Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

International Journal of Epidemiology, 2017, 1147–1156

doi: 10.1093/ije/dyx016
Advance Access Publication Date: 27 February 2017
Original article

Social and Economic Determinants

Economic growth and mortality: do social


protection policies matter?
Usama Bilal,1,2* Richard Cooper,3 Francis Abreu,4 Claudia Nau,5

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ije/article/46/4/1147/3057401 by guest on 20 January 2023


Manuel Franco1,2 and Thomas A Glass1
1
Department of Epidemiology, Johns Hopkins Bloomberg School of Public Health, Baltimore, MD, USA,
2
Social and Cardiovascular Epidemiology Research Group, Universidad de Alcala, Madrid, Spain,
3
Department of Public Health Sciences, Loyola University Stritch School of Medicine, Chicago, IL,
USA, 4Department of Biostatistics and 5Department of Population, Family and Reproductive Health,
Johns Hopkins Bloomberg School of Public Health, Baltimore, MD, USA
*Corresponding author. Johns Hopkins Bloomberg School of Public Health, Department of Epidemiology – Rm W6604, 615
N Wolfe St, Baltimore, MD, 21205, USA. E-mail: ubilal@jhmi.edu
Accepted 17 January 2017

Abstract
Background: In the 20th century, periods of macroeconomic growth have been associated
with increases in population mortality. Factors that cause or mitigate this association are
not well understood. Evidence suggests that social policy may buffer the deleterious
impact of economic growth. We sought to explore associations between changing un-
employment (as a proxy for economic change) and trends in mortality over 30 years in the
context of varying social protection expenditures.
Methods: We model change in all-cause mortality in 21 OECD (Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development) countries from 1980 to 2010. Data from the Comparative
Welfare States Data Set and the WHO Mortality Database were used. A decrease in the un-
employment rate was used as a proxy for economic growth and age-adjusted mortality
rates as the outcome. Social protection expenditure was measured as percentage of gross
domestic product expended.
Results: A 1% decrease in unemployment (i.e. the proxy for economic growth) was asso-
ciated with a 0.24% increase in the overall mortality rate (95% confidence interval:
0.07;0.42) in countries with no changes in social protection. Reductions in social protec-
tion expenditure strengthened this association between unemployment and mortality.
The magnitude of the association was diminished over time.
Conclusions: Our results are consistent with the hypothesis that social protection policies
that accompany economic growth can mitigate its potential deleterious effects on health.
Further research should identify specific policies that are most effective.

Key words: Business cycles, macroeconomic conditions, mortality, unemployment, social policies

C The Author 2017; all rights reserved. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the International Epidemiological Association
V 1147
1148 International Journal of Epidemiology, 2017, Vol. 46, No. 4

Key Messages
• Economic change is an important macrosocial determinant of health.
• Economic growth has been associated with increases in mortality, whereas economic recessions seem to lower

mortality.
• We found that these associations are only present in countries with decreasing social protection expenditure.
• The nature of this association has changed over time and may be inverting from 2006 onwards.

Introduction highlighted increases in drug overdoses and cirrhosis mor-


The relationship between short-term economic growth and tality in US adults, but did not discuss macroeconomic con-
mortality patterns has been found to be consistently posi- ditions.8 A second possibility, suggested recently by Lam

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ije/article/46/4/1147/3057401 by guest on 20 January 2023


tive, but counterintuitive findings have been reported.1 and Pierard, is a decrease in the value of unemployment as
Two key ideas by Geoffrey Rose2 may help interpret these a proxy for macroeconomic conditions over time.9 A third
findings. First, economic change represents what Rose explanation, as yet inadequately examined, could be the
called a ‘mass influence acting on populations as a whole’ role of health policy as a modifier of this association.10
that shifts the distribution of risk factors. Second, the Understanding the character and magnitude of policies
causes of individual risk (i.e. the effects of individual ex- that buffer or exacerbate the health impacts of economic
perience of unemployment) and population rates (e.g. the change provides an opportunity to pursue a consequential-
effects of an increase in the unemployment rate) need not ist epidemiology.11,12 Social policies represent mass influ-
be the same and may act in opposite directions. ences on entire regions and countries. If plausible links to
The study of economic change and health has been a secular trends in rates of disease in populations can be
topic of interest in the past century. Despite varying meth- defined, this suggests population interventions. Three re-
ods and across economic cycles, a consistent procyclical ports, by Reeves13 and Cylus,14,15 have explored how in
pattern has been found (mortality increasing with eco- European countries and US states, higher spending on la-
nomic growth); suicide remains the main exception.3,4 bour market policies mitigates the association between sui-
This association would appear to be counterintuitive, given cides, self-rated health and recessions. Nonetheless, few
that individual unemployment, under-employment and studies looking at overall mortality burden have evaluated
loss of job security are consistently associated with higher the hypothesis that social protection policies blunt or coun-
risk of illness and death.1 ter cyclical trends. Those investigations that have pursued
Rose argued2 that the causes of individual cases need not this question16,17 used crude estimates of social protection
be the same as the mass influences determining population policies with time-fixed classifications obtained from
rates over time. Tapia-Granados5 and Noelke6 recently single-year estimates that may not be stable or representa-
demonstrated that whereas individual unemployment was tive of entire study periods. The latest period of economic
associated with increased mortality for the individual, at the turmoil has sparked a debate on the role of ‘austerity meas-
societal level unemployment was associated with decreased ures’ that tighten social expenditure to promote a return to
mortality rates. Economic slowdown, on average, generates economic growth.18 Social protection expenditures vary
health benefits for those who remain employed, potentially with economic changes, either by entitlements that auto-
due to reduced air pollution, traffic accidents, alcohol con- matically trigger when, for example, the unemployment
sumption and other risk factors that decline with economic rate goes up (i.e. expenditure on unemployment benefits),
slowdown.6 or by specific patterns of policies related to social expend-
This report focuses on two aspects of the association be- iture (i.e. austerity policies). Hence, it is necessary to ac-
tween economic change and mortality: (i) changes over count for the time-varying nature of this potential effect
time in the strength and direction of this association; and modifier (see review by Stuckler19 for an overview on the
(ii) the potential of effect modification through policy. importance of these effect modifiers).
Ruhm recently reported that procyclical mortality associ- We explored the association between economic growth
ations have shifted toward the null in the late 1990s and and all-cause mortality across 21 OECD countries, ad-
2000s (and potentially toward a more countercyclical pat- dressing two key limitations of previous studies. First, we
tern).7 He attributes these changes to an intensification of used a robust longitudinal model to examine change across
the counter-cyclicality of external mortality causes, espe- a 30-year time frame. Second, we evaluated effect modifi-
cially drug overdoses and cancer. Case and Deaton recently cation of the business cycle-mortality association by social
International Journal of Epidemiology, 2017, Vol. 46, No. 4 1149

Table 1. Description of the 21 OECD countries in the study sample for selected years in terms of unemployment rate (%), public
social protection expenditure (% of GDP) and all-cause mortality per 100 000. Countries are sorted by average level of social pro-
tection expenditure over the study period (1980–2010)

Unemployment rate (%) Public social protection Mortality per 100 000
expenditure (% of GDP)

Country 1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010 1980 1990 2000 2010

Low social Japan 2.0 2.1 4.7 5.0 10.4 11.3 16.2 22.5* 1441.1 1126.4 897.2 791.6
protection Australia 6.1 6.9 6.3 5.2 10.3 13.2 17.3 17.9 1542.1 1275.7 1036.9 864.6
expenditure USA 7.1 5.6 4.0 9.6 12.9 13.4 14.3 19.7 1477.1 1345.6 1251.7 1060.9
Portugal 8.1 4.8 4.0 11.0 9.9 12.5 18.9 25.6* 1986.9 1655.2 1335.7 1075.5
Switzerland 0.2 0.6 2.7 4.5 13.8 13.5 17.8 18.4* 1459.6 1273.2 1068.6 869.0

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ije/article/46/4/1147/3057401 by guest on 20 January 2023


Ireland 7.3 13.4 4.2 13.9 16.5 17.3 13.4 23.7 1959.3 1673.9 1453.7 1085.7*
Canada 7.5 8.2 6.8 8.0 14.2 18.1 16.6 18.9 1419.8 1247.5 1083.8 893.3
Medium social Greece 2.8 7.1 11.2 12.6 10.3 16.6 19.3 23.9* 1502.3 1358.3 1329.3 1046.9
protection New Zealand 2.2 8.0 6.2 6.5 17.0 21.5 19.0 21.2 1791.2 1400.9 1115.8 923.1
expenditure UK 6.2 6.9 5.4 7.8 16.9 17.0 18.8 24.4* 1722.3 1441.9 1309.0* 1006.5
Spain 10.5 14.4 11.7 20.1 15.5 19.9 20.2 26.0* 1463.4 1319.0 1106.8 898.4
Italy 7.4 8.9 10.1 8.4 18.0 19.9 23.1 27.8* 1596.9 1326.1 1109.8 894.9
Norway 1.7 5.2 3.2 3.6 16.9 22.3 21.3 23.3* 1459.2 1395.1 1198.1 992.1
The Netherlands 6.1 5.1 3.1 4.5 24.8 25.6 19.8 23.2* 1437.1 1350.6 1271.3 1011.4
High social Germany 3.2 4.7 8.0 7.1 22.7 22.3 26.6 27.1 1693.6 1509.4 1213.7 1033.4
protection Finland 4.6 3.2 9.8 8.4 18.1 24.1 24.2 29.4* 1707.2 1527.8 1268.7 1034.1
expenditure Belgium 8.5 6.5 6.9 8.3 23.5 24.9 25.3 29.7* 1743.7 1406.1 1252.0 1045.5
Austria 1.7 3.0 3.6 4.4 22.4 23.8 26.6 29.1* 1784.6 1457.9 1212.8 1001.1
Denmark 6.1 7.2 4.3 7.5 24.8 25.1 26.4 30.2* 1599.2 1523.2 1339.7 1150.4
France 5.4 8.0 9.0 9.7 20.8 25.1 28.6 32.0* 1459.2 1197.2 1082.2 884.6
Sweden 2.0 1.7 5.6 8.6 27.1 30.2 28.4 29.8* 1490.8 1301.5 1125.7 972.7

*Value from previous year.

protection policies, treated as a time-varying factor. We Data on population estimates of all-cause mortality
hypothesized that increased public expenditures on social rates, stratified by age and sex, were obtained from the
protection policies may reduce the negative effect of eco- World Health Organization Mortality Database (updated
nomic growth on all-cause mortality. 25 May 2015). We age-adjusted mortality rates to the
European Standard Population of 2013 using the direct
standardization method.
Methods Economic data were obtained from the Comparative
Welfare States Data Set20 where data on welfare policies
Data sources
from 22 countries have been compiled for five decades.
This study is an ecological analysis of time trends in mor- The main exposure of interest was the harmonized un-
tality rates across 21 OECD (Organization for Economic employment rate (variable hunemr2 in the CWSD), our
Cooperation and Development) countries from 1980 to surrogate measure of economic change. We relied on
2010. These 21 countries were selected based on data unemployment since it has been extensively used in stud-
availability in the Comparative Welfare States Data Set ies of the impact of macroeconomic change on health,
(CWSD: http://www.unc.edu/jdsteph/common/data-com allowing us to better compare our findings with previous
mon.html). We restricted our analysis to industrialized research. Moreover, it represents a sensitive measure
high-income nations with functioning welfare systems, to of the effect of the economy on the people’s health.
avoid comparability issues. Table 1 shows the included Unemployment was defined as the number of unemployed
countries. people as a percentage of the civilian labour force, using a
The time period (1980 to 2010) was selected to ensure uniform definition of unemployment across all countries
enough coverage of a full range of experimental conditions (people of working age who, in the reference period, are
(i.e. several growth and recession periods and changes in without work, are available to work and have taken spe-
the social protection system). cific steps to find work). This indicator pools several
1150 International Journal of Epidemiology, 2017, Vol. 46, No. 4

harmonized unemployment estimates from the OECD; a lnðMortalityÞji ¼b0 þu0j þðb1 þu1j ÞðYearij 1980Þij
more uniform indicator (variable hunemr in the CWSD)
þðb2 þu2j ÞðYearij 1980Þ2ij þb4 ðURij UR j Þ
uses a single definition but is not available for the entire
study period or for all countries. We performed a sensitiv- þ b5 ðSPPij SPP j Þþb6 ðURij UR j ÞðSPPij SPP j Þ
ity analysis using this alternative, to determine how our þ b7 UR j þb8 SPP j þeij
inferences were affected. 2 3 0 2 31 0 2 31
l0j s00 1
Social protection expenditure was defined as all public 6 7 B 6 7C B 6 7C
6 7 B 6 7C B 6 7C
social protection expenditures as a percentage of GDP 6 l1j 7 NB0; 6 s10 s11 7C eji  N B0;r2  6 q1 1 7C
6 7 B 6 7C B 6 7C
(gross domestic product) (available from 1980 to 2010; 4 5 @ 4 5A @ 4 5A
variable socx_pub in the CWSD). These expenditures in-
l2j s20 s12 s22 q2 q1 1
clude old age and survivor policies, incapacity-related
benefits, health and family protection, active labour mar- In order to check the robustness of our results to this

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ije/article/46/4/1147/3057401 by guest on 20 January 2023


ket and unemployment expenditures, and housing policies. within-between-model specification, we also estimated a
Given that we used a measure of social protection expend- two-way fixed-effects model (the typical specification in pre-
iture that is relative to overall GDP, this measure may be vious studies,25 including a fixed term for each country and
biased when GDP changes (i.e. if GDP goes down, social year) with a first-order autocorrelation structure of residuals.
protection expenditure may go up because the denomin- In secondary analyses, we also assessed (i) whether the
ator becomes smaller). To test the robustness of our results effect of unemployment changed over time (as hypothesized
to this, we conducted a sensitivity analysis in which we fur- by Ruhm7) by introducing an interaction term of unemploy-
ther adjusted our models with GDP growth [defined as ment and social protection expenditure and time (linear
(GDP in current year – GDP in previous year)/GDP in pre- time, along with linear splines with knots every 10 years to
vious year]. allow for changes in the associations to vary linearly every
decade); and (ii) if there were non-linear effects (as hypothe-
sized by Bonamore26), by adding a quadratic term for both
Statistical models the unemployment rate and the social protection policies.
Main coefficients are presented as (1)*(eb1)*100,
The goal of this analysis was to study the association
and can be interpreted as the percentage change in mortal-
between economic change and mortality and interaction
ity per 1% decrease in unemployment. Analyses were con-
by changes in social protection policies. Analyses were
ducted using STATA/SE 13.1 (STATACorp, College
conducted using linear models with the natural logarithm
Station, TX).
of age-adjusted all-cause mortality rate as the dependent
variable. We used a mixed-effects model that decomposes
between- and within-group (country) variance compo- Results
nents21,22 by group-mean centring covariates and intro- A descriptive overview of the data is presented in Table 1.
ducing these terms into the model along with a random The first four columns provide the unemployment rate for
effect for the mean of each group. These models have the a sample of time periods. Large differences can be seen
advantages of removing time-fixed confounding on the across countries and time. Structural unemployment (con-
group-mean centred covariate (like fixed-effects models) sistent high levels) is evident in countries like Spain, where
and still make it possible to study the effect of time- rates never go below 10%, but also in Italy, Greece and
fixed covariates, deal with variables missing at random Ireland. Period effects are also evident as indicated by in-
and increase the efficiency of the analysis.23 Recent creases in unemployment in 2010 in 18 of the 21 countries,
simulation studies have confirmed these aforementioned as a result of the Great Recession of 2009. Cross-country
advantages.24 variations are large also for social protection. Some coun-
The model building process included regressing mor- tries, like Australia, Canada, New Zealand and the USA,
tality on a series of year polynomials (including fixed and have low levels of social protection expenditure, never
random terms for each one) and adding a first-order auto- reaching 20% in any given year. Other countries, mostly in
correlation structure for the level-1 residuals. The model Scandinavia and Central Europe, consistently have expend-
with the lowest AIC (Akaike Information Criterion) was itures of 23% and above. Mortality rates have declined
selected. The final model was specified as follows (the j monotonically in all countries during the study period. In
index represents a country and the i index represents a year 1980, mortality rates varied from a high of 1987 in
of observation): Portugal to a low of 1437 in The Netherlands. Rates of
International Journal of Epidemiology, 2017, Vol. 46, No. 4 1151

decline varied widely; Japan declined by 45% whereas the showed analogous inferences to our main analysis (model
USA saw a 28% decline. 5 in Table 2). The sensitivity analysis adjusting for GDP
The primary results are based on a series of multilevel growth (%) to control for potential changes in the de-
mixed-effects models that capture change in mortality rates nominator of social protection expenditure showed no dif-
as a function of unemployment, social protection expend- ferences compared with the main model (see model 6 in
iture and time (Table 2). In model 1 without an interaction Table 2).
term between unemployment and social protection ex-
penditure, a decrease in unemployment (a proxy for eco-
nomic growth) is associated on average with an increase in Discussion
mortality. Model 2 includes an interaction term between The primary finding of this study was that the association
unemployment and social protection expenditure; this between economic change and mortality is weakened in
model indicates that the association between unemploy- countries that concurrently increase social protection ex-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ije/article/46/4/1147/3057401 by guest on 20 January 2023


ment and mortality is attenuated in countries with higher penditure. These results add support to previous reports
expenditures. that economic growth is associated with an increase in
A more complete characterization of these findings mortality rates. A key contribution of the present study
can be seen in Figure 1: a 1% decrease in unemployment is that this association is only apparent in countries that
(a proxy for economic growth) is associated with a concurrently decrease social protection expenditures.
0.24% increase in mortality [95% confidence interval Secondary analyses provide evidence that the negative con-
(CI) ¼ 0.07;0.42]. This is the estimated association (Figure 1, sequences of growth on mortality may have diminished or
centre) for countries that do not change their social protec- reversed since 2006.
tion expenditure levels in the same time period. In countries Previous research has consistently identified increases in
with a 5% decline in social protection expenditures, the as- mortality accompanying economic growth.4,16,27–34 Two
sociation between economic growth and mortality is almost previous studies have identified country-level effect modi-
double in magnitude (0.45% increase in mortality, 95% fiers using percentage of GDP spent on social protection
CI ¼ 0.17;0.73; left side of Figure 1). In contrast, in countries services;16,17 one study measured expenditures on services
where social expenditures increase, changes in unemploy- in 1995 and the other averaged over 10 years. Both studies
ment are associated with smaller or null changes in mortality found similar results to ours: the effects of macroeconomic
(Figure 1, right side). change are more pronounced in countries with weaker so-
We conducted two secondary analyses to test hypothe- cial protection systems. Nonetheless no study, to our
ses suggested in previous studies. Figure 2 shows the asso- knowledge, has assessed the effect of changes in expend-
ciation between economic growth and mortality and itures and their interaction with trends in economic activ-
interaction with social protection expenditure over time. ity. Our results provide evidence to support pro-active
Two trends are apparent. Economic growth (as proxied by policies to strengthen welfare systems as a means of ensur-
a decrease in unemployment) is associated with increased ing optimal public health35.
mortality from the 1980s through the early 2000s; this as- The effects of economic growth on health can be medi-
sociation is especially strong in countries with a decrease in ated through changes on the supply side or the demand
social protection expenditure (left panel, Figure 2). side. Supply side changes include rising working hours and
Moreover, the size of these changes is stronger in countries increased demand for labour as a function of increasing in-
with decreasing social protection expenditure, whereas dustrial production. These changes may lead, inter alia, to
countries that increase expenditure only see variations of increased stress resulting from rising competition and work
this association around the null (right panel, Figure 2). The demands1,36–40 or to an increase in the cost of time, reduc-
strength of the unemployment-mortality association is di- ing the probability of engaging in healthy (and time-costly)
minished in the 2000s. recreational or health-affirming behaviours.4 Changes in
Table 2 also shows the results of an additional second- the demand side41 could include increases in consumption
ary analysis (model 3), adding a quadratic term for un- of products which erode health, primarily tobacco, alcohol
employment to test the hypothesis that the association and a diet high in animal products and calories,41–45 to-
between unemployment and mortality was not linear. gether with exposure to worsening air pollution and
Model fit was not improved suggesting a linear associ- increased risk of accidents associated with greater motor-
ation. The sensitivity analysis using the alternative out- ized transport and longer working hours.46 A recent report
come (completely harmonized unemployment rates, model by Cutler28 highlights the role of pollution, accidents, alco-
4 in Table 2) demonstrates consistent inferences. The sensi- hol and tobacco consumption in this association, and
tivity analysis using a regular fixed-effects model also stresses the importance of considering age-specific effects
1152

Table 2. Results from the main model and secondary and sensitivity analyses

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6


(without Main model Secondary Sensitivity Sensitivity Sensitivity
interaction) (incl. interaction) analysis: analysis: analysis: analysis:
quadratic UE harmonized UE two-way FE control for GDP
b*100 (95% CI) b*100 (95% CI) b*100 (95% CI) b*100 (95% CI) b*100 (95% CI)

Year 1.14 (1.44;0.83) 1.11 (1.42;0.80) 1.10 (1.41;0.79) 1.11 (1.46;0.75) 1.04 (1.36;0.72)
Year2 0.02 (0.02;0.01) 0.02 (0.02;0.01) 0.02 (0.02;0.01) 0.02 (0.03;0.01) 0.02 (0.03;0.01)
1% increase in 0.21 (0.39;0.04) 0.24 (0.42;0.07) 0.17 (0.41;0.07) 0.27 (0.48;0.07) 0.27 (0.51;0.04) 0.23 (0.41;0.05)
unemployment rate
Unemployment x 0.04 (0.00;0.08) 0.07 (0.01;0.13) 0.04 (0.01;0.09) 0.04 (0.01;0.08) 0.05 (0.01;0.09)
social protection
expenditure
1% increase in 0.22 (0.01;0.43) 0.12 (0.10;0.35) 0.10 (0.14;0.33) 0.18 (0.05;0.41) 0.05 (0.23;0.32) 0.01 (0.26;0.24)
social protection
expenditure
1% increase in 0.01 (0.05;0.02)
unemployment rate2
Unemployment2 x 0.00 (0.01;0.00)
social protection
expenditure
AIC 2751.9215 2754.558 2749.9507 2257.447 2880.3987 2758.966
AIC change – 2.63 þ 1.97 N/A N/A 7.04
No. parameters 15 16 19 16 34 17
No. observations 613 613 613 504 592 613

All coefficients are shown untransformed to facilitate comparison, but scaled times 100 to ease visualization. Model 2 is the one shown in the methods section. Model 1 is analogous to model 2 without the unemployment
x social protection expenditure interaction coefficient. Model 3 is analogous to model 2, with a quadratic coefficient for unemployment (and its interaction with social protection expenditure). Model 4 uses the completely
harmonized unemployment rate as the main exposure. Models 1–4 further include a term for mean unemployment rate and mean social protection expenditure for each country. Model 5 is a two-way fixed-effects model
with a fixed effect for year and a fixed effect for time, with a first-order autoregressive residual structure.
UE: unemployment rates; FE, fixed effects; incl, including; N/A, not available; no., number.
International Journal of Epidemiology, 2017, Vol. 46, No. 4

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ije/article/46/4/1147/3057401 by guest on 20 January 2023


International Journal of Epidemiology, 2017, Vol. 46, No. 4 1153

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ije/article/46/4/1147/3057401 by guest on 20 January 2023


Figure 1. Percentage change in mortality (and 95% CI) per 1% decrease in unemployment across levels of change of social protection expenditure.
The histogram represents the observed distribution of social protection expenditure changes

Figure 2. Change in the unemployment/mortality association over time by levels of social protection expenditure. The left panel represents countries
with decreasing social protection expenditure, the right panel represents countries with increasing social protection expenditure and in the middle
one are countries with no changes in social protection expenditure. Coefficients come from a random-effects model that includes linear and quadratic
time (both fixed and random), unemployment (within-country change and mean over the study period), social protection expenditure (within-country
change and mean over the study period), form and linear spline terms with knots every 10 years, along with the interactions between unemployment,
social protection expenditure and the linear time splines. The grey band represents the 95% confidence interval of the unemployment/mortality
association

(i.e. most work-related or risk factors apply only to with increased consumption; in contemporary consumer
adults). culture, a proportion of that consumption may be detri-
It should be emphasized that though unemployment de- mental to health.
creases during growth and increases during recessions, A key contribution of this paper is our finding suggest-
only a fraction of the population is affected by unemploy- ing that social protection policies may buffer the conse-
ment and the majority of the population remains in stable quences of economic growth on mortality. Two
employment. Thus, whereas the experience of unemploy- mechanisms may be at play. First, well-developed social
ment is negative for the health of an individual,47 the over- protection systems may push fewer people with health vul-
all effect we measure here reflects the population-wide nerabilities into the work force. A recent report by Regidor
influences of changing unemployment rates (including indi- et al.27 supports this hypothesis, as it found that the in-
viduals whose status did not change).48 As hypothesized by crease in mortality during periods of growth (or the de-
Cooper,41 economic growth (prosperity) may be associated crease during recessions) was stronger in people of lower
1154 International Journal of Epidemiology, 2017, Vol. 46, No. 4

socioeconomic position, who are most prone to be pushed study to the impact of specific concurrent social expend-
into the work force while sick.49 Second, buffering may iture policies, but at the same time reduces the possibility
arise from a reduction of either the negative contextual ef- of time-fixed confounding by unmeasured country-level
fect of economic growth or the positive contextual effect of characteristics (e.g. history of egalitarianism) that may af-
economic recessions. Although the latter seems likely, a hy- fect levels of social protection expenditure. Finally, we
pothesis regarding the former can be found in the downsiz- relied on unemployment changes as our surrogate of eco-
ing/job insecurity literature, where previous research has nomic growth. Although not perfect, this proxy has been
shown the negative effects of these practices.50 Moreover, extensively used in studies of the impact of macroeconomic
as hypothesized by Ruhm, social protection expenditure change on health. Other alternatives, such as change in
may be a marker for ‘broader patterns of government in- GDP, may not be sensitive measures of the effect of eco-
volvement’ that may reduce the overall effects of economic nomic change on people’s lives. Sensitivity analyses
changes.10 As mentioned in the introduction to this paper, showed that the use of harmonized or non-harmonized un-

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ije/article/46/4/1147/3057401 by guest on 20 January 2023


social protection expenditure changes vary with the econ- employment rates did not affect our inferences.
omy, as certain sources of expenditure are entitlements Ecological studies are known to have additional limita-
that trigger when the economy shrinks (like unemployment tions. We address this concern in part by limiting our infer-
benefits), whereas other changes are contemporaneous, ences to the population level, making no claims about the
like austerity policies. Our measure of social protection ex- effects of changing economic conditions on the risk of
penditure combines both, but our model implicitly adjusts death for individuals. We were interested in identifying
for the first (entitlements triggered during recessions) by macrosocial processes that affect population-level mortal-
including unemployment changes in the model. ity rates. These factors may differ from individual-level
The strengths of this study include the use of data on a risk factors.2,51 In a recent review, Stuckler19 argued for a
large number of countries (N ¼ 21) over a long time period better conceptualization of causal frameworks to study
(30 years) encompassing several economic cycles. This en- this problem. We believe that population-level inferences
hances the generalizability and robustness of our results. are relevant to a consequentialist epidemiology12 by pro-
Our time frame included (but was not limited to) the recent viding guidance about how national policies can buffer the
economic turmoil beginning in 2008 which has been the effects of important mass influences on health. Given the
subject of research and policy scrutiny. Lastly, this large interest in studying how austerity affects population
temporal scope allowed us to test for heterogeneity over health,18 this study can inform future policy making. If
time by policy-sensitive factors, a mechanism that may economic growth is associated with mortality only in coun-
underlie these changes7. tries that concomitantly decrease social protection expend-
A potential limitation of this study is the possibility of itures, then interventions that increase or maintain such
confounding. Using both random (primary analysis) and expenditures may promote growth with fewer negative
fixed-effects models24 (sensitivity), we found little evidence consequences.
that a diverse set of country-specific time-fixed confound-
ers might explain this association. We are unable to rule
out additional unmeasured time-varying confounders. A Conclusions
second limitation is that the use of a general measure of so- Economic growth over the period 1980–2010 was associ-
cial protection expenditure does not allow testing of the ated with a slower decline in mortality rates over time in a
buffering effects of particular policies. This limits our abil- sample of 21 OECD countries. This association is observed
ity to provide guidance about whether, for example, in- only in countries that decrease social protection expend-
come transfers, job training or active labour policies are itures. This suggests that maintaining or increasing the
most effective. Future studies should consider investigating strength of the social safety net can diminish the associ-
which specific policies may be driving the effect modifica- ation between economic change and population health.
tion. Third, we focus our inferences on the changes in so- Replication of these results in other industrialized coun-
cial protection expenditure, instead of focusing on the tries may provide more information on the mechanisms
consequences of (cross-sectional) levels of social ex- and specific policies behind this phenomenon and may in-
penditure. These two variables are independent in our data form future interventions to avoid increases in mortality
set (See Supplementary Figure 2, available in the with economic growth.
Supplementary data at IJE online); we therefore believe
that the effect-modifying nature of social protection ex-
penditure changes is not due to baseline or average levels Supplementary Data
of social protection. However, this limits the scope of our Supplementary data are available at IJE online.
International Journal of Epidemiology, 2017, Vol. 46, No. 4 1155

Funding views? A network analysis of literature across disciplines. Health


Econ Policy Law 2015;10:83–99.
U.B. was supported by a Johns Hopkins Center for a Livable Future
20. Brady D, Huber E, Stephens JD. Comparative Welfare States
– Lerner Fellowship, and a Postgraduate Fellowship from the Obra
Data Set. 2014 http://www.unc.edu/jdsteph/common/data-
Social La Caixa.
common.html (21 January 2016, date last accessed).
Conflicts of interest: F.A. currently works at Genentech and con- 21. Allison PD. Fixed Effects Regression Models. Thousand Oaks,
ducts research sponsored by this company. This study is not part of CA: SAGE Publications, 2009.
any research supported or sponsored by Genentech. 22. Fitzmaurice GM, Laird NM, Ware JH. Applied Longitudinal
Analysis. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley, 2011.
References 23. Clark TS, Linzer DA. Should I use fixed or random effects? Polit
Sci Res Methods 2015;3:399–408.
1. Catalano R, Goldman-Mellor S, Saxton K et al. The health effects
24. Bell A, Jones K. Explaining fixed effects:random effects modeling
of economic decline. Annu Rev Public Health 2011;32:431–50.
of time-series cross-sectional and panel data. Polit Sci Res
2. Rose G. Sick individuals and sick populations. Int J Epidemiol
Methods 2015;3:133––53.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ije/article/46/4/1147/3057401 by guest on 20 January 2023


1985;14:32–38.
25. Ruhm CJ. Commentary: Macroeconomic conditions and social out-
3. Ogburn WF, Thomas DS. The influence of the business cycle on
comes through a 90-year lens. Int J Epidemiol 2015;44:1490–92.
certain social conditions. J Am Stat Assoc 1922;18:324–40.
26. Bonamore G, Carmignani F, Colombo E. Addressing the
4. Ruhm CJ. Are recessions good for your health? Q J Econ
unemployment-mortality conundrum: non-linearity is the an-
2000;115:617–50.
swer. Soc Sci Med 2015;126:67–72.
5. Tapia Granados JA, House JS, Ionides EL, Burgard S, Schoeni
27. Regidor E, Vallejo F, Granados JAT, Viciana-Fern andez FJ, de la
RS. Individual joblessness, contextual unemployment, and mor-
Fuente L, Barrio G. Mortality decrease according to socioeco-
tality risk. Am J Epidemiol 2014;180:280–87.
nomic groups during the economic crisis in Spain: a cohort study
6. Noelke C, Avendano M. Who suffers during recessions?
of 36 million people. Lancet 2016;388:2642–52.
Economic downturns, job loss, and cardiovascular disease in 28. Cutler DM, Huang W, Lleras-Muney A. Economic conditions
older Americans. Am J Epidemiol 2015;182:873–82. and mortality: evidence from 200 years of data. National Bureau
7. Ruhm CJ. Recessions, healthy no more? J Health Econ
of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 22690.
2015;42:17–28. Cambridge, MA: NBER, 2016.
8. Case A, Deaton A. Rising morbidity and mortality in midlife 29. Ruhm CJ. Economic conditions and health behaviors: are reces-
among white non-Hispanic Americans in the 21st century. Proc sions good for your health? N C Med J 2009;70:328–29.
Natl Acad Sci U S A 2015;112:15078–83. 30. Tapia Granados JA. Increasing mortality during the expansions of
9. Lam J-P, Pierard E. The time-varying relationship between mortal- the US economy, 1900–1996. Int J Epidemiol 2005;34:1194–202.
ity and business cycles in the US. Health Econ 2017;26:164–83. 31. Tapia Granados JA. Economic growth and health progress in
10. Ruhm CJ. Macroeconomic conditions, health, and government England and Wales: 160 years of a changing relation. Soc Sci
policy. In: Schoeni RF (ed). Making Americans Healthier:Social Med 2012;74:688–95.
and Economic Policy as Health Policy. New York, NY: Russell 32. Tapia Granados JA, Ionides EL. The reversal of the relation be-
Sage Foundation, 2008. tween economic growth and health progress: Sweden in the 19th
11. Galea S, Link BG. Six paths for the future of social epidemiology. and 20th centuries. J Health Econ 2008;27:544–63.
Am J Epidemiol 2013;178:843–49. 33. Tapia-Granados JA. Macroeconomic fluctuations and mortality
12. Galea S. An argument for a consequentialist epidemiology. Am J in postwar Japan. Demography 2008;45:323–43.
Epidemiol 2013;178:1185–91. 34. Thomas D. Social Aspects of the Business Cycle. London:
13. Reeves A, McKee M, Gunnell D et al. Economic shocks, resilience, George Routledge and Sons, 1925.
and male suicides in the Great Recession: cross-national analysis 35. Reeves A, McKee M, Stuckler D. The attack on universal health
of 20 EU countries. Eur J Public Health 2015;25:404–09. coverage in Europe: recession, austerity and unmet needs. Eur J
14. Cylus J, Glymour MM, Avendano M. Do generous unemploy- Public Health 2015;25:364–65.
ment benefit programs reduce suicide rates? A State fixed-effect 36. Cooper M, Lynne MR, Frone MR. Work stress and alcohol ef-
analysis covering 1968–2008. Am J Epidemiol 2014;180:45–52. fects: A test of stress-induced drinking. J Health Soc Behav
15. Cylus J, Glymour MM, Avendano M. Health effects of un- 1990;31:260–76.
employment benefit program generosity. Am J Public Health 37. Hlatky MA, Lam LC, Lee KL et al. Job strain and the preva-
2015;105:317–23. lence and outcome of coronary artery disease. Circulation
16. Toffolutti V, Suhrcke M. Assessing the short term health impact 1995;92:327–33.
of the Great Recession in the European Union: A cross-country 38. James SA, Keenan NL, Strogatz DS, Browning SR, Garrett JM.
panel analysis. Prev Med 2014;64:54–62. Socioeconomic status, John Henryism, and blood pressure in black
17. Gerdtham UG, Ruhm CJ. Deaths rise in good economic times: adults. The Pitt County Study. Am J Epidemiol 1992;135:59–67.
evidence from the OECD. Econ Hum Biol 2006;4:298–316. 39. Karasek R. The stress-disequilibrium theory: chronic disease de-
18. Stuckler D, Basu S. The Body Economic: Why Austerity Kills. velopment, low social control, and physiological de-regulation.
New York, NY: Basic Books, 2013. Med Lav 2006;97:258–71.
19. Stuckler D, Reeves A, Karanikolos M, McKee M. The health ef- 40. Karasek R, Baker D, Marxer F, Ahlbom A, Theorell T. Job deci-
fects of the global financial crisis: can we reconcile the differing sion latitude, job demands, and cardiovascular disease: a
1156 International Journal of Epidemiology, 2017, Vol. 46, No. 4

prospective study of Swedish men. Am J Public Health 1981; 46. Chen G. Association between economic fluctuations and road
71:694–705. mortality in OECD –countries. Eur J Public Health
41. Cooper RS. Prosperity, of the capitalist variety, as a cause of 2014;24:I612–14.
death. Int J Health Serv 1977;9:155–59. 47. Halliday TJ. Unemployment and mortality: Evidence from the
42. Colell E, Sanchez-Niub o A, Delclos GL, Benavides FG, PSID. Soc Sci Med 2014;113:15–22.
Domingo-Salvany A. Economic crisis and changes in drug use 48. Tapia Granados JA. Response: on economic growth, business
in the Spanish economically active population. Addiction fluctuations, and health progress. Int J Epidemiol 2005;
2015;110:1129–37. 34:1226–33.
43. Courtemanche CJ, Pinkston JC, Ruhm CJ, Wehby G. Can chang- 49. Catalina-Romero C, Sainz JC, Pastrana-Jiménez JI et al. The im-
ing economic factors explain the rise in obesity? National pact of poor psychosocial work environment on non-work-
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 20892. related sickness absence. Soc Sci Med 2015;138:210–16.
Cambridge, MA: NBER, 2015. 50. Quinlan M, Bohle P. Overstretched and unreciprocated commit-
44. Harhay MO, Bor J, Basu S et al. Differential impact of the eco- ment: reviewing research on the occupational health and safety
nomic recession on alcohol use among white British adults, effects of downsizing and job insecurity. Int J Health Serv

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ije/article/46/4/1147/3057401 by guest on 20 January 2023


2004–2010. Eur J Public Health 2014;24:410–15. 2009;39:144.
45. Nandi A, Charters TJ, Strumpf EC, Heymann J, Harper S. 51. Rockhill B. Theorizing about causes at the individual level while
Economic conditions and health behaviours during the ‘Great estimating effects at the population level: implications for pre-
Recession’. J Epidemiol Community Health 2013;67:1038–46. vention. Epidemiology 2005;16:124–29.

You might also like