Moore, J.W. 2015 - Nature in The Limits To Capital

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

Nature in the limits to capital

(and vice versa)


Jason W. Moore

Of all the varieties of crisis thinking, ecological crisis not around, nature. Culture and symbolic praxis, too,
is perhaps the least developed. It is certainly the become ‘material forces’. We are dealing not with
least conceptualized. To be sure, there is no scar- Nature/Society but with an ‘unbroken coincidence of
city of empirically rich analyses of biophysical shifts being, knowing, and doing’.2
at every scale. But ecological crisis in its popular
usage has been an expansive concept, implicating the Beyond limits
widest range of human activity. It invokes questions The ‘limits to growth’ in the capitalist era are neither
of history, power and capital just as much as those Natural nor Social – not, at any rate, in the way we
of ecology. And therein lies the source of consider- usually think of these terms. They are, rather, the
able confusion and uncertainty – not so much about limits of capitalism’s strategic relations in the web
what might happen (a necessarily contingent matter), of life. The ‘object’ of crisis is not a substance but a
but about what has happened, and how that history relation of organizing and reproducing life, power
shapes the possibilities we face today. and capital. This perspective comes from seeing the
Such weak conceptualization stems from a way of modern world-system as a capitalist world-ecology,
thinking with origins in the rise of capitalism, more joining the accumulation of capital, the pursuit of
than five centuries ago, which I will call ‘Cartesian power, and the production of nature in dialectical
dualism’, extending Descartes’ famous mind–body unity. This is not the ecology of Nature – with the
dualism to the notion that Nature and Society are upper-case ‘N’ – but the ecology of the oikeios: that
epistemically, even ontologically, independent enti- creative, generative and multilayered relation of life-
ties. That dualism powerfully shapes how we think, making, of species and environments. Species make
see and act upon ‘ecological crisis’ today. environments; environments make species. The
Of several alternatives now emerging, the world- philosophical point shapes the historical method:
ecology conversation has offered a means of refram- human activity is environment-making. And in this
ing world history as a unity of power, capital and observation, nature moves from noun (‘the’ envi-
nature.1 If modern world history is typically viewed ronment) to verb (environment-making). Human
as a history of human relations with environmental organizations are environment-making processes and
consequences, a broader synthesis is suggested by projects; they are shaped by manifold environment-
four decades of Green thought: modernity does not making processes in the web of life. This is the double
only act upon nature, but develops through the web internality of historical change – humanity inside
of life. I call this synthesis world-ecology – but not nature; nature inside humanity. (With humanity dif-
because it is committed to studying the ‘ecology of ferentiated, not reduced to formless, abstract homo-
the world’. Rather, world-ecology is a way of concep- geneity.) World-ecology is not alone in making the
tualizing and investigating historical change in the broad philosophical argument; but it is distinctive
web of life. This optic is at once a protest against the in arguing for the translation of these philosophical
‘Cartesian’ binary and an alternative to it; the world- positions into methodological premisses, narrative
ecology perspective engages capitalist civilization as strategies and theoretical frames in which specific
a relation of all nature, including those symbolic forms of human organization – capitalism especially
and material relations between humans often viewed – are producers/products of the web of life. The
as unquestionably social. In this perspective, the present argument is intended as a series of openings,
relations of capital, labour and power move through, an invitation to dialogue – not as a new orthodoxy.

r a d i c a l p hilo s o p h y 1 9 3 (sep t/o c t 2 0 1 5) 9


World-ecology therefore contrasts sharply with commodi-faunation. The acceleration of ecocide and
the conventional sorting of Social and Natural the take-off of the meat-industrial revolution since
limits and crises. Consider the usual catalogue of the 1970s are, in such a frame, no mere coincidence.
the forces behind biospheric change, some version They are joined in the fundamental relations of
of which finds a place in nearly every survey of capital, power and nature that make the modern
ecological crisis: industrialization, urbanization, world what it is. Such an alternative follows the really
economic growth, capitalism, imperialism, over- decisive relations of capitalist crisis-generation, from
population, overconsumption, and a great many the biosphere to animal and human bodies to the
beyond. Mainstream and radical scholars prefer dif- capitalist transformation of landscapes. In Weis’s
ferent factors and different concepts, but all share powerful formulation, we are able to follow the
the same premiss: Society (humans without nature) world-historical movements of ‘ghosts’ (extinguished
and Nature (ecologies without humans) are the basic species) and ‘things’ (commodified animals as meat).
units of global change. Thus, the distinctive quality One part of this movement renders the necessary
of these driving forces is the assumption that human human labour-power and raw materials to the gates
activity and human organization somehow form of meatpacking plants and factory farms. The other
prior to the awful environmental consequences that part simply exterminates life, carrying the law of
follow from that activity. In environmental studies value to its logical conclusion. Neither part of this
today there is a clear movement away from Car- crisis-generating complex can be reduced to its Social
tesian dualism, but only up to a point. For those and Natural parts because every moment implicates
fields focusing on regional change – such as political specific bundles of human and extra-human nature.3
ecology and environmental history – a relational The limits to modernity are made through the web
approach finds growing resonance. For those who of life. Once a novel, even controversial, statement,
study global change, however, Cartesian dualism has that idea is now widely accepted. But it hasn’t quite
been empowered, unfolding as if four decades of the sunk in. Not really. The web of life today is still widely
critique of dualism never occurred. Our big concepts considered in its 1970s’ incarnation: natural limits.
of global change – capitalism, imperialism, indus- The very core of capitalist development is premissed
trialization, commercialization, and so on – remain on a dialectical movement that simultaneously glo-
safely insulated from the critique of dualism. balizes our daily lives and our relations to planetary
The resilience of Nature/Society dualism means nature, not only creating successive opportunities for
that too many scholars – and activists – continue to capital accumulation, but persistently undermining
look for the causes and consequences of capitalist the real basis of accumulation: the Cheap Natures
crisis through a seventeenth-century lens. Nature/ of food, labour-power, energy and raw materials. As
Society doesn’t add up to a compelling picture of Marx and Engels understood, ‘natural’ conditions are
capitalist crisis today – that’s why the seemingly not so natural as we might think.
abstract questions of epistemology and ontology have There are limits. But limits to what? A quarter-
become oh so very practical in our disastrous con- century ago, Ted Benton rightly observed that every
juncture. The very constructs we have used to discern civilization is a ‘specific structure of natural/social
the present, disastrous state of affairs – the Nature/ articulation’ with specific limits to the reproduction of
Society divide – have outlived their usefulness. That that articulation.4 Radicals have focused on the first
dualism runs a knife through the web of real con- part of that observation – ‘natural/social’. But we find
nections between human and extra-human natures the heart of the matter in that last word: articulation.
that are fundamental to an emancipatory politics of Once we start to look at the relationality of power
life-making in the coming century. and re/production in the web of life, we move beyond
Consider the ongoing dialogue over the Sixth dualism; it begins to dissolve.
Extinction of planetary life. Scholars, somewhat If limits are found in the relations of power and re/
antiseptically, call this ‘de-faunation’. In this production, bundled with specific historical natures,
important discussion, Nature/Society threatens to then our thinking about crisis begins to shift. A
short-circuit a radical analytical imagination, one limit for one civilization is not necessarily a limit for
that would join the extinction of species with the another. Civilizations – call them historical systems
accumulation of capital. A world-ecological account, or modes of production if you wish – are ways of
as Tony Weis shows, begins with such connec- organizing the relations of human and extra-human
tions. Here de-faunation appears as the flip side of natures. The putatively social relations of territorial

10
power, surplus production and accumulation, hege- unfolds within the zone of commodification. My
monic cultures – all can be seen as bundled relations argument says something different: the problem of
within specific historical natures. And the relations crisis unfolds through the unifying relations between
of ‘social reproduction’ are at once revealed as central the zone of commodification and the zone of repro-
to a civilization’s power/production relations and duction, which is partly inside but largely outside the
as transcendent of any Nature/Society dualism. (If immediate circuit of capital. The tendency of surplus
someone can show me where the ‘social’ moment of capital to rise, and of the world-ecological surplus to
child-rearing ends, and the ‘natural moment’ begins, fall, are entwined.
please enlighten me.) In medieval Europe, this was We may begin with the basics. Capitalism is a
parcellized sovereignty, the lord–peasant relation, system of endless accumulation. Because accumu-
and land productivity. In historical capitalism, this lated capital flows into the hands of a few (capitalists),
is the interstate system, bourgeois and proletarian, a problem presents itself. Marx called this the ‘general
and labour productivity. These relations we call law of capitalist accumulation’: riches for the few,
social, which they are in an expansive sense: they poverty for the many. At some point, the goods and
are relations of sociality and cooperation within the services produced in the ‘real economy’ cannot be
web of life. And they are relations co-produced with purchased in a rising volume by those in ‘real life’.
and within the web of life – yes, capitalism makes In one sense, this is an overproduction problem: too
environments; yes, the web of life makes capitalism. many factories produce too many cars, or refrig-
Here is our double internality at work. Each moment erators or computers that cannot be purchased in
internalizes the other, but never equally. Limits for sufficient volumes to maintain the rate of profit. In
one civilization take shape out of the very innova- another sense, it is an overaccumulation problem: the
tions – and evolving eco-geographical conditions rate of profit in existing investment lines begins to
– that allowed for its initial expansion. Capitalism, fall, and new, more profitable investment opportuni-
born of the prodigious and violent effort to produce ties have not emerged.
Cheap Nature through global expansion, now finds So far, so good. What has happened – in both
itself limited by the same Cheap Nature strategies radical and mainstream economic thinking – is a
that allowed it to thrive for the past five centuries. curious conflation of overaccumulation and overpro-
How do we go about sustaining a global conversa- duction. Why this should be so is no mystery. The
tion that would synthesize – theoretically, but one formation of Marxist and neoclassical thought across
hopes also politically – a unified theory of capitalist the long twentieth century occurred during the long
crisis in the web of life? The question finds some fossil-fuel boom. That boom made possible a series
traction – but also opposition – among a growing of innovations and transformations that propelled
layer of the world’s Left, supported by a broad con- rising labour productivity, new agricultural and
sensus around ‘converging’ crises.5 The ‘ecological’ resource frontiers, and the radical extension of value
and the ‘economic’ are, we are told, converging. But relations worldwide, setting hundreds of millions of
such a view presupposes that these moments were peasants ‘free’ to work for wages. It seemed to abolish
once separated. Hence the underlying uncertainty the spectre of crisis haunting early capitalism: under-
at the core of the consensus: the ongoing, cascading production. Thus overproduction was the necessary
and impending tipping points of capitalism and the and immediate problem that needed to be explained.
biosphere interact with each other – somehow. And it became very easy to conflate overproduction
But how? That’s a question with surprisingly few with overaccumulation.
answers. What would such a synthesis look like? It was especially easy to conflate the two if one
Let me outline the beginning of a more fruitful assumed that capitalism begins around 1800. This is
approach. what I call the ‘Two Century Model’. As I’ve explored
elsewhere, this view has obscured the revolution-
Crisis ary shift in environment-making that occurred after
Everyone knows why capitalism runs itself into crisis, 1450.6 Early capitalism was indeed real capitalism in
right? Too many commodities chasing too few cus- every major respect: labour productivity increased,
tomers. Economists call this the problem of ‘effective commodification widened and deepened with no
demand’. For Marxists, the emphasis lies squarely systemic reversals, proletarianization accelerated
within production and investment: overproduction sharply, capital moved into production, from farming
and overaccumulation. For both, the problem of crisis to heavy industry, and a new scale, scope and speed

11
of environment-making altered regional ecologies capital. Circulating capital is the forgotten moment in
across the planet. Marx’s model – a casualty of dualist habits of thought
Early capitalism’s dominant crisis tendency was and a legacy of the fossil boom’s intellectual foot-
not overproduction, but underproduction – the insuf- print. It consists of energy and raw materials used up
ficient flow of labour, food, energy and materials during a production cycle. The dynamism of capital-
relative to the demands of value production. Early ist production, observes Marx, leads the ‘portion of
capitalism’s greatest problem centred on the delivery constant capital that consists of fixed capital … [to]
of cheap inputs to the factory gates, not on selling run significantly ahead of the portion consisting of
the commodities that issued from manufacturing organic raw materials, so that the demand for these
centres. To be clear, we are dealing with configura- raw materials grows more rapidly than their supply.’
tional weight: underproduction and overproduction Marx goes still further. Not only does fixed capital in
always operate simultaneously. The Dutch Repub- industrial production tend to ‘run ahead’ of raw mate-
lic was the seventeenth century’s ‘model capitalist rials sectors; the condition for large-scale industrial
nation’ (Marx) because it organized and led a world- production is Cheap Nature – ‘it was only the large
ecological regime that delivered cheap grain (from fall in the price of cotton which enabled the cotton
Poland), cheap energy (from domestic peat) and cheap industry to develop in the way that it did.’8 In sum:
timber (from Norway and the Baltic) to the northern the ‘overproduction’ of machinery (fixed capital) finds
Netherlands. When this regime faltered, definitively its dialectical antagonism in the ‘underproduction’ of
by the 1760s, the British married technical ingenuity raw materials (circulating capital). This law, like the
with geological good fortune to move from increas- tendency of the rate of profit to fall, is a dialectic of
ingly expensive wood fuel to increasingly cheap coal. tendencies and counter-tendencies, in which the latter
This marriage solved – but did not abolish – the are endogenous. This endogeneity of nature – through
problem of underproduction, setting the stage for the double internality – sets Marx’s perspective as a
two centuries of remarkable expansion. clear contrast to the Malthusian programme.
The issue is therefore not overproduction or
Marx’s general law of underproduction underproduction. It is how the two fit together in
Marx did not like to write about scarcity. Malthus successive eras of accumulation. Underproduction
ruined the question for him. But it’s not true that is of course much more than the overproduction
Marx avoided the problem. Arguably, Marx’s general of machinery and the underproduction of inputs.
model of accumulation crisis is grounded in capital’s The model is too simple. We cannot, however, get
co-production of value. The organic composition of to the complexities without it. The overproduc-
capital, writes Perelman with some exaggeration, tion of machinery and the underproduction of raw
was ‘a code for scarcity… In the back of Marx’s mind, materials is where long cycles of accumulation end
[capitalism’s co-production of] scarcity was [partly] up: rising raw materials prices and overcapacity. If
responsible for the falling rate of profit.’7 there is nothing particularly revolutionary in the
Scarcity probably isn’t the best word for what we observation, it points us in two promising directions.
have seen in the history of capitalism. I’m with Marx The first is how the ‘normal’ accumulation of capital
on this – there is a better conceptual language we can drives the rising costs of production through the
use. Marx’s choice was ‘underproduction’. And among progressive exhaustion of the natures within both
Marx’s many ‘general laws’ the least appreciated is the the circuit of capital (exploitation) and in the orbit of
general law of underproduction. In this, Marx identi- capitalist power (appropriation). The second is how
fies the circuit of capital as a socio-ecological relation, underproduction fetters – or threatens to fetter –
albeit one whose substance (value) is necessarily blind accumulation, and how it has been resolved through
to ‘natural distinctness’. In this model, ‘the rate of great waves of geographical restructuring. Thus, eras
profit is inversely proportional to the value of the raw that mark the demise of one long wave of accumula-
materials’: the cheaper the raw materials and energy, tion and the rise of another tend to be accompanied
the higher the rate of profit. Why? Because ‘constant’ by ‘new’ imperialisms and ‘new’ scientific revolutions.
capital comprises two moments. One is fixed capital, In these periods, capitalist and territorialist agencies
comprising machinery, but also other extra-human seek to find, secure and appropriate Cheap Natures
forces of production, including animals, that outlast that can resolve the problems of the old order.
the production cycle. The other is circulating capital, How do we go about unifying overproduction and
not to be confused with the circulation (and circuit) of underproduction in our model of accumulation?

12
The tendency of the ecological surplus to fall invested – pioneered by ecological economists. Its
This is a vexing question. Capital engages the world decline is suggested by the declining energy efficiency
as something to be reduced to an interchangeable of industrial agriculture, a long-time staple of Green
part. These reductions are at once symbolic and critique. This orients us to the centrality of unpaid
material. They comprise market-, class- and state-led work/energy in the rise and demise of successive
simplifications. Crucially, the tendential generaliza- accumulation cycles. EROI becomes useful in analys-
tion of value relations works through a dialectic of ing capitalism’s crisis, however, only when we move
capitalizing production and appropriating reproduc- towards EROCI: energy returned on capital invested.
tion. Value is encoded simultaneously through the EROCI’s decline is suggested by mounting evidence
exploitation of labour-power in commodity produc- of rising production costs and slowing labour pro-
tion, and through the appropriation of nature’s life- ductivity growth over the past two decades – in
making capacities. Accumulation by appropriation agriculture, extraction and industry. That decline
involves those extra-economic processes – perhaps suggests a powerful question: has capitalism entered
directly coercive, but also cultural and calculative – a new era of secular decline in the ecological surplus,
through which capital gains access to minimally or and therefore in its capacity to achieve a significant
non-commodified natures for free, or as close to free advance in system-wide labour productivity?
as it can get. If appropriation is partly about primi- Historically, ‘great depressions’ have been
tive accumulation, it is equally about the cultural resolved through world-ecological revolutions that
hegemonies and scientific-technical repertoires that create opportunities for windfall profits. These
allow for unpaid work/energy to be mobilized, on a new opportunities depend upon the restoration of
sustained but not sustainable basis, for capital accu- the Four Cheaps – labour-power, food, energy and
mulation. Such accumulation proceeds vigorously raw materials. These Cheaps form the core of the
when unpaid work/energy is appropriated in service world-ecological surplus. It is a ‘surplus’ relative to
to commodity production, and opens new opportu- the average costs of production in capitalism, which
nities for capital investment. This occurs through take many forms but are ultimately rooted in the
geographical expansion, and is most effective when productivity of labour. Such productivity is, however,
empires and states do the hard work of imposing decisively linked to the production of new historical
order – cultural, scientific, juridical and the rest – on natures and their chief historical forms: successive
new spaces. Such geographical expansion, in other waves of enclosure, imperial expansion, scientific
words, must involve capitalist power and rational- practice and dispossessionary movements. These
ity in rather heavier doses than capitalization itself. combine with technical change to appropriate unpaid
Appropriation works through projects to control, work/energy faster than the tendentially rising capi-
rationalize and channel potentially unruly human talization of global nature.
and extra-human sources of unpaid work/energy, When the ecological surplus is very high, as it
without immediately capitalizing these sources. was after World War II, productivity revolutions
Capitalization can and does occur. But it must be occur and long expansions commence. Naturally,
kept in check. If accumulation is to revive, capitaliza- this is not merely a story of appropriation, but also
tion must serve the ‘greater good’ of appropriation. of capitalization and socio-technical innovation.
When capitalists can set in motion small amounts The ecological surplus emerges as new accumula-
of capital and appropriate large volumes of unpaid tion regimes combine plunder and productivity,
work/energy, the costs of production fall and the joining the enclosure of new geographical fron-
rate of profit rises. In these situations, there is a tiers (including subterranean resources) and new
high world-ecological surplus (or simply ‘ecologi- scientific-technological revolutions in labour produc-
cal surplus’). This ecological surplus is the ratio of tivity. Great advances in labour productivity, express-
the system-wide mass of capital to the system-wide ing the rising material throughput of an average
appropriation of unpaid work/energy. In this, the hour of work, have been possible through these great
‘mass of capital’ involves not only fixed capital but expansions of the ecological surplus. The assembly
also relations of human and extra-human reproduc- line of classic Fordism, for instance, was unthinkable
tion that are increasingly capitalized: labour-power, without cheap steel, rubber and oil. It is impossible
tree plantations, factory farms, and so forth. to overstate the irreducibly socio-ecological charac-
The ecological surplus is suggested, albeit too nar- ter of this surplus, which comprises not only food,
rowly, by the EROI ratio – energy returned on energy energy and raw materials, but also human nature as

13
labour-power and domestic labour. The origins of the of accumulated capital tends to rise faster than the
long twentieth century were found not only in the appropriation of unpaid work/energy – a necessary
mass production systems of the ‘second industrial implication of Marx’s general law of underproduc-
revolution’, but also in multiple appropriations of tion. (Capital’s bets on the future grow faster than
human and extra-human natures: of the soil and the practical activity of locating new Cheap Natures.)
water resources of the American Midwest; of eastern Even in the exceptional circumstances of the ‘second’
European and South Asian peasantries; of the forests, industrial revolution and the post-World War II golden
fields and resource veins of the colonial and semi- age – when the appropriation of unpaid work/energy
colonial worlds. was at an all-time high – the cheapening of food, raw
The ecological surplus declines over the course of materials and energy required extraordinary effort
every long wave of accumulation. It falls for four big and was sometimes reversed. The cyclical movement
reasons. First, there is wear and tear on the oikeios towards rising costs, like the entropy problem, can
– on the specific historical natures in play. This is be reversed, but the space for such reversals narrows
an entropy problem: matter/energy move from more over capitalism’s longue durée. In this light, Marx’s
useful to less useful forms within the prevailing general law of underproduction may be formulated as
configuration of the oikeios. The ‘law of entropy’ a tendency for the rate of accumulation to decline as
– whereby ‘all economic process[es] … transform the mass of capitalized nature rises. It finds historical
valuable matter and energy into waste’9 – operates expression in recurrent waves of financialization, the
within specific patterns of power and production. It chief expression of the overaccumulated capital that
is not determined by the biosphere in the abstract. piles up as opportunities for appropriation decline.
From the standpoint of historical nature, entropy is Third, the ecological surplus declines through
reversible and cyclical – but subject to rising entropy the contradiction between the reproduction time
within specific civilizational logics. Capitalism’s logic of capital and the reproduction times of the rest of
of appropriating work/energy therefore allows recur- nature. Capital’s dystopian drive towards temporal
rent fixes to rising entropy by locating uncapitalized instantaneity manifests itself by finding ‘short cuts’ to
natures on the frontier. compress the reproduction times of manifold natures.
Second, even if there was no wear and tear, the Not all human-initiated compressions are violent; but
ecological surplus would tend to decline. The mass nearly all of capitalism’s are. Capitalist agriculture,

14
with its monocultures and labour productivity fetish, the non-capitalist to the capitalist world. And they
is a prime example. The capitalization of nature pro- are about more than the relation of bourgeois and
ceeds because this confers a competitive advantage proletarian. Primitive accumulation is equally about the
over the short run. Capitalizing nature yields short- restructuring of the relations of reproduction – human
run gains for particular capitalists, but middle-run and extra-human alike – so as to allow the renewed and
costs. These costs are externalized wherever possible, expanded flow of cheap labour, food, energy and raw
but ultimately new sources of work/energy must be materials into the commodity system.
found, and appropriated. Thus every long accumula-
tion cycle unfolds through new commodity frontiers. The dialectic of capitalization and
Finally, the share of unpaid work/energy tends to appropriation
fall relative to the mass of capital not only because of Let us now consider capitalization and appropriation
entropy, capitalization and temporal disproportion- not merely as accumulation strategies but as relations
ality, but also because the accumulation of capital of reproduction. From there we may consider the
becomes more wasteful over time. This dimension relations between the two. First, the capitalization
is cyclical, but the least cyclically problematic. (Until of relations of reproduction has occurred most con-
now.) It is arguably the most cumulatively significant. spicuously through the proletarianization of human
One form is the colossal energy inefficiency of indus- labour. ‘Proletarianization’ is another way of saying
trial agriculture. Another, epoch-making dimension that the reproduction of labour-power flows through
of waste production concerns the ways that massive capital, largely in the form of paid work. Of course,
energy and chemical use is now toxifying the bio- even proletarian households in the global North
sphere, and activating negative-value: the emergence continue to rely upon significant expenditures of
of historical natures that are increasingly hostile to unpaid work (laundry, cooking, raising children, etc.).
capital accumulation, and that can be temporarily Humans transform the rest of nature only through
fixed (if at all) only through increasingly costly and work, and the commodification of work – directly
toxic strategies. The rise of negative-value – expressed and indirectly – is therefore pivotal to the capitaliza-
starkly in contemporary climate change – suggests a tion of extra-human natures.
significant and rapid erosion of the ecological surplus But it is not just the reproduction of labour-power
in the early twenty-first century. that has become capitalized; it is also the reproduc-
This means that capital, over time, must pay a tion of extra-human natures. Flows of nutrients, flows
greater share of its costs of doing business. In formal of humans, and flows of capital make a historical
terms, every great wave of accumulation begins with totality, in which each flow implies the other. Modern
a high ecological surplus, which is created through agriculture, from its genesis in the sugar plantations
combinations of capital, science and power.10 We may of the long sixteenth century, reveals cash-crop agro-
associate these moments with abstract social labour, ecologies as a process of appropriating nutrients,
abstract social nature, and primitive accumulation. energy and water through global capital flows, credit
This triple helix of accumulation works by developing especially. The extraordinary shift that occurred in
new ways of advancing labour productivity, alongside the twentieth century – through successive hybridi-
the securing of new and greatly expanded sources of zation, chemical and biotechnological ‘revolutions’
unpaid work in service to accumulation. This is the – has been the rising capitalization of nature. But it
dialectical counterpoint to the traditional render- has been non-linear, and consequently obscured until
ing of Marx’s so-called primitive accumulation as recently, because of the radical cheapening of energy.
a process of class formation (bourgeois and prole- Nitrogen-fixation was of course central, but so were
tarian). Class formation is one result of primitive mechanization, pesticides and electrification. The
accumulation. This result depends upon, and is co- liberation of capitalist agriculture from its depend-
produced through, the appropriation of unpaid work ence on local energy sources significantly reduced
by ‘women, nature and colonies’. But the processes capitalization for a quarter-century after World War
of identifying, mapping and rationalizing those new II – and modestly after the 1970s. Recently, however,
sources of unpaid work/energy cannot be explained this process has boomeranged, significantly advancing
by economic forces alone; they depend upon state and capitalization over the past decade. At some point,
science to make them work. Thus, primitive accumu- every agricultural revolution faces a ‘blowback’: from
lation and the geographical expansion of capitalism human-centred revolts to extra-human resistance
are about more than the transfer of wealth from (e.g. ‘superweeds’). The dynamic is captured, albeit

15
partially, in discussions of capitalist agriculture’s boundary, but rather of capitalism as an internal-
‘technological treadmill’, as farmers are locked into izing civilization. We are speaking of internal as
a regime of rising costs through dependence on com- methodological premiss, not descriptive statement.
modified seeds, machines and poisons. But the ‘tread- Ecological economists often speak of how capitalism
mill’ expands beyond the forces of production. It is a ‘externalizes’ costs. The conversion of the atmosphere
treadmill of capital, tools and nature – the technics to a dumping ground for greenhouse gases is a prime
of agro-industrial capitalism. The farm family must example. Such externalization of costs is also the
strive to produce more and yet more to satisfy the internalization of spaces necessary for capital accu-
debt obligations of an agro-ecological model whose mulation. The atmosphere, for instance, must be
reproduction flows primarily through the circuit of put to work as capital’s unpaid garbage man. These
capital. The capitalization of agriculture today – in spaces may or may not be directly within the circuit
contrast to a century ago – is now exceeding cash- of capital. Such spaces may be oilfields (internal to
crop agriculture’s appropriation of unpaid work/ capital) or they may be frontier zones, where waste is
energy, a reality indicated by industrial agriculture’s dumped, or unpaid work appropriated. While waste
three decades of declining productivity growth. The frontiers are now partially recognized, the internal-
ecological surplus is contracting. izing character of capitalist civilization goes still
Capitalization transcends the ‘Cartesian’ binary. further, precisely because the accumulation of capital
So too does the appropriation of unpaid work/energy. depends upon the active incorporation of ‘physically
This dialectic allows us to see beyond the reduction- uncorrupted’ sources of work/energy.11
ist language of Society and Nature. For in capital- This inverts the usual thinking about capitalist
ism, the crucial divide is not between Society and development. Capitalism expands not to expand the
Nature – it is between capitalization and the web domain of commodification as such; it expands to
of life. Capitalism’s arrogance is to assign value to shift the balance of world accumulation towards
life-activity within the commodity system (and an appropriation. Thus capitalism’s geographical expan-
alienating value at that) while devaluing, and simul- sions only sometimes – and only partially – privilege
taneously drawing its lifeblood from, uncommodified commodification. Most often, the priority is the
life-activity within reach of capitalist power. projection of capitalist power into uncapitalized
These movements of capitalization and appropria- domains of reproduction: of uncommodified human
tion mutually determine socially necessary labour- and extra-human natures. These latter have been
time. The first movement occurs within Marx’s continually invaded, penetrated and subsumed by
‘organic whole’ of commodity production, comprising capital, but always only ever partially – and for a good
distribution, exchange, alongside immediate produc- reason. Great advances in labour productivity – the
tion. The other is the ‘organic whole’ of appropriating British-led Industrial Revolution and American-led
unpaid work in service to advancing labour produc- Fordism in the long nineteenth and twentieth cen-
tivity. In other words, the rate of exploitation under turies – have been strongly conditioned on gigantic
the law of value is determined not only by the class appropriations of unpaid work, performed by human
struggle within commodity production (between natures (domestic labour) and extra-human natures
capitalist and the direct producers), and not only by (geological accumulations) alike. Such industri-
the organization and value composition of commod- alizations depend on a configuration of rising labour
ity production. It is also determined by the contribution productivity (rate of exploitation) in commodity pro-
of unpaid work – work reproduced largely outside the duction, alongside a disproportionately greater appro-
circuit of capital – performed by human and extra- priation of unpaid work. The implication is crucial
human natures alike. and merits emphasis: the relation between exploita-
The appropriation of unpaid work – manifested tion and appropriation is asymmetrical. Rising labour
in the cyclical rise and decline of the Four Cheaps productivity in commodity production implies an
– is consequently central to conceptualizing and even greater augmentation of the volume of energy
investigating capitalism’s limits. This is because the and raw materials (circulating capital) for every unit
real historical limits of capitalism derive from capital of labour-time. Accumulated unpaid work/energy is
as a relation of capitalization and appropriation. especially important. The British- and American-led
The ‘limits to growth’ are not external, but derive industrial revolutions, for example, unfolded through
from relations internal to capitalism. Why internal? epoch-making appropriations of the accumulated
Clearly, we are not speaking of ‘internal’ as a fixed work/energy of fossil fuel formation (coal, then oil)

16
and the accumulated work/energy of humans raised project is directly bio-material. Maize is a paradigm
to adulthood outside the commodity system (dispos- case, leading the way for all manner of ‘flex crops’.
sessed peasants). It provides the raw materials for, seemingly, just
This highlights the historical unity of the repro- about everything: ethanol, food and raw materials
duction of human and extra-human natures. From in construction and industrial production. Another
this perspective, work encompasses much more moment is the generalization of energy-intensive
than direct participation in commodity production. nitrogen fertilizers in world agriculture, compelling
Rather, work encompasses the totality of waged and a growing share of humanity to ‘eat’ fossil fuels. And
unwaged activity performed by humans and the rest let us not forget that capitalism is premissed on the
of nature within reach of capitalist power. The unpaid dissolution of human specificity – craft knowledge
‘work of nature’ – over the short run of agriculture, and the like – that is embodied in the incessant drive
the inter-generational time of child-rearing, the geo- to replace ‘living’ with ‘dead’ labour.
logical time of fossil-fuel creation – is the pedestal The movement towards the increasing fungibil-
upon which the paid ‘work of capital’ unfolds. Both ity of extra-human nature is also calculative. The
moments are inscribed in the law of value. While the financialization of commodities since the turn of
value form (the commodity) emerges in the immediate the millennium is another key moment in this dis-
process of production, the value relation – including solution of the boundaries between the Big Four
the systemic determination of socially necessary labour- inputs. Perhaps most spectacular is the recent history
time – encompasses not only production relations, but of global primary commodity markets. Before the
also the broader relations of appropriation necessary twenty-first century, these were largely independent
to the expanded production of surplus value. The rate ‘from outside financial markets and from each other’
of exploitation is fundamentally conditioned by the – for example, the price of oil was not necessar-
scale, speed and scope of appropriation of nature’s ily correlated with the price of copper. After 2000,
work/energy, provided ‘free of charge’, or as close to however, financial actors, index investors especially,
free as possible. ‘precipitated a fundamental process of financializa-
As the Four Cheaps materialize, new opportuni- tion among commodities markets, through which
ties for capital accumulation appear: for instance, commodity prices became more correlated with
the railroad revolution of the nineteenth century or prices of financial assets and with each other. … As
the automobile revolution of the twentieth century. a result of [this] financialization … the price of an
Over time, the Four Cheaps cease being Cheap. individual commodity is no longer simply determined
The squeezing out of unpaid work/energy in the by its supply and demand.’12 This combination of
upswing of an accumulation cycle exhausts the resil- bio-material and financial restructuring suggests a
ience of uncommodified relations of reproduction. twenty-first-century scenario in which the tendency
Meanwhile, workers and peasants find new ways to towards underproduction reasserts itself, through an
contest capital and the world market. Labour and unusual and unstable combination of physical deple-
input costs rise, and the rate of profit in established tion, climate change, new anti-systemic movements
lines of production falters. This is when financial and financialization.
expansions – a recurrent feature of capitalism from Underproduction signifies a conjoncture – the
the sixteenth century – commence. As leading states downslope of a bell-shaped curve – in which one
feel the pinch, they set to work restructuring their or more of the Big Four inputs becomes increas-
relations of power and re/production within histori- ingly costly, and begins to fetter the accumulation
cal nature. Thus do financial expansions inaugurate process. In this, underproduction is an immanent
new eras of primitive accumulation, as capitalists and contradiction of overproduction. This means that
states pursue the restoration of Cheap Nature. underproduction is not about ‘scarcities’ that reside
Haunting capital’s productive dynamism is the in an external nature – a neo-Malthusian view.
spectre of underproduction. There is, consequently, Rather, underproduction takes shape through the
a strong impulse to dissolve the boundaries between relations that obtain, cyclically and cumulatively,
the Big Four inputs: to turn food into energy and in historical capitalism and historical nature (our
raw materials, energy into food, and of course double internality). Underproduction is co-produced
energy into labour-power. Here is capital’s project by human and extra-human natures, and historically
to create Nature in its own image, endlessly quan- specific. ‘Scarcity’ for one civilization may not be for
tifiable and interchangeable. One moment of this another. Capitalism’s scarcities are imposed through

17
price – the food price inflation that began in 2003 (EROCI): calories or joules per dollar. EROCI puts
is not a function of inadequate world food supplies, the relative contributions of paid and unpaid work/
but of distribution, power and capital. This allows energy at the centre. The peak in question is not,
us to see the really relational sources of hunger and then, a peak in output – of energy, or some other
other forms of deprivation and oppression. But the primary commodity. It is, rather, the peak ‘gap’
analysis cannot stop there. We need a way to see how between the capital set in motion to produce a given
changes in the biosphere translate into deepening commodity and the work/energy embodied in that
contradictions in capitalism – and vice versa. commodity: dollars per bushel, or ton, or barrel,
or horse, or hour of labour-power. Even here, the
language is imprecise, because we are dealing with
Peak appropriation an incommensurable mix of specific work/energies.
Depletion is real enough. Its most salient contem- Quantification can illuminate but not adequately
porary expression is probably energy. Here, the capture these specifics. Energy and material flows
geographical retreat of easy-to-extract big oilfields can be measured; but within capitalism they cannot
is clearly a contest over the terms of the double be counted – for the secret of capital’s dynamism is
internality. Will capitalism’s internalization of that it counts only what it values (labour produc-
nature produce new geographies that allow for Cheap tivity). Peak appropriation is, moreover, not simply
Energy’s return? Or will nature’s internalization of about particular commodities, but about the ways
capital produce new geographies that make such a that certain primary commodities – coal and oil are
return impossible? We have been distracted from this paradigm examples – ‘diffuse’ Cheap Natures across
double internality by the terms of the ‘peak every- the whole accumulation process. Cheap Food after
thing’ debate. These terms pose a question about the 1930s, for instance, became ‘petro-farming’, its
substances, not relations: have we reached a ‘peak’ prodigious appropriations of soil, water and life
in global output for oil, coal, phosphorous, even soil, increasingly mediated through Cheap Energy.
from which a ‘post-peak’ world of scarcity ensues? For long waves of capital accumulation, peak
What happens if we approach the problem of appropriation occurs when the contribution of appro-
depletion from a world-ecological perspective? Here priated natures ‘peaks’ relative to capitalized natures.
we find more useful a different kind of peak: peak Hence Marx’s insight on soil fertility as ‘fixed capital’.
appropriation. Peak appropriation may be visualized Of course Marx understood fertility as not so natural
as the maximal inflection point of a bell-shaped (fixed) as Ricardo believed; fertility could be increased
curve in which the share of unpaid work/energy through the application of fertilizers as circulating
peaks relative to the capitalization of nature: that capital.13 But where fertility was given, prior to the
‘peak’ represents the world-ecological surplus at its advance of capitalist agriculture, the windfalls of
highest point. Of course the visualization is merely a peak appropriation could be epoch-making. The
thought exercise. Cyclical changes and sectoral shifts American grain frontiers of the nineteenth century
alter the picture in significant ways. Since the early appropriated nutrients accumulated over millennia.
nineteenth century, moreover, the relative ease with When combined with the capital-intensive family
which Cheap Energy could be mapped, extracted and farm, they revolutionized not only American capi-
put to work has smoothed the transition from one talism but also flooded Europe with Cheap Food,
phase of capitalism to another. ‘freeing’ Cheap Labour for American industrializa-
Peak appropriation is one way of building on tion. As with early capitalism’s sugar plantations,
EROI (energy returned on energy invested) analyses. we see the precocious combination of cutting-edge
It allows for the enfolding of resource and energy industrial production and frontier appropriation. The
measures in a historical and relational frame. The potential consequences of rising capital-intensity –
movement towards peak appropriation, as we’ve rising production costs – could be offset through new
noted, sees a rising ecological surplus. Post-peak appropriations and enclosures. The radical accelera-
appropriation is characterized by a falling ecologi- tion of appropriation was expressed in all manner of
cal surplus. But EROI cannot get us to a model of enclosures, colonial and metropolitan, new and old.
accumulation that unifies energy/capital. These allowed capital to advance labour productivity
Appropriation and the cyclical movements of while reducing (or checking) the tendentially rising
the ecological surplus direct our attention not only value composition of production. The technical com-
to EROI but to Energy Returned on Capital Invested position of production – the mass of machinery and

18
raw materials relative to labour-power – could rise sacrificed in service to the productivity of wage-
without undermining the rate of profit. labour. These frontiers of appropriation were the
major way of making others, outside the circuit of
The final frontier capital but within reach of capitalist power, foot
At the core of the capitalist project, from its sixteenth the bill for the endless accumulation of capital. The
century origins, has been the scientific and symbolic great secret and the great accomplishment of capital-
creation of nature in its modern form, as something ist civilization have been to not pay its bills. Frontiers
that could be mapped, abstracted, quantified and made that possible. Their closure is the end of Cheap
otherwise subjected to linear control. This was exter- Nature – and with it the end of capitalism’s free ride.
nal nature; it is what we have come to call Nature,
even if many of us no longer believe in a Nature
that is independent of the Anthropos. (And is not Notes
the Anthropos as violent an abstraction as Nature?) 1. Key texts in the world-ecology conversation include Jason
W. Moore, Capitalism in the Web of Life, Verso, London,
It is easy to talk about the ‘limits to growth’ as if 2015; Tony Weis, The Ecological Hoofprint, Zed Books,
they were imposed by this (external) Nature. But the London, 2013; Christian Parenti, ‘The Environment Making
State’, Antipode, 2014 (early view version); Sharae Deckard,
reality is thornier, more complex – and also more ‘Mapping the World-Ecology’, Ecologies Technics & Civiliza-
hopeful. The limits of capitalist civilization include tions, forthcoming; Michael Niblett, ‘World-Economy,
biophysical realities, but are not reducible to them. World-Ecology, World Literature,’ Green Letters, vol. 16,
no. 1, 2012, pp. 15–30; Benjamin Marley, ‘The Coal Crisis in
And if the limits of capitalism today are limits of Appalachia,’ Journal of Agrarian Change, 2015 (early view
a particular way of organizing nature, we are con- version); Roberto José Ortiz, ‘Latin American Agro-Indus-
trialization, Petrodollar Recycling, and the Transformation
fronted with the possibility of changing humanity’s of World Capitalism in the Long 1970s’, Critical Sociology ,
relation to nature – which is to say also humanity’s 2014 (online first).
relation to itself. We are frequently warned of the 2. Quotations, respectively, from Karl Marx, Critique of Hegel’s
‘Philosophy of Right’, trans. Annette Jolin and Joseph
alleged dangers of civilizational ‘collapse’. But is the O’Malley, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1970,
‘collapse’ of capitalism – a civilization that plunges p. 137; H. Maturana and F. Varela, The Tree of Knowledge,
Shambhala Press, Berkeley CA, 1987, p. 25.
a third of its population into malnutrition – really 3. Rodolfo Dirzo et al. ‘Defaunation in the Anthropo-
something to be feared? Historical experience sug- cene’, Science 345, 2014, pp. 401–6. See also Weis,
gests not. The Fall of Rome after the fifth century, Ecological Hoofprint; ‘Ghosts and Things: Animal Life in the
Capitalocene’, paper presented to the conference ‘World
and the collapse of feudal power in Western Europe Society, Planetary Natures’, Binghamton University 8–10
in the fourteenth century, ushered in golden ages in July 2015.
4. Ted Benton, ‘Marxism and Natural Limits’, New Left Review
living standards for the vast majority.14 We should be I/178, 1989, pp. 51–86.
wary of making too much of such parallels. Neither 5. See, for example, S. George, ‘Converging Crises’, Globaliza-
should we ignore them. tions, vol. 7, nos 1–2, 2010, pp. 17–22; J.B. Foster, ‘The
Epochal Crisis’, Monthly Review, vol. 65, no. 5, 2013, pp. 1–12.
I have long thought that the most pessimistic 6. See especially Jason W. Moore, ‘The Capitalocene, Part I’,
view is one that hopes for the survival of moder- Journal of Peasant Studies, forthcoming.
7. M. Perelman, ‘Marx and Resource Scarcity’, in Ted Benton,
nity in something like its present form. But this is ed., The Greening of Marxism, Guilford Press, New York,
impossible, because capitalism’s metabolism is inher- 2006, p. 73.
ently an open-flow system that continually exhausts 8. Karl Marx, Capital, Volume III, trans. Ernest Untermann,
International Publishers, New York, 1967, pp. 111–19;
its sources of nourishment. There are limits to how Grundrisse, trans. Martin Nicolaus, Vintage, New York,
much new work capitalism can squeeze out of new 1973, p. 141; Theories of Surplus Value, Volume III, Progress
Publishers, Moscow, 1971, p. 368.
working classes, forests, aquifers, oilfields, coal 9. N. Georgescu-Roegen, ‘Energy and Economic Myths’,
seams and everything else. Nature is finite. Capital Southern Economic Journal, vol. 41, no. 3, 1975, pp. 347–81.
is premissed on the infinite. And both are historical 10. These three categories – ‘science’ most of all – are
tremendously blunt instruments.
in a very specific sense: what worked at one histori- 11. Marx, Capital, Volume I, p. 380.
cal juncture will not necessarily work at the next. 12. K. Tang and W. Xiong, ‘Index Investment and Financializa-
tion of Commodities’, working paper, Department of
Thus the centrality of frontiers in the history of Economics, Princeton University, Princeton NJ, March 2011
capitalism, and the significance of the end of the (emphasis added); www.princeton.edu/~wxiong/papers/
last frontiers – cheap oil in the Middle East, cheap commodity.pdf; accessed 17 March 2011.
13. Marx, Grundrisse, p. 748; and Karl Marx, The Poverty of
labour-power in China, cheap food everywhere – in Philosophy, International Publishers, New York, 1963, pp.
the present conjuncture. It was capitalism as frontier 162–3.
14. C. Wickham, Framing the Middle Ages, Oxford University
that inaugurated a civilizational metabolism in Press, Oxford, 2005; Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern
which most nature, including most humans, was World-System I, Academic Press, New York, 1974.

19

You might also like