted. The emphasis is on persistently, as explained
open-pit workings that both scar the landscape and create sub- later. The cost of transport relative to the price of the final
stantial volumes of waste rock. product dictates the geographical reach of each mine’s market
42 SMe Mining engineering handbook

and strongly influences the nature and degree of processing by-products, their production decisions can become complex,
at the mine site. Those products with high value-to-volume especially where, as is usually the case, the grades of the con-
ratios, such as gemstones and precious metals, can be trans- stituent elements vary throughout the ore body. Sometimes
ported long distances easily and will have global markets. At those decisions may appear perverse, as when maximizing
the other extreme, products with high volume-to-value ratios, profitability may involve concentrating on by-product recov-
such as sand and gravel and construction materials, will secure ery at the expense of the main product’s output, irrespective
only local markets. Marked reductions in the costs of deep-sea of shifts in its demand and prices. This merely emphasizes
shipping since World War II have widened the geographical that the underlying objective of mine managements is usually
markets for bulk products, such as iron ore and coal, from the creating value for shareholders rather than ensuring supplies
national to the regional and even to the global. of raw materials.
Where mineral deposits are located deeply inland, remote
from major markets for their products, they can only compete ore grades and exploration
if their products are upgraded locally in order to minimize The relative grades of ore of different deposits, even allowing
transport costs. Such upgrading will, in turn, rely on the prox- for the contributions of all the salable products, are not nec-
imity of sufficient competitive sources of energy. Whereas essarily reflected in the relative costs per unit of product. The
Chile’s copper mines are fortunate in being close to the sea, higher the grade, the more a deposit is able to support deep
which can be used to profitably ship concentrates, those of underground mining, which usually costs far more per ton of
central Africa depend on local smelting and refining to mini- ore than open-pit mining. Also higher grades may be able to
mize the volumes being transported to ports. offset the additional costs of complex treatment and processing.
In theory, the higher-grade, more easily processed, and
Competitive influences more accessible deposits are mined first. Certainly, the aver-
A mine’s ability to compete mainly depends not on relative age grades mined of some metallic ores such as copper have
transport costs, important though those are, but on the char- tended to decline over time, being substantially lower today
acteristics of its mineral deposit, on the mining method used, than in the 19th century. The tendency toward declining
and on the nature of its processing plant. These inherent influ- grades has in many cases been countered by falling transport
ences will inevitably be modified by the political, social, and costs and by improvements in the technology both of extrac-
economic conditions of the host countries, including such tion and processing and of exploration. The average iron con-
factors as wage inflation, energy costs, and exchange rates, tent of ores mined in Western Australia and Brazil today is
which are outside the mining company’s control. Such factors much higher than the typical grades of iron minerals earlier
tend to be relatively more important for manufacturing indus- processed in most of Western Europe. The uranium deposits of
tries, including mineral processing plants such as smelters and Ontario exploited in the 1950s had much lower average grades
refineries, than for mines. than the latest generation of Canadian mines.
The nature of each ore deposit normally dominates the
inherent influences on relative costs. Since few mineral depos- ore Depletion and Technological Change
its are identical in all respects, their costs, and hence their In essence, each generation will tend to exploit the best depos-
profitability, will tend to vary. Some will be close to ample its of which they are aware with the technologies at their
supplies of water and energy, and easily accessible, while oth- disposal. As geological knowledge increases, both through
ers will be more remote. Some may outcrop at or near the a better understanding of the nature and genesis of mineral
surface and be amenable to surface mining through open-cast deposits and through continued exploration with ever more
methods, whereas others may be so deep as to require extrac- sophisticated techniques, the number of known mineral
tion through shafts or adits. The nature of the host rocks and deposits also rises. Some may have higher ore grades than the
of the minerals themselves will vary from the easily worked deposits already being worked but in many cases will suffer
to the physically demanding. In some instances, the commer- from offsetting disadvantages, such as remoteness from mar-
cially valuable components may be easily liberated, whereas kets or poor accessibility. Simultaneously, the technology of
in others, complex physical and chemical processing may be ore extraction and processing is continuously changing and
needed. Perhaps the major factor is the grade of a deposit— enabling the economic development of previously sterile min-
the proportion of salable materials it contains. Other things eral deposits. Such technological changes can be driven both
being equal, which they seldom are, the higher the grade of a by end-use requirements and by a need to remove existing
mineral deposit, the lower its relative costs compared with a constraints and bottlenecks in supply.
similar but lower-grade deposit. Over time, changes in the costs of producing mineral
For many raw minerals, the average grade is less impor- products result from a continuing tug of war between the cost-
tant than the extent to which a mine can maximize its output of raising effects of ore depletion and the cost-reducing impact
the higher-priced types of the basic product without expensive of technological change and rising productivity. That leaves
processing. Typically the higher-value uses offer sizable pre- aside such general economic influences as movements in
miums over the more common uses. Metallic ores are seldom general price levels, wage rates, energy costs, and exchange
pure, but they contain a variety of different elements and com- rates. The result is never a foregone conclusion. There have
pounds. Obviously, the higher the content of the main metal, been periods where the forces of depletion have prevailed and
the more attractive the deposit, but the nature and importance inflation-adjusted costs of production have tended to rise, as
of co- and by-products are also relevant. Some are highly in the 1950s and 1960s. There have also been lengthy peri-
desirable and raise the potential value of the ore, whereas oth- ods, as in the 1980s and 1990s, where those forces have been
ers are toxic and reduce the marketability of the mine’s prod- outweighed by productivity improvements and real costs have
ucts. Sometimes the costs of their removal and safe storage tended to fall. That the real prices of most mineral products
outweigh any mining benefits. Where mines yield a range of have not shown any marked trends over long periods suggests
economics of the Minerals industry 43

that the opposing forces have been fairly evenly balanced. In their initial capital expenditure. As mining progresses and the
that regard, however, the past is not necessarily a good guide operators obtain a better understanding of their ore deposits’
to the future, if only because there have been wide and pro- characteristics, they will often delineate additional material
longed fluctuations around the long-term averages. While all that can justify mine expansion. The expansion of existing
mineral products are subject to some common influences, the mines on known ore deposits usually accounts for a substan-
historical behavior of their prices has differed widely, reflect- tial share of annual changes in net capacity. At one extreme,
ing both their different end uses and the varying influences on such expansions may involve no new capital spending, per-
the nature and locations of their production. haps by the use of different explosives in the mine or a new
reagent in the processing plant, while, at the other extreme,
Capital expenditure Requirements substantial capital expenditure is needed to deepen or extend
The industry’s requirements for capital spending vary with the mine. A common feature is the introduction of the latest
the location and nature of each mineral deposit. In addition to available technology, allowing improved productivity and off-
construction of the mine itself and of the associated process- setting underlying cost increases.
ing plant necessary to produce a marketable product, usually
an associated infrastructure is needed. This will naturally be economies of Scale
less when the mine is situated near an established town or an As mines expand and become larger, they can exploit econo-
existing mining district, with existing supplies of water and mies of scale. The larger the mine, the more it can reduce its
power and established transport links, than when located in fixed costs per unit by spreading them over an increased out-
virgin territory. Even in the former instance, existing facilities put. It can justify investment in larger items of equipment,
will probably need supplementing and upgrading. Although such as shovels and trucks, or in more capital-intensive min-
mining may not be the most capital intensive of industries, it ing methods than smaller mines. It can also support the mining
is one of the leaders. of much-lower-grade ores than smaller operations. Indeed, it
The lead times before a mine produces any income can is only by operating on an ever-increasing scale that the min-
be considerable, especially if full account is taken of the ing industry has been able to offset the costs of extracting and
period from initial exploration to commercial production. processing leaner ores in more remote locations. From time
Even the lead time from first discovery to a decision to invest immemorial there has been an inexorable trend toward more
will normally exceed a decade for a large mineral deposit. capital-intensive and larger-scale mining methods. This trend
The expenses of prefeasibility and feasibility studies in fully accelerated across the board from the late 1980s, resulting
delineating the deposit, developing a viable extraction and in reductions in the number of mines for each product and
treatment process, and carrying out the requisite environmen- a strong rise in their average size. Open-pit mines tend to
tal assessments will normally be capitalized. Construction operate on a much larger scale than underground mines, and
itself is likely to be spread over several years, and it normally their relative expansion was favored for many years because
takes about 2 years from start-up for a large mine to reach and of their ability to exploit technical economies of scale to the
sustain its design capacity. There has, however, been a near- utmost.
universal tendency for the scale of mines to increase over time. That ability was enhanced by the growth of debt-based
Unlike many productive enterprises, the mining indus- project finance in the post-war decades. Historically, the risks
try not only has a heavy burden of capital expenditure before involved in mining inhibited companies from relying unduly
starting production but also large continuing needs over the on debt finance. That necessarily meant a dependence on
life of its mines. This is an inevitable feature of the deplet- equity markets and internally generated funds that tended to
ing nature of mineral deposits. In addition to normal capital constrain companies’ abilities to optimize the scale of their
spending on replacement equipment and maintenance, the mines. The scope of the local market was often a further limi-
industry has to meet the capital costs involved in extracting tation when transport costs acted as a constraint. Thus mines
ore from increasing depths and more remote sections of the tended to start off relatively small and expand when market
deposit, and in maintaining production in the face of declining conditions and finances permitted. In the past two decades,
ore grades. Without such continuing capital expenditure, an however, the availability of project finance on a large scale
individual mine’s output would soon tail off and decline. and the existence of a global market enabled companies to
So, too, replacement investment is needed in each develop at a technically optimum scale from the outset.
mineral-producing sector. Although mine closures are likely to Increasing scale is a mixed blessing. The larger the mine,
be bunched in periods of weak market conditions, some take especially if open pit, the greater its environmental and social
place even when markets are buoyant. When total demand is impact on the surrounding neighborhood. Moreover, the larger
static or even falling, new capacity is needed to offset losses mines’ needs to minimize their fixed costs per unit of output
from mine closures and from reductions in the output of some reduce their flexibility to respond to changing market condi-
continuing operations. As the overall demand for most min- tions. That can potentially lead to a greater volatility of prices
eral products rises over time, the gross annual additions to than in markets with a larger number of smaller operations.
capacity normally need to exceed the net additions—and in In practice, most mines tend to maximize their through-
many instances by a substantial margin. The balance depends put during periods of low prices, often by raising the average
on the typical life and size of mines, which are a function grade of ore mined. If mining companies aim to maximize the
of the nature of the underlying deposits, and on the rate of net present value (NPV) of their ore deposits, they might logi-
demand growth. cally reduce their cutoff grades when prices weaken, but their
Additional capacity can come from expansions of exist- objectives are more complex. They also need to watch the prof-
ing facilities on known mineral deposits or their extensions, itability of their capital investment, which is different from the
or from the exploitation of previously undeveloped deposits. implied value of the mineral deposit. Corporate survival will
Usually mining companies only prove sufficient ore to justify tend to take precedence over theoretical maximization of NPV.
44 SMe Mining engineering handbook

Closures and Cutbacks deposits are known to exist, they may not be commercially
Mines tend to remain in production as long as possible, even viable with the existing technology. In some instances, the
when prices fail to cover their costs. Experience shows that possession of proprietary technology by the existing pro-
downturns do not last indefinitely, and companies hang on in ducers sets a high hurdle for new entrants. Elsewhere the
the hope of improved conditions, as long as variable costs are limited size of the total market and its concentration may
covered and some contribution is made to fixed costs. Banks restrict the scope for new suppliers to secure sufficient sales
may support a loss-making mine’s continued operation to to justify investment.
ensure the eventual repayment of their loans. In many cases, Most of the barriers except geological shortage can
the costs of closure may exceed the costs of continued produc- eventually be surmounted or circumvented. Even that
tion because of the need for rehabilitating the site. The con- encourages exploration, which may result in the discovery
tinuing expenses of care and maintenance need to be taken of new deposits that, in some instances, may be superior in
into account. If mines are crucial contributors to the local many respects to the deposits already being mined. The exis-
economy, governments may be prepared to underwrite their tence of processing constraints fosters technical research and
losses to maintain a district’s economic and social stability. development that often results in less expensive or more effi-
In some cases, the mine’s product may be essential for down- cient processes, thereby enabling the new entrant to leapfrog
stream operations, and the need for a continued supply of raw over the constraint. Even the small size of an existing market
materials counterbalances any cash losses. is not an absolute barrier for innovative new entrants that
The rigidity of production in the face of falling prices search out and develop new uses. In order to keep prices in
is greatest in terminal markets of last resort or where the check, most purchasers will be keen to encourage additional
costs of stock building are low relative to the value of out- suppliers. Users naturally favor a degree of excess capacity
put. By-products have to be stored in one form or another among their suppliers. Over time the role of falling transport
when their market conditions weaken differentially to those costs in lowering the locational barriers to entry and expand-
of the main product. Thus the sour gas producers of Canada ing the geographical reach of markets has greatly reduced
have periodically vatted large quantities of by-product sul- the abilities of local and regional suppliers to control their
fur, whose removal is essential for the sale of gas. The costs prices and market conditions.
of mining and stockpiling most industrial and bulk minerals Frequently, artificial impediments to new entrants can
are prohibitive, and their mines will normally have to reduce be as effective as technical limitations. For national markets
their output when demand falls and prices weaken. By con- these include subsidies and trade barriers of all types. Shielded
trast, producers of products with terminal markets, namely the from the full ravages of foreign competition, local suppliers
major nonferrous and precious metals, can always sell their can wield considerable control over their local markets. Most
entire output as long as they are prepared to accept the going tariffs and similar obstacles to trade in mineral products have
prices. Even when users are unable or unwilling to purchase, been eliminated or greatly reduced over the years in succes-
they can place their product in warehouses. sive rounds of international tariff negotiations. Nevertheless,
some tariff barriers still remain, mainly affecting countries
Pricing and Barriers to entry that want to do more than simply extract and export their
The ease or difficulty of building up inventories is only one minerals without further processing. Imports of basic mineral
of the factors explaining the pricing of mineral products. The products may be duty free, but there may be seemingly modest
most important are the responsiveness of supply to chang- tariffs on downstream products, including semimanufactures.
ing demand and prices, and the level and nature of barriers to In such instances, there may be fairly heavy effective protec-
entry. These factors are closely intertwined. Where the barri- tion on the value added in the downstream products.
ers are high, the existing producers will enjoy some monopoly
power and will be able to influence prices. In the short term, PoliTiCAl fACToRS
that power will be circumscribed only by the availability and Trade barriers aside, most administrative and political fetters
effectiveness of substitutes, including recycled materials; by on supply are in mineral-rich rather than importing countries.
any countervailing power of purchasers; and by the extent Even where many known mineral deposits are awaiting devel-
to which the existing producers share similar objectives and opment, and seemingly able to produce profitably with exist-
philosophies. In the longer term, the existence of apparently ing technology, their exploitation depends on a benign, or at
attractive profits will attract new entrants, whose successful least neutral, social, political, and economic environment. In
penetration of the market will depend on the causes of high many mineral-rich countries, the environment is anything but
barriers to entry. Where the barriers to the entry of new sup- benign. As noted earlier, mineral enterprises commit consid-
pliers are low and easily surmountable, markets will tend to be erable resources to developing mines over many years before
competitive, with prices more closely reflecting the interplay commercial production starts. The prospective lives of their
of supply and demand. investments stretch many more years from start-up. At each
Easily the most important constraint on new produc- stage, the technical and economic risks are high, with an
tion is the availability of untapped mineral deposits. That ever-present possibility that the investment will fail. After the
is not just a function of a mineral’s crustal abundance, vital investor has committed resources to developing a deposit, it
though that is, but also depends on the number and nature is a captive hostage to fortune. The company’s capital is well
of the potentially mineable deposits. The crustal abundance and truly sunk, and it is impossible to transfer the investment
of platinum is slightly higher than that of gold, but the com- to a more accommodating environment. Thus a mining com-
mercial deposits are few and geographically concentrated, pany’s bargaining power with the host country weakens con-
whereas deposits of gold are much more widely dispersed. siderably after its capital is invested.
Therefore, platinum’s barriers to entry are considerably This change in relative bargaining strength is not nec-
higher than those of gold. Even where unexploited mineral essarily reflected in any change in the terms under which a
economics of the Minerals industry 45

mine is developed. It does, however, focus exploration and inherent nature with prevailing technologies and geological
mine development on countries with relatively stable political, knowledge.
social, legal, and economic frameworks. Where these essen- Resource rents are only mobilized when a mineral deposit
tial preconditions are not met, many companies will tend to is mined. They require the application of the other production
shun investment, no matter how geologically prospective the factors, notably labor and capital, before they are valorized.
country. Investors in riskier countries will seek commensu- When undeveloped mineral deposits are sold or auctioned,
rately high returns and will tend to concentrate on developing those involved are making implicit assumptions about the
mines with limited needs for expensive infrastructure and with NPV of the future rents that their exploitation will yield.
rapid payback periods. Those assumptions may prove wide of the mark, whether
By no means are all the administrative and political bar- unduly optimistic or far too cautious.
riers to entry confined to developing countries. For example, The concept of mineral rents may be straightforward, but
Australia restricted the development of new uranium mines their estimation is complex. Even where prices and demand
for several decades because of opposition to nuclear power. are stable, costs and incomes will vary from one year to the
Concern over potential environmental damage from mineral next. Heavy capital expenditure is incurred before commercial
development has also led to specific prohibitions on mining in, production and at periodic intervals during subsequent years,
or near to, national parks and areas of natural beauty in North and capital costs are also associated with final closure. Given
America, Australia, and Western Europe. the costs involved in the discovery and proving of ore, the life
Such environmental concerns are but a part of the strong of the mine is unlikely to be known with certainty. Typically,
atavistic feelings aroused by mining throughout the world. No companies only prove sufficient mineral content to justify
matter that mineral deposits have little or no value until their their initial investment, no matter how large the underlying
contents are extracted by mining, there are widespread and deposit. As mines near the end of their productive lives, their
deeply held beliefs that its rewards should accrue not to the operating costs tend to rise as their grades decline and they go
investor but primarily to the state as the custodian of the pub- deeper. In practice, demand and the prices of inputs and prod-
lic interest. With but a few exceptions, most mineral rights ucts can fluctuate considerably, even where their underlying
throughout the world are vested in the state. Where undevel- trend is stable. All too often it is not. For these varying rea-
oped mineral deposits are sold or auctioned, their prices reflect sons, the amount of rent will vary from one year to the next.
a mixture of the capital already expended in their exploration That means that all incomes and expenditures should be con-
and discovery, and the expected rent accruing from their future verted to NPVs in order to ascertain a mineral deposit’s rents.
development and exploitation. This raises further complications. Should future values
be discounted at the investor’s opportunity cost of capital or
Mineral exploration at some other rate? In any case, what is the opportunity cost
Like any other form of investment, mineral exploration is of capital? It is likely to vary among different categories of
made in the expectation of yielding a return over and above the potential investor and among different countries. The mini-
capital invested. Although the risks of failure are high, com- mum required rate of return will be lower for a short-lived
panies do not explore in the pursuit of average rates of return, operation requiring minimal facilities in a developed country
but in the hope that they will, so to speak, hit the jackpot with than for a long-lived large-scale mine needing massive infra-
a highly attractive discovery. Their return may come either structure in an unstable developing country. A large diversified
from their own development of mines to exploit any discover- mining company may be able to raise funds far more cheaply
ies or from selling the discovered deposits to other companies. than a much smaller company without an established track
Thus, guaranteed property rights that can be legally enforced record, but the cost of finance to governmental agencies may
are as essential for exploration as for mine development. The well be lower still. Since mineral rents ultimately arise from
exploring company needs an assurance that it can profit from the nature of the underlying resource, these opportunity costs
any discovery it makes. are in any case less relevant for discounting future values than
the national social discount rates of the host countries. These
Mineral Rents are also likely to differ, probably being much lower in a rich
The mining industry’s economic contribution is measured advanced economy than in a poor developing country.
by its value added: the sum of the rewards paid to the pri-
mary factors of production, namely land, labor, and capital. Rent and Depletion
For all but the marginal producer, a proportion of the value No matter how future values are discounted to present val-
added reflects rents accruing to the resource. In that regard, ues, part of the rent more properly represents the cost of the
mining is like other primary industries such as agriculture depletion of the resource rather than a genuine surplus. As
and forestry where part of the annual income springs from such, this user cost element of the rent should naturally go
the characteristics of the natural resources used. Rent is the to the owner of the resource, usually the state, as recompense
difference between the value of the product and the sum of for its exhaustion. This user cost is specific to nonrenewable
the opportunity costs of all the resources involved in making resources, as the productivity of most agricultural land can
the product, including the minimum rate of return to capital be maintained or restored by appropriate husbandry. The pre-
required to make an investor commit funds in the first place. cise magnitude of user costs varies from mineral to mineral
In the short run, it can accrue to any of the factors involved, and over time. Theoretically, its annual incidence should in
including labor and management, but such quasi-rents are some manner reflect the rate of net depletion of each deposit.
normally competed away in the longer term, unless there As already noted, however, the ultimate size of most mineral
are artificially high barriers to competition for these fac- deposits and the lives of the mines they support can normally
tors. By contrast, the rent accruing to the resource reflects its be assessed only retrospectively rather than in advance.
46 SMe Mining engineering handbook

Rent and Taxation countries were compounded when mineral prices appeared to
There is no theoretical basis for sharing among the various be on a long-term declining trend in real terms. They were
stakeholders any remaining rents beyond user costs. In prac- then faced with falling terms of trade so that it became pro-
tice, the owners of the mineral deposits, usually the state, gressively harder to earn sufficient foreign exchange to finance
make strong claims for retaining the lion’s share through taxa- imports. Although the mid-2000s’ boom apparently disrupted
tion. That presupposes that the potential rents of each deposit previous trends, it might be premature to announce their death.
are not captured by purchasers of mineral products through For many economies, the start-up of new mining projects
prices that fail to cover full costs or are prematurely wiped out can cause sudden spurts in incomes, employment, and foreign
by new entrants or technological developments. Changes in exchange earnings. This lumpiness accentuates the problems
geological knowledge, in mining and processing technology, caused by the underlying volatility of most sectors of the min-
and in end uses can affect the inherent profitability of operat- erals industry. Unless it is appropriately managed, a surge in
ing mines and even lead to their early closure before they have activity arising from new mine development can unbalance the
extracted the full potential of their mineral deposits. In such host economy. The effects tend to be much more pronounced
instances, some of the potential rent will remain sterilized. in the oil and gas sector than in nonfuel minerals, but they
That mineral rents are both unpredictable and unstable and are nonetheless observable. A strong rise in exports affects the
can only properly be assessed retrospectively make them an balance of payments and tends to cause the currency to appre-
unsatisfactory basis for taxation. Governments want and need ciate. At the time, resources, especially labor, are attracted
some degree of certainty in their fiscal receipts. Typically, roy- away from their existing uses into the newly expanded min-
alties that are linked in some manner to output provide such ing sector, and costs are bid up. The competitiveness of the
certainty and are relatively easy to compute. That is a further existing sectors declines, leading to reduced sales and rising
advantage for many host nations that have limited administra- unemployment, so that booming mineral exports are accompa-
tive capacity and shortages of skilled labor. Companies are nied by a shrinking economic base in the rest of the economy.
liable to pay such royalties as long as they produce, even when These are the symptoms of Dutch disease, named after the
they make no profits, so that governments are guaranteed an experiences of the Netherlands following large natural gas
income. Ad valorem percentage royalties based on turnover discoveries in the 1960s. It is not an inevitable accompani-
are more flexible than fixed royalties based solely on volumes ment of mineral development and can be countered by the host
of production. The great disadvantage of any output-related government taking timely and appropriate budgetary and fis-
royalty, no matter how it is calculated, is that it is a fixed cost cal action.
and consequently raises the economic cutoff grade for mining,
potentially sterilizing marginal parts of a mineral deposit that institutional Capacity and Mining
might be extracted and processed in its absence. Nonetheless, Unfortunately, some host countries lack the necessary insti-
governments regard that as a price worth paying for royal- tutional capacity and administrative competence to adopt and
ties that typically average in the 1%–3% range. Higher royalty pursue appropriate fiscal policies. Nor are they always capable
rates are often applied to precious metals and gemstones. In all of installing and operating systems for offsetting volatile tax
cases they are seen as payments to the owners of the resource receipts. Such systems include stabilization funds that receive
and may be conceptually regarded as covering user costs. all mineral tax revenues as they are earned but only release
Most governments also levy income taxes of varying them for government spending over a period based on an
coverage and complexity. Attitudes to appropriate rates and estimate of likely average earnings over the business cycle.
allowances change over the course of the economic cycle with Effective stabilization funds can insulate governmental spend-
shifts in product prices and profitability. During the 1980s ing from extreme fluctuations in tax receipts, but they are
and 1990s, there was a tendency for the overall tax burden not a universal panacea. Aside from the inherent difficulties
on mining projects to fall. Competition between putative host involved in assessing future trend prices and revenues are the
countries to attract new investment led to a narrow range of problems of ensuring the independence of a fund’s manage-
tax incidence. Those countries with tax burdens significantly ment and operations from political and bureaucratic interfer-
above the prevailing norm were considered unlikely to cap- ence. Those are issues for mature democracies, let alone for
ture foreign investors. In reality, tax is only one factor among most developing countries.
many in influencing investment decisions and is by no means Geology knows few (if any) political or social boundar-
the most important. The boom of the mid-2000s caused host ies, and mineral deposits are often located in unstable coun-
nations to reassess their tax regimes and to seek additional tries riven by tribal and social tensions. That their exploitation
revenues. Some countries raised or imposed royalties and oth- might finance civil wars, exacerbate preexisting tensions, or
ers reexamined their income/profits taxes in order to capture involve corruption is not the fault of mining in and of itself.
greater shares of increased profits. The sharp drop in the prices With proper management, mineral wealth can be used to
of many minerals in the second half of 2008 demonstrated the ensure economic and social development and eliminate such
volatility of the industry’s profits and that host countries were tensions. All too often, however, powerful interest groups
chasing an elusive moving target. seek to capture the potential benefits of mineral development
for their own ends rather than for the national good. At the
Mining and economic Management extreme, such rent-seeking behavior might become kleptoc-
Volatile and unpredictable earnings because of fluctuating racy by the ruling elite.
demand and prices can be readily absorbed by a broad-based When the obvious environmental impacts of mineral
and widely diversified economy, even if the local impact development, no matter how well and sensitively those are
may be great. They are much less manageable for developing managed, are added to its potential adverse economic and
countries with few or no alternative sources of income and social consequences in poorly managed countries, it is under-
employment. The problems of economic management for such standable that the mining industry’s critics talk in terms of an
economics of the Minerals industry 47

inevitable resource curse. In many instances, however, host their direct employment and purchases, mining developments
countries have few, if any, alternative sources of potential can create indirect demands from their workers and suppliers.
wealth creation. They lack the luxury of choosing between The size of such multiplier effects depends on the location and
mining and other economic activities. Furthermore, weak nature of the initial projects, and on the extent to which those
institutions and poor governance are the major causes of most of the mine itself or all the facilities associated with the proj-
of the ills that have been ascribed to dependence on mineral ect are taken into account. Often the main, indirect benefits
development. The appropriate response is to tackle those may be realized far from the mine itself and for many coun-
issues directly rather than abjure mining on the grounds that it tries and regions may indeed leak overseas. Similarly, there
might make them worse rather than help solve them. may be little prospect of economic downstream processing in
many countries that lack appropriate infrastructure or suitable
Resource Depletion and Sustainability labor. Compared with earlier times, changes in communica-
Regardless of the effectiveness and competence of host gov- tions and technology have greatly reduced the potential for
ernments, all mineral-rich countries have to cope with the con- local multiplier effects.
sequences of reserve depletion. No matter how extensive a Even in advanced countries, mine closures raise economic
country’s mineral deposits, they will eventually be exhausted. and social problems. There is a perennial debate between those
In this narrow sense, mining is not sustainable. Often the min- who would create alternative employment opportunities near
erals extracted will have been exported rather than retained worked-out mines and those who would completely abandon
within the country and hence will not be potentially available remote mine-based settlements and move their inhabitants
for recycling locally. Unless new discoveries and technologi- elsewhere. If alternatives can flourish without artificial sup-
cal developments unlock additional mineral resources, alter- port such as subsidies, the former may be the more sustainable
native means of wealth creation will be required to maintain approach. In other cases, it is best to tackle the social disloca-
existing living standards, let alone meet the rising needs of tions involved head on and accept that townships orphaned by
an expanding population. Investment of some of the proceeds mine closures are unlikely to be sustainable.
of today’s mining in other means of generating wealth may The paradox is that mineral development mobilizes
be economically and socially desirable, but the imperative of wealth by using up the potential wealth inherent in natural
satisfying immediate needs may be difficult to resist, even in resources. Provided that some of the wealth thus mobilized is
well-governed nations. In weakly governed states they may reinvested in providing for future needs, then mining makes
be irresistible. a proper contribution to sustainable development. An unex-
Historically, mining has often provided the springboard ploited mineral deposit is completely sterile, making no con-
for sustained economic development, both through its require- tribution toward meeting either present or future needs. There
ments for infrastructure, its demands for goods and services, is never any guarantee that its contents will be needed in the
and downstream linkages into further processing. As well as future.

You might also like