Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 18

Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938

Rethinking the public sector: idiosyncrasies of biotechnology


commercialization as motors of national R&D reform
in Germany and Japan
Mark Lehrer a,∗ , Kazuhiro Asakawa b,1
a College of Business Administration, University of Rhode Island, Kingston, RI 02881, USA
b Graduate School of Business Administration, Keio University, 2-1-1 Hiyoshi-honcho, Kohoku-ku, Yokohama 223-8523, Japan
Received 12 February 2003; received in revised form 20 November 2003; accepted 29 January 2004

Available online 10 May 2004

Abstract
Recent policies to promote biotechnology are motors of broader R&D reform in Germany and Japan. The idiosyncrasies of
biotechnology commercialization could not be readily accommodated by these countries’ traditional technology policies, thus
prompting reforms in institutions governing the commercialization of basic scientific research. These reforms provide a novel
perspective on the nature of innovation in biotechnology; while previous research has underlined factors such as the national
science base, industry–university links, entrepreneurship and venture capital, the German and Japanese cases highlight the
importance of other mediating variables such as the level of public governance within national research institutions, the
autonomy of the university/research sector, and the historical role of the public sector generally.
© 2004 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords: National R&D policy; Biotechnology commercialization; Private-public sector linkages

The concept of “comparative institutional advantage” arrangements but ultimately affect hard economic
(Hall and Soskice, 2001) suggests that the industries factors like relative costs, the flow of new ideas, and
in which countries specialize depend not only on the incentives to innovate (Zysman, 1983; Ziegler, 1997).
relative factor costs of classical trade theory, but on the While economists generally deny the proposition that
national institutional frameworks in which a country’s nations compete over markets like firms do (Krugman,
producers are embedded. However, institutions are not 1996), the belief by policy-makers that their coun-
fixed but evolve over time. To the extent that countries tries do compete is nonetheless an important factor
can create or reform national institutions that support in explaining institutional change. Just as Japanese
targeted industries, they may be able to create sources advantages in electronics and semiconductors led not
of comparative advantage that take root in specific only to US protectionism, but also to US domestic
reforms in the 1980s (e.g. the Sematech consortium,
∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-401-874-7882
more flexible application of antitrust laws), the US
fax: +1-401-874-4312.
E-mail addresses: lehrer@uri.edu (M. Lehrer),
lead in biotechnology has inspired other countries to
asakawa@kbs.keio.ac.jp (K. Asakawa). initiate institutional changes (Casper, 2000; Casper
1 Tel.: +81-45-564-2021; fax: +81-45-562-3502. and Kettler, 2001).

0048-7333/$ – see front matter © 2004 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.respol.2004.01.011
922 M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938

As demonstrated by German and Japanese efforts in particular the idiosyncratic institutional linkages
to improve their national frameworks for biotechnol- between basic science and technology commercializa-
ogy, comparative institutional advantages, just like tion. While prior studies of biotechnology underline
trade advantages, are often “revealed” by performance the need for institutions facilitating the production
statistics. There is one positive consequence of con- of basic scientific knowledge, industry–university
sidering oneself engaged in cross-border competition links, entrepreneurship and venture capital, the Ger-
that is overlooked by conventional Ricardian trade man and Japanese cases highlight the importance of
theory and it is this: trade and other performance other mediating institutional variables such as public
statistics serve as valuable heuristics for helping na- governance of national research institutes (Whitley,
tional policy-makers to identify domestic institutions 2003), the autonomy of the university/research sector
in need of reform and as political leverage for pushing (Ben-David, 1971), and the historical role of the pub-
such reforms through. Competition between nations lic sector generally (Streeck and Yamamura, 2001).
or regions can serve as a stimulus to modernize and The crux of the matter is this. When biotechnol-
innovate institutionally (Dohse, 2000), to combat the ogy was found to require incentives for scientists to
institutional sclerosis decried by Olson (1982). Thus, engage in commercial activities such as patenting
when German policy-makers announced in 1995 and firm founding, countries like Germany and Japan
that Germany should try to become “number one in found themselves in a “public-sector bind.” This bind
Europe” in the life sciences by the end of the decade arose because the majority of top scientists were em-
(BMBF, 1996), the objective was not to “beat the UK” ployed in the public sector whose raison d’être was
but to reform the German R&D landscape. What fol- largely defined by its contrast to profit-motivated,
lows is essentially a study of “revealed comparative private-sector activity. Discussion of how German
institutional advantage” and its effects. and Japanese policy-makers attempted to cope with
Although the political economies of Germany and the “public-sector bind” is organized as follows. First,
Japan are rather different (Soskice, 1994; Streeck and a review of prior literature on the idiosyncrasies of
Yamamura, 2001), the two countries are often grouped biotech innovation clarifies the institutional difficul-
together on the basis of topical economic similari- ties that Germany and Japan faced. Second, some
ties, notably bank-based finance (Porter, 1992), high historical background on the university and research
levels of firm investment in human capital (Lazonick sectors of Germany and Japan is provided. Third, re-
and O’Sullivan, 1996), and even national systems of cent biotechnology policies in the two countries are
innovation (Patel and Pavitt, 1994). Undeniably, Ger- outlined, and fourth, the role of biotechnology pol-
many and Japan are linked by striking, partly coinci- icy as a motor for broader reform of national R&D
dental parallels in historical development, from late is discussed. The conclusion raises the question of
“catch-up” industrialization in the 19th century and whether recent developments are truly indicative of
authoritarian nationalism in the 1930s to post-WW2 a path towards longer-term success or whether even
economic “miracles” and unexpected stagnation in the broader institutional and societal changes, extend-
1990s. Not surprisingly, recent German and Japanese ing well beyond the R&D and educational system,
R&D policies to promote “catch-up” in biotechnology might be required for Germany and Japan to develop
exhibit significant parallels. vigorous biotechnology-based industries.
German and Japanese reforms to promote biotech- The patenting statistics in Fig. 1 give a basic indica-
nology are of both empirical and theoretical interest. tion of the German and Japanese lag in biotechnology
Empirically, biotechnology induced minor revolu- vis à vis the US in the 1990s. Germany and Japan also
tions in the R&D policies of both countries. Because lagged far behind the US in the number of biotech-
biotechnology was more dependent on basic scientific nology firms: whereas the US had over 1300 biotech
research than prior strategic technologies (e.g. semi- companies in the mid 1990s, Germany and Japan had
conductors), biotechnology catch-up policies required well under 100 each (BMBF, 1996: 42; Interministerial
fairly broad reforms in the national R&D system. Agreement, 1999). Table 1 indicates the importance
At a more theoretical level, these reforms shed new of start-up companies for patenting in biotechnology
light on the nature of innovation in biotechnology, and suggests that Germany and Japan were both overly
M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938 923

Fig. 1. Patenting intensity of US, UK, Japanese and German biotechnology.

Table 1 1. The idiosyncrasies of innovation in


Percentage of patents by institutional type, 1987–1993 biotechnology: a review
Technology Established Universities,
start-ups corporations research 1.1. Sectoral ecology
firms institutes
USA 40.4 38.1 20.7
In the biomedical sector, biotechnology innovation
UK 23.7 44.7 31.6
Germany 3.0 80.0 17.0 commonly involves a division of labor between new
Japan 3.1 86.9 10.0 technology-based firms (NTBFs) and large estab-
lished pharmaceutical companies. Explanations for
Source: Henderson et al. (1999).
the small–large firm mix include the vastly different
economics involved in the discovery as opposed to the
dependent on established firms for conducting R&D testing and commercialization of biotech therapeutics,
in biotech. By the mid 1990s, the need for start-up as well as differences between drug search activities,
firms to build an internationally competitive biotech more easily undertaken by large companies, and the
base had become manifest.2 search for new production techniques, which can be
German and Japanese policies to create more mastered by smaller firms (Henderson et al., 1999).
biotechnology start-ups illuminate the institutional In some ways, the presence of different firm sizes in
framework required by biotechnology. A brief review biotechnology fulfills a division of labor considered
of prior findings on the idiosyncrasies of biotechnol- to be natural under common economic conditions
ogy commercialization, besides facilitating compre- (Arrow, 1983; Gambardella, 1995).
hension of the issues that confronted policy-makers
in Germany and Japan, enables the identification of 1.2. Networks
important public-sector characteristics affecting the
rate of biotechnology innovation. Biotechnology has spawned extended networks
of relationships between pharmaceutical firms and
smaller biotech companies. A major factor behind
2 One possible interpretation of Table 1 is to attribute these leads
such networks is technological uncertainty (Powell
and lags in NTBFs to different “varieties of capitalism” (Casper
et al., 1999; Hall and Soskice, 2001) and comparative market
et al., 1996). Large pharmaceutical firms there-
institutions like venture capital. We return to the matter in the fore develop “portfolios” of relations to NTBFs in
conclusion. order to diversify and manage their risk (George
924 M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938

et al., 2001). Networks of inter-firm relations en- 1.5. Private appropriation of publicly funded
able especially the large companies to learn rapidly research
of emerging developments and to re-allocate re-
sources quickly among different technological ap- An important characteristic of the biotech sector
proaches as events unfold (Gambardella, 1995: is captured in a remark by Orsenigo (1989: 126–7)
Ch. 7). that “in a sense, the creation of a [biotech] company
was equivalent . . . to the establishment of a new de-
1.3. Importance of start-ups partment entirely devoted to the main interest of the
leading scientist and under his sole responsibility.”
Biotech NTBFs generally pursue particular prod- A pronounced idiosyncrasy of the biotech sector are
uct or process development techniques that had shown the dual hats worn by major scientists as contributors
promise of commercial applicability in the research to basic science and simultaneously as profit-driven
laboratory. The multiplicity of explorable approaches firm managers (Murray, 2002). Given the constantly
is high, giving rise to high “opportunity conditions” evolving state of knowledge, remaining in the scien-
(Malerba and Orsenigo, 1997). NTBFs are viable par- tific loop is a condition sine qua non for successful
ticipants because the current economics of biotech- biotech companies.
nology allow for low experimentation costs (Pavitt, Familiar though these facts are, they pose consider-
2001). Whereas novel production techniques in tra- able institutional stumbling blocks for policy-makers.
ditional industries are often pioneered on the shop The for-profit ventures of biotech scientists who re-
floor (“learning by doing”), new techniques of produc- main in their research positions create debate about
tion in biotech are frequently developed in a test-tube entitlements to the pecuniary gains of R&D commer-
environment. Pisano (1996) terms this “learning be- cialization. On the one hand, it can be claimed that
fore doing” and cites biotechnology as a prime ex- scientist–entrepreneurs effectively appropriate pub-
ample of a sector characterized by learning before licly funded research for private gain. Objections of
doing. this kind to technology start-ups are common in all
countries, including the US. There is, however, an
1.4. Link with basic science alternative way of viewing biotech start-ups by sci-
entists. According to this view, start-ups funded by
A fundamental characteristic of the biotechnology outside venture capital represent welcome additions
industry is its tight link to basic science (McMillan to the national science base at no additional cost to the
et al., 2000). Biotechnology confounds traditional public. To the extent the mission of publicly funded
distinctions between basic and applied science, just R&D is to provide positive knowledge externalities
as scientists at biotech companies regularly publish (Nelson, 1959), encouraging the formation of NTBFs
in leading scientific journals, academic scientists in- can be considered a legitimate way for policy-makers
volved in basic research regularly start their own to derive such externalities and to fund supplemental
firms and file key patents (Murray, 2002). The pri- R&D cost-effectively.
mary source of competitive advantage for US biotech In a nutshell, the politico-ideological challenge for
firms is usually considered to be the national science German and Japanese policy-makers was to make the
base (Orsenigo, 1989; Pavitt, 2001). Studies in the transition from the former to the latter way of viewing
geography of biotech lend additional support to this biotech start-ups. Part of the interest of the German
view. Not only did Zucker et al. (1998) find a tight and Japanese catch-up policies is the implicit per-
distribution of NTBFs around star scientists, but the spective they provide on the institutional advantage of
residual effect of venture capital actually appeared the US and UK. The US biotech advantage has been
to be negative. Of particular interest to German and attributed to the “closer integration between industry
Japanese policy-makers was the fact that biotechnol- and the academic community” in the US (Henderson
ogy start-ups tend to cluster around research insti- et al., 1999: 306). The present research is consistent
tutions, especially universities (Swann and Prevezer, with this statement, though in a specific sense. The US
1996). advantage does not inhere in different communication
M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938 925

patterns, but in different institutional patterns. In parisons of German–Japanese patterns of institutional


particular, the US institutional advantage appears to evolution in the volume by Streeck and Yamamura
derive from the fact that its universities and scientists (2001).
were not nearly as much part and parcel of public-
sector institutions as their German and Japanese 2.1. Elements of historical continuity
counterparts. American universities were more on the
In both countries, industrial development preceded
“non-profit” border between the public and private sec-
political liberalism. Industrialization was encouraged
tors (an analogous argument could be made for certain
by a governing elite as a means of achieving national
highly autonomous elite universities in the UK like
security and self-sufficiency. To this end, the gov-
Cambridge and Oxford). This made it inherently eas-
erning elite conferred special privileges on specific
ier for American (and British) scientists to jump into
social groups whose cooperation was important—in
private science-based ventures than for German and
Japan, to private corporations (often privatized after
Japanese scientists whose behavior was more narrowly
starting out as state enterprises), which were consti-
circumscribed by public-sector regulations and norms.
tuted as tight-knit social communities dedicated to in-
dustrial expansion; in Germany, to labor and industry
2. The public-sector status of universities and associations whose ancestry dates back to medieval
research centers guilds. To this day, Germany and Japan are referred
to as “corporatist” countries, yet the use of a com-
mon term is misleading because the “corporations” in
German and Japanese universities are, for slightly
the Japanese case are vertically integrated joint-stock
different reasons, dominated by the effects of
companies-qua-social-communities whereas the “cor-
public-sector governance. In Germany, the over-
porations” in the German case are horizontally orga-
whelming majority of universities are state-funded
nized producer groups, i.e. industry associations and
and state-controlled; only a few small private col-
industry-specific labor unions (Ziegler, 1997).
leges exist. Though private universities are common
Yet in both national variants, “corporatism” casts
in Japan, most are fairly impoverished tuition-funded
the public sector as the highest authority in a social hi-
schools (aside from a small number of leading private
erarchy. For the state to be a dispenser of social privi-
universities), while the publicly funded national uni-
leges, the public sector requires at least the aura (if not
versities, with vastly better resources for conducting
always the reality) of independence from private inter-
research, account for at least 75% of university R&D
ests. In both countries civil servants enjoyed substan-
(Kneller, 2003a: 357). This is in marked contrast to
tial status and autonomy, and a traditional role of the
the US, where private elite universities play a leading
universities was to select and train the nation’s most
role in the American research landscape and exert
qualified individuals for civil service; certain Japanese
competitive pressures on state universities to emulate
elite universities to this day conserve some of this
private-university practices. In both Germany and
heritage.
Japan, state control deeply conditions the functioning
The university systems in both Germany and Japan
of the university system, either directly as in Ger-
have traditionally been divorced from commercial
many or more indirectly as in Japan, where the vast
interests and, indeed, relatively divorced from other
regulating and funding powers of the education min-
sectors of society (Swinbanks, 1995; Kocka, 1999).3
istry exert considerable control even over the private
universities (Cummings et al., 1979). 3 This fact may seem surprising given the prominent role played
While understanding traditions of public-sector by university professors in the 19th-century German dyestuffs
governance in these countries’ universities and re- industry, which, however, was rather an anomaly. The clearest
search centers requires a certain historical review, the manifestation of this is that Germany’s universities in the 19th
mix of historical continuity and discontinuity in both century ferociously opposed the right of the polytechnic colleges
to award PhDs—precisely because the application-oriented nature
countries makes providing a brief synopsis difficult. of polytechnic education was seen as tainting “pure” science.
The following separation of components of continuity The objections of the universities were overridden by personal
and discontinuity is heavily indebted to in-depth com- intervention of the Kaiser in 1899.
926 M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938

Nonetheless, the autarkic nature of the academic form since the late 1960s has been to cope with broad
community in both countries follows logically from social demands, not specific economic challenges
corporatist forms of organization and privileges con- (Teichler, 1996). Germany’s universities, formerly
ferred on special social groups in return for basic somewhat elitist, were opened to any graduate of a
loyalty to the state. In Germany, academic freedom German Gymnasium. Free-tuition enrollment at Ger-
(Lehrfreiheit) was an age-old privilege of professors man universities swelled, but without commensurate
whose collective “mandarin” identity entailed sub- increases in university funding, so that class sizes
stantial social distance from commerce and the indus- swelled as well (Buechtemann and Vogler-Ludwig,
trial class (Ringer, 1983). While Japan’s universities 1996). The transition to mass education was in some
date only from the 1870s as part of a general effort ways even more drastic in Japan, which financed
to catch up with Western science and knowledge, expansion of the university system on the cheap by
Japanese academics quickly grasped the German idea allowing the expansion of private colleges to meet the
of academic freedom and in the early part of the 20th demand for higher education. Most tuition-funded col-
century were quick to assert their autonomy. leges lack the means to fund major research projects.
As in Germany, academics in Japan were unable Post-war Germany and Japan deepened the in-
to withstand the nationalist authoritarianism of the stitutional divide between education and research
1930s (Marshall, 1992). However, Japanese professors by creating specialized research institutes. Germany
re-asserted their social autonomy after the war, and entrusted research in several biotechnology-related
their interaction with the private sector was quite lim- areas to Max-Planck and Helmholtz institutes, gener-
ited. Indeed, the main economic function of post-war ally with joint funding from Land and federal levels.
Japanese universities has been to screen talented indi- Japanese counterparts include RIKEN (Institute of
viduals through grueling entrance examinations; the Physical and Chemical Research) and the National
real training of employees took place within large Institute of Genetics. To be sure, the move toward
firms, which were little concerned with the content of specialized research institutes to cope with new scien-
academic curricula (Jolivet, 1985). Given the relative tific sub-fields was not unique to Germany and Japan
autarky of universities, Japanese professors have by (Whitley, 2003).4 Nor was the development entirely
and large focused their energies on research, though discontinuous: on the eve of World War I, Germany
academic research has not always been especially founded its first Kaiser Wilhelm Institutes in chem-
international in scope (Shimbori, 1979; Kitamura, istry and physics, later transformed into Max Planck
1985). Institutes (Ben-David, 1971).

2.2. Elements of historical discontinuity The public-sector orientation of national education


and research created a series of institutional obstacles
Germany and Japan accomplished their successful to the commercialization of basic research:
transitions to democracy not by dismantling their re-
spective types of “corporatism” but by broadening 2.3. Intellectual property rights
them to include larger segments of the population
(Streeck, 2001). For example, the German welfare While professors in both countries could patent
state essentially involved extending corporatist modes discoveries made using their own institutional base
of social service provision to virtually all members of funds, this privilege disappeared in the case of external
society, while Japanese corporate social communities
proved able to assimilate Western-style labor unions. 4 For additional information on why US universities were

With respect to universities and research centers, fairly unique on being able to integrate new emerging scientific
historical discontinuity in some ways deepened the fields while most European countries instead founded special-
public-sector orientation of research institutions. The ized research institutes, see Ben-David (1971) and Mowery and
Rosenberg (1998). The latter book, to which an anonymous re-
transition from elitist to mass higher education in both viewer called the authors’ attention, cites a SPRU working paper
countries was accompanied by often violent student (Sharp, 1989) that coincides with much of our general argument
protests, and the major thrust of higher education re- about public-sector science (1998: 36).
M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938 927

funding, weakening incentives for professors—or any- their jobs defined as the production of public goods;
one else—to pursue commercially promising leads neither they nor the institutions that employed them
emerging from larger research projects (Abramson had ever taken more than a peripheral interest in com-
et al., 1997: 300; Kneller, 2003a). According to mercial revenue. Technology licensing organizations
Japanese law, inventions arising under government- (TLOs) at universities did not begin to emerge until
sponsored research projects belonged to the nation; the mid 1990s in Germany and the late 1990s in Japan
researchers had little incentive to see their discoveries (Abramson et al., 1997; Kneller, 2003a).
classified as National Inventions, which in practice
was often “equivalent to the technology slipping into
a black hole” (Kneller, 2003a: 383). While Japanese 3. Basic principles of recent German and
researchers could and did obfuscate their funding Japanese biotech policies
sources so as to circumvent National Invention classi-
fication, the “Sword of Damocles” threat of such clas- 3.1. Indicators of “technology gaps”
sification was detrimental in areas like biotechnology
where clear exclusive intellectual rights are needed Policy-makers in Germany and Japan had no-
to encourage private-sector investment in promising ticed a growing biotech gap in the 1980s, but by the
early-stage inventions (Kneller, 2003a: 432). In Ger- 1990s awareness of US domination in biotech be-
many the intellectual property rights situation was not came acute. Indicators of the gap went beyond just
much better, as the government was entitled to a vary- the already-mentioned differences in start-up activity.
ing share of revenues generated from publicly funded The German government’s own official technology
research.5 Just as importantly, little infrastructure ex- report of 1996 noted that biotech patenting in the
isted to help scientists or their research institutions years 1987–94 had increased by 120% in the US,
explore patenting options (Abramson et al., 1997). but only by 16% in Germany; the US had over 300
genetic-engineering production facilities in 1994, but
2.4. Employment rigidities Germany only nine (BMBF, 1996: 42). However,
German policy-makers were convinced that the gap
Differences between public- and private-sector em- lay more in commercialization than in basic science,
ployment conditions made it difficult for public-sector citing R&D spending levels, Nobel prizes, and repu-
employees to manage private-sector enterprises. In tational studies as evidence of high-quality German
Japan, professors at the national universities were for- research capabilities (BMBF, 1996: 42, 208).
bidden to serve on or start private companies because In Japan, in contrast, both the basic science base
of their civil servant status; in Germany, professors and commercialization rates were considered deficient
could devote up to 20% of their time to outside ac- (JBIF, 1999). The number of individuals engaged in
tivities, yet dual public–private appointments were genome research was only about 8000 in Japan, com-
nearly impossible for staff, with mobility between the pared to about 71,000 in the US and 64,000 in the
public and private sector rendered difficult by dis- EU. Japan produced only 200 PhDs per year in biol-
parate regulatory regimes in job security, promotion, ogy, compared to 6000 in the US (Nakazawa, 2000).
and social security coverage. In addition, the US competitive advantage was much
more broadly based. In Japan, large firms continued
2.5. Institutional incentives to dominate the patenting process for pharmaceuti-
cals (Thomas III, 2001; Kneller, 2003b). Thus, 86% of
the total biotechnology patent applications came from
Perhaps the deepest obstacle to biotechnology
large firms. This was the mirror opposite of the US,
entrepreneurship was simply that most academic re-
where the bulk of total patent applications in biotech-
search scientists, employed in the public sector, had
nology were from universities, research institutions
5 The exact share depended on the classification of research and venture firms (JPO, 2000).
institution involved and level of government funding. For specifics, Policy-makers in both countries identified biotech-
see Abramson et al. (1997). nology as a key strategic technology for the 21st
928 M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938

Fig. 2. Comparative patenting in genomics.

century with a limited time window of opportunity. effort involved a broader coalition of ministries and
German government-sponsored Delphi studies of the agencies. The formulation of an overarching policy
1990s suggested that by 2020 biotechnology would framework—the “Basic Policy Towards Creation of
contribute about half of the top 30 most important a Biotechnology Industry” of 1999—required agree-
innovations (BMBF, 1996: 208). Such forecasts were ment among five ministries—the Directorate General
familiar to Japanese policy-makers as well,6 who of the Science and Technology Agency, the Ministry
were in addition concerned about a Western patent of Education, the Ministry of Health and Welfare, the
blockade in genetics. A special concern of Japanese Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries and the
R&D reformers was to induce scientists to patent and Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI).7
stem the kind of genomics patenting rout indicated in Thus, whereas biotechnology reform in Germany was
Fig. 2. a fairly quiet bottom-up and compartmentalized pro-
cess (leading ultimately to minor rather than major
3.2. Foci of German and Japanese biotechnology R&D reform), in Japan more top-level consultation
policies and political management was involved (and entailed
a more radical effort to reform the national R&D
In both Germany and Japan, the focus of biotech system).
policies was on producing a new class of high-tech
actor: the “networked scientist–entrepreneur.” Con- 3.3. German biotechnology policies
vinced that the networked scientist–entrepreneur was
an indispensable element in the technological regime German biotech policy focused on encouraging
of biotechnology, policy makers endeavored to enrich start-ups to cluster around existing research institu-
the institutional and economic resources available to tions. The so-called BioRegio competition of 1995
scientists. The German policy-makers were essen- (Dohse, 2000) awarded prize money to regions offer-
tially officials in the Federal Research and Education ing the best regional biotechnology commercializa-
Ministry (BMBF), with some input from the Eco- tion networks. In the BMBF’s words, the competition
nomics Ministry (BMW). In contrast, the Japanese
7 The titles of some ministries are abbreviated here for the sake
6 The German survey instrument was a virtual translation of of brevity and familiarity. For instance, the Minister of Education
the Delphi survey funded by the Science and Technology Agency is actually the Minister of Education, Culture, Sports, Science and
(STA) in Japan (Cuhls et al. (1995)). Technology. The fuller titles are given in some instances below.
M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938 929

was “to provide an incentive to induce regional Table 2


cooperation among scientific research institutions Therapeutic product pipeline of UK and German public companies,
mid-2001
from the public and private sectors, venture capital-
ists, banks, local support programs, and regulatory Preclinical Phase I Phase II Phase III Total
agencies” (BMBF, 1996: 43). There were two rea- United 32 37 46 13 128
sons for choosing the novel policy instrument of Kingdom
an interregional competition rather than direct fund- Germany 2 2 1 1 6
ing. The first was limited federal funds. The second Source: Ernst and Young.
was that the Länder controlled the universities and
partial funding of many research centers, thus favor-
ing devolution of policy implementation to regional in stock market value and no other German biotech
levels. start-up comes close (Ernst and Young, 2002).
In response to the BioRegio competition, 17 re-
gional biotechnology offices sprang into existence. 3.4. Japanese biotech policies
These were technology parks in which the public
sector provided services normally associated with While Japan’s “Basic Policy Towards Creation
the private sector (Casper, 2000). The biotechnology of a Biotechnology Industry” of 1999 did mention
offices offered German scientists help in writing busi- the importance of NTBFs (and set a target of 1000
ness plans, guidance on financing options and mar- biotechnology start-ups by 2010), the starting point
keting assistance for their start-ups. They subsidized was Japan’s belated entry into the international patent
patenting activities as well. In essence, the regional race. The following excerpt from the Basic Policy
offices taught German scientists how to appropriate expresses the Japanese worry about being shut out of
their discoveries. a major 21st century industry:
The BioRegio competition was seen as a signif-
In recent years, governments in Europe and North
icant policy success (Casper, 2000; Dohse, 2000).
America have rapidly enhanced initiatives for re-
Virtually all of the biotechnology offices became
search and development of biotechnology and for
permanent installations as Germany experienced a
promotion of industries related thereto, while devel-
take-off in biotech start-ups. As foreseen, the majority
oping legal systems, etc. related to life sciences. In
of start-ups clustered around German universities and
consideration of the finite organic generic resources
research centers (Casper and Kettler, 2001).8 From
and heavy investment for patenting in Europe and
about 75 biotech firms in 1995 Germany counted 222
the USA, the coming few years seem to be a very
by 1998 and 379 by the end of 2002, according to an-
important period for developing foundations for fu-
nual surveys of Ernst and Young. A milestone along
ture development of the industry . . . The ministries
the way was that Germany actually surpassed the UK
and agencies concerned should drastically reinforce
in the number of biotech firms in 1999 (Ernst and
their initiatives for accelerated promotion of indus-
Young, 2000). Nonetheless, Germany remains far be-
trialization utilizing genome information for which
hind the UK in the development of therapeutic drugs
the coming few years are very critical, in order to
(see Table 2) and most of the German NTBFs are
industrialize biotechnology intensively and swiftly.
very small; only one German biotech NTBF figures
(Interministerial Agreement, 1999)
among the eight largest European biotech companies
As discussed, public-sector obstacles stood in the way
8 The Martinsried biotechnology center outside Munich exem- of university professors engaging in commercial ac-
plifies the German biotech boom. In 1973, a Max Planck Insti- tivities and, in addition, the performance evaluation
tute for biochemistry was built. A decade later, the University of system in Japanese academia failed to include patents
Munich added a center for genetic research to the village. In the as an index of achievement.
wake of the BioRegio competition, Martinsried was designated the
Munich center for biotech start-ups. Within 5 years Martinsried
The Basic Policy vowed to change all this and
housed over 50 biotech companies and more than 1000 biotech some of its objectives were subsequently realized in
employees, constituting a major European biotech center. the Strengthening Industrial Technology bill, which
930 M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938

passed the legislature in April 2000. The new law qualitative improvements of the research base. Quan-
allowed faculty in national universities to assume titatively, despite scanty overall fiscal resources, the
management positions in companies established to Basic Policy committed the government to fund more
develop their technologies; to work after hours with competitive research, new bioinformatics institutes,
pay; and to take up to three years off to commercial- and more doctoral stipends. Qualitatively, policy
ize their discoveries and still return to their faculty called for more “networking” among national actors
position (Kneller, 2000). in the sector—“We will work on the improvement and
Concurrently with the formulation of the Basic Pol- networking of Japanese research organizations . . .
icy, Japanese lawmakers approved measures allowing We will promote greater cooperation among indus-
universities to set up their own Technology Licensing try, academic circles and government by improving
Organizations (TLOs). The Japanese TLO law passed the information flow of research results to promote
in August 1998. Virtually all major universities took commercialization...” (Interministerial Agreement,
immediate advantage of the TLO law.9 In the case of 1999).
CASTI (the TLO of the University of Tokyo), the pro- The Japanese Government installed a national
portion of biotechnology-related technology transfer biotechnology panel in July 2002 to supervise policy
was quite high as early as 2000—52% of marketed implementation. The Biotechnology Strategy Council
technologies; six out of seven licensed technologies; is headed by Dr. Kishimoto, President of Osaka Uni-
and six out of eight nearly contracted technologies versity, and it includes Prime Minister Koizumi and
(Takada, 2000). A number of problems nonetheless six of his key ministers as well as a dozen experts
plague Japanese TLOs at this time (Kneller, 2003a). from medical, academic and business circles. A set
The effects of the TLO law were enhanced by pas- of strategic objectives included an action plan for
sage in 1999 of the “Special Law for Revitalizing development of technology capabilities to the year
Industry.” The effective equivalent of the Bayh–Dole 2010 and guidelines for the use of genetic engineer-
act in the US, the law resolved the question of own- ing in food products. Further strategic goals include
ership of government-sponsored research in favor of attaining a 25 trillion yen market for biotech-related
the consigned researchers and was especially advanta- products and a doubling of the government’s R&D
geous for private universities (as well as private com- budget for biotechnology within 5 years.
panies). All these measures, flanked by grants, loans
and equity financing to start-ups from various govern-
ment agencies, have generated a certain momentum in 4. Biotechnology policy as a motor of broader
changing the habits of university scientists. Patenting, R&D reform
working in firms, and even founding enterprises are
no longer the unheard-of activities that they largely In both Germany and Japan, recent biotechnology
used to be among Japanese professors. By 2002, there policies were part and parcel of broader reforms in the
were several Japanese biomedical investment capi- national R&D system. The institutional requirements
tal funds (Kneller, 2003b). From only about 60 total of biotechnology were basically incompatible with the
biotech venture companies in 1995 (Interministerial existing framework of public-sector science, necessi-
Agreement, 1999), Japan counted 334 by the end of tating reform. More broadly, however, R&D reform
2002 (Japan Bioindustry Association, 2003), exactly was a response to relatively poor economic perfor-
one-third of the Basic Policy’s target of 1000 by 2010. mance in these countries during the 1990s, prompting
Beyond encouraging commercialization of biotech, greater departures from prior technology policies.
the Basic Policy envisaged both quantitative and While the originality and success of the BioRegio
competition are well documented, less well-known are
the ramifications of this competition for the overall
9 A partial list of universities that quickly moved to establish
R&D policies pursued by the Federal Research and
TLOs include Holkkaido U., Tohoku U., Tsukuba U., U. of Tokyo,
Nihon U., Waseda U., Keio U., Tokyo Denki U., Tokyo Institute
Education Ministry (BMBF). Prior to the mid 1990s,
of Technology, Yamanashi U., Nagoya U., Kyoto U., Kobe U., this highly endowed ministry (1999 budget: 5.3 billion
Yamaguchi U. and Kyushu U. Euro) had primarily funded R&D as a public good,
M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938 931

leaving commercialization largely in the hands of the IT) and transform their knowledge faster into new
private sector. Occasional forays into the commercial market products” (BMBF, 1996: 28). The basic thrust
realm, such as subsidizing German computer compa- of the section can be divined from the titles of the
nies in the 1970s, had proven to be failures, while sub-sections (Table 3). Many proclamations were,
ideologically and politically the involvement of the compared with traditional German technology pol-
BMBF in commercial activities always risked putting icy, fairly novel, especially the depiction of private
it at odds with the Economics Ministry, which by tra- spin-offs by public-sector scientists as a natural exten-
dition since Ludwig Erhard (the Economics Minister sion of national R&D and, more generally, the view
from 1949 to 1963, credited with Germany’s “eco- of scientists as central technology transfer agents re-
nomic miracle”) has been a bastion of market liber- quiring stronger individual incentives to engage in
alism in Germany (Stucke, 1993).10 In other words, commercialization.
within the German context, an ideology of market lib- Another significant shift involved policies for small-
eralism long had the effect of reinforcing boundaries to medium-sized firms (SMEs). The BMBF’s tradi-
between the public and private sector. For example, in tional programs to help SMEs involved earmarking a
the German high-tech crisis of the early 1990s (col- certain amount of funding for R&D projects in which
lapse of major domestic computer companies, stag- SMEs participated. Promotion of start-ups had never
nation in semiconductors and electronics) the BMBF been more than a peripheral BMBF objective and had
rejected strong public pressure to emulate MITI—as never been considered part of its policies for SMEs.
MITI was understood in the West at the time—as a na- In the 1996 manifesto, SME policy now emphasized
tional agency of central strategic technology guidance start-ups. Just as telling was the description of the new
(Reister, 1995). policy for start-ups as Mittelstand policy (Table 3).
Nonetheless, concurrently with the BioRegio com- The German Mittelstand is usually associated with
petition, the BMBF was formulating a fundamental established medium-sized family-owned firms, espe-
reorientation of technology policy, now conceived cially those occupying high-margin specialized niches
as “innovation policy” and called the Innovation ‘96 using highly skilled labor. To describe its policy for
initiative (BMBF, 1996: 29). The public manifesto of technology start-ups as Mittelstand policy involved the
this initiative was contained in the Federal Research retroactive fitting of old terms (Mittelstand) into a new
Report of 1996, normally a dutiful but dull catalogue context (NTBFs) that reflected the ministry’s radically
of the ministry’s funding activities issued every 3–4 increased emphasis on technology start-ups.
years. The front end of the 1996 report struck a num- While not the only technology area affected by
ber of new notes with no equivalent in either the R&D reform, biotechnology was evidently the prime
preceding (1993) or following (2000) versions of the driver of reform. First, in the section of the 1996 mani-
report. The Minister’s opening letter evoked the dras- festo devoted to specific “future-oriented” R&D areas
tic unemployment problem, the “alarming” stagnation (Section 4), biotech is discussed first, ahead of IT,
of German R&D, and the need for fundamental system energy, environment, and transportation. Second, the
changes, most specifically in the commercial exploita- BioRegio competition served as a model for further in-
tion of German research capabilities (BMBF, 1996: 1). terregional competitions designed to promote start-ups
The R&D policy reorientations were formulated (Wilson and Souitaris, 2002). For example, the EXIST
in a section entitled “From Research to Innovation” initiative (co-sponsored by the BMBF and the Eco-
that began with the announcement—“Important com- nomics Ministry) awarded prize money to the best pro-
petitors in the Triad have made greater progress in posals for university-based entrepreneurial regional
new technologies (microelectronics, biotechnology, networks. The federal government was able to solicit
109 proposals from over 200 out of 326 total German
universities and colleges, another policy success. A
10 The Economics Minister was frequently a member of the
Multimedia Start-up Competition was similarly orga-
liberal Free Democratic Party (FDP). Yet even when the FDP
was not in the governing coalition, other parties generally put a
nized, and in biotechnology another interregional con-
free-marketer into this post. For example, during the 1998–2002 test, the BioProfile competition (1999–2001), funded
term, the Economics Minister was a party-unaffiliated businessman. the top four of 20 proposals to develop regional
932 M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938

Table 3
Sub-section headings and excerpts from the Federal Research Report, 1996, Section 2.3 (“from research to innovation”)
Lead projects as an element of research, technology and innovation promotion
Building of innovative networks between public science and the private sector . . .
Including research institutes in the innovation process as partners and technological service providers
The flexibility of state research institutes will be raised through introduction of private-sector organizational forms and incentives. . .
Initiative to found and promote NTBFs
Market access through the founding of new firms is a dynamic element of structural change . . . . The federal government therefore
views a consistent policy of strengthening market forces and the opening and keeping-open of markets as a central component of
its policies for the Mittelstand . . .
Provision of innovation capital (i.e. venture capital)
Support of SMEs in the new federal states (i.e. in East Germany)
Support of spin-offs from research institutes
The founding of NTBFs through employees of research institutes (“spin-offs”) is an important method for transforming R&D
results into industrial application . . . but the potential for spin-offs to date has only been partially exploited . . .
Patent promotion
The planned support of SMEs in their initial patent applications rests on the general realization that SMEs often possess
patent-relevant inventions but fail to apply not only because of economic considerations, but because of ignorance or reservations
about the effort and expense. These firms need to be guided to the patent system; especially their nervousness needs to be
overcome. Only personal experience with the patent system will help them increase their applications . . .
Technology transfer
Scientists themselves must be motivated to make the technology transfer of their knowledge succeed . . . (we will set up) transfer
organizations to assist scientists with contracts, patents, licensing, marketing, invention issues, and building up contacts . . .
Source: BMBF (1996: 28-34).

networks of specific biotech expertise, e.g. “functional form was actually fairly narrow. This is shown by the
genome analysis” in Southern Lower Saxony. contrast with Japan. German R&D reform enabled
Helped by the Internet boom and the numerous scientists to wear a second hat as entrepreneurs but left
government initiatives to promote NTBFs, Germany the system of conducting basic science more or less
experienced a brief explosion of high-tech start-ups unchanged. In contrast, recent biotechnology policies
generally in the years 1996–2000. A low-cap stock in Japan accompanied a tectonic shift in the whole
market, the Neuer Markt, was launched in early 1997 system of public science. The Japanese government
and by early 2000 listed over 300 companies with is endeavoring not merely to improve the commer-
a total market capitalization of some 200 billion cialization of scientific discoveries, but also to raise
Euro at its peak (Lehrer, 2000). After mid-2000, the the productivity and international competitiveness of
Neuer Markt collapsed and was closed in September the Japanese science base. Whereas German R&D
2002. Interestingly, the least novel aspect of German reform essentially added an entrepreneurial layer on
high-tech policy in the 1990s was venture capital; the top of the existing public-sector science system, Japan
German government (in particular the BMBF) had is committed to substantial administrative reform of
funded substantial programs to inject venture capital Japanese science altogether.
into NTBFs since the 1980s (Kulicke, 1997). More- Japan is in the process of converting its national
over, the often-cited lack of venture capital overlooks universities and national research laboratories into
the fact that venture capitalists since the 1980s had self-governing Independent Administrative Institu-
long combed the German landscape for lucrative tions (IAIs) and subjecting them to more competitive
business ideas but failed to find viable enterprises pressures. Ongoing reforms will remove these insti-
(Wupperfeld, 1997; Lehrer, 2000). tutions from direct ministry control and civil service
Despite these improvements in the German employment regulations while imposing more strin-
high-tech landscape, the scope of German R&D re- gent external evaluation to encourage internationally
M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938 933

oriented research and measurable R&D results. The the nuts and bolts of R&D policy to the overall outlook
new rules will also permit merit-based salary increases of society:
rather than the age-related salary scales that have pre-
In promoting S&T to make Japan into the nation
vailed hitherto. The first change of status began with
it aims to become, we must adopt and implement
several dozen national research labs converted into
S&T policies formed on the basis of how they re-
IAIs in 2001. The planning of administrative auton-
late to society. As S&T holds true value only if
omy for universities, involving many rather complex
accepted by society, society’s understanding, judg-
questions, is still ongoing at the time of writing, with
ment, and acceptance of S&T are crucial. This is a
the first conversion of national universities into IAIs
point to be recognized and striven for not only by
scheduled for 2004.
the natural scientists and technological experts, but
The overall framework for reform is set forth in
by experts in the social sciences and humanities as
the Second Science and Technology Basic Plan of
well (Government of Japan, 2001).
2001–2005. (A First Basic Plan of 1996–2000 was
comparatively modest in scope.) The Second S&T Such a declaration is less conceivable in Western coun-
Basic Plan calls for Japan to become a top con- tries, including Germany; technology doubters are
tributor to the world’s scientific knowledge; major numerous in Germany and enjoy powerful political
goals include creating more Nobel Prize winners representation in the Green Party. The Japanese gov-
and promoting powerful linkage mechanisms among ernment, in contrast, has elected to face technology
firms, universities and government to develop future foes (including humanities professors and students)
industries. in head-on fashion. Thus, the S&T plan harps on
The plan establishes clear science and technol- “the need for human wisdom to integrate the natural
ogy (S&T) priorities for R&D funding. The four sciences with social sciences and the humanities”
top-priority S&T fields chosen are—(1) Life Sciences; (Government of Japan, 2001).
(2) ICT [Information and Communications Technolo- There are several reasons for believing that biotech-
gies]; (3) Environmental Sciences; (4) Nanotechnol- nology is the most important driver of Japanese R&D
ogy and Materials. Notably assigned to merely the reform. The life sciences are mentioned first among
second tier of S&T fields is manufacturing technol- the four top S&T priorities and biotechnology is the
ogy, “the very source of Japan’s economic power” most frequently mentioned S&T area throughout the
(Government of Japan, 2001). In fact, the plan is document; furthermore, biotechnology is a component
quite explicit about the need for Japan to create “new of all three other high-priority S&T areas (ICT, en-
knowledge bases” for its economy and to evolve into vironment, nanotechnology). Just as significantly, the
a science-based society. life sciences constitute the only S&T area in which
The S&T Basic Plan of 2001–2005 addresses R&D Japan is recognized as lagging far behind North Amer-
reform within the context of large-scale social chal- ica and Europe; the S&T plan describes Japan as ba-
lenges like an aging population, security risks, and sically at parity in the other three top-priority S&T
sustainable development. Table 4 lists the general and areas. Finally, the S&T plan refers repeatedly to the
specific goals in the overall “vision of Japan” artic- challenge of Japan’s aging population and the poten-
ulated in the document. The odd combination of vi- tial of biotechnology to help respond to this challenge.
sionary declarations and specific R&D goals is held Unlike German R&D reform, which was confined
together by the central goal of permeating Japanese mainly to a single ministry at the margins of gov-
society with scientific thinking: “The nation will have ernmental decision-making, recent Japanese R&D
to prepare an atmosphere where the scientific view, reform is quite central to national policy. This is sig-
scientific way of thinking, and scientific mind are naled by the establishment of the Council for Science
highly valued; and to build a knowledge-based soci- and Technology Policy (CSTP) in 2001. The CSTP is
ety that nurtures talented persons who can create new chaired by the Prime Minister, counts six ministers as
knowledge” (Government of Japan, 2001). members along with several top Japanese professors,
In fact, the 2001–2005 S&T plan clearly betrays a science officials, and two business executives. The
certain heritage of elite guidance that extends beyond CSTP is one of four major advisory councils in the
934 M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938

Table 4
“Vision of Japan” in the science and technology plan 2001–2005, Section 1.2
1. A nation that contributes to the world by creating and using scientific knowledge
Firstly, a nation that creates new knowledge by clarifying unknown phenomena and discovering new scientific laws and principles; and
secondly, a nation that copes with various problems by utilizing accumulated knowledge . . .
More specifically, the goal is to create outstanding R&D results and to disseminate them widely across to the world, for example, by
publishing a profusion of excellent papers . . . by providing centers of excellence that attract outstanding foreign researchers, and by
producing just as many Nobel Prize winning scientists as the most technologically advanced European countries (some European
countries have produced as many as 30 Nobel laureates in the last 50 years)
2. An internationally competitive nation capable of sustainable development
A nation that can improve people’s living standards and maintain vitality for sustainable economic growth and international
competitiveness by overcoming current difficulties . . . Industrial technological power is not merely a foundation of international
competitiveness for Japanese companies, but a driving force to vitalize all industrial activities that support people’s lives . . .
More specifically, the goal is to strengthen international competitiveness by widely transferring R&D results from public research
organizations to private companies, by proposing various international standards, by further increasing the number of international
patents obtained, and by improving industrial productivity
3. A safe, secure nation where people enjoy a high quality of life
A nation that reliably assures safe and high-quality living for its people. Such a nation serves its people by: improving disease
treatments and prevention to maximize its citizens’ chances for a long and healthy life; minimizing the risks posed by natural and
artificial disasters . . .
The specific goals are to form S&T bases to analyze genetically caused diseases and develop tailor-made medical therapies for their
treatment, to minimize damage from natural disasters such as earthquakes and typhoons, and to secure stable supplies of
high-quality foods by applying biotechnology, whilst minimizing the possible risks of S&T
Source: Government of Japan (2001).

Prime Minister’s so-called Cabinet Office. To date, dividuals who could advance the technological frontier
the Council has already conducted several “summits” rather than merely learn the state-of-the-art through
to facilitate networking among industry, academia traditional study (Cummings, 1991; Haiducek, 1991).
and government at all levels—national, regional, and A major thrust of the Science and Technology Ba-
local. A major task of the Council is to overcome or at sic Plan, in fact, concerns measures to promote the
least palliate ministerial sectionalism within the gov- efforts of young researchers: better career tracks to
ernment, which is considered a major impediment to enable young researchers to get started, better oppor-
the creation of new industries such as biotechnology. tunities for young researchers with creative ideas to
The CSTP acts as advocate for university reform, gain access to competitive project funds, and further
including reform of private universities, which com- reforms of R&D project evaluation methods to iden-
prise nearly 80 percent of all universities in Japan. tify proposals with scientific breakthrough potential.
Fostering the creation of academia-industry networks
(a major priority of the 2001–2005 S&T plan) is a spe-
cific charge of the Council. Indeed, recent Japanese 5. Final comments: is it enough to reform
policies for biotechnology and R&D represent a first national R&D?
peak in a slow decade-long effort to improve connec-
tions between higher education and industry in Japan. The R&D reforms outlined above undoubt-
Traditionally, industry and government, students and edly helped spark a wave of firm foundings in
parents alike had passively accepted the gap between biotechnology—several hundred new biotech firms
what students learned at the university and genuinely in both nations. Yet doubts must always be raised
useful job skills. Yet even during the booming late about the long-term efficacy of taxpayer-sponsored
1980s it had become apparent to policy-makers that as activism. While biotechnology subsidies are no doubt
Japanese science and technology had all but fulfilled unlike agricultural subsidies, there is no doubt that
the program of “catching up” with the West, the educa- biotechnology has become—even with the active
tional system would have to produce more creative in- participation of private venture capital—a subsidized
M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938 935

activity. As of this writing, the largest biotechnology contrast, the Japanese conversion of R&D institutions
companies in Germany and Japan are not the recent into independent administration institutions testifies to
start-ups. Germany’s largest biotech company, Qia- more than just incremental reform effort. This is not to
gen (headquartered in Holland) was founded in the say that every element in the government’s Basic S&T
1980s; a maker of “platform technologies,” its mar- Plan of 2001–5 is immune to skepticism: in perusing
ket capitalization of roughly 3 billion Euro has been the document, one can hardly refrain from wonder-
almost ten times as large as the next largest Ger- ing whether the government’s rhetoric on behalf of
man biotech company (Ernst and Young, 2002). In “science” reflects, in part, an embarrassing lack of
Japan, too, the largest biotech operations tend not to more focused policy responses to difficult questions.
be recent start-ups, but older divisions or ventures of One can imagine that if Germany and Japan develop
established companies, especially of pharmaceutical thriving biotechnology industries, then it will be more
firms and distillers with special fermentation skills because of diffuse institutional side-effects of policy
(Ernst and Young, 2002). than of specific measures to assist biotech companies.
It is therefore important to raise certain critical What may, in the longer run, turn out to be more
questions, particularly for the sake of tracking future important than the initial programs of biotechnology
progress in German and Japanese biotechnology. Two sponsorship is the weakening of boundaries between
related questions will be briefly considered. The first the public and private sector—the opening-up, as it
is whether R&D reform in Germany and Japan goes were, of the “corporatist” structures. Biotechnology
far enough to promote science-based industries like has provided an important impulse for the creation of
biotechnology. The second question is whether R&D new R&D spaces at the intersection of publicly funded
policies per se can address sufficiently deep charac- science and private finance, of higher education and
teristics of the German and Japanese economies to industry. The longer-term impact of recent biotech-
succeed in science-based high-tech sectors. nology policies might well be better indicated by the
Concerning the first question, the German–Japan growth of total patent revenues and IPOs from uni-
comparison reveals the much greater seriousness of versity and research institute spin-outs than by perfor-
Japan toward structural reform of the public-sector mance statistics in biotechnology alone.
science system. There is no comparative drive in The other question is whether R&D reform alone
Germany to makes its numerous research universities will suffice for Germany and Japan to become global
administratively autonomous. While some reforms leaders in the commercialization of fields like biotech-
to improve efficiency and accountability have taken nology. To be sure, reforms in both countries did spill
place on the margins, Germany’s new approach to over to other areas (start-up incubation, new priori-
R&D can essentially be characterized as one of basic ties for higher education, etc.) Nonetheless, the issue
complacency with German science combined with must be faced as to whether, in the long run, success
some novel economic incentives for public-sector sci- in biotechnology depends less on reform of the R&D
entists to undertake entrepreneurship on the side. Yet system per se than of these countries’ overall economic
a truly serious push to abolish obvious anachronisms framework. As recently as the early 1990s, the combi-
like Lehrstühle and Habilitationen at the universities nation of patient labor and patient capital in Germany
has not taken place.11 Profound reform of the R&D and Japan was considered a major competitive ad-
system in Germany is made difficult, it is true, by vantage in knowledge- and skill-intensive sectors. Yet
overlapping jurisdictions for education and research at while the “coordinated market economies” (Hall and
the federal and Länder levels (Politikverflechtung). In Soskice, 2001) of Germany and Japan fit the require-
ments of certain sectors, rapidly evolving technology
11 A Lehrstuhl is a professorial chair with many subordinate as- sectors represent something of a quandary (Casper and
sistants, a Habilitation is like a second doctoral dissertation which Whitley, 2004). The presence of high-powered incen-
qualifies one to become a professor. The system of Lehrstühle tives in the “liberal market economy” of the US may
and Habilitationen give a comparatively small number of German
professors extensive control over people and resources at German
well be just as important in explaining American suc-
universities. Recently, a few junior professorships have been in- cesses in biotechnology as the institutional details of
troduced. the R&D system (Casper et al., 1999).
936 M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938

The risk of R&D reform not being enough is large Casper, S., Kettler, H., 2001. National institutional frameworks
in both countries but takes, very broadly speaking, and the hybridization of entrepreneurial business models: the
German and UK biotechnology sectors. Industry and Innovation
somewhat different forms. In Germany, biotech re-
8 (1), 5–30.
forms were mainly the province of a single agency, the Casper, S., Lehrer, M., Soskice, D., 1999. Can high-technology
Federal Education and Research Ministry (BMBF). industries prosper in Germany? institutional frameworks and the
While the Economics Ministry (BMW)—now the evolution of the German software and biotechnology industries.
Economics and Technology Ministry (BMWi)—did Industry and Innovation 6 (1), 5–24.
Casper, S., Whitley, R., 2004. Managing competences in
participate in certain programs as well, the impression
entrepreneurial technology firms: a comparative institutional
still remains that reforms to favor new science-based analysis of Germany, Sweden and the UK. Research Policy 33,
industries like biotechnology remain highly com- 89–106.
partmentalized. While there was much talk of en- Cuhls, K., Breiner, S., Grupp, H., 1995. Delphi–Bericht 1995 zur
couraging “entrepreneurship” in German political Entwicklung von Wissenschaft und Technik. BMBF, Bonn.
Cummings, W.M., 1991. Japan’s science and engineering pipeline:
discussions of the 1990s, even the talk hardly out- structure, policies, and trends. In: Beauchamp, E.R. (Ed.),
lasted the collapse of the short-lived Internet bubble. Windows on Japanese Education. Greenwood Press, Westport,
In Japan, the interministerial coordination of effort to CT.
promote biotechnology is broader than in Germany. Cummings, W.K., Amano, I., Kitamura, K., 1979. Changes in the
Yet the top-down nature of the government effort Japanese University: A Comparative Perspective. Praeger, New
York.
to promote “science” in Japanese society raises a Dohse, D., 2000. Technology policy and the regions: the case of
troubling paradox. Science research and discovery the BioRegio context. Research Policy 29, 1111–1133.
also require dynamic bottom-up and self-organizing Ernst and Young, 2000. Evolution: European Life Sciences Report.
processes. And such processes pre-suppose the prac- Ernst & Young, London.
Ernst and Young, 2002. Beyond Borders: The Global
tice of authority being rather different from what it
Biotechnology Report. Ernst & Young, London.
has been in Japan. Simply making science-worship Gambardella, A., 1995. Science and Innovation: The US
the centerpiece of broader societal reform may not Pharmaceutical Industry During the 1980s. Cambridge
achieve a great deal. While the government is un- University Press, Cambridge.
doubtedly right to emphasize the huge qualitative George, G., Zahra, S.A., Wheatley, K.K., Khan, R., 2001. The
effects of alliance portfolio characteristics and absorptive
difference between being a leader as opposed to a capacity on performance: a study of biotechnology firms.
fast-follower in global science, the societal challenge Journal of High Technology Management Research 12, 205–
that is involved for Japan is probably a great deal 226.
more diffuse—and a great deal more difficult—than Government of Japan, 2001. The Science and Technology Basic
what can be achieved by government initiative alone. Plan (2001–2005). Tokyo.
Haiducek, N.J., 1991. Japanese Education: Made in the USA.
Praeger, New York.
Hall, P., Soskice, D. (Eds.), 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The
References Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford
University Press, Oxford.
Henderson, R.M., Orsenigo, L., Pisano, G.P., 1999. The
Abramson, H.N., Encarnaçao, J., Reid, P.R., Schmoch, U. (Eds.),
pharmaceutical industry and the revolution in molecular biology.
1997. Technology Transfer Systems in the United States and
In: Mowery, D.C., Nelson, R.R. (Eds.), Sources of Industrial
Germany. National Academy Press, Washington, DC.
Leadership: Studies of Seven Countries. Cambridge University
Arrow, K.J., 1983. Innovation in Large and Small Firms. In:
Press, Cambridge, pp. 267–311.
Ronen, J. (Ed.), Entrepreneurship. D.C. Heath, Lexington, MA,
Interministerial Agreement, 1999. Biotechnology sangyo no Sozo
pp. 15–28.
ni Muketa Kihon Hoshin. Document, Japanese Government.
Ben-David, J., 1971. The Scientist’s Role in Society. University Japan Bioindustry Association, 2003. Statistical Analysis of
of Chicago Press, Chicago. Japanese Bioventures. Japan Bioindustry Letters, 20 (1–3):
BMBF, 1996. Bundesbericht Forschung. BMBF, Bonn. http://www.jba.or.jp.
Buechtemann, C.F., Vogler-Ludwig, K., 1996. The “German JBIF, 1999. Bio Sangyo Gijutsu Senryaku. Report, Japan
Model” under pressure: human capital investment and economic Biotechnology Industry Forum.
performance in Germany. Report #E96-05, CRIS. Jolivet, M., 1985. L’université au service de l’économie japonaise.
Casper, S., 2000. Institutional adaptiveness, technology policy, and Economica, Paris.
the diffusion of new business models: the case of German JPO, 2000. Biotechnology no Patent ni Tsuite. Report, Japanese
biotechnology. Organization Studies 21 (5), 887–914. Patent Office.
M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938 937

Kitamura, K., 1985. New implications for the educational function Pisano, G.P., 1996. Learning-before-doing in the development of
of the Japanese university. In: Research Institute for Higher new process technology. Research Policy 25, 1097–1119.
Education (Ed.), The Changing Function of Higher Education. Porter, M.E., 1992. Capital choices: changing the way America
Hiroshima University: Hiroshima, pp. 3–12. invests in industry. Report, Council on Competitiveness.
Kneller, R. 2000. University-industry cooperation in biomedicine. Powell, W.W., Koput, K.W., Smith-Doerr, L., 1996.
Presentation, Tokyo, Japan. Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation:
Kneller, R., 2003a. University-industry cooperation and technology networks of learning in biotechnology. Administrative Science
transfer in Japan compared with the United States: Quarterly 41, 116–145.
another reason for Japan’s economic malaise? University of Reister, H., 1995. Paradigmenwechsel: Entwicklungen und
Pennsylvania Journal of International Economic Law 24 (2), Kontroversen zur deutschen Technologiepolitik in den
329–449. 90er Jahren, In: Martinsen, R., Simonis, G. (Eds.),
Kneller, R., 2003b. Autarkic drug discovery in Japanese Paradigmenwechsel in der Technologiepolitik? Leske and
pharmaceutical companies: insights into national differences in Budrich, Opladen, pp. 97–119.
industrial innovation, Research Policy 32, 1805–1827.
Ringer, F.K., 1983. The Decline of the German Mandarins: The
Kocka, J., 1999. Industrial Culture and Bourgeois Society.
German Academic Community, 1890–1933. Harvard University
Berghahn Books, New York.
Press, Cambridge, MA.
Krugman, P.R., 1996. Pop Internationalism. MIT Press, Cambridge.
Kulicke, M., 1997. The promotion of new technology-based Sharp, M., 1989. European countries in science-based competition:
firms in Germany, In: K. Koschatzky (Ed.), Technology-Based The case of biotechnology. Working Paper, SPRU.
Firms in the Innovation Process. Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg, Shimbori, M., 1979. The productivity of the Japanese scholar. In:
pp. 107–124. Cummings, W.K., Amano, I., Kitamura, K. (Eds.), Changes in
Lazonick, W., O’Sullivan, M., 1996. Organization, finance, and the Japanese University: A Comparative Perspective. Praeger,
international competition. Industrial and Corporate Change New York, pp. 149–165.
5 (1), 1–49. Soskice, D., 1994. Germany and Japan: Industry-coordinated
Lehrer, M., 2000. Has Germany finally fixed its high-tech problem? versus group-coordinated market economy. Working Paper,
the recent boom in German technology-based entrepreneurship. Social Science Center, Berlin.
California Management Review 42 (4), 89–107. Streeck, W., 2001. Introduction: explorations into the origins of
Malerba, F., Orsenigo, L., 1997. Technological regimes and sectoral nonliberal capitalism in Germany and Japan. In: Streeck, W.,
patterns of innovative activities. Industrial and Corporate Yamamura, K. (Eds.), The Origins of Nonliberal Capitalism:
Change 6 (1), 83–117. Germany and Japan in Comparison. Cornell University Press,
Marshall, B.K., 1992. Academic Freedom and the Japanese Ithaca, pp. 1–38.
Imperial University. University of California Press, Berkeley. Streeck, W., Yamamura, K. (Eds.), 2001. The Origins of Nonliberal
McMillan, G.S., Narin, F., Deeds, D.L., 2000. An analysis of Capitalism: Germany and Japan in Comparison. Cornell
the critical role of public science in innovation: the case of University Press, Ithaca.
biotechnology. Research Policy 29, 1–8. Stucke, A. 1993. Institutionalisierung der Forschungspolitik:
Mowery, D.C., Rosenberg, N., 1998. Paths of Innovation: Entstehung, Entwicklung und Steuerungsprobleme des
Technological Change in 20th-century America. Cambridge Bundesforschungsministerium. Campus Verlag, Frankfurt.
University Press, Cambridge. Swann, P., Prevezer, M., 1996. A comparison of the dynamics of
Murray, F., 2002. Innovation as co-evolution of scientific and industrial clustering in computing and biotechnology. Research
technological networks: exploring tissue engineering. Research Policy 25, 1139–1157.
Policy 31, 1389–1403. Swinbanks, D., 1995. University-industry ties: Japan vs. US.
Nakazawa, Y. 2000. Genome Soyaku to Kongo no Iyakuhin
Research Technology Management 38 (1), 4–6.
Gyakai. Report, Tokyo Mitsubishi Securities.
Takada, H., 2000. Bio Bunya no Sankagu Renkei. Paper Presented
Nelson, R., 1959. The simple economics of basic scientific
at the Center for Advanced Science and Technology Incubation,
research. Journal of Political Economy 67 (3), 297–306.
Tokyo.
Olson, M., 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations. Yale U. Press,
New Haven. Teichler, U., 1996. Higher education in Japan, In: Burgen, A. (Ed.),
Orsenigo, L., 1989. The Emergence of Biotechnology: Institutions Goals and Purposes of Higher Education in the 21st Century.
and Markets in Industrial Innovation. St. Martin’s Press, New Jessica Kingsley, London, pp. 192-212.
York. Thomas III, L.G., 2001. The Japanese Pharmaceutical Industry.
Patel, P., Pavitt, K., 1994. Uneven (and divergent) technological Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
accumulation among advanced countries: Evidence and a Whitley, R., 2003. Competition and pluralism in the public
framework of explanation. Industrial and Corporate Change sciences: the impact of institutional frameworks on the
3 (3), 759–787. organization of academic science. Research Policy 32, 1015–
Pavitt, K., 2001. Public policies to support basic research: What 1029.
can the rest of the world learn from US theory and practice? Wilson, D., Souitaris, V., 2002. Do Germany’s federal and
(and what they should not learn). Industrial and Corporate land governments (still) co-ordinate their innovation policies?
Change 10 (3), 761–779. Research Policy 31, 1123–1140.
938 M. Lehrer, K. Asakawa / Research Policy 33 (2004) 921–938

Wupperfeld, U., 1997. The venture capital market in Germany, Zucker, L.G., Darby, M.R., Brewer, M.B., 1998. Intellectual human
In: Koschatzky, K. (Ed.), Technology-Based Firms in the capital and the birth of US biotechnology enterprises. American
Innovation Process. Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg, pp. 149– Economic Review 88 (1), 290–306.
174. Zysman, J., 1983. Governments, Markets and Growth: Financial
Ziegler, J.N., 1997. Governing Ideas: Strategies for Innovation in Systems and the Politics of Industrial Change. Martin Roberts,
France and Germany. Cornell University Press, Ithaca. Oxford.

You might also like