Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 28

Poverty and Environment:

Evidence of Links and Integration into the


Country Assistance Strategy Process

Anders Ekbom
Jan Bojö

January 1999

Discussion Paper No. 4

Environment Group
Africa Region
The World Bank
Poverty and Environment: Evidence of
Links and Integration into the Country
Assistance Strategy Process

Anders Ekbom
Jan Bojö

January 1999

Environment Group
Africa Region
The World Bank
1
Introduction

“Povertyii is a major cause and effect of global envi- members to put lessons into practice. In the
ronmental problems” stated the influential Brundt- ensuing debate, considerable interest was
land Commission (WCED, 1987; p. 3) in a sen- expressed to further elaborate the central theme
tence that captures widely held beliefs: Poor of poverty-environment linkages; poverty allevi-
people are often seen as compelled to exploit ation being the generally accepted core of the
their surrounding for short-term survival, and World Bank’s work. This debate brought about
are assumed to be the ones most exposed to nat- this paper.
ural resources degradationiii. Despite these intu- The target group of the paper is primarily
itively plausible statements, the debate on the World Bank staff involved in the CAS process,
characteristics of poverty-environment interac- but we hope that a wider group of readers inter-
tion has been likened to a puzzle (World Bank, ested in the general topics of poverty alleviation
1997), where we possess several pieces, have and environmentally sustainable development
identified some crucial links and features, but (ESD) will find something of interest.
still lack the entire picture. The structure of the paper is as follows: Sec-
The aims of this paper are hence to (i) specify tion 2 presents some arguments on how poverty
the main hypotheses on how poverty and envi- and environment impact on each other, includ-
ronment are linked, (ii) examine empirical evi- ing key references and some empirical evidence.
dence linked to each one of them, and (iii) pro- Section 3 presents some good examples from
vide good examples of joint poverty- existing CASs and PAs of country-specific pov-
environment analyses in the World Bank’s Coun- erty-environment interactions. The section also
try Assistance Strategies (CASs) and Poverty presents some suggestions on how to address the
Assessments (PAs). issues jointly in the CAS process.
This report is a continuation of a previously We see this document as a contribution to a
published Discussion Paper from the Environ- process. Its effectiveness will mainly depend on
ment Group in the Africa Region of the World its usefulness in successfully integrating poverty
Bank (No. 1) entitled Mainstreaming Environment and environment in the CAS process. Ways to
in Country Assistance Strategies (Ekbom and Bojö, achieve this include working upstream in the
1997). The previous study was based on a global CAS process, linking up early with poverty
review of 34 CASs which showed that CASs experts in the Country Team and others inside
could substantially improve their analyses of and outside the Bank, identifying key areas
poverty and environment. Our previous work where a joint poverty-environment approach
has been applied to many country contexts, would be useful, and pursuing synergies and
where we have worked with Environment win-win solutions by e.g. including poverty alle-
Group colleagues and other Country Team- viation components in Environmental Support

1
Programs or, conversely, including environmen- cases with limited evidence of poverty-environ-
tal management components in poverty allevia- ment links, further analysis may be necessary.
tion projects. Obviously, it is also useful to con- The need for such analysis can be identified
sult the poverty documents such as Poverty through Economic Sector Work (ESW) or
Assessments (PAs), Participatory PAs, and Liv- through monitoring of selected performance
ing Standard Surveys to identify the entry points indicators and evaluation criteria which link
for poverty-environment integrated work. In poverty and environment.

2
2
Poverty-Environment Interactions

Below we specify a set of hypotheses (Hn) of deltas, they are all subject to aggravated risks such
how poverty and environment are linked, and as land slides, soil degradation, drought or floods.
examine available empirical evidence. The empirical example from Ghana in Box 1
below brings out this hypothesis in statistical
numbers.
H1. Poor people are the main victims of a bad
In conclusion on this point, the results of this
environment
study confirm the hypothesis that poor are victims
of a degraded environment, deprived of resources
We will refer to this as the “victims” hypothesis, to escape the situation, and Songsore and
advanced by, for example, the influential Brundt- McGranahan (1993, p. 33) conclude that: “environ-
land Commission. Some common but general mental risks go hand-in-hand with socio-economic
observations that underpin this hypothesis are deprivation”. Turning this into a constructive
the following: Poor people are commonly bound point, the opportunities are there for “win-win”
to reside in areas with poor environmental qual- investments in a better environment for the poor.
ity. Defining “the poorest” as the poorest 20 per-
cent among the total population of all develop- H1a: Poor people are more vulnerable to loss of biolog-
ing countries, Leach and Mearns (1991) have ical resources. An aspect of the “victims hypothe-
shown that 60 percent of them live in “ecologi- sis” is that poor people are more directly depen-
cally vulnerable areas”, including rural areas of dent on biological resources for their livelihood
low agricultural potential and squatter settle- than richer people. Loss of flora and fauna is
ments within urban areas. thus relatively more costly to poorer segments of
Poor people lack resources to relocate from society. Furthermore, poor people often are com-
these areas and to adopt defensive measures pelled to settle close to these resources com-
against negative exposure. Lower education monly found in open access areas, to be
increases their vulnerability to health risks. The exploited at family-labor costs only.
associated political marginalization decreases the People particularly dependent on biological
opportunities for environmental protection and resources include (i) small-scale farmers, who
provision of basic services such as safe drinking often derive additional sources of income from
water, access to clean air, functioning sewerage wild fruits, nuts, berries, herbs, medicinal plants,
and waste collection. Urban squatters are com- bushmeat and roots, (ii) trans-humant pastoral-
monly exposed to polluted air, contaminated ists, who derive essential nutrients from similar
water, and hazardous and solid waste. Rural land- wild flora and fauna in marginal areas such as
less people are forced for their survival to settle on drylands, and (iii) artisanal fishermen, who derive
marginal lands, and cultivate poor soils. Whether a variety of coastal and marine resources such as
it is steep slopes, arid or semi-arid lands or river shells, seaweed, coral and fishes, which provide

3
Box 1: Environmental Risks
and Living Standards in Ghana
In a study of 1000 randomly selected households in Accra, Ghana, Songsore and McGranahan (1993) ana-
lyze the links between local environment, wealth and health. Wealth is measured in terms of possession of
certain consumer durables and frequency of meat, poultry or fish consumption. The poorest and richest quin-
tiles are singled out for comparison. The study focuses on diarrhea and respiratory diseases. Principal analyt-
ical methods are bi-and multivariate regression analyses.
The poorest households show higher incidence of diarrhea, especially among children: 22% of the children
in the poorest quintile, but only 9% in the richest were subject to diarrhea in the two weeks prior to the inter-
view. The links between respiratory diseasesiv and wealth are weaker, but suggest a negative relationship for
women and children. The poorest enjoy significantly less environmental services (safe water, sewerage). They
lack knowledge or means to efficiently prevent diseases, are exposed to more health hazards, and are subject
to more crowding, i.e. more people share pots, toilets, living room etc. Poverty is statistically related to higher
prevalence of parasitic and diarrhea infections.
Specific explanations for some of the symptoms are that poor food handling, storage and hygiene practices
transmit diseases, especially parasitic and diarrhea infections. Here, local food vendors are a potential source
of contaminated food; 61% of the poorest, but only 33% of the wealthiest households in Accra depend on food
vendors for daily intake. Water provided to poorer households is not safe and supply is often interrupted.
Some 83% of the richest, but only 3% of the poorest stored food in refrigerators. Similar disparities were
reported for other hygiene practices (e.g. low frequency in hand washing prior to meals). Measures of crowd-
ing indicated that 71% of the poorest households, but only 34% of the richest occupy less than 4m2 per person
in the sleeping room. Likewise, 69% of the poorest, but only 12% of the richest share toilet with more than 10
persons. Further, pests are also key transmitters of diseases. The poorest households reported a very high
prevalence of flies (95%), cockroaches (66%), and rats (56%), respectively. The corresponding figures for the
top quintile were 22%, 30% and 15%.

food, building material, ornaments, cultural arti- choice of settlement will still be constrained, as
facts and cash income. The case study in box 2 indicated by the overall “victims” hypothesis,
looks more closely at the dependence on biologi- and the two hypotheses are mutually compati-
cal resources among different income segments. ble. Natural and man-made disasters often force
In conclusion, this well-documented example the poorest to temporarily or permanently leave
suggests that (a) poor people may be relatively their homestead to seek survival elsewhere. The
more dependent on biological resources found on associated environmental stress and resource
commons, but (b) that better off people actually scarcity has resulted in widespread displacement
consume a greater amount of them, in absolute of poor people. This resource-induced migration
terms, per household. This lends some support to has become so pertinent that the victims have
the hypotheses as stated, but it complicates mat- been labeled “environmental refugees” and sub-
ters somewhat. The policy implication is that ject to specific assessment and action.
biodiversity conservation might benefit the poor- It should be recognized that migratory pat-
est, but it could be a blunt instrument. To target terns are traditionally part of the coping mecha-
interventions effectively, we need to know more nisms of, in particular, nomadic pastoralist soci-
about what specific resources the poor utilize the eties. In such cases, it could represent a well-
most, not only that they are biological resources. established, risk-minimizing and functional rela-
Particularly in cases where local resource use tionship with a fragile but dynamic environ-
would be limited, it is important to understand ment. This type of migration would not fall
how the local population is affected, and what under the definition of “environmental refugees”
compensation might be warranted.v and is not our concern here.
In conclusion, while not all environmental ref-
H1b: Extreme environmental stress can force the ugees are poor, and while many poor do not
poorest to migrate. Another corollary to the “vic- migrate, it is evident that poor people have less
tims hypothesis” states that the poor, although resources to adapt to inhospitable environ-
less empowered to relocate from inhospitable ments, and are therefore forced to migrate in
surroundings, are often forced to long-range substantial numbers, as Myers and Kent (1995)
migration due to environmental hardship. Their have documented.

4
Box 2: Use of Biological Resources
in Zimbabwe
A detailed survey in Zimbabwe of 213 rural households’ use of several hundred non-marketed (“wild” or
“environmental”) goods collected at local commons, shows that these goods account for a substantial share of
poor people’s household budgets, and a significantly larger share than in richer households. Value derived
from environmental goods constitute as much as 40% of the total household budget in the lowest income
quintile, but only 25% among the top quintile.
Ordinary Least Squares (OLS)- and Tobit-regressions show that all but one of the income elasticities for
“wild” goods are positive but mostly low. This indicates that as incomes rise, the relative budget share of wild
goods decreases but—contrary to the H1a hypothesis—that total demand for wild goods increase, albeit at a
slow pace. The study also identifies that the elasticities vary widely between individual species: increasing
incomes result in substantially larger consumption of e.g. fish, game meat, and local pottery, moderate
increase of e.g. mice, and wild fruit, and decreased consumption of some e.g. household utensils. Hence,
some wild goods are complements and some substitutes to purchased goods. Cavendish concludes that the
common notion of a single poverty-environment relationship is not supported by his evidence.
Source: Cavendish (1997).

Box 3: Environmental Refugees Box 4: Inequality and the Environment


Myers and Kent’s (1995) comprehensive study A notorious example of inequality and its
“Environmental Exodus—An Emergent Crisis in effect on environment and health is South
the Global Arena” indicates that there are Africa’s former Homelands—one of the major
approximately 25 million environmental refu- legacies of Apartheid—where many of the black
gees in the world. For comparison, the number Africans reside. Due to crowding, poverty,
of traditional (political and war) refugees are neglect and past policies of institutionalized
estimated at 22 million. The report defines “envi- inequity, they are now subject to extremely poor
ronmental refugees” as “…persons who can no health and environmental conditions. Around
longer gain a secure livelihood in their tradi- 1/3 of the children of the black majority suffer
tional homelands because of environmental fac-
from chronic malnutrition, only around 25%
tors of unusual scope, notably drought, desertifi-
have electricity and running water, and less than
cation, deforestation, soil erosion, water
20% have modern sanitation. At the same time
shortages and climate change, also natural disas-
most whites enjoy “first world” conditions in all
ters such as cyclones, storms and floods” (p. 19).
respects. Consequently, infant mortality rate is
Many of these refugees are located on the
about 7–13% for black Africans, but only 1.2%
Horn of Africa and in the Sahelian region, but a
large portion also resides in the Indian sub-con- for whites, and whites live 11.5 years longer on
tinent, China, Mexico and Central America. average. (World Bank, 1994).
Based on six regional case studies, the report
states that “poverty, and especially absolute
poverty, works in conjunction with environmen-
quality, many local common property manage-
tal factors and population pressures to produce
ment schemes break down. This, in turn, results in
sizable numbers of refugees who are driven by
negative impacts on the most vulnerable.
all three factors working in conjunction” (Ibid.,
p. 49). A corollary to the hypothesis above is that
average GDP growth does not by definition
imply simultaneous poverty alleviation and
H1c: Inequality reinforces environmental pressure. A environmental improvements. The effect can in
skewed distribution of wealth and income has fact be the opposite or mixed, if growth plays
implications for environmental pressure. For into the hands of a privileged elite.
example, if small-scale farmers are compelled to For a full account, the effects of economic
utilize marginal areas because large-scale land- growth on poverty and environment need to be
owners occupy the best agricultural land, the ineq- evaluated at household level. The effect on indi-
uitable land distribution may be an important vidual household members of a deteriorating
driving force behind deforestation and land degra- environment can vary widely. In particular, chil-
dation. Along this line, Dasgupta and Mäler (1994) dren are the most vulnerable to poverty and
argue that poverty and many environmental prob- environmental degradation: for instance, chil-
lems stem from, or are exacerbated by, inequality. dren inhale greater quantities of air-borne pollut-
They also emphasize that in the presence of ine- ants relative to their body weight because of their

5
higher activity levels; they contract diarrhea
more frequently due to higher exposure to vec- Box 5: Policy Failures,
tors; infants in particular are exposed to higher Environment and the Poor
health risks as they have not fully developed Mahar (1988) and Binswanger (1989) analyze
their immune system. There is also a gender the impact of Brazil’s government’s policies on
aspect to the poverty-environment linkage the forest resources of the Amazon region and
(Agarwal, 1997). Thus, it is imperative to develop conclude that they have contributed to large-
the understanding of poverty-environment inter- scale deforestation. An area of more than
actions among sub-sets of poor people. 600,000 km2 has been cleared, 80% of which has
occurred since 1980. The government’s role in
H1d: Governmental policies can create or reinforce a this massive loss of natural capital has been one
vicious circle of poverty-environment interaction. of biasing the allocation of land and agricultural
Governments do this through policy failures, credits towards the rich, promoting environ-
including failure to address market failures, mentally hazardous road developments, conces-
imposing negative externalities with particularly sioning settlements in ecologically sensitive
severe impacts on the poor. Market failures are areas, and encouraging livestock development
exemplified by missing or incomplete markets through grazing-area expansion.
for environmental goods and services (clean Specific policy failures include substantial
agricultural tax exemptions for large-scale farm-
water, air, biodiversity resources, wetlands etc.).
ers, public-land allocation rules of differing
In the context of this paper, policy failures can be
claim security as well as land taxes which pro-
described as policy makers’ actions or failures to
vide incentives for land clearing and conversion
act, which results in environmental degradation to crop land or pasture, tax credit schemes
or pollution. Examples include subsidies to pol- favoring livestock ranching on cleared forest
luting industries and tenure insecurity, which land, and subsidized credits to corporate live-
encourage poor people to engage in non-sustain- stock ranches.
able resource use. It also includes corruption
contributing to environmental degradation: “The A review of studies from ten countries (Bojö,
existence of large resource rents from harvesting 1997) covers Côte d’Ivoire, Cameroon, Ghana,
mature timber has attracted politicians as well as Mali, Mexico, Philippines, Tanzania, Thailand,
businessmen to the opportunities of immediate Zambia, and Zimbabwe, which all have been
gain” (Repetto & Gillis, 1988, p. 388). subject to structural adjustment programs
The example from Brazil in Box 5 below (SAPs). The implementation of SAPs has been
describes how government policies have contrib- erratic, which, compounded by insufficient data
uted to environmental degradation in the Ama-
and analytical methods, have made it difficult to
zon and reduced the chances of the poor to
identify the specific effects of SAPs. However,
become farmers, which have left many of them
the study of Thailand, based on an extensive
landless or unemployed.
Computable General Equilibrium model of 90
Structural Adjustment Policies (SAPs) pro-
sectors and 5 policy scenarios, reports that SAPs
moted by IMF and the Bank represent a subset of
have contributed to reduced pollution and
governmental policies. Their effects on social
resource depletion per unit of GDP, but due to
welfare and the environment have been subject
to much debate and some analysis (see e.g. economic growth they have also led to an overall
Munasinghe and Cruz, 1995; Reed 1992, 1996). decline of environmental quality.
Few reliable empirical studies exist, mainly due A result common to several of the studies in
to insufficient environmental data fed into weak Sub-Saharan Africa is that reduced subsidies on
analytical frameworks, difficulties in establishing fertilizers and pesticides combined with cur-
the counterfactual, and the fact that SAPs often rency devaluation, reportedly have contributed
are only partially implemented. Timing and to agricultural encroachment into forests and
sequencing often deviate from the original policy increased timber exports. On the positive side,
package, which makes it difficult to disentangle the increased costs have decreased the use of pol-
the (often lagged) effects. While the need for luting agro-chemicals. A general conclusion from
adjustment of economic policies in Sub-Saharan the studies is that SAPs have been necessary to
Africa is clear and increasingly beyond contro- bring fundamentals in order, but that there is a
versy, analyses of SAPs have shown both posi- need to deploy complementary measures to min-
tive and negative impacts on the environment. imize the negative environmental effects.

6
Box 6: Structural Adjustment and the Box 7: Poverty and Deforestation
Environment
Mexico lost some 19.2 million ha of forest
Holden (1997) analyzes the impact of Zam- between 1980 and 1990. Empirical evidence
bia’s SAPs on the Chitemene slash-and-burn from the country indicate that poverty is associ-
shifting cultivation system, which requires large ated with higher levels of deforestation, and that
amounts of woody biomass for crop production. the poorer municipalities lost a greater propor-
The adjustment policies included (i) introduc- tion of local forest resources during this period.
tion of a market-based exchange rate; (Deininger and Minten, 1996).
(ii) removal of price controls, leading to regional In a two-period Cobb-Douglas production
and local price differentiation, (iii) removal of function model, Deininger and Minten estimate
food and fertilizer subsidies, leading to higher determinants of deforestation through Tobit-
consumer food prices and higher fertilizer regressions applied to eight different agro-cli-
prices for farmers, (iv) reduced government matic regions. The socio-economic data is based
involvement in production and marketing, and on the 1991 Agricultural census and the 1990
(v) reduced government expenditure. Population census, which give information on
Based on Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) and municipality level. The bio-physical data con-
Tobit-regressions of cross-section data from sists of information on land use, soil type and
1992/93, Holden concludes that removal of fer- vegetation cover. This data are based on satellite
tilizer and transport subsidies resulted in substi- images of 22,000 sample plots, each 100m.
tution from maize to local crops (such as finger x100m. in size, complemented by extensive
millet, groundnut, beans and cassava), expan- ground truthing.
sion of shifting cultivation and thus increased The study shows that the massive forest loss
deforestation. Deforestation has had limited primarily is driven by smallholders’ need for
negative environmental impact, however, agricultural land, and secondarily driven by
mainly because the miombo woodlands in commercial interests. Regression analyses of
northern Zambia are still abundant, the biodi- deforestation rate yield positive, statistically sig-
versity value is relatively low, local externalities nificant coefficients for (a proxy variable of)
such as soil erosion and water contamination are poverty.
not yet disturbing, and other use and non-use
values of the forest resources are limited. Hence,
the opportunity cost of burning the forest is still to other resources, exacerbates the conditions of
small, but Holden cautions that if population the poor by limiting their already restricted pro-
growth continues and current policies are pur- duction possibilities. This applies in particular to
sued, deforestation may become a serious envi- rural water, soils and energy. One of the basic
ronmental and economic problem.vi forces behind the vicious circle between poverty
and environment is thus suggested to be that
poverty limits people’s options and induces
H2. Poor people are agents of environmental them to deplete resources faster than is compati-
degradation ble with long-term sustainability. Hence the poor
themselves will aggravate the process of envi-
This hypothesis is not about “putting the blame ronmental degradation.
on the poor,” but to state that the rural poor are Dasgupta (1993) describes how closely depen-
often compelled to exploit marginal areas, such as dent poor people are on their surrounding envi-
steep hillsides, or derive resources from protected ronmental resource base for their livelihood, and
areas. Compounded by the impact of population how poverty can be a driving force to environ-
growth, they often lack the incentives or means to mental degradation. Based on theory and some
intensify their production and are forced to empirical evidence he argues that poverty is both
exploit new, fragile lands. The urban poor unwill- a cause and effect of resource degradation or lack
ingly contribute to a different kind of environ- of access to resources, including natural capital.
mental degradation, resulting in poor health, To exemplify the above arguments he describes
which can further reduce income opportunities. how poor nomadic dryland herdsmen often are
World Bank (1992, 1995) elaborate on some of excluded from formal credit, capital and insur-
the links between poverty and environment. It is ance markets and are forced to invest their capi-
stated that a declining natural resource base, tal in cattle, resulting in non-sustainable herd
largely caused by poor people deprived of access sizes and overgrazing.

7
Plausible explanations to the hypothesis that
the poor are agents of environmental degrada- Box 8: Time Horizon and the Environment
tion are that (i) poor people have shorter time Ostrom (1990) shows how poor people indeed
horizon and (ii) higher risk-aversion and a pro- can utilize fragile ecosystems and common-pool
pensity to use implicit, higher discount rates, resources sustainably over long time periods,
which leads us to specify the following sub- even centuries in some cases, if some specific
hypothesis:vii conditions or, in her terminology, “design princi-
ples” are fulfilled. Her global review draws on
H2a: Poor people have shorter time horizons, which evidence from cases such as communally man-
exacerbates environmental degradation. Allegedly, aged high mountain meadows and forests in
Switzerland and Japan, basin water resources in
poverty often results in myopic production and
south-western USA, and irrigation-water
consumption decisions, and precludes longer
schemes in Spain and the Philippines.
term investments in preservation and accumula- Based on the empirical survey, the conditions
tion of natural capital (Holden et. al., 1996; she identifies as essential for long-term, sustain-
Prakash, 1997). Consequently, poor people’s lim- able management of common pool resources
ited economic options and low savings rates (CPRs) are: First, the geographical boundaries of
cause them to deplete and degrade their immedi- the CPR must be clearly defined. Second, appro-
ate environment (soils, forest, fisheries), and priation of CPRs, provision rules for CPRs and
impose externalities on future generations. the local socio-economic and environmental
However, Ostrom (1990), Rhoades (1988), conditions must be congruent and coherent.
Prakash (1997), Jodha (1986), and Bromley (1992) Third, consensus-like collective-choice arrange-
support the alternative hypothesis by suggesting ments for managing the CPRs must exist; in
other words, most individuals who are affected
that poverty does not necessarily imply short
by the operational rules can participate in modi-
time horizons and environmental degradation.
fying them. Fourth, adequate monitoring of the
They argue that locally designed and governed use of the resource must be developed and func-
resource management institutions provide resil- tion over time, i.e. monitors who actively audit
ience towards risks and exogenous shocks, and CPRs and the appropriators are accountable to
facilitate sustainable use over time. Accordingly, the appropriators or are the appropriators. Fifth,
poor people do not inherently have relatively graduated sanctions must be imposed on those
shorter time-horizons. They are forced to dimin- violating the rules. The sanctions are preferably
ish their time horizon only when subject to exter- assessed by other appropriators, by officials
nal shocks or extreme events, it is argued. accountable to the appropriators, or both. Sixth,
Prakash (1997, p. 7) summarizes: “…it is not short cost-efficient conflict-resolution mechanisms
time-horizons so much as exogenous factors and mis- (e.g. low-cost local courts) must be developed
and utilized. Seventh, stakeholders’ rights to
guided policy and administrative mechanisms that are
organize themselves in CPR-management
primarily responsible for the environmental degrada-
schemes must obtain (at least minimal) recogni-
tion attributed to the poor.” tion by the Government. Eighth, based on the
Ostrom observes that neither the state nor the subsidiarity principle, the above design princi-
market has been uniformly successful in ples should be coherently tied together locally,
enabling individuals to sustain long-term, pro- regionally and nationally, and implemented (in
ductive use of natural resource systems in many “nested enterprises”) at the lowest appropriate
locations. Instead, communities of individuals level of decision making.
have relied on institutions resembling neither the
state nor the market to govern resource systems
with considerable degrees of success over long In conclusion on this point, we can observe
periods of time. Long-time neighbors, driven by that poor people, under certain conditions, enter
maintaining their reputation as reliable members into activities of a long-term, sustainable nature.
of the community and recognizing the need for Again, we are led to search behind the hypothe-
sustained future resource availability, expect also sis to explain particular behavior, and Ostrom’s
their offspring to be subject similar conditions. “design principles” point in a very interesting
Hence, people have developed, independent of and plausible direction.
the market and the State, sustainable CPR man-
agement institutions, which facilitate access to H2b: Poverty increases risk-aversion and discount
essential resources across time. rates, aggravating environmental pressure. It is often

8
assumed that poorer people have higher dis- Rhoades (1988) describes how poor farmers
count rates than richer people. For example, the respond to enhanced levels of risk of crop failure
World Bank’s Forestry Policy (1991, p. 11) cites by diversifying land allocation and scattering
high private discount rates, especially among parcels over a larger area in consent with other
poor people who depends on the forests, as a farmers. By cultivating lands of different soil
driving force behind deforestation. types, quality and altitude, they manage to
Pearce and Warford (1993) identify a vicious reduce their risks from pest or climate variability
circle between poverty, high discount rates and in a cost-effective way.
environmental degradation by arguing that: These results have important policy implica-
“High discount rates are one cause of environmental tions. For instance, farmers with differing levels
degradation because they encourage individuals to opt of wealth would have different willingness and
for short-term measures that satisfy immediate needs ability to undertake long-term investments. For
instance, a flat (uniform) subsidy of e.g. soil con-
or wants and to ignore more environmentally appro-
servation to individual farmers would induce
priate practices such as planting trees. In turn, this
some (presumably the rich) to act on the incen-
environmental degradation leads to the poverty that
tive whereas others (the poor) would fail to act,
causes high discount rates” (p. 72). They also argue
due mainly to poor people’s lower valuation of
that poverty-induced high discount rates not future benefits. Although poor people often have
only delay pay-offs and prevent investments in lower opportunity costs, and thus would be
physical and natural capital, but also discourage expected to invest in labor-intensive activities,
investments in human-capital such as children’s their limited ability to await distant, uncertain
schooling. This would be particularly pertinent benefits—driven by high discount rates—would
where mortality is high and prospects for formal counteract such behavior.
employment limited. While higher discount Even if it is plausible that poorer people have
rates among the poor could be explained by sim- higher discount rates, the problem remains that
ple lack of resources which creates an urgent this would deter them not only from conserva-
need for immediate gains, there is also the fact tion investments, but also from investments with
that poor people often have to borrow in infor- a detrimental environmental impact. The same
mal, high-interest rate markets, as documented argument can be advanced with regard to risk-
by Leach and Mearns (1991). aversion; it deters people from behavior that

Box 9: Poverty, Risk-aversion


and Discount Rate
In a study of 240 households in the semi-arid, tropical rural areas of India, Binswanger (1980) uses an
experimental, sequential gambling approach with real pay-offs to identify attitudes toward risk. The house-
holds in the sample are predominantly poor, but with considerable variation. He finds that relatively poorer
people tend to be slightly more risk-averse. Although the estimated coefficients are largely consistent for the
poverty variables (salary, assets and net transfers) across all sub-sets (villages) of respondents, the results are
in several instances not statistically significant. The study does not extend to capture environmental impacts
of differing risk aversion at different poverty levels. Without explicitly translating his findings into implica-
tions on discount rate, Binswanger (1982) summarizes in a discussion paper based on broader empirical evi-
dence: “Farmers in developing countries are almost universally risk averse when confronted with prospects
with significant outcomes.“ and …“every local measure of risk aversion on a utility function would differ
according to wealth unless very restrictive utility functions are chosen.” [p. 392].
Based on an empirical assessment of farmers’ discount rates in Costa Rica and a review of 14 other empiri-
cal studies, Cuesta et. al. (1997) conclude that “[T]here is some evidence of declining discount rates with
increasing income, time frame, and size of investment” (p. 3). They show that several analytical methods can
been used to measure individuals’ real rate of time preference: e.g. experimental games-approaches using
binary choice, actual asset-choice models based on loans and land transactions, utility maximization models
reflecting valuation of inter-temporal cost-benefit streams, and Contingent Valuation (CV) using willingness-
to-pay (WTP).
In their study they apply CV and asset-choice models to reveal the real discount rate among 292 Costa
Rican small- and large-scale farmers. When faced with questions on past and expected price changes, and
their WTP for certain farm technology, 95% of the farmers show real discount rates in an interval from 15.1%
to 21.9%. The results show a negative relationship between income and real discount rate.

9
could be both environmentally benign, or envi-
ronmentally detrimental. While the tendency to Box 10: High Income
a lower investment level with higher interest and High Levels of Pollution
rates is ambiguous in terms of environmental By using a large cross-national data set, based
impacts, we can postulate (cf. Pearce, et al. 1990) on 95 indicators, Easterly (1997) attempts to
that higher interest rates makes it rational: answer the question: will rising income over
time for a given country translate into increasing
(i) to more quickly exploit exhaustible
quality of life? Data was collected for the years
resources (e.g. mineral deposits), as moving
1960, 1970, 1980 and 1990. The methodology is
income forward in time is more important based on linear or non-linear econometric esti-
the higher the discount rate, and mation of the pooled data, where each indicator
(ii) to maintain a smaller stock of renewable is regressed against the logarithm of the per cap-
resources (e.g. timber, soil organic matter), ita income. Environment is one of the indicators.
as the relative return of these (generally) Easterly identifies several strongly positive rela-
tionships between per capita income and emis-
decline with size and the opportunity cost is
sion of some pollutants, for example CO2, NO2
higher the higher the discount rate.
and SO2 in tons per capita, and wastepaper pro-
While sometimes tempered by the increased duction in tons per 1000 inhabitants.
capital cost in a high interest rate economy, these
forces do point in the direction of higher envi-
ronmental pressure. When capital costs are low, Shafik and Bandyopadhyay (ibid., p. 11) iden-
the incentive would be for poor people to tify, based on cross-country regression analyses
quickly exploit what is immediately available. from the 1980s, empirical evidence of an environ-
mental Kuznets-curve for urban concentrations
H3. Higher incomes increase some environmental of sulfur dioxide (SO2). Initially, the SO2 levels
pressure amount to less than 10 micro grams per m3 of air
at per capita income-levels around US$100. They
A feature of the H2 hypothesis above is that pov- then increase exponentially with income and
erty is assumed to increase pressure on local nat- peak at 50 micro grams at US$2000 per capita,
ural resources. But this observation immediately and then decline dramatically as incomes con-
invites the counter-hypothesis that high income tinue to increase to again achieve very low SO2
earners tend to put relatively more stress on the levels, but only at per capita incomes around
national and global environment, e.g. emission US$20,000-30,000.
of greenhouse gases, ozone-depleting CFCs, etc. In conclusion, it should however be noted that
This brings us to H3, which is not merely the in cases where environmental Kuznets curves do
counter-hypothesis of H2, but an argument about
exist, they may very well be influenced by poli-
the relationship between environmental degra-
cies, and should not be taken as an excuse for a
dation in poor versus rich economies. Hence, the
laissez-faire attitude. It is not a given that one
debate is much more macro-oriented in this case.
“must wait” for a certain income level before tak-
Examples when higher incomes at some levels
ing measures to mitigate environmental loss.
may increase environmental pressure include air
pollution from a larger pool of motor vehicles, Furthermore, despite real decline in emission
waste generation from greater consumption in or effluent levels, environmental pressure is still
general, and carbon emission from increased use positive and may be cumulative. This may have
of fossil fuels. a lagged but irreversible impact on flora, fauna
Some of these results are corroborated by and ecosystem functions, for example in terms of
World Development Report (World Bank, 1992), species loss. Therefore, flow indicators of envi-
which presents positive exponential relation- ronmental pressure are not sufficient in diagnos-
ships between per capita income, and CO2 emis- ing the level of environmental degradation.
sions and municipal waste per capita, respec-
tively. However, emission of some pollutants H4. Incomplete property rights reinforce the vicious
(notably sulfur dioxide) initially go up and then poverty-environment circle
decrease with rising incomes. This bell-shaped
pattern of increasing followed by decreasing The rural poor are normally the ones with least
environmental impact with rising income is often secure rights to their assets, and are often com-
called the “Environmental Kuznets-curve”.viii pelled to exploit open access resources for sur-

10
Box 11: Rising Income and Afforestation in Peninsular Malaysia
Between 1966 and 1981, Peninsular Malaysia lost about 236,000 hectares of forest each year and its total for-
est area fell from 9.65 to 6.82 million hectares. Rubber and oil palm plantations replaced much of the forest
lost. However, by the late 1980s the rate of conversion slowed, as industrialization and urbanization caused
the rural labor market to tighten and agricultural returns to fall. The area in agriculture grew 520,000 hectares
in the seven years between 1974 and 1981, but only 160,000 hectares in the nine years that followed.
Based on a regression analysis of the region’s 65 districts, Vincent and Ali (1998) found that deforestation
rates increased as per capita incomes rose until districts reached an average income of 1,100 Malaysian Ring-
git, after which they fell sharply. By 1987, practically all of Peninsular Malaysia’s districts had income levels
higher than that. Not only did deforestation rates fall, but farmers also left significant areas ’idle’ and allowed
them to begin to revert to secondary forest. As rural youth moved to the cities to obtain manufacturing and
public sector jobs and the farm population aged, farmers apparently decided to take more marginal farm
lands out of production.
Using a global pooled cross-section and time-series data set between 1961–88, Cropper and Griffiths (1994)
identify a similar inverted U-relationship between deforestation rates and income in Africa and Latin Amer-
ica. The Kuznets curve’s theoretically estimated turning point occurs at a per capita income of US$4,760 for
Africa, and US$5,420 for Latin America. Since these incomes are rarely obtained throughout most of these
regions (i.e. most of the observations occur to the left of the curve’s global maximum), the deforestation curve
is currently leveling off as income increases. The same results could not be obtained for Asia, due mainly to
the region’s massive effort at afforestation and the data set’s blunt definition of forest (no distinction between
forest plantations and natural forests), the authors conclude.

vival. The World Bank’s Forest Policy (1991, p. 11) Resources (CPRs) such as fisheries, grazing
specifically cites “weak property rights in many lands, fresh-water supplies and village forests. In
forest and wooded areas” as a driving force most cases the schemes have sustained change,
behind deforestation. In urban areas, the poor— without involvement of the government or mar-
commonly squatters and migrants—often lack ket transactions, over decades or even centuries.
tenure over their land and homestead. Poor pro- Based on the survey, the eight design principles
vision of public infrastructure investments in she identifies which facilitate sustainable man-
sewage, garbage collection and safe water supply agement of common pool resources are:
are at times justified on grounds of the illegal (i) clearly defined property boundaries, (ii) con-
nature of (urban) settlements. Incomplete prop- gruence between appropriation of the CPRs,
erty rights, compounded by the lack of public their provision rules and the local conditions,
investment and poverty reduce the individual’s (iii) consensus-like collective-choice arrange-
incentive for, and capacity to engage in, local ments for using the CPRs, (iv) adequate monitor-
environmental management. Tangible effects of ing, (v) graduated sanctions of violators,
these conditions in urban areas include poorer (vi) conflict-resolution mechanisms, (vii) at least
health, in particular increased incidence of intes- minimal recognition by the government of stake-
tinal infections and other communicable diseases. holders’ rights to organize themselves in CPR
In summary, there are studies that support the management, and (viii) nested enterprises (i.e.
hypothesis that tenure security (perceived rather principles (i)–(vii) coherently implemented
than formal) is correlated with the quality of locally, nationally or regionally).
environmental management. A cautionary note
is in order when drawing the policy conclusions H5. Population pressure exacerbates both poverty
from this evidence. The case described below and environmental degradation
brings out the lesson that merely privatizing the
rights, which is sometimes advocated by the It is often asserted that population growth or
“tragedy of the commons” school (Hardin, 1968) high population density impacts negatively on
in the name of environmental protection, can be the environment, and this, in turn, exacerbates
a counter-productive strategy. poverty. Most of SSA experiences unsurpassed
There are alternatives to privatization that rates of population growth, and there is a crucial
deserve consideration. Ostrom (1990) reviews nexus of interaction between population growth,
hundreds of robust schemes, in which predomi- poverty and environmental degradation (Cleaver
nantly poor communities have established self- and Schreiber, 1994). But the actual, location-spe-
governing systems to manage Common Pool cific links can vary.

11
Box 12: Property Rights and the Environment Box 13: Privatization of Common Property
Resources in India
Saxena (1988) shows in a detailed study of
forests with different property rights in Uttar Jodha (1986) shows that Common Property
Pradesh, India, how tree cover had degraded to Resources (CPRs) provide a significant contribu-
10% on forest lands owned by the Revenue tion towards employment and income genera-
Department, 50% in forests owned by the Forest tion for the rural poor in India. Based on data
Department, and 70% in forests owned and from 80 villages in 21 districts in dry regions of
managed by local communities and village for- seven states in India, he shows that the depen-
est councils. The study concludes that the level dence of richer households on CPRs is much
of effective enforcement of property rights was less. Further, the area of CPRs has decreased
crucial in explaining the level of degradation. dramatically during the last three decades, rang-
Hoy and Jimenez (1996) analyze the impact of
ing between 26–63% in the studied districts.
incomplete property rights on urban environ-
Privatization of CPRs was introduced to sup-
ments in Indonesia. Given variable property
port the poor, but the result was the reverse: 49–
rights, they estimate in a probit model determi-
86% of the privatized CPR areas ended up in
nants to the probability that households invest in
local public goods, specifically the households’ hands of non-poor, and CPRs held by poor were
propensity to purchase garbage collection ser- eventually sold to richer people to facilitate
vices. Among other results they “…find strong short-term survival. Jodha concludes: “Thus the
support for the hypothesis that reduced tenure rural poor collectively lost a significant part of
security significantly reduces the level of local the source of their sustenance through the
public goods”, and that “…going from squatter to decline of CPRs. This loss does not seem to be
moderate [tenure] security increases the probabil- compensated by privatized CPR lands given to
ity of garbage collection by 32%, while going from (or retained by) them. The situation calls for
squatter to high security raises the probability by greater attention to CPRs as a part of the anti-
44%” (p. 16). They also report an independent, sta- poverty strategy” (Ibid., p. 1169).
tistically significant positive relationship between
household income and the probability that house-
holds purchase garbage collection services.
Mink (1993), for instance, argues how the
Southgate, Sierra and Brown (1989) empiri-
cally estimate the causes of tropical deforestation poor’s living environment—characterized by
in Ecuador. Based on data from eastern Ecua- low quality and access to water—poor sanitation
dor’s twenty cantons and statistical Ordinary and polluted in-door air, and production prac-
Least Squares (OLS)-regressions to explain defor- tices impact negatively on themselves and oth-
estation, they come to the conclusion that it is ers. It is among others manifested in lowered
negatively correlated with land tenure security. household productivity, which further exacer-
bates the environmental degradation and pro-
vides incentives for households to raise large
There are several driving forces behind the
families. This would further contribute to pau-
population-poverty-environment nexus. Al-
perism in an adverse, dynamic pattern. Mink
though many poor people are old people or sin-
makes the case that alleviating poverty is a win-
gle mothers, many poor households are poor
because they are large, and large because they win strategy with respect to population growth,
are poor. Poor parents tend to produce many the economy and the environment.
children to secure income at old age, and pro- Lacking the means to move to a better envi-
vide labor to collect essential goods such as ronment, large households suffer from their own
water, firewood and fodder. Children also play (and others’) resource degradation. The mutual
an important role in attending grazing animals, interdependence between these factors sets off a
do other household chores and earn incomes by negative spiral: the poorer a household is, the
e.g. selling crops or other household produce. more children are needed to secure current and
Further, poorer households are large due to lack future livelihood. The larger the family is, the
of knowledge or means to sufficiently protect more resources it needs. The higher the resource
themselves against unwanted pregnancies. demand, the larger the pressure on the scarce or
Family size is also determined by social norms fragile surrounding natural-resource base. The
and cultural traditions. In some societies adults more degraded or depleted the environment, the
are also expected to have many children as a more children it has to have to secure old age
sign of wealth or fertility, or both. and provide essential goods and services. The

12
more time spent on collection, less time is avail- population density and environmental degrada-
able for education and human-resource develop- tion. The assumption that high population den-
ment. Less time for education will perpetuate sity will necessarily cause greater anthropogenic
poverty into next generation. degradation is exceptionally difficult to justify
Boserup (1965, 1986), however, has become the given the available evidence.” [p. 12].
principal representative of the contesting view. Based on the above arguments and empirical
She argues that resource scarcity and population evidence, it seems clear that it is not possible, a
growth jointly induce technological change, priori, to say that population growth or high
innovation and intensification, which does not density will result in environmental degradation.
necessarily impact negatively on the environ- Clearly, population growth plays a crucial role in
ment. Hence, poverty and population growth determining the quality and stock of natural cap-
become positive agents of change in a dynamic ital, but in many instances it is not the root cause
interplay, which often results in introduction of of environmental degradation. Rather than
more efficient production techniques. embarking on massive population-control pro-
In fact, empirical studies of the population- grams, underlying policy and market failures
poverty-environment links indicate validity of should be scrutinized and corrected first and
each of the contesting views, as shown in box foremost. Good economic policies, secure tenure
14.ix Hence, it might very well be, as argued by rights, political stability and a dynamic economy
Heath and Binswanger (1996), that the final out- can all contribute to alleviate the pressures from
come can go either way and is essentially driven population. Again, this reinforces the comple-
by policy; i.e. whether growing population pres- mentarity between different types of operations.
sures induce positive or negative environmental Much of this complementarity appears obvi-
change is ultimately and fundamentally driven ous: market-oriented reforms that stimulate
by the overall policy framework. urban job growth can attract surplus labor out of
In a summary view, Prakash (1997) who exem- a sensitive forest zone, and so forth. However,
plifies Boserup’s school of thought, states that one type of complementarity that has been given
based on empirical studies in Kenya (Tiffen et. little notice is one between community-based
al., 1993; Bradley, 1991; Ferguson-Bison, 1992) population control and environmental manage-
and the Himalayas (Ives and Messerli, 1989), ment (CBPE) activities. The interesting research
…”there is no fundamental relationship between by Population Plan International (Engelman,

Box 14: Population and the Environment


Pearce and Warford (1993) argue that there is strong evidence of negative environmental impacts of
increasing populations. They exemplify by referring to the strong negative relationship identified between
forest coverage and population density in 72 tropical countries.
Cropper and Griffiths (1994) state that: “…there is no question that population growth contributes to envi-
ronmental degradation…” (p. 250). They confirm this by estimating statistically the impact of increasing pop-
ulation pressure (defined as the rural population density), population growth rate and increased per-capita
income on deforestation, respectively. They use data from 64 developing countries between 1961–1988. Their
results indicate that population pressure as well as population growth are generally positively correlated
with deforestation. In Africa, for instance, the deforestation rate would increase 0.33% as population-density
increases with one person per 10 hectares. These effects are to some extent offset by increasing GDP and
GDP/capita.
Filmer and Pritchett (1997) assess the existence of a vicious circle between environmental degradation and
fertility. Based on data from Pakistan, they conclude that (i) firewood availability seems to be negatively cor-
related with fertility, and (ii) households living far from firewood have more children. Filmer and Pritchett
also present a model of population-forest cover interaction. It identifies distinct stages (or phases) across time,
in which population and forest cover alternately correlate positively or negatively depending on the popula-
tion growth. They cautiously conclude: “A claim that these results confirm the existence of a vicious circle
between environmental degradation and demand for children is clearly far too strong. The results, however,
are supportive of the notion that there is a stage in time in the relationship between environmental degrada-
tion, fertility, and land ownership rights during which children are in relatively high demand” (p. 31).

13
1998) provides a synthesis of the experience so empirical evidence. Where evidence is available,
far. From a population perspective, the experi- it often points in the direction of multi-causal
ence of several NGOs suggest that this approach chains, where the influence of a single factor
to linking conservation and reproductive health (tenure security, population growth etc.) is very
activities, at the request of community members, difficult to ascertain. Nevertheless, we have gone
can reduce costs for family planning service beyond the simplified statements in our hypoth-
delivery in remote areas by taking advantage of eses and discovered a diverse set of conditions
personnel and networks already developed for that will increase the probabilities of support or
conservation work. From the environmental per- rejection of the hypothesis at hand. While, “it
spective, women who manage the timing of depends” is not a very forceful conclusion, it is a
childbearing may be better able to manage com- useful one, if we know something about “what it
peting tasks, including the local natural depends on.”
resources, Engelman argues. We do conclude that “the poor as victims”
hypothesis of environmental degradation appears
quite plausible, and that it does open up an
Concluding Note
agenda of potential win-win operations that com-
We close this section by noting that the literature bine poverty alleviation with environmental man-
is richer in general assertions than in rigorous agement measures.

14
3
Synthesizing Poverty and Environment in
CASs

Poverty is a frequently discussed topic in CASs. poverty, and where weaknesses have led to high envi-
However, the sample of 34 CASs reviewed in ronmental pollution and increasing costs in main-
Ekbom and Bojö (1997) shows that it is rather sel- taining health standards in drinking water. Only
dom analyzed jointly with environmental degra- about 20 percent of collected sewage is treated. Fur-
dation. Poverty and environment are usually thermore, these weaknesses disproportionately affect
treated in separate sections, specifying separate the poor. About 92 percent of the urban population
activities, use separate evaluation criteria and without public sewerage services are poor” (p. 55).
indicators, and refer to different analytical back- The Senegal Poverty Assessment elaborates
ground documents: Poverty Assessments and on several of the hypotheses, among them the
Living Standard Surveys address poverty, and observation that the poor occupy unhealthy sur-
National and Local Environmental Action Plans roundings: “In spite of better standards of living in
and Country Environmental Strategy papers urban areas on average, a substantial number of poor
address the environment. live in the “quartiers flottantes” or squatter area in
There are however some good examples of peri-urban Dakar. Dakar serves as a magnet for the
joint analysis. Below we present some of them handicapped, orphans, and destitute who seek ser-
from existing CASs and PAs. The structure fol- vices, special care, or income from begging. Increasing
lows the hypotheses presented in section 2. More rates of rural to urban migration (and migration from
frequent analyses of this kind would greatly neighboring countries) appear to contribute to the
enhance the understanding and policy formula- problems of these squatter neighborhoods which have
tion of the inter-related problems of poverty and poor or nonexistent sanitation, often house up to 8
environment. people in a room measuring 1.5 to 2 square meters,
lack water or electricity, and are characterized by
H1. Poor people are the main victims of a bad housing made of discarded metal or cardboard. Such
environment environments become breeding grounds for increases
in disease” (p. 13).
The Brazil CAS capture the links between pov- The issue of environmental refugees, where
erty and environment aptly: “Since the poor tend environmental stress force the poorest to tempo-
to reside in the most polluted neighborhoods, they also rarily or permanently leave their homestead to
suffer most from health damages and reduced quality seek survival elsewhere, is addressed in some
of life caused by pollution” (p. 7). “About 20 million Poverty Assessments. The Kenya PA exemplifies
Brazilians lack safe drinking water and 40 million by stating that: “emigration from the better endowed
have inadequate sanitation services. These are two highlands to semi-arid districts, such as Machakos,
services where expansion of service is closely con- Kitui and Kajiado, in search of land, has been a major
nected to improving living standards and reducing phenomenon in Kenya in the last two decades or so.

15
Without this population movement, the incidence of by poor people, the Philippines CAS describes
poverty in the better endowed areas would have prob- how the upland areas are rapidly being popu-
ably been higher. However, this migration in search of lated due to lowland poverty and marginaliza-
land has had the effect of displacing nomadic tribes tion of small-scale farmers. The combination of
who historically used the land and watering holes for poverty-driven lowland-to-upland migration,
their cattle” (p. 19). inadequate farming techniques and extensive
The Niger PA states that “Migration is wide- deforestation, cause detrimental on-site and
spread: it is a survival strategy for individuals and down-stream effects in terms of soil erosion,
households in difficulty, a relief mechanism for house- reducing agricultural productivity, and siltation
holds and communities and a possibility of enrich- of vital infrastructure such as irrigation, hydro-
ment—but also of impoverishment; the poor migrate electric, and municipal water installations.
to look for food and work within Niger or to a neigh- The Madagascar CAS poses yet another good
boring country (usually Nigeria), often returning to example, and stresses the need to address the
the village during the period of cultivation. Some complex interactions between poverty, unem-
“come back only with an illness”, AIDS or venereal ployment, high population growth and environ-
disease. Migration of an entire family is a sign of mental degradation through an integrated eco-
great distress. These migrants attach themselves to nomic development strategy. It emphasizes
urban relatives and increase the masses of unem- specifically the issue of inequality by stating that
ployed” (p. 30). “poverty and population growth are the principal
On the argument that governmental policies causes of environmental damage, that environmental
create or reinforce a vicious circle of poverty- degradation leads to lower crop yields and infrastruc-
environment interaction with specifically severe ture deterioration, and that rapid economic growth is
impact on poor people, the Senegal Poverty essential to break this vicious circle”, but that ….”the
Assessment describes that: “Poor incentives in the structure of growth is as important to ensure that
market for charcoal only serve to accelerate erosion of economic benefits are distributed equitably, and that
soil and forests. …charcoal prices are not set to reflect development must foster the use of the most abundant
the full economic cost, and the permits are granted resource of the poor-labor” (p. 7–8).
according to the amount of charcoal produced rather Few, if any, CASs and PAs elaborate on the
than the number of trees cut thus providing no incen- issue whether poor people have shorter time
tive to manufacture the charcoal more efficiently. horizons, are risk averse or have higher dis-
….the revenues from the licensing system are con- count rates, and how that would link to resource
trolled by the Forestry Service, and not by the local use and environmental quality. Although the dis-
population. Local participation is thus essentially lim- cussion in the Senegal Poverty Assessment does
ited to serving as labor for cutting trees (a common not substantially address short- vs. long-term
activity of the poor). Thus rural communities have lit- investments, it touches upon the poor’s con-
tle incentive to protect this resource, and substantial strained time horizon by stating that: “…recent
incentive to cultivate land even if not optimal for the surveys show that obtaining food and seeds are of
soil, simply to prevent the land from being harvested greater concern to farmers….. These trends illustrate
by an outsider. This, in combination with national the current constraints faced by the rural poor—the
energy policies that keep tariffs on alternatives to need to choose between long-term investment in
charcoal such as petroleum high (largely to reap tax inputs versus immediate necessities, as well as the
revenue), also serve to accelerate deforestation rates” decline in cash income” (p. 29).
(p. 29–30).
H3. Higher incomes increase some environmental
H2. The poor are agents of environmental pressure
degradation
Interestingly enough, we note that very few
The Brazil CAS states: “…the increasing demand of CASs in our sample pay particular attention to
growing urban population for sanitation and trans- the impact of economic growth on the natural
port services remains unsatisfied, thereby generating resource base, pollution levels or the environ-
a cycle of urban pollution, health problems, and lower mental sustainability of that growth in the long
quality of life for the population at large” (p. 7). run. Admittedly, this is not a serious issue in
Implicitly addressing inequality as a trigger- some of the world’s poorest countries, but in a
ing factor to environmental degradation caused growing number of developing countries eco-

16
nomic growth is major contributing factor to nat- growth: “…In order to preserve the long-term natu-
ural resource depletion and pollution. ral resource base (and income base) in the rural sector,
The Indonesia CASs (1995, 1997) pursue the progress is urgently needed in controlling population
issue of growth and environment, and provide pressure, and in implementing an incentive structure
arguably the best examples: “Environmental qual- conducive to sound and locally-driven natural
ity and sustainability are an integral part of Indone- resource management. The collision course between
sian government’s stated development concerns. The managing the meager resource base, providing for
growing attention to these issues in the Government’s food needs, and supporting a growing population is
development strategy reflects an increased awareness now at a critical stage. As can be seen …declining
of the costs and risks of the worsening environmental availability of arable land lies at the heart of this colli-
conditions due to past growth, and the potential for sion, and is being driven over the long-term by popu-
continued environmental degradation in the future” lation growth, the increased demand for food produc-
(1995, p. 8). Further: “In spite of rapid growth …, tion for an increasingly urbanized population, and
Indonesia’s competitive position in low-skilled labor declining rainfall patterns” (p. 29).
and resource intensive industries is now being The Burkina Faso CAS asserts in many sec-
eroded…[due to] environmental degradation in areas tions that there is a vicious interaction between
such as forestry and large-scale mining” (1997, p. 7) population growth, poverty and environmental
“[T]he negative externalities of rapid growth have to degradation, and that “regionally, there is a strong
be captured and mitigated through comprehensive correlation between rainfall patterns, soil degrada-
institutional and regulatory structures” (1997, p. 23). tion, and the incidence of poverty” (p. 3). It empha-
It is explained that Indonesia’s historically lax sizes that environmental conservation and natu-
policies on natural resource extraction, particu- ral resource management are critical to poverty
larly in the forestry sector, facilitated growth, but alleviation and economic growth, and that many
also caused a “first generation” of green environ- activities, detrimental to the environment (min-
mental problems such as soil erosion. The ing of agricultural and forest lands), are indeed
growth initiated significant socio-economic tran- poverty driven.
sitions, including rural-urban migration and
massive industrialization, which facilitated sus-
tained economic growth, but also gave rise to a Concluding Note
“second generation” of new, primarily brown
environmental problems: water contamination, Even though several poverty assessments deal
solid and hazardous waste, urban and industrial with issues relating to environment, the focus is
air pollution, etc. often too narrow. To exemplify, the Senegal Pov-
erty Assessment analyzes health issues very
H4. Incomplete property rights reinforce the vicious well in a traditional sense. However, some
poverty-environment circle aspects remain unexplained, for instance the
large differences in health expenditures between
On the complex issue of property rights, the urban and rural citizens in Senegal: “it would be
Senegal Poverty Assessment writes: “The current worthwhile to examine through rapid qualitative
incentive system governing land and natural resource assessment why poor rural households spend so little
use states that land not under cultivation can be on health care compared to their urban counterparts
“leased” by the state to outsiders or others, without (e.g. because of income constraints, because health
necessarily requiring permission from the local popu- services are simply not available, because of low
lation. This practice only compounds the incentive to demand for modern health care, or because of the
maximize land use, and creates a disincentive to availability of low-priced generic drugs through
planting forests, thus contributing to problems of soil health posts…”(p. 36).
degradation” (p. vi). Here, as in many cases, the environmental
dimension of the issue is overlooked. While we
H5. Population pressure exacerbates both poverty do not know the specific answer regarding Sene-
and environmental degradation gal, the importance of access to biological
resources (“wild” or “environmental” goods),
The Senegal Poverty Assessment elaborates on biological diversity and poor people’s depen-
how poverty interacts, in a vicious circle, with dence on, and use of, it for good health is not
environmental degradation and population considered. The option many rural poor have of

17
obtaining traditional medicines and many other pressure, state and response, indicators of mate-
essential goods and services from local natural rial flows, soil-nutrient balances as well as the-
resources, can provide an important additional matic environmental indicators used by progres-
piece in the puzzle of understanding poverty- sive governments. The 1998 World Development
environment links. Indicators-report (World Bank, 1998a) and World
Our review shows that few CASs elaborate on Resources 1998–99 by World Resources Institute
the poverty-environment links, and we have (1998) present real data on some useful environ-
found few examples of good PAs in this respect. mental indicators, which however are somewhat
As pointed out in many studies, there is an limited due to lack of coverage and reliability.
urgent need to enhance the understanding of One promising attempt (World Bank, 1998b) is
how poor people depend on, interact with and the joint project developed between the Bank,
utilize their local environment for survival. For UNEP and regional institutions, where prelimi-
instance, poor people’s survival mechanisms nary indicators of environmental sustainability
developed in their inter-play with biological in Central America’s rural areas have been sug-
diversity and common property resources are gested. At present the indicators are preliminary
only superficially understood. and the project is in a development stage. The
As some of the empirical evidence corroborates approach, where pressure, state, impact and
the fact that poverty and environment are pro- response have been used as points of departure,
foundly linked and do indeed impact on each is however promising. Some of these and other
other through various means—it is also critical to indicators are presented in Appendix 1.
identify and systematically use appropriate indi- To understand the interplay between the local
cators to enhance our knowledge in this realm. environment and poverty, one would have to relate
Ideally, these indicators should encompass both the data gathered in a particular context to socio-
poverty and environment, and should capture the economic data from the same area. This would
allow us to answer important questions like:
mechanisms through which they are linked.
What might those indicators look like? Jodha • to what extent are different income categories
(1991) has suggested a large set of indicators cov- affected by natural resource degradation?
ering major agro-ecological zones and the urban
• to what extent are different income catego-
environment, many of which are relevant also
ries affected by pollution?
from a poverty perspective. Similarly, the World
Bank-report Expanding the Measure of Wealth: The answers could then guide targeted efforts
Indicators of Sustainable Development (1997) sug- to mitigate environmental pressures that have
gests e.g. soil-related land quality indicators for the greatest effects on the poorest people.

18
References

Agarwal, Bina, 1997; Gender, Environment, and Technical, Economic and Cultural Factors in The
Poverty Interlinks: Regional Variations and Tempo- State of Population Theory (pp. 239–255) by
ral Shifts in Rural India, 1971–91, World Devel- Coleman and Schofield [Eds.], Blackwell,
opment, Vol. 25, No. 1, pp. 23–52, Elsevier Sci- Oxford.
ence Ltd, U.K.
Bradley, Phil, 1991; Woodfuel, Women and Woodlots
Binswanger, Hans P., 1980; Attitudes toward Risk: (Volume 1), MacMillan Press Ltd., London.
Experimental Measurement in Rural India,
Bromley, Daniel, 1992; Making the Commons Work:
pp. 395–407 in American Journal of Agricul- Theory, Practice and Policy, Institute for Contem-
tural Economics, Vol. 62, No. 1 porary Studies Press, San Francisco.
Binswanger, Hans P., 1982; Empirical Estimation Cavendish, William, 1997; The Complexity of the
And Use Of Risk Preferences: Discussion”, Commons: Environmental resource demands in
pp. 391–393 in American Journal of Agricul- Rural Zimbabwe, mimeo [processed], Centre for
tural Economics, Vol. 64, No. 2 the Study of African Economies, Oxford Uni-
Binswanger, Hans P., 1989; Brazilian Policies that versity, Oxford
Encourage Deforestation in Brazil, Environment Cropper M. and C. Griffiths, 1994; The Interaction
Department Working Paper No. 16, World of Population Growth and Environmental Quality,
Bank. Washington D.C. American Economic Review, Papers and Pro-
Bojö, Jan, Karl-Göran Mäler, and Lena Unemo, ceedings Edition, vol. 84, no. 2, pp. 250–254.
1992; Environment and Development: an Eco- Cuesta, Mauricio, Gerald Carlson, and Ernst
nomic Approach, [2nd ed.] Kluwer Academic Lutz, 1997; An Empirical Assessment of Farmers’
Publishers, The Netherlands. Discount Rates in Costa Rica, Environment
Bojö, Jan, 1997; Structural Adjustment and the Department, World Bank. Washington D.C.
Environment: A Review of Studies with Emphasis Dasgupta, Partha, 1995; Population, Poverty And
on Sub-Saharan Africa in Forum for Develop- Local Environment, Scientific American, 272(2),
ment Studies [Ed. Olav Stokke], No. 1, 1997, pp. 26–31.
Norwegian Institute of International Affairs,
Flekkefjord. Dasgupta, Partha, and Karl-Göran Mäler, 1994;
Poverty, Institutions, and the Environmental-
Boserup, Ester, 1965; The Conditions of Agricul- Resource Base, World Bank. Washington D.C.
tural Growth, Allen and Unwin, London.
Easterly, William, 1997; Life During Growth: a com-
Boserup, Ester, 1986; Shifts in the Determinants of pendium of political, social and environmental
Fertility in the Developing World: Environmental, indicators of what gets better and what gets worse

19
from low to high income, Working paper no. 17, Property Rights, Working paper no. 14, Policy
Policy Research Department, World Bank. Research Department, World Bank. Washing-
Washington D.C. ton D.C.
Ekbom, Anders, and Jan Bojö, 1997; Mainstream- International Journal of Ecological Economics,
ing Environment in Country Assistance Strategies, 1998; Special Issue: The ‘Environmental Kuznets
Discussion Paper No. 1, Environment Group, Curve’ (Vol. 25, Nr. 2), International Society of
Africa Region, World Bank. Washington D.C. Ecological Economics.
Engelman, R., 1998; Plan & Conserve: A Source Ives, J., and B. Messerli, 1989; The Himalayan
Book on Linking Population and Environmental Dilemma: Reconciling Development and Conserva-
Services in Communities. Population Plan Inter- tion, Routledge/United Nations University,
national, Washington, D.C. London.

English J., Mary Tiffen, and Michael Mortimore, Jodha, N.S., 1986; Common Property Resources and
1994; Land Resource Management in Machakos Rural Poor in Dry Regions of India, Economic &
District, Kenya 1930–1990, World Bank. Wash- Political Weekly, Vol. 21 (27): 1169–81
ington D.C. Journal of Environment and Development Eco-
nomics, 1997; Special Issue: The ‘Environmental
Ferguson-Bison, D., 1992; Rational Land Manage-
Kuznets Curve’ (Vol. 2, Issue 4), Cambridge
ment in the Face of Demographic Pressure: Obsta-
University Press, Cambridge, UK.
cles and Opportunities for Rural Men and Women,
Ambio 21 (1): 90–94. Kramer, R.A., N. Sharma, and M. Munasinghe,
1995; Valuing Tropical Forests: Methodolgoy and
Filmer, Deon, and Lant Pritchett, 1996; Environ- Case Study of Madagascar, Environment Paper
mental degradation and the Demand for Children: No. 13, World Bank. Washington D.C.
Searching for the Vicious circle, Working paper
no. 12, Policy Research Department, World Leach, Melissa, and Robin Mearns, 1991; Poverty
Bank. Washington D.C. and Environment in Developing Countries: An
Overview Study. Insitute of Development Stud-
Green, Cynthia P. [Ed.], 1993; Sustainable Develop- ies, Sussex, UK. Processed.
ment: Population and the Environment, Academy
Lopez, Ramon, 1997; Where Development Can or
for Educational Development, Washington D.C.
Cannot Go—The Role of Poverty and Environ-
Hardin, Garrett, 1968; The Tragedy of the Com- ment, World Bank, Washington D.C.
mons, in Science, Vol. 162, pp: 1243–48. Mahar, Dennis, 1988; Government Policies and
Heath, John, and Hans Binswanger, 1996; Natural Deforestation in Brazil’s Amazon Region, Envi-
Resource Degradation Effects Of Poverty And Pop- ronment Department Working Paper No. 7,
ulation Growth Are Largely Policy Induced: The World Bank. Washington D.C.
Case Of Colombia in Journal of Environment Mink, S., 1993; Poverty, Population and the Envi-
and Development Economics, Vol. 1: pp. 65–83. ronment, Discussion paper no. 189, World
Bank, Washington D.C.
Holden, Stein, Bekele Shiferaw, and Mette Wik,
1996; Poverty, Market Imperfections, and Time Munasinghe, M., and W. Cruz, 1995. Economy-
Preferences: of Relevance for Environmental Pol- wide Policies and the Environment, Lessons from
icy?, Discussion paper #D-26/1996, Depart- Experience, Environment paper No. 9, World
ment of Economics and Social Sciences, Agri- Bank. Washington D.C.
cultural University of Norway. Myers, Norman, and Jennifer Kent, 1995; Environ-
Holden, Stein T., 1997; Adjustment Policies, Peasant mental Exodus—An Emergent Crisis in the Global
Household Resource Allocation and Deforestation Arena, Climate Institute, Washington D.C.
in Northern Zambia: an Overview and some Policy Ostrom, Elinor, 1990; Governing the Commons: the
Conclusions in Forum for Development Studies Evolution of Institutions for Collective Actions,
[Ed. Olav Stokke], No. 1, 1997, Norwegian Cambridge University Press, New York.
Institute of International Affairs, Flekkefjord.
Pearce, David, E. Barbier, and A. Markandya, 1990;
Hoy, Michael, and Emmanuel Jimenez, 1996; The Sustainable Development: Economics and Environ-
Impact on the Urban Environment of Incomplete ment in the Third World. Edward Elgar, London.

20
Pearce, David W., and Jeremy J. Warford, 1993; analysis of intra-urban differentials within the
World Without End—Economics, Environment Greater Accra Metropolitan Area, Ghana, Envi-
and Sustainable Development, Oxford University ronment and Urbanization, 5(2):10–34.
Press, New York
Southgate, Douglas, Rodrigo Sierra, and
Prakash, Sanjev, 1997; Poverty and Environment Lawrence Brown, 1989; The Causes of Tropical
Linkages in Mountains and Uplands: Reflections Deforestation in Ecuador: A Statistical Analysis,
on the “Poverty Trap” thesis, CREED Working LEEC Paper 89-09, IIED/UCL London Envi-
paper Series No 12, IIED, London. ronmental Economics Centre.
Ravallion, Martin, 1992; Poverty Comparisons: A Tiffen, Mary, Michael Mortimore, and Francis
guide to Concepts and Methods, Living Standards Gichuki, 1994; More People, Less Erosion, Envi-
Measurement Study Working paper, No 88, ronmental Recovery in Kenya, John Wiley and
Poverty Analysis and Policy Division, World Sons, New York.
Bank. Washington D.C.
Vincent, Jeffrey, and Rozali Mohamed Ali, 1998;
Ravallion, Martin, 1998; Poverty Lines in Theory Environment and Development in a Resource-
and Practice, Living Standards Measurement Rich Economy, Malaysia Under the New Eco-
Study Working paper, No 133, Development nomic Policy, Harvard Institute for Interna-
Research Group, Development Economics tional Development.
Department, World Bank. Washington D.C.
World Bank, 1991; The Forest Sector: A World Bank
Reed, David, [Ed.], 1992; Structural Adjustment
Policy Paper. Washington, D.C.
and the Environment, Earthscan Publications
Ltd., London. World Bank, 1992; World Development Report
1992—Development and the Environment, Oxford
Reed, David, [Ed.], 1996; Structural Adjustment,
University Press, New York.
the Environment, and Sustainable Development,
Earthscan Publications Ltd., London. World Bank, 1994; Reducing Poverty in South
Repetto, Robert, and M. Gillis [Eds.], 1988; Public Africa: Options for Equitable and Sustainable
Policies and the Misuse of Forest Resources, Cam- Growth, Southern Africa Department, Wash-
bridge University Press. ington D.C.

Rhoades, Robert, 1988; Thinking Like a Mountain, World Bank, 1996; Toward Environmentally Sus-
Newsletter of the Information Centre for Low tainable Development in Sub-Saharan Africa: A
External Input Agriculture, 4(1): 3–5, Leusden, World Bank Agenda, Africa Region, Technical
The Netherlands. Department, Washington D.C.

Saxena, N.C., 1988; Social Forestry in U.P. Hills, World Bank, 1997; Expanding the Measure of
International Centre for Integrated Mountain Wealth: Indicators of Sustainable Development,
Development, Kathmandu. ESD Series No. 17, Washington D.C.

Sida, 1991; Poverty, Environment and Develop- World Bank, 1998a; 1998 World Development Indi-
ment—Proposals for Action, Stockholm cators, Washington D.C.
Segnestam, Mats, 1996; Poverty and Environment, World Bank, 1998b; Project Summary: Indicators of
Task force on Poverty Reduction: Working Rural Sustainability: An Outlook for Central
paper 10, Sida, Stockholm America (processed), Washington D.C.
Songsore, Jacob, and Gordon McGranahan, 1993; World Resources Institute, 1998; World Resources
Environment, Wealth and Health: Towards an 1998–99, Oxford University Press, New York.

21
Appendix 1. Selected Environmental
Indicators

Variable Pressure State Impact Response


1. Population •Population growth (% •Population density (p/ha) •Population distribution (% •Fertility rate (%)
rural, urban) •Population size (#) rural, urban) •Population projections
2. Socio-economic •GNP per capita ($US) •Employment structure (%) •Infant mortality rate (x1000 •% of GNP to Education
development •GNP distribution (%) •Income Gini Coefficient births) •% of GNP to Health
•Production structure (%) •Rural population w. service •Rural poor (%) •% of population
•Unemployment rate (%) access (%) •Malnourished children (%) immunized
•School enrollment rate (%) •Minors in labor force •% of women w. family-
•Rural literacy (%, by sex) (urban, rural; % of total) planning access
•Natural capital/cap. ($US, •Participation in
%) agreements, treaties
•Daily Caloric intake/cap.
•Agriculture labor force (%)
•Life expectancy (yrs.)
3. Land use •Pesticide use t/ha) Cereal production (t) •Erosion rates (t/ha) •Agriculture land needed to
•Fertilizer use (t/ha) •Cereal yields (t/ha) •Soil degradation index feed projected population
•Agricult. land per capita •Roots, tuber production (t) •Cropland affected by pest (ha)
(ha) •Roots, tuber yields (t/ha) and disease (%) •Agriculture research/
•Irrigated land (% of crop •Food-consumption change •Food export/import ratio training expenditures ($US)
land (%) •Nutrient balance •Potential agriculture yields
•Crop prices ($US) •Agriculture as % of GNP •Soil organic matter •Forest action plans
•Input prices ($US) •Cropland area (ha) •Soil loss volume (t) •Annual reforest. (ha)
•Grain-fed livestock (%) •Centers of crop prod’n (ha) •Soil compaction •Reforest./deforest.-ratio
•Land concentr. (Gini coeff.) •Wood reserve/production •Wood scarcity (% of pop.) •Deforestation projections
•Drug cultivation areas (ha) ratio •Forest fragmentation (ha) (ha/yr)
•Charcoal production (m3/ •Forest area (ha) •Carrying-capacity index •Restored/rehabilitated
cap) •Pasture area (ha) (AU/ha) surfaces (ha)
•Fuel production (m3/cap) •Land use/cover area (ha) •Erosion-affected area (ha) •Land-use proj. (ha)
•Annual wood production •Land use index (pot./act.) •Desertific.-affected area
(m3) •Net primary productivity (ha)
•Deforestation (ha/yr.) (t/ha) •Salinization-affected area
•Livestock population (#) (ha)
•Land-use changes (ha)
4. Biodiversity •Non domesticated land •% of natural areas •Conservation state •Protected areas
(ha) •Threatened species (% of •Biodiversity inventories
•Species extinction rates total) •Participation in
•Conservation condition •Endemic species (% of agreements, treaties
•Species (#) used in total) •Ecoregions needed for
agriculture •Threatened plants taxones representation in bio-
(#) regions
•Biodiversity distinctives
•Major habitat type

22
Variable Pressure State Impact Response
5. Water and Coastal •Population in coastal areas •Mangrove, coral reef area •Mangrove, coral reef/coast •Participation in
resources (#) (ha) line-ratio agreements, treaties
•Marine and continental •Annual internal renewable •BOD and COD in water •Protected coastal areas (ha)
catch (t/yr) water resources (m3/cap.) (mg/l) •Waters treated (%)
•Coast-tourist arrivals (p/ •Sectoral withdrawals •Pesticide, fertilizer •Rural population w. safe-
km of coast line) concentration in water water access (%)
•Water consumption (m3/ (mg/l)
cap.)
•Annual water withdrawal
(% of total)
6. Energy and •Fuel, wood consumption Hydro-power potential (G/ •Traditional fuels (% of total •Bio-energy potential (t)
Atmosphere (m3/cap.) h/yr) requirements) •Participation in
•Hydro-power generation •Installed hydro-power agreements, treaties
(total and % of capacity) capacity (G)
•Energy consumption (J/ •Energy reserves (tep)
cap.) •Dam efficiency (Kw/ha)
•Global warming net •Emissions (tC/cap.)
emissions (t CO2 eq. C) •Agriculture emissions (% of
•Net emissions due to land total)
use change (% of total) •Livestock emissions (% of
total)
7. Natural events •Frequency of natural •Population affected by •Financial losses due to •National plans against
disasters (#/yr) natural disasters natural disasters ($US) destruction of natural
•Lives lost due to natural disasters
disasters (#)
Source: World Bank, 1998b.

Tropical drylands
•sheet erosion, wind erosion
•lowered water tables, groundwater salinisation
•growth of inferior annuals, thorny and woody shrubs (i.e. reduced availability of useful biomass)
•declining crop productivity
•declining availability of common property resources

Mountain areas
•increased landslips, gully erosion, terrace abandonment
•decline in species diversity in pastures and forests
•substitution of cattle by sheep and goats, increased seasonal migration
•substitution of deep-rooted crops by shallow-rooted ones
•persistent decline in agricultural productivity
•increased distance and time involved in gathering fodder and fuelwood
•reduced fallowing, intercropping and crop diversification

Tropical moist forests


•declining species diversity, decline in forest area
•reduction in length and deterioration of vegetation, composition of fallows
•decline in useful species present in bush and fallow
•gully erosion

Tropical wetlands
•decline in useful macrophytes through eutrophication, chemical pollution and presence of metals
•soil drying and compaction

Irrigated lands
•waterlogging, salinisation
•mining of productive soil components (organic matter, available macro-, micro-nutrients)

Rainfed cropland
•sheet and gully erosion, declining crop productivity
•increased yield variability/ increasing rainfall variability
•increasing crop disease and pest damage
•reduced fallowing, intercropping and crop diversification

Urban areas
•Increased presence in human environment of health damaging pollutants and micro-organisms
•increased presence of toxic wastes in air and water
•declining availability of clean drinking water
•decreased quality and increased overcrowding of housing
Source: Leach and Mearns (1991) adapted from Jodha (1991)

23
End Notes

i. There are other arguments pertaining to the important determinant and effect of environ-
efforts to curb population growth, such as public mental degradation, and that investing in the
health aspects. These are valid, but outside of the environment is often a win-win solution with
scope of this publication. respect to poverty reduction. The reverse may
also be true. The report describes how rural poor
ii. The concept of “poverty” has been given sev- are marginalized or forced to intensify their
eral definitions. The most central concept is the resource use resulting in environmental degra-
poverty line, where the Absolute Poverty Line dation, which in turn exacerbates the poverty.
(APL) is the minimum level of expenditure Lopez (1997) argue that there might be a virtuous
deemed necessary to satisfy individual’s require- or vicious cycle of interaction between popula-
ment of food and some non-food necessities. The tion growth, environment, poverty and institu-
head count ratio measures the proportion of peo- tions. The final outcome is crucially determined
ple (or households) whose adjusted equivalent by policies, he argues. Sida (1991) and Segnestam
income is below the poverty line. The Food Pov- (1996) adhere generally to these views but also
erty Line is the minimum expenditure necessary emphasize, inter alia, (i) the extremely high com-
for satisfying food needs only. Depth of poverty, plexity of the issue, (ii) the importance of under-
often labeled the Poverty Gap Index, is the dif- standing these processes as well as the local
ference between the absolute poverty line and socio-economic and ecological context, and
the average consumption expenditure of the (iii) that pursuit of economic-growth policies and
poor, expressed as a percentage of the APL. The poverty-reduction policies without due attention
Gini Coefficient is a summary measure of inequal- paid at their environmental consequences entail
ity in the distribution of expenditure (for further serious inherent risks to the sustainability of the
reference, see e.g. Ravallion, 1992, 1998). Another very same policies.
set of definitions are derived in Participatory
Poverty Assessments and based on local peo- iv. This could be related to the type of cooking
ple’s perceptions and characteristics of that soci- fuel used; e.g. fuelwood as opposed to kerosene,
ety’s poor. For the purposes of this paper, we liquefied petroleum gas (LPG) or electricity.
have to accept the fact that different sources used
will be based on different definitions of poverty. v. See for example Kramer et. al. (1995) for a
We do not believe that this ambiguity should carefully conducted study to assess the compen-
stand in the way of a search a synthesis of empir- sation needs of local villagers in the vicinity of a
ical lessons. national park in Madagascar.

iii. The World Development Report on poverty vi. A word of caution in the interpretation of this
(World Bank, 1990) argues that poverty is an study is in order. The comprehensive impact of

24
the policy reforms must be taken into account time preference rate (STPR) or social opportunity
when evaluating the impact, not only the cost of capital (SOC). STPR is based on the elas-
removal of certain subsidies. Thus, it would be ticity of marginal utility of income (or consump-
enlightening to also include in the evaluation the tion) multiplied by income growth per capita
impact of changed incentives on the output side plus the social rate of time preference (“impa-
and other relevant reforms pertaining to the tience”). SOC is based on marginal productivity
profitability of Zambian small-holder’s agricul- of capital.
tural production, as well as other exogenous
causes of their purported behavioral change. It has been debated whether society and the
social discount rate should reflect “impatience”
This is justified based on the argument that it is by simply aggregating all individuals’ pure time
not the removal of fertilizer subsidies that has preference into the STRP and hence place differ-
made maize less profitable than other crops, ent values for nominally identical costs or bene-
increased slash-and-burn cultivation and trig- fits incurred across time. Based on the goal of
gered substitution towards environmentally sustainable development and inter-generational
malign local crops, but rather elimination of the equity, we argue that no such distinction can be
pan-territorial pre-planting prices offered to justified. Society has a responsibility, which goes
farmers, which amounted to a transport subsidy beyond individual preferences of the current
to their maize production (and marketing) in generation, to also include future generations.
remote areas. It is doubtful whether maize farm- Society’s discounting also includes an element of
ers in the relevant areas received or used much risk and uncertainty, which are normally identi-
fertilizer even when it was subsidized. More- fied by multiplying (a distribution of) probabili-
over, the analysis gives no guidance as to ties with utilities of various outcomes.
whether the changed input and output prices
provided, on balance, improved or worsened High discount rate are generally caused by (fear
terms-of-trade for most of the affected farmers. of) economic and social instability, and high real
Further, we do not know whether changes in for- interest rates in credit markets. A further compli-
est cover were (also) due to exogenous causes cation is the separation between risk-aversion and
such as population growth, in-migration, or “pure” discount rates. Conceptually, one can sep-
abnormal climate during the survey period. arate the valuation of future costs and benefits at
their expected values from the consideration of
vii. While it may be difficult to separate the time variance around those expected values. In prac-
horizon impacts from the discount rate impact tice, the distinction becomes blurred, and we have
by merely observing behavior, they are concep- found it difficult to separate the two elements
tually different factors. Time horizon refers to the when interpreting empirical studies. Hence, those
fact that some costs or benefits may not enter at two factors have been lumped together. For a dis-
all into the calculation. An example would be a cussion see e.g. Bojö, Mäler and Unemo (1992,
farmer clearing a plot of land with the perspec- pp. 65–71); Pearce and Warford (1993, pp. 65–80).
tive of harvesting for three seasons, and then to
move on. Another would be a farmer within a viii. The term stems from the seminal work of
rotational 5 or 7-year system, as traditionally Simon Kuznets, primarily in the 1950s, on the
practiced in parts of Ethiopia and Eritrea. While relationship between income distribution and
social forces are still at work to define acceptable income level. The debate about this curve
behavior, such a system does provide a definite applied to the environmental domain has
time horizon for investment decisions. become quite lively, and recent issues of the Jour-
nal of Environment and Development Econom-
Discount rate refers to the conceptually distinct ics (1997) and International Journal of Ecological
case of weighing future cost and benefits, perhaps Economics (1998) are entirely devoted to this
over a considerable time horizon. It is often theme, with articles covering indicators pertain-
divided into individual or social discount rates. ing to air and water pollution, inequality, defor-
Individual or private discount rates are primarily estation, trade, energy and traffic volumes.
determined by individual pure time preference
(“impatience” or individuals’ premium for ix. In addition to the studies presented in box 14,
delayed pay-off), risk and uncertainty. Social dis- Cleaver and Schreiber (1994) find that the defor-
count rates are either determined by the social estation rate correlates positively with the total

25
fertility rate in a cross-section of 38 countries in cients. In the simple cross-country sample, popu-
Sub-Saharan Africa. However, they also report lation pressure had the expected negative sign
that the econometrically estimated effect of pop- on the coefficient, but it is very small and not sta-
ulation pressure (cultivated area per person) on tistically significant. Cleaver and Schreiber con-
deforestation, having pooled the cross-country clude that “the result is therefore ambiguous and
sample, yield statistically non-significant coeffi- unconfirmed” (p. 72).

26

You might also like