Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 12

Academy o/Monaffemeni Review, 1988, Vol. 13, No. 3, 390-400.

A Contingency View of
Porter's "Generic Strategies"
ALAN I. MURRAY
University of Alberta
According to Porter, cost leadership and product differentiation can
be pursued simultaneously only under rare conditions: It is also
unclear how these strategies can be implemented. In this article
Porter's generic strategies are linked to external preconditions. This
approach shows that the generic strategies are not mutually exclu-
sive and that each strategy may be linked to a variety of strategic
means. The implications that these results have for structuring organi-
zations are discussed.

In 1980 (Hall, 1980; Porter, 1980), the notion of compatibility of generic strategies to be resolved
generic strategy swept through the business pol- and facilitates a discussion of the link between
icy area. It was very appealing because it generic strategies and the strategic means (Dess
seemed to offer a solid theoretical framework for & Davis, 1982, 1984) used to implement them.
a discipline that often lacked theoretical founda-
tions. As Hambrick (1983a, p. 688) commented,
A Contingency View of
"Porter's typology of generic strategies seems es- Generic Strategies
pecially useful, because (1) it builds on previous Contingency approaches to strategy are not
findings and (2) it is appropriately broad, but not new (e.g., Hofer, 1975); in fact, a contingency
vague." White (1986, p. 220) noted that Porter's perspective is implicit in the adaptive view of
generic approach to business strategy incorpo- strategy that currently dominates the literature
rated "a few critical dimensions yet has strong (Miles & Snow, 1978). Its clearest manifestation
theoretical underpinnings." in the strategy area is the structure-strategy-
As it stands. Porter's generic strategy concept performance paradigm that was introduced by
does not satisfy this desire for a solid theoretical institutional economists (e.g.. Bain, 1956; Caves,
framework. In order to be useful, theory should 1980; Porter, 1981; Rumelt, 1974). Applying a con-
guide empirical research. Yet, the empirical in- tingency approach to the generic strategy litera-
vestigations spawned by the generic strategy ture also is not new.
concept (Dess & Davis, 1982, 1984; Hambrick, Especially in his discussion of fragmented
1983a, 1983b; Miller & Friesen, 1986a, 1986b; industries, and what to do about them. Porter
PhilUps, Chang, & Buzzell, 1983; White, 1986) are (1980) hinted that the efficacy of generic strate-
not comparable, and their results are contra- gies may be contingent on industry structure. In
dictory. Here it is argued that the generic strat- his 1985 treatment, this link became explicit:
egy concept can be clarified by linking each strat- "Cost advantage and differentiation in turn stem
egy to a set of environmental preconditions. De- from industry structure" (Porter, 1985, p. 11).
veloping these preconditions also allows the key However, Porter stopped short of explaining this
question (e.g.. Miller & Friesen, 1986b) of the link.

390
Day (1984) also tied the efficacy of generic product differentiation or cost leadership. Thus,
strategies to environmental factors, specifically according to Porter, a firm could take either a
to customer perceptions of product offerings. focused or broad approach to either product dif-
Hambrick (1983a, p. 702) too concluded that a con- ferentiation or cost leadership. Yet even today
tingency view of generic strategies may be many researchers confuse a focused strategy
appropriate: "It is simply not accurate to say that with a product differentiation strategy.
all generic strategies are equally viable within The problem is one of levels of analysis.
an industry . . . any broadly 'generic' strategy is Whether pursuing cost leadership or product
really a composite of numerous variations, not differentiation, the strategist using a focused ap-
all of which are equally suited to a given situa- proach must first differentiate the product offer-
tion." Phillips, Chang, and Buzzell (1983, p. 42) ing from offerings aimed at other segments of
concluded from their study that: "While our the same market, hence the confusion between
analysis has produced generalizable results a focused strategy and product differentiation.
showing that certain types of generic strategies Southland's 7-11 stores, for example, exemplify
do lead to success, the exact manner in which product differentiation based on convenience,
these strategies are translated into success var- but this is only when they are compared with
ies dramatically by type of business." food retailers targeting other market segments
Finally, Miller and Friesen (1986a, p. 39) also (e.g., supermarkets). When they are compared
advocated a contingency view: "Although some with other firms competing in their own niche
industrial product and capital goods industries (i.e., other convenience stores), it becomes clear
may exhibit relatively pure types, we do not feel that 7-11 stores strive for cost leadership.
convinced that this would be true for consumer Given that both cost leadership and product
durables industries." In addition. Miller and differentiation have broad and focused variants,
Friesen advanced reasons for their expectation the obvious question is: Which variant should a
that different strategic configurations would firm choose? A conjoint analysis fram.ework
emerge in different industries, yet they too (Green & Srinivasan, 1978; Shocker & Srinivasan,
stopped short of presenting a theoretical frame- 1974, 1979; Srinivasan & Shocker, 1973) can help
work to explain the predicted differences. to answer this question. This approach repre-
This article attempts to provide the theoreti- sents a product as a "point" in "attribute space"
cally based contingent approach to Porter's ge- in which each dimension is a product attribute
neric strategies that the authors cited above (including price) valued by customers. By using
advocated. Beginning with the focus strategy, Linmap (Srinivasan & Shocker, 1973) and sim-
it is hypothesized that the viability of each ge- ilar statistical techniques, firms can deduce sur-
neric strategy is dependent on the presence of veyed customers' attributed weights that repre-
certain external conditions, specifically on indus- sent the importance of each attribute to each
try structures or customer characteristics and customer. But, conjoint analysis permits not only
preferences. the derivation of attribute's weights for individual
customers but also the derivation of individual
Focused Versus Broad Strategies customer's "ideal points." An ideal point is that
Of Porter's three original generic strategies combination of product attributes (including price
(product differentiation, cost leadership, and and the trade-offs thus implied) which the cus-
focus) the focus strategy seems to have caused tomer prefers to all other points in the attribute
the greatest confusion (e.g., Dess & Davis, 1982, space. Because the attribute space is common
1984). Porter (1985) attempted to resolve this con- for all customers, it is possible to collapse numer-
fusion by positing that the choice of a focused or ous customers' ideal points into a single space.
broad strategy is independent of the choice of This feature is useful because it permits firms to

391
identify if the market can be segmented on the essary condition in order for a focus strategy to
basis of customer needs. be viable, it is not a sufficient condition: Syner-
If all customers' ideal points fall into roughly gies across segments must be absent or nega-
the same region, one product configuration tive before a focus strategy can be adopted.
should suit all customers. But, if ideal points form
Structural Preconditions for Cost Leadership
two or more clusters, the firm may be able to
offer more than one product configuration suc- In a previous attempt to provide a contingency
cessfully. Obviously, if all customers prefer a basis to the generic strategy concept. Day (1984)
roughly similar product offering, a focus strat- linked customer price sensitivity to the viability
egy is not viable. Thus, the viability of the focus of a cost leadership strategy. This approach con-
strategy is tied directly to exogenous factors; in fuses the necessary and sufficient conditions that
this case it is the heterogeneity of customer are needed in order for a cost leadership strat-
preferences. egy to be successful. Price sensitivity is, at best,
However, even if multiple segments are identi- a necessary but not sufficient condition for cost
fied, a focus strategy may not be viable. It may leadership. Greater price sensitivity increases the
be that sufficient economies of scope exist so that advantage a cost leader has over other firms,
a multisegment producer can outcompete a com- but it is not sufficient to justify adopting a cost
petitor that focuses on a single niche. Only if leadership strategy.
synergies between segments are low or nega- For example, in the gasoline retailing industry,
tive will a focus strategy be viable. customers are extremely sensitive to prices, but
In Figure 1 the conditions which determine the optimal scale of operations is low relative to
whether a broad strategy that includes one or the size of the total market. In this situation, in-
several product offerings will be more successful stead of a single cost leader emerging to enjoy
than a focused strategy that includes one or a supra-normal profits, many firms have similar cost
few product offerings are summarized. It can be structures. Yet, in order to maintain sales, these
seen that although market heterogeneity is a nec- firms are forced to slash prices until profits virtu-
ally disappear.
Number oi Product Offerings There are external preconditions for a cost
leadership strategy but customer price sensitiv-
One Several ity is a minor consideration. A cost leadership
strategy is viable only if cost structures vary
across competitors within an industry in ways
Heterogeneous
other than in direct ratio to output. Cost struc-
Homogeneous market with
Broad tures can deviate from a direct ratio due to varia-
market positive synergies
between segments tions in the quality of management across com-
petitors, as a result of economies of scale, or as a
Strategy result of economies independent of scale such
as learning effects, or preferential access to in-
Heterogeneous
Heterogeneous market with puts or distribution channels.
market with negative synergies The first factor, competitors' incompetence,
Focused negative synergies between groups of usually is not a strong foundation for a sustained
between segments segments and cost leadership strategy because it is dependent
positive synergies on factors beyond management control. Each of
within groups
the remaining factors provides a more substan-
tial basis for a cost leadership strategy, but it is
Figure 1. External factors supporting a argued that each is determined by industry
focused strategy. structure.
392
Perhaps economies that are independent of Being first with a new technology, even if this
scale can provide the most durable basis for a is formally protected by patents or copyrights,
cost leadership strategy. These can be grouped only provides the firm with a temporary cost ad-
into three categories: access to raw materials, vantage because imitation is inevitable. In order
access to product or process technology, and ac- to sustain any cost advantage innovation may
cess to distribution channels. But whether or not provide, the firm must buttress the initial advan-
each of these economies can offer a firm founda- tage by capitalizing on learning effects. But,
tion for cost leadership depends on external learning effects also depend on industry char-
factors. acteristics:
In the case of access to raw materials, this Experience curve slopes vary -widely from prod-
foundation depends on the supplier industry's uct to product. . . . In some industries the slope
characteristics. If the supplier industry enjoys may be as steep as 60%; in others it may not
considerable economies of scale and if entry- occur at all. (Ghemawat, 1985, p. 144)
barriers are high, the potential for high transac- Cost declines with experience seem to be most
tion costs (Williamson, 1981) exists, suggesting significant in businesses involving a high labor
that cost advantages may be derived from back- content performing intricate tasks and/or com-
plex assembly operations (aircraft manufacture,
ward integration. Alternatively, if there is high shipbuilding). (Porter, 1980, p. 12)
variability across suppliers in the basic (excluding
transaction costs) cost of raw materials (as is the If an industry is not characterized by a suffi-
case in many extractive industries), cost advan- ciently "steep" learning or experience curve that
tages, again, can be gained if access to materi- will provide a significant cost advantage for those
als can be controlled. Thus, for example, a cor- firms that are "lower" on the curve, a cost leader-
nerstone for success in the oil business tradition- ship strategy based on pursuit of learning effects
ally has been access to crude oil reserves that will collapse. Here again, how viable the cost
have the lowest extraction costs ("Why Things," leadership strategy will be is tied to exogenous
1982). Where upstream industries are character- factors.
ized by low barriers to entry and where econo- Finally, cost advantages independent of scale
mies of scale are few, little opportunity exists to can be gained from preferential access to distri-
generate differential cost structures. bution channels, but this also will depend on
In order for a firm to achieve differential cost industry structure. Forward integration can pro-
structures, independent of economies of scale in vide cost advantages by capturing the best loca-
the production process itself, it must either pro- tions for distribution, leaving the less desirable
duce defensible technological breakthroughs or sites for the competitors.
pursue learning effects, or, preferably, both. Here Economies of scale provide the other major
again, how viable this will prove to be depends durable basis for a cost leadership strategy. Ev-
on the industry or, more specifically, on the ery industry is characterized by unique optimal
industry's maturity. scales of operations, which are determined by
Abernathy and Utterback (1978) argued that product and market characteristics and by pro-
as an industry matures both the rate and charac- duction and marketing technologies.
ter of innovation change. Initially, innovations For example, manufacturing a wide-body air-
come rapidly and tend to be radical in nature. craft demands a greater scale of operations than
Later, they are slower in coming and are more manufacturing a light, recreational aircraft, in
incremental in nature. Thus, predicating a cost part, because a wide-body aircraft is technologi-
leadership strategy on heavy research and de- cally more sophisticated. Fast food restaurants
velopment (R&D) spending may be sensible can achieve a greater scale of operations than
when an industry is new but may not pay off in French restaurants because customers tend to
more mature industries. prefer a standardized product from the former
393
and a distinctive product from the latter. Nuclear tivity and differentiation can be clearly identi-
power generation demands a greater scale of fied if the conjoint analysis framework, described
operations than solar power generation because above, is used. Attribute weights can be stan-
the processes involved in the former occur most dardized so that they sum to one. If this is done,
efficiently at a much larger scale of operations the inverse relationship between price and other
than is the case for the latter. attributes is clear; that is, the weight accorded
If the optimal scale that these exogenous fac- the price attribute is one minus the sum of the
tors dictate is small relative to the size of the weights attached to all other attributes. If those
market, many firms can achieve the same opti- other weights are low, the customer will be ex-
mal cost structure, and as a result, a fragmented, tremely price sensitive and will care little about
highly competitive industry will develop. Any the level of the product on other attributes. This
firm that tries to gain a dominant market share may encourage a cost leadership strategy, but
in such an industry will experience diseconomies only to the extent that it eliminates its generic
of scale and will suffer accordingly (Porter, 1980). alternative, the product differentiation strategy.
However, as the optimal scale of operations If customers do not value products that differ
approaches one-half of the size of the market, along nonprice dimensions, they will not value
only one competitor can enjoy operating at full a differentiated product and will not pay more
capacity at the optimal scale of operations. In for it. Therefore, a product differentiation strat-
order to become the cost leader, a firm must egy is viable only if customers, when making
build operations which approach that optimal purchase decisions, give weight to product attri-
scale. Of course, given that the optimal size rela- butes other than price. Just as they did in the
tive to the market size is high when cost leader- focus strategy, customer characteristics will dic-
ship is viable, any aspiring cost leader must tate the viability of a product differentiation
achieve a dominant market share so that the strategy. But, just as they did in the focus
cost benefits gained from its efficient scale opera- strategy, customer characteristics alone cannot
tions are not nullified by overcapacity. guarantee the success of a product differentia-
A cost leadership strategy based on econo- tion strategy.
mies of scale can only guarantee superior perfor- Customers' attachment of importance to prod-
mance if only one firm can achieve it (Porter, uct attributes other than price is a necessary con-
1985), and this can occur only when the optimal dition for a product differentiation strategy's
scale of operations exceeds one-half of the size viability, but it is not a sufficient condition. In
of the market. But, the optimal scale of opera- order for a product differentiation strategy to be
tions is determined by production, distribution, viable, a firm must be able to build and sustain
and product and market constraints. Similarly, noticeable differences in its product offerings or
although cost leadership also can depend on in brand image, packaging, pre and post sales
economies independent of scale such as experi- service, and financing arrangements. However,
ence or learning effects, preferential access to this can be done only under specific conditions.
raw materials, or distribution channels, these, Innovation can produce a product that is per-
in turn, depend on industry structure. ceived by consumers to be intrinsically superior
Market-Based Preconditions for to competitors'offerings. But, both Abernathy and
Product Differentiation Utterback (1978) and Porter (1985) suggested that
as an industry matures, competitors' product of-
The price sensitivity which Day (1984) linked to ferings tend to converge toward those product
cost leadership is really the inverse of perceived configurations most preferred by customers.
product differentiation, which Strategic Planning Thus, the probability that expenditure on R&D
Associates link to the product differentiation will result in significant product innovations di-
strategy. This relationship between price sensi- minishes over the product/industry life cycle.
394
A differentiation strategy based on an intrinsi- cent more than supermarkets for identical mer-
cally superior product depends on the firm's abil- chandise because it lowers customers' purchase
ity to maintain those intrinsic differences in the "costs'- through more convenient locations,
face of competitor imitation. As the industry- handy parking, smaller stores, shorter checkout
matures, this task becomes increasingly difficult. lines, and longer hours.
Sony Corporation is encountering these prob- Differentiation based on quality, reliability, and
lems because its traditional product differentia- service is more durable because usually it is
tion strategy, based on product innovation, is more difficult to sustain. A single act of imitation
running into trouble as the consumer electronics can eliminate the advantage an innovative prod-
industry matures (Cieply, 1983; Armstrong 1987). uct design provides for a firm, but quality and
Because product innovation probably cannot service can be sustained only by ongoing, day-
ensure sustainable differentiation, other bases in, day-out attention throughout the organiza-
for product differentiation must be found. Two tion.
such bases have received much attention re- Similar to that of the focused and cost leader-
cently (e.g., Peters, 1987): quality and service. ship strategies, the viability of a product differ-
Customers are not as interested in the claimed entiation strategy depends on a number of exog-
performance of a product as they are in its ac- enous factors (see Table 1). First, customers must
tual performance. When a new product life cy- perceive and value differences between product
cle begins, customers have no information about offerings. When a product class is new, the best
the relationship between claimed and actual way to achieve uniqueness may be to have an
performance. This is why emergent industries inherently superior product design. As the mar-
often are plagued by "fly-by-night" operators ket matures, however, the ability to sustain that
who offer substandard products or services uniqueness diminishes, and because customers'
(Porter, 1980). However, as an industry/market product familiarity increases, differentiation
matures, customers become crware of each prod- based on quality, reliability, and service be-
uct offering's performance history, through their comes preferable.
own past experience, word of mouth, consumer
advocate or support groups, or the manufactur- Can Cost Leadership and
ers themselves.
Product Differentiation
If product quality is defined as the ratio of ac-
tual performance to specified performance, then
Be Pursued Simultaneously?
quality variation will have a greater impact on The exogenous, industry/market-level condi-
sales as the industry-/market matures. The de- tions that are necessary for a firm to successfully
gree this impact has will depend on the cost to pursue the focus, cost leadership, and product
the customer of poor performance. If the cost is differentiation strategies are summarized in Ta-
high, as is the case for earth-moving machinery, ble 1. Pointing out these external preconditions
a viable differentiation strategy can be built on could be nothing more than an interesting aca-
product quality and reliability (Porter, 1985). demic exercise if it were not for some of the impli-
The cost that a customer incurs in acquiring a cations of this approach. Table 1 shows that the
product or service does not simply include the exogenous preconditions for a viable cost leader-
purchase price, but it also includes the inconven- ship strategy stem principally from industry's
ience, uncertainty, and potential unpleasantness structural characteristics. The preconditions for
associated with the purchase process. If the ac- product differentiation stem primarily from cus-
tual cost of making a purchase is low relative to tomer tastes. Because these two sets of exoge-
these other costs, a viable strategy exists for dif- nous factors are independent, the possibility of a
ferentiation based on service. For example. firm pursuing cost leadership and product differ-
Southland Corporation is able to charge 15 per- entiation simultaneously is not precluded.
395
Table 1 that customers in any market will, if given the
Summary of Links Between External Factors opportunity, base purchase decisions on attri-
and the Viability of Generic Strategies butes other than price, and because most indus-
tries seem to offer opportunities to exploit
economies of scale or economies independent of
A Focused Strategy will be viable only:
scale at some point in their value chain (Porter,
If customer's needs within the given product class 1985), it would seem that combining both the
are heterogeneous
product differentiation and cost leadership
and If synergies between the value chains associated strategies should be feasible in many industries.
with the product offerings targeted at each indi-
cated market segment are zero or negative. This reasoning contradicts Porter, who argued
that firms can successfully pursue a combina-
A Cost Leadership Strategy will be viable only: tion of generic strategies only if competitors are
If high transaction costs or differentials in the cost "stuck in the middle," if the firm enjoys over-
of producing inputs exist, and these can be whelming economies of scale, or if it holds exclu-
overcome through vertical integration or some sive rights to a major technological innovation
other means of achieving preferential access
(Porter, 1985, pp. 19-20). If these conditions are
and/or If the state of development of the process not met. Porter warned, "a firm that engages
technologies employed m the value chain in each generic strategy but fails to achieve any
indicates that significant innovations can still
be realized of them is 'stuck in the middle.' It possesses no
competitive advantage. This position is usually
and/or If the process technologies employed m the value
chain are sufficiently complex to permit significant a recipe for below average performance"
cost improvements to be realized from learning (Porter, 1985, p. 16). On this point Porter's logic is
effects inconsistent, and it has been contradicted by em-
and/or If the optimal scale for some significant part of the pirical findings.
value chain exceeds one-half of the size of the Elsewhere, Porter noted "a cost leader must
market. achieve parity or proximity in the bases of differ-
entiation relative to its competitors to be an above
A Product Differentiation Strategy will be viable only:
average performer, even though it relies on cost
If customers attach weight to product attributes
other than price when making purchase decisions
leadership for its competitive advantage" (1985,
p. 13). Similarly, he stated: "A differentiator can-
and/or If the state of development of product technologies
not ignore its cost position, because its premium
indicates that significant product innovations can
still be realized prices will be nullified by a markedly inferior
and/or If the process technologies employed in the value
cost position. A differentiator thus aims at cost
chain are sufficiently complex to permit significant parity or proximity relative to its competitors, by
quality or service differentials between reducing cost in all areas that do not affect
competitors' product offerings to be maintained. differentiation" (1985, p. 14). This implies that a
cost leader that competes against a product dif-
ferentiator must also be a product differentiator,
This is an important point. Most of the empiri- and vice versa.
cal studies on generic strategies show that firms Empirical investigations also contradict Porter
that successfully pursue generic strategies out- on this point. For example, Phillips, Chang, and
perform their competitors. Extending the logic, Buzzell (1983) found that product quality (a basis
by combining both generic strategies success- for product differentiation), through a positive as-
fully, a firm should be able to outcompete rivals sociation with relative market share, was nega-
that pursue only one strategy. Further, because tively related to relative direct costs (an indica-
Peters and Austin (1985, pp. 51-70) argued that tion of cost leadership). Providing further evi-
there is "no such thing as a commodity," meaning dence of a link between product differentiation
396
and cost leadership, they also found that rela- may be inevitable because of different value
tive price was positively related to market share. orientations (Beyer, 1981), applying conflict reso-
Extending further the link between one of the lution techniques may minimize the conflict to a
bases of differentiation and one of the bases of point which permits the firm to pursue cost lead-
cost leadership (the learning curve). Fine (1983) ership and product differentiation strategies
found that costs declined more rapidly for firms simultaneously. With this approach, the prob-
that produced high quality products than for firms lem becomes one of differentiation and integra-
that produced low quality ones. Thus, cost sav- tion (Lawrence & Lorsch, 1967). Porter suggested
ings due to experience can be gained more rap- that cost leadership and product differentiation
idly for quality products. imply distinctly different organizational config-
Because the exogenous preconditions for the urations. According to Lawrence and Lorsch
cost leadership and product differentiation (1967), this statement could mean that the inte-
strategies are not mutually exclusive, the basis gration task, the management task in an enter-
for Porter's warnings against combining strate- prise for which both cost leadership and product
gies must be found elsewhere. differentiation are indicated, is more compli-
cated.
Generic Strategies and By using the techniques described above,
Organizational Configurations Toyota topped ratings of product reliability and
customer satisfaction while simultaneously pro-
Porter argued that: ducing cars for $1500 less per unit than their U.S.
The three generic strategies differ m dimensions rivals (Armstrong, 1987). In North America, the
other than the functional differences noted Kellogg Company has buttressed its impressive
above. Implementing them successfully requires lead in the breakfast cereals industry by simulta-
different resources and skills. The generic strate-
gies also imply differing organizational arrange- neously leading in the introduction and develop-
ments, control procedures, and incentive sys- ment of new production techniques, new prod-
tems. . . . The generic strategies may also re- uct introductions, and brand loyalty (Mitchell,
quire different styles of leadership and can trans- 1987). If Porter's admonitions against pursuit of
late into very different corporate cultures and multiple generic strategies are taken seriously,
atmospheres. Different sorts of people -will be
attracted. (1980, pp. 4(}-41) other firms may be discouraged from emulating
Toyota and Kellogg, and as a result, they may
This statement can be responded to on two risk erosion of their competitive positions.
levels. First, according to research in the area of
production (e.g., Hayes & Wheelwright, 1984; Generic Strategies and
Schonberger, 1982), techniques such as Total
Quality Control combined with Just-In-Time in-
Strategic Means
ventory control and purchasing procedures can Presented above is a contingency approach to
provide both greater market responsiveness and generic strategies which suggests that the viabil-
higher product quality. Obviously, these bene- ity of each of Porter's strategies is tied to the pres-
fits appeal to customers but they also reduce costs ence of a number of environmental precondi-
dramatically, thus eliminating much of the struc- tions. Cost leadership can occur only if the poten-
tural conflict between the production and mar- tial exists to create cost savings in ways other
keting functions and between cost minimization than through cutting back production. How these
strategies and price maximizing strategies. cost savings can be achieved will depend on the
According to a second approach based on the structure of the firm's industry or on the structure
work of Lawrence and Lorsch (1967), although of those firms that supply it or it supplies. If cost
structural conflict between functional areas (and, leadership is derived primarily from realizing
by extrapolation, between generic strategies) economies of scale (e.g., many parts of the

397
chemical industry), making accurate production or both. How easily the indicated set of strategic
capacity decisions becomes a key strategic im- means can be implemented will depend on
perative. If production capacity is set too low, whether an internal configuration of structures,
potential economies are not realized; if it is set systems, and culture can be devised which will
too high, overcapacity will nullify economies due support the set.
to scale. However, if cost economies come from Contingency theories too easily fall into the
overcoming high transaction costs, an entirely trap of assuming that any set of external con-
different set of strategic means, vertical integra- straints has an internally consistent structural
tion for example, may be indicated. response. The work of Lawrence and Lorsch
Similarly, there are a variety of strategic means (1967) and Weick's (1969) work on loose coupling
a firm can use for achieving product differen- point to the difficulties of mounting a coherent
tiation. When a new product class is created, the organizational response to a contradictory set of
potential for producing unique product configu- external demands. The arguments above sug-
rations is greatest, suggesting that high levels of gest that many optimal strategic responses im-
spending on product R&D may be justifiable. As ply just such internal contradictions. Yet, given
the product matures, potential returns diminish the competitive importance of implementing such
but the rewards for consistently producing qual- sets of strategic means, further research on inno-
ity products grow. Where significant costs may vative responses to contradictory external de-
be associated with the purchase process itself, mands would seem to be a worthwhile research
product differentiation through service may be a avenue.
viable approach. In order for the central arguments of the arti-
cle to be stated as clearly as possible, a some-
Conclusions what deterministic approach was taken. There
The generic strategy concept is of great inter- is an inherent risk in doing this because per-
est to business policy researchers because it dis- haps the most resilient criticism of contingency
criminates the strategies of high performing firms theories is that they are too deterministic. Be-
from those of less successful competitors. But, cause examples can be found, in any industry,
the concept is also a disappointment because it of adopters and nonadopters of generic strate-
is confusing, does not explain specifically how gies is proof that managers enjoy considerable
any of the generic strategies should be imple- strategic freedom, and that their actions are not
mented, and does a disservice to practicing man- inextricably constrained by external factors.
agers by advocating limitation to a single ge- Although it is true that managers do enjoy con-
neric strategy when no sound reason for such a siderable strategic freedom, that freedom is di-
limitation exists. rectly related to the competitive intensity of the
Here a contingency approach is suggested as industry. In order for a firm to survive, it does not
a way to overcome these weaknesses. This ap- have to be "excellent"; usually it simply must be
proach demonstrates that there is no a priori rea- as good as or better than its competitors. If its
son why firms should limit themselves to a single competitors are strategically incompetent, the
generic strategy. It also shows that each generic firm has considerable strategic flexibility. Now,
strategy is associated with a whole cluster of however, globalization, the reduction in indus-
strategic means. Choice among strategic means try concentration accompanying this trend, and
should be made by referring to the specific exter- deregulation are raising the competitive inten-
nal context of the firm. In summary, external fac- sity in many industries and reducing firms' stra-
tors dictate a set of strategic means which may tegic choices. Although competitive intensity may
include components aimed at reducing costs, never reach the level at which strategic discre-
raising revenues through product differentiation. tion is eliminated, managers are being forced to

398
become more attuned to environments' strategic factors irrelevant. On the contrary, managers
implications. Therefore, it is important to build must understand the strategic implications of
models linking external factors with appropriate these external constraints if they are to alter them
internal responses. This article attempts to build in beneficial ways.
such a model; however, given the range of strat- A number of studies have tested aspects of the
egies currently in use, there are other links to be generic strategy hypotheses, and each set of con-
discovered. clusions has been different. Currently, there is no
Another overlooked fact is the bilateral nature basis for reconciling these differences. This arti-
of a firm's relationship with its environment. For cle hypothesizes a set of relationships between
the sake of simplicity, it has been assumed that external factors, sets of strategic means, and
external factors are truly exogenous. Obviously structures for implementing those strategic
they are not: Customers' perceptions of products, means. Operationalizing these variables and as-
their own needs, and the technologies that deter- sessing their relationships will be a major re-
mine what potential economies of scale and search undertaking, but one that is worthwhile
learning effects are present can be manipulated because it should eliminate the confusion which
and altered by firms. However, because firms exists and should produce valuable practical
can alter external factors does not make these imphcations.

References
Abernathy, W. J., & Utterback, J. M. (1978) Patterns of indus- Ghemawat, P. (1985) Building strategy on the experience
trial innovation. Technology Review, 80(7), 41-47. curve. Harvard Business Review, 63(2), 143-149.
Armstrong, L. (1985, November 4) Toyota's fast lane. Business Green, P. E., & Srinivasan, V. (1978) Conjoint analysis in
Week. pp. 42-46. consumer research: Issues and outlook. Journal of Con-
Armstrong, L. (1987, June 1) Sony's challenge. Business sumer Research, 5, 103-122.
Week, pp. 64-69. Hall, W. K. (1980) Survival strategies m a hostile environment.
Bain, J. S. (1956) Barriers to new competition. Cambridge, Harvard Busmess Review, 58(5), 75-85.
MA: Harvard University Press. Hambrick, D. C. (1983a) High profit strategies in mature capi-
tal goods industries: A contingency approach. Academy
Beyer, J. (1981) Ideologies, values, and decision making in
of Management Journal, 26, 687-707.
organizations. In P. C. Nystrom & W, H. Starbuck (Eds.),
Handbook of organizational design (pp. 166-202). London: Hambrick, D. C. (1983b) An empirical typology of mature
Oxford University Press. industnal-product environments. Academy of Management
Caves, R. E. (1980) Industrial organization, corporate strategy, Journal, 26, 213-230.
and structure: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature. Hayes, R. H., & Wheelwright, S. C. (1984) Restoring our com-
18, 64-92. petitive edge: Competing through manufacturing. New
York: Wiley.
Cieply, M. (1983, October 24) Sony's profitless prosperity.
Forbes, pp. 128-134. Hofer, C. W. (1975) Toward a contingency theory of business
strategy. Academy of Management Journal, 18, 784-810.
Day, G. S. (1984) Strategic market planning: The pursuit of
competitive advantage. St. Paul: West. Lawrence, P. R., & Lorsch, ]. W. (1967) Organization and
environment: Managing differentiation and integration.
Dess, G. G., & Davis, P. S. (1982) An empirical investigation
Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
of Porter's (1980) generic strategies. Paper presented at the
meeting of the Academy of Management, New York. Miles, R. E., & Snow, C. C. (1978) Organizationai strategy,
structure, and process. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Dess, G. G., & Davis, P. S. (1984) Porter's (1980)genenc strate-
gies as determinants of strategic group membership and Miller, D., & Friesen, P. H. (1986a) Porter's (1980) generic
organizational performance. Academy of Management strategies and performance: An empirical examination with
Journal 27, 467-488. American data. Part 1: Testing Porter. Organizafionai Stud-
ies, 7, 37-55.
Fine, C. H. (1983) Quality control and learning in productive
systems. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Stanford Uni- Miller, D., & Friesen, P. H. (1986b) Porter's (1980) generic
versity, Graduate School of Business. strategies and performance: An empirical examination with
399
American data. Part II: Performance implications. Organi- Schor±ierger, R. J. (1982)/apanese man u/acturingfechnigues;
zation Studies, 7, 255-261. Nine hidden lessons in simplicity. New York: Free Press.
Mitchell, R. (1987, March 30) The health craze has Kellogg Shocker, A. D., & Srinivasan, V. (1974) A consumer-based
feeling G-R-R-Reat. Business Week, pp. 52-53. methodology for the identification of new product ideas.
Management Science, 20, 921-937.
Peters, T. J. (1987) Thriving on chaos. New York: Knopf.
Peters, T. J., & Austin, N. K. (1985) A passion for excellence: Shocker, A. D., & Srinivasan, V. (1979) Multiattribute ap-
The leadership difference. New York: Random House. proaches for product concept evaluation and generation:
A critical review. Journal of Marketing Research, 16,
Phillips, L. W., Chang, D. R., & Buzzell, R. D. (1983) Product 159-180.
quality, cost position and business performance: A test of
some key hypotheses. Journal of Marketing, 47(2), 26-43. Srinivasan, V., & Shocker, A. D. (1973) Linear programming
techniques for multidimensional analysis of preferences.
Porter, M. E. (1980) Compe/i/ivesfrafegy; Techniques/or ana- Psychometrica, 38, 337-369.
lyzing industries and competitors. New York: Free Press.
Weick, K. E. (1969) The sociai psychoiogryo/organizing. Read-
Porter, M. E. (1981) The contribution of industrial organiza- ing, MA: Addison-Wesley.
tions to strategic management. Academy of Management White, R. E. (1986) Generic business strategies, organizational
Review, 6, 609-^20. context and performance: An empirical investigation.
Porter, M. E. (1985) Competitive advantage: Creating and Strategic Management Journal, 7, 217-231.
sustaining superior performance. New York: Free Press. Why things aren't going right for Exxon. (1982, June 7) Business
Rumelt, R. P. (1974) Strategy, structure and economic per- Week, p. 88.
formance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Graduate Williamson, O. E. (1981) The economics of organization: The
School of Business Administration, Division of Research. transaction cost approach. American Journal of Sociology,
87, 548-577.

Alan I. Murray is an Associate Professor in the Depart-


ment of Organizational Analysis in the Faculty of Busi-
ness at the University of Alberta. Correspondence re-
gardmg this article can be sent to him at the Faculty
of Business, Department of Organizational Analysis,
University of Alberta, Edmonton, Alberta, Canada
T6G 2R6.

400

You might also like