Economics of Production

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

Economics of Production

Concept of production function


Production function is a mathematical expression showing quantity of a good that can be
produced per unit of time from a set of alternative inputs, when the best production technique
available is used. Symbolically, Q = f (𝑥1 , 𝑥2 ¸ 𝑥3 , …… 𝑥𝑛 ), is a production function in case
of ‘n’ number of inputs; Q being quantity of the good produced and xi = quantity of ith input.

Short-run and long-run production function


In the theory of production, the term short-run signifies a period of time when at least one of
the inputs participating in the production process is held constant. Hence, a short-run
production function is of the form: Q = f (𝑥1 , 𝑥2 ¸ 𝑥̅ 3, …… 𝑥𝑛 ), where the bar sign above the
symbol for input indicates constancy of that input. Conversely, the term long-run signifies a
period of time when all the inputs participating in the production process are variable.
Symbolically, a long-run production function is of the form: Q = f (𝑥1 , 𝑥2 ¸ 𝑥3 , …… 𝑥𝑛 ).

Concept of total product, average product and marginal product


Total product of input x1 (TPx1 ) refers to the amount of output which is produced when all
other input quantities are held constant and only the quantity of input ‘x1’ is varied.
Accordingly, 𝑇𝑃𝑥1 = Q = f (𝑥1 , x̅2 , 𝑥̅3 ….…𝑥̅𝑛 )

Average product of x1 ( APx1 ) is defined as the amount of output which is on average

produced by one unit of x1, when all other input quantities are held constant and only the

quantity of input x1 is varied. Mathematically, APx1 can be expressed as,


𝑇𝑃𝑥1 Q 𝑓 (𝑥1 , 𝑥̅2 , 𝑥̅ 3 …….. 𝑥̅𝑛 )
APx1 = = =
𝑥1 x1 𝑥1

Marginal product of x1 ( MPx1 ) is defined as the amount of incremental output which is


produced by an additional unit of x1, when all other input quantities are held constant and
∆TPx1
only the quantity of input x1 is varied. That is, MPx1 = (for large changes in x1). And,
∆x1

∂TPx1 ∂Q ∂𝑓 (𝑥1 , 𝑥̅2 , 𝑥̅ 3 …….. 𝑥̅𝑛 )


MPx1 = = = (for very small changes in x1)
∂x1 ∂x1 ∂x1

1
Concept of iso-quant and rate of technical substitution (RTS)

In case of two input case, production function is Q = f (x1, x2), and production function for a
specific iso-quant is Q0 = f (x1, x2). Along a definite iso-quant curve, dQ = 0. Hence, f1dx1 +
𝑑𝑥2 𝑓
f2dx2 = 0 and
𝑑𝑥1
= – 𝑓1 = RTS
2

Concept of cost equation and iso-cost line

In two-input case, cost equation is, C = r1x1 + r2x2 + b and equation form of isocost line is,
C0 = r1x1 + r2x2 + b.

𝐶0 − 𝑏 𝑟1 𝑥1 𝑑𝑥2 𝑟
Or, x2 = − . Hence, slope of iso-cost line = = − 𝑟1 = ratio of input prices.
𝑟2 𝑟2 𝑑𝑥1 2

Cobb-Douglas Production Function


The Cobb-Douglas production function is based on the empirical study of the American
manufacturing industry made by Paul H. Douglas and C.W. Cobb. It took into account two
inputs, labour and capital, for the entire output of the manufacturing industry. Moreover, it is
a homogeneous production function having homogeneity of degree one. The production
function solved by Cobb-Douglas had 1/4th contribution of capital to the increase in
manufacturing industry and 3/4th of labour so that the C-D production function is: AK 0.25L 0.75

General form of Cobb-Douglas production function is, Q = AKαLβ, where,


Q = Quantity of output produced (Q ˃ 0); A = Efficiency parameter (A ˃ 0)
K = Amount of capital used (K ˃ 0); L = Amount of labour used (L ˃ 0);
α = Exponent of capital ( 0 < α < 1); β = Exponent of labour ( 0 < β < 1);

Characteristics Features of Cobb-Douglas Production Function (CDPF)


In case of CDPF corresponding iso-quant is negatively sloped and convex to the origin
We know that, along any iso-quant, dQ = f1dx1 + f2dx2 = 0
𝜕𝑄 𝜕𝑄
Hence, in case of Cobb-Douglas production function, dQ = dK + dL = 0
𝜕𝐾 𝜕𝐿

Or, α A K α−1 L β dK + β A K α L β−1 dL = 0


𝑑𝐾 𝛽𝐴𝐾 𝛼 𝐿𝛽−1 𝛽𝐾
Or, =− =− ˃0 (K ˃ 0; L ˃ 0; α ˃ 0; β ˃ 0 )
𝑑𝐿 𝛼𝐴𝐾 𝛼−1 𝐿𝛽 𝛼𝐿

2
𝑑 𝑑𝐾 𝑑2𝐾 𝑑 𝛽𝐾 𝛽 𝑑 𝐾
Now, ( )= = (− )=− ( )
𝑑𝐿 𝑑𝐿 𝑑𝐿2 𝑑𝐿 𝛼𝐿 𝛼 𝑑𝐿 𝐿
𝑑𝐾 𝑑𝐿 𝛽𝐾
𝛽 (𝐿 𝑑𝐿 ‒ 𝐾 𝑑𝐿) 𝛽 {𝐿 (‒ 𝛼𝐿 ) ‒ 𝐾}
=− =−
𝛼 𝐿2 𝛼 𝐿2
𝛽𝐾 𝛽 𝛽𝐾
=
𝛼𝐿2
( 𝛼 + 1) =
𝛼 2 𝐿2
(α + β) ˃ 0 (K ˃ 0; L ˃ 0; α ˃ 0; β ˃ 0)

Homogeneous and non-homogeneous production function


A production function is said to be homogeneous if it is possible to change the inputs used by
a fixed factor. Let, Q = f (K, L) = K.L
In this case, Q* = (𝜆 K) (𝜆 𝐿) = 𝜆2K.L = 𝜆2 Q, and, hence, degree of homogeneity is 2.
A production function is said to be non-homogeneous if it is not possible to change the inputs
used by a fixed factor. Let, Q = f (K, L) = L + K2
In this case, Q*= (𝜆 𝐿) + (𝜆 K)2 = 𝜆 L + 𝜆2 K2

Degree of homogeneity and returns to scale


Returns to scale describes the output response to a proportionate change in the level of all
inputs. If output changes by the same proportion, returns to scale are constant for the range of
input combinations under consideration. They are increasing, if output increases by a greater
proportion and decreasing if it increases by a smaller proportion. Returns to scale are easily
defined for homogeneous production functions. A production function is homogeneous of
degree ‘r’ if, f (λ K, λ L) = λr f (K, L), where, ‘r’ is a positive real number and is constant. In
this case, if both inputs are increased by the factor, ‘λ’, output is increased by the factor ‘λr’.
Returns to scale are increasing, if, r ˃ 1; returns to scale are constant, if, r = 1 and returns to
scale are decreasing, if, r < 1.

Case of constant returns to scale (r = 1):


Q = f (K, L) = K.75 L.25 In this case, Q* = (λ K).75 (λ L).25 = λ1 KL = λ Q
Case of increasing returns to scale (r ˃ 1):
Q = f (K, L) = K.75 L.3 In this case, Q* = (λ K).75 (λ L).3 = λ1.05 K.75 L.3 = λ1.05 Q
Case of decreasing returns to scale ( r < 1):
Q = f (K, L) = K.75 L.2 In this case, Q* = (λ K).75 (λ L).2 = λ.95 K.75 L.2 = λ.95 Q
Case of zero returns to scale ( r = 0):
Q = f (K, L) = K.5 L−.5 In this case, Q* = (λ K).5 (λ L) −.5 = λ0 KL = λ0 Q

3
Characteristic features of homogeneous production functions
a) These production functions give rise to downward sloping and convex to the origin
indifference curves.
b) In case of these functions, expansion paths are straight lines passing through the origin.
c) In case of these production functions, ridge lines are also straight lines passing through the
origin.

Cobb-Douglas production function is homogeneous of degree α + β


For estimating the degree of homogeneity, we change both ‘K’ and ‘L’ by ‘λ’ times. Hence,
we have, Q* = A (λ K)α (λ L) β = λα + β A K α L β = λα + β Q (where, Q* = new output)
In the special case of α + β = 1, the production function will be homogeneous of degree one.

Marginal and average products of capital and labour are homogeneous of degree α+β–1
for unspecified values of α and β and are homogeneous of degree zero when α + β = 1
Given Q = A Kα Lβ ;
𝜕Q
MPK = = α A Kα – 1Lβ ,
∂K

Hence, MPK∗ = α A(λ K)α – 1 (λ L)β = λα + β – 1 α AKα– 1Lβ = λα + β – 1 MPK


𝜕Q
MPL = = βAKαLβ – 1
∂L

Hence, MPL∗ = βA (λ K)α (λ L) β – 1 = λα + β – 1 β A Kα Lβ – 1 = λα + β – 1 MPL


Q 𝐴𝐾 𝛼 𝐿𝛽
APK = = = AKα – 1Lβ
K 𝐾
α–1 β
Hence, APK∗ = A(λ K)α – 1 (λ L)β = λα + β – 1 AK L = λα + β – 1 APK
Q 𝐴𝐾 𝛼 𝐿𝛽
APL = = = A Kα L β – 1
L 𝐿

Hence, APL∗ = A (λ K)α (λ L) β – 1 = λα + β – 1 A K α Lβ – 1 = λα + β – 1 APL

Exponents of the variables express output elasticity with respect to those variables
Given Q = A K αL β
𝜕Q 𝐾𝛼 𝐿𝛽 𝛼𝑄 𝜕𝑄 𝐾𝛼 𝐿 𝛽 𝛽𝑄
∂K
= α A K α – 1L β = α A = and,
𝜕𝐿
= β A K αL β–1 = β A =
𝐿
𝐾 𝐾 𝐿

𝜕𝑄 𝐾 𝛼𝑄 𝐾
Now, elasticity of output with respect to capital (K) = EQK = = =α
𝜕𝐾 𝑄 𝐾 𝑄
𝜕𝑄 𝐿 𝛽𝑄 𝐾
And, elasticity of output with respect to labour (L) = EQL = = =β
𝜕𝐿 𝑄 𝐾 𝑄

4
Exponents of each variable show relative share of that input in total output
Given Q = A K α L β
𝑀𝑃𝐾 𝑥 𝐾 𝛼𝑄 𝐾
Capital’s share in total output = = = α (constant)
𝑄 𝐾 𝑄
𝑀𝑃𝐿 𝐿 𝛽𝑄 𝐾
Similarly, labour’s share in total output = = = β (constant)
𝑄 𝐾 𝑄

Euler’s Theorem
Leonard Euler, a Swiss mathematician developed this theorem at the end of 1930s. The
theorem played a major role in the development of ‘Marginal Productivity Theory of
Distribution’. The theorem is a mathematical proposition which states that if a production
function is homogeneous of degree one (i.e. it exhibits constant returns to scale) and the
participating inputs are paid in accordance to their marginal productivity; then, while making
payments to inputs, total product will be fully exhausted with no surplus and deficit.

Basic assumptions of the theorem


i) There is perfect competition in both the product and factor markets. ii) Factors of
production are perfectly divisible. iii) Production technology is given. iv) Long-run period is
considered. v) Each input is paid the value of its marginal product. vi) Production function is
homogeneous of degree one; that is, it exhibits constant returns to scale.

Economic implications of the theorem


a) If production function is homogeneous of degree one and inputs are paid at the rate of their
MPs, then total output will be exhausted. That is, MPK.K + MPL.L = Q

b) If production function is homogeneous of degree one and inputs are paid at the rate of their
MPs, then monetary value of output will be equal to total cost of production.
As we have seen, Q = MPK.K + MPL.L
Or, PQ = P. MPK.K + P.MPL.L (dividing both sides by ‘P’)
= VMPK.K + VMPL.L (VMPK= Value of MPK ; VMPL = Value of MPL)
= rK + wL = TC

c) Long-run profit is zero.


We know, ∏ = TR ─ TC = PQ ─ TC.

5
According to (b) PQ = wL + rK and, TC = wL + rK, hence, TR = TC ; that is, ∏ = 0

d) Under perfect competition, factor shares in total output equal total output.
𝑤𝐿 𝑟𝐾
Labour’s share in total output = , and capital’s share in total output =
𝑃𝑄 𝑃𝑄
𝑤𝐿 𝑟𝐾 𝑤𝐿 + 𝑟𝐾 𝑃𝑄
Hence, combined share of labour and capital = + = = =1
𝑃𝑄 𝑃𝑄 𝑃𝑄 𝑃𝑄

(earlier proved that, wL + rK = PQ)

e) In case of homogeneous production functions of degree one, if MP of one factor is zero,


then, in case of other factor MP = AP
Proof: Q = MPK.K + MPL.L
If, now MPK = 0, then, Q = MPL.L; Or, Q L = MPL i.e., APL = MPL

CDPF satisfies Euler’s theorem


Given Q = A K α L β
MPK x K αQ K
Capital’s share in total output = = =α
Q K Q
MPL x L βQ L
And, labour’s share in total output = = =β
Q L Q

That is, share of capital and labour in total output = α + β.

a) In case of constant returns to scale, α + β = 1; hence, total output will be fully exhausted in
making payments to inputs used.
b) In case of increasing returns to scale, α + β ˃ 1; hence, total payments would exceed
output. That is total output will fall short while making payments to inputs used.
c) In case of decreasing returns to scale, α + β < 1, hence, total payments would be less than
output. That is, while making payments to inputs used, there will be surplus retained.

In case of CDPF, elasticity of substitution is unity


𝐾 𝑓𝐿
𝑑 𝑓𝐾
We know that the co-efficient of elasticity of substitution is, σ = 𝐿
𝑓𝐿 x 𝐾
𝑑 𝐿
𝑓𝐾

𝛼𝑄 𝛽𝑄
In case of Q = A K αL β ; fk = and fL = 𝐿
.
𝐾

6
𝛽𝑄
𝑓𝐿 𝐿 𝛽𝑄 𝐾 𝛽𝐾
Therefore, = 𝛼𝑄 = =
𝑓𝑘 𝐿 𝛼𝑄 𝛼𝐿
𝐾
𝐾
𝐾 𝛼 𝑓𝐿 𝑑 𝛼
𝐿
Or,
𝐿
=
𝛽 𝑓𝑘
Therefore, 𝑓𝐿 =
𝑑𝑓 𝛽
𝐾

𝐾 𝑓𝐿 𝛽𝐾
𝑑𝐿 𝑓𝐾 𝛼 𝛼𝐿 𝛼 𝛽𝐾 𝐿
Hence, σ = 𝑓 x 𝐾 = x 𝐾 = =1
𝑑 𝐿 𝛽 𝛽 𝛼𝐿 𝐾
𝑓𝐾 𝐿 𝐿

Expansion path is an upward sloping straight line passing through the origin
𝑀𝑃𝐾 𝑃𝐾
According to producers’ equilibrium condition, =
𝑀𝑃𝐿 𝑃𝐿
𝛼𝑄 𝛽𝑄
Given Q = A K α L β ; MPK = and MPL =
𝐾 𝐿
Let, PK = r and, PL = w
𝛼𝑄
𝑀𝑃𝐾 𝐾 𝛼𝑄 𝐿 𝑃𝐾 𝑟
Hence, = 𝛽𝑄 = x = =
𝑀𝑃𝐿 𝐾 𝛽𝑄 𝑃𝐿 𝑤
𝐿
𝛼𝑄𝐿 𝑟 𝛽𝑟 𝛼𝑤
Therefore, = Or, L = K and K = L (β ˃ 0; α ˃ 0; r ˃ 0; w ˃ 0)
𝛽𝑄𝐾 𝑤 𝛼𝑤 𝛽𝑟

Hence, ‘L’ is a positive and linear function of ‘K’ and vice versa. Moreover, both equations
have no intercept term. That is, in case of CDPF, the expansion path is an upward sloping
straight line passing through the origin for any degree of homogeneity.

Derivation of cost curves from CDPF and their shape


𝑀𝑃𝐾 𝑃𝐾 𝑟
According to producers’ equilibrium condition, = = (Let, PK = r and, PL = w)
𝑀𝑃𝐿 𝑃𝐿 𝑤
𝛼𝑄 𝛽𝑄
For Q = A K α L β MPK = and MPL =
𝐾 𝐿
𝛼𝑄
𝑀𝑃𝐾 𝐾 𝑃𝐾 𝑟 𝛼𝑄𝐿 𝑟
Hence, = 𝛽𝑄 = = or, =
𝑀𝑃𝐿 𝑃𝐿 𝑤 𝛽𝑄𝐾 𝑤
𝐿

𝛽𝑟 𝛼𝑤
Therefore, L = K , and K= L
𝛼𝑤 𝛽𝑟

𝛽𝑟
Now, cost function is C = wL + rK = w K + rK = rK ( 𝛼+𝛽
𝛼 )
𝛼𝑤

7
𝛼𝐶 𝛽𝐶
Therefore, K = , and L =
𝑟(𝛼+ 𝛽) 𝑤(𝛼+ 𝛽)

Putting these values in the production function we get,

𝛼𝐶 𝛼
𝛽𝐶 𝛽 𝐴𝛼 𝛼 𝛽𝛽 𝐶 𝛼+𝛽
Q = A(𝑟(𝛼+ ) ( ) = 𝛼 𝛽
𝛽) 𝑤(𝛼+ 𝛽) 𝑟 𝑤 (𝛼+𝛽)𝛼+𝛽

𝑟 𝛼 𝑤 𝛽 (𝛼+𝛽)𝛼+𝛽
Or, Cα + β = Q
𝐴𝛼𝛼 𝛽 𝛽

1 1
1 1
𝑟𝛼𝑤𝛽 𝛼+𝛽 𝑟𝛼𝑤𝛽 𝛼+𝛽
Or, C = (𝛼 + 𝛽) ( ) (𝑄 ) 𝛼+𝛽 Or, C = 𝑚𝑄 𝛼+𝛽 (𝛼 + 𝛽) ( 𝛽) =m
𝐴𝛼𝛼 𝛽𝛽 𝐴𝛼𝛼𝛽
1 1
1 − 𝛼−𝛽 1 − 𝛼−𝛽
𝐶 𝑚𝑄𝛼+𝛽 𝑚𝑄𝛼+𝛽 𝑑𝐶
AC =
𝑄
=
𝑄
=
𝑄
= 𝑚𝑄 𝛼+𝛽 ; MC =
𝑑𝑄
= (𝛼+1 𝛽) 𝑚𝑄 𝛼+𝛽
1
= (𝛼+ 𝛽) AC

1
𝑇𝐶 𝑚𝑄 𝑑𝐶
i) Now, if, α + β = 1; TC = 𝑚𝑄 𝛼+𝛽 = mQ ; AC = = = m ; MC = =m
𝑄 𝑄 𝑑𝑄

Here, α, β, r, w, all being positive, m is also positive. That is, TC is a positive and linear
function of Q. Moreover, it has no intercept term. That is, in case of α + β = 1, the total cost
curve is an upward sloping straight line passing through the origin. Furthermore, in this case,
average cost, AC = marginal cost, MC = m. That is, AC and MC are not only constants, they
are also equal; they, therefore, coincide with each other and are parallel to quantity axis.
C,
MC, AC TC
AC = MC = m

O Q

1
ii) When, α + β > 1, following the relation, MC = AC, we get, MC < AC. In this case,
(𝛼+ 𝛽)

TC, AC and MC all are non-linear. TC is upward sloping and bending towards x-axis. MC
and AC are downward sloping and MC lies below AC.
TC AC, MC
TC
AC
MC
O Q O Q

8
1
iii) When, α + β < 1, following the relation, MC = AC, we get, MC < AC. In this case
(𝛼+ 𝛽)

also TC, AC and MC all are non-linear. TC is upward sloping and bending towards y-axis.
MC and AC are also upward sloping and MC lies above AC.
TC AC, MC MC AC

O Q O Q
In actual form, the three curves (TC, AC and MC) are as follows:

TC TC AC, MC MC AC

O Q O Q

Derivation of input demand function and supply function (when α + β = 1)


Given, 𝑄 = 𝐴𝐾 𝛼 𝐿𝛽 ; Log Q = Log A + α Log K + β Log L
Let, cost equation is, C = wL + rK
Now, if product price is ‘P’, then corresponding profit function becomes,
Profit (π) = TR ̶ TC = PQ ̶ TC = P( Log A + α Log K + β Log L) ̶ rK ̶ wL
Following the rule of optimization, we can write:
𝜕𝜋 α𝑃 α𝑃
= ̶ r = 0, Or, K =
𝜕𝐾 𝐾 𝑟
𝜕𝜋 β𝑃 β𝑃
= ̶ w=0 Or, L =
𝜕𝐿 𝐿 𝑤
That is, demand for inputs depends inversely on respective input prices and directly on
product price (P).

Using above result, supply function corresponding to CDPF can be derived as follows:
𝛼𝑃 𝛼 𝛽𝑃 𝛽 𝛼 𝛼 𝛽 𝛽 𝛼 𝛼 𝛽 𝛽
𝑄 = 𝐴𝐾 𝛼 𝐿𝛽 = 𝐴 ( ) ( ) = 𝐴 ( ) ( ) 𝑃𝛼+𝛽 = 𝐴 ( ) ( ) 𝑃 (when α +β = 1).
𝑟 𝑤 𝑟 𝑤 𝑟 𝑤

That is, under constant returns to scale, supply curve is an upward sloping straight line
passing through the origin.

9
Criticisms of C-D Production Function:
The C-D production function has been criticizd by Arrow, Chenery, Minhas and Solow as
discussed below:
a) The C-D production function considers only two inputs, labour and capital, and neglects
some important inputs, like raw materials, which are used in production. It is, therefore, not
possible to generalize this function to more than two inputs.
b) In the C-D production function, the problem of measurement of capital arises because it
takes only the quantity of capital available for production. But the full use of the available
capital can be made only in periods of full employment. This is unrealistic because no
economy is always fully employed.
c) The C-D production function is criticized because it shows constant returns to scale. But
constant returns to scale are not an actuality, for either increasing or decreasing returns to
scale are applicable to production. Moreover, it is not possible to change all inputs to bring a
proportionate change in the outputs of all the industries. Some inputs are scarce and cannot be
increased in the same proportion as abundant inputs. On the other hand, inputs like machines,
entrepreneurship, etc. are indivisible. Thus when the supply of inputs is scarce and
indivisibilities are present, constant returns to scale are not possible. Whenever the units of
different inputs are increased in the production process, economies of scale and specialization
lead to increasing returns to scale.
d) The C-D production function is based on the assumption of substitutability of factors and
neglects the complementarity of factors.
e) This function is based on the assumption of perfect competition in the factor market which
is unrealistic. If, this assumption is dropped, then, the coefficients α and β do not represent
factor shares.
f) One of the weaknesses of C-D function is the aggregation problem. This problem arises
when this function is applied to every firm in an industry and to the entire industry. In this
situation, there will be many production functions of low or high aggregation. Thus the C-D
function does not measure what it aims at measuring.

Thus the practicability of the C-D production function in the manufacturing industry is a
doubtful proposition. This is not applicable to agriculture where for intensive cultivation,
increasing the quantities of inputs will not raise output proportionately. Even then, it cannot
be denied that constant returns to scale are a stage in the life of a firm, industry or economy.
It is another thing that this stage may come after some time and for a short while.
10
Significance
Despite these criticisms, the C-D function is of much importance.
a) It has been used widely in empirical studies of manufacturing industries and in inter-
industry comparisons. (b) It is used to determine the relative shares of labour and capital in
total output. (c) It is used to prove Euler’s Theorem. (d) Its parameters α and β represent
elasticity coefficients that are used for inter-sectoral comparisons. (e) This production
function is homogeneous of degree one; which shows constant returns to scale. If α + β > 1,
there is increasing returns to scale and if α + β < 1, there is diminishing returns to scale.

Constant Elasticity of Substitution Production Function (CES Production Function)


This function has been developed by R.M. Solow, M. Minhas, K. J. Arrow, and H. B.
Chenery.
1

Symbolically, it is: Q = A [𝛿𝐾 −𝜌 + (1 − 𝛿)𝐿−𝜌 ] 𝜌

Where, A = Efficiency parameter/total productivity factor (A > 0)


K = Amount of capital used (K ˃ 0); L = Amount of labour used (L ˃ 0);
δ = Distribution parameter ( 0 < δ < 1); ρ = Substitution parameter ( ρ > ̶ 1);

CES production function is homogeneous of degree one


1

Given, Q = A [𝛿𝐾 −𝜌 + (1 − 𝛿)𝐿−𝜌 ] 𝜌 ,
To estimate the degree of homogeneity; K and L are changed by λ times. Thus,
1

Q* = A [𝛿(𝜆𝐾)−𝜌 + (1 − 𝛿)(𝜆𝐿)−𝜌 ] 𝜌

1

= A [λ−𝜌 {𝛿𝐾 −𝜌 + (1 − 𝛿)𝐿−𝜌 ] 𝜌

1

= λ(−𝜌)( ̶ 1/𝜌)
A [𝛿𝐾 −𝜌 + (1 − 𝛿)𝐿−𝜌 ] 𝜌 = 𝜆Q (proved)

In case of CES production function MPs are homogeneous of degree zero


1

Q = A [𝛿𝐾 −𝜌 + (1𝛿𝐾 −𝜌 − 𝛿)𝐿−𝜌 ] 𝜌

𝜕𝑄 1 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
MPK = = (− )A 𝑍 .δ. ( ̶ ρ) 𝐾 −𝜌 −1 = δ A 𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
𝐾 −(𝜌+1)
𝜕𝐾 𝜌

For estimation of degree of homogeneity; K and L are changed by λ times.


Hence, 𝑀𝑃𝐾∗ = δ A [𝛿(λ𝐾)−𝜌 + (1 − 𝛿)(λ𝐿)−𝜌 ] ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
(λ𝐾)−(𝜌+1)
= δ A [λ−𝜌 {𝛿𝐾 −𝜌 + (1 − 𝛿)𝐿−𝜌 }] ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
(λ)−(𝜌+1) (𝐾)−(𝜌+1)
̶ 1/𝜌 −1
=δA𝑍 (λ)−(𝜌+1) (𝐾)−(𝜌+1) (λ)−𝜌 ( ̶ 1/𝜌 −1)

11
̶ 1/𝜌 −1
= δA𝑍 (𝐾)−(𝜌+1) (λ)−(𝜌+1) +(𝜌+1) = λ0 δ A 𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
(𝐾)−(𝜌+1) = λ0 MPK = MPK
𝜕𝑄 1 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
MPL = = (− )A 𝑍 .(1 ̶ δ). ( ̶ ρ) 𝐿−𝜌 −1 = (1 ̶ δ) A 𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
𝐿−(𝜌+1)
𝜕𝐿 𝜌

Now, to estimate the degree of homogeneity; K and L are changed by λ times. Thus, the new
function is:
𝑀𝑃𝐿∗ = (1 ̶ δ)A [𝛿(λ𝐾)−𝜌 + (1 − 𝛿)(λ𝐿)−𝜌 ] ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
(λ𝐿)−(𝜌+1)
= (1 ̶ δ)A [λ−𝜌 {𝛿𝐾 −𝜌 + (1 − 𝛿)𝐿−𝜌 }] ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
(λ)−(𝜌+1) (𝐿)−(𝜌+1)
̶ 1/𝜌 −1
= (1 ̶ δ) A 𝑍 (λ)−(𝜌+1) (𝐿)−(𝜌+1) (λ)−𝜌 ( ̶ 1/𝜌 −1)

̶ 1/𝜌 −1
= (1 ̶ δ) A 𝑍 (𝐾)−(𝜌+1) (λ)−(𝜌+1) +(𝜌+1)
= λ0 (1 ̶ δ) A 𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
(𝐿)−(𝜌+1) = λ0 MPL = MPL

CES production function satisfies Euler’s Theorem


1

Given, Q = A [𝛿𝐾 −𝜌 + (1 − 𝛿)𝐿−𝜌 ] 𝜌

̶ 1/𝜌 −1
MPK = δ A 𝑍 𝐾 −(𝜌+1) , and, MPL = (1 ̶ δ) A 𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
𝐿−(𝜌+1)
̶ 1/𝜌 −1
MPK.K= δ A 𝑍 𝐾 −(𝜌+1) . K = δ A 𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
𝐾 −𝜌 , and,
̶ 1/𝜌 −1 −(𝜌+1) ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
MPL.L= (1 ̶ δ) A 𝑍 𝐿 . L = (1 ̶ δ) A 𝑍 𝐿−𝜌
Therefore, MPK. K + MPL. L
̶ 1/𝜌 −1
=δA𝑍 𝐾 −𝜌 + (1 ̶ δ) A 𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
𝐿−𝜌
̶ 1/𝜌 −1
=A𝑍 [δ𝐾 −𝜌 + (1 ̶ δ)𝐿−𝜌 ] = A 𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1
𝑍=A𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌
= Q (proved)

CES production function exhibits constant elasticity of substitution.


𝑑𝐾⁄ 𝑓𝐿
⁄𝑓
𝐿
We know, constant elasticity of substitution, σ = 𝑑𝑓𝐿 . 𝐾⁄
𝑘

⁄𝑓 𝐿
𝑘

𝑓𝐿 (1 ̶ δ) A 𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1 𝐿−(𝜌+1) (1 ̶ δ) 𝐾 𝜌 +1
Here,
𝑓𝐾
=
δ A 𝑍 ̶ 1/𝜌 −1 𝐾 −(𝜌+1)
=
δ
(𝐿 )
1 1
𝐾 𝜌 +1 δ 𝑓𝐿 𝐾 δ 𝜌 +1 𝑓 𝜌 +1
Or, ( )
𝐿
=
1 ̶ δ 𝑓𝐾
, therefore,
𝐿
=(
1 ̶δ
) (𝑓𝐿 )
𝐾
1 1
𝑑𝐾⁄ 1 δ 𝑓𝐿 𝜌 +1 ̶ 1
𝐿 𝜌 +1
Hence, 𝑑𝑓𝐿 =
ρ+ 1
(1 ̶δ
) (𝑓 )
⁄𝑓 𝐾
𝑘

𝑑𝐾⁄ 𝑓𝐿 1 1 𝑓𝐿
𝐿
⁄𝑓 1 δ 𝜌 +1 𝑓 𝜌 +1 ̶ 1 ⁄𝑓 1
Or, σ = 𝑑𝑓𝐿 . 𝐾⁄
𝑘
= (1 ) (𝑓𝐿 ) . 1
𝑘
1 =
⁄𝑓 𝐿 ρ+ 1 ̶δ 𝐾 δ 𝜌 +1 𝑓 𝜌 +1
ρ+ 1
𝑘 ( ) ( 𝐿)
1 ̶δ 𝑓𝐾

12
In case of CES production function, shape of the isoquant depends on the value of σ
1 1
We have seen that, σ = , therefore, ρ = ̶ 1
ρ+1 𝜎

a) When, σ = 0; ρ = ∞ K
This is the case when in the production process; substitution
between inputs is not possible. Consequently, the production b
function is characterized by the existence of fixed input a IQ2
proportion. That is, the corresponding isoquant curves are IQ1
right-angled shaped. Points ‘a’ and ‘b’ indicate the input ratio. O L
b) When, σ = ∞; ρ = ̶ 1 K
This is the case when in the production process perfect
substitution between inputs is possible. Consequently, the
production function is characterized by the existence of
constant MRTS. That is, the corresponding isoquant curves are
downward sloping straight lines. O IQ1 IQ2 ` L
c) When, σ = 1; ρ = 0 K
In this case CES production function becomes Cobb-Douglas
production function. Here, in the production process,
substitution between the inputs is possible but the rate of IQ2
MRTS decreases. Consequently, the corresponding isoquant IQ1
curves are downward sloping and convex to the origin. O `L
d) When, 0 < σ < 1; ρ > 0 K
In this case in the production process, substitution between the
inputs is possible only over a definite range of the isoquant (ab a c
for IQ1 and cd for IQ2). Consequently, they are downward
sloping and convex to the origin in this range. The range where d IQ2
substitution between the inputs is not possible, segments of the b IQ1
corresponding isoquant curves are either parallel to ‘x’ axis or O `L
are parallel to ‘y’ axis.
e) When, σ > 1; ̶1<ρ<0 K
In this case in the production process, substitution between the
inputs is possible over the entire range of the isoquants.
Moreover, consequent isoquant curves touch both the axes.

O IQ1 IQ2 `L

13
Examples of Production Function
a) Production function modeling case of fixed proportions
An important family of production functions models technologies involving a single technique of
production. The only way to produce a unit of output, for example, may be to use 1 machine and 2
workers; if the firm has available 2 machines and 2 workers then the extra machine simply sits idle,
and if it wants to produce two units of output then it has to use 2 machines and 4 workers. Such a
production function has fixed proportions. If the only way to produce one unit of output is to one
machine and two workers then the output from ‘M’ number of machines and L workers is the
minimum of M and L/2. This case is portrayed above as case (a), when, σ = 0; ρ = ∞.

b) Production function modeling perfect substitutes


A technology whose character is exactly the opposite to that of a fixed proportions technology allows
one input to be substituted freely for another at a constant rate. In this case, the technology can be
described generally by any production function of the form f (K,L) = aK + bL, for some
nonnegative numbers a and b is one in which the inputs are perfect substitutes. Such a production
function models a technology in which one unit of output can be produced from 1/a units of input K,
or from 1/b units of input L, or from any combination of K and L for which aK + bL = 1. That is, one
input can be substituted for the other at a constant rate. This case is portrayed above as case (b),
when, σ = ∞; ρ = ̶ 1.

c) Production function modeling smooth but not perfect substitution between inputs
Many technologies allow inputs to be substituted for each other, but not at a constant rate. A class of
production functions that models situations in which inputs can be substituted for each other
to produce the same output, but cannot be substituted at a constant rate, contains functions of
the form f (K, L) = AKα Lβ , for some constants A, α, and β. Such a production functions are known as
Cobb-Douglas production function. This case is portrayed above as case (c), when, σ = 1; ρ = 0.

Incorporation of technology in production function


There are three common ways to incorporate technology (or the efficiency with which factors
of production are used) into a production function:

i) Hicks-neutral technology, or factor augmenting technology: Q = A f (K, L)


ii) Harrod-neutral technology, or labor augmenting technology: Q = f (K, AL)
iii) Solow-neutral technology, or capital augmenting technology: Q = f (AK, L)

14
Transcendental Logarithmic (Translog) Production Function
Translog production function is a generalization of the Cobb-Douglas production function.
The name stands for 'transcendental logarithmic'. The translog production functions occurred
in the context of researches related to the discovery and definition of new flexible forms of
production functions and to the approximation of CES production function; when the
elasticity of substitution is very close to the unitary value, which is the case of Cobb-Douglas
production function.

The term ‘translog production function’ coming from the term ‘transcendental logarithmic
production function’ was proposed by Christiansen, Jorgensn and Lau in two papers
published in 1971 and 1973, which dealt with the problems of strong separability (additivity)
and homogeneity of Cobb-Douglas and CES production functions and their implications for
the production frontier. The translog production functions represent in fact a class of flexible
functional forms for the production functions. One of the main advantages of the respective
production function is that, unlike in case of Cobb-Douglas production function, it does not
assume rigid premises such as: perfect or smooth substitution between production factors or
perfect competition in the product and factor markets.

Also, the concept of the translog production function permits to pass from a linear
relationship between the output and the production factors; thus, to take into account of
nonlinear ones. Due to its properties, the translog production function can be used for second
order approximation of a linear-homogenous production, estimation of the ‘Allen elasticities
of substitution’, and estimation of the production frontier or the measurement of the total
factor productivity dynamics.

The translog production function is much more general (it has a flexible functional form
permitting the partial elasticities of substitution between inputs to vary). Cobb-Douglas
production function and constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function place
restriction on elasticity of substitution. Alternatively, the generalized Leontief, generalized
Cobb-Douglas and Translog function all are sufficiently flexible. The Translog function
allows for variability of Allen partial elasticities of substitution and for using any number of
inputs. Moreover, this function has both linear and quadratic terms with the ability of using
more than two factor inputs.

15
Two factor translog production function
lnY = ln(A) + a. ln K + b. ln L + c. ln2 (K/L)
Where, Y= Output, K= Fixed capital, L= Employed population, and, A, a, b, c are parametres
to be estimated.

Three factor translog production function


ln(Y) = ln(A) + a.L.ln(L) + aK.ln(K) + aM.ln(M) + bLL.ln(L).ln(L) + bKK.ln(K).ln(K) +
bMM.ln(M).ln(M) + bLK.ln(L).ln(K) + bLM.ln(L).ln(M) + bKM.ln(K).ln(M)

Where, Y = product, L = labour, K = capital and M = materials and supplies.

Isoelastic elasticity of substitution (IEES) production function


Isoelastic elasticity of substitution (IEES) production function is derived through generalizing
the normalized constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function by allowing the
elasticity of substitution to vary isoelastically with (i) Relative factor shares, (ii) Marginal
rates of substitution, (iii) Capital-labor ratios, or (iv) Capital-output ratios.

These four variants of isoelastic elasticity of substitution (IEES) production functions have a
range of intuitively desirable properties and yield empirically testable predictions for the
functional relationship between relative factor shares and capital-labor ratios. IEES functions
generalize the CES function in the same way as the CES function generalizes the Cobb–
Douglas. The Cobb–Douglas production function is isoelastic and implies constant factor
shares; the CES production function implies isoelastic factor shares and has a constant
elasticity of substitution; whereas IEES functions have an isoelastic elasticity of substitution
and a constant elasticity of elasticity of substitution.

16

You might also like