The Role of Regret in The Owner Manager

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

Journal of Family Business Strategy 3 (2012) 118–126

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Journal of Family Business Strategy


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jfbs

The role of regret in the owner-manager decision-making in the family business:


A conceptual approach
Gérard Hirigoyen a, Rania Labaki a,b,*
a
University of Montesquieu Bordeaux IV, Research Institute of Organizations Management (IRGO), 35 Avenue Abadie, 33072 Bordeaux Cedex, France
b
INSEEC Business Schools, INSEEC Research Centre, France

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Article history: This article responds to recent calls of scholars for more research on emotions in the family business by
Received 19 July 2011 providing an initial analytical study of the owner-manager regret in decision-making. First, we suggest
Received in revised form 20 March 2012 an enlarged theoretical framework for analyzing decision-making in the family business by building on
Accepted 23 March 2012
the behavioural model of emotions in decision-making of Loewenstein and Lerner (2003) and Regret
Theory. Second, we offer a first characterization of the emotion of regret in the family business. Given the
Keywords: overlap between the family and the business systems, we introduce a dual dimension of regret that is
Decision-making
family-based and business-based. We also extend the analysis towards a dynamic view of regret by
Emotions
accounting for the owner-manager’s experienced regret at the time of decision in addition to the
Family business
Regret traditionally analyzed expected regret. Departing from the common assumption that the owner-
Value manager is altruistic towards the family and acts as a steward for the business, we consider that the
owner-manager’s expected outcomes refer to emotional and financial value maximization. Based on
these characterizations, we develop a conceptual model with a series of propositions on the role of the
owner-manager regret in decision-making. Finally, we present the theoretical, conceptual and practical
contributions of the study as well as its limitations from which stem research avenues on regret and
decision-making in the family business.
ß 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction disciplines such as economics, finance, organizational behaviour,


marketing, and entrepreneurship. Research on the role of emotions
In the opening words of his Nobel Memorial Lecture, Simon in family business decision-making is to date still, however, at its
(1978) referred to Alfred Marshall’s statement proclaiming early stages of development.
economics as a psychological science: ‘‘It is on one side a study Recently, family business scholars called for more studies on
of wealth; and on the other, and more important side, a part of the emotions in the family business (Astrachan & Jaskiewicz, 2008;
study of man’’ (Marshall, 1920, p. 1). Traditionally, scholars in Labaki et al., 2012; Pieper, 2010; Van den Heuvel et al., 2007). The
economics have placed little or no emphasis on the psychological International Family Enterprise Research Academy (IFERA) sug-
aspects in their decision-making models aimed at maximizing the gested ‘‘Emotional dynamics in the family business’’ as its main
utility function of the firm. A paradigm shift has progressively annual conference theme for 2012. These considerations reflect the
allowed to open the black box by moving the focus from The Nature increasing awareness of the importance of emotions in explaining
of the Firm (Coase, 1937) to the Nature of Man (Jensen & Meckling, family business behaviour. It is important to note, nevertheless,
1994). Managers have henceforth been acknowledged as having a that existing studies on emotions in the family business comprise
bounded rationality and irrationality, the latter being considered a major limitations. They often rely on new and confusing emotional
response to their emotions that leads to deviations from rational constructs, restrict the analysis to emotions in the family system,
actions (Simon, 1945, 1987). This has marked the starting point for and fail to take into account the organizational behaviour literature
a growing research interest on emotions in decision-making across findings, which heavily explored emotions in the business system
(Labaki et al., 2012). The emotional process that entails the owner-
manager making decisions in the family business is not yet
sufficiently analyzed.
* Corresponding author at: University of Montesquieu Bordeaux IV, Research While there is still considerable debate regarding what
Institute of Organizations Management (IRGO), 35 Avenue Abadie, 33072 Bordeaux
constitutes emotions (Labaki et al., 2012), there is a widespread
Cedex, France. Tel.: +33 663603725.
E-mail addresses: gerard.hirigoyen@u-bordeaux4.fr (G. Hirigoyen), consensus on the relevance of the emotion of regret for understand-
rania.labaki@u-bordeaux4.fr (R. Labaki). ing decision-making. Regret is the prototypical decision-related

1877-8585/$ – see front matter ß 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfbs.2012.03.004
G. Hirigoyen, R. Labaki / Journal of Family Business Strategy 3 (2012) 118–126 119

emotion as it is the only negative emotion that cannot be by bridging the state-of-the-art research on regret and decision-
experienced without choice (Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007). Although making in behavioural economics, management sciences and family
it has received the most attention from decision theorists (Connolly business. We depart from a critical analysis of the traditional
& Zeelenberg, 2002)1, only few family business scholars dealt with Expected Utility (EU) Theory as it pertains to family businesses. By
regret in their studies. This has been done by either empirically relaxing its assumptions, we extend the analysis toward behavioural
linking different dimensions of regret to different types of managers economics developments on emotions in decision-making. In
in their late life stage (Sonnenfeld & Spence, 1989), or by particular, we build on the model of emotions developed by
conceptually recognizing that managers’ decisions under uncer- Loewenstein and Lerner (2003), that we suggest enriching with
tainty are influenced by expectations of regret (Shepherd & insights from Regret Theory (Bell, 1982, 1983; Loomes & Sugden,
Zacharakis, 2000). The owner-manager’s regret remains surprisingly 1982) applied to the owner-manager decision-making in the family
unexplored. Neither the conceptualization of the emotion of regret businesses (Section 2).
nor the exploration of its antecedents and expectations has been Second, we propose a characterization of regret as a multidi-
developed to account for the unique nature of family businesses as mensional construct in the family business. In order to account for
compared to non-family businesses. the dynamic role of regret in decision-making, we consider both
Family businesses are characterized by the bivalent attributes the classically studied expected regret that appears before the
of the family and business systems (Tagiuri & Davis, 1996). The decision is made, as well as the scarcely studied experienced regret
family and the business are overlapping systems moving that occurs at the time of decision, feeding future decision-making.
simultaneously towards mutual existence, when changes in one To offer a more fine-grained perspective on the role of expected
system manifests in changes in the other system (Danes, Lee, and experienced regret, we include the business-based regret along
Stafford, & Heck, 2008). Regret experienced in one system (e.g., the with the family-based regret that is particular to family businesses
family) may affect the decision-making in the other system (e.g., (Section 3). We then suggest focusing the model of emotions of
the business), and vice versa. Managers in non-family businesses Loewenstein and Lerner (2003) on the owner-manager regret. By
may not experience these dynamics, or at least not as strongly as in introducing our typology of regret and bridging it with insights
family businesses. Based on the common assumption that the from the family business literature, we present a model on the role
owner-manager often acts as a steward for the business (Miller, Le of the owner-manager regret in the family business with a series of
Breton-Miller, & Scholnick, 2008) and has an altruistic behaviour propositions (Section 4). Finally, we conclude with the contribu-
towards the family (Eddleston & Kellermanns, 2007), s/he will be tions and limitations of our work, and close with new research
impelled to maximize the family business value in a way that avenues for investigating the emotion of regret and decision-
meets the business and the family needs. The family business making in the family business (Section 5).
utility function encompasses the maximization of the emotional
value in addition to the traditional financial value (Zellweger & 2. An enlarged theoretical framework for analyzing the
Astrachan, 2008). The owner-manager regret that influences emotion of regret in family business decision-making
decision-making is therefore dual, in that it is both family and
business-based. Family business owners-managers are long-term In the field of economics, the predominant model of choice
oriented (Miller & Le Breton-Miller, 2005) and remain active in the under uncertainty was traditionally backed by the Expected Utility
business for a longer period of time than non-family business (EU) Theory (Bell & Farquhar, 1986; Rick & Loewenstein, 2008).
managers (Gomez-Mejia, Nunez-Nickel, & Gutierrez, 2001). They This theory is not exempt from important limitations that restrict
may benefit from past family and business-based regret experi- the analysis of decision-making in the family business. As
ences to improve their family business decisions and meet both the introduced above, we suggest overcoming its pitfalls by extending
family and the business expectations. In this line of thought, it is the analysis to recent developments on decision-making that
crucial to include in the analysis the owner-manager’s experienced account for the role of emotions. We suggest focusing the model of
regret in addition to the traditional expected regret that is often emotions developed by Loewenstein and Lerner (2003) on the
included in non-family managers’ models of decision-making. This emotion of regret based on a complementary theory that is Regret
contributes to providing a dynamic view of owner-manager regret. Theory (Bell, 1982, 1983; Loomes & Sugden, 1982). This provides
By accounting for these distinct characteristics, an adaptation of us with a dynamic and a more relevant theoretical framework for
the traditional definitions of regret (e.g., Elster, 1998; Lin, Huang, & understanding the different ways in which the emotion of regret
Zeelenberg, 2006; Zeelenberg, 1999) becomes necessary in the enters into the owner-manager decision-making.
family business context. Hence, we define the owner-manager’s
regret as ‘‘the emotion that s/he realizes or imagines if the present 2.1. Relaxing assumptions of the traditional expected utility theory as
situation, perceived by the family on one hand and by the business on a guide to behaviour
the other hand, would have been better if s/he would have acted
differently’’. The concept of Expected Utility (EU) originates back to the 18th
Given the scarcity of research and the gaps in knowledge on century. Based on several illustrations such as the St Petersburg
regret in the family business, there is a need to take into account the Paradox, Bernoulli (1738) has argued that individuals do not
identified characteristics of the owner-manager regret for a more maximize the expected monetary value of an item but the utility it
exhaustive understanding of its role in decision-making. Our article yields, which is dependent on the circumstances. Two centuries
suggests an initial analytical study exploring the research question: later, Von Neumann and Morgenstern (1944) have built on this
‘‘How does the emotion of regret affect the owner-manager decision- concept to develop one of the most influential theories of
making in the family business?’’. First, we aim to offer a more relevant individual choice behaviour, the EU Theory, in their seminal book
theoretical framework for the analysis of the owner-manager regret Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour. The theory aimed at
analyzing how individuals make decisions while accounting for
risk aversion. It assumes that individuals compare the expected
1
For example, scholars in economics analyzed how regret misleads investors utility of existing alternatives and choose the alternative with the
when they have to choose profitable and less risky assets while applying it to
decision making, whereas scholars in marketing analyzed the influence of regret on
highest expected utility. Despite its significant contributions to the
the consumer’s purchase decision and the post-learning process that will feed analysis of decision-making, the axioms foundations of the EU
future decision-making given the experienced regret. theory have been criticized by scholars who reported paradoxes
120 G. Hirigoyen, R. Labaki / Journal of Family Business Strategy 3 (2012) 118–126

and violations of its predictions while suggesting a series of Among major findings, emotions impact cognitive functions of
refinements (e.g., Allais, 1953; Fishburn, 1970; Jensen, 1967). individuals (Johnson & Tversky, 1983; Shiv, Loewenstein, Bechara,
Among the main limitations2, two pertain especially to the owner- Damasio, & Damasio, 2005), as well as their behaviour and the
manager’s decision-making. By briefly highlighting them, we behaviour of close contacts due to emotional contagion (Hareli &
justify the need for alternative theories to complement the analysis Rafaeli, 2008). Both positive and negative emotions have been
in the family business. considered as influencing risky decisions in different ways and
The first limitation refers to the assumption of the EU as the sole leading to behavioural choices that are different in terms of risk
factor affecting decisions. Until recently, most economists aversion or preferences (e.g., Isen, 2001).
excluded the idea that the utility an individual associates with In particular, there are two main types of influence of emotions
an outcome might arise from or depend on expected emotions upon decisions: (1) the experienced emotions affect several levels
(Rick & Loewenstein, 2008). Building on the EU theory, the of cognitive processes, and (2) the expected emotions prepare
manager acts rationally by making a choice based on the value of future decisions (Mellers, Schwartz, & Ritov, 1999). Among
the firm’s expected utility. However, recent research has revealed relevant conceptual developments, Loewenstein and Lerner
how counterfactual emotions, such as regret, may influence (2003) initiated a general model of positive and negative emotions.
decision-making. In the family business, emotions pervade not Their model differentiates itself from other economic models of
only the business system but also the family system, and have the decision-making, in that it explicitly introduces experienced
potential to move from one system to another. Factors pertaining emotions in addition to the commonly used expected emotions
to emotions in the family and the business should be included to in the analysis. The model allows us to expand our understanding
extend the EU model since they do affect decisions in the family of the emotional part of the decision-making process through a
business in a particular way that may not be experienced in series of propositions on the mutual influence of the expected and
businesses with no family connections (Brundin & Melin, 2006; experienced emotions, along with their influence on the expected
Brundin & Nordqvist, 2008; Van den Heuvel et al., 2007). outcomes of the decision to be made.
The second limitation relates to the consideration of satisfac- Since the model of Loewenstein and Lerner (2003) is not
tion as a criterion for choice given that choice is based on stable focused on one type of emotion, we suggest building on the Theory
individual preferences. As Elster (1983) puts it, however, of Regret to translate it to the emotion of regret, which is the only
individuals are able to adjust their aspirations to their possibilities. negative emotion that cannot be experienced without choice. This
The author refers to the ‘‘Sour grapes fable’’ that tells us about a fox allows us to account for the expected regret and experienced regret
changing the course of his decision-making because of his of the owner-manager.
incapacity to reach the grapes that attracted him. In a utilitarian
point of view, the fox decides not to consume the grapes because 2.3. Regret Theory as a complementary perspective on family business
he perceives them as sour, therefore leading to no welfare loss. In decision-making
Elster’s point of view, the phenomenon of sour grapes is an
adaptive preference formation or change. Sour grapes are simply a Whereas during the past decades a proliferation of theories on
way of reducing the cognitive dissonance of the fox in the sense of emotions dominated the organizational behaviour, psychology,
Festinger (1957). Since preferences can be adaptive, there is need and sociology fields, several economists independently generated
for a more realistic model of managerial decision-making that their own theories to overcome the limitations of the EU Theory by
helps to overcome these limitations. In particular, the owner- accounting for behaviour not predicted by that theory based on the
manager’s adaptive preferences are generally not self-oriented. S/ emotion of regret. While most scholars attribute Regret Theory to
he might adapt his/her preferences depending on family and Bell (1982, 1983) and Loomes and Sugden (1982), premises of this
business’ perceptions over time. Subsequent developments made theory had already been developed in the 1950s with the principle
in the literature revealed important progress in models of decision- of Minimax Regret (Luce & Raiffa, 1957; Savage, 1951). This
making that would help refine the analysis in a dynamic principle refers to decisions made after computing the maximum
perspective. of possible regrets for each option and choosing the option with the
lowest regret. Building on insights from Savage (1951), Paroush
2.2. Emotions in behavioural models of decision-making and Venezia (1979) introduced regret in addition to profits in the
analysis of the utility function of decision-makers.
Despite the seminal work of the economist Smith (1759) on The Regret Theory is an alternative theory of rational choice under
Theory of Moral Sentiment more than two centuries ago, emotions uncertainty, in that it intends to explain many of the observed
have only recently been taken into account in explaining human axiom violations of EU theory by introducing a correction to the
behaviour. While scholars in economics started recognizing the utility calculation (Bell, 1982; Loomes & Sugden, 1982). This
role of emotions in decision-making from a managerial perspective correction refers to a change in the utility assessment of an
(e.g., Simon, 1955), the family behavioural perspective did not outcome, which is viewed as the result of comparing the achieved
appear until 20 years later (e.g., Becker, 1976, 1993). In the family outcome with the outcome the decision-maker could have
business field, scholars are now increasingly analyzing how obtained under the realized state of the world, had s/he chosen
emotions influence decision-making, for example by including a different option.
emotions as part of the manager’s business valuation (Astrachan & Preferences are defined by actions that assign outcomes to a
Jaskiewicz, 2008; Zellweger & Astrachan, 2008) or as part of the particular state of the world (Loomes, Starmer, & Sugden, 1992).
entrepreneurial process (Baron, 2008). Initially, Regret Theory was considered as one of pairwise choices
Intensive developments in behavioural economics translated under uncertainty, in which there is a finite number of states of the
into a series of models on decision-making which introduced the world, any of which might occur with some probability (Bell, 1982;
emotions component under the assumption of risky situations. Loomes & Sugden, 1982). It has been extended by Loomes and
Sugden (1987) and Sugden (1993) towards choices where there are
2
more than two alternative actions; each alternative being
An exhaustive overview of the limitations of EU theory is beyond the aim and
scope of this article. The reader is invited to refer to Bell and Farquhar (1986),
associated with various probabilistic outcomes.
Loewenstein and Lerner (2003), Rick and Loewenstein (2008) and Laciana and By viewing individuals as being impelled to avoid the
Weber (2008). experience of regret and make decisions that minimize the
G. Hirigoyen, R. Labaki / Journal of Family Business Strategy 3 (2012) 118–126 121

expected regret to achieve the desired outcomes, Regret Theory in the finance literature from the perspective of the investors’
offers a relevant framework to understand the regret-related choices (Michenaud & Solnik, 2008). Little is known in the family
preferences of the owner-manager over actions that have the and the family business fields, especially regarding the owner-
potential to impact the family and the business. Family businesses manager’s decision-making. This is surprising given the sharp
are indeed often distinguished by the owner-manager’s steward- development of academic interest in regret since the 1990s, as
ship (Miller et al., 2008) and altruism that is recognized to be of shown by a review of academic databases from 1945 to 2005
significant importance in the family (Becker, 1993; Eddleston & (Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007).
Kellermanns, 2007). We therefore bridge recent developments on the role of
In order to reduce the Loewenstein and Lerner’s (2003) model emotions in decision-making in general (Loewenstein & Lerner,
complexity when applied to the emotion of regret, we build on the 2003; Rick & Loewenstein, 2008) and the role of regret in particular
assumption that the owner-manager is driven by stewardship (Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007). The owner-manager regret appears
towards the business and by altruism towards the family. Her/his as a multidimensional construct specific to the family business. In
utility function reflects the family and business utility functions. addition to the classical distinction between expected regret and
Since Regret Theory is mainly focused on expected regret whereas experienced regret, we offer an original typology of family and
Loewenstein and Lerner’s (2003) model focus on expected and business-based regret that is peculiar to the family business. This
experienced emotions, a more fine-grained characterization of the typology builds the basis of our conceptual model in the following
owner-manager regret and value in the family business is sections.
necessary for a better delineation of our conceptual model.
3.1.1. Expected regret versus experienced regret
3. Characterization of regret and value in family business Regret is the result of a comparison between ‘‘what is’’ and
decision-making ‘‘what might have been’’ (Lin et al., 2006) that is generated by
thoughts about what might have happened but didn’t (Elster,
According to Regret Theory, the optimal expected utility 1998). Traditionally, scholars have made two relevant distinctions
function has two attributes: value and regret. These components given the experience of regret and the related perception of
determine the choice of the alternative. In the family business, decisions. First, managers may regret the decision outcomes.
value does not have the same connotation than in non-family Second, they may regret the decision process (to act and not to act;
businesses. Accordingly, regret is differently viewed given the to act according to several alternatives) (Zeelenberg & Pieters,
additional family system. Introducing regret and expected utility 2007). Thus, a decision process that is bad in comparison to an
to analyse the decision-making process of the owner-manager alternative decision process can be regretted even if the decision
requires a delineation of their definitions and characteristics in the outcomes are good3.
specific family business setting. Given the decision time frame, researchers tend to agree that
managers include a dual regret in their decision-making process:
3.1. Regret in family business anticipated regret also called expected regret, and immediate
regret also called experienced regret. This dual regret acts at
Whereas regret is generally not considered as a basic emotion different points in time during the decision-making process. It is
(Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007), it is acknowledged as a distinct taken into account before the decision is made, therefore playing
emotion essential to understanding decision-making. In fact, all an important role in determining what the manager will choose, as
negative emotions, except regret, can be experienced without well as at the moment at which the decision is made, which will in
choice (Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007). As Zeelenberg and Pieters turn determine future decisions in a feedback loop stance.
(2007) put it, regret is uniquely tied to the making of decisions. It is Expected regret takes explicit account of the consequences of a
a ‘‘counterfactual’’ (Elster, 1998; Kahneman & Miller, 1986) and decision. It refers to expectations about the regret that will be
‘‘cognitive’’ emotion which is developed relatively late in our experienced in the future as a result of the outcomes materialized
emotional development while stemming from and producing by the decision, and that will shape the present decision
higher order cognitive processes (Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007). (Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007). Immediate regret is an experienced
The most common definition of regret refers to ‘‘the negative, regret at the time of decision-making (Rick & Loewenstein, 2008;
cognitively-based emotion that we experience when realizing or Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007) when decisions are based on future
imagining that our present situation would have been better, had outcomes (Zeelenberg, 1999). It happens after having chosen a
we acted differently’’ (Zeelenberg, 1999, p. 325). Stated differently, course of action, when the manager feels that s/he would have
it requires the ability to compare processes (Van Dijk & Zeelenberg, been better off choosing a different course (Bell, 1982; Loewen-
2005; Zeelenberg & Van Dijk, 2005) by reflecting on one’s choices stein & Lerner, 2003; Loomes & Sugden, 1982; Zeelenberg, 1999).
and the outcomes generated by these choices, as well as on what Both anticipated and immediate types of regret have been
other outcomes might have been obtained by making a different described as ‘‘retrospective’’ and ‘‘prospective’’. Anticipated regret
choice (Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007). has a prospective element that signals to the manager when
Whereas research on emotions is relatively old, research on decisions would be regrettable, and a retrospective element that
regret originated only a quarter of a century ago in economics (Bell, looks backward from the future to guide her/his present decisions.
1982; Loomes & Sugden, 1982) and psychology (Gilovich & Immediate regret has a retrospective element that informs the
Medvec, 1995; Kahneman & Tversky, 1982) while being focused manager about the level of goal achievement and a prospective
mainly on decision-making. Rapidly though, it expanded towards element that shapes her/his future behaviour (Zeelenberg &
other fields such as marketing, law, organizational behaviour, Pieters, 2007).
medicine, cross-cultural psychology, economic psychology, health Since executive tenure of family managers is higher as
psychology, and neuroscience (Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007). compared to non-family managers (Gomez-Mejia et al., 2001),
Although regret is the emotion that has received the most both the expected and experienced dimensions of regret may play
attention from decision theorists (Connolly & Zeelenberg, 2002) a greater role over the long-run than in non-family businesses, as
especially in the management sciences, today it is mostly studied
in the marketing literature from the perspective of the consumer 3
Notwithstanding the relevance of the process regret, the upcoming develop-
decision-making process while being developed to a lesser extent ments will focus on the outcome regret.
122 G. Hirigoyen, R. Labaki / Journal of Family Business Strategy 3 (2012) 118–126

they may continuously contribute to shaping the owner-manager goals and thus to maximize the owners’ utility (Astrachan &
decisions towards better achievements of the family business Jaskiewicz, 2008). Apart from financial goals, the utility of the
expectations. owner-manager can include non-financial goals (Zellweger &
Dehlen, 2011), which relate to the business (e.g., business
3.1.2. Family-based regret versus business-based regret reputation, products and services quality) (Donnelley, 1964), to
Regret entails attempts to maximize utility over time, by the family (e.g., family members’ security and emotional well-being)
comparing decision processes and outcomes to what might have (Pollak, 1985), and to the individual (e.g., individual pride) (Davis,
been, and informing the self and others about it (Zeelenberg & 1983). Therefore, family business value in the eye of the owner-
Pieters, 2007). In a systems view, the owner-manager’s utility manager refers to both emotional and financial value (Astrachan &
function is distinct from a non-family business manager’s since it Jaskiewicz, 2008; Zellweger & Dehlen, 2011; Zellweger & Astrachan,
articulates two intermingling systems and their expectations, the 2008). In turn, it is closely associated with the bi-dimensional regret
family system and the business system (Astrachan & Jaskiewicz, that is family and business-based.
2008; Tagiuri & Davis, 1996). Added to this, the ‘‘others’’ to be
informed refer to a specific category of family members that can be 4. Towards a conceptual model of the emotion of regret in the
both active and passive in the business. Although predominantly family business
family business research tends to consider that emotions belong
only to the family system whereas the business system is based on A few family business scholars have considered regret in their
rationality (Carlock & Ward, 2001; Kepner, 1983), the broader conceptual models and empirical studies. Sonnenfeld (1988) and
organizational behaviour research is rich with studies on emotions Sonnenfeld and Spence (1989) were the first to suggest different
in business settings (Barsade et al., 2003). Emotions in the family dimensions of the family business manager’s regret, while focusing
business exist both in the family and the business systems (Labaki on the later life stage. Since managers are more likely to consider
et al., 2012). Regret has therefore two dimensions: it is both family- regret over mistakes and lost opportunity in late life (Erikson,
based, taking into account the family effect upon decisions; and 1963), the authors suggested a typology of managers at the later
business-based taking into account the business effect upon life cycle stage, then empirically analyzed different dimensions of
decisions. Given the lack of a distinctive definition of regret in regret based on their typology: regret over an uncompleted
the family business, we suggest that while making decisions the mission, regret over the firm’s performance after they left, regret
owner-manager expects and experiences regret by reference to over the performance of an individual successor, regret over the
both the family and the business systems. By extending our timing of the retirement decision, and the feeling that their skills
previous developments of the literature on regret to the family were underutilized. The findings of their survey show that the
business literature, we offer a more refined definition: ‘‘the family ‘‘Generals’’ type of manager was far more likely to express regret
business owner-manager regret is the emotion the manager realizes or over loss of power, regret over loss of prestige, and over loss of
imagines if the present situation, perceived by the family on one hand being centre of attention. Although interesting, this unique study is
and by the business on the other hand, would have been better if s/he still restricted to the family business owner-manager at a specific
would have acted differently’’. life cycle stage whereas regret has not been introduced in
modelling decision-making at this point.
3.2. Family business value Given these gaps, it becomes crucial to adapt models on emotions
in decision-making from other disciplines to the family business.
Understanding the owner-manager’s perception of regret Most of the existing models, however, focus on one timeframe of the
requires identifying her/his multiple reference points. Regret has decision-making which does not account for a dynamic perspective
been reported as being influenced by losses or gains relative to on regret. As stated earlier, among relevant although general models
each reference point rather than by the size of the loss or gain (Lin of emotions in decision-making, we identified the model of
et al., 2006). In most regret studies, subjects are simply asked to Loewenstein and Lerner (2003) revised by Rick and Loewenstein
indicate their regret over a decision concerning two alternatives, (2008) as offering an interesting and dynamic frame of analysis. We
with the not chosen alternative as the only reference point. suggest adopting their model of expected and experienced emotions
Although some scholars have recognized that decision makers may and focusing it on the emotion of regret to offer a dynamic
use multiple reference points in decision-making and in judgments perspective on family and business-based regret, that is expected
of post-decisional regret (Bell, 1982), the information of multiple and experienced, in the owner-manager decision-making.
reference points and their relative weighting has not been
sufficiently investigated empirically (Lin et al., 2006). 5. The dynamic role of experienced and expected regret in the
Multiple reference points can be included to assess the owner- owner-manager decision-making
manager’s regret and build a family business decision-making
model: action versus inaction outcomes (e.g., investment versus no We suggest two different ways in which emotions enter into
investment decision) and different intensities of outcomes and decision-making in the family business: through the influence of
expectations (e.g., the best-performing investment project; the expected regret and through the influence of experienced regret.
worst-performing investment project). For our propositions to be relevant, we consider that they apply to
Since we depart from the assumption that the owner-manager is important outcomes since the more important an outcome is, the
altruistic toward the family and a steward for the business, the more likely it is that the decision-maker engages in the
formulation of the utility function leads us to consider the expected anticipation of regret, because more important decisions will
utility of the owner-manager in the family business (in terms of result in more intense regret when things go awry (Zeelenberg &
preferences) as the maximization of the family business value. Pieters, 2007). We follow the same line of analysis of Loewenstein
In a family business, value is perceived as bi-dimensional since it & Lerner (2003) to develop our series of propositions.
is induced by both economic benefits (wealth creation) and non-
economic benefits (socio-emotional wealth) (Chrisman, Chua, & Litz, 5.1. On the influence of expected regret
2003; Gomez-Mejia, Haynes, Nunez-Nickel, Jacobson, & Moyano-
Fuentes, 2007). In fact, a family business can be thought of as a By applying the literature reflections on the outcomes of
vehicle enabling a family to achieve its financial and non-financial expected emotions to the family business, it is possible to suggest
G. Hirigoyen, R. Labaki / Journal of Family Business Strategy 3 (2012) 118–126 123

Proposition c3: In the family business, the expected financial


value will influence the extent of the expected family-based
regret.
Proposition c4: In the family business, the expected emotional
value will influence the extent of expected business-based regret.

5.2. On the influence of experienced regret

In the family business, the owner-manager’s immediate regret


(experienced at the time of decision) influences decision-making in
two ways:
Fig. 1. A conceptual model of the owner-manager regret in decision-making.
Legend: EV = Emotional Value; FV = Financial Value, FR = Family-Based Regret;
(1) When sufficiently strong (Rick & Loewenstein, 2008),
BR = Business-Based Regret. immediate regret can exert a direct impact on a decision (line d)
(Loewenstein & Lerner, 2003) precluding cognitive decision-
making (Loewenstein, 1996). This can be illustrated by the
that the expected regret of the owner-manager predicts the example of the conflicted manager who experiences immediate
emotional consequences associated with alternative courses of regret at the prospect of and at the moment of choosing an
action. This consequently persuades her/him to select actions that alternative. Let us assume that there are discrepancies between
lead to outcomes that minimize negative emotions such as regret. two possible alternatives with the first being less efficient in terms
In considering an important decision (such as the choice of of business performance and more efficient in terms of family
the family business successor or the choice of an investment/ performance. If the first alternative is chosen, the immediate regret
divestment project), the owner-manager attempts to predict the will be business-based. Depending on the extent of immediate
probabilities of different outcomes, such as better business and regret, it might deter the owner-manager from choosing or
worse business performance (Sonnenfeld, 1988) or higher and supporting the same alternative in the future. If the owner-
lower financial capital (Sharma, 2004) from the business side manager’s choice is the more efficient alternative business wise
(line b stemming from the decision to its expected consequences). but less efficient family wise, the highest level of regret would be
On the other hand, the owner-manager attempts to predict family-based and might encourage the owner-manager to choose
issues from the family side such as higher or lower family the first alternative instead.
satisfaction in terms of family well-being (Olson et al., 2003), Given this, we suggest the following propositions:
emotional capital or family harmony (Sharma, 2004) from the Proposition d: In the family business, the extent of immediate
family side, as well as whether or not s/he would feel regret (and regret will exert a direct impact on the owner-manager’s decision.
which intensity of regret if any) toward the family and the Proposition d1: In the family business, the extent of immediate
business under each alternative (line c running from expected family-based regret will exert a direct impact on the owner-
consequences to expected regret). As an example, the owner- manager’s decision.
manager might wonder whether s/he will feel regret about Proposition d2: In the family business, the extent of immediate
choosing a specific alternative because this choice will lead to a business-based regret will exert a direct impact on the owner-
decline in business performance or whether s/he will feel regret manager’s decision.
about not having chosen a different alternative because of (2) Immediate regret can exert an indirect impact on a decision
possible family conflicts. This consideration might depend on by either altering the decision maker’s expectations of the
what extent the owner-manager is blinded by altruism (Schulze, probability (line e); either desirability of future consequences or
Lubatkin, & Dino, 2003), which may lead to a biased assessment the way that these consequences are processed (line f).
of the decision alternative. The desire to avoid experiencing In terms of the indirect influence of the owner-manager’s
family or business regret might then dissuade the manager from immediate family-based regret, linked to the original choice of a
choosing a specific alternative (line a). specific alternative, this would lead to a biased calculation of the
Given this, the following propositions are suggested: probability of emotional value maximization. S/he might feel that
Proposition a: In the family business, the extent of expected the consequence of that decision will lead to a lower probability of
regret will influence the owner-manager’s decision. emotional value maximization. In the same line of thought, the
Proposition a1: In the family business, the extent of expected owner-manager’s estimation of the financial value might be
family-based regret will influence the owner-manager’s decision. biased pertaining to a higher probability of financial value
Proposition a2: In the family business, the extent of expected maximization following the choice of the alternative. This could
business-based regret will influence the owner-manager’s be explained by the owner-manager altruism (Lubatkin, Schulze,
decision. Ling, & Dino, 2005) or illusion of control (Schwenk, 1984) known
Proposition b: In the family business, the owner-manager for skewing the manager’s perceptions. Due to altruism and
makes the decision that is likely to achieve the expected family stewardship, the owner-manager might feel more optimistic
business value maximization. about the prospects of an alternative business or family-wise or
Proposition b1: In the family business, the owner-manager about his/her ability to shrug off regret if the alternative is not
makes the decision that is likely to maximize the emotional value. performing well. Driven by altruism, the owner-manager might
Proposition b2: In the family business, the owner-manager not be sufficiently rigorous during future assessment processes
makes the decision that is likely to maximize the financial value. and pursue the wrong course of action.
Proposition c: In the family business, the expected value Given this, the following propositions are suggested:
maximization will influence the extent of expected regret. Proposition e: In the family business, the extent of immediate
Proposition c1: In the family business, the expected emotional regret will alter the owner-manager’s expectations of the
value will influence the extent of the expected family-based regret. probability of maximizing value.
Proposition c2: In the family business, the expected financial Proposition e1: In the family business, the extent of immediate
value will influence the extent of the expected business-based family-based regret will alter the owner-manager’s expectations of
regret. the probability of maximizing emotional value.
124 G. Hirigoyen, R. Labaki / Journal of Family Business Strategy 3 (2012) 118–126

Proposition e2: In the family business, the extent of immediate family and business-based. It also presents a dynamic view of
business-based regret will alter the owner-manager’s expectations owner-manager regret that takes into account the traditional
of the probability of maximizing financial value. expected regret along with the scarcely studied experienced
Returning to the conflicting manager, her/his immediate regret. Our conceptual model is however not exempt from
family-based regret would translate into an erroneous perception limitations that open new avenues of research.
of the real intensity of the family-based expected regret. S/he First, the analysis we present is restrictive since it is based on
might feel that the expected family-based regret will be higher (or the assumption that owner-managers are stewards of their
lower) than expected, which in turn might influence the decision business and altruistic towards their family, while having a unique
by leading her/him to choosing one alternative versus the other utility function that is aligned with the maximization of the
alternative. In the same vein, the manager might overestimate or emotional and financial value of the family business. Taking into
underestimate the expected business-based regret following the account different configurations of family ownership and distinct
choice of one of the existing alternatives. preferences of family managers and family stakeholders regarding
Given this, the following propositions are suggested: emotional versus financial value (Hirigoyen, 2009) would help
Proposition f: In the family business, the extent of immediate refining the analysis.
regret will alter the owner-manager’s perceptions of the extent of Future studies should emphasize the evolution of the expected
expected regret. utility function of family stakeholders (e.g., from active to passive)
Proposition f1: In the family business, the extent of immediate as the family spans many generations. Since family relationships
business-based regret will alter the owner-manager’s perceptions tend to weaken starting with the second generation in business
of the extent of expected business-based regret. (Labaki, 2007), an in-depth analysis of the model in later stages
Proposition f2: In the family business, the extent of immediate could be foundational for a matrix outlining the predominant
family-based regret will alter the owner-manager’s perceptions of regret type of family stakeholders according to their expected
the extent of expected family-based regret. value in the family businesses. The choice made by the owner-
By focusing the analysis on the emotion of regret of the owner- manager, taking into account the regret factor, may differ
manager in decision-making, we contribute to extending Regret depending on the characteristics of the family stakeholders. The
Theory and enriching the model of emotions initially developed by total family business utility function (maximisation of total value)
Loewenstein & Lerner (2003). encompasses the maximization of the emotional value and the
financial value. Depending on the stakeholders’ interests over time,
6. Conclusions and suggestions for future research the owner-manager may be impelled to predominantly seek to
maximize one type of value (e.g., financial value) at the detriment
In family business literature, little attention has been devoted of another type of value (e.g., emotional value), given the weight
to the emotions of owner-managers in decision-making. It is this that family shareholders give to each value. Sometimes the
article’s contention to respond to the recent calls for research by maximization of the financial value takes over the emotional value
shedding light on this missing piece of the puzzle while focusing on given the predominance of family or business-based regret. A clear
the emotion of regret. Despite the sharp increase of interest on understanding of the stakeholders characteristics, regret, and
regret in multiple disciplines such as psychology, management, value expectations would help the manager to choose the decision
economics and finance, no in-depth research has yet been done on that best fits their interests in an altruistic and stewardship view.
regret in the family business. We suggest setting the ground for Building on existing typologies of family business stakeholders’
future studies on regret while dealing with common issues expectations can be useful in that sense.
pertaining to new and original areas of research. Second, the owner-manager may benefit from adequate gover-
By building on existing theories of choice and extending nance mechanisms to achieve the optimal arbitrage between family-
previous models of emotions in behavioural economics to the based regret and business-based regret and contribute to the total
family business, we conceptually provide a more fine-grained value maximization. We therefore suggest to introduce governance
perspective on the role of the emotion of regret in family business mechanisms as moderators in our model, both at the family and the
decision-making. We present a first characterization of regret in business side, to help prevent (or at least limit) the owner-manager’s
the family business that introduces a dual dimension accounting decision to result in regret. Many family businesses focus primarily
for the unique nature of family businesses. Unlike other businesses, on the business side and tend to ignore the family side. This would
the owner-manager’s regret is not only conceptualized as being still allow regret from the family system to freely ‘‘spill’’ into the
experienced and expected but also as being family-based and business system and hinder the expected value maximization. In
business-based. Building on this typology, we propose a model fact, recent empirical research shows that family businesses that
with a series of propositions on the role of regret in the owner- manage both family and business systems are more successful than
manager decision-making. Globally, our model indicates that the those focusing on the business side only (Basco & Pérez Rodrı́guez,
family business manager’s decision-making is complex, pertaining 2009, 2011). In addition, setting up both formal (contractual) and
both to the expected utility function and the dual immediate and informal (relational) governance mechanisms in the family business
expected regret. Departing from a business-stewardship and has a positive impact on strategic decision making (Mustakallio,
family-altruistic vision of the owner-manager, we base our model Autio, & Zahra, 2002). Among effective governance mechanisms, the
on the assumption that his/her utility function refers to the owner-manager may rely on trust (Steier, 2001), family meetings,
maximization of the family business emotional value and financial family plans and family councils to achieve the optimal decision
value. We outline relationships of the role different dimensions (Mustakallio et al., 2002).
play with respect to regret in the family business from a dynamic Third, our model can be extended to non-family business
perspective (Fig. 1). managers. By modelling their decision-making in a stakeholders’
This article offers several conceptual, theoretical and practical perspective, the regret of non-family business managers could be
contributions to the literature. viewed as multidimensional, featuring both business-based regret
On the conceptual level, it adds knowledge to the family and other stakeholders-based regret.
business field through suggesting a model of the owner-manager’s Fourth, our series of propositions do not illustrate a specific
regret in decision-making. In particular, it provides an original decision. Further insight through applications in financial deci-
effort of characterization of the owner-manager’s regret as being sions in the family business, such as investment, financing and
G. Hirigoyen, R. Labaki / Journal of Family Business Strategy 3 (2012) 118–126 125

dividends distribution decisions, or in managerial succession method along with neuropsychological and neuroimaging data
decisions would expand our understanding. could prove interesting given the progress neurosciences have
Fifth, the emotion of regret can enter decision-making in other made in studying emotions. For instance, researchers started
ways not depicted in our model. Our model focused the analysis on exploring regret based on magnetic resonance imaging during the
the emotion of regret per se. However, several extended regret phase of choice, when the brain is anticipating possible future
constructs exist in the literature and can add to our knowledge on consequences of decisions (Coricelli, Dolan, & Sirigu, 2007).
decision-making: regret aversion (Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007), On the practical level, our article sets the stage for a functional
regret learning experience (Shefrin & Statman, 1985), and regret grid of analysis on regret and expected value based on our dynamic
specificity (Pieters & Zeelenberg, 2007). Control variables not model. By referring to our preliminary insights, owner-managers
explored in the present paper can also be included in the analysis and advisors would gain a more exhaustive understanding of the
such as the life cycle stage (ownership structure, business characteristics of the decision-making process that guides them
development and size, degree of family involvement in the towards achieving the desired objectives of the family business.
business) to understand how they can differently orientate the
owner-manager’s decision.
Sixth, regret is intrinsically connected to the information References
regarding the choices to be made. Individuals are more likely to
Allais, M. (1953). Le comportement de l‘Homme Rationnel devant le risque: Critique
recall information that is congruent rather than incongruent with des postulats et axiomes de l‘école Americaine. Econometrica, 21, 503–546.
their current feelings (Bower, 1981; Isen, Shalker, Clark, & Karp, Astrachan, J. H., & Jaskiewicz, P. (2008). Emotional returns and emotional costs in
1978). Avoiding biases in collecting, processing and selecting the privately held family businesses: Advancing traditional business valuation. Family
Business Review, 21(2), 139–149.
relevant information is a crucial determinant of the success of the Baron, R. A. (2008). The role of affect in the entrepreneurial process. Academy of
owner-manager endeavour in maximizing the family business Management Review, 33(2), 328–340.
utility function. In addition, the emotional state of the owner- Barsade, S. G., Brief, A. P., & Sapataro, S. E. (2003). The affective revolution in organiza-
tion behavior: The emergence of a paradigm. In J. Greenberg (Ed.), Organization
manager plays an important role in biasing her/his perceptions of behavior: The art of the science. NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.
the intensity of family and business-based regret. Other emotions Basco, R., & Pérez Rodrı́guez, M. J. (2009). Studying the family enterprise holistically.
can therefore influence the experienced regret. According to Family Business Review, 22(1), 82–95.
Basco, R., & Pérez Rodrı́guez, M. J. (2011). Ideal types of family business management:
Schwarz and Clore (1988, 1996), managers are impelled to assess a Horizontal fit between family and business decisions and the relationship with
decision in a more positive way when they have positive emotions family business performance. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 2(3), 151–165.
(such as being happy) than when they have negative emotions Becker, G. S. (1976). The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
(such as being sad). Happy owner-managers adopt a top-down
Becker, G. S. (1993). A treatise on the family (enlarged ed.). Cambridge, MA: Harvard
processing of information that encompasses a high level of University Press.
confidence regarding existing knowledge and little attention to Bell, D. E. (1982). Regret in decision making under uncertainty. Operations Research,
details. On the opposite side, sad owner-managers adopt a bottom- 30(5), 961.
Bell, D. E. (1983). Risk premiums for decision regret. Management Science, 29(10),
up processing of information with poor confidence in existing 1156–1166.
knowledge and more accurate attention to detail. Johnson and Bell, D. E., & Farquhar, P. H. (1986). Perspectives on utility theory. Operations Research,
Tversky (1983) and Nygren, Isen, Taylor, and Dulin (1996) note that 34(1), 179–183.
Bernoulli, D. (1738). Specimen theoriae novae de mensura sortis. Commentarii acade-
serene and happy individuals tend to overestimate the probability miae scientiarum imperialis Petropolitanae, 5, 175–192, Translated by Louise Som-
of occurrence of positive results and underestimate negative mer as Exposition of a new theory on the management of risk, Econometrica 22 (1)
results–the opposite is true for sad individuals. (1954) 23–36..
Bower, G. H. (1981). Mood and memory. American Psychologist, 36(2), 129–148.
On the theoretical level, this article extends Regret Theory and Brundin, E., & Melin, L. (2006). Unfolding the dynamics of emotions: How emotion
behavioural economics models of emotions in decision-making drives or counteracts strategizing. International Journal of Work Organization and
(Loewenstein & Lerner, 2003) to the family business field. On one Emotion, 1(3), 277–298.
Brundin, E., & Nordqvist, M. (2008). Beyond facts and figures: The role of emotions in
hand, this helps in building an emotional-based theory of the boardroom dynamics. Corporate Governance, 16(4), 326–341.
family business, and on the other hand, contributed to broadening Carlock, R. S., & Ward, J. L. (2001). Strategic planning for the family business. New York:
the scope of these models and theories towards new implementa- Palgrave.
Chrisman, J. J., Chua, J. H., & Litz, R. (2003). A unified systems perspective of family firm
tions in the family business. Whereas other complementary
performance: An extension and integration. Journal of Business Venturing, 18(4),
theories and models may enrich the analysis, our existing model 467–472.
should also be studied on the empirical level. Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.
As a first stage, in-depth interviews with owner-managers Connolly, T., & Zeelenberg, M. (2002). Regret and decision making. Current Directions in
Psychological Science, 11, 212–216.
during the decision-making process would enlighten our under- Coricelli, G., Dolan, R. J., & Sirigu, A. (2007). Brain, emotion and decision making: The
standing of the emotional process and help better articulate certain paradigmatic example of regret. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 11(6), 258–265.
propositions. Micro-economic modelling of decisions that is Danes, S. M., Lee, J., Stafford, K., & Heck, R. K. Z. (2008). The effects of ethnicity, families
and culture on entrepreneurial experience: An extension of sustainable family
widespread in financial economics can also be implemented to business theory. Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship, 13(3), 229–268.
analyse the owner-manager’s decision. At a later stage, we suggest Davis, P. S. (1983). Realizing the potential of the family business. Organizational
surveys with questionnaires using scales on regret from consumer Dynamics, 12(1), 47–56.
Donnelley, R. G. (1964). The family business. Harvard Business Review, 42(4), 93–105.
psychology—although not excluding strong limitations such as Eddleston, K. A., & Kellermanns, F. W. (2007). Destructive and productive family
response bias—to be adapted to the family business setting. relationships: A stewardship theory perspective. Journal of Business Venturing,
Researchers should, however, be aware of the managers’ biases in 22(4), 545–565.
Elster, J. (1983). Sour grapes: Studies in the subversion of rationality. Cambridge: Cam-
predicting future emotions, which may have negative conse-
bridge University Press.
quences on decision-making (Hirigoyen, 2008; Simon, 1945). Elster, J. (1998). Emotions and economic theory. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(1),
Furthermore, researchers should take into account the fact that 47–74.
Erikson, E. (1963). Childhood and society (2nd ed.). NY: Norton.
although decision-makers are often reluctant to acknowledge
Festinger, L. A. (1957). A theory of cognitive dissonance. Stanford: Stanford University
regret, they may be willing to express regret at some other time Press.
because of the expected immediate social gains (e.g., criminals Fishburn, P. C. (1970). Utility theory for decision making. NY: John Wiley & Sons.
who do not show regret can expect higher sentences, which makes Gilovich, T., & Medvec, V. H. (1995). The experience of regret: What, when, and why.
Psychological Review, 102(2), 379–395.
expressing regrets in court both suspicious and necessary at the Gomez-Mejia, L. R., Haynes, K. T., Nunez-Nickel, M., Jacobson, K. J. L., & Moyano-
same time) (Zeelenberg & Pieters, 2007). Finally, the scenarios Fuentes, J. (2007). Socioemotional wealth and business risks in family-controlled
126 G. Hirigoyen, R. Labaki / Journal of Family Business Strategy 3 (2012) 118–126

firms: Evidence from spanish olive oil mills. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52(1), Olson, P. D., Zuiker, V. S., Danes, S. M., Stafford, K., Heck, R. K. Z., & Duncan, K. A. (2003).
106–137. The impact of the family and the business on family business sustainability. Journal
Gomez-Mejia, L. R., Nunez-Nickel, M., & Gutierrez, I. (2001). The role of family ties in of Business Venturing, 18(5), 639–666.
agency contracts. Academy of Management Journal, 44(1), 81–95. Paroush, J., & Venezia, I. (1979). On the theory of the competitive firm with a utility
Hareli, S., & Rafaeli, A. (2008). Emotion cycles: On the social influence of emotion in function defined on profits and regret. European Economic Review, 12(3), 193–202.
organizations. Research in Organizational Behavior, 28, 35–59. Pieper, T. M. (2010). Non solus: Toward a psychology of family business. Journal of
Hirigoyen, G. (2008). Biais comportementaux dans l’entreprise familiale: Antécédents Family Business Strategy, 1(1), 26–39.
et impacts. Economie et Sociétés, 19, 1901–1930. Pieters, R., & Zeelenberg, M. (2007). A theory of regret regulation 1.1. Journal of
Hirigoyen, G. (2009). Concilier finance et management dans les entreprises familiales. Consumer Psychology, 17(1), 29–35.
Revue Française de Gestion, 198/199, 393–411. Pollak, R. A. (1985). A transaction cost approach to families and households. Journal of
Isen, A. M. (2001). An influence of positive affect on decision making in complex Economic Literature, 23(2), 581–608.
situations: Theoretical issues with practical implications. Journal of Consumer Rick, S., & Loewenstein, G. (2008). The role of emotion in economic behavior. In M.
Psychology, 11(2), 75–85. Lewis, J. M. Haviland-Jones, & L. F. Barrett (Eds.), Handbook of emotions (3rd ed., pp.
Isen, A. M., Shalker, T. E., Clark, M., & Karp, L. (1978). Affect accessibility of material in 138–156). New York: The Guilford Press.
memory, and behavior: A cognitive loop? Journal of Personality and Social Psychol- Savage, L. J. (1951). The theory of statistical decision. Journal of the American Statistical
ogy, 36(1), 1–12. Association, 46(253), 55–67.
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. (1994). The nature of man. Journal of Applied Corporate Schulze, W. S., Lubatkin, M. H., & Dino, R. N. (2003). Toward a theory of agency and
Finance, 7(2), 4–19. altruism in family firms. Journal of Business Venturing, 18(4), 473–490.
Jensen, N. E. (1967). An introduction to Bernoullian utility theory: I. Utility functions. Schwarz, N., & Clore, G. L. (1988). How do I feel about it? The informative function of
The Swedish Journal of Economics, 69(3), 163–183. affective states. Affect, Cognition, and Social Behavior, 44–62.
Johnson, E. J., & Tversky, A. (1983). Affect, generalization, and the perception of risk. Schwarz, N., & Clore, G. L. (1996). Feelings and phenomenal experiences. Social
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 45(1), 20. Psychology: Handbook of Basic Principles, 2, 385–400.
Kahneman, D., & Miller, D. T. (1986). Norm theory: Comparing reality to its alternatives. Schwenk, C. R. (1984). Cognitive simplification processes in strategic decision-making.
Psychological Review, 93(2), 136–153. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 111–128.
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1982). The psychology of preferences. Scientific American, Sharma, P. (2004). An overview of the field of family business studies: Current status
246, 160–173. and directions for the future. Family Business Review, 17(1), 1–36.
Kepner, E. (1983). The family and the firm: A coevolutionary perspective. Organiza- Shefrin, H., & Statman, M. (1985). The disposition to sell winners too early and ride
tional Dynamics, 12(1), 57–70. losers too long: Theory and evidence. Journal of Finance, 40(3), 777–790.
Labaki, R. (2007). Contribution à la connaissance des liens familiaux dans les entre- Shepherd, D. A., & Zacharakis, A. (2000). Structuring family business succession: An
prises familiales françaises cotées: Renforcement versus atténuation. Unpublished analysis of the future leader’s decision making. Entrepreneurship: Theory and
PhD Dissertation, University of Montesquieu Bordeaux IV, Bordeaux. Practice, 24(4), 25–39.
Labaki, R., Michael-Tsabari, N., & Zachary, R. K. (2012). Emotional dimensions within Shiv, B., Loewenstein, G., Bechara, A., Damasio, H., & Damasio, A. R. (2005). Investment
the family business–Toward a conceptualization. In K. Smyrnios, P. Z. Poutziouris & behavior and the negative side of emotion. Psychological Science, 16(6), 435–439.
S. B. Klein (Eds.), Handbook of Research on Family Business (2nd ed.): Edward Elgar. Simon, H. A. (1945). Administrative behaviour: A study of decision-making processes in
In press. administrative organizations (4th ed.). New York: Free Press.
Laciana, C. E., & Weber, E. U. (2008). Correcting expected utility for comparisons Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. The Quarterly Journal of
between alternative outcomes: A unified parameterization of regret and disap- Economics, 69(1), 99–118.
pointment. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 36(1), 1–17. Simon, H. A. (1978). Rationality as process and as product of thought. American
Lin, C.-H., Huang, W.-H., & Zeelenberg, M. (2006). Multiple reference points in investor Economic Review, 68(2), 1–16.
regret. Journal of Economic Psychology, 27(6), 781–792. Simon, H. A. (1987). Making management decisions: The role of intuition and emotion.
Loewenstein, G. (1996). Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organizational Academy of Management Executive, 1(1), 57–64.
Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65(3), 272–292. Smith, A. (1759). The theory of moral sentiments (1976 ed.). Oxford: Oxford University
Loewenstein, G., & Lerner, J. S. (2003). The role of affect in decision making. In R. J. Press.
Davidson, K. R. Scherer, & H. H. Goldsmith (Eds.), Handbook of affective sciences (pp. Sonnenfeld, J. A. (1988). The hero’s farewell: What happens when CEOs retire. NY: Oxford
619–642). New York: Oxford University Press Inc. University Press.
Loomes, G., Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (1992). Are preferences monotonic? Testing some Sonnenfeld, J. A., & Spence, P. L. (1989). The parting patriarch of a family firm. Family
predictions of regret theory. Economica, 59(233), 17–33. Business Review, 2(4), 355–375.
Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (1982). Regret theory: An alternative theory of rational choice Steier, L. (2001). Family firms, plural forms of governance, and the evolving role of trust.
under uncertainty. Economic Journal, 92(368), 805–824. Family Business Review, 14(4), 353–367.
Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (1987). Some implications of a more general form of regret Sugden, R. (1993). An axiomatic foundation for regret theory. Journal of Economic
theory. Journal of Economic Theory, 41(2), 270–287. Theory, 60(1), 159–180.
Lubatkin, M. H., Schulze, W. S., Ling, Y., & Dino, R. N. (2005). The effects of parental Tagiuri, R., & Davis, J. (1996). Bivalent attributes of the family firm. Family Business
altruism on the governance of family-managed firms. Journal of Organizational Review, 9(2), 199–208.
Behavior, 26, 313–330. Van den Heuvel, J., Goel, S., Van Gils, A., & Voordeckers, W. (2007). Family business as
Luce, R. D., & Raiffa, H. (1957). Games and decisions. New York: Wiley. emotional arenas: The influence of family CEO’s empathy and external monitoring
Marshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics (8th ed.). New York: Macmillan. on the importance of family goals. Paper presented at the Family Firms Manage-
Mellers, B., Schwartz, A., & Ritov, I. (1999). Emotion-based choice. Journal of Experi- ment Research Workshop, Jönköping.
mental Psychology: General, 128(3), 332–345. Van Dijk, E., & Zeelenberg, M. (2005). On the psychology of ‘if only’: Regret and the
Michenaud, S., & Solnik, B. (2008). Applying regret theory to investment choices: comparison between factual and counterfactual outcomes. Organizational Behavior
Currency hedging decisions. Journal of International Money and Finance, 27(5), and Human Decision Processes, 97(2), 152–160.
677–694. Von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1944). Theory of games and economic behavior.
Miller, D., & Le Breton-Miller, I. (2005). Managing for the long run: Lessons in competitive Princeton: Princeton University Press.
advantage from great family businesses. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Zeelenberg, M. (1999). The use of crying over spilled milk: A note on the rationality and
Miller, D., Le Breton-Miller, I., & Scholnick, B. (2008). Stewardship vs. stagnation: An functionality of regret. Philosophical Psychology, 12(3), 325–340.
empirical comparison of small family and non-family businesses. Journal of Man- Zeelenberg, M., & Pieters, R. (2007). A theory of regret regulation 1.0. Journal of
agement Studies, 45(1), 51–78. Consumer Psychology, 17(1), 3–18.
Mustakallio, M., Autio, E., & Zahra, S. A. (2002). Relational and contractual governance Zeelenberg, M., & Van Dijk, E. (2005). On the comparative nature of regret. In D. Mandel,
in family firms: Effects on strategic decision making. Family Business Review, 15(3), D. Hilton, & P. Catelani (Eds.), The psychology of counterfactual thinking (pp. 147–
205–222. 161). London: Routledge.
Nygren, T. E., Isen, A. M., Taylor, P. J., & Dulin, J. (1996). The influence of positive affect Zellweger, T., & Dehlen, T. (2011). Value is in the eye of the owner: Affect infusion and
on the decision rule in risk situations: Focus on outcome (and especially avoidance socioemotional wealth among family firm owners. Family Business Review.
of loss) rather than probability. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Zellweger, T. M., & Astrachan, J. H. (2008). On the emotional value of owning a firm.
Processes, 66(1), 59–72. Family Business Review, 21(4), 347–363.

You might also like