Deregulation and The Consequences For Airport Planning in Europe

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

DISP 154 37 2003

Guillaume Burghouwt, Menno Huys

Deregulation and the Consequences for


Airport Planning in Europe

The regulatory situation in European avi- sion of seat capacity between the desig- lated. The process was completed in
ation has changed dramatically in the nated carriers (mostly on a 50/50 ba- 1997. Every package reduced the regu-
last fifteen years. One of the major ele- sis). In most cases, the designated carri- latory restrictions and widened the op-
ers were the two national airlines or portunities for airlines to set air fares
ments of the change has been the dereg-
“flag carriers” of each country. Tariffs in and choose frequency and capacity
ulation of the European aviation market. ASAs were generally derived from deci- and entry and exit routes (Button et al.
With deregulation, the bilateral regula- sions of the International Air Transport 1998). In 2000, the fifteen member
tion of air services and IATA tariff regula- Association (IATA), the organisation of states of the European Union, Norway
tion was gradually replaced by a regula- international airlines, founded in 1945. and Iceland were part of a single
However, the bilateral system only ap- European aviation market (Doganis
tory regime of limited competition. As a
plied to scheduled traffic. Charter oper- 2001:42). In 2002, Switzerland also
consequence, airlines have developed ations were exempted from the system entered the arena. This gradual replace-
new network strategies. Airport planners and were relatively free of restrictions ment of the bilateral regulation of air
have to think differently about the plan- (Doganis 1991). services and IATA tariff regulation
ning and development of airport site ca- During the bilateral period, the Euro- brought in a period of limited competi-
pean air transport market was heavily tion.
pacity.
centred around the national airlines and The new phase of competition is lim-
This article addresses two main issues. their respective national airports. Every ited because some regulatory barriers
First, the change in European aviation European nation had its own national remain. The European Union has the
and the consequences for airline network airline (e.g., KLM, British Airways, Air right to intervene when the market is
behaviour. We will look at the new net- France). The network maps created by structurally out of balance, in the case of
these agreements covered the world a sustained downward development of
work strategies of European airlines such
with various overlapping star-shaped fares and in support of necessary but
as hub-and-spoke networks and global configurations. There was little room unviable routes to peripheral areas
strategic alliances. Second, the article de- for competition since virtually no entry (public service obligation). Moreover,
scribes the new context in which airport was possible for new scheduled air- the multilateral deregulation of the EU
planners operate. It discusses some con-
lines. Besides, ticket prices followed the aviation market only applies to the air
IATA conferences. Moreover, the air- services within the EU. For their inter-
temporary forms of airport planning such
lines were more or less the offspring of continental air services, European air-
as the commercialisation of the airport the governments. Most flag carriers lines still depend on the bilateral air
product, new airport layout requirements were (partially) owned by their govern- service agreements of the governments
and the case for flexible planning. ments and heavily subsidised. The lack of the respective country of registration.
of competition resulted in high-ticket Therefore, carriers without a designa-
prices for scheduled flights. Airlines had tion in the bilateral treaties cannot set
little incentive to reduce costs or im- up an intercontinental network.
prove efficiency. Due to these changes in the aviation
industry, the major European airlines
1.2 Limited Competition have adopted new network strategies to
1 History During the eighties, the positive experi- cope with the intensified competition.
ences with airline deregulation in the The adoption of hub-and-spoke net-
1.1 Bilateral Regulation United States, a lobby of airlines and works, the formation of global strategic
From the Second World War on, the consumers in favour of deregulation, alliances and the low-cost concept are
trinity of the national government, the new economic theories and the Euro- the most important of these new strate-
national carrier and the national airport pean unification process opened the gies. Deregulation and the changing
characterised European aviation. Indi- door for deregulation and unification of airline network pattern have signifi-
vidual nations negotiated the air serv- the European aviation market [1]. cantly affected the context in which air-
ices between two countries on a bilat- In 1987, the European Council adopt- port planners operate. We will first dis-
eral basis: the bilateral air service ed the first “package” of deregulation cuss the consequences for airline net-
agreements (ASAs) (Doganis 1991; measures, which was the first step to- work development and then the chang-
Zacher and Sutton 1996). Governments wards the creation of a single European ing context for airport planners. Finally,
reached agreement on the number of aviation market without any significant we will discuss some of the possible im-
gateways (airports) accessible to each regulatory restrictions on competition plications for future airport planning
carrier of each nation, the frequency on between European airlines. By imple- and development.
routes between the two countries, the menting a second and a third package
designated carriers operating the routes in 1990 and 1993 respectively, the EU
between the two countries and the divi- aviation market was further deregu-
DISP 154 38 2003

et al. 1998). Direct flights from medium-


sized airports to other medium-sized air-
ports were increasingly replaced by in-
direct flights via central airports or hubs
(see Figure 1). Hub-and-spoke networks
offer airlines advantages on the cost
and demand side in a highly competi-
tive market. The advantages of these
hub-and-spoke systems have been exten-
sively discussed elsewhere (see, Button
2002; Hanlon 1996; Pels 2001).
Spatial concentration and temporal
concentration are the two main features
of the hub-and-spoke network (Reynolds-
Feighan 2001). The hub carrier concen-
trates its network spatially around one
hub or a small number of hubs (see Fig-
ure 1). Reynolds-Feighan (2001) con-
cluded that most large US carriers, such
as United Airlines and Continental, did
Figure 1: Network of Western before (above)
reorganise their networks around a lim-
and after deregulation (below).
Source: Williams, 1994
ited number of central airports.
With respect to temporal concentra-
100
tion, a hub airline operates synchro-
nised, daily waves of flights through its
hubs (Reynolds-Feighan 2000). The aim
of such a “wave-system structure” is to
80
optimise the number and quality of con-
nections offered by an airline (Bootsma
1997). Many US airlines adopted or in-
60
Number of flights

tensified wave-system structures after


deregulation, such as Delta Airlines at
Atlanta Hartsfield (see Figure 2).
40

2.2 Are European Airlines


20 Forming Hubs?
The question arises whether European
airlines have followed the same network
0
6:00 7:70 9:40 11:10 12:80 14:50 16:20 17:90 19:60 21:30
strategy of implementing hub-and-spoke
6:85 8:55 10:25 11:95 13:65 15:35 17:05 18:75 20:45 networks by concentrating their route
Time of the day networks in both space and time. As we
will see, large European airlines do op-
Figure 2: The heartbeat of a hub: wave-
erate hub-and-spoke networks. How-
system structure of Delta Airlines at Atlanta
Hartsfield in 1999.
ever, the long-term process of forming
Source: OAG hubs has been limited to temporal con-
centration.
2 New Airline Network Strategies deregulation on airlines was the adop- Recalling the situation of European
tion and intensification of hub-and- aviation during bilateral regulation, na-
2.1 Hub-and-spoke Networks: spoke networks. Airlines wanted to take tional airlines were, in most cases, the
the US Case advantage of the opportunities of the designated airlines in the bilateral air
To understand the changing network be- liberalised market and reorganised service agreements. These airlines oper-
haviour of European carriers, it is useful their networks. A number of carriers re- ated from the national airports, also
to consider the consequences of airline organised their networks from “point- designated in the bilateral agreements.
deregulation in the United States in to-point” into “hub-and-spoke” networks Hence, European airline networks were,
1978. One of the most striking effects of (Reynolds-Feighan 1998, 2000; Viscusi in contrast to their American counter-
DISP 154 39 2003

parts, already heavily concentrated in


space before deregulation. These radial
networks were not hub-and-spoke net-
works in a strict sense since air services
were not coordinated in time through a
wave-system structure.
Even under limited competition, the Figure 4: Route network of Régional Airlines
in 1990 and 1999.
national carriers such as KLM, Air
Source: Burghouwt et al., 2003
France and Iberia are bound to these
national airports because their intercon-
tinental services are still subject to bilat- dial, hub-and-spoke system and made more airlines have adopted or intensi-
eral negotiations. KLM cannot simply use of the renovated airport of Cler- fied their wave-system structures at cen-
move its home base to another EU coun- mont-Ferrand. With its new airport lay- tral airports. KLM, for example, reor-
try without losing its portfolio of inter- out, Clermont-Ferrand allowed for very ganised its three to four wave-system
continental traffic rights. As a result, the short minimum connection times of into a more effective five wave-system.
level of network concentration for Euro- about twenty minutes during the four Lufthansa started a wave-system struc-
pean flag carriers has remained re- daily waves of incoming and outgoing ture at the newly constructed airport,
markably high and stable even after Eu- short-haul flights of Régional Airlines. Munich II, alleviating some of the ca-
ropean deregulation (see Figure 3). Major European airlines did, how- pacity problems at Frankfurt. Initially,
Only a few regional airlines reconfig- ever, reorganise their networks in a tem- Air France did not operate any wave-
ured their networks from point-to-point, poral sense. Burghouwt and De Wit system structure at Paris Charles de
criss-cross networks into radially organ- (2003) have concluded that more and Gaulle or Lyon. However, the carrier did
ised hub-and-spoke networks. Régional implement a fully effective traffic pump
Airlines is perhaps the best example of at Charles de Gaulle in March 1996
such a network reorganisation (see Fig- 30 (see Figure 5) and a more modest sys-
ure 4). Régional Airlines and its prede- tem at Lyon in the same year.
cessor Air Vendée used to operate a lin- In contrast to the US airlines, Euro-
ear network. After deregulation, the air- 20
pean airlines had entered the phase of
line reconfigured its network into a ra- spatial network concentration long be-
Number of flights

fore deregulation. In general, these star-


shaped networks were not coordinated
10
in time. Transfer opportunities at central
airports were mostly created “by acci-
0.9
dent.” With the deregulation of the EU
0.8
0 air transport market from 1988 on, a
0.7 6:00 7:80 9:60 11:40 13:20 15:00 16:80 18:60 20:40
second phase of airline network con-
Network concentration

6:90 8:70 10v50 12:30 14:10 15:90 17:70 19:50 21:30


0.6
Departures Arrivals Wave centre centration started. European airlines
0.5
concentrated their networks in time by
0.4
30
adopting or intensifying wave-system
0.3
structures in their flight schedules, trans-
0.2
forming the carriers into hub-and-spoke
0.1
airlines.
0.0 20
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999
Number of flights

low-cost 2.3 Global Strategic Alliances


national The airline alliance frenzy of the 1990s
regional
extra-EU 10
was another outcome of deregulation in
European aviation. From a geographi-
Note: A high network concentration index repre-
sents spatial concentration of airline traffic on a limi- cal point of view, three types of airline
ted number of hubs. Low network concentration indi- alliances can be identified. The first
ces represent a spatially deconcentrated, point-to- 0
type, the route-specific alliance, is the
6:00 7:80 9:60 11:40 13:20 15:00 16:80 18:60 20:40
point network. See for a detailed description of the
network concentration index: Burghouwt et al.,
6:90 8:70 10v50 12:30 14:10 15:90 17:70 19:50 21:30
simplest and by far the most numerous.
Departures Arrivals Wave centre
2003. The second type, the regional alliance,
Figure 3: Network concentration indices for Figure 5: Wave-system structure of Air France covers a much wider scale. The third
national, regional, low-cost and extra-Euro- at Paris CDG in 1990 (above) and 1999 (be- type is the global alliance.
pean airlines, 1990–1999 low). Global airline alliances are the most
Source: Burghouwt et al., 2003 Source: Burghouwt & De Wit, 2003 important ones in terms of network ex-
DISP 154 40 2003

25

20

15

10

5
Virgin Express
pansion and they have the most far- greater part of the total number of pas- easyJet 0
reaching consequences for the airport. sengers. As a consequence of the con- Ryanair 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
The hub-and-spoke networks of two or centration process of the transfer pas-
Figure 6: Passenger growth of the three
more large airlines that operate in geo- sengers on these hubs, their market
largest low-cost carriers (in millions), 1998 to
graphically distinct markets, often on share in intercontinental seat capacity
2002.
different continents, are linked by their rose from 44% in 1990 to more than Source: Annual reports Ryanair, easyJet, Vir-
respective hubs. This means an increase 50 % in 1999. (Burghouwt and Hak- gin Express
in the scope and size of the airline net- foort 2001) The growth potential of an
works, which normally means an in- airport is therefore largely dependent
crease in passengers and freight vol- on the presence or absence of a global The success of the low-cost carriers is
ume. Alliances can also lead to a re- alliance at the airport. Airports that are a result of the business model of these
duction of costs by producing eco- not a home-base for a global alliance airlines, which can be defined by three
nomies of density, size and scope and partner are condemned to growing at a key elements. The most important ele-
by joint purchasing of aircraft. A third modest pace, especially because they ment is the low operating costs, caused
reason for alliance building is reducing lack the high numbers of transfer pas- by low personnel costs (ticket-less sales,
competition, which is most effective sengers. cheap labour), low airport fees (use of
when the partners serve the same secondary airports), low costs for main-
routes. A final reason for forming al- tenance (single aircraft type) and high
liances is to bypass the nationality rules 2.4 The Low-cost Concept levels of productivity (high daily utilisa-
and other regulatory barriers that make Sometimes it is said that there are two tion by reducing turnaround time). The
cross-border acquisitions and mergers ways to make money in the aviation second element is the simple product
impossible for the time being (Doganis business. The first is by creating a hub- (no frills) offered. No free in-flight cater-
2001; Oum et al 2001). and-spoke network with additional al- ing or entertainment, narrow seats
At present, four strategic global al- liances. The second way is by imple- (higher seating density) and no seat
liances can be identified, which make menting the low-cost concept, originally reservations are the most important fea-
up about 60 % of the world passenger- introduced by the US airline Southwest tures of the product. The third element
kilometers. The Star Alliance (i.e., in 1967. of the business design is its positioning
United Airlines, Lufthansa, SAS) is the Ryanair started the low-cost revolution in the market. Low-cost carriers offer
largest one, followed by the Oneworld in Europe, when it began with genuine high frequency, scheduled, point-to-
Alliance (i.e., American Airlines, British low-cost operations on the British Isles in point short-haul services, which they
Airways, Iberia), Sky Team (i.e., Air 1991, patterned after the Southwest promote with very aggressive marketing
France, Delta, Alitalia) and Wings (i.e., model. The real revolution started after strategies.
KLM, Northwest). Until recently, there the implementation of the third deregu-
was a fifth alliance, Qualiflyer, but it lation package in 1993, which deregu-
ceased to exist after the bankruptcies of lated the international air services 3 Increased Volatility
Swissair and Sabena in 2001. One within the European Union. The devel- As we have seen, the period of limited
must keep in mind that alliances are opment of low-cost carriers started in the competition in European aviation and
only transitional devices on the rocky UK because of the lower labour costs, the resulting network strategies of
road to full mergers. the huge London market and the light- European carriers have dramatically
It is expected that a period of great in- handed regulatory environment (Doga- changed the context in which airport
stability will occur when the nationality nis 2001). Go, Buzz and EasyJet all planners operate. Two main features
rules and other constraints are relaxed started there. Since 1999, after the ex- characterise the new context: volatility
during the coming years and cross-bor- pansion in the UK, the low-cost carriers and new requirements for airport layout
der acquisitions and mergers become began increasingly to take a hold on the and functions.
possible. The alliance structures will continental market. The only exception The market environment of European
change, which affects the future traffic is Virgin Express, which started with a airports is getting more and more
volumes for airports since every alliance home-base in Brussels in 1994. volatile for a number of reasons. First of
has its own primary hub. These primary With growth rates of 15 to 60 % per all, deregulation abolished the exten-
hubs function as the major transfer year, the low-cost carriers have rapidly sive financial state support to European
points between the networks of the al- expanded their market power. The pas- carriers. When carriers do not operate
liance partners on the different conti- senger growth of the most important efficiently enough, they simply disap-
nents. Nowadays, Europe has four pri- low-cost carriers is presented in Figure pear from the arena or merge with an-
mary hubs (Paris Charles de Gaulle, 6. It is expected that the low-cost carri- other carrier. The effect on the traffic vol-
Frankfurt, London Heathrow, Amster- ers will expand their European market ume of the central airports of these car-
dam Schiphol), each bound to a global share from the present 5% to 25% by riers are widely known in Europe and
alliance that is responsible for the 2010. the United States. Brussels Zaventem
DISP 154 41 2003

25
20
15
10
5
0
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002
Brussels Zurich

Figure 7: Number of passengers at Brussels


had to cope with the bankruptcies of its Zaventem and Zürich Unique Airport, 1993
cessary information to make a rational
home carrier Sabena and its Qualiflyer to 2002. decision and choose the best develop-
Alliance partner Swissair (see Figure 7 Source: Statistical Yearbook 2002 Zurich; ment alternative for the airport.
and Table 1). The airport lost huge num- BRUtrends 1998 and 2002 • Reactivity: the master plan is one res-
bers of passengers, especially transfer ponse to one specific expectation about
passengers. the future.
Second, airlines are now free to enter transfer passengers to the airport that • Inflexibility: the master plan does not
(if capacity is available) and exit routes functions as the primary hub of the al- consider alternative futures for the air-
as they wish. For intra-European traffic, liance network. port.
carriers are no longer bound to the De Neufville and Barber (1991a) • The role of power: The rational-com-
bilateral treaties. In theory, airlines studied volatility in airport traffic before prehensive model assumes a unitary,
can build up and abandon hubs in and after US deregulation. They con- powerful actor. It ignores the role and
a relatively short period of time – as cluded that volatility in airport traffic has preferences of other important stakehol-
happened in the United States after indeed increased due to deregulation ders (e.g., airlines, the public) during
deregulation. However, for interconti- and changing network strategies. As far the decision-making process.
nental services, European airlines are as Europe is concerned, Burghouwt et However, the changing context in
still bound to their country of registra- al. (2003) have concluded that net- which airport planners operate has
tion. Relocation of intercontinental hubs works of national airlines were quite sta- made traditional airport master plan-
is therefore less likely in Europe for the ble during the first ten years of deregu- ning inadequate for a number of rea-
time being [2]. lation. Volatility in airport traffic was sons. First of all, the informational re-
Third, the intensification and adoption mainly caused by bankruptcies of quirements of the rational-comprehen-
of hub-and-spoke networks by airlines regional airlines, the growth of regional sive master planning are unrealistic. In-
has increased volatility of airport traffic, hub airlines (such as Régional Airlines creased volatility in airport traffic vol-
since transfer traffic generated by these at Clermont-Ferrand) and low-cost umes has resulted in the fact that air traf-
networks (see Table 1) is to a large ex- carriers (such as Ryanair at London fic forecasts, basic to the traditional
tent unpredictable. Airports and the Stansted). Recently, however, volatility master plan, are almost always wrong
home carrier compete for transfer traf- of airport traffic might have increased (de Neufville and Barber 1991a; de
fic. Changes in the quality of the con- significantly due to bankruptcies of ma- Neufville and Odoni 2003; Dempsey et
necting service (transfer time, ticket jor European carriers (Swissair, Sabe- al. 1997). The future will likely be very
price, frequency, quality of the hub air- na) and specialisation of hubs within different from the master plan forecast.
port) may easily result in declining num- global alliance groupings. A master plan based on a single traffic
bers of transfer passengers since those Increasing volatility demands that the forecast and a single future therefore
transfer passengers can travel through standard process of airport “blue-print” cannot be justified. Moreover, rational-
other European hubs (de Neufville master planning be adapted. comprehensive master planning as-
1995; Veldhuis and Kroes 2002). sumes that all policy alternatives and
Finally, volatility is further being stimu- consequences are known. But, this is not
lated by the increasing importance of 4 Volatility Demands correct; planners do not have complete
global airline alliances. Secondary air- Flexible Planning and unbiased knowledge. Second, so-
ports in networks of global airline al- Traditionally, the rational comprehen- cio-economic and political variables
liances may lose the greater part of their sive model was the dominant paradigm cannot be ignored during the decision-
in airport master planning (Dempsey making process. Due to deregulation,
et al. 1997). A master plan consisted the balance of power in the airline in-
of a future vision of the architectural/ dustry has shifted from the governments
Airport 1997 2002
engineering development of a single air- to the airlines. Hence, the role of airlines
Amsterdam Schiphol 42 % 42 % port (de Neufville and Odoni 2003). de in the decision-making process can no
Copenhagen Kastrup 45 % 46 % Neufville and Odoni (2003), de longer be ignored, nor can the role of
Frankfurt Fraport 47 % 53 % Neufville (1991b), de Neufville and Bar- the public, especially in dense metropol-
Paris Charles de Gaulle 38 % 58 %
ber (1991a), Dempsey et al. (1997), itan areas.
Brussels Zaventem 25 % 7%
and Hakfoort and Kreukels (1998) state A leading academic on airport plan-
Zurich Unique 37 % 38 %
London Heathrow 32 % – that the traditional, rational comprehen- ning, Richard de Neufville, argues that
sive master planning is characterised traditional master planning needs to
Note: Data for London Heathrow 2002 not available. by: be discarded in favour of dynamic
Table 1: Transfer traffic (percent in total number • Detailed forecasts: detailed forecasts strategic planning (de Neufville and
of passengers) at major European hubs in on future traffic are basic to the plan- Odoni 2003). Comparable planning
1997 and 2002 ning and design of an airport. It is assu- concepts are flexible planning (Demp-
Source: Various annual/statistical reports med that planners have access to all ne- sey et al. 1997; Goetz and Szyliowicz
DISP 154 42 2003

1997), “marketplace” planning (Caves abandoned the idea that the planning have evolved from origin-destination
and Gosling 1999) and contingency authority is the dominant actor during nodes to transfer nodes. Hub-and-spoke
planning (Hakfoort and Kreukels 1998). the planning process. Goetz and Szyli- traffic has different requirements than
We will call these concepts “flexible owicz (1997) add an organisational di- origin-destination traffic. Hub-and-spoke
planning”. mension to this concept. Flexible airport networks imply a concentration of traffic
Flexible planning is flexible, proactive planning needs an appropriate organi- in both space and time. From the airline
and interactive. It is flexible in the sense sational structure that is robust and re- or alliance viewpoint, spatial concentra-
that it recognises uncertainty and risk as silient. The organisation should be both tion requires a vast daily capacity at
an inescapable reality. There are differ- prepared and able to continue working the hub airport. Besides, because hub
ent ways to deal with an uncertain fu- after unexpected developments. airlines use wave-system structures to
ture. First of all, flexible planning does Flexible planning might be the right facilitate transfers, the hub airport
not produce a single forecast but multi- answer to the changes in the European should also have a large peak-hour ca-
ple traffic forecasts under different sce- aviation industry because it builds in pacity at the runway, the terminal and
narios. The determination of initial air- flexibility as an answer to uncertainty. the landside infrastructures. Amsterdam
port facility requirements is suitable for The study of de Neufville (1991c) on Schiphol, for example, has presented its
several possible levels and types of traf- Sydney Airport has clearly demon- plans for a sixth and seventh runway to
fic in different scenarios. Second, the strated the benefits of a flexible plan- stimulate peak hour capacity and make
new generation of airport planning ac- ning strategy, whereas the extensive it possible to use two parallel runways
knowledges uncertainty because it is in- study of Dempsey et al. (1997) on Den- for both take-off and landing in virtually
cremental and phased: it selects the ver International Airport has proven the every wind direction.
most suitable initial development that al- failure of traditional master planning in Because airlines compete for transfer
lows planners to respond appropriately a volatile market environment. traffic, they will prefer passenger build-
to future levels of traffic. “Go/no-go” However, it is not clear to what extent ings that minimise walking distances be-
checkpoints might prepare planners for European airports have implemented tween the gates in order to provide
the unexpected (Goetz and Szyliowicz flexible planning strategies, although smooth transfers. De Neufville and
1997). After the initial development, some indications show that elements of Odoni (2003) state that midfield pas-
new information is used to evaluate the flexibility have been introduced to Euro- senger buildings (such as the passenger
situation again and decide about the pean airport planning. After September buildings at Denver International, Lon-
next development stage. Incrementality 11 and the SARS outbreak, a number of don Stansted and Pittsburg) are the
demonstrates itself physically as modu- airports postponed further development preferred form for transfer traffic, com-
larity: facilities such as piers and termi- of piers and terminals, which could be pared to the linear building (e.g.,
nals are no longer indivisible entities but seen as a form of incrementalism and Munich, Barcelona), the finger-pier
consist of various modules that can be phased planning. Amsterdam Schiphol, building (e.g., Frankfurt, Amsterdam
built up when traffic grows. for example, decided to build only one Schiphol, London Heathrow) and the
Finally, flexible planning deals with module of the terminal extension instead transporter building (e.g., Washington
uncertainty because it is characterised of the planned four modules. The picture Dulles). The midfield passenger building
by hedging: some kind of back-up sys- is far from complete, however. Given minimises walking distances for transfer
tem or insurance protects against an un- the increasingly volatile nature of the Eu- passengers and taxi time for aircraft.
foreseen and less favourable develop- ropean air transport industry, more re- Airports with long minimum connec-
ment (contingency planning). This can search on this topic is needed. tion times between flights such as Lon-
be a financial matter (buying insurance) don Heathrow are generally not very at-
but also a technical (e.g., a backup-up tractive transfer points for passengers.
baggage system) or spatial matter To ensure the competitive strength of a
(reservation of land for future develop- 5 New Requirements for Airport hub, the transfer process should also be
ments). Layout and Development reliable and easy. Passengers find trans-
In contrast to traditional master plan- fers within one building more attractive
ning, flexible planning is proactive. It 5.1 Hub Airports than between different buildings, for ex-
seeks to use new opportunities given the The changes in European aviation have ample. Although, it must be borne in
strengths and weaknesses of the airport not only resulted in the need for a more mind that the availability of an intelli-
instead of waiting for future develop- flexible airport planning process. It also gently managed midfield concourse is
ments. Flexible planning is interactive has affected the requirements for the no guarantee for having a hub-and-
in the sense that it acknowledges the physical layout of airports. Due to the spoke airline and a large number of
preferences of other stakeholders such adoption and intensification of hub-and- transfer passengers. In the case of Brus-
as airlines and the inhabitants of the spoke systems, the function of airports in sels Zaventem, the airport opened the
airport region (Dempsey et al. 1997; general has changed significantly. A most modern midfield pier in Europe
Goetz and Szyliowicz 1997). It has number of central European airports in 2002, but as a consequence of the
DISP 154 43 2003

demise of Sabena the excellent transfer ulation, airports were seen as public util- itself as being in the business of “creat-
opportunities remain largely unused ities with public service obligations. The ing airport cities” (Schaafsma 2001).
(BIAC, 2003). Since transfer traffic is management of the airport was rela- Triggered by the necessity of finding
highly unpredictable, the passenger tively simple. Providing infrastructure for additional financing, other than public
buildings should have some flexibility in national purposes was the core task and funds, for the building of additional in-
their use, for example, they can be ex- only a few business skills and compe- frastructure, airport privatisation be-
tended easily when traffic grows. Devel- tencies were required. came a reality in the 1990s. Privatisa-
opment space has to be available next Under limited competition, however, tion reduces the need for public sector
to existing airport facilities. airports have to meet the needs of the investment and gives access to commer-
new airline customers (such as hub car- cial markets. Privatisation can also im-
5.2 Low-cost Airports riers, alliances and low-cost carriers) prove efficiency and accommodate fur-
Of course, not all hub airports fit the de- and passengers to compete in a volatile ther commercialisation of the airport in-
scription in a strict sense. Only 22 out of marketplace. One of the strategies air- dustry. On the other hand, it is feared
461 EU airports with scheduled services ports used to fight the increasing com- that the needs of the community and air-
had some kind of wave-system structure petition and uncertainty was to modify lines will be neglected and that airports
in 1999, while about 40 airports were and diversify their product. So, during will become natural monopolies after
hub airports in the sense that they pro- the 1980s the commercialisation of the privatisation (CPB 2000). In Europe,
vided more than ten indirect connec- airport industry began to gain momen- only some of the airports in the United
tions per day but they did not have a tum. The commercialisation process in- Kingdom have been fully privatised to
clear wave-system structure (Burghouwt troduced a more business-like, market- date (Humphreys 1999). The airports of
and de Wit 2003). The rest of the air- orientated approach to the manage- Zurich, Vienna, Copenhagen, Rome
ports can be considered non-hub air- ment of airports (Jarach 2001). The in- and Frankfurt are partially privatised.
ports. creased focus on non-aeronautical or Privatisation of airport authorities in
An interesting group of airports commercial revenues, the more proac- many countries were planned for the
among the non-hub airports are the tive role of marketing and the introduc- beginning of the 21st century, for
home-bases of low-cost carriers. The on- tion of new business skills like financial example, in the Netherlands (Schiphol
going low-cost revolution has had seri- management and quality management Group) and Belgium (BIAC), but have
ous consequences for these airports. Re- are visible indications of the commer- been postponed as a result of the pres-
gional airports benefit the most from the cialisation of airports (Graham 2001). ent-day uncertainties in the rather unsta-
low-cost revolution because they can of- The rise of the airport city can be seen ble aviation sector.
fer low-cost airlines remarkable opportu- as the result of the differentiation and
nities for growth: they are uncongested commercialisation strategies of the air-
and charge relatively low airport fees. port site as a way to spread the risks
The expansion of Ryanair’s operations and reduce the dependence on the 6 Conclusion: Towards a New
at Brussels South (Charleroi) and at aeronautical revenues. The largest air- Generation of Airport Planning?
Frankfurt-Hahn are good examples of ports of Europe are increasingly being Due to the deregulation of the European
booming low-cost operations from a re- integrated into the regional and high airline industry, airlines have become
gional airport. The point-to-point opera- speed train networks, which makes them market-driven entities. Governments, air-
tions make the specific facilities for easy focal points of landside transport. Be- lines and airports are no longer a trinity
transfers unnecessary and the low-cost cause of their central network position in bilateral air service agreements. Bi-
carriers are certainly not willing to pay on the airside (mega hub) and their lateral regulation has now been trans-
for an expensive hub infrastructure. The landside connections (multimodal inter- formed into a situation of limited com-
price tag for making the airport suitable change node), these airports become petition. Airlines have adopted new net-
for low-cost carriers includes providing an attractive development pool (Cofar work strategies to cope with the intensi-
the necessary infrastructure and facili- 2001). In particular, the primary hubs fied competition. The adoption and in-
ties. These facilities include single storey of Schiphol, London Heathrow and tensification of hub-and-spoke networks
terminals, lower (and cheaper) service Frankfurt are turning into powerful cen- by airlines and global alliances as well
levels, quick turnaround times and high- tres of urban development by concen- as the low-cost concept are among the
speed check-in facilities. trating various functions at the airport most important of these strategies.
site like office buildings, shopping The new network strategies have had
5.3 Commercialisation malls, casinos, hotels, conference halls, some significant consequences for the
The changing network behaviour of air- etc. (Burghouwt 2002). At these pri- context in which airport planners oper-
lines has also changed the management mary hubs, the commercial activities ate, especially regarding the new air-
structure of airports, which seems to have brought in up to 50 % of the air- port layout requirements and the in-
have serious implications for the func- port’s profits (Güller and Güller 2001). creased uncertainty for airport planners.
tioning of airports. During bilateral reg- The Schiphol Group especially presents We have discussed some of the possible
DISP 154 44 2003

impacts of the new context for airport Notes DEMPSEY, P. S., A. R. GOETZ and J.S.
planning practices. The case for the SZYLIOWICZ (1997): Denver International
[1] See Button (1998), Doganis (1991), Na- Airport; Lessons Learned. New York, Mc-
midfield passenger building, the need
yar (1995), Dagtoglou (1994) and Williams Graw-Hill.
for a more flexible planning model and
(1994) for a detailed description of the
the commercialisation and diversifica- deregulation process.
DOGANIS, R. (1991): Flying Off Course.
tion of the airport product may be the The Economics of International Airlines. Lon-
[2] Recently, however, the EU transport minis-
most important aspects of a new gener- don, Routledge.
ters have opened the door for one bilateral
ation of airport planning. treaty between the EU and the United States. DOGANIS, R. (2001): The Airline Business
The fact that airport planners are This bilateral will replace the umbrella of air in the 21st Century. London, Routledge.
nowadays confronted with a very unsta- service agreements of the individual member
states. GOETZ, A. R. and J. S. SZYLIOWICZ
ble market environment deserves atten-
(1997): Revisiting Transportation Planning
tion. Investments in airport capacity and Decision-making Theory: the Case of
are high-cost, long-term developments Denver International Airport. In: Transporta-
whereas airlines’ network behaviour tion Research A 31(4): 263–280.
is increasingly dynamic. Examples from References
GRAHAM, A. (2001): Managing Airports:
the United States (Denver International BIAC (2003): Annual Report, Brussels Airport an International Perspective. Oxford, Butter-
Airport) and Canada (Montreal Mira- Zaventem 2002. BIAC, Zaventem. worth-Heinemann.
bel) have clearly demonstrated the fail-
BOOTSMA, P. D. (1997): Airline Flight GÜLLER, M. and GÜLLER, M. (2001): From
ure of traditional airport master plan-
Schedule Development; Analysis and Design Airport to Airport City. Barcelona, Litogama.
ning approaches where detailed fore- Tools for European Hinterland Hubs. Utrecht,
casts of future traffic volumes are central University of Twente. HAKFOORT, J. R. and A. J. M. KREUKELS
to decisions on future developments and (1998): Planologische theorie en de
BURGHOUWT, G. and J. R. HAKFOORT
master plans are of a high “blue print”, besluitvorming rondom Schiphol. Colloquium
(2001): The European Aviation Network,
centralised character. Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk, Amster-
1990–1998. In: Journal of Air Transport
A new generation of airport master dam.
Management 7(5): 311–318.
planning is therefore needed. This new HANLON, P. (1996): Global Airlines. Com-
BURGHOUWT, G. (2002): De onweerstaan-
generation of airport planning adopts petition in a Transnational Industry. Oxford,
bare opkomst van de airport city. In: Ge-
flexibility in order to cope with a highly Butterworth-Heinemann Ltd.
ografie (September 2001).
unstable market environment. The ques- HUMPHREYS, I. (1999): Privatisation and
BURGHOUWT, G., J. R. HAKFOORT and J.
tion remains as to what extent European Commercialisation. Changes in UK Airport
R. RITSEMA VAN ECK (2003): The Spatial
airport authorities have already adopt- ownership patterns. In: Journal of Transport
Configuration of Airline Networks in Europe.
ed flexible planning approaches. More In: Journal of Air Transport Management Geography 7: 121–134.
research is needed to answer this ques- 9(5): 309–323. JARACH, D. (2001): The Evolution of Airport
tion. It is certain, however, that the management Practices: Towards a Multi-
BURGHOUWT, G. and J. DE WIT (2003):
changes in European aviation have had point, Multi-service, Marketing-driven Firm.
The Temporal Configuration of European Air-
a structural impact on airline network In: Journal of Air Transport Management
line Networks. Air Transport Research Soci-
behaviour. The context in which airport ety Conference, Toulouse. 7(4): 119–125.
planners operate has changed forever.
BUTTON, K., K. HAYNES and R. STOUGH NAYAR, B. R. (1995): Regimes, Power and
(1998): Flying Into the Future. Air Transport International Aviation. In: International Orga-
Policy in the European Union. Cheltenham, nization 49(1): 139–170.
Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.
DE NEUFVILLE, R. and J. BARBER (1991a):
BUTTON, K. (2002): Debunking Some Com- Deregulation Induced Volatility of Airport
mon Myths about Airport Hubs. In: Journal of Traffic. In: Transportation Planning and Tech-
Air Transport Management 8(3): 177–188. nology 16: 117–128.
CAVES, R. E. and G. D. GOSLING (1999): DE NEUFVILLE, R. (1991b): Understanding
Strategic Airport Planning. Amsterdam, Perg- and Using Forecasts. Foreword to Passenger
amon. Forecasts for Logan International Airport.
COFAR (2001): Airport City and Regional Boston.
Embeddedness. Project Interreg IIC, Theme DE NEUFVILLE, R. (1991c): Strategic Plan-
2.3. Paris, IAURIF Prins DC. ning for Airport Capacity: an Appreciation
CPB (2000): Schiphol: een normaal bedrijf? of Australia’s Process for Sydney. In: Aus-
Den Haag, Centraal Planbureau. tralian Planner 29(3): 174–180.

DAGTOGLOU, P. D. (1994): Air Transport DE NEUFVILLE, R. (1995): Designing Airport


and the European Union. Essays and Com- Passenger Buildings for the 21st Century. In:
ments. Deventer, Kluwer. Transport Journal 111(May): 83–96.
DISP 154 45 2003

DE NEUFVILLE, R. and A. R. ODONI (2003): Drs. Guillaume Burghouwt


Airport Systems. Planning, Design and Man- Faculty of Geographical Sciences
agement. New York, McGraw Hill. Department of Urban and Regional Planning
Utrecht University
OUM, T. H., C. YU and A. ZHANG. (2001):
Heidelberglaan 2
Global Airline Alliances: International Regu-
NL-3508 TC Utrecht
latory Issues. In: Journal of Air Transport
The Netherlands
Management 7: 57–62.
G.Burghouwt@geog.uu.nl
PELS, E. (2001): A Note on Airline Alliances.
In: Journal of Air Transport Management 7: Drs. Menno Huys
3–7. Faculty of Geographical Sciences
REYNOLDS-FEIGHAN, A. (1998): The Im- Department of Urban and Regional Planning
pact of US Airline Deregulation on Airport Utrecht University
Traffic Patterns. In: Geographical Analysis Heidelberglaan 2
30(3): 234–253. NL-3508 TC Utrecht
The Netherlands
REYNOLDS-FEIGHAN, A. (2000): The US M.Huys@geog.uu.nl
Airport Hierarchy and Implications for Small
Communities. In: Urban Studies 37(3):
557–577.
REYNOLDS-FEIGHAN, A. (2001): Traffic Dis-
tribution in Low-cost and Full-service Carrier
Networks. In: Journal of Air Transport Man-
agement 7(5): 265–275.
SCHAAFSMA, M. (2001): Planning Schiphol
Airport City. Flughafen- und Raumentwick-
lung. In: B. SCHOLL and E.-A. BUDAU. Karls-
ruhe, Institut für Städtebau und Landespla-
nung, Universität Karlsruhe: 7–15.
VELDHUIS, J. and E. KROES (2002): Dynam-
ics in Relative Network Performance of the
Main European Hub Airports. European
Transport Conference, Cambridge.
VISCUSI, W. K., J. M. VERNON and J.E.
HARRINGTON (1998): Economics of Regu-
lation and Antitrust. Cambridge, MIT Press.
WILLIAMS, G. (1994): Airline Industry and
the Impact of Deregulation. Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
ZACHER, M. W. and C. J. SUTTON (1996):
Governing Global Networks: International
Regimes for Transportation and Communica-
tion. Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.

View publication stats

You might also like