Fighting Carbon Leakage Through Consumption Based Carbon Emissions

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Applied Energy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/apenergy

Fighting carbon leakage through consumption-based carbon emissions T


policies: Empirical analysis based on the World Trade Model with Bilateral
Trades
Matteo V. Roccoa, , Nicolò Golinuccia,b, Stefano M. Roncoc, Emanuela Colomboa

a
Department of Energy, Politecnico di Milano, Via Lambruschini 4, 21056 Milan, Italy
b
Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei (FEEM), Corso Magenta 63, 21056 Milan, Italy
c
Università degli Studi di Torino, Via Giuseppe Verdi 8, 10124 Turin, Italy

HIGHLIGHTS

• Production- and Consumption-based carbon emissions taxation schemes are revised.


• Carbon policies are applied to Europe, assessing economic and environmental impacts.
• The World Trade Model coupled with Exiobase MRIO database is used for the analysis.
• Application of Production-based carbon taxation leads to carbon leakage.
• Results of Production- and Consumption-based schemes are comparatively analysed.

ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT

Keywords: Policy initiatives towards reduction of CO2 emissions implemented so far are grounded on the so-called
Carbon leakage Production-Based paradigm: this approach allocates responsibility of emissions to countries that directly caused
Production-based accounting such emissions, without taking into account all the indirect contributions to CO2 emissions caused outside
Consumption-based accounting country’s borders, eventually leading to the so-called carbon leakage phenomenon. In this paper, the alternative
World Trade Model with Bilateral Trades
Consumption-Based approach is proposed, and its effectiveness assessed: according to this approach, policy
Greenhouse Gases Emissions
initiatives allocates responsibility for CO2 emissions proportionally to the CO2 emissions embedded in goods and
services required by industries as inputs for production. Global environmental and economic consequences of
carbon emissions reduction policies, applied at the European level based on both Production- and Consumption-
Based paradigms, are comparatively assessed based on the World Trade Model with Bilateral Trades. Results of
this study suggest that defining CO2 emissions policies based on a Consumption-Based paradigm seems to be the
most effective way to reduce the global carbon emissions, avoiding the carbon leakage phenomenon which may
occur in economies regulated by Production-Based policies. Indeed, an imposed reduction in CO2 emissions
embedded in EU final demand through a Consumption-Based Accounting policy would result in a global CO2
emissions reduction up to almost 1.2 Gton. On the other hand, an imposed reduction in direct EU CO2 emissions
according to a PBA approach would result in an overall increase in global carbon emissions up to almost 0.8
Gton.

1. Introduction significantly increased mainly due to combustion of fossil fuels [2].


Even if most of the GHG emissions have been historically produced
Presence of greenhouse gases (GHG) in the atmosphere has been within developed countries borders, the weight of developing countries
argued to have a significant impact on the radiative balance of the at- in total global emission is becoming increasingly relevant. At the same
mosphere, leading to changes in climatic patterns [1]. Over the last time, important efforts have been made by developed countries to re-
150 years, concentration of carbon dioxide (CO2) in atmosphere, which duce the carbon emission generated within their borders: considering in
accounts for the largest share of anthropogenic GHG emission, has EU28, while population has grown by 7% from 1990 to 2015, CO2


Corresponding author at: Department of Energy, Politecnico di Milano, Via Lambruschini 4, 21056 Milan, Italy.
E-mail address: matteovincenzo.rocco@polimi.it (M.V. Rocco).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2020.115301
Received 15 September 2019; Received in revised form 22 April 2020; Accepted 30 May 2020
Available online 12 June 2020
0306-2619/ © 2020 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
M.V. Rocco, et al. Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

emissions have dropped by a factor of 21% [2]. Recently, the Interna- an influent portion of GHG is usually embedded in products traded and
tional Energy Agency has estimated a substantial flattening of global consumed by economies which have assumed climate reduction com-
energy-related emissions for 2019, an algebraic sum between 400 Mton mitments. Therefore, if the participation to a climate international
CO2 less in developed countries and the same amount more in devel- commitment is not covering all the world economies, the problem of
oping countries [3]. carbon leakage may arise. A recent article by Afionis et al. [11], pro-
Nowadays, only 15% of global GHG emissions are covered by vides an extensive discussion about advantages and drawbacks of PBA
carbon pricing policies [4]. A large share of these emissions is regulated and CBA techniques, examining opportunities for climate policy in-
by developed countries, mostly under the European Union Emission novations. From one side, CBA could strengthen the participation be-
Trading System (EU ETS). EU ETS, originally launched in 2005, has tween countries in reducing global emissions, promulgating measures
been the first large GHG emission trading scheme in the world and the aimed at reducing embodied emissions in developed world consump-
first actuation of Kyoto Protocol international treaty. Recently, it has tion, enhancing the development of a wider coalition with a common
been argued that, beside direct GHG emission, also the indirect emis- political vision towards more international actions. However, according
sions embodied in international trades may have a significant impact in to this paradigm, countries should accept to be responsible of emissions
global climate policies effectiveness [5]. Therefore, it has been shown on which they have no direct control; at the same time, developing
how policies with the purpose of limiting CO2 emission can be in- countries would be exposed to influence of economies which import
efficient: even if developed countries regulations keep emissions low by goods and services from them. This scenario implies a not trivial con-
limiting or pricing, their economy may react importing more from text of cooperation between governments as embodied emission of
growing and unregulated regions, which usually rely on a more carbon developing countries exports should be monitored, reported and ver-
intensive production system. This phenomenon, known as carbon ified by the international community to provide transparency and to
leakage, may occur in two ways: strong carbon leakage occurs when an guarantee trustworthiness to the system of responsibility. Jakob,
industry in an environmental controlled country shuts down and opens Steckel and Edenhofer [12], in addition to expose the critical issues
in a nonparticipating region with lax ecological regulation; on the other connected to market imbalances generated by consumption-based
hand, weak carbon leakage occurs when demand for goods is not covered policy such as border tax adjustment (BTA), state that both CBA and PBA
anymore by internal production, which is discourage by environmental do not represent an optimal policy for the current geopolitical context,
regulations, but by imports from economies relying on a less efficient suggesting that a more composite framework of specific policies would
technological structure [6]. Empirical evidence of carbon leakage has be the most efficient solution for emission reduction. In this perspec-
not yet been ascertained and this may be determined by the low price of tive, it must be underlined the recent statement of European Commis-
emission that have characterized recent years of carbon pricing in de- sion president Ursula von der Leyen on the willingness to introduce BTA
veloped economies [7]. Nevertheless, a model-based approach can in- (in the form of a so called Carbon Border Tax) in EU [13].
ternalize the effect of carbon pricing in exposed to delocalization sec-
tors according to strict emission reduction objectives, assessing the 1.1. Brief literature review
occurring of this phenomenon.
An essential prerequisite for the implementation of environmental This sub-section provides a brief overview of the recent literature
emissions policies is the definition of the emissions accounting para- focused on modelling carbon emissions reduction policies and on the
digm, that is, the approach for allocating the responsibility connected assessment of their effects on international trades.
with the production of the emissions. The following approaches may be A widespread modelling approach in economics relies on
adopted for this purpose: Computable General Equilibrium models (CGE). Wang et al. [14] study
the effect on China’s growth of a gradually strengthen energy cap to
• Production Based Accounting (PBA). Each country is responsible for limit Chinese rapid growth in energy consumption and GHG emissions,
the emissions produced within its boundaries, disregarding the finding that energy cap policy will not disadvantage the economic de-
purpose for which these emissions are produced (i.e. endogenous velopment or harm the consumption in residential sector. The different
consumption or exports). roles and impacts of upstream and downstream subsidies have been
• Consumption Based Accounting (CBA). Each country is responsible for investigated through market equilibrium model by Fischer et al. [15],
the overall emissions caused by the production of goods and services finding that downstream subsidies technology policy may expose global
invoked as its own final demand, even if these emissions occur be- abatement technology price to an undesirable increase while upstream
yond the borders of the country. grants reduces it. Other researches analyze the impact of a multi-re-
gional ETS through a CGE model, showing how extending participation,
The accountability of countries’ direct emissions is straightforward: integrating the scheme to a composite set of countries, may represent a
national environmental accounts are regularly updated and produced more economically effective measure to tackle emission reduction than
according to widely accepted standards. On the other hand, universal separate sets of single region ETS [16].
consensus about methodologies to assess emissions embedded into Other modelling approaches slightly different than CGE models
goods and services has not yet reached. For such reasons, all the en- belongs to the family of Environmentally Extended Input-Output
vironmental policies implemented so far are based on a PBA approach, models (EE-IO). An example of this approach is represented by the work
while theoretical definition and practical implementation of policies of Liu et al. who developed an EE-IO model to assess the most appro-
based on CBA approach is still lagging behind (as well as hybrid PBA- priate mitigation strategy between PBA and CBA for each type of in-
CBA techniques [8]). Recent developing of emerging technologies such dustrial activity. Their work, applied in a provincial context in Canada,
as blockchain could represent an interesting solution to the im- shows that it tends to be more effective to apply PBA for primary sectors
plementation of CBA policies, overcoming problems of reliability and and CBA for sectors at the bottom of the industrial chain [17]. Static
trustworthiness. ETS schemes based on the integration with the ad- and linear EE-IO models are also used to perform different kind of
vancements of Industry 4.0, through blockchain, have been proposed footprinting and LCA analyses. In particular, Ivanova et al. plumb the
by Khaqqi et al. and implemented on a case study in Fashion Apparel deep interaction between different world sectors and countries to
Manufacturing Industry by Fu, Shu and Liu [9]. analyze the environmental impact of household consumption in terms
The work made by Peters and Hertwich [10] sheds light on the role of material, water, land-use and GHG emission, computing households
played by international trade in evaluating the impact of climate po- carbon footprint (CF) [18]. Wood et al. introduce a method to evaluate
licies, assessing that 20–25% of the world CO2 emissions are released the impact of consumer-oriented policy overall productive system, de-
for the production of products which are internationally traded. Such tecting rebound effects, change in domestic and international

2
M.V. Rocco, et al. Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

production mix and reduction in carbon intensity [19]. Lenzen et al. advantages and drawbacks. Special attention is devoted to the identi-
face the problem of carbon footprint double counting demonstrating fication of the practical implementing barriers for consumption-based
and discussing a non-arbitrary method of consistently delineating paradigm.
supply chains of goods and services. In this way a mutually exclusive The empirical analysis is performed according to the World Trade
and collectively exhaustive shares of responsibility for all actors in an Model with Bilateral Trades (WTMBT), assuming the Exiobase v.2 data-
economy is provided [20]. Vita et al. have recently studied the impact base as the reference database for macroeconomic empirical data (re-
on water use, land use, toxicity and carbon footprint of a wide range of ferred to year 2007). The WTMBT optimizes the global international
scenarios of reduction or shift in consumption and technological pat- trade patterns within a given set of constraints and by considering the
terns using Exiobase v.2 database [21]. Zhu et al. propose an alternative comparative advantage as the only production and trade mechanism.
paradigm with respect to CBA and PBA, developing an algorithm able to Therefore, specific country agreements, other policies implementation
summarize a fair share of responsibility [22]. Choi et al. study and as- or any social phenomenon that may affect international trades have
sess the impacts of an emission mitigation policy in 2 steps, taxing been neglected. Since the only degree of freedom of the model resides
diesel in the first time period and encouraging the use of renewables in in the shape and arrangement of international trades, the application of
the second time period, through a sequential input–output framework alternative carbon emissions policies will generate different production
[23]. In the report of the CarbonCAP project, the evaluation of the and consumption patterns among countries, resulting in different global
environmental and socio-economic impacts of several consumption- consumption of factors of production, resources and CO2 emissions.
based emission reduction options are provided based on three different Any change in trade patterns is assumed to occur overnight (i.e. com-
models (E3ME, EXIOMOD and FIDELIO) [26]. parative statics), without considering any structural dynamics of the
Two recent contributions try to fill the research gap identified in the countries, and by considering constant production technologies.
literature, by comparing the effects of PBA and CBA carbon mitigation Notably, compared to the current literature on the topic, this study
policies on the environmental and socio-economic context. Both these introduces for the first time an empirical comparison of PBA and CBA
studies adopt a combined use of Input-Output and CGE models. Sommer emissions policies at global level.
and Kratena evaluate the two approaches in the way of revenue neutral
carbon tax through a Dynamic New Keynesian model, finding no sig- 2. Carbon emissions taxation: a policy perspective
nificant advantages in switching from PBA to CBA even if negative
carbon leakage is observed [24]. Nabernegg et al. investigate the impact Production-based approach is currently considered as the ac-
of a set of policies in the Austrian national context, for 3 sectors with a counting standard of reference in the 1992 United Nations Framework
high carbon footprint (building, public health and transport), identi- Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) and in the Kyoto Protocol
fying effective solutions in reducing consumption-based emissions [25]. [34]. It is widely recognized that the PBA approach seems to be not
Duchin et al. proposed two extensions of the traditional EE-IO adequate if it is unable to reach a global consensus among world
model, namely the Rectangular Choice of Technology (RCOT) model countries, which may entail significant free-riding risks that could ul-
[26] and the World Trade Model (WTM) [27]. A combination of this timately impair its policy goals and fail to achieve the result of curbing
two model have been employed for analyzing possible scenarios and CO2 emissions on a global scale.
implications of satisfying 2050 food requirements [28]. As formalized The PBA/CBA classification adopted in this research is not widely
by Strømman and Duchin, the WTM can be extended taking into ac- used in the legal dialogue. Doctrinal studies have advocated for a more
count the costs of international trades within the so called World Trade nuanced approach to be taken in connection thereto, whereby alter-
Model with Bilateral Trade (WTMBT) [29]. The same authors, together native accounting methods for purposes of carbon emissions reduction
with Hertwich, have also employed the WTMBT to investigate costs and schemes should be considered as well. Considering the lack of con-
changes in the geographic distribution of production driven by the sensus in the doctrinal debate on the preeminence of one or the other
minimization of global carbon emissions [30]. These modelling ap- accounting standard and the absence of a recognized and legally
proaches can be defined as Input-Output based optimization models binding PBA-approach adopted at global level, a high-level analysis of
grounded on the comparative advantage principle, respectively adopted the interplay of the PBA and CBA approaches and an assessment of their
to assess the production alternative or the international trades patterns critical issues in the current legal scenario is a worthwhile exercise. In
that minimize the global use of economic factors given a set of eco- this regard, as the appreciation of regulatory-based tools for the inter-
nomic and environmental binding constraints. Duchin and Levine have nalization of environmental external costs has grown over time, taxes
recently further explained WTMBT conceptual framework, mathema- and other regulatory instruments have come to play a significant role in
tical formalization and integration with MRIO in two papers [31,32]. dealing with environmental externalities and they are nowadays widely
Many applications of these modelling approaches can be found in the adopted in OECD countries with a view of effectively countering CO2
literature. As an example, López-Morales and Duchin study on the role emissions by economic activities [35]. These solutions do not, however,
of natural resources availability on the Mexican economy, assessing advocate for a level of zero emissions, as it is considered that the social
regional water endowments resilience to consumption and related costs of a legislation approach which mandates a policy of no allowed
sustainability-oriented policies [33]. emission from economic activities would greatly exceed the envisaged
damages to the environment and, therefore, should not be considered
1.2. Objectives of the research an optimal policy goal [36].
The following regulatory tools are usually taken into considerations
While recent studies included in the literature review provide in- as optimal solutions to reduce carbon emissions: (1) a classic command
depth theoretical assessments of PBA-CBA based policies, based on the and control administrative legislation, - namely a direct regulation by
Authors knowledge fewer empirical analyses focused on the prospected legislative act of an activity or industry that dictates what is permitted
effects and comparison of PBA and CBA carbon policies at global level and what is illegal - which sets limits and conditions for the polluting
have been published so far. For this reason, the general objective of this activity, allowing emissions up to a certain threshold; (2) a levy or a tax,
study consists in assessing the effectiveness of a production- and con- whose tax base and/or rate is linked to the amount of carbon emissions
sumption-based paradigms in the application of carbon emissions from the polluting activity; (3) a tax or a charge, imposed on specific
taxation at the EU level, quantifying their economic and environmental products, whose production is considered to be the cause of significant
performance as a consequence of a gradual reduction in the EU carbon carbon emissions in the environment; (4) a tradable permits scheme,
emissions budgets. The empirical test is accompanied by a theoretical which allows polluters to emit CO2 as much as they like, so long as they
and legislative comparison of both the paradigms, identifying their are in possession of permits, which are exchangeable among private

3
M.V. Rocco, et al. Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

entities [36]. Each of these regulatory tools has distinct advantages and Conversely, a CBA tax would work exactly in the opposite way, mostly
disadvantages and there is no consensus as to the optimal solution to be benefiting net carbon importing countries.
adopted in practice and in general terms an intertwined approach seems As mentioned in the Introduction, the President of the EU
to be preferable. For instance, tax-based instruments seem to be easier Commission has recently claimed for the introduction of border trade
to be put into place and enforced and, additionally, provide govern- adjustments determined based on the CO2 embodied in EU imported
ments with revenue income which could be direct to further the un- products [13]. This policy measure is based on a Consumption-Based
derlying environmental goals. However, in many circumstances, pol- Accounting paradigm, and its prospective implementation claims for an
luting entities are able to pass along the economic tax burden to ex-ante robust empirical assessment of its consequences. From a Eur-
consumers and clients. On the other hand, non-tax compulsory reg- opean Union perspective, the implementation of a CBA-based tax would
ulatory schemes – such as mechanisms under (1) and (4) – are definitely incur in several drawbacks, which should be carefully considered
more complex to be implemented in practice and, in certain instances, during the legislative process. On the one hand, it could be disputed
allow relevant parties to exploit regulatory loopholes and obtain undue whether the measure at hand should be qualified as a direct or indirect
advantages in prejudice to the goals of the rules. These latter instru- taxation and the final answer would very much depend on the structure
ments however, if properly applied and fined tuned in light of relevant of the levy, to be assessed based on a detailed analysis of its mechanism.
characteristics of polluting activities, are more capable to guarantee a Whereas the measure at stake were structured similarly to a direct levy
greater internalization of environmental external costs by the same based on the amount of CO2 emission contained in the energy product,
polluting entities, avoiding the passing along to consumers of the higher the qualification in terms of direct tax would prevail, as the levy would,
environmental costs [37]. to some extent, set the CO2 emission as its primary tax base of re-
This analysis will adopt a normative approach and will try to ference. On the contrary, should it be designed to target specifically
evaluate, from a legal perspective, which standard would be better certain energy products (e.g. fuels) without attributing relevance to its
suited, and would suffer less drawbacks, to achieve the envisaged policy CO2 emission content (so that the CO2 emissions embodied in the
goal of curbing CO2 emissions globally. In addition, considering the product are only indirectly targeted by the tax) the measure at hand
growing preeminence of tax-related instruments as CO2 emissions re- should be considered more similar to an indirect tax instrument, which
duction schemes among OECD countries [35], this section will only could then take the form of a value added tax (VAT) or an excise tax.
consider the effects and drawbacks of a PBA or CBA approach adopted The definition of the nature of the tax (i.e. direct/indirect) is not
by way of a tax measure (generally classified as a carbon tax). merely a theoretical issue, as important consequences flow from this
The envisaged tax measure could be characterized as a proportional qualification: in this regard, EU law prohibits to introduce or maintain
levy set either on the unit of CO2 emission or on energy products which in the legal order of Member States taxes or levies that could be char-
embody significant amount of CO2 emissions in their production or acterized as turnover taxes and that are levied in a way comparable to
consumption. Such a levy is generally seen as a valuable tool, con- VAT, as they would jeopardize the proper functioning of the VAT
sidering that it does not purports to achieve a generic and vaguely system at European Union level1. Therefore, as it appears, an indirect
defined environmental justification, as it is the case for many excise levy on the consumption of products which embody a significant
taxes. On the contrary, it effectively incentives the polluter and/or the amount of CO2 emissions would prima facie fall within the scope of
consumer to modify his behavioral pattern, subjecting its non-com- application of such European Union prohibition and an in-depth ana-
pliance to a proportionally higher cost. Administrative costs are, how- lysis should be carried out as regards the adjustments mandated to
ever, not negligible considering the complexity of the tasks involved in comply with such very broad European Union law’s requirement on the
the monitoring and enforcing phase of this mechanism, especially prohibition of turnover taxes comparable to VAT. The situation would be
whereas its tax base is the unit of CO2 emission per se. Thus, such a levy different in case the tax measure at hand were characterized as a direct
would work properly only if the tax is designed in a way to be imposed form of taxation. On the one hand, each Member State retains a sig-
only on few business undertakings of large dimensions, whereas it nificant degree of discretion as to the introduction of new direct taxes;
would fail (or at least be very cumbersome to enforce) if it were levied meaning that every Member State is free to adopt unilateral solutions
on a larger scale of polluting activities, irrespective of their dimensional and, as a consequence, could introduce new environmentally-justified
setting. It is for such a reason that carbon taxes usually take the form of direct taxes, so long as they do not impinge on the fundamental free-
a tax on the carbon content of fuels or similar energy products, as they doms and principles granted by the Treaties of the European Union and
are both capable to proxy for the carbon emissions that are the result of do not counter with domestic constitutional and/or legislative provi-
the combustion process and are easier to enforce from an administrative sions. However, careful consideration should be paid to state aid re-
point of view. In particular, this is consistent with developed countries’ quirements, especially with reference to the selectivity criterion set out
practice: for instance, countries such as Denmark, Finland, Norway, by Article 107 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union,
France and Japan have adopted a carbon taxation scheme structured in which could potentially require domestic legislators to undertake a
a way that basically applies to oil products, natural gas and related process of fine-tuning of the tax measure at hand, considering the jur-
energy products at rates varying in proportion to fuels’ carbon content, isprudence of the Court of Justice of the European Union.
refraining to expand the scope of the tax to cover products other than Whereas a multilateral solution at European Union level were
energy ones. In effect, even if an optimal tax should target CO2 emis- sought with a view to adopt a EU-wide environmental tax based on CBA
sions irrespective of their origin, targeting both individuals and firms so approach, the major hurdle would be to reach a unanimous agreement
long as they are responsible for the emissions, in practical terms it is by all Member States, as European Union law mandates that decisions
recognized that such a levy would be difficult to enforce properly, given on not-harmonized taxes (and environmental taxes are not-harmonized
that sources of CO2 emissions are too wide and vary significantly, levies) shall be agreed unanimously. Considering that the European
therefore making their measurement an highly complex task. Therefore, Commission had proposed unsuccessfully in the past to introduce an
taking as a reference a levy that subjects to tax the carbon content of EU-wide CO2 emission-based tax and no agreement has since been
specific fuels or energy products, the comparison between the CBA and reached among Member States, it is questionable if a compromise
PBA approaches should start from the following economically-based would ever materialize on the matter in the close future. In any case,
consideration: if the country adopting the levy is a net CO2 emission
exporter, a PBA tax would result in an extraction tax and would,
therefore, mostly benefit, from an environmental point of view, States 1
This provision is found in Article 401 of the VAT Recast Directive, Council
which are net carbon exporters, without working in favor of net im- Directive 2006/112/EC of November 28, 2006 and it has been affirmed over
porters of fuels or energy products, like the European Union [38]. time by the Court of Justice of the Europea Union.

4
M.V. Rocco, et al. Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

the considerations made so far would not differ much if a PBA-approach


were followed in lieu of the CBA one.
Finally, an additional aspect that should be analyzed carefully when
considering the adoption of such a tax concerns its compatibility with

technical coefficients in regioni

Vector of factor scarcity rents in region i


trade agreements. As already pointed out, the reach of a PBA tax would

Vector of factor endowments in regioni

Vector of goods price index in region i


transport supplies from i to j
be domestic in scope, as the levy would be set on domestically produced

Vector of goods exported from i to j


Vector of final demand in regioni
Vector of factor prices in region i
energy products or on CO2 emissions originated from polluting activ-
factor input in region i
interregional distances
Number of factors of production
Indices for regions i, j = 1. ..m

ities at domestic level. Therefore, no significant issues should arise as to

Vector of output in region i


the compatibility of such schemes with existing binding trade agree-
ments signed by EU countries or by the EU considered as a unique trade
Number of regions

bloc. On the other hand, a CBA tax could have a major impact on im-
Number of sectors

ports, as it could significantly disadvantage imported products origi-


Description

nated from third countries outside the EU. In such a case, an analysis
of
of
of
of

should be undertaken as to the compatibility of such a tax measure with


Matrix
Matrix
Matrix
Matrix

the World Trade Organization (WTO) agreements entered by the


Member States and/or by the European Union as representative of the
EU trade bloc. This issue is not settled in scholarly studies. As a matter
of principle, it is well-known that WTO agreements strictly limit the
introduction of trade barriers by signatory countries and en-
vironmentally based border measures could fall within the definition of
trade barrier. Notwithstanding that, exceptions are allowed in specific
cases and environmental concerns are taken into considerations in the
General Agreement of Trade and Tariffs (‘GATT’) and in Article II:2(a)
[12]. However, as it has been pointed out, a CBA tax on imported goods
based, directly or indirectly, on CO2 emissions could involve significant
transaction costs, considering the complexity, for purposes of the tax, of
tracking and monitoring the origin of products shipped from third
countries outside the European Union and the uncertainties on their
Dimensions

CO2 emission content. In addition, the measure at hand should be


(m × m)

carefully tailored, so as not to determine a discrimination, prohibited


(n × n)

(n × n)
(k × n)

(n × 1)

(n × 1)
(n × 1)
(n × 1)
(k × 1)
(k × 1)

(k × 1)

under the WTO framework, against importers either in favor of do-


mestic economic activities, or in favor of undertakings from selected
third countries [12].

3. Methods and models

This section introduces the adopted model, conceptualized in the


framework of Input-Output analysis, and the way production- and
consumption-based emission policies are implemented.

3.1. The World Trade Model with Bilateral Trades

The World Trade Model with Bilateral Trades [32] (WTMBT in the
following) is a meso-economic linear optimization model based on the
comparative advantage principle. Considering m world regions with n
Symbol

industries each, the WTMBT enables to endogenously determine the


ex ij
i, j

Ai

Tij

xi
m

pi
i
Fi
D

yi

ri
fi
n
k

production yields and trades patterns required to satisfy an exogenously


specified final demand yield in each region, minimizing the use of
factors of production (labor and capital) by complying with regional
Exogenous and endogenous parameters of the WTMBT.

factors endowments (e.g. availability of natural resources, land, work-


force, etc.). The choice of developing the study on the version of the
World Trade Model which includes the cost of bilateral trades (i.e.
WTMBT), is driven by the relevance of transport in determining the
arrangement of production and trades and by its non-negligible impact
on carbon emissions. The economic and environmental implications of
national and international transport of products are included in the
model and weighed depending on transport distances. With respect to
General Equilibrium Models (CGE), the WTMBT requires less exogenous
data since it considers households and government final demand as
constant and perfectly rigid with respect to endogenous change in
Endogenous variables
Exogenous variables

prices of goods and services. Therefore, instead of maximizing social


utility, the WTMBT establishes that the highest-cost producers set the
products prices, and each region chooses to produce or to import by
Category

minimizing the overall costs complying with their own production


Indices
Table 1

factors availability (i.e. factor endowments). In the WTMBT, production


technologies, factors use coefficients and final demand for each country

5
M.V. Rocco, et al. Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

are derived from Multi-Regional Input-Output tables (MRIO). Other


exogenous inputs like factor endowments, weights of transported goods
and regional distances are derived from other databases (e.g. World
Bank, International Energy Agency), depending on the scope of the
adopted MRIO and on the type of analysis to be carried out.
Assumptions of WTMBT are simple and grounded on widely re-
cognized economic principles. However, results of the model are af-
fected by sources of uncertainty: process characterization allow each
sector to produce only one output, technological coefficients and de-
mand are fixed and sectoral aggregation may lead to detail loss.
Furthermore, factor endowments represent crucial parameters, since
they practically limit regional production, and are hard to rigorously be
determined. Therefore, it cannot be expected that such limitations and
hypothesis could intercept even more complex market mechanisms, Fig. 1. Schematic representation of the modelling process. The blue curve re-
presents the range of possible model solutions corresponding to different global
resulting in a perfect representation of reality.
factor uses and carbon emissions in case no carbon policies are imposed. Other
Two different mathematical formulation of the WTMBT can be
curves represent the same outputs but considering scenarios with different
adopted, depending on the adopted endogenous/exogenous parameters carbon budgets.
summarized in Table 1, but they return the same result, that it, the
arrangement of international trades that leads to the minimization of
global factors use. In particular: account. In the original Dunchin’s formulation of the WTMBT [32],
transport technologies were modelled by explicitly considering weights

• Quantity Model (also referred as the Primal Model), expressed by the of transported products: to overcome the lack of such sectoral detailed
data, an alternative approach has assumed here, by hypothesizing that
system of equations. It minimizes global factors cost (Z) en-
dogenously returning production and exports by each sector. The regional specific cost for each transport technology increase pro-
global factors, considered as costs from the model perspective, are portionally with the travelled transport distance. This has been made by
primary inputs, value added in the form of compensation of em- defining the international transport coefficients matrix Tij (n × n) (in
ployees, taxes and subsidies, net operating surplus and consumption monetary units) calculated by equation: technical coefficients related to
of fixed capital. This minimization is subjected to three sets of transport activities in each region Mj (n × n) (in monetary units) are
constraints. The first one secures that total domestic supply, which is weighted based on the ratio between the average transport distances
represent by the sum of output and imports, covers the domestic among countries i and j (dij , in km), and the average transport distance
final uses, expressed in turn by the sum of internal demand, final covered by the exporting country for its own endogenous transport
demand, exports and international transportation of imports. The (CDj , in km).
second constraint defines that all the invoked production factors are dji Mj
less or equal to regional factors endowments. The last constraint Tji =
CDj (3)
establishes that the production in every regional sector cannot be
less than zero. Notice that Tji (n × n) is the matrix of international Most of the parameters exogenously required by the model (see
transport coefficients and it represents the specific cost of importing Table 1) can be obtained from Multi-Regional Monetary Input-Output
products from j to i: these values depend on each regional tech- (MRIO) databases, providing technical coefficients, final demand and
nology and on distances between regions (further explained later). factor inputs. Notably, factor input Fi may collect both the value-added
Moreover, yi (n × 1) represents the regional final demand, denoting components (with prices i different than zero) and the environmental
all the quantity of output requested by final users of region i, in- transactions (with prices i equal to zero), including CO2 emissions,
dependently from where this good or service is produced. energy use, land use, and so on. Several MRIO can be adopted for this
purpose, and the main ones are: Eora [39], WIOD [40], GTAP [41] and
Min Z = T
i Fi x i EXIOBASE [42]. Selection of the appropriate database depends on the
i
purpose and scope of the analysis; a comprehensive comparison among
xi + exji Ai xi + yi + exij + Tji exji i them can be found in the recent literature [43].
j i j i j i
s.t. Noteworthy, technical coefficients and final demand for each region
Fi xi fi i
provided by MRIO databases reflect one specific arrangement of in-
xi 0 i (1) ternational trades in one given year. However, since arrangement of
international trades are provided endogenously by the WTMBT, data
• Price Model (also referred as the Dual Model), expressed by the provided by the MRIO must be properly processed before being used in
system of equations. It targets to the maximization of the total va- the model. In particular, technical coefficients for each region should
lues of final demand net of scarcity rents (W), endogenously re- represent the total inputs required by a sector to produce its outputs,
turning price indices and scarcity rents for each sector, subjected to independently on where outputs are produced, hence deriving a total
three sets of constraints: the first and second ones ensure that prices direct technical coefficients per unit of each output for the jth region:
of goods do not exceed costs for endogenous and traded products; A = Aj j . The same can be done for final demand matrix, deriving
i ij
the last constraint ensures the non-negativity of prices indices. the total amount of product invoked by one region independent by the
country which delivers it i yij = yj j . According to this procedure,
Max W = yTi pi fTi ri technical coefficients and final demand matrices are populated only in
i i
their diagonal blocks, which characterize the overall input and final
pi ATi pi FTi ( i + ri) i demand structures of each region.
s.t. pi TTji pi pj i
pi 0 i (2) 3.2. Definition and application of CO2 emissions policies

A region makes an endogenous choice between potential regional Once the WTMBT is fully characterized, carbon emissions reduction
sources for imports by including the related transport costs into commitments (named carbon budgets in the following) are respectively

6
M.V. Rocco, et al. Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

defined and imposed to one or more regions as additional constraints to A final methodology remark is in order to justify the adopted ap-
the model. In compliance with this new set of constraints, the Primal proach. The modelling approach proposed in this study can be defined
Model returns the new arrangement of international trades that enable as a comparative statics analysis: the adopted WTMBT is capable to
to satisfy the final demand of all the regions by minimizing global capture the prospective economic and environmental effects caused by
economic factor use, while the Dual Model returns the related price an exogenously imposed shock (i.e. a carbon tax scheme) as if it appears
indices and scarcity rents of products. Notably, the scarcity rents en- overnight, assuming that industries are ruled by the comparative ad-
dogenously returned by the model result from the exogenously imposed vantage principle, and disregarding other policy mechanisms and reg-
carbon budget constraint, and these rents can be assimilated to the ulatory frameworks already in place. Notably, this approach is widely
corresponding carbon tax yields. In other words, to achieve the change accepted in economic theory and currently adopted by analysts in
in overall carbon emissions initially imposed to the model, these carbon economics and industrial ecology fields. Therefore, policy frameworks
tax yields need to be set and imposed to industries. for carbon emissions reduction already in place are not included in the
Fig. 1 provides a general sketched overview of the modelling pro- analysis: this is justified and fully consistent with our objective, since
cess, identifying model results based on the overall factor cost (Z) and we are interested in the comparative assessment of the effects of pure
on the overall regional CO2 emissions. Case 00 represents the trades, PBA and CBA schemes.
costs and emissions derived from the adopted MRIO database. The ar-
rangement of international trades in the Case 0 (assumed as the baseline
4. Case study: CO2 emissions policies at the EU level
scenario) will be different from the original arrangement of the MRIO
model, because production and trades are only governed by the com-
This section describes the adopted MRIO database, provides the
parative advantage principle, assumed as an approximation of the
main assumptions and simplifications adopted for the analysis, and fi-
complex dynamics governing real productive systems. Once carbon
nally presents and discusses the obtained results. The WTMBT model
budgets are defined and applied through a PBA or a CBA approach, the
has been specifically developed for this study based on the Python
WTMBT returns new arrangements of international trades (Case n),
language. For the sake of transparency and reproducibility of the ob-
implying different values of costs and emissions compared to the
tained results, the developed model, the input data and all the results of
baseline.
the analysed scenarios are provided alongside this manuscript as elec-
Application of CO2 emissions policy on a given region based on a
tronic supplementary material.
Production-Based Accounting (PBA) paradigm can be performed by im-
posing to the ith region a maximum amount of allowed direct CO2
emissions as a new constrained factor endowment for the group of re- 4.1. Main data and assumptions
gions subjected to limitation (e.g. EU) fEU
PBA
, CO2 , defined by equation as a
fraction (%) of the baseline CO2 emissions for the same region (i.e. the The Exiobase v.2 (http://www.exiobase.eu/) [44] has been selected
matrix product of the CO2 emissions coefficients Fi, CO2 (1 × n) and the as the reference Multi-Regional Environmentally Extended Input-
total production x i0 (n × 1) ). Output database. The database includes data related to 48 countries
PBA and 5 rest of the world regions (see electronic supplementary material),
fEU = · (Fi, CO2·x i0)
, CO2
(4) with a resolution of 163 sectors each, it provides interindustry trans-
i EU
actions, 7 final demand categories, 7 value added categories, and a
In the same vein, the implementation of Consumption-Based multiplicity of environmental transactions (namely resources con-
Accounting (CBA) paradigm is performed by imposing to the ith region a sumption and emissions, including CO2 emissions from combustion
maximum amount of allowed CO2 emissions embedded into its own final covered by the analyzed emissions policies). With reference to Table 1,
demand as a new constrained factor endowment f EU , CO2 , defined by
CBA
the MRIO database provides technical and input coefficients Ai and Fi ,
equation as a fraction (%) of the baseline CO2 emissions embedded in and final demand yi . To reducing computational efforts due to the
the final demand of the same region. The latter term is calculated as the WTMBT, EXIOBASE sectors have been aggregated moving from 163 to
sum of the direct emissions caused by region i to produce its own final 57 sectors (refer to electronic supplementary material for the detailed
demand (first term in rhs of) plus the emissions caused by all the other list of sectors): logic underlying sectoral aggregation choices has been
regions to produce exports supplied to the ith region (second term in rhs driven by the attempt of keeping carbon intensive sector fully dis-
of). aggregated, in order to detect and analyze potential changes in world
m
technology mix. Transport distances matrix D has been derived as the
CBA
f EU = · Fi, CO2 x i0 ex ij0 + (Fj, CO2· ex0ji) distances between countries’ capitals. Finally, factor endowments fi
, CO2
i EU j i j i (5) have been estimated starting from the factor use in the baseline year
available from the adopted MRIO model.
According to the CBA paradigm, every country is responsible for the European Union (EU27) has selected for the application of the
emissions caused by the production of its own imported products: carbon emissions policies, assuming 2007 as the reference year for
therefore, the model will try to re-import and re-export products defining the baseline case (Case 0). While the selection of the time
through low emissions country to numerically satisfy constraint. To frame is mainly due to the MRIO data availability, the choice of the EU
avoid such phenomenon, constraint is formulated by imposing the ex- as the country scope for the application of the carbon emissions policies
ports of each country equal at most to its overall production. is motivated by the need to better understand the reasons behind to the
undesirable effect of carbon leakage occurred with the EU Emissions
ex ij xi
Trading System (EU ETS), and which countermeasures could be taken
j i (6)
to mitigate this effect.
It is worth to notice that while the interpretation of the results of the Since we rely on an Input-Output database with 2007 as the re-
Primal Model is straightforward (i.e. the quantities of products traded ference year, the issue of adequacy of outdated input–output datasets
among regions), the interpretation of the results of the Dual Model is less for providing insights on current policy measures may arise. However,
immediate. Beside the price indices of sectors’ outputs, the scarcity it should be observed that relying on outdated IOTs is a common
rents ri endogenously returned by the model can be interpreted as the practice in economic and environmental analyses, since the structure of
contribution of the carbon emissions policy in increasing the price of national supply chains does not exhibit disruptive changes over time, as
products, that is, the CO2 emissions price endogenously determined by empirically demonstrated by the authoritative studies of Miller and
an emissions trading market. Blair [45], Wood [46] and Dietzenbacher and Hoen [47].

7
M.V. Rocco, et al. Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

Table 2
Summary of the modelled scenarios. Economic and environmental impact of the prospected policies is performed by considering the difference between the PBA x%
or the CBA x% with the Case 0 (assumed as the baseline).
Policy case name Description

Case 00 Production and consumption pathways for the global economy, derived from the EXIOBASE v.2 MRIO database.
Case 0 Result of the WTMBT optimization model with constraints on factor endowments (economic and environmental resources) but without any constraint on
carbon emissions. This case is set as the baseline for assessing the impact of carbon emissions policies.
PBA x% Result of the WTMBT subjected to an additional constraint on EU27′s PBA carbon emissions, equal to the PBA carbon budget in the Case 0 reduced by x%.
CBA x% Result of the WTMBT subjected to an additional constraint on EU27′s CBA carbon emissions, equal to the CBA carbon budget in the Case 0 reduced by x%.

4.2. Scenarios definition budget of 1%, 5%, 10%, 20%, 30% and 40%, hence simulating the
imposition of policy commitments. Notably, such carbon budgets are
With reference to Fig. 1, starting from MRIO data (Case 00), the applied to the whole EU27 region: this choice is in line with the current
baseline scenario (Case 0) has been determined by running the WTMBT EU ETS, which established a CO2 emissions allowances market at the
without any emissions policy implemented, and it will be subsequently European level, stimulating a cooperative behavior between its coun-
adopted as the reference case for comparing effects of PBA and CBA tries. Table 2 summarizes the cases investigated in this analysis.
emissions policies. Finally, due to the crucial role played by exogenously determined
With respect to Case 00, global factors use in Case 0 (i.e. gross value national factors endomwents, a sensitivity analysis has been carried out
added) is overestimated by +5.2%. The shares of macro-regions factor by testing different sets of them in order to assess the robustness of the
use do not change significantly: Canada (+14.8%) and Middle East obtained results.
(−2.5%) respectively results as the most over- and under-estimated
regions. Overall, EU27 results in a +9.3% overestimation of factor use.
From an environmental point of view, global CO2 emission from fossil 5. Results and discussion
fuel combustion results in line with 2007 IEA data (approximately 29
Gton). Overall, observed differences between Case 0 and Case 00 have Starting from output of the Case 0, assumed as the baseline, results
been considered acceptable. PBA and CBA policies implementation have been derived. Among the
From a practical viewpoint, the only differences between PBA and multiplicity of results returned by the WTMBT, this section examines
CBA resides in the definition of the carbon budget constraints, respec- the change in global CO2 emissions and factor use.
tively determined through relations (4) and (5). Both the scenarios are Fig. 2 and Fig. 3 respectively reports the changes in global CO2
performed by imposing a progressive reduction of the EU27 carbon emissions and the change in factor use that result from the imposition of
PBA and CBA carbon policies. Results are expressed in terms of change

Fig. 2. EU27 carbon budget reduction (%) vs regional and global change in CO2 emissions (Mton). Upper side: results grouped by macro-region; Lower side: results
grouped by industries. Left side: results of production-based policy; Right side: results of consumption-based policy.

8
M.V. Rocco, et al. Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

Fig. 3. EU27 carbon budget reduction (%) vs global change in factor use (primal problem objective function, in B€2010). Upper side: results grouped by macro-
region; Lower side: results grouped by industries. Left side: results of production-based policy; Right side: results of consumption-based policy.

in emissions and factor use with respect to the baseline scenario, framework, the PBA scheme fails in reducing global carbon emissions while
grouped by region, by sector, and as total net values (black diamonds). implying additional global costs; conversely, the CBA policy succeeds in
Arrangement of production and trades among sectors and regions re- reducing global carbon emissions. As an example, with reference to a
sulting from PBA and CBA policies influences the direct carbon emis- carbon budget of 40%, the PBA scheme causes a global increase of 0.8 Gton
sions and factor use of each region, that ultimately results in a net with an increase in 12.5B€; conversely, the CBA scheme causes a global
change in global CO2 emissions and global factor use. If an increase in reduction of −1.2 Gton by means of 25.5 B€ of increase in factor use.
overall CO2 emissions occurs, it reveals that the carbon leakage effect is With a carbon budget reduction ranging from 1% up to 20%, the
predominant compared to the desired CO2 emissions reduction even- implementation of CBA results in global CO2 emissions reduction ac-
tually induced by implemented policy. On the other hand, global factor companied by cost increase for EU and a corresponding cost decrease in
use will always increase compared to the baseline to comply with the other regions: EU regions are thus relying on more expensive en-
new carbon budget constraint: this may be interpreted as the increase in dogenous technologies by reducing imports from foreign carbon in-
total costs due internalization (or monetization) of an environmental tensive industries (from USA in particular). However, after 20% of
externality or, equivalently, the overall cost induced by implementation carbon budget reduction, reduction in cost for the EU region reveals
of the prospected policy intervention. that a portion of the EU final demand is satisfied by imports from a
With reference to Fig. 2 and Fig. 3, the following comments can be balanced mix of foreign industries. On the other hand, with reference to
made. PBA, the carbon leakage effect becomes increasingly important with the
For carbon budgets reduction within 5%, both PBA and CBA provide a increase in carbon budgets reductions: after 20%, the direct emissions
comparable environmental effectiveness and costs, reducing global carbon in foreign countries (rest of Europe, Russia and Canada in particular)
emissions. However, while the application of CBA stimulates the coopera- becomes increasingly relevant, becoming greater than avoided CO2
tion between EU countries and the adoption of their own cleaner technol- emissions in EU. Notably, even if the EU emissions get lower, the
ogies, with PBA EU countries find more convenient to import products from overall cost of the policy and the overall emissions increase, thus re-
abroad. For carbon budgets reduction greater than 5%, the CBA policy sulting in an overall inefficient and undesirable plot.
becomes effective in reducing global emissions, while PBA policy appears to The sectors whose exhibit greater changes in carbon emissions with
cause carbon leakage, increasing global emissions. As previously mentioned, respect to the base case are, not surprisingly, the more carbon intensive
both schemes result in an increase in global factor use, that results greater ones. Indeed, the weight of the imposed policies (both PBA and CBA) are
for CBA than PBA: this is motivated by the fact that while a decrease in PBA proportional to the carbon emission yields, and the model attempts to
carbon budget allows EU countries to rely on less expensive and higher satisfy the imposed carbon budget constraints starting from those sectors.
carbon intensive imports, the same is not allowed for an equal reduction in Power generation is mostly affected by the PBA and CBA carbon policies:
CBA carbon budget, which forces EU countries to rely on more expensive from Fig. 2, it is evident that in a PBA approach, production of goods and
technologies with lower carbon intensities. It can be concluded that, for services shifts from EU to foreign countries not subjected to carbon policy
high values of carbon budget reductions and within the adopted modelling constraints, and the electricity required by the products supply chain

9
M.V. Rocco, et al. Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

Fig. 4. Results of the sensitivity analysis on global factor endowments. Left side: change in global factor cost (B€2010); Right side: change in global CO2 emissions
(Mton).

follows this shift. This ultimately results in higher global emissions due to emissions. In particular, the research provides a global empirical ap-
high carbon intensity of electricity production by extra-EU countries. plication of a CO2 emissions policy based on a consumption-based ap-
Likewise, with reference to Fig. 3, the increase in global factor use is proach and compares the obtained results with the widely adopted
mostly due to electricity generation shift from EU region to Asia and production-based approach. The study adopted the World Trade Model
Middle East regions. The application of CBA affects again power genera- with Bilateral Trades applied to background macroeconomic data
tion, but in a radically different manner compared to PBA: indeed, the supplied by the Exiobase v.2 global Multi-Regional Input-Output data-
reduction in carbon emissions by the EU region is not the result of a base. This approach makes it possible to evaluate the introduction of
leakage, but it results from a shift from high to low carbon intensive power the policy net of market mechanisms that intervene and that are in-
generation technologies mostly occurring within the EU region. cluded in more complex models (e.g. Computable General Equilibrium
A closer look to the results may give further insights related to the models) requiring further assumptions. In this sense, the analysis con-
carbon policy mechanisms. As an example, looking at the CBA case with a ducted here can be defined as a study on the supply side only, useful to
20% of carbon budget reduction, it appears that Canada makes a greater evaluate the interactions that would occur if these policies were im-
use of economic factors, which is matched by a significant cut in CO2 plemented overnight.
emissions. By looking at the sectoral contributions of this country, it is Results of this study are useful to understand the potential of in-
observed how metal production increases (also exported to European ternational trades in reducing overall carbon emissions given a set of
countries such as Spain), gas extraction activities decrease, and the elec- constant technological alternatives available to produce the same pro-
tricity mix changes from gas to nuclear power generation. Therefore, the ducts. The obtained results suggest that defining CO2 emissions policies
effectiveness of CBA in terms of CO2 emissions reduction appears also based on a consumption-based paradigm seems to be the most effective
outside the countries where this policy is applied. In other words, the way to reduce the global carbon emissions, avoiding the carbon leakage
countries trading with the area where the CBA policy is applied will be phenomenon caused by current production-based policies. Indeed, an
those most able to meet the additional demand for carbon intensive pro- imposed reduction in CO2 emissions embedded in European Union final
ducts with the cleanest infrastructure. Another example of this behavior is demand through a Consumption-Based Approach policy would result in
provided by Italy, that becomes a producer of electricity from cleaner a global CO2 emissions reduction up to almost 1.2 Gton. On the other
energy sources in the CBA 20% case, managing to meet the demand of hand, an imposed reduction in direct European Union CO2 emissions
neighboring countries through a relatively cleaner infrastructure; how- according to a PBA approach would result in an overall increase in
ever, this implies an increase in the use of economic factors in the elec- global carbon emissions up to almost 0.8 Gton. The analysis conducted
tricity transmission sector in the same region. here shows how a paradigm shift from Production-Based Approach
Results of the sensitivity analysis on factors endowments of all the towards Consumption-Based Approach can lead to an actual improve-
national economies are reported in Fig. 4, where a reduction in the ment in the effectiveness of mitigation policies on what should be the
available amount of national workforce, land and primary energy have ultimate target of these (i.e. global emissions). This is may not represent
been tested. As suggested by the figure, CO2 emissions and factor use the most adequate strategy for the achievement of the CO2 emission
are strongly sensitive to change in factor endowments, and this sensi- cuts targets, but it can be taken into consideration by policy-maker as a
bility increases with the increase in carbon budgets reductions. Eco- more effective alternative that, net of the possible legislative hurdles,
nomic cost of CBA policy still appears to be higher compared to PBA. would represent an intermediate solution as long as a more efficient
The robustness of the model results is demonstrated by the sensibility of strategies are hampered by political constraint.
CO2 emissions, that keep the same trends for PBA and CBA: overall, In order to improve the quality and reliability of the obtained re-
policies based on PBA always result affected by carbon leakage, while sults, several aspects of the adopted modelling framework deserve to be
CBA policies provides always a net emissions reduction. developed in future studies. Given the crucial role of factor endow-
ments in determining production and trade patterns, much efforts
should be devoted in their conceptual and numerical definition (e.g.
6. Conclusion availability of renewable energy sources, water, others…). Secondly,
definition of transport modes deserves further analysis: an improved
This paper provides a formalization and a first comparative appli- technology-dependent definition of transport distances among regions
cation of two opposite paradigms for allocating responsibility for CO2

10
M.V. Rocco, et al. Applied Energy 274 (2020) 115301

needs to be made, and all the unrealistic transport solutions should be [19] Wood R, Moran D, Stadler K, Ivanova D, Steen-Olsen K, Tisserant A, et al.
numerically constrained by the model. Then, introducing Rectangular Prioritizing consumption-based carbon policy based on the evaluation of mitigation
potential using input-output methods. J Ind Ecol 2017:1–13. https://doi.org/10.
Choice of Technology (RCOT) will make the model flexible and capable 1111/jiec.12702.
to select among alternative technology options for providing the same [20] Lenzen M, Murray J, Sack F, Wiedmann T. Shared producer and consumer re-
product, hence giving the opportunity to investigate multiple tech- sponsibility - Theory and practice. Ecol Econ 2007;61:27–42. https://doi.org/10.
1016/j.ecolecon.2006.05.018.
nology options. Finally, beside the improvements related to the mod- [21] Vita G, Lundström JR, Hertwich EG, Quistd J, Ivanova D, Stadler K, et al.
elling approach, one very crucial aspect that deserve for a thorough Sustainable lifestyle scenarios to curb European environmental impact: connecting
discussion is concerned with the practical and legislative barriers that local visions to global consequences. Under Rev Ecol Econ
2018;164:106322https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2019.05.002.
may arise in the implementation of an environmental policy based on [22] Zhu Y, Shi Y, Wu J, Wu L, Xiong W. Exploring the characteristics of CO2 emissions
the Consumption-Based paradigm. Alongside this, multiple different embodied in international trade and the fair share of responsibility. Ecol Econ
scenarios may be conducted to explore which is the best policy para- 2018;146:574–87. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.12.020.
[23] Choi JK, Bakshi BR, Hubacek K, Nader J. A sequential input-output framework to
digm to be adopted depending on the economic and technology struc-
analyze the economic and environmental implications of energy policies: gas taxes
tures of the analyzed region. and fuel subsidies. Appl Energy 2016;184:830–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
apenergy.2016.05.033.
Credit authorship contribution statement [24] Sommer M, Kratena K. Consumption and production-based CO 2 pricing policies:
macroeconomic trade-offs and carbon leakage. Econ Syst Res 2020;5314. https://
doi.org/10.1080/09535314.2019.1612736.
Matteo V. Rocco: Conceptualization, Methodology, Formal ana- [25] Nabernegg S, Bednar-Friedl B, Muñoz P, Titz M, Vogel J. National policies for global
lysis, Writing - original draft, Writing - review & editing. Nicolò emission reductions: effectiveness of carbon emission reductions in international
supply chains. Ecol Econ 2019;158:146–57. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.
Golinucci: Conceptualization, Methodology, Formal analysis, 2018.12.006.
Investigation. Stefano M. Ronco: Conceptualization. Emanuela [26] Duchin F, Levine SH. Sectors may use multiple technologies simultaneously: the
Colombo: Conceptualization, Validation, Supervision. rectangular choice-of-technology model with binding factor constraints. Econ Syst
Res 2011;23:281–302. https://doi.org/10.1080/09535314.2011.571238.
[27] Duchin F. A world trade model based on comparative advantage with m regions, n
Declaration of Competing Interest goods, and k factors. Econ Syst Res 2005;17:141–62. https://doi.org/10.1080/
09535310500114903.
[28] Springer NP, Duchin F. Feeding nine billion people sustainably: conserving land and
The authors declare that they have no known competing financial water through shifting diets and changes in technologies. Environ Sci Technol
interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influ- 2014;48:4444–51. https://doi.org/10.1021/es4051988.
[29] Hammer Strømman A, Duchin F. A world trade model with bilateral trade based on
ence the work reported in this paper.
comparative advantage. Econ Syst Res 2006;18:281–97. https://doi.org/10.1080/
09535310600844300.
References [30] Strømman AH, Hertwich EG, Duchin F. Shifting trade patterns as a means of re-
ducing global carbon dioxide emissions a multiobjective analysis. J Ind Ecol
2009;13:38–57. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1530-9290.2008.00084.x.
[1] IPCC. Summary for Policymakers. 2014. doi:10.1017/CBO9781107415324. [31] Duchin F, Levine SH, Strømman AH. Combining multiregional input-output analysis
[2] Iea IEA. CO2 emissions from fuel combustion 2017 - highlights. Int Energy Agency with a world trade model for evaluating scenarios for sustainable use of global
2017;1:1–162. https://doi.org/10.1787/co2_fuel-2017-en. resources, Part I: conceptual framework. J Ind Ecol 2016;20:775–82.
[3] International Energy Agency. Global CO2 emissions in 2019; 2020. [32] Duchin F, Levine SH. Combining multiregional input-output analysis with a world
[4] World Bank Group and Ecofys. Carbon Pricing Watch 2016 2016:1–16. doi:10. trade model for evaluating scenarios for sustainable use of global resources, Part II:
1596/978-1-4648-0268-3. Implementation. J Ind Ecol 2016;20:783–91. https://doi.org/10.1111/jiec.12302.
[5] Peters GP, Marland G, Hertwich EG, Saikku L, Rautiainen A, Kauppi PE. Trade, [33] López-Morales CA, Duchin F. Economic implications of policy restrictions on water
transport, and sinks extend the carbon dioxide responsibility of countries: An edi- withdrawals from surface and underground sources. Econ Syst Res 2015;27:154–71.
torial essay 2009:379–88. doi:10.1007/s10584-009-9606-2. https://doi.org/10.1080/09535314.2014.980224.
[6] Peters GP. Policy update: managing carbon leakage. Carbon Manag 2010;1:35–7. [34] Boitier B, Jakob M, Steckel J, Edenhofer O, Johansson TB, Ouedraogo NS, et al.
https://doi.org/10.4155/cmt.10.1. Consumption-vs. production-based emission policies. Appl Energy 2017;190:12–5.
[7] Franzen A, Mader S. Consumption-based versus production-based accounting of https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-resource-100913-012342.
CO2 emissions: is there evidence for carbon leakage? Environ Sci Policy [35] Aldred J. Tax by design: the mirrlees review (OUP, 2011). New Polit Econ 2012.
2018;84:34–40. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.envsci.2018.02.009. https://doi.org/10.1080/13563467.2011.608122.
[8] Gallego B, Lenzen M. A consistent input-output formulation of shared producer and [36] Castellucci L, Markandya A. environmental taxes and fiscal reform. Environ Taxes
consumer responsibility. Econ Syst Res 2005;17:365–91. https://doi.org/10.1080/ Fisc Reform 2016. https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230392403_1.
09535310500283492. [37] Haites E. Carbon taxes and greenhouse gas emissions trading systems: what have we
[9] Khaqqi KN, Sikorski JJ, Hadinoto K, Kraft M. Incorporating seller/buyer reputation- learned? Clim Policy 2018. https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2018.1492897.
based system in blockchain-enabled emission trading application. Appl Energy [38] Pearce D. The role of carbon taxes in adjusting to global warming. Econ J 2006.
2018;209:8–19. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2017.10.070. https://doi.org/10.2307/2233865.
[10] P GP, Hertwich EG. Policy analysis CO 2 embodied in international trade with [39] Manfred Lenzen, Daniel Moran, Keiichiro Kanemoto AG. Building Eora: a global
implications for global climate policy 2007;42:1401–7. doi:10.1021/es072023k. multi-region input-output database at high country and sector resolution. Econ Syst
[11] Afionis S, Sakai M, Scott K, Barrett J, Gouldson A. Consumption-based carbon ac- Res, 2013;25(1):20–49.
counting: does it have a future? Wiley Interdiscip Rev Clim Chang [40] Timmer M, Erumban AA, Gouma R, Los B, Temurshoev U, de Vries GJ, et al. The
2017;8:e438https://doi.org/10.1002/wcc.438. world input-output database (WIOD): contents, sources and methods. WIOD Backgr
[12] Jakob M, Steckel JC, Edenhofer O. Consumption- versus production-based emission Doc Available Www Wiod Org 2012;40.
policies. Annu Rev Resour Econ 2014;6:297–318. https://doi.org/10.1146/ [41] Badri NG, Walmsley TL. Global trade, assistance, and production: the GTAP 7 data
annurev-resource-100913-012342. base. Cent Glob Trade Anal Purdue Univ; 2008.
[13] von der Leyen U. A Union that strives for more: My agenda for Europe 2019:1–24. [42] Merciai S, Schmidt J. Methodology for the construction of global multi-regional
[14] Wang F, Liu X, Nguyen TA. Evaluating the economic impacts and feasibility of hybrid supply and use tables for the EXIOBASE v3 database. J Ind Ecol 2018.
China’s energy cap: based on an Analytic General Equilibrium Model. Econ Model https://doi.org/10.1111/jiec.12713.
2018;69:114–26. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2017.08.034. [43] Moran D, Wood R. Convergence between the eora, wiod, exiobase, and openeu’s
[15] Fischer C, Greaker M, Rosendahl KE. Robust technology policy against emission consumption-based carbon accounts. Econ Syst Res 2014;26:245–61. https://doi.
leakage: the case of upstream subsidies. J Environ Econ Manage 2017;84:44–61. org/10.1080/09535314.2014.935298.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2017.02.001. [44] Wood R, Stadler K, Bulavskaya T, Lutter S, Giljum S, de Koning A, et al. Global
[16] Zhang X, Qi T yu, Ou X min, Zhang X liang. The role of multi-region integrated sustainability accounting—developing EXIOBASE for multi-regional footprint ana-
emissions trading scheme: a computable general equilibrium analysis. Appl Energy lysis. Sustainability 2014;7:138–63.
2017;185:1860–8. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2015.11.092. [45] Miller RE, Blair PD. Input-output analysis: foundations and extensions. Cambridge
[17] Liu L, Huang G, Baetz B, Zhang K. Environmentally-extended input-output simu- University Press; 2009.
lation for analyzing production-based and consumption-based industrial green- [46] Wood R. Construction, stability and predictability of an input-output time-series for
house gas mitigation policies. Appl Energy 2018;232:69–78. https://doi.org/10. Australia. Econ Syst Res 2011. https://doi.org/10.1080/09535314.2011.564156.
1016/j.apenergy.2018.09.192. [47] Dietzenbacher E, Hoen A. Coefficient stability and predictability in input-output
[18] Ivanova D, Stadler K, Steen-Olsen K, Wood R, Vita G, Tukker A, et al. Environmental models: a comparative analysis for the Netherlands. Constr Manag Econ 2006.
impact assessment of household consumption. J Ind Ecol 2016;20:526–36. https:// https://doi.org/10.1080/01446190600567985.
doi.org/10.1111/jiec.12371.

11

You might also like