The Impact of Industrial Diversification On Employment Growth in The 50 U.S. States: 2000-2013

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

731599

research-article2017
EDQXXX10.1177/0891242417731599Economic Development QuarterlyPallares and Adkisson

Research and Practice


Economic Development Quarterly

The Impact of Industrial Diversification on


1­–10
© The Author(s) 2017
Reprints and permissions:
Employment Growth in the 50 U.S. States: sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0891242417731599
https://doi.org/10.1177/0891242417731599

2000-2013 journals.sagepub.com/home/edq

Francisco J. Pallares1 and Richard V. Adkisson2

Abstract
Economic developers express concern for both employment growth and employment stability. This study asks whether
there is a trade-off between the quantity and reliability of jobs. Does industrial diversification, presumed to lead to more
reliable jobs, have an impact (perhaps negative) on overall job growth? Using data from the 50 U.S. states from 2000 to 2013,
this study explores the relationships between employment growth and industrial diversification measured in four ways. The
results are mixed, suggesting that overreliance on employment in stable industries might retard employment growth but that
overreliance on employment in volatile industries does not have a clear positive or negative impact on employment growth.

Keywords
employment growth, diversification, regional economic development

Volatility implies unreliability and irregularity, conditions this is correct, a more diversified economy would be
that introduce uncertainty into many business and economic expected to suffer less employment volatility when com-
decisions, as well as potentially disturbing individual and pared with a less diversified economy. Where job reliability/
community well-being. As examples, economic volatility of stability is a goal, an industrial diversification strategy
one type or another has been shown to be related to crime would seem warranted.
(Bausman & Goe, 2004), economic growth (Mobarak, 2005), Job reliability may be desirable, but it is not the only goal
imports (Kenen & Rodrik, 1986), food security (Naylor & for economic development. Overall growth in jobs (employ-
Falcon, 2010), and private investment (Aizenman & Marion, ment) is also a major, perhaps primary, goal of local and
1999). The potential negative impacts of excessive economic regional economic development. Stable and high-quality
volatility have not been lost on students of local and regional jobs may be more difficult to attain, if for no other reason
economic development. than many regions compete to attract them. Thus, an interest-
Although economic development thinking has evolved ing question is to ask whether diversification, presumed to
through time (Bradshaw & Blakely, 1999; Reese, 2014), the lead to more reliable jobs, has an impact on overall job
ultimate goal of economic development policies and actions growth. Rephrased in the negative, does overreliance on vol-
is typically the creation or attraction of jobs for local resi- atile industries and/or industrial concentration (suggesting a
dents (Sparks, 2013). However, as stated in a document of lack of diversification) affect job growth and, if so, in what
the International Economic Development Council, simply direction? Diversification hedges against both upside and
“creating jobs” is no longer a sufficient economic develop- downside risk. Is there a trade-off between the quantity and
ment plan (Anderson et al., 2010). Economic development is reliability of jobs?
now focused on creating reliable (nonvolatile) “quality jobs,” The purpose of this study is to investigate whether a lack
preferably with high wages (Anderson et al., 2010). of diversity in employment, proxied by concentration in vol-
Unreliable unemployment is seen as one of the two funda- atile industries, reliance on exports, and general industrial
mental problems associated with economic volatility
(Baldwin & Brown, 2004). 1
Austin Community College, Round Rock, TX, USA
Employment volatility can be driven by business cycle 2
New Mexico State University, Las Cruces, NM, USA
fluctuations, seasonal fluctuations, industry-specific shocks,
Corresponding Author:
and exchange rate fluctuations, among other things.
Richard V. Adkisson, Department of Economics, Applied Statistics, and
Typically, diversification is seen as a means to reduce to International Business, New Mexico State University, MSC 3CQ,
volatility (Chen, 2014; Dammon, Zhang, & Spatt, 2001; Box 30001, Las Cruces, NM 88003-8001, USA.
Mayer, Wang, Egginton, & Flint, 2012; Scordis, 2000). If Email: radkisso@nmsu.edu
2 Economic Development Quarterly 00(0)

Figure 1.  Percentage change in wage and salary employment from previous year 2000-2014, U.S. national and state range.
Note. Data from Bureau of Economic Analysis, regional accounts, SA4, personal income and employment by major component, wage and salary
employment.

concentration, affects employment growth. Data from the 50 Macroeconomic Stability: It Is a Good Thing
states are observed over the years 2000 to 2013. The knowl-
edge generated from this study should be useful in shaping Prior to the Great Recession of 2007-2009, many economists
future state economic development policy. expressed their delight at what seemed to be a taming of the
business cycle. Arthur Burns (1960,1969) wrote “[T]hat
although our economy continues to be swayed by the business
Background cycle, its impact on the lives and fortunes of individuals has
The National Bureau of Economic Research reported two been substantially reduced in our generation” (p. 102). Burns
recessionary periods in the post-2000 period. The first lasted credits the evolution of corporate practice, better government
from the first quarter of 2001 through the fourth quarter of financing, improved unemployment insurance and social
2001. The second, the more severe of the two, began in the security, and lower reliance on traditionally volatile industries
fourth quarter of 2007 and concluded in the second quarter of for the moderation. Similarly, Warnock and Warnock (2000)
2009, although the recovery has been sluggish. The impact suggested that the source of increased stability is a dramatic
of these recessions on employment1 growth is obvious in post–World War II structural transformation with the United
Figure 1, which also shows the range of employment growth States becoming less reliant on volatile industries. Stock and
rates across the 50 states. Beyond the national trend, state- Watson (2003) provided further documentation of the modera-
by-state employment growth rates vary substantially within tion trend. Although the Great Moderation idea has been
certain years. For example, from 1999-2000, national wage deflated by the Great Recession, the topic continues to attract
and salary employment grew by 2.1%, while state employ- research interest; perhaps this is because stability continues to
ment growth varied from -0.1% (Mississippi) to 4.2% be considered a positive economic outcome.
(Nevada). In 2009, the depth of the Great Recession, the Reduced macroeconomic volatility has numerous bene-
national change was -4.3% with the state range from -8.9% fits: decreased price volatility, improved market functioning,
(Nevada) to 0% (Alaska). By 2014 the employment growth easier economic planning, and reduced resources devoted to
range narrowed to a range of −0.4% (West Virginia) to 4.0% hedging inflation risks. Lower volatility of output implies
(North Dakota). more stable employment and a reduction in the extent of eco-
nomic uncertainty confronting households and firms
(Bernanke, 2004). In the international context, Koren and
Literature Review Tenreyro (2007) found employment volatility to be an impor-
This literature review serves two purposes. The first is to tant reason why poor nations remain poor. Baldwin and
understand the post–World War II trend toward macroeco- Brown (2004) specifically mentioned the possibility of a
nomic stability and the pre-Great Recession moderation growth/stability trade-off.
debate. This is included primarily to document that reduced
economic volatility is generally seen as a positive economic
sign. The second purpose is to explore possible sources of
Regional Variation in Employment Growth
variations in employment growth and volatility to guide the Researchers have explored the role industrial specialization/
empirical work. diversification plays in economic growth (Conroy, 1975),
Pallares and Adkisson 3

real per-capita income (Grennes, Guerron-Quintana, & To conclude, the review above suggests that a variety of
Leblebicioglu, 2010), wages/productivity (Kemeny & possible influences on employment growth, overall industrial
Storper, 2015), and unemployment and per-capita income concentration, concentration in specific industries, interna-
(Attaran, 1986). Substantial prior research focused primarily tional openness, size of the economy, labor regulations/rigidi-
on the impact of diversification on employment volatility ties, and spatial effects could be present as well. The empirical
rather than growth, although the two are potentially related. model developed below operationalizes these factors and
Kort (1981) examined employment volatility across 106 includes a few control variables not mentioned above.
metropolitan statistical areas during the 1967-1976 period.
He concluded that industrial diversification plays a role in
The Data, Model, and Method
employment volatility, but also found evidence that employ-
ment volatility varies with city size. Malizia and Ke (1993) The purpose of this research is to ask whether overreliance
observed U.S. metropolitan statistical areas over the 1972- on volatile or export industries and/or general industrial con-
1988 period and concluded that reliance on highly volatile centration affects job growth and, if so, in what direction. As
industries, especially mining and manufacturing, tends to discussed earlier, the motivation is that economic develop-
increase both unemployment and employment volatility. ment authorities typically seek both to attract a high quantity
Felix (2012) studied the Tenth District of the U.S. Federal of jobs and at the same time target high-quality and reliable,
Reserve System to test whether industrial diversity by county but presumably scarcer, jobs. Together this raises the possi-
is associated with employment growth. Felix found that bility of a trade-off between attracting industries promising
more industrially diverse counties have more stable growth, jobs in quantity and attracting industries promising more
but that long-run employment growth does not seem to be reliable, but possibly fewer, jobs.
affected by industrial diversity. Specifically, this study examines the impact of industrial
Industrial diversification is not the only potential influ- concentration/diversification and export exposure on the
ence over employment volatility and growth. Cabrales and growth of wage and salary employment. The specification of
Hopenhayn (1997) studied the impacts of regionally differ- the empirical model is driven by the literature reviewed
ent labor market regulations in Spain. Labor market restric- above and examples of empirical growth models provided by
tions in Spain are associated with lower turnover and lower Reed (2009), Monchuk, Miranowski, Hayes, and Babcock
productivity; however, the evidence associating it with (2007), Carlino and Mills (1987), and Peach and Starbuck
higher unemployment is not strong. Blanchard (1997) was (2011). As is typical, these authors used modified growth
critical of their methods, but agreed that the topic is worthy models to measure economic growth (variously defined).
of study. Partridge and Rickman (1996) investigated the The particular variables included in their empirical models
influences that industry composition and traditional cost fac- vary with their purposes. In the present case, EMPGROW,
tors such as wages and unionization have on state employ- the year-to-year percentage change in wage and salary state
ment growth. Using unionization as a proxy for variation in employment (annual employment growth), serves as the
state-level labor climates, their results provided no evidence dependent variable.2
that union membership affects employment growth.
International linkages may also influence employment
The Data
volatility and potentially employment growth. Ocegueda,
Escamilla, and Mungaray (2011) studied employment vol- The independent variables of primary interest are the
atility in the northern Mexican states that are heavily reli- Herfindahl–Hirschman Index (HHI) to measure general
ant on manufacturing (maquiladoras). Among other industrial concentration; SNONVOL, the percentage of state
influences, they indicated that the high correlation of employment in nonvolatile industries; and SVOL, the per-
Mexican and U.S. business cycles makes the northern centage of state employment in volatile industries.
Mexican states especially vulnerable to employment vola- SNONVOL and SVOL measure a state’s relative reliance on
tility. Buch and Schlotter (2013) explored the links between volatile industries. When grouped, industries that are indi-
trade openness and employment volatility in German vidually highly volatile could appear less volatile if industry
states. Their evidence suggested that higher shares of ser- cycles are offsetting, so SVOL (and SNONVOL) are entered
vice-sector employment, higher unionization, and higher in the model alternatively as states’ shares of employment in
shares of long-term unemployment are associated with the five most volatile and least volatile industries. Location
lower employment volatility. Buch and Schlotter (2013) quotients are also used as an alternative measure of states’
concluded that volatility of employment is not linked to relative reliance on volatile and nonvolatile industries.
trade openness, at least in most German states. The excep- LQNVOL is the location quotient for employment in non-
tions are states hosting international harbors. Spatial volatile industries. LQNVOL measures the concentration of
impacts within national regions are also possible (Komarek nonvolatile employment in a state compared with nonvola-
& Loveridge, 2013; Overman & Puga, 2002). tile industry employment in the nation. LQVOL is the
4 Economic Development Quarterly 00(0)

location quotient of employment in volatile industries for a Table 1.  Descriptions and Sources of Variables.
state relative to the nation’s employment in volatile indus- Variable Description Sourcea
tries. OPENNESS, state exports as a percentage of state
gross domestic product, measures state export exposure. Dependent variable
 EMPGROW The percentage change in state 1
The observed data come from the 50 U.S. states over the
wage and salary employment from
years 2000 to 2013, a total of 700 observations. Table 1 pro- previous year, 2000 to 2013
vides a brief description of the variables used in the model. Independent variables
Justification for their inclusion and detailed information are  HHI Annual Herfindahl–Hirschman Index by 1
provided below. state from 2000 to 2013. Calculated
using total full-time and part-time
The HHI is a standard way of comparing industrial con- employment in 92 NAICS industries
centration across industries. HHI is calculated by summing  SNONVOL A state’s percentage of total full-time 1
the squared percentage market shares of all firms in an indus- and part-time employment in
try as in the equation below: nonvolatile industries as measured
by five industries with the lowest
n employment coefficients of variation
HHI = ∑s .
i =1
2
i
 SVOL
from 2000 to 2013
A state’s percentage of total full-time 1
and part-time employment in
volatile industries as measured by
In this equation, s is the market share of firm I and n is the
the five industries with the highest
number of firms in the industry. employment coefficients of variation
The squaring accentuates the effects of firms with particu- from 2000 to 2013
larly large market shares. The range of possible HHI values  LQNVOL State’s location quotient, state 1
is from near 0 to 10,000. A firm with a 100% market share employment nonvolatile industries
relative to national employment
(pure monopoly) would have a HHI of 10,000. As an indus- in same using five industries with
try becomes less concentrated (more competitive), its HHI lowest employment coefficients of
moves toward zero. In this case, the HHI is modified to mea- variation from 2000 to 2013
sure concentration across industries. State HHI values were  LQVOL State’s location quotient, state 1
employment volatile industries
calculated using U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis total relative to national employment
full-time and part-time employment by 92 North American in same using five industries with
Industry Classification System (NAICS) industries. In the highest employment coefficients of
modified version, s represents the share of a state’s employ- variation from 2000 to 2013
 OPENNESS Export openness, measured as the 2
ment in industry i and n is the total number of industries, 92 percentage of exports to GDP by
in this case. The more concentrated a state’s employment in state from 2000 to 2013
a few sectors, the higher its HHI.  RPCGDP Real per capita GDP (2009 U.S. 1
The shares of volatile (SVOL) and nonvolatile dollars) by state from 2000 to 2013
(SNONVOL) industries are calculated as follows. First,  POPGROW State population growth from previous 4
year expressed in percentage terms
national-level data on wage and salary employment in 20  LFPRCH2 Percentage change in the labor force 5
U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis–reported NAICS sectors participation rate from previous year,
for 2000 to 2013 were gathered. Second, the mean and stan- both sexes, squared
dard deviation of 2000-2013 annual employment in each  UNEMPLAG State unemployment rate lagged 1 year 5
sector was calculated. Third, coefficients of variation (stan-  UNION Percentage of employed persons who 3
are union members, by state
dard deviation divided by mean) were calculated for each  Y2000-Y2013 Dummy variables to identify year of  
industry. Finally, industries were sorted by their employment observation, Y2000 is the base year
coefficients of variation. The five most volatile and five least
Note. NAICS = North American Industry Classification System.
volatile industries are listed in Table 2. a
1. Bureau of Economic Analysis (2013): Regional economic accounts (retrieved from
The SVOL and the SNONVOL variables provide infor- http://www.bea.gov). 2. U.S. Department of Commerce (2013): International trade
mation that the HHI is unable to provide. For example, even administration (retrieved from http://tse.export.gov). 3. Bureau of Labor Statistics
(2013): Economic news release (retrieved from www.bls.gov). 4. U.S. Census Bureau:
if a state relies fairly heavily on employment in volatile Table 1—Intercensal estimates of the resident population for the United States,
industries the HHI could still be small. The HHI provides regions, states, and Puerto Rico: April 1, 2000 to July 1, 2010 and Table 1—Annual
estimates of the resident population for the United States, regions, states, and
insight in the concentration of employment across broad Puerto Rico: April 1, 2010 to July 1, 2014. 5. Bureau of Labor Statistics—Local area
industries, but it does not help to distinguish whether or not unemployment statistics, states, and selected areas: Employment status of the civilian
noninstitutional population, 1976-2015.
these industries are volatile. Thus, including the SVOL,
SNONVOL, and HHI in the same model should not create
problems. Variance inflation factors (VIFs) are calculated at growth in employment for 10 states with the highest propor-
the estimation stage to verify this. Figure 2 indicates average tion of employment with volatile industries and nonvolatile
Pallares and Adkisson 5

Table 2.  NAICS Sector Volatility Rank.

Rank BEA code Most volatile CV BEA code Least volatile CV


1 200 Mining 0.168 600 Wholesale trade 0.028
2 500 Manufacturing 0.131 1000 Finance and insurance 0.025
3 400 Construction 0.118 2000 Government and government enterprises 0.022
4 900 Information 0.104 1900 Other services (except public administration) 0.0220
5 1500 Educational services 0.101 700 Retail trade 0.022

Note. BEA = U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis; NAICS = North American Industry Classification System; CV = coefficient of variation. Source: Authors’
calculations using data from BEA (2013): Regional economic accounts (retrieved from http://www.bea.gov).

Figure 2.  Average growth in employment for top 10 states with highest volatile/nonvolatile share in employment.
Note. From authors’ calculations with data from Bureau of Economic Analysis, regional accounts, SA4, personal income and employment by major
component, wage and salary employment.

industries. Figure 2 shows that states more reliant on volatile SVOL and SNONVOL. The location quotients norm state
industries tend to have more intense movements in their employment to a national standard, while the share measures
employment growth rates when compared with states that norm to a state’s total employment in all industries. Using
are more reliant on nonvolatile industries. The influence of them as alternative measures helps check the robustness of
the business cycle on both groups is also evident. the model estimated below.
The location quotient of industries in volatile (LQVOL) The variables SVOL, SNONVOL, LQVOL, LQNVOL,
and nonvolatile (LQNVOL) industries are used as alternative HHI, and OPENNESS are the variables of primary interest in
measures of concentration in volatile or nonvolatile sectors this work. In particular, a state that is heavily reliant on vola-
for the states. LQs are calculated as follows: tile, a concentrated few, or export industries may be subject
to external economic shocks (volatility) than would a more
E Xi EYi evenly diversified state. Several control variables are
ETi LQNVOL ETi , included to account for other possible influences on employ-
=
LQVOLXi = Yi
E Xb EYb ment growth.
ETi ETi The variable RPCGDP is included to control for the over-
all levels of state economic development. Hints in the litera-
where E = employment, X = top 5 volatile industries as iden- ture and an initial examination of the data suggested a
tified in Table 2, Y = top 5 nonvolatile industries as identified nonlinear relationship between RPCGDP and EMPGROW,
in Table 2, T = total employment, i = state, and b = national. so a squared term of RPCGDP was initially calculated in the
A location quotient equal to 1 indicates that state employ- estimation; although, after the estimation it was statistically
ment in the top five volatile or nonvolatile industries is the insignificant and was therefore omitted from the models.
exact percentage of the nation’s employment in those indus- Hypothetically, a higher level of development, proxied by
tries. Values greater than or less than 1 mean that the state has RPCGDP, would invite higher employment growth.
relatively higher or lower (respectively) employment in the Several variables are included to control for factors that
industry (volatile or nonvolatile) than the nation. The LQVOL could influence a state’s employment growth. The popula-
and the LQNVOL provide slightly different information than tion growth from the previous year (POPGROW) is expected
6 Economic Development Quarterly 00(0)

to relate positively with EMPGROW. A change in labor force Table 3.  Descriptive Statistics, Continuous Variables.
participation rate could also be influential. Other things equal
Mean Minimum Maximum
a growing labor force participation rate affects the availabil-
ity of workers for hire and thus one might expect a positive EMPGROW 0.47 −8.9 8.2
relationship with employment growth (EMPGROW). Early HHI 374.43 298.00 561.52
analysis indicated a possible nonlinear relationship, so the SVOL 19.58 10.03 29.71
percentage change in labor force participation is entered in LQVOL 1.01 0.36 1.28
squared form (LFPRCH2). VIFs and correlation coefficients SNONVOL 42.26 32.01 51.18
(included in the appendix) are calculated at the estimation LQNONVOL 1.02 0.81 1.22
stage to verify that there is no substantial presence of multi- OPENNESS 6.80 0.76 25.64
collinearity among the variables. Similarly, a high level of RPCGDP 45,654 28,956 71,047
POPGROW 1.05 −5.99 11.58
unemployment in the previous period suggests slack in the
LFPRCH2 1.07 0 15.51
labor market that could affect a state’s capacity for increas-
UNEMPLAG 5.73 2.3 13.7
ing employment, so the unemployment rate is entered with a
UNION 11.3 2.3 26.1
1-year lag (UNEMPLAG). In earlier iterations, median age
and educational attainment were included to account for Note. EMPGROW = The percentage change in state wage and salary
variation in labor characteristics; however, their contribution employment from previous year, 2000 to 2013; HHI = Herfindahl–
Hirschman Index; SNONVOL = the percentage of state employment
was negligible so they were excluded from the final model.
in nonvolatile industries; SVOL = the percentage of state employment
Finally, UNION is included as a proxy for flexibility in in volatile industries; LQNVOL = location quotient for employment
the labor market and perhaps reflects state policy attitudes in nonvolatile industries; LQVOL = location quotient of employment
toward labor. The literature suggests that the labor policy in volatile industries for a state relative to the nation’s employment in
volatile industries; OPENNESS = state exports as a percentage of state
environment can affect employment, although the evidence gross domestic product; RPCGDP = real per capita gross domestic
is mixed. A high value of UNION suggests that a state’s poli- product; POPGROW = state population growth from previous year;
cies are more sympathetic to labor concerns (more regula- LFPRCH2 = percentage change in the labor force participation rate from
tion) and/or that the state’s labor market might be relatively previous year, both sexes, squared; UNEMPLAG = state unemployment
rate lagged 1 year; UNION = percentage of employed persons who are
inflexible. The expectation is that, other things being equal, a union members, by state.
higher percentage of union membership will have a con-
straining, or at least stabilizing, effect on employment.
Annual dummy variables are included to account for national The second model is expressed in the equation below and
influences on state growth. As mentioned above, the period it uses employment location quotients on volatile and non-
under study includes two recessionary periods. The results on volatile industries to explain the variation in employment
the annual dummies are expected to mirror the national business growth.
cycle. Similarly, the model is estimated using cross-section Model 2:
fixed effects to account for state-specific but unobserved phe-
nomena to include possible spatial effects. Table 3 provides EMPGROWit = ϕ1HHI it + ϕ2 LQNVOLit + ϕ3 LQVOLit
descriptive statistics of the continuous variables. +ϕ4OPENNESSit + ϕ5 RPCGDPit + ϕ6 POPGROWit
+ϕ7 LFPRCH 2it + ϕ8UNEMPLAGit + ϕ9UNIONREPIT
Model +ϕ10YEAR2001 +  + ϕ22YEAR2013 + uit .
The model is designed to explain state-by-state variation in
annual employment growth rates. The intention is to ask Method
whether state industrial concentration, relative reliance on Initial diagnostics indicated serially correlated errors over
volatile or nonvolatile industrial sectors, and/or export expo- more than one lagged period. The model was estimated
sure has statistically detectable relationships with annual using the Park–Kmenta method (Kmenta, 1986) as pro-
employment growth and, if so, to reveal the direction of the grammed in Shazam Econometrics Software (Whistler,
influence. The first model is expressed in the equation below. White, Wong, & Bates, 2004). This is a generalized least
Model 1 uses the share of volatile and nonvolatile industries squares method that corrects for both cross-sectional het-
to explain the variation of employment growth. The sub- eroscedasticity and time-wise autoregression. In this case,
scripts identify statei and timet. it is thought to be a better method than making a simple
Model 1: AR(1) correction. Year dummy variables are included to
EMPGROWit = β1HHI it + β 2 SNONVOLit + β3 SVOLit account for national-level influences. The model is esti-
mated twice, once using the five most and least volatile
+ β 4OPENNESSit + β5 RPCGDPit + β 6 POPGROWit
industries for SVOL and SNONVOL, and once with
+ β 7 LFPRCH 2it + β8UNEMPLAGit + β9UNIONREPIT employment location quotients in the five most and least
+ β10YEAR2001 +  + β 22YEAR2013 + eit . volatile industries (LQVOL and LQNVOL). Both model
Pallares and Adkisson 7

Table 4.  Estimation Results.

First model coefficient (t- Second model coefficient (t-


ratio), VIF ratio), VIF
HHI 0.018 (3.83)***, 1.96 0.019 (4.47)***, 1.81
SVOL −0.161 (−2.65)***, 2.50 —
SNONVOL −0.527 (−7.25)***, 1.29 —
LQVOL — 0.217 (0.27), 2.04
LQNVOL — −12.301 (−5.91)***, 1.40
OPENNESS 0.118 (5.31)***, 1.38 0.133 (5.79)***, 1.40
RPCGDP 0.916 × 10−04 (4.72)***, 1.61 0.842 × 10−04 (4.27)***, 1.61
POPGROW 0.458 (7.96)***, 2.27 0.458 (7.84)***, 2.17
LFPRCH2 −0.057 (−4.01)***, 1.09 −0.060 (−4.12)***, 1.09
UNEMPLAG 0.188 (4.89)***, 3.57 0.264 (6.67)***, 3.44
UNION −0.055 (−2.25)**, 1.78 −0.043 (−1.74)*, 1.92
R2 .8735 .8818

Note. VIF = Variance inflation factor; HHI = Herfindahl–Hirschman Index; SNONVOL = the percentage of state employment in nonvolatile industries;
SVOL = the percentage of state employment in volatile industries; LQNVOL = location quotient for employment in nonvolatile industries; LQVOL =
location quotient of employment in volatile industries for a state relative to the nation’s employment in volatile industries. OPENNESS = state exports as
a percentage of state gross domestic product; RPCGDP = real per capita gross domestic product; POPGROW = state population growth from previous
year; LFPRCH2 = percentage change in the labor force participation rate from previous year, both sexes, squared; UNEMPLAG = state unemployment
rate lagged 1 year; UNION = percentage of employed persons who are union members, by state; EMPGROW = percentage change in state wage and
salary employment from previous year, 2000 to 2013. Dependent variable = EMPGROW; pooled data, 50 states, 2000-2013, n = 700, df = 626, with
cross-section and time fixed effects.
*Indicates statistical significance with at least 90% confidence. **Indicates statistical significance with at least 95% confidence. ***Indicates statistical
significance with at least 99% confidence.

specifications tell the same story. Specific interpretations 0.527 percentage point decrease in annual employment
are based on the first model. growth. By comparing the coefficients of SVOL and
SNONVOL, the results suggest that concentration in both
volatile and nonvolatile industries reduced employment
Results growth, but that SNONVOL had a greater negative impact
The first four results reported in Table 4 provide the esti- on employment growth than SVOL.
mated relationships for the primary variables of interest, The relationship between export openness (OPENNESS)
HHI, SNONVOL, SVOL, and OPENNESS. The four vari- and employment growth (EMPGROW) is statistically detect-
ables, HHI, SVOL, SNONVOL and OPENNESS, show sta- able. The sign and size of the coefficient suggest that a state’s
tistically detectable relationships with EMPGROW. HHI employment growth rate would increase slightly if it
exhibited a positive relationship to employment growth, sug- increased its export exposure. By the five-industry estimate,
gesting that the concentration of state employment in a few a one percentage point increase in export share relates to a
industries (regardless of whether these industries are volatile 0.118 percentage point increase in employment growth. The
or nonvolatile) tended to increase employment growth. results suggest that exports add a dynamic aspect to a state’s
The sign on the estimated coefficient for SVOL suggests economy.
that reliance employment on volatile industries had a nega- All control variables had detectable influences that pro-
tive influence on EMPGROW. The coefficient suggests that vide insights into employment growth. The estimated coef-
a one percentage point increase in the share of state employ- ficient on real per capita gross domestic product (RPCGDP)
ment in volatile industries reduced employment growth by is positive and statistically significant. As one might expect,
0.16 percentage point. This coefficient indicates that concen- higher income invites higher rates of employment growth.
tration in employment on volatile industries tended to reduce Demographic and labor force changes seem to have some
employment growth. short-term influence on employment growth. Population
The share of nonvolatile industries (SNONVOL) had a growth (POPGROW) showed a positive and statistically
negative relationship with the dependent variable. This detectable relationship with EMPGROW. A one percentage
implies that, by itself, a purposeful policy of promoting point increase in population is associated with a 0.458 per-
employment in nonvolatile industries will have a negative centage point increase in employment, though a decrease in
impact on state employment growth as suggested by Malizia the share of the population that is employed. The relationship
and Ke (1993). A one percentage point increase in a state’s between EMPGROW and the change in labor force partici-
share of employment in nonvolatile industries relates to a pation is parabolic and statistically detectable, this time with
8 Economic Development Quarterly 00(0)

Figure 3.  Yearly dummy values, share model.


Note. Omitted year is 2000.

a maximum value of EMPGROW at LFPRCH2 = zero. In The results on the second model imitate the results of the first
this model, as the labor force participation rate grows, state model in terms of hypothesized sign and statistical relevance
employment growth rates decrease at an increasing rate. This in all instances except on the LQNVOL, which carries no
finding suggests that, other things equal, increasing the labor statistically detectable relation to EMPGROW. Besides this,
force participation alone may be insufficient to support to test for robustness, the models were reestimated dropping
employment growth. the HHI on both, which had neither significant difference in
As expected, the one-period lagged unemployment rate the signs of the coefficients nor the statistical influence of the
(UNEMPLAG) showed a positive and statistically detectable variables. The VIFs have values that are well below five,
relationship with employment growth. High unemployment in indicating that multicollinearity is minimal.
the previous year seemed to help drive current-year employ-
ment growth. The model predicts that a one percentage point
Discussion and Conclusions
increase in the previous year’s unemployment rate will
increase current-year employment growth by 0.188 percent- This study opened by asking whether a lack of diversity in
age point. As discussed above, unemployment may represent a employment, proxied by concentration in volatile industries,
readily available workforce to support employment growth. reliance on exports, and general industrial concentration,
Union membership (UNION) had a negative and statisti- affects employment growth. Based on the first model analy-
cally detectable relationship with EMPGROW. As union sis described above, the answer is yes, though perhaps in
membership increases, employment growth decreases. One unexpected ways. General industrial concentration (HHI) is
interpretation of this result is that unionization constrains the positively related to employment growth. Employment
labor market and thus retards employment growth. Another intensity in volatile industries (SVOL) seemed to have a neg-
possible interpretation is that unions bring stability to state ative influence on employment growth. Employment inten-
employment by making it harder to hire and fire employees. sity in nonvolatile industries (SNONVOL) also seems to
The model predicts that a one percentage point increase in retard employment growth somewhat. Export intensity
union membership relates to a 0.055 percentage point (OPENNESS) has a slightly positive impact on employment
decrease in state employment growth; thus, the impact on growth. Given these results, economic development policies
employment growth, while detectable, is small. aimed specifically at attracting stable industries may be
The results on the annual dummy variables are omitted counterproductive if the goal is high rates of employment
from Table 4. As expected, the results mirror the national growth. On the other hand, to focus on either avoiding or
business cycle. The coefficients are statistically significant in attracting volatile industries would likely have a small or
all 13 years. The national business cycle has important neutral impact on employment growth. Increasing employ-
impacts on state employment growth. Figure 3 provides a ment in export industries may provide a small boost to
graphical depiction of the annual intercept changes revealed employment growth.
by the year dummy variable estimates. Population growth (POPGROW) relates positively to
Finally, the second model incorporates location quotients employment growth as does the lagged value of unemploy-
in the volatile and nonvolatile industries to measure the reli- ment (UNEMPLAG). Together these findings hint that, for
ance in employment on those industries relative to the nation. employment to grow, there needs to be a supply of new and
Pallares and Adkisson 9

resident workers available to take advantage of employment indicated a statistically detectably negative relationship
opportunities when they arise. Conversely, growth in labor with employment growth, LQVOL, the location quotient
force participation (LFPRCH2) is negatively related to for volatile industries, lacks statistical influence, some-
employment growth, suggesting that relying solely on new what clouding the conclusion above that employment
entrants to the labor force to fill new jobs constrains employ- intensity in volatile industries (SVOL) has a negative
ment growth. Union membership (UNION) put a slight influence on employment growth. The fact that no other
damper on state employment growth. conclusions changed suggests the findings on the other
As a robustness check, the second model replaces variables to be robust.
industry shares, SVOL and SNONVOL, with LQVOL and Finally, the national business cycle (measured using year
LQNVOL, alternative measures of state reliance on either dummy variables) has a strong influence on state employ-
volatile or nonvolatile industries. The interpretations ment growth. This suggests that states will be limited in their
immediately above hold with one exception. Where ability to maintain an employment growth trend that runs
SVOL, the share of employment in volatile industries, counter to national trends.

Appendix
Table A1.  Correlation Coefficients.
EMPGROW HHI SVOL5 SNVOL5 LQVOL5 LQNVOL5 OPENNESS RPCGDP POPGROW LFPRCH2 UNEMPLAG UNION

EMPGROW 1.00  
HHI 0.07 1.00  
SVOL5 −0.01 −0.62 1.00  
SNVOL5 0.01 0.24 −0.31 1.00  
LQVOL5 −0.09 −0.56 0.81 −0.23 1.00  
LQNVOL5 0.11 0.21 −0.36 0.89 −0.29 1.00  
OPENNESS 0.03 −0.19 0.21 −0.16 0.36 −0.17 1.00  
RPCGDP 0.11 0.18 −0.22 −0.11 −0.23 −0.09 −0.06 1.00  
POPGROW 0.37 0.18 0.01 −0.09 −0.16 0.02 −0.09 0.02 1.00  
LFPRCH2 −0.21 0.11 −0.08 −0.03 −0.02 0.00 0.09 −0.08 −0.03 1.00  
UNEMP LAG −0.04 0.18 −0.29 −0.13 −0.01 −0.18 0.33 −0.04 −0.26 0.19 1.00  
UNION −0.08 0.02 −0.15 −0.17 −0.28 −0.25 −0.07 0.44 −0.16 −0.06 0.06 1.00

Declaration of Conflicting Interests missing. Rather than eliminate states based on this small
amount of missing data, estimated values based on linear
The authors declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect
extrapolations from available data were entered. Any bias
to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.
caused by this choice should be insignificant. This affeccts the
variables EMPGROW, LQVOL, LQNVOL, HHI, SVOL, and
Funding SNONVOL.
The authors received no financial support for the research, author-
ship, and/or publication of this article.
References
Notes Aizenman, J., & Marion, N. (1999). Volatility and investment:
Interpreting evidence from developing countries. Economica,
1. In this study, the focus is on wage and salary employment.
66, 157-1179.
According to the Bureau of Economic Analysis, wage and sal-
Anderson, L., Clogston, F., Erekat, D., Garmise, S., Ghosh, S.,
ary employment measures the average annual number of full-
Girdwood, C., & Thorstensen, L. (2010, March). Creating
time and part-time jobs in each area by place of work. All jobs
quality jobs: Transforming the economic development land-
for which wages and salaries are paid are counted. Although scape. Washington, DC: International Economic Development
compensation paid to jurors, expert legal witnesses, prison- Council.
ers, and justices of the peace (for marriage fees) is counted Attaran, M. (1986). Industrial diversity and economic performance
in wages and salaries, these activities are not counted as jobs in US areas. Annals of Regional Science, 20(2), 44-54.
in wage and salary employment. Corporate directorships are Baldwin, J. R., & Brown, W. M. (2004). Regional manufacturing
counted as self-employment. employment volatility in Canada: The effects of specialization
2. With 14 years, 20 industries, and 50 states there are potentially and trade. Papers in Regional Science, 83, 519-541.
14,000 individual observations of wage and salary employ- Bausman, K., & Goe, W. R. (2004). An examination of the link
ment. Of the 14,000 possible, 58 variable observations were between employment volatility and the spatial distribution
10 Economic Development Quarterly 00(0)

of property crime rates. American Journal of Economics and Mayer, W. J., Wang, H. C., Egginton, J. F., & Flint, H. S. (2012).
Sociology, 63, 665-696. The impact of revenue diversification on expected revenue and
Bernanke, B. S. (2004). The great moderation. In E. F. Koenig, R. volatility for nonprofit organizations. Nonprofit and Voluntary
Leeson, & G. A. Kahn (Eds.), The Taylor Rule and the trans- Sector Quarterly, 43, 374-392.
formation of monetary policy (pp. 145-162). Stanford, CA: Mobarak, A. M. (2005). Democracy, volatility, and economic
Hoover Institution Press. development. Review of Economics and Statistics, 87, 348-361.
Blanchard, O. J. (1997). Labor-market flexibility and aggregate Monchuk, D. C., Miranowski, J. A., Hayes, D. J., & Babcock, B.
employment volatility: A comment. Carnegie-Rochester A. (2007). An analysis of regional economic growth in the US
Conference Series on Public Policy, 46, 229-239. Midwest. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy, 29, 17-39.
Bradshaw, T. K., & Blakely, E. J. (1999). What are “third-wave” Naylor, R. L., & Falcon, W. P. (2010). Food security in an era of
state economic development efforts? From incentives to indus- economic volatility. Population and Development Review, 36,
trial policy. Economic Development Quarterly, 13, 229-244. 693-723.
Buch, C. M., & Schlotter, M. (2013). Regional origins of employ- Ocegueda, J. M., Escamilla, A., & Mungaray, A. (2011). Estructura
ment volatility: Evidence from German states. Empirica, 40, económica y tasa de crecimiento en la frontera norte de México.
1-19. Problemas del Desarrollo [Economic structure and the rate of
Burns, A. F. (1969). Progress towards economic stability. In The growth along Mexico’s northern border], 42(164), 71-97.
business cycle in a changing world (chap 3; pp. 101-128). Overman, H. G., & Puga, D. (2002). Unemployment clusters across
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Europe’s regions and countries. Economic Policy, 17, 115-148.
(Reprinted from American Economic Review, 1960, Vol. 50, Partridge, M. D., & Rickman, D. S. (1996). The role of industry
pp. 1-19.) structure, costs, and economic spillovers in determining state
Cabrales, A., & Hopenhayn, H. A. (1997). Labor-market flexibil- employment growth rates. Review of Regional Studies, 26, 235.
ity and aggregate employment volatility. Carnegie-Rochester Peach, J., & Starbuck, C. M. (2011). Oil and gas production and
Conference Series on Public Policy, 46, 189-228. economic growth in New Mexico. Journal of Economic Issues,
Carlino, G. A., & Mills, E. S. (1987). The determinants of county 45, 511-526.
growth. Journal of Regional Science, 27, 39-54. Reed, W. R. (2009). The determinants of US state economic growth:
Chen, T. J. (2014). The impact of diversification on risk-taking A less extreme bounds analysis. Economic Inquiry, 47, 685-700.
in the financial holding companies. Academy of Management Reese, L. A. (2014). The alchemy of local economic development.
Proceedings, 2014(1), 11320. Economic Development Quarterly, 28, 206-219.
Conroy, M. E. (1975). The concept and measurement of regional Scordis, N. A. (2000). Integrated risk management: Techniques and
industrial diversification. Southern Economic Journal, 41, strategies for reducing risk. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 67, 667.
492-505. Sparks, E. (2013, August). Top trends in state economic devel-
Dammon, R. M., Zhang, H. H., & Spatt, C. S. (2001). Diversification opment (National Governors Association Policy Paper).
and capital gains taxes with multiple risky assets. Retrieved from Washington, DC: National Governors Association.
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=281663 Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (2003, August 28-30). Has the busi-
Felix, A. (2012). Industrial diversity, growth, and volatility in the ness cycle changed? Evidence and explanations. Paper pre-
seven states of the Tenth District. Economic Review—Federal sented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City symposium
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 97(4), 55-77. on Monetary Policy and Uncertainty: Adapting to a Changing
Grennes, T., Guerron-Quintana, P., & Leblebicioglu, A. (2010). Economy, Jackson Hole, Wyoming.
Economic development and volatility among the states. Warnock, M. V. C., & Warnock, F. E. (2000, August). The declin-
Economics Bulletin, 30, 1963-1976. ing volatility of US employment: Was Arthur Burns right?
Kemeny, T., & Storper, M. (2015). Is specialization good for regional (International Finance Discussion Paper No. 677). Washington,
economic development? Regional Studies, 49, 1003-1018. DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Kenen, P. B., & Rodrik, D. (1986). Measuring and analyzing the Whistler, D., White, K. J., Wong, S. D., & Bates, D. (2004).
effects of short-term volatility in real exchange rates. Review of SHAZAM Econometrics Software, User’s reference man-
Economics and Statistics, 68, 311-315. ual (Version 10). Vancouver, British Columbia, Canada:
Kmenta, J. (1986). Elements of econometrics. New York, NY: Northwest Econometrics.
Macmillan.
Komarek, T. M., & Loveridge, S. (2013). Too big? Too small? Just Author Biographies
right? An empirical perspective on local firm size distribution
Francisco J. Pallares is an associate professor of economics at
and economic growth in US counties and high-poverty rural
Austin Community College. He earned his Doctor of Economic
regions. Economic Development Quarterly, 28, 28-41.
Development degree from New Mexico State University and his
Koren, M., & Tenreyro, S. (2007). Volatility and development.
Master of Science degree in economics from the University of
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 243-287.
Texas, El Paso.
Kort, J. R. (1981). Regional economic instability and industrial
diversification in the US. Land Economics, 57, 596-608. Richard V. Adkisson is a professor of economics and the Garrey
Malizia, E. E., & Ke, S. (1993). The influence of economic diversity E. and Katherine T. Carruthers Endowed Chair in Economic
on unemployment and stability. Journal of Regional Science, Development at New Mexico State University. He earned his PhD
33, 221-235. in economics at the University of Nebraska, Lincoln.

You might also like