Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 18

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/253844375

What is an ”optimal” tax system?

Article  in  National Tax Journal · March 1996


DOI: 10.1086/NTJ41789190

CITATIONS READS
129 4,218

1 author:

James Alm
Tulane University
260 PUBLICATIONS   12,011 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

40 years of Tax Evasion Games: a Meta-Analysis View project

All content following this page was uploaded by James Alm on 23 April 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

SYMPOSIUM ON INCOME TAX COMPLEXITY AND ENFORCEMENT

WHAT IS AN “OPTIMAL”
TAX SYSTEM?
*
JAMES ALM

Abstract - A central issue in public enhance our understanding of appropri-


economics is the appropriate design of a ate tax policy in several ways: it can
tax system. This paper argues that illuminate and quantify with a common
previous attempts to derive an “optimal yardstick the various trade-offs that
tax system” are largely irrelevant to taxes necessarily create, it can highlight
practical tax design, because they the areas that require additional
typically ignore a range of consider- research, and it can provide specific
ations reflecting fiscal and societal guidelines that tax policies should take
institutions that are essential elements in particular country circumstances,
in the normative and positive analysis of guidelines that seem often likely to be
taxation. In particular, the standard significantly different than those that
optimal taxation methodology often emerge from the optimal taxation
ignores the equity and efficiency effects approach.
that arise because taxes must be
collected, at some cost both to the tax
agency and the taxpayer, and this
collection must be enforced, again at
some cost to the agency and the INTRODUCTION
individual. However, the paper also
argues that there are ways in which A central issue in public economics is
many of these relevant institutional the appropriate design of a tax system.
features can be incorporated into a Such a system is usually viewed as
framework more general— but also balancing the various desirable at-
more cumbersome, at least in its most tributes of taxation: taxes must be
general form —than that characteristic raised (revenue-yield) in a way that
of the optimal taxation methodology. treats individuals fairly (equity), that
Such a framework will never be able to minimizes interference in economic
capture all of the incredible complexity decisions (efficiency), and that does not
that characterizes the real world and impose undue costs on taxpayers or tax
that must be considered in the actual administrators (simplicity).
design and reform of tax systems.
However, the suggested framework can One way in which at least some of these
attributes have been analyzed is in an
area of research that is commonly
*
Department of Economics, University of Colorado at Boulder, known as “optimal taxation.” This is an
Boulder, CO 80309-0256. explicitly normative approach to tax

117
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 1

analysis that is based on standard tools ways in which many of these relevant
of welfare economics, as applied in a institutional features can be incorpo-
world when the first-best allocation of rated into a framework more general—
resources and distribution of income but also more cumbersome, at least in
cannot be achieved. There have been its most general form—than that
many insights from this literature characteristic of the optimal taxation
(Auerbach, 1985; Stern, 1987). How- methodology. Such a framework will
ever, even its adherents would, I believe, never be able to capture all of the
admit that the practical applicability of incredible complexity that characterizes
its basic theorems has been remarkably the real world and that must be
limited to date. Indeed, there often considered in the actual design and
seems a schism, if not an animosity, reform of tax systems. However, I
between those who work on the believe that the suggested framework
rarefied heights of optimal tax theory can enhance our understanding of
and those who toil in the trenches of appropriate tax policy by illuminating
practical tax design. and quantifying with a common
yardstick the various trade-offs that
In this paper, I argue that optimal taxes necessarily create, by highlighting
taxation as it has been practiced is in the areas that require additional
fact largely irrelevant to practical tax research, and by providing specific
design, because it typically ignores a guidelines that tax design and tax
range of considerations reflecting fiscal reform should take in particular
and societal institutions that are country circumstances, all in a more
essential elements in the normative and comprehensive manner than previously
positive analysis of taxation. In particu- undertaken. I also believe that the tax
lar, the standard optimal taxation guidelines that emerge from this
methodology often ignores the equity framework will often be significantly
and efficiency effects that arise because different than those that emerge from
taxes must be collected, at some cost the optimal taxation approach. It is
both to the tax agency and the taxpayer, toward the establishment of this
and this collection must be enforced, research framework that this paper is
again at some cost to the agency and largely addressed.
the individual. Because most analyses in
the optimal taxation tradition ignore In the next section, I discuss the
these features, their basic policy standard optimal taxation methodology
prescriptions are unlikely to lead to an and present several of its more widely
improvement in welfare, when com- known results. The following sections
pared to those policy rules derived from outline some of the important consider-
a less formal but more realistic perspec- ations that have been largely ignored by
tive; in fact, they are even unlikely to be this methodology and also discuss
implemented or to be taken as serious recent research on these considerations.
guides to policy. Admittedly, this I then present a suggestion for research
argument is not new (Slemrod, 1990; that systematically incorporates the
Bird, 1992). It is also somewhat various institutional features. In the
overstated, especially given some recent final section, I speculate on the ways in
work in the optimal taxation methodol- which the standard optimal tax results
ogy that examines some of these issues. seem likely to be modified by these
Nevertheless, I also argue that there are considerations.

118
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

SYMPOSIUM ON INCOME TAX COMPLEXITY AND ENFORCEMENT

THE OPTIMAL TAX APPROACH implying marginal tax rates of 100


percent. However, on efficiency
The standard approach to optimal grounds, marginal tax rates should be
taxation is based on several method- lower the more responsive are individu-
ological assumptions: the government is als in their labor decisions, the smaller is
required to raise a specified amount of the spread in the skills of the individuals,
revenues; it is limited in the types of tax the less concerned with equality is
instruments that it has available to it, society, and the lower is the amount of
such as only commodity taxes, only revenue that government must collect.
income taxes, or both types; its deci- In fact, the marginal tax rate on the
sions must be consistent with individual single richest individual should be zero.
and firm optimization; and it makes its
choices in order to maximize a “social Optimal Tax Mix
welfare function,” which indicates the
value that society places on the welfare On efficiency grounds, the optimal tax
of different individuals. mix requires simply a lump-sum income
tax, and commodity taxes are not used.
The major results that have been derived On equity grounds, both income and
from this framework can be classified 2
commodity taxes should be used in
according to the types of tax instru- general; however, under some restrictive
ments that the government can select conditions, the optimal form of com-
(see Auerbach [1985] and Stern [1987] modity
2 tax rates that are imposed in the
for a detailed discussion of these presence of an optimal income tax
results), as illustrated in the following requires that the commodity tax rates be
subsections. uniform, so that taxation of commodi-
ties at different rates is not optimal and
Optimal Commodity Taxes only the optimal income tax is used.

On efficiency grounds, commodity tax The framework discussed in the previous


rates should be chosen to achieve equal subsections is, of course, a highly
proportional reductions in the (compen- stylized one that by necessity ignores a
sated) demands for all commodities, so number of relevant considerations. Still,
that goods with more elastic demands it is a useful framework, at least in part
1
should be taxed at lower rates (the because it forces the analyst to make
“Ramsey Rule”). However, on equity explicit the trade-off between equity (via
grounds, goods consumed more heavily the social welfare function) and effi-
by those with lower income (or, more ciency (via an array of individual and
generally,
1 by those whose welfare is firm behavioral effects) in the choice of
weighted more heavily by society) taxes.
should be taxed at lower rates.
For example, consider optimal commod-
Optimal Income Taxes ity taxes. Commodities with more
inelastic demands should be taxed more
On equity grounds, income taxes should heavily in order to reduce the excess
be higher on those with greater income; burden of taxation; however, if these
indeed, under some special conditions, goods are consumed predominantly by
income taxes should be chosen to those with lower incomes, then equity
equalize after-tax incomes, thereby concerns argue for lower tax rates.

119
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 1

Similarly, optimal income taxes must complicated tax forms, seeking profes-
balance the equity gains that higher sional advice, filling out returns, and the
marginal tax rates allow with the like are legion and legendary.
efficiency losses that higher tax rates
generate. In general, the optimal tax Furthermore, even casual economic
rules involve balancing these equity and analysis clearly indicates that we should
efficiency considerations. 3
always expect paying taxes to imply
incurring costs. No one likes the loss of
However, there is little dispute that the income from taxes, and people will
standard optimal framework ignores, or clearly take actions to avoid (or reduce)
at least does not adequately consider, a their liability. It is a standard result in
number of important considerations in economics that agents will increase their
the design of taxes. In particular, these actions up to the point where the
optimal tax rules depend primarily upon marginal benefits of their actions—in
the preferences of the individuals (as this case, the reduced taxes—equals the
well as upon the tax instruments marginal costs—or the compliance
available to government). These rules costs—of the actions. On the margin,
neither consider the costs imposed upon then, the costs of paying taxes should
the taxpayer and the government of be approximated by the tax savings
collecting the taxes, nor do they from the array of legal tax avoidance
consider the costs imposed on the schemes that taxpayers have pursued,
respective agents of enforcing this the accuracy of the approximation
collection. Now if it can be argued that depending largely upon the way in
these considerations are sometimes which the marginal costs of compliance
relevant but seldom central to the increase with the extent of their
design of taxes, then the failure to magnitude.
model them systematically would be
irritating but unimportant. However, as Finally, and most importantly, there are
I argue in the next sections, the failure now a number of estimates, derived
to address these different costs of taxes from a variety of methodologies, of the
is far from inconsequential. actual magnitudes of the individual and
firm compliance costs in the United
States. For individuals, Slemrod and
INDIVIDUAL AND FIRM COMPLIANCE Sorum (1984) and Blumenthal and
COSTS Slemrod (1992) use surveys of taxpayers
to estimate that the compliance cost of
Implicit in much of the optimal taxation the individual income tax may approach
literature is the assumption that it is about seven percent of its revenues.
costless for individuals and firms to pay Using a different approach based upon
their taxes. There is little question that econometric analysis of individual tax
this assumption is simply wrong, for a returns, Pitt and Slemrod (1989)
number of reasons. calculate that the compliance cost of
itemizing deductions in 1982 totaled
On a purely anecdotal basis, it has been nearly 0.5 percent of revenues. On the
evident for some time that there are corporate side, Blumenthal and Slemrod
substantial individual and firm “compli- (1995) conclude from a survey of
ance costs” from taxation. Taxpayer “large” corporations that corporate
complaints about keeping records compliance costs are over three percent
throughout the year, deciphering of total federal and state corporate

120
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

SYMPOSIUM ON INCOME TAX COMPLEXITY AND ENFORCEMENT

income tax collections. Evidence for the taxes and can sometimes be substan-
United Kingdom (Sandford, 1995), tially higher (Vaillancourt, 1989;
Australia (Pope, Fayle, and Duncanson, Sandford, 1995). Unfortunately, there is
1990), and Canada (Vaillancourt, 1989) little information on how these costs
suggests that compliance costs can vary with various policy tools; that is, it
range from 2 to 24 percent of revenues seems likely that the administrative costs
for selected taxes. change in large and discrete amounts
with the scale of collections (or they
In total, these studies clearly indicate may exhibit “discontinuities”) and that
that the compliance costs of taxation they may also display economies of
are significant, often of comparable or scale in their collections (or they may
even larger values than the more exhibit “nonconvexities”), but these
traditional calculations of the excess aspects of the collection cost technology
burden of taxation. In part because of are not known.
these results, economists have begun to
add compliance costs to their standard The administrative dimension of
theoretical analyses of individual taxation has long been recognized by
taxpayer behavior (Alm, 1988; Slemrod, tax administrators, especially those
1995). There is also some theoretical working on tax policy in developing
work that has begun to incorporate countries (Bagchi, Bird, and Das-Gupta,
some aspects of individual compliance 1995). However, it has not been until
costs in an optimal tax framework recently that administrative costs have
(Slemrod, 1994; Slemrod and Yitzhaki, been formally incorporated in the
1994). However, despite the insights analysis of optimal taxation. Mayshar
from this work, it is still subject to some (1991) assumes that there are costs to
limitations: it typically examines only a the taxpayer and to the government
limited number of tax instruments, such from collecting a generic form of taxes
as those that apply to individuals only; it and determines the conditions that
is based upon very stylized assumptions characterize the optimal use of the tax.
about individual behavior; and it seldom Other work has examined the optimal
deals precisely with the exact nature of choice of tax instruments in the pres-
the compliance costs to individuals. ence of positive administrative costs.
Clearly, there is more that needs to be For example, Wilson (1989) examines
done to model, as well as to measure, the optimal number of commodities to
the compliance cost of taxes. be taxed, where there is some cost to
government from the expansion of the
THE ADMINISTRATIVE COSTS OF optimal commodity tax base; he
TAXATION concludes that the optimal size of the
tax base balances the extra administra-
Although there is considerably less tive costs from taxing more commodities
systematic work on the costs to the with the efficiency (and revenue-yield)
government of collecting taxes (or the gains from the base expansion. Differ-
“administrative costs” of taxation), the ent aspects of the optimal administra-
available evidence from government tion of the individual income tax have
budgetary information clearly indicates also been considered. Stern (1982)
that the budget cost of collecting assumes that the characteristics of the
individual income, business income, and taxpayers cannot be observed with
sales taxes is generally in excess of one certainty, and Slemrod and Yitzhaki
percent of the revenues from these (1994) analyze the trade-off between

121
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 1

more accurate measurement of income Tax evasion is important for many


via itemized deductions and less costly reasons. In the context of the discussion
measurement via the standard deduction. here, it affects the efficiency of the tax
system by creating misallocations in
These analyses have generated numer- resource use as agents alter their
ous insights. However, to repeat some behavior—and incur costs (or “noncom-
points made about the analyses of pliance costs”)—to cheat on their taxes.
compliance costs, they are also largely Evasion also has equity effects because
based on fairly arbitrary assumptions it alters the distribution of income in
about such things as the available tax unpredictable ways. Because it causes
instruments (e.g., only commodity or the government to expend resources (or
income taxes can be used), the behav- “enforcement costs”) to reduce its
ioral responses of taxpayers (e.g., magnitude and it also reduces the taxes
taxpayers have only some particular and that individuals pay, tax evasion affects
restrictive forms of preferences), the the tax rates that compliant taxpayers
administrative costs to government face and the public services that all
(e.g., the administrative costs increase citizens receive. More broadly, it is not
smoothly and continuously from policy possible to understand the true impact
changes), and the like. Clearly, there is of taxation without recognizing the
more that needs to be done to model existence of evasion. It is clearly not
and, again, to measure the administra- possible to design an optimal tax system
tive cost dimension. without appropriate consideration of tax
evasion and its effects on individuals
TAX EVASION AND ENFORCEMENT and on government.

The standard optimal tax approach In comparison to the other areas of


assumes that individuals and firms research discussed above, there is an
voluntarily pay all of their tax liabilities. extensive literature devoted to the
This assumption is wildly inaccurate. theoretical and empirical analysis of tax
Individuals pursue many illegal avenues evasion (Cowell, 1990). The theoretical
to reduce their payments, such as analysis of tax evasion most often builds
underreporting incomes, overstating on the economics-of-crime model first
deductions and exemptions, or failing to applied to tax evasion by Allingham and
file returns. Despite obvious measure- Sandmo (1972). The focus of nearly all
ment difficulties, there is widespread of this work is on the behavior of a
evidence that tax evasion is extensive representative individual who faces an
and commonplace in nearly all coun- individual income tax. The individual is
tries. For the United States, the most viewed as maximizing the expected
reliable estimates project the amount of utility of the evasion gamble, weighing
unpaid federal income taxes at $127 the benefits of successful cheating
billion for 1992, with an annual growth against the risky prospect of detection
rate of roughly ten percent since 1973 and punishment, and the individual pays
(U.S. Government Accounting Office, taxes because he or she is afraid of
1995). Other taxes at other levels of getting caught and penalized. This
government are also subject to nonpay- approach gives the plausible and
ment. Evidence from other countries productive insight that compliance
suggests that the American experience depends upon audit and fine rates.
is not an isolated one. Indeed, the central conclusion of this

122
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

SYMPOSIUM ON INCOME TAX COMPLEXITY AND ENFORCEMENT

approach is that an individual pays taxes (2) Endogenous audit selection rules:
only because of this fear of detection The agency may use information
and punishment, and an increase in the from the tax returns to determine
fine or the audit rate can be shown to strategically whom to audit, so
increase compliance. Surprisingly, an that the probability of audit is
increase in the tax rate generally has an endogenous, dependent in part on
ambiguous effect on reported income in the behavior of the taxpayer and
the standard model; under plausible the tax agency (Reinganum and
assumptions, compliance actually rises Wilde, 1985).
with higher tax rates, in contrast to the (3) Use of paid preparers: Paid
common perception that higher tax preparers may both reduce
rates have contributed to evasion. taxpayer confusion and encour-
age noncompliant behavior
on ambiguous items (Erard,
However, it is clear to a number of 1993).
observers that at least some forms of (4) Tax avoidance: An individual
compliance cannot be explained entirely simultaneously chooses the
by the level of enforcement (Graetz and amounts of tax evasion and tax
Wilde, 1985). The levels of audit and avoidance (Alm, 1988).
penalty rates are set so low that most (5) Structure of taxation: Some kinds
individuals would either underreport of taxes are easier to evade than
income not subject to source withhold- others (Kesselman, 1989).
ing or overclaim deductions not subject
to independent verification if they were
purely “rational,” because it is unlikely To date, however, no single theory has
that such cheating would be caught and been able to incorporate more than a
penalized. few of these factors in a meaningful
way, and it seems unlikely that such a
general model will be forthcoming.
In part because of this quandary, there
have been numerous extensions of the
basic theoretical model, to consider Empirical analysis of individual behav-
other factors not included in the basic ioral responses has also grown dramati-
theoretical model or to consider other cally in the last 20 years. The main
factors not captured appropriately by difficulty in this work is finding informa-
the theory. These extensions include tion on the compliance behavior of
such things as government services, individuals. Because of this problem,
overweighting of low probabilities, the empirical work draws creatively on a
social norms, and labor supply choices. variety of data sources. The most
Of particular relevance here, the theory extensively used source for the United
has also expanded to include the State relies on information generated by
following. the Internal Revenue Service. Other
sources include taxpayer returns, survey
(1) Uncertainty and complexity: data, national income accounts, and
Individuals may not know with laboratory experiments. In its entirety,
certainty their tax liability or the this work suggests the following
tax agency’s enforcement strategy conclusions relevant to the discussion
(Cronshaw and Alm, 1995). here.

123
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 1

(1) An increase in tax complexity leads policies (Sandmo, 1981; Kaplow, 1990;
to greater use of a tax practitioner, Cremer and Gahvari, 1993; Boadway,
and the average level of noncom- Marchand, and Pestieau, 1994). The
pliance is higher for returns standard policy prescription has long
prepared with paid assistance been an increase in penalty and audit
(Erard, 1993). rates; indeed, at least the theoretical
(2) A higher audit rate leads to more work suggests that sufficient—and
compliance, at least to a point, draconian—increases in penalty and
with an estimated reported audit rates could substantially eliminate
income–audit rate elasticity evasion.
ranging from 0.1 to 0.2 (Dubin
and Wilde, 1988). However, it is unlikely that such extreme
(3) A higher fine rate leads to margin- measures will actually be implemented,
ally more compliance, with an at least in part because there is a
estimated reported income–fine widespread belief that “the punishment
rate elasticity less than 0.1 (Alm, should fit the crime.” Moreover, it
Bahl, and Murray, 1993). should be remembered that, although
(4) A higher tax rate leads to less higher penalty and audit rates generate
compliance, with an estimated benefits, they also entail costs, both to
reported income–tax rate elasticity the government that must use real
ranging from –0.5 to –3.0. resources in its efforts and to the
(Clotfelter, 1983). individuals who suffer a loss in utility
(5) Audit rates are endogenous, in from greater enforcement. These
that they depend in part on the considerations clearly suggest that
choices of taxpayers (Feinstein, government should not expand its
1991). enforcement actions to the point where
an additional dollar of enforcement
There is now also some empirical work costs yields an additional dollar of
on corporate income tax compliance revenues: the former involves a real
(Rice, 1992) and on firm sales tax resource cost to the economy, while the
compliance (Murray, 1995). latter is simply a transfer from the
private to the public sector (Slemrod and
Given the underlying data problems, this Yitzhaki, 1987; Alm, 1988). Instead,
empirical work needs to be treated most analyses of the optimal amount of
cautiously. Still, these results indicate government enforcement conclude that
that individuals incur costs and change optimal enforcement must equate the
their behavior in response to enforce- marginal costs of enforcement with the
ment activities and that the enforce- marginal benefits, where these benefits
ment agency can increase compliance should include the added revenues but
by taking advantage of these responses should also reflect the impact of greater
in its choice of an enforcement strategy. induced honesty and the loss in indi-
They also clearly indicate that there are vidual expected utility. Consequently, it
limits to strategies based only on greater seems clear that optimal enforcement
enforcement. should not eliminate all tax evasion
(Polinsky and Shavell, 1984). As noted
There has also been much work on above, there is also clear theoretical
optimal government policy in the face evidence that the optimal enforcement
of tax evasion, including theoretical policy should utilize information from
analysis of optimal tax cum enforcement the tax returns in the selection of

124
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

SYMPOSIUM ON INCOME TAX COMPLEXITY AND ENFORCEMENT

returns for audit (Reinganum and Wilde, considered in its effects on the other
1985). Such “endogenous” audit three dimensions of a desirable tax
selection rules are able to generate system.
higher levels of compliance than equal
cost rules in which returns are selected The omission of simplicity as an explicit
randomly (Alm, Cronshaw, and McKee, measure and its incorporation in other
1993). goals is important and needs some
justification; this justification also serves
A FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS to illustrate the ways in which compli-
ance, administrative, noncompliance,
It is obviously difficult to know how all and enforcement costs can be incorpo-
these considerations will affect the rated in the analysis. The reasons for
standard optimal taxation rules. Indeed, this omission are best illustrated by
it is difficult even to know where to start means of some examples. Consider, say,
to analyze in a systematic way the the introduction of some specific tax
effects of these factors on the appropri- provision that affects individuals via the
ate design of tax systems. individual income tax (e.g., the deduc-
tion of business-related expenses). This
Still, I believe that a careful examination change is often discussed as involving a
of these factors suggests that they all balancing of simplicity, efficiency, equity,
involve trade-offs among essentially and revenue-yield effects. The change
three main criteria: allows the tax to be imposed on a more
accurate measure of an individual’s
(1) How does the choice of taxes ability to pay, and it encourages, or at
affect the yield of the tax collec- least does not discourage, the individual
tions, where the yield is defined from engaging in those business-related
broadly in terms of the gross activities that generate income. How-
collections in excess of administra- ever, there are clearly added costs
tive and enforcement costs imposed on individuals from this
(revenue-yield)? feature. There are compliance costs to
(2) How does the choice affect the the individual because records of these
distribution of the burden of expenses need to be maintained, and
taxation on individuals, where the these costs reduce the individual’s
burden is defined broadly in terms income. There are also added adminis-
of the tax burden, the compliance trative costs that lower net revenues,
cost burden, and the noncompli- since these deductions complicate the
ance cost burden on taxpayers administration of the tax. Further,
(equity)? individuals may fraudulently claim these
(3) How does the choice affect the expenses, which implies that the
decisions of individuals and firms, government must expend resources
where the decisions are defined enforcing the provision, at some cost
broadly in terms of the responses both to the government and to the
of the agents to the entire tax, taxpayer. Finally, the deduction itself
compliance, and enforcement will generate some revenue loss to the
parameters (efficiency)? government.

Note in particular that I do not define a However, these various aspects will be
separate criterion for simplicity. Instead, incorporated in the standard measures
simplicity is implicitly assumed to be of equity, efficiency, and revenue-yield.

125
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 1

The direct effect of the deduction on behavior in the face of the stricter
revenues enters in an obvious way, as enforcement. Because different
do the impacts of the extra administra- individuals will be affected in different
tive costs and enforcement costs on ways, the distribution of income will
government revenues net of these costs. also be altered, thereby creating equity
The effects on efficiency are reflected in effects. All of these effects will be
any lost output that arises from behav- captured by the usual standards of
ioral responses to the tax provision itself, revenue-yield, efficiency, and equity.
from the individuals’ efforts to establish
the legitimacy of the deductions, from Consequently, analysis of taxation
the noncompliance actions of the requires balancing the trade-offs
individuals, and from the enforcement between equity, efficiency, and revenue-
activities of government, all of which are yield, where each is broadly defined and
represented by the standard measure of commonly measured. Still, analysis of
the excess burden of taxation. The even these three factors is obviously a
effects of the tax provision on equity are daunting task. It seems to me that the
captured by the differential impact of best option involves a threefold strategy.
the provision on the income of different
individuals and by the weights of those First, empirical work must continue to
individuals in the social welfare function; be performed to estimate both the
that is, the provision both increases an magnitude of the compliance costs of
individual’s income (because it generates different taxes and the determinants of
tax savings) and decreases income those compliance costs (or the individual
(because it produces compliance and and firm “compliance cost function”).
noncompliance costs), and these equity At least for the United States, most
effects are measured in the social previous work has focused on the cost
welfare function by the combination of to individuals of the individual income
the change in individual income and the tax and, to a lesser extent, on the cost
social weights on the welfare of those to large corporations of the corporate
individuals who experience these income tax. However, there are clearly
changes. (Note that these comments compliance costs from many other
pertain to the vertical equity of taxes. major taxes, costs that are borne largely
The effects on horizontal equity are by firms. Firms of all sizes incur costs in
more difficult to determine; indeed, as the collection of sales and excise taxes,
argued by Kaplow (1989), even the payroll taxes, severance taxes, user fees,
existence of a separate notion of and so on; the costs incurred by “small”
horizontal equity is controversial.) A and “medium” size firms are largely
separate criterion for simplicity is unknown. Further, the ways in which
therefore not needed. these compliance costs are affected by
different tax design features is essential
Or consider a change in enforcement in the determination of government
policy (e.g., an increase in audit cover- policies but again is not known. How
age). There is a range of effects that do compliance costs increase with
determines the desirability of this policy special provisions of the taxes? Are
change. The government will incur compliance costs affected by progressive
some added administrative and enforce- tax rates? What is the magnitude of the
ment costs but will also generate some costs in the “start-up” phase of new
extra revenues. The level of output will taxes or of new tax provisions? How
be affected as individuals change their significant are scale economies in tax

126
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

SYMPOSIUM ON INCOME TAX COMPLEXITY AND ENFORCEMENT

compliance? How do individuals and component of the optimal design of


firms respond in their decisions to taxes, and the analysis of these re-
changes in government tax policies, sponses must continue.
such as an increase in the standard
deduction or a strengthening of Second, the equity, efficiency, and
reporting requirements? These and revenue-yield effects generated by these
other questions are unanswered. behavioral responses must be incorpo-
rated into an analysis in which they can
Similarly, although there is budgetary be measured on a common scale. As
information on the administrative costs argued above, these effects are cap-
of various taxes, there has been little tured by standard measures, known and
systematic analysis of the determinants used by economists. Note again that
of these administrative costs and the the consideration of (vertical) equity
effects of these determinants on the effects requires that explicit judgments
quantity and the quality of tax about the relative social worth of
administration (the “administrative cost different individuals must be made by
function”). In particular, it seems likely the analyst. Such judgments are always
that there are significant fixed costs made, perhaps especially when they are
when a new tax is imposed or when not made explicitly.
the features of an existing tax are
changed. For similar reasons, it seems Third, I think it unavoidable that
likely that the expansion of, say, an rigorous analysis of the range of
existing sales tax to include new considerations relevant to tax design
commodities involves a stepwise, or requires numerical analysis, perhaps in a
discontinuous, increase in costs. Also, computable general equilibrium
there may well be some economies of framework, in which the different
scale, or nonconvexities, in tax adminis- considerations are sequentially layered,
tration. However, these issues have one atop another, until the full model
received little attention, at least by captures the relevant factors. The
economists. Similar questions surround numerical analysis would necessarily
noncompliance (the “noncompliance incorporate the empirical analyses of
cost function” for taxpayers) and compliance cost, administrative cost,
enforcement (the “enforcement cost noncompliance cost, and enforcement
function” for tax agencies). There is cost functions.
clearly much scope for empirical
analysis, and such analysis is a necessary The reason for reliance upon numerical
input in the design of taxes. analysis is easily stated. Even simple
theoretical models of optimal taxation
It is, however, important to emphasize quickly become unwieldy and incapable
that a focus on the measurement of of interpretation or generalization. At
compliance, administrative, noncompli- best, these models only characterize the
ance, and enforcement costs does not optimal tax rules by defining the
mean that empirical work on the more numerous conditions that must be
common behavioral responses to taxes satisfied if taxes are to be optimal; that
should be ignored. There is an enor- is, these models specify a system of
mous—and surprising—amount that we equations that must hold simultaneously
simply do not know about how indi- in order for the tax rates to be optimal.
viduals and firms react to taxes. Empiri- However, these models do not actually
cal work on these aspects is the central determine the precise pattern of the

127
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 1

taxes. Unless the exact forms of the efficiency effects of taxes and when
various equations are specified, it is there are no compliance costs, adminis-
clearly impossible to solve analytically trative costs, noncompliance costs, or
the system of equations for the actual enforcement costs? This analysis would
tax rates; even with these specifications, consider a numerical representation of a
there is obviously no guarantee that the specific economy in which consumer
equations can be solved for unique tax and firm decisions are modeled with
rates. Further, these models almost functional forms whose parameter
always assume that the various func- values replicate the real world outcomes
tions change smoothly and continu- of that economy. The outcome of this
ously, an assumption that allows the use simulation would be the standard
of differential calculus. However, as optimal commodity tax result that tax
discussed above, it seems likely that the rates should be higher on commodities
various cost functions, especially the with less elastic demands.
administrative and enforcement cost
functions, are characterized both by This analysis would then be modified to
large discrete changes and by econo- incorporate efficiency and equity
mies of scale. The search for purely concerns: If individuals differ and if
analytical solutions seems a dead end. government is concerned with raising
revenues to meet efficiency and equity
There are now many examples of goals, how should commodity tax rates
numerical analyses in the optimal tax be chosen? Note that this analysis
tradition. There is also a growing requires explicit assumptions about the
literature on general equilibrium social worth of different individuals.
modeling (Shoven and Whalley, 1992).
The combination of these literatures A third layer of analysis would then add
seems a fruitful path of research. Like the compliance costs on firms (and,
the standard optimal taxation approach, perhaps, on individuals) of commodity
such a framework requires an explicit taxes. This analysis would be based on
modeling of the behavioral effects of estimates of the compliance cost
taxation, as well as an explicit recogni- function generated from empirical
tion of the welfare weights placed on studies of firm behavior, and its results
different classes of individuals. Impor- would indicate the effects of compliance
tantly, it also requires explicit incorpora- costs on the simple optimal tax rules. A
tion of the different cost functions. The possible complication in this stage is the
numerical specification necessarily potential for discontinuities and
pertains to the characteristics and nonconvexities in the compliance cost
institutions of a particular country. function. These are difficult to analyze
in theoretical models, but there are now
For example, consider the process by methods for incorporating such factors
which optimal commodity taxes could in numerical models.
be determined in such a framework.
The analysis would begin with the A fourth layer would incorporate
simplest case, which forms the basis of administrative costs, using administra-
the standard optimal commodity tax tive cost function estimates that allow
problem: How should tax rates on for discontinuities and nonconvexities.
commodities be chosen to raise a A fifth layer would consider noncompli-
specified amount of revenues when the ance. Some commodity taxes are easier
government is concerned only with the to collect, and some are easier to evade,

128
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

SYMPOSIUM ON INCOME TAX COMPLEXITY AND ENFORCEMENT

than others (e.g., commodities versus present, we do not know many of the
services). How does the presence of characteristics of the relevant functions.
noncompliance with commodity taxes Still, my own guess is that a full analysis
affect the optimal commodity tax of these factors will lead to modification
structure? The enforcement of com- of the standard optimal tax rules, as
modity taxes would then be added in a discussed in the following subsections.
final layer, based on the individual
noncompliance and the agency enforce-
ment cost functions. Obviously, other Optimal Commodity Taxes
sequences could be usefully considered.
Commodity tax rates should be largely
Similar steps can be followed for proportional. Proportional tax rates
optimal income taxes. The first stage reduce compliance costs and administra-
would examine the optimal form of a tive costs because they eliminate the
(linear) income tax, when the govern- necessity of separate measurement of
ment is concerned with equity only and the tax bases. For similar reasons, they
when there are no compliance costs, lower the enforcement costs to the
administrative issues, noncompliance government. Proportional tax rates also
problems, or enforcement difficulties; reduce the incentives for noncompli-
transfer (or welfare) programs would ance, and they reduce the distortions
also be separately incorporated. Then from changes in the relative prices of
the following sequence of layering commodities. Divergences from
would be analyzed: equity only; equity proportional commodity tax rates should
and efficiency; equity, efficiency, and be minimal and should largely take the
compliance costs; equity, efficiency, form of marginally higher tax rates on
compliance costs, and administrative goods that are unresponsive to price
costs; equity, efficiency, compliance changes (e.g., necessities, for efficiency
costs, administrative costs, and noncom- reasons), on goods that generate
pliance costs; and equity, efficiency, significant negative spillovers (e.g.,
compliance costs, administrative costs, alcohol or tobacco, also for efficiency
noncompliance costs, and enforcement reasons), on goods consumed by higher
costs. The result of this (or some other income groups (e.g., luxuries, for equity
sequence) would be a much more reasons), and on goods for which taxes
detailed and realistic set of policy can be easily and cheaply collected (e.g.,
prescriptions for the appropriate design goods versus services, for administrative
of tax policies in a specific setting. cost and revenue-yield reasons).

Conclusions: Optimal Taxation In Optimal Income Taxes


The Real World
Income taxes should be imposed at
What would be the form of the tax rules constant marginal tax rates on broadly
that would emerge from such a defined tax bases above some level of
framework? It is risky to make general income determined by generously
statements. Indeed, I think it certain defined exemptions and (standard)
that the tax rules would vary, perhaps deductions with minimal use of special
significantly, across the different tax incentives. Constant marginal tax
economies subject to this analysis. Tax rates reduce compliance costs by
design must always consider the reducing the incentive to engage in tax
particular circumstances at hand, and at shifting schemes; for related reasons,

129
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 1

they reduce administrative costs. direct and indirect taxes in theory is


Broadly defined tax bases allow lower unlikely to hold in practice. “General”
marginal tax rates to generate a given sales taxes are never general, due to
level of revenue, and so reduce the difficulties in administration and
distorting effects of taxes on behavior, enforcement. Similarly, income taxes
including behavior related to noncompli- are never imposed and collected on all
ance. Generously defined exemptions incomes. When it is also recognized
help achieve equity goals with reduced that compliance costs for income and
compliance and administrative costs and commodity taxes differ in both their
imply that lower income individuals will magnitude and their incidence, that the
pay negative taxes. Standard deduc- taxes differ in their costs of collection,
tions reduce the equity of the income that some individuals are better able to
tax but lower administrative, compli- evade income taxes than others while
ance, noncompliance, and enforcement most individuals are unable to cheat on
costs; in contrast, tax incentives increase commodity taxes, that enforcement of
the range of taxpayer and tax agency income taxes is generally more difficult
costs with uncertain impacts on their than that for commodity taxes, then in
desired ends. Income taxes should also such circumstances I think it plausible
be collected by source withholding, that both taxes should be used. In
thereby lowering compliance and short, it is the fact that each tax is
administrative costs. imperfect—and that each is imperfect in
different ways—that suggests that both
Optimal Tax Mix should be used.

Both direct and indirect taxes should be Although it is comforting that these
levied. Use of both taxes allows each broad guidelines are similar to those
tax to be imposed at lower marginal tax suggested by others (Bird, 1992), more
rates, which reduces distortions and, systematic analysis of these issues is
most likely, noncompliance. Use of both obviously needed, and such analysis
taxes also gives the government more may well lead to different guidelines.
flexibility to achieve its equity and its There is clearly a pressing need for
revenue-yield goals, especially given the analyses in which specific features of a
limitations that administrative consider- particular country are incorporated and
ations impose on the scope and even analyzed in useful and usable simulation
the use of some taxes. models. I believe that such analyses
serve at least three ends: they indicate
The optimal tax mix guidelines are the and quantify with a standard measure
most uncertain and the most in need of the trade-offs that taxes necessarily
additional research. It is easily estab- create; they indicate the areas in which
lished that proportional income and our knowledge is incomplete; and they
commodity taxes are equivalent when provide specific guidelines for tax design
each is imposed on a comprehensive and tax reform, in particular country
base. Given such equivalence, only one circumstances. I also believe that the
of these taxes need be used; indeed, the guidelines that emerge from such
incorporation of the range of costs analyses are in most cases likely to be
discussed above clearly implies that only significantly different than those that
one should be used. However, it is also emerge from the optimal taxation
easily recognized that the equivalence of approach.

130
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

SYMPOSIUM ON INCOME TAX COMPLEXITY AND ENFORCEMENT

It is, unfortunately, important to keep in implement fully the prescriptions of


mind that this exercise may ultimately optimal tax theory. There are simply too
prove futile. The informational require- many tax features that are possible
ments for the kind of analysis outlined candidates for action but that cannot be
here are daunting, and there is too modeled to consider fully their use.
much that we do not and, indeed, that Still, this should not discourage the
we cannot know. It is also impossible to search for specific tax design—and,
consider all possible aspects that are especially, tax reform—guidelines that
relevant in the optimal design of tax apply to a single country at a point in
systems; even if all of the factors time and that incorporate the range of
discussed at length above were to be considerations discussed here. Such
incorporated, there would necessarily guidelines will necessarily be couched in
remain omissions. Perhaps most general terms. However, if the guide-
important among these omissions, the lines are generated from models that
optimal taxation methodology does not incorporate the factors discussed here, I
consider the positive aspects of the believe that they will offer a better map
enactment and the enforcement of tax for tax policy than those derived from
rules. The individuals who pass the tax the standard optimal tax framework.
laws have interests that may not always
coincide with the somewhat amorphous ENDNOTE
notion of social welfare that is used in
optimal taxation; that is, there is a I have benefited greatly from comments by Richard
Bird, Louis Kaplow, and Joel Slemrod.
political dimension to tax policies that
may well outweigh the purely normative
considerations at the foundation of REFERENCES
optimal taxation (Hettich and Winer, Allingham, Michael, and Agnar Sandmo.
1988). As one example, these interests “Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analysis.”
may lead individuals in authority to Journal of Public Economics 1 No. 3/4 (1972):
enact complex tax rules because of the 323–38.

political gains from complexity, even Alm, James. “Compliance Costs and the Tax
Avoidance–Tax Evasion Decision.” Public Finance
though such complexity may have
Quarterly 16 No. 1 (January, 1988): 31–66.
efficiency, equity, and revenue-yield
Alm, James, Roy Bahl, and Matthew N.
costs. Appropriate government policy Murray. “Audit Selection and Income Tax
must also recognize that the individuals Underreporting in the Tax Compliance Game.”
responsible for administering and Journal of Development Economics 42 No. 1
enforcing the tax rules may well need (October, 1993): 1–33.
oversight as well. There is widespread Alm, James, Mark B. Cronshaw, and Michael
evidence of corruption by government McKee. “Tax Compliance with Endogenous
Audit Selection Rules.” Kyklos 46 No. 1 (1993):
officials, and the ways in which this 27–45.
corruption should be controlled must be
Auerbach, Alan J. “The Theory of Excess
considered (Chander and Wilde, 1992). Burden and Optimal Taxation.” In Handbook of
Public Economics, Vol. 1, edited by Alan J.
In short, the search for a general Auerbach and Martin S. Feldstein, 61–128.
Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1985.
scheme that specifies, for all countries
and all times, the details of an optimal Bagchi, Amaresh, Richard Bird, and Arindam
Das-Gupta. “An Economic Approach to Tax
tax system is certain to fail. There are Administration Reform.” Discussion Paper No. 3.
simply too many details that must be Toronto, Canada: International Centre for Tax
known but that are unknowable to Studies, University of Toronto, 1995.

131
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL VOL. XLIX NO. 1

Bird, Richard M. Tax Policy and Economic Kaplow, Louis. “Horizontal Equity: Measures in
Development. Baltimore, MD: The Johns Search of a Principle.” National Tax Journal 42
Hopkins University Press, 1992. No. 2 (June, 1989): 139–54.
Blumenthal, Marsha, and Joel Slemrod. “The Kaplow, Louis. “Optimal Taxation with Costly
Compliance Cost of the U.S. Individual Income Enforcement and Evasion.” Journal of Public
Tax System: A Second Look After Tax Reform.” Economics 43 No. 2 (1990): 221–36.
National Tax Journal 45 No. 2 (June, 1992): 185–
202. Kesselman, Jonathan R. “Income Tax Evasion:
An Intersectoral Analysis.” Journal of Public
Blumenthal, Marsha, and Joel Slemrod. “The
Economics 38 No. 2 (1989): 137–55.
Compliance Costs of Big Business.” University of
Michigan Working Paper No. 93-11. Ann Arbor, Mayshar, Joram. “Taxation with Costly
MI: University of Michigan, 1995. Administration.” Scandinavian Journal of
Boadway, Robin, Maurice Marchand, and Economics 93 No. 1 (1991): 75–88.
Pierre Pestieau. “Towards a Theory of the Murray, Matthew N. “Sales Tax Auditing and
Direct-Indirect Tax Mix.” Journal of Public Compliance.” National Tax Journal 48 No. 4
Economics 55 No. 1 (1994): 71–88. (December, 1995): 515–530.
Chander, Parkash, and Louis L. Wilde.
Pitt, Mark M., and Joel Slemrod. “The
“Corruption in Tax Administration.” Journal of
Compliance Cost of Itemizing Deduction:
Public Economics 49 No. 3 (1992): 333–49.
Evidence from Individual Tax Returns.” The
Clotfelter, Charles T. “Tax Evasion and Tax American Economic Review 79 No. 5 (December,
Rates: An Analysis of Individual Returns.” The 1989): 1224–32.
Review of Economics and Statistics 65 No. 3
(August, 1983): 363–73. Polinsky, A. Mitchell, and Steven Shavell.
“The Optimal Use of Fines and Punishment.”
Cowell, Frank A. Cheating the Government: Journal of Public Economics 24 No. 1 (1984):
The Economics of Tax Evasion. Cambridge, MA: 89–99.
MIT Press, 1990.
Pope J., R. Fayle, and M. Duncanson. The
Cremer, Helmuth, and Firouz Gahvari. “Tax
Compliance Costs of Personal Income Taxation in
Evasion and Optimal Commodity Taxation.”
Australia, 1987/87. Sydney, Australia: Australian
Journal of Public Economics 50 No. 3 (1993):
Tax Research Foundation, 1990.
261–75.
Cronshaw, Mark B., and James Alm. “Tax Reinganum, Jennifer F., and Louis L. Wilde.
Compliance with Two-Sided Uncertainty.” Public “Income Tax Compliance in a Principal-Agent
Finance Quarterly 23 No. 2 (April, 1995): 129– Framework.” Journal of Public Economics 26
66. No. 1 (1985): 1–18.

Dubin, Jeffrey, and Louis L. Wilde. “An Rice, Eric. “The Corporate Tax Gap: Evidence
Empirical Analysis of Income Tax Auditing and on Tax Compliance by Small Corporations.” In
Compliance.” National Tax Journal 41 No. 1 Why People Pay Taxes: Tax Compliance and
(March,1988): 61–74. Enforcement, edited by Joel Slemrod, 125–61.
Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press,
Erard, Brian. “Taxation with Representation: An
1992.
Analysis of the Role of Tax Practitioners in Tax
Compliance.” Journal of Public Economics 52 Sandford, Cedric T., ed. Tax Compliance Costs:
No. 2 (1993): 163–97. Measurement and Policy. Bath, United Kingdom:
Feinstein, Jonathan S. “An Econometric Fiscal Publications, 1995.
Analysis of Income Tax Evasion and Its Detec- Sandmo, Agnar. “Income Tax Evasion, Labour
tion.” The Rand Journal of Economics 22 No. 1 Supply, and the Equity-Efficiency Tradeoff.”
(Spring, 1991): 14–35. Journal of Public Economics 16 No. 3 (1981):
Graetz, Michael J., and Louis L. Wilde. “The 265–88.
Economics of Tax Compliance: Fact and Fantasy.”
Shoven, John B., and John Whalley. Applying
National Tax Journal 38 No. 3 (September, 1985):
General Equilibrium. Cambridge: Cambridge
355–63.
University Press, 1992.
Hettich, Walter, and Stanley L. Winer.
“Economic and Political Foundations of Tax Slemrod, Joel. “Optimal Taxation and Optimal
Structure.” The American Economic Review 78 Tax Systems.” Journal of Economic Perspectives
No. 4 (December, 1988): 701–12. 4 No. 1 (Winter, 1990): 157–78.

132
National Tax Journal
Vol 49 no. 1 (March 1996) pp. 117-33

SYMPOSIUM ON INCOME TAX COMPLEXITY AND ENFORCEMENT

Slemrod, Joel. “Fixing the Leak in Okun’s Stern, Nicholas H. “Optimum Income Taxation
Bucket: Optimal Tax Progressivity When with Errors in Administration.” Journal of Public
Avoidance Can Be Controlled.” Journal of Economics 17 No. 2 (1982): 181–212.
Public Economics 55 No. 1 (1994): 41– Stern, Nicholas H. “The Theory of Optimal
51. Commodity and Income Taxation: An Introduc-
tion.” In The Theory of Taxation for Developing
Slemrod, Joel. “A General Model of the
Countries, edited by David Newbery and Nicholas
Behavioral Response to Taxation.” University of
H. Stern, 22–59. New York, NY: Oxford
Michigan. Mimeo, 1995.
University Press, 1987.
Slemrod, Joel, and Nikki Sorum. “The U.S. Government Accounting Office.
Compliance Cost of the U.S. Individual Income Taxpayer Compliance: Reducing the Income Tax
Tax.” National Tax Journal 37 No. 4 (December, Gap. GAO/T-GGD-95-176, Washington, D.C.:
1984): 461–74. June, 1995.
Slemrod, Joel, and Shlomo Yitzhaki. “The Vaillancourt, Francois. The Administrative and
Optimal Size of a Tax Collection Agency.” Compliance Costs of the Personal Income Tax
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 89 No. 2 and Payroll Tax System in Canada, 1986.
(1987): 183–92. Toronto, Canada: Canadian Tax Foundation, 1989.
Slemrod, Joel, and Shlomo Yitzhaki. Wilson, John Douglas. “On the Optimal Tax
“Analyzing the Standard Deduction as a Base for Commodity Taxation.” The American
Presumptive Tax.” International Tax and Public Economic Review 79 No. 5 (December, 1989):
Finance 1 No. 1 (May, 1994): 25–34. 1196–1206.

133

View publication stats

You might also like