Labour Market Participation in Brazil A Discrete Game Approach

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

Applied Economics

ISSN: 0003-6846 (Print) 1466-4283 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20

Labour market participation in Brazil: a discrete


game approach

Marcelo Resende & Vicente Cardoso

To cite this article: Marcelo Resende & Vicente Cardoso (2019): Labour market participation in
Brazil: a discrete game approach, Applied Economics, DOI: 10.1080/00036846.2019.1680792

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2019.1680792

Published online: 05 Nov 2019.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 15

View related articles

View Crossmark data

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=raec20
APPLIED ECONOMICS
https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2019.1680792

Labour market participation in Brazil: a discrete game approach


Marcelo Resendea and Vicente Cardosob
a
Instituto de Economia, Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro, Rio de Janeiro-RJ, Brazil; bBanco Nacional de Desenvolvimento
Econômico e Social-BNDES, Rio de Janeiro-RJ, Brazil

ABSTRACT KEYWORDS
The article aims at investigating labour market participation of couples in Brazil in 2013. The Labour market participation;
observed endogenous variables portraying participation are assumed to be the outcome of a static discrete game; Brazil
discrete game between the partners. Different solution concepts are considered (Nash, Stackelberg JEL CLASSIFICATION
and imposed Pareto optimality). The evidence, in comparison with previous evidence for more J21; C35
developed and homogeneous countries, display qualitative similarities in terms of own wage, cross
wage and age effects and a stronger inhibiting role of the number of small children in the case of
the female partner. In particular, cross-wage effects also indicated gender-asymmetry. Additionally,
one identifies a slightly better fit in the case of the Stackelberg male leader model that could be
suggestive in terms of the relevance of cultural aspects on labour market participation, but the
differences among the different models are not striking.

I. Introduction can be traced back to essential gender differences,


whether more structural or cultural. Empirical
The study of decisions within a household still
challenges to the unitary perspective on house-
motivates a non-trivial discussion on the proper
hold behaviour are evident. Thomas (1990) con-
approach to assess such decision units. Becker
sidered survey data on family health and nutrition
(1964) pioneered the application of consumer the-
in Brazil, and the evidence did not provide sup-
ory to the family. At the empirical frontier, one
port for the common preference model of the
often relies on more aggregate data from surveys
household, as parental income effects on child
that may not favour intra-household analyses and
survival probabilities were not homogeneous
are consistent with a more aggregate perspective.
across parents.
Nevertheless, the controversy between unitary
More generally, gender differences can be poten-
and non-unitary models of household behaviour
tially relevant particularly when one is focusing on
is by no means settled, as suggested, for example,
labour force participation, which is the object of the
by McElroy (1990), Chiappori and Donni (2011)
present article. Even if gender segregation in terms
and Grossbard (2011). In fact, the relevant litera-
of wage differentials does not appear to be decisive
ture on household behaviour clearly distinguishes
in curbing female labour force participation, as
between the cooperative and non-cooperative
suggested by Barros, Ramos, and Santos (1995), it
approaches. In the former, the allocations in the
is possible to conceive asymmetries within the
household reflect collective decisions and are
household that might make the aforementioned
assumed to be Pareto efficient, whereas, in the
unitary models of the household questionable.
latter category, one considers a non-cooperative
The resort to empirical models for discrete games
game-theoretic approach with the related solution
provides a possible methodological alternative for
concepts, as, for example, the Nash equilibrium.
assessing heterogeneous preferences within house-
A key issue is to what extent the preferences of the
holds. Bjorn and Vuong (1984, 1985) assume that
household members are unalike.
actually observed choices are consistent with parti-
Potential heterogeneities across members of
cular equilibrium concepts and outline identifica-
a household might be related to contrasts that
tion and estimation approaches using Nash and

CONTACT Marcelo Resende mresende@ie.ufrj.br Instituto de Economia, Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro, Av. Pasteur 250, Urca, Rio de
Janeiro-RJ 22290-240, Brazil
© 2019 Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group
2 M. RESENDE AND V. CARDOSO

Stackelberg models in the context of labour force and weaker when the number of preschool children
participation.1 The illustrative empirical application was larger.
that follows is further enhanced by Kooreman Altogether, the previous evidence suggests
(1994), who also considered a Pareto efficient potentially relevant gender differences in the con-
model applied to Dutch survey data for couples. text of labour force participation and the need for
Those frameworks remain as relevant approaches careful controls for heterogeneity across house-
in the case of static econometric models for discrete holds. Moreover, even though it is possible that
games [see useful overviews of the literature in some of those differences have faded over the
Bajari, Hong, and Ryan (2010) and Bajari, Hong, years, the issue still is relevant. The present article
and Nekipelov (2013)] undertakes a discrete game-theoretic application to
Thus, one can highlight non-cooperative models labour force participation in the Brazilian econ-
that may or may not allow for leadership behaviour omy. It intends to contribute in at least two levels:
of one of the partners and yet impose Pareto
optimality and are compatible with a collective (a) Previous game-theoretic applications that
decision in the household. The empirical evidence are analogous to the present study were
has made use of models with a relatively limited based on smaller and more homogeneous
number of controls for individual characteristics economies. The consideration of a large and
but indicated some noticeable results, such as the heterogeneous developing economy similar
asymmetric effect of one spouse’s wage on the to Brazil may potentially uncover important
participation of the other member of the couple.2 gender differences that are relevant for
Previous empirical evidence on labour force par- labour force participation. Thus, the
ticipation in Brazil appears to favour the existence empirical application for such a complex
of heterogeneous preferences within households. economy, segmented by rural and urban
The evidence based on the same survey data for areas, might potentially underscore differ-
Brazil [Pesquisa Nacional por Amostra de ences between more traditional and more
Domicílios (PNAD-IBGE)] is suggestive. Sedlacek modern regions;
and Santos (1991), based on survey data for the (b) Potential shortcomings of earlier related evi-
1980s, also highlight a negative income effect asso- dence included the reliance on a relatively
ciated with the husband’s work and therefore sug- limited number of controls given estimation
gest a non-negligible dependence of the wife on her problems and a strongly asymmetric criterion
husband. Hoffmann and Leone (2004) investigated for defining women’s labour force participa-
labour force participation and household inequal- tion, as any part-time effort was accepted. The
ity in the period of 1981–2002. The decomposition present article also attempts to improve on
of the Gini index by factor components displayed those aspects.
a decrease in the participation of men’s earnings
and an increase in the participation of both The article is organized as follows. The second
women’s earnings and pensions in the inequality section provides a brief overview on the specifica-
of per capita household income. Thus, gender dif- tion of non-cooperative and cooperative discrete
ferences, while relevant, might also show important models for labour force participation. The third
changes over time. Finally, Ramos, Aguas, and section discusses the data construction and the
Furtado (2011) address the role of the socio- specification of the different empirical models.
economic status of the household in women’s par- The fourth section presents and discusses the esti-
ticipation in the labour force, taking as a reference mated results. The fifth section provides some final
survey data for the period of 2001–08. Participation comments and suggests avenues for possible future
was found to be stronger among poorer households research.

1
Kooreman and Kapteyn (1990) discuss identification issues in terms of game-theoretic models for labour supply with an empirical illustration that benefits
from information on preferred working hours.
2
Nevertheless, the game-theoretic approach to labour force participation includes only a handful of contributions, and another example pertains to volunteer
work participation as exemplified by Abbott (2009).
APPLIED ECONOMICS 3

II. Discrete games of labour market aspect advanced by those authors, mostly following
participation: an overview the notation of the latter. At first, we consider
Introduction
a general discussion of the different game-theoretic
solution concepts and in the sequence outline the
The random utility model discussed in McFadden linear parameterization of payoffs (utilities) of the
(1981) provides an economic foundation for dis- players along the lines of previous studies.
crete choice models where the observed value for
a discrete endogenous variable can be related to
Nash
particular values of latent variables reflecting differ-
The standard Nash equilibrium definition posits
ences between unobserved utilities associated with
a strategy profile (henceforth referred to as an allo-
the occurrence and non-occurrence of a particular
cation) defined by a pair of discrete choices in the
action. The model contends that the total utility
present where no player has a unilateral incentive to
associated with a particular choice may be decom-
deviate or equivalently the equilibrium choices
posed in terms of the sum of a deterministic com-
are mutually a best-response to each other. Thus,
ponent that can be related to particular observed
for Nash equilibrium to prevail, under a strict defi-
exogenous variables and a stochastic term. An
nition.
immediate challenge concerns the extension of the
single-agent choice formulation to a multiple agent
U m ðk; lÞ > U m ð1  k; lÞ and U f ðk; lÞ > U f
choice model with various interdependencies. In
ðk; 1  lÞ for k,l = 0,1
principle, one could conceive a simultaneous probit
model as a useful generalization of the single-agent
Once more, it becomes clear that one must essen-
problem; however, as indicated by Heckman (1978),
tially be concerned with the signs of differences in
the required coherency restrictions on the para-
utility levels. Specifically, if we consider the para-
meters eliminate the proposed simultaneity. Bjorn
meterization suggested in (1), the differences
and Vuong (1984) further elaborate on that issue in
Um(1,1) – Um(0,1), Um(1,0) – Um(0,0), Uf(1,1) –
the context of labour market participation. In parti-
Uf(1,0) and Uf(0,1) – Uf (0,0) will be readily
cular, the authors address the referred shortcoming
obtained. Furthermore, it becomes clear that
by considering two simplifying assumptions. First, m f
the difference in the stochastic components between αi 0 and αi 0 are not identified in this model.
working versus not working is equal across the Finally, a difficulty observed in this model per-
choices of the partner and the implied stochastic tains to cases of multiple equilibria or non-existence
components for the male and female agents of equilibrium. In those cases, Bjorn and Vuong
(denoted as εm and εf, respectively). Additionally, (1984), Kooreman (1994) and Abbott (2009) attrib-
one assumes that those values follow a bivariate uted equal weights for each of the individual out-
normal distribution with a zero mean, unit variance comes while constructing the maximum likelihood
and correlation ρ. Second, the difference in utility function.
that an agent obtains from working versus not
working when the partner works differ on the ana- Stackelberg
logous difference in the case that the partner does Bjorn and Vuong (1985) outline the discrete game
not work only by a constant term.3 Those assump- formulation in the Stackelberg model. The under-
tions provide the basis for discrete choice with lying logic of the model is to introduce an asymmetry
multiple agents, but to explicitly consider interde- between the partners where the leader has the advan-
pendencies, Bjorn and Vuong (1984, 1985) and tage in anticipating his/her partner’s best response
Kooreman (1994) interpret endogenous observed and incorporating it into its maximization problem.
variables as the outcome of a static discrete game. A male leadership model, for example, could be
Next, we schematically outline the main conceptual appealing if cultural aspects restrict the autonomy

3
The referred simplifications were considered in terms of assumptions A1, A2 and A3 in Bjorn and Vuong (1984) and lead to distinct-identified parameters under
the Nash, Stackelberg leadership (for male and female partners) whereas Kooreman (1994) develops the mixed Pareto–Nash model.
4 M. RESENDE AND V. CARDOSO

of female participation in decisions. Thus, the con- U m ðk; lÞ > U m ð1  k; 1  lÞ or


sideration of the analysis segmented in terms of rural U f ðk; lÞ > U f ð1  k; 1  lÞ
and urban areas will be potentially informative in the However, a shortcoming of the simple imposition
case of Brazil as considered in the later application. of Pareto optimality involves a large number of
An allocation (k,l), for k,l = 0,1, constitutes multiple solutions. Thus, to reduce the number of
a Stackelberg solution with the male as a leader Pareto optimal solutions, Kooreman (1994) con-
and the female as a follower if: siders the following simplifying assumptions to
U f ðk; lÞ > U f ðk; 1  lÞ consider the endogenous variables as outcomes of
a mixed Pareto optimality/Nash model:
and U m ðk; lÞ > U m ð1  k; lÞ
(i) Unique Nash equilibrium
U f ð1  k; lÞ > U f ð1  k; 1  lÞ
a. If the Nash equilibrium is also Pareto
or optimal, it is assumed to be the observed
outcome.
U f ðk; lÞ > U f ðk; 1  lÞ b. If the Nash equilibrium is not Pareto opti-
and U m ðk; lÞ > U m ð1  k; 1  lÞ mal, there exists exactly one outcome
where both the male and the female are
U f ð1  k; lÞ < U f ð1  k; 1  lÞ better off when compared to the Nash equi-
In the case that the leadership is reversed, one librium; then it is assumed that the players
can readily obtain analogous conditions by switch- choose such a Pareto efficient allocation.
ing subscripts. Given the parameterizations that are (ii) Two Nash equilibria (at least one of these
assumed for the utility levels in expression (1), it is will be Pareto optimal)
possible to establish the relevant probability state- a. If only one is Pareto optimal, this is
ments to construct the maximum likelihood func- assumed to be the observed outcome.
tion. The reader is once more referred to the details b. If both Nash equilibria are Pareto opti-
provided in Bjorn and Vuong (1984, 1985), mal, the players are assumed to choose
Kooreman (1994) and Abbott (2009). one of them with equal probability.
(iii) No Nash equilibrium and the game involves
two, three or four Pareto optimal alloca-
Pareto-Nash
tions. The players are assumed to randomly
It is well known that allocations associated with Nash select one of these Pareto optimal alloca-
equilibrium need not be Pareto efficient. Kooreman tions with equal probabilities.
(1994) extended the approach advanced by Bjorn
and Vuong (1984, 1985) by considering the possibi- In order to obtain an empirical implementation, we
lity of imposing Pareto optimality. Thus, it is possible need to consider the basic steps for identifying
to obtain a closer perspective on a cooperative different models as follows:
approach associated with a unitary household. One
cannot observe allocations upon which both partners (i) Parameterize utility levels U(ym,yf) for the
simultaneously improve, and therefore an allocation different combinations of discrete choices of
(k,l) is Pareto efficient if, for k,l = 0,1: the couple in terms of the labour market. The
decomposition posed by the random utility
U m ðk; lÞ > U m ðk; 1  lÞ or model is implemented with a linear func-
U f ðk; lÞ > ; U f ðk; 1  lÞ tional form for the deterministic component
and that depends on a vector of exogenous vari-
U m ðk; lÞ > U m ð1  k; lÞ or U f ðk; lÞ > U f ð1  k; lÞ ables. The latent variable that induces the
observed discrete choice consists of differ-
(3)
ences of utility levels, and specific differences
and display discrepancies among themselves by
APPLIED ECONOMICS 5

constant terms. Such an assumption greatly Notice that difficulties associated with non-
reduces the number of possible utility rank- existence or multiplicity of equilibria are
ings per player. The specifications are sum- approached by attributing equal weights in the
marized as follows: maximum likelihood function. In the case of this

U m ð1; 1Þ ¼ x0 βm U f ð1; 1Þ ¼ x0 β1 þ α1 þ ε1
f f f
1 þ α1 þ ε1
m m

U m ð1; 0Þ ¼ x0 βm U f ð1; 0Þ ¼ x0 βm
f
1 þ εm
1 0 þ α0 þ ε 0
m
(1)
U m ð0; 1Þ ¼ x0 βm U f ð0; 1Þ ¼ x0 β1
f f
0 þ α0 þ ε0 þ ε1
m m

U m ð0; 0Þ ¼ x0 βm U f ð0; 0Þ ¼ x0 β0
f f
0 þ εm
0 þ ε0

The contrast between the different formulations model, the individual gender-specific parameters
f f
1 , α0 , α1 and α0 are identified.
αm
[Nash, Stackelberg leadership (by male or female) m

and imposed Pareto optimality] will emerge in


terms of partner-specific constants or differences
in the constants identified in each case. It will be III. Data construction
convenient to define αi ¼ αi1  αi0 and εi ¼ εi1  εi0 This study is based on the annual household survey
for i = m, f. conducted by the Brazilian statistical bureau [Pesquisa
Under the linear parameterizations specified in Nacional de Amostra por Domicílios-PNAD-IBGE]
m f
expression (1) αi 0 and αi 0 are not identified in the for 2013. In this survey, samples of couples were
Nash model. In the case of Stackelberg leadership, constructed for rural and urban areas. The dependent
it is possible to verify that in the case of male variables are given by binary variables indicating
leadership, αm1 , α0 and α are readily identified,
m f
participation or non-participation in the labour mar-
whereas α can be recovered upon the first two
m
ket. In contrast, with Kooreman, who considered
parameters. In the case of female leadership, the a full-time participation criterion for men and
f f
reverse situation occurs, with the α1 , α0 and αm a flexible part-time criterion for women, we consider
coefficients being readily identified. a symmetric principle for both. Specifically,5
ym = 1 if the man works at least 40 h per week
(1) The different solution concepts will impose and 0 otherwise,
restrictions in terms of consistency as related yf = 1 if the woman works at least 40 h per week
to the best responses of the players. Thus, it and 0 otherwise.
will be possible to construct the maximum In our full sample of 71,438 households, we
likelihood functions once probability state- observe the following allocation: (0,0): 17,906
ments are established for different ranges of cases; (0,1): 4221 cases; (1,0): 30,125 cases; and
the stochastic term εi. The relevant details (1,1): 19,186 cases.
appear in Bjorn and Vuong (1984, 1985) The definitions of the considered variables and
and Kooreman (1994). Next, we sketch some the related summary statistics are presented in
basic aspects in each of the considered models Table 1.
and closely follow, in a more synthetic form, Additionally, we have considered a dummy
the presentation by Kooreman (1994).4 variable DURB that assumes value one in urban

4
The equilibria for the possible configurations in the case of the four solution concepts are detailed in Tables AI, AII and AIII presented in Kooreman (1994).
5
The econometric analysis also considered regional dummies for the macro-regions in Brazil (North, Midwest, Northeast, Southeast and South), and the
corresponding estimates can be provided upon request.
6 M. RESENDE AND V. CARDOSO

Table 1. Description of variables and summary statistics (no. of observations: 70,079).


Variable Description Mean Std. Dev. Minimum Maximum
AGEM Age in years (male partner) 46.467 14.670 15.000 94.000
AGEF Age in years (female partner) 42.865 14.060 13.000 90.000
EDUCM Schooling in years (male partner) 7.426 4.660 0.000 17.000
EDUCF Schooling in years (female partner) 8.085 4.583 0.000 17.000
EMPM Employed – 40 hours of weekly work (male partner) 0.691 0.462 0.000 1.000
EMPF Employed – 40 hours of weekly work (female partner) 0.325 0.468 0.000 1.000
WAGEM Monthly wage in $R (male partner) 1,531.904 1,827.283 0.000 30,000.000
WAGEF Monthly wage in $R (female partner) 642.937 992.344 0.000 11,000.000
NPH Number of people living in household 3.554 1.385 2.000 19.000
CHILD Number of children younger than 6 years old living in household 0.315 0.577 0.000 7.000
NLINC Other non-labour incomes in R$ 522.651 1,138.889 0.000 20,100.000

areas and 0 in rural areas and yet a set of dummy IV. Empirical results
variables for the five macro-regions in Brazil
Introduction
[North (DNO). Northeast (DNE), Midwest
(DMW), South (DSO) and southeast (DSE)], In this section, we discuss the most prominent
those variables assume value one for households results and contrasts observed in the different mod-
in the given region and 0 otherwise. In the actual els in comparison with previous analogous evi-
estimation, DSE was not considered so as to avoid dence for developed economies. All estimations
the so-called dummy trap. were implemented with Stata codes available in
It is important to stress that sample has Abbott (2009) using the software Stata 13. The
a large number of observations with a zero results are reported in Table 2.
wage in association to non-participating persons A first general remark involves the prevalence
that might induce convergence problems in the of non-linear effects for some variables, the
estimation of the models. Kooreman (1994) similarity of coefficients of some variables across
addresses such issue by means of a data imputa- models and gender asymmetries. Those general
tion procedure where the (potential) wages of features also prevailed in the case of Kooreman
non-participating persons are predicted upon (1994), who studied the Netherlands, a small,
the selectivity bias-corrected wage equations. developed and more homogeneous country.
The exact details are not provided; however, However, in the present application, there are
one can conceive an analogous procedure to dissimilarities with the aforementioned previous
the so-called heckit [see e.g. Heckman (1976, work. In particular, it is possible to effectively
1979)]. In the present application, however, we incorporate the education and non-labour
have bivariate models and therefore income controls that led to estimation problems
consider the estimation of bivariate probit to in Kooreman’s work. Nevertheless, a general
obtain inverse Mills ratios from the estimated par- convergence problem prevailed when trying to
ticipation equation. Those are used as additional include a quadratic term for wages in the differ-
regressors in the wage equations for participating ent models, and thus such a specification was
persons in order to correct for sample selection. disregarded.
The equations were estimated by the method of
Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR) in order
Main results
to take into account a possible correlation between
errors of the wage equations for the male and From a statistical perspective, the models dis-
female partners. The predicted values can then be played satisfactory results, with a high propor-
used as potential wages for non-participating tion of individually significant coefficients at the
persons.6 5% significance level that typically displayed

6
The wage equations followed a Mincerian specification with age, squared age, education, squared education, regional dummy variables and a dummy variable
for urban areas.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 7

Table 2. Estimation results for 2013 (no. of observations: 70,079). Table 2. (Continued).
Mixed Mixed
Stackelberg Stackelberg Pareto– Stackelberg Stackelberg Pareto–
Nash male leader female leader Nash Nash male leader female leader Nash
βm αf0 – – −0.589 0.816
Constant −0.188 −0.163 −0.157 −0.182 (0.000) (0.015)
(0.004) (0.016) (0.016) (0.005) αm 0.219 0.309* −0.053 −0.224*
WAGEM 2.66E-04 3.03E-04 2.59E-04 2.66E-04 (0.000) (0.994) (0.129) (0.004)
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) αf 0.123 −0.034 0.176** −0.125**
WAGEF −1.20E-04 −1.36E-04 −5.38E-05 −1.20E-04 (0.050) (0.000) (0.515) (0.852)
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) ρ 0.144 0.106 0.149 −0.008
AGEM 0.058 0.056 0.059 0.058 (0.731) (0.008) (0.000) (0.843)
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) loglikelihood −64,222.036 −64,113.936 −64,227.191 −64,221.525
AGEM2 −9.06E-04 −9.00E-04 −9.29E-04 −9.07E-04 Wald χ 2 (14) 13,135.25 12,781.95 16,062.09 12,730.83
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
EDUCM 0.047 0.047 0.050 0.047 AIC 128,510.1 128,295.9 128,522.4 128,513.1
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) BIC 128,812.3 128,607.2 128,833.7 128,833.6
EDUCM2 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 % of correct 80.55% M 80.66% M 80.48% M 80.55%M
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) predictions 77.67% F 79.41% F 76.82% F 77.73% F
CHILD −0.028 −0.032 −0.040 −0.029
1 and α0
Note: p-values are reported in parentheses; (*) obtained upon the αm m
(0.017) (0.016) (0.000) (0.015)
NPH 0.018 0.018 0.018 0.017 estimated coefficients; (**) obtained upon the αf1 and αf0 estimated
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) coefficients
NLINC −2.35E-04 −2.37E-04 −2.45E-04 −2.35E-04
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
DURB −0.080 −0.084 −0.064 −0.080
(0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) expected signs. In terms of the overall fit, the
DNE −0.173 −0.166 −0.180 −0.173
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
models exhibit similarities and, if we take as
DNO −0.157 −0.152 −0.169 −0.157 reference the information criteria based on the
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
DSO −0.013 −0.019 −0.001 −0.013 log-likelihood, such as the AIC and BIC, the
(0.456) (0.305) (0.963) (0.462) evidence favours the choice of the Stackelberg
DMW −0.025 −0.020 −0.030 −0.026
(0.213) (0.345) (0.136) (0.211) male leader model. The same model is favoured,
βf if one considers a criterion based on the propor-
Constant −2.10 −2.014 −2.138 −2.209
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
tion of correct predictions. It is worth mention-
WAGEF 9.13E-04 9.08E-04 9.19E-04 9.13E-04 ing that:
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
WAGEM −1.16E-04 −1.13E-04 −1.19E-04 −1.17E-04
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (i) The own wage coefficients are now
AGEF 0.055 0.057 0.055 0.055
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) always positive and significant for both
AGEF2 −8.02E-04 −8.30E-04 −7.89E-04 −8.00E-04 equations and with similar patterns
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
EDUCF 0.113 0.114 0.113 0.113 across models;
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (ii) Cross-wage effects are significant for
EDUCF2 −0.007 −0.007 −0.007 −0.007
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) male participation, with WAGEF exert-
CHILD −0.150 −0.151 −0.150 −0.150
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
ing a negative effect on male participation
NPH −0.005 −0.004 −0.005 −0.004 under all models. Similarly, WAGEM
(0.357) (0.448) (0.319) (0.349)
NLINC −1.51E-04 −1.64E-04 −1.43E-04 −1.50E-04 appears to inhibit female participation
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) under all specifications;
DURB 0.165 0.160 0.168 0.163
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (iii) Non-linear impacts of age prevail with
DNE −0.101 −0.110 −0.100 −0.100 similar patterns across models and indicate
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
DNO −0.164 −0.173 −0.161 −0.162 decreasing importance of additional years
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
DSO 0.158 0.160 0.160 0.158
in explaining labour market participation;
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (iv) The clear non-linear effect of education is
DMW −0.067 −0.070 −0.066 −0.067
(0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) similar across models and reveals
αm
1 – 9.472293 – −0.239 a decreasing role of additional schooling
(0.651) (0.000)
αm
0 – 9.16457 – −0.015 years on labour force participation. In the
(0.662) (0.509) case of the female partner, the result is
αf1 – – −0.413 0.691
(0.003) (0.038) slightly more clear cut, with a positive effect
(Continued)
8 M. RESENDE AND V. CARDOSO

that slows down with additional years of coefficients show non-negligible variation
schooling;7 across the different models. The former coef-
(v) The number of persons in the household ficient is significant and positive in the Nash
(NPH) have similar significant coefficients equilibrium specification and negative under
across the different models. However, it is the mixed Pareto–Nash model, whereas the
possible to observe asymmetric patterns latter is significant and positive the Nash
across partners in terms of a positive effect specification but negative and significant
on the man’s participation decision but under the Stackelberg male leader formula-
a negligible effect on the woman’s partici- tion. A positive sign for αm would indicate
pation decision; that, ceteris paribus, the male partner is
(vi) Non-labour income (NLINC) negatively more likely to participate in the labour mar-
affects market participation for both part- ket if his female partner works, whereas
ners, with similar coefficients across mod- positive and negative signs for αf would,
els for a given partner; respectively, suggest that, ceteris paribus,
(vii) The number of children under the age of the male partner’s participation tends to
six (CHILD) can potentially motivate an positively/negatively affect female
asymmetry between the two partners in participation.
terms of labour market participation.
However, the evidence supporting signifi-
Summary of the evidence and preliminary
cant negative effects occurs in both gen-
conclusions
ders and under all models, albeit the effect
was stronger for women, as expected. The roles of own and cross wages and age in
However, if the sample is restricted to explaining labour market participation are qualita-
men younger than 55 years old, the para- tively similar to the previous evidence provided by
meter loses its statistical significance, while Kooreman (1994) for a small-developed country.9
it does not for women;8 An important contrast with the previous evidence
(viii) The dummy for urban areas (DURB) involves the relevant and robust roles exhibited by
always has significant coefficients in all education and non-labour income (NLINC) in
models but with negative signs in the case explaining labour market participation. Thus, the
of male partners and positive signs in the present article identifies an important inhibiting role
case of female partners; on participation accruing from non-labour income.
(ix) The different regional dummy variables Educational levels exerted a positive influence on
exerted significant effects on labour market the labour participation decision of both members
participation, which reinforces the hetero- of the family but the effects operate at a decreasing
geneous nature of that large economy; rate as indicated by the negative coefficients of
(x) Finally, it is worth commenting on gender- EDUCM2 and EDUCF2.10
specific parameters or the difference of para- Some features of the households also indicate
meters that are specifically identified under important gender contrasts. The number of per-
the different models. The αm and αf sons in the household is significant for male

7
Such a consideration is especially discussed in the literature on returns for education, but a limitation of the usually available data refers to the lack of
information on education quality. Resende and Wyllie (2006) provide evidence on the positive role of education quality on the aforementioned returns.
8
Unfortunately, the survey data do not include information on daycare availability, but in any case, it is well known that daycare is much less widespread in rural
areas in Brazil. Evidence, as suggested by Gathman and Sass (2012), appears to indicate a non-negligible role of childcare availability on labour supply in
terms of the impact of related taxes.
9
However, one has to be cautious about direct comparisons, as Kooreman (1994) adopted a part-time participation criterion for the female partner, and the
present study considers a more recent period.
10
Educational levels of the partners may be positively correlated in terms of an assortative mating phenomenon as investigated by Greenwood et al. (2014). We
carried out an exploratory estimation that appears to suggest the relevance of that effect. However, female labour market participation is still low in Brazil
despite relevant increases over time. In fact, a counterfactual exercise for Brazil involving a random matching procedure indicated a sharp contrast against
evidence for the US, where the effect of female labour participation in labour income inequality seems to be substantial, which can be explained by the
higher female labour participation rate in the US. It is also important to note that despite the historical increase in female participation in Brazil, as
documented by Scorzafave and Menezes-Filho (2001), it remains somewhat low.
APPLIED ECONOMICS 9

partners only and tends to increase the propensity that the well-known low labour market participation
to participate in the labour market. However, the for women in Brazil embodies to some extent
number of children younger than 6 years old a cultural component. It is worth noticing that
showed negative parameters for all equations, labour market participation by women can have
albeit the effect was much stronger for women, as relevant implications for labour income inequality
expected. However, when the sample is restricted [see Hoffmann and Leone (2004) and Greenwood
to men younger than 55 years old, the parameter et al. (2014)]. In any case, and similarly to
loses its statistical significance. Kooreman (1994), the contrasts between the differ-
The regional terms either in terms of the macro- ent models are somewhat subtle and as conjectured
regions or in terms of the rural/dichotomy appear as by that author, it could be the case that the inter-
relevant in a large and heterogeneous economy such dependence between male and female partners are
as Brazil. mostly captured by cross coefficients that could
reduce the scope for a relevant role by the αm and
αf coefficients.
V. Final comments The topic of the present article warrants further
This article investigated labour force participation investigations, as a large and complex emerging econ-
by considering a game-theoretic framework where omy similar to Brazil, may be more prone to gender-
the observed endogenous variables are assumed to specific issues than more developed economies. In
be the outcome of a game in accordance with particular, it is possible to suggest at least two avenues
different solution concepts. The consideration of for future research:
a large and heterogeneous developing economy
segmented into rural and urban areas led to statis- (a) Consider a similar study in a more distant
tically sound estimates that partially corroborated past period, in that case, cultural aspects
previous evidence for a developed country but dis- could have been more relevant and the com-
played important contrasts. In fact, the effects per- parison of the results and evidence of possible
taining to own wage, cross wage and age effects contrasts relative to 2013 could be relevant;
were qualitatively similar as was the stronger inhi- (b) The maximum likelihood procedures adopted
biting role of the number of small children in the for the estimation of the models relied on ran-
case of the female partner. dom selection when non-existence or multi-
However, other important asymmetries emerged plicity of equilibria were an issue, with the
as given by the more limited role of schooling in imposition of equal weights as done in Bjorn
labour market participation in rural areas. The very and Vuong (1984), Kooreman (1994) and
high returns to education in Brazil might shed some Abbott (2009). A less restrictive treatment of
light on this question, as urban households have the multiple equilibria phenomenon consid-
a markedly higher educational level. Important gen- ered in a recent study would be a pertinent
der contrasts are suggestive in terms of the number extension [see De Paula (2013) for an
of persons in the household.11 This variable has overview]
a significant effect on male partners only and indi-
cates a larger propensity to participate in the labour
market. Although some coefficients are sometimes Acknowledgments
similar across models, it is possible to observe regio- The authors acknowledge comments from two anonymous
nal and gender-specific contrasts that reinforce the referees but the usual caveats apply.
potential interest in a complex developing economy
similar to Brazil. Moreover, the identification of the
Disclosure statement
Stackelberg male leader model as a preferential spe-
cification under a particular criterion might indicate No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.

11
There are studies that assess the returns to schooling in Brazil from a regional perspective, such as Suliano and Siqueira (2012), although they do not consider
the rural/urban contrast. A summary of the earlier literature on returns to schooling in Brazil appears in Resende and Wyllie (2006).
10 M. RESENDE AND V. CARDOSO

References dependent cariables.” Annals of Economic and Social


Measurement 5: 475–492.
Abbott, M. R. 2009. Modelling Decisions to Volunteer at Heckman, J. J. 1978. “Dummy endogenous variables in
a Household Level, unpublished B.S. Honors Monograph. a simultaneous equation system.” Econometrica 46: 931–
University of New South Wales- School of Economics. 960.
Bajari, P., H. Hong, and D. Nekipelov. 2013. “Game theory and Heckman, J. J. 1979. “Sample selection bias as a specification
econometrics: a survey of some recent research.” In Advances error.” Econometrica 47: 153–161.
in Economics and Econometrics: Tenth World Congress, edited Hoffmann, R., and E. T. Leone. 2004. “Participação da
by D. Acemoglu, M. Arellano, and E. Dekel, 3–52. Vol. 3. mulher no mercado de trabalho e desigualdade da
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. renda domiciliar per capita no Brasil: 1981-2002.” Nova
Bajari, P., H. Hong, and S. P. Ryan. 2010. “Identification and Economia 14: 35–58.
estimation of adiscrete games of complete information.” Kooreman, P. 1994. “Estimation of econometric models of
Econometrica 78: 1529–1568. some discrete games.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 9:
Barros, R., L. Ramos, and E. Santos. 1995. “Gender differences 255–268.
in Brazilian labor markets.” In Investment in Women’s Kooreman, P., and A. Kapteyn. 1990. “On the empirical imple-
Human Capital, edited by P. Schultz, 380–427. Chicago: mentation of some game theoretic models of household labor
University of Chicago Press. supply.” Journal of Human Resources 25: 584–598.
Becker, G. S. 1964. Human Capital. New York: Columbia McElroy, M. B. 1990. “The empirical content of
University Press. Nash-bargained household behavior.” Journal of Human
Bjorn, P. A., and Q. H. Vuong. 1984. “Simultaneous equations Resouces 25: 559–583.
models for dummy endogenous variables: a game theoretic McFadden, D. 1981. “Econometric models of probabilistic
formulation with an application to labor force choice.” In Structural Analysis of Discrete Data with
participation.” Social Science Working Paper 537, Econometric Applications, edited by C. Manski and
California Institute of Technology. D. McFadden, 198–272. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Bjorn, P. A., and Q. H. Vuong. 1985. “Econometric modeling Ramos, L., M. F. F. Aguas, and L. M. S. Furtado. 2011.
of a Stackelberg game with an application to labor force “Participação feminina na força de trabalho metropolitano:
participation.” Social Science Working Paper 577, California o papel do status socioeconômico das famílias.” Economia
Institute of Technology. Aplicada 15: 595–611.
Chiappori, P. A., and O. Donni. 2011. “Non-unitary models of Resende, M., and R. Wyllie. 2006. “Retornos para educação no
household behavior: a survey of the literature.” In Brasil: evidências empíricas adicionais.” Economia Aplicada
Household Economic Behaviors, edited by A. Molina, 10: 349–365.
1–40. New York: Springer. Scorzafave, L. G., and N. A. Menezes-Filho. 2001. “Participação
De Paula, A. 2013. “Econometric analysis of games with, ultiple feminina no mercado de trabalho brasileiro: evolução e
equilibria.” Annual Review of Economics 5: 107–131. determinantes.” Pesquisa e Planejamento Econômico 31:
Gathman, C., and B. Sass. 2012. “Taxing childcare: effects on 441–478.
family labor supply and children.” IZA DP No. 6440. Sedlacek, G. L., and E. C. Santos. 1991. “A mulher cônjuge
Greenwood, J., N. Guner, G. Kocharkov, and C. Santos. 2014. no mercado de trabalho como estratégia de geração da
“Marry your like: assortative mating and income renda familiar.” Pesquisa e Planejamento Econômico 21:
inequality.” American Economic Review: Papers and 449–470.
Proceedings, 104, 1–10. Suliano, D. C., and M. L. Siqueira. 2012. “Retornos da
Grossbard, S. 2011. “Independent individual decision-makers educação no Brasil em âmbito regional considerando um
in household models and the new home economics.” In ambiente de menor desigualdade.” Economia Aplicada 16:
Household Economic Behaviors, edited by A. Molina, 41–56. 137–165.
New York: Springer. Thomas, D. 1990. “Intra-household resource allocation: an
Heckman, J. J. 1976. “The common structure of statistical inferential approach.” Journal of Human Resources 25:
models of truncation, sample selection and limited 635–664.

You might also like