Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 22

WHEN IT COMES TO PRODUCT INNOVATION,

WHAT IS SO BAD ABOUT BUREAUCRACY?

DEBORAH DOUGHERTY
McGill Universiy

SARAH M. CORSE
University of Virginia

In theory, bureaucracy is said to be “bad” for innovation. Yet large bureaucratic


organizations often need to be both adept at innovation and capable of ongoing
routinized production. Unfortunately, little is actually known about how
bureaucracy hinders innovation, since research on the relationship of structural
characteristics of organization and innovation is ambiguous. This study attempts
to illuminate the specific relationship between bureaucracy and innovation so as to
permit progress beyond the innovation-bureaucracy stalemate. Building on an
interpretive rather than structure perspective, we analyzed 134 people’s experiences
with product innovation in 15 large bureaucracies. We found four patterns of
bureaucratic thinking and acting that systematically inhibited effective action in
defining, organizing, evaluating, and staffing the innovation effort. These patterns
are described and illustrated at some length. Then, drawing on Weber’s original
theory of bureaucracy and other classics of innovation, we theorize that it is an
interpretive system of instrumental rationality, not only a bureaucratic structure,
that creates and maintains these patterns. From this insight we speculate on how
large bureaucracies can become more innovative without losing their efficiency.

Heightened global competition and changing customer needs are pressuring large,
bureaucratic firms to change their product offerings, or even to develop new ones.
Unfortunately, organization theory has little to say about how bureaucratic
organizations can become more innovative and still generate established products
efficiently. On the one hand, theorists argue that the bureaucracy is here to stay because
it is an efficient way to organize complex but routinizable tasks (Meyer 1990; Perrow

Direct all correspondence to: Deborah Dougherty, Department of Management, McGill University,
Montreal, Canada H3A IG5; Sarah M. Corse, Department of Sociology, University of Virginia,
Charlottesville, VA 22903.

The Journal of High Technology Management Research, Volume 6, Number 1, pages 55-76.
Copyright @ 1995 by JAI Press, Inc.
All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.
ISSN: 1047-8310.
56 THE JOURNAL OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Vol. ~/NO. I/ 1995

1986). Ideally speaking, according to Weber (1947, p. 339): “Bureaucratic administration


means fundamentally the exercise of control on the basis of knowledge. This is the
feature of it which makes it specifically rational.” On the other hand, evidence suggests
that bureaucracy is bad for innovation because it can squelch the creativity, nonstandard
activity, and speed of response innovation requires (Galbraith 1982; Quinn 1985;
Johnson 1988; Pearce & Page 1988). Popular writers admonish managers to “bust”
their bureaucracies to become innovative, but define the alternate organizing form only
vaguely in terms of nonbureaucratic structure, that is, nonhierarchical, informal,
decentralized (see Dumaine, 1991). Managers of large bureaucratic organizations are
caught in a paradox: they must innovate and maintain bureaucratic efficiency, but in
theory the two do not mix.
One reason for this apparent paradox is that we do not know how bureaucracy is
bad for innovation. Following Blau and his colleagues (e.g., Blau & Meyer, 1987) and
the Aston group (Pugh, Hickman, Hinings, & Turner, 1969), many innovation
researchers define “bureaucracy” in narrow structural terms such as hierarchy,
centralization, size, specialization, and formalization. But as Mohr (1982) and Nord
and Tucker (1987) show in two thorough reviews, these structural characteristics do
not explain the relationship between bureaucracy and innovation very well. Studies
on the relationship generate ambiguous results. For example, centralization removes
decision making from those who may know the most, but direct participation of senior
management focuses a team’s efforts and removes barriers (Day, 1994). Adherence to
formal rules inhibits creativity (Dougherty & Heller, 1994) but formal processes such
as phase reviews enhance a product’s design and development speed (Cooper 1983).
Centralized, informal structures enhance the adoption of radical process technologies,
but complex, decentralized structures enhance new product introductions (Ettlie, 1988).
Nord and Tucker (1987) conclude from their in-depth analysis of the literature that
innovation requires an organization that is flexible, concentrates power sufficiently,
generates effective inputs, and has appropriate levels of technology. They found that
a variety of structural configurations can produce these conditions, and conclude that
structural views of organization cannot adequately explain how to organize, or not,
for innovation.
The goal of this study is theory building to get beyond the paradox of innovation
and bureaucracy. For all its flaws, the bureaucracy remains society’s most legitimate form
of organizing, and is taken for granted by many. People cannot simply abandon it for
a new system of organizing, especially if that system is not fully described. Theories of
change management make it clear that people need to know both what is wrong with
their current practices (i.e., unfreeze), and how they should change (change and refreeze),
see Schein, 1979). In this paper we take a first step toward developing a more useful
theory of organizing for innovation by identifying what specific aspects of bureaucracy
hinder new product development. From that analysis we develop some insight into why
these barriers arise and speculate on what managers can do to overcome them.

ANINTERPRETIVEPERSPECTIVEOFBUREAUCRACY

The ambiguous research record indicates that conventional structural characteristics


of bureaucracy are not strongly associated with innovation. An interpretive perspective
Bureaucracy and Product Innovation 57

on bureaucracy offers another vantage point from which to explore how it might hinder
innovation. An interpretive perspective considers the ways in which people define a
situation, develop and maintain shared understandings, and make sense of their and
others’ beliefs and experiences. The conventional structural view sees “organization”
as a fairly static network of roles and relationships which channel information, decisions,
and authority. In contrast, an interpretive perspective sees “organization” as a process
of social action which creates and channels meaning. People understand their world
as they act, socially constructing meaning in context with reference to others (Daft &
Weick, 1984; Smircich & Stubbart, 1985; Weick 1979). In that process, people use shared
understandings or cognitive maps which may range from simple “theories of action”
(cf. Argyris & Schon, 1978) to institutionalized systems of knowledge and beliefs (Berger
& Luckmann, 1967). Bureaucracies are key institutions of modern society and, we
believe, engender their own set of shared understandings, some of which, we will show,
impede product innovation.
Both bureaucracy and innovation have been studied from interpretive perspectives.
According to Weber (1947), the bureaucracy embodies a particular type of rationality,
which he defined as a form of social action or a worldview. Weber distinguished two
types of rationality. Substantive rationality is oriented to values, such as religion or
duty, which are pursued for their own sake. A substantively rational organization would
emphasize complex qualitative goals such as justice or quality of life and commitment
to those goals. Choices are guided by values rather than by rules, but are rational because
values are consistent. In contrast, instrumental rationality is oriented to “the
methodological attainment of a definitely given and practical end by means of an
increasingly precise calculation of means” (Weber 1946, p. 293). An instrumentally
rational organization would emphasize what Parsons (in Weber, 1947, p. 36) called
“enormously simplified” goals and standards, universally agreed upon rules,
quantification, and formalistic impersonality. Weber based his theory of bureaucracy
primarily on instrumental rationality, not substantive rationality, even though many
theorists gloss over his distinctions and use the general term “rationality” in discussing
bureaucracy.
March & Simon (1958) att~buted a narrow form of rationality to limits in human
ability rather than to a worldview. Nonetheless their theory of organization is both
similar to Weber’s, as Perrow (1986) argues, and based on an interpretive view. To
them, the organization is comprised of programs, decision premises, and repertoires
of action that operate unobtrusively to limit information content and flow, highlight
some aspects of a situation over others, and limit search. A number of interpretive views
on organizations have emerged since, such as “garbage can” decision-making from a
loose formation of decision rules (Cohen, March, & Olsen, 1972), organizational
learning (Hedberg 1981; Starbuck & Milliken, 1988), organizational cognition (Sims
& Gioia, 1986), and organization culture and symbols (Gagliardi, 1990; Schein, 1985).
Together these and related works provide a good base for an interpretive view of
bureaucracy, but they have not been applied systematically to product innovation.
Innovation researchers have also developed interpretive approaches, however they
are in turn unconnected from organizational ones. Perhaps the most famous, but
unacknowledged, is Burns & Stalker (1966). They defined their mechanistic and organic
organizational forms as “interpretive systems,” not structures, even though most have
redefined their forms in structural terms. Burns & Stalker’s non-innovative mechanistic
58 THE JOURNAL OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Vol. ~/NO. I/ 1995

interpretive system was characterized by a differentiation of tasks that have been


abstracted from the whole, a precise definition of rights and obligations, hierarchical
communication and control, and an emphasis on internal (local) knowledge. Their
innovative organic system was characterized by an orientation to the interconnectedness
of tasks, the spread of commitment and responsibility beyond functionary definition,
network control and communication, and an emphasis on external (cosmopolitan)
knowledge. Burns & Stalker argued that “codes of conduct” for practice sustained the
two forms, but they never defined these codes beyond a vague sense of culture.
Unfortunately, innovation research since has not developed Burns and Stalker’s ideas
on “codes of conduct” either. Others have, however, reiterated their idea that an overall
perspective like a mechanistic interpretive system (which can be seen as the worldview
of instrumental rationality) thwarts innovation. For example, Schon (1967) argues that
what he called “technical rationality” hinders innovation by reinforcing sequential
development, functional separation, and precise measurement; Nelson & Winter (1977)
suggest that “economic rationality” ignores the complex, uncertain realities of
innovation; and Kanter (1983) describes the negative effects of a “segmentalist culture.”
Research has also considered the more day-to-day level of social action, where things
like decision premises or codes of conduct thwart innovation. For example, Burgelman
(1984) describes the anti-innovation effects of “administrative neglect” and an
orientation to the current strategic and structural context. Van de Ven & Polley (1992)
show how tacit patterns of funding-based planning, fluid participation, and a
proliferation of activities inhibited effective learning during a new product effort.
Similarly, Dougherty (1992a) shows how entrenched routines for defining markets and
evaluating products kept innovators from understanding actual market needs.

Research Questions. These various threads suggest that an interpretive perspective


can help us understand how bureaucracy hinders product innovation. The interpretive
perspective does not assume that people’s perceptions are necessarily accurate from an
“objective” viewpoint. It does assume that people act on the basis of their perceptions
of the situation, so studying those perceptions is important. To develop the potential
of this interpretive approach, we focus on the particular activities of new product
development in order to ground the analysis in both the specifics of new product
development and the everyday world of people at work. A large literature has established
that product innovators ought to do four things:

1) work closely with potential customers;


2) work creatively to integrate technology with market needs;
3) collaborate in multifunctional teams to pool diverse perspectives and coordinate
efforts; and
4) build on the firm’s resources and strategy (Cooper 1983; Souder 1987; Zirger
& Maidique, 1990).

Research also shows that people have difficulty in carrying out these necessary activities.
We investigate why these difficulties occur in bureaucracies first by looking for
underlying patterns of thought and action that may get in the way of effective product
innovation. We do not assume that simply generating innovation is good, but rather
ask why people have such difficulty even when they decide that innovation is necessary
Bureaucracy and Product Innovation 59

for a particular situation. We do assume that people in large firms wish to innovate
more effectively (as indicated by surveys, e.g., Arthur D. Little, 1991), but not necessarily
that they wish to innovate more often. Second, we develop a conceptual understanding
to make sense of what we find. We draw on the ideas summarized above to suggest
why these patterns exist and what can be done about them.

METHODS

Smircich & Stubbart (1985) suggest that to develop an interpretive understanding, one
must consider people’s reasons for their actions and the meanings they assign to events.
To generate data which reflect interpretive insights, we first approached bureaucratic
firms and asked to interview people who were actively working on a new product. The
15 firms that gave us access represent a variety of industries, and average 96 years of
age, 54,000 employees, and $9.4 billion annual revenue. Next we selected products in
consultation with a firm’s representative that embodied unfamiliar technology, were
intended for unfamiliar markets, or both. As shown in Table 1, the products vary on
their current success status, which was determined through follow-up phone calls two
years later, and on degree of innovativeness (see Table 1 for how each was coded).
Then we interviewed 134 people from a variety of departments who were working
on one of the products identified. Our focus in the interviews was on the person’s
understandings of the specific activities of innovation in the particular case; why events
happened as they did and how the person interpreted them. To that end, the innovators
were asked to tell the story of the product, and to describe how much they knew about
the market and technology, how they worked with other departments, two problems
in the innovation effort that came up and how they were solved, and if the firm had
“got in the way.” The interviews averaged one hour each. The people were all white
collar managers, engineers, or scientists from different departments, and averaged nine
years of tenure with the firm. Eleven described products that had already been cancelled,
while 123 described products that were still in development. Our primary unit of analysis
is the innovators’ experiences, not the merits of a particular product. For each product,
we tried to talk to at least several people who played an important role to get multiple
views about events in the product’s history. For 30 of the 40 cases, we talked to all
those identified by the contact person or product manager as playing an important role
in the product. We acquired multiple interviews for five of the remaining cases.
This is a nested design (Yin, 1989) in which the experiences of innovation are nested
within a variety of products which in turn are nested in a variety of firms. The extensive
variation in the data across industries, firms, and product types meets the criterion of
richness recommended by Bailyn (1977) and Eisenhardt (1989), allowing us to develop
a more broadly grounded understanding that is not bound to only one firm or
innovation type. In addition, multiple researchers brought different perspectives to bear
on the data. Data were collected over a two year period for many of the cases as well,
so we have some (albeit limited) insight into processes over time. We also combined
first order qualitative data with second order quantitative data. As Eisenhardt (1989)
suggests, combining these two data types helps researchers avoid focusing in on vivid
but perhaps limited qualitative impressions, while at the same time understanding
processes behind quantitative relationships. One important limit is that the data come
TABLE 1
New Product Cases by Current Status and ln~~vatjvaness
Current Status
In Market Success Not Cancelled in
Znnovativenessb Success Clear In Development Developmenl Failed

LOW Bond (3)” Bond (8) Bond (1) Bond (4)


(U~amiliar in one Food Item (7) Information Package (2) Information Package (1)
or two ways) Document System (2)

Medium Food Item (3) Rock Crusher (2) Specialty Chemical (1) Specialty Chemical (3)
(Unfamiliar in Chemical (4) Document System (5) Lubricant (3)
three ways) Office Product (4) Building Product (1)
Chemical (2) Machine (4)
Chemical (3) Solvent (4)
Information Package (I) Office Machine (1)
Food Item (5)
Chemical (3)
Communication System (4)
Plastic (6)

High Medical System (2) Medical Product (3) Communication System (2) Operating System (4)
(Unfamiliar in four or Expert System (4) Computing System (2) Site Mgt System (2)
five ways) Expert System (7) Robot (5) Waste-fix (4)
Warehouse System (1) Office Machine (1) Food Item (10)

No. Products: 5 16 12 4 3
No. Firms in Cat: 5 IO 8 4 3

(shows that results not due to data coming from only 1 or 2 firms)

Notes: ’ Number of individuals interviewed.


’ Five different ways to be innovative: new users, new uses, new product technology, new manufacturing, new distribution.
Bureaucracy and Product Innovation 61

only from large bureaucracies. We cannot compare our underlying patterns with those
in nonbureaucratic firms to assure that they are different, so important follow-up
research remains to be done.
To search for possible patterns of bureaucratic thinking and acting in the interview
data, we used the procedures for qualitative analysis described by Strauss (1987). The
first step in the Strauss approach is “open coding.” Working together and with research
assistants in multiple coding sessions, we closely scrutinized people’s descriptions in a
subset of interviews of how established practices failed them, how procedures that did
not fit were imposed anyway, and problems with understanding customers, working
with others and so forth. We were looking at how their ideas were organized, and trying
to understand the expectations, rationales, and attributions they used in order to identify
patterns of thinking and acting that lay behind the problems people described. For
example, when people described problems with other departments, we asked: What
conditions contributed to this inability to collaborate? When they said that senior
managers did not know much about innovation, we asked: Why were senior managers
seen as inaccessible or incompetent? The outcome of this step was a set of initial patterns
of thinking and acting that hindered product innovation.
The second step is “axial coding.” Here, each initial theme was explored across the
data in different types of situations, product types, and firms in order to “test” the
robustness of the idea and/ or clarify it. The analysis was guided further by descriptions
of how problems were sometimes solved, because (in this case) people often explained
why usual approaches did not work and how they developed alternate approaches.
Continuous comparative analyses such as these helped to sharpen the underlying
patterns.
The third step is “selective coding.” In this step, the boundaries of each pattern are
clarified to ensure conceptual distinction by content-analyzing the interviews. First, we
specified problem indicators for each pattern, and had research assistants code the
descriptions of organizational problems in all interviews into one of the four patterns
based on the indicators. The problems had been previously identified by Dougherty
& Heller (1994). The inter-rater consistency among the assistants was high, which
suggests that the indicators for each pattern could be distinguished.’ The codes also
allowed us to count how often each pattern occurred, and to compare and contrast
the relative frequencies across different groups of innovators to check our inferences
further.
Our analysis identified four patterns of bureaucratic thinking and acting that inhibited
the activities of effective product innovation. While we cannot assure that the patterns
are exhaustive and mutually exclusive, the Strauss method emphasizes the development
of categories with these characteristics.

1. Definition of the Product through Inward Orientation: Following this


bureaucratic pattern, innovators defined their new product narrowly from the
inside out, by emphasizing their firm’s internal resources and technology. This
penchant to concentrate on the technological side suppressed people’s ability to
appreciate the external world of customers and markets, to see how customers
would use the product, to understand how they perceive value, and to translate
customer issues into product attributes. Instead, innovators tended to ignore or
misinterpret customer needs.
62 THE JOURNAL OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Vol. ~/NO. l/ 1995

2. Organization of Innovation through Linear Progression: Following this pattern,


the innovation process was organized in a fixed, sequential, and linear fashion.
Not only was work segmented, but innovation was presumed to progress
methodically along already defined paths, where activities were only a small,
incremental step from routine. This pattern suppressed people’s ability to react
quickly to unexpected developments, to take up discontinuous lines of thought
or action, to incorporate surprising feedback on changing conditions, or to learn
from problems. Instead, people tended to conform to routinized processes even
though they did not work.
3. Evaluation of Progress through Detached Judgement: Following this pattern,
people evaluated the new product with standard rules or measures that were
detached from the complex reality of the market and technology. This pattern
suppressed the ability to evaluate the product’s new or unfamiliar aspects, to
develop workable heuristics, or to devise useful milestones to monitor progress.
Instead, the pattern produced false impressions of measurability and control and
kept people from understanding real progress.
4. Staffing Projects Through Dislocated Responsibility: This pattern chopped up
accountability and responsibility into fixed and narrow roles, which made it hard
to develop the collective accountability innovation requires. Ironically, this
pattern located the responsibility for product innovation in individuals, rather
than in organizational positions as is the case with normal bureaucratic work.
Dislocated responsibility discouraged people from becoming involved because
innovation was not seen as legitimate work, forced innovators to adopt a
marginal or maverick role, and prevented the development of a sense of collective
commitment to innovation.

Table 2 shows that problems with each pattern are widely distributed across the
products and firms. This is consistent with our idea that these patterns do not derive
solely from specific organizational cultures or innovation experiences, but rather are
properties of large bureaucracies in general. If these patterns thwart product innovation,

TABLE 2
Proportion of Firms and Products with Bureaucratic Patterns
Inward Dislocated
Orientation Linear Progression Detached Responsibility
(Problems with (Problems Judgemen t (Problems with
understanding organizing project, (Problems of risk averse climate,
customers, connecting to imposition of getting
markets) firm) standards, rules) commitment)

Percent of Firms 87% 100% 93% 100%


with one or more
people with indicator

Percent of products 80% 93% 88% 93%


with one or more
people with indicator
Bureaucracy and Product Innovation 63

TABLE 3
Average Proportion of Problems that were Solved by Products’ Success Status
Inward Dislocated
Orientation Linear Progression Detached Responsibility
(Problems with (Problems Judgement (Problems with
understanding organizing project, (Problems of risk averse climate,
customers, connecting to imposition for getting
market) firm) standards, rules) commitment)
N= 74 N=98 N= 74 N=86

Total Average** 40% 38% 26% 42%


Success Status
1. Successful 75% 47% 57% 62%
2. Out, uncertain 45 35 30 38
3. In development 25 40 18 51
4. Cancelled in
development 42 60 08 32
5. Failed 9 6 0 0
*p = .07 p = .02
without failures NS without failures without failures NS

Notes: Products innovativeness, stage of development, people’s department do not affect conclusions.
* based on one-way ANOVA
** only those who had problems are included

we would also expect that successful product innovators would solve problems more
frequently than others. Table 3 shows that, on the whole, successful innovators
overcame these anti-innovation patterns more often. Looking at specific patterns,
successful innovators solved more problems associated with designing and development
the product (i.e., Patterns 1 and 3). They did not solve more problems associated with
organizing their work (Patterns 2 and 4), although the data for Pattern 4 are in the
expected direction. We infer that connecting products to the firm and getting
commitment were not as necessary to a particular product’s commercial success as its
design. However, difficulty with these organizational activities even for successes
suggests that the organizations overall were not conducive to innovation.
Below we describe each pattern in detail. We also describe how people who overcame
the pattern tended to create alternate approaches to thinking and acting which enabled
them to carry out the innovation activity more effectively.

Definition of the Product By Inward Orientation

Research shows that successful product innovators link technological possibilities


with market needs to create a comprehensive package of design attributes (for reviews
see Dougherty, 1992b; Rothwell, 1977; Zirger & Maidique, 1990). Successful product
innovators have more knowledge about how the product fits into customers’work, what
the customers’ problems are, and how customers evaluate solutions to those problems
(Cooper, 1983; von Hippel, 1986). However, when we examined the difficulties with
product conception and incorporating market insights, we found a tendency to define
new products primarily in terms of technologies. Many innovators focused on the
product’s physical features such as how fast, hard, or resistant it was. Some did not
64 THE JOURNAL OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Vol. ~/NO. I/ 1995

consider knowledge of customer needs to be necessary. Others knew that such


knowledge was important, but could not figure out how to make sense of it. For
example, this planner was aware that she and her colleagues did not appreciate
customers as well as they should, so they hired a consultant to teach the team how.
But here she explained how gathering customer data was so foreign to their established
ways that they would rather, in effect, “retreat” to the technology:

We generally approach things too piecemeal; we muddle along. So we called in a


consultant to help us [learn to talk to customers]. The consultant had an iterative
process to get ideas and insights from customers in one and a half weeks. He gets
into the interactive process quickly. We were uncomfortable with decision making
that goes that fast. Instead, we like to go away for three months and work on the
product, and then come back and say to customers: “Here it is.”

This inward orientation could also be seen in descriptions of usual approaches to market
analysis, where “the market” was seen in piecemeal, idiosyncratic terms:

Doing market research is new at ZCO. With the old process, product design evolves
as customer needs present themselves or as design problems come up. There was
no marketing per se.. . We never did analyses in the traditional marketing sense.
It was always sales support. We would develop a product, and then find a customer
to try it on. A lot of [these products] failed because if they didn’t work for the first
customer, that would be it.. .
The market focus in this division is zero. Say we have a product that we think
Proctor and Gamble might like. We go to them and say: “Do you like it?” If they
say: “Well, maybe not,” that would be the end of that business. In fact, all the soapers
like Lever Brothers may be interested, but we never ask.

In another example, a sales director for a cancelled product recalls his attention to the
technology and his concomitant glossing of what customers were actually interested
in:

When we first talked to possible customers, we said: “Look at all the good
information the device can capture abut the operation of your machinery.” They
said: “Great, but what do we do with all that information?” So Jack worked like
a tiger for three months writing new software that would summarize the information.
We went back and said: “Remember when you asked what could you do with all
this information? Well, here are bar charts and histograms.” They said: “Great, but
what do we do with the bar charts and histograms?” Boy, I tell you, they sure had
us there.

Defining the product as technology was also self-consciously addressed by some who
overcame this pattern of thinking and acting. Here, a planner described how his group
first approached potential customers in the “usual fashion”:

Our division typically sells amine, which is a nitrogen with a few hydrogens. Another
manufacturer can combine these with other material-for example, amine and acid
makes nylon. We found out that we could make a few different kinds, so we went
to the marketplace and said: “Hey, we’ve got great amine if you want to buy them.”
Bureaucracy and Product Innovation 65

The group quickly found out that customers were much more interested in another
intermediary that combined amine with other chemicals. The innovators explained that
this time they caught themselves and deliberately stepped out of their accustomed
behavior. Instead of simply pushing their new amine as usual, they listened to customers,
and then developed a more comprehensive understanding of their product that
incorporated how customers would use the product and the actual performance
requirements they had. This more complete understanding helped the innovators see
the product attributes as a complete package, and thus to make informed trade-offs
among product quality, cost, delivery schedules, and performance as the development
proceeded.

Organization of Innovation Through Linear Progression

Research shows that developing a viable new product requires creativity,


experimentation, and occasional discontinuous leaps in imagination (see Van de Ven,
1986). To craft the full product under such conditions, product innovators need to
pursue multiple paths, test a variety of attribute mixes, and respond rapidly to customer
feedback. This requires mutually adaptive interdepartmental collaboration, in which
people jointly create the product over time (Mintzberg & McHugh, 1985).
When we examined how people actually organized their innovation activities or
organized the product’s connection to the firm, we found an underlying understanding
of appropriate work as a fixed, sequential, and linear process. One aspect of linear
progression was to separate development activities, as in this planner’s description of
how they normally first create and refine a plastic, and only then think about possible
markets:

[We normally] would do resins in ZCO very methodically. Something would break
in the lab or a research guy working along a particular avenue would create a unique
material, and then they would hunt around for a market. For example, we developed
a fiber product that skipped the knitting and weaving process. Our initial thrust
was to try and sell it for fabric, but now 20 years later we use it to line drainage
ditches.

Other ZCO people told similar stories of how people would invent a technology and
then spend years hunting around for applications. One material was developed for
automobile tires, but ended up 10 years later being used to make combat gear.
Unfortunately, ZCO’s penchant to break up innovation into discrete activities, took
far more development time than they could afford as competition increased.
Even though people recognized the inadequacies of linear progression, this pattern
was easy to fall into. Consider this person’s recollection of the launch of a new product
that was designed to prevent the counterfeit of important documents. The description
appears ludicrous to an outsider. However, he was the sales manager at the tail end
of a progressively linear process, and he was simply doing his job, developing sales
materials by following procedures which everyone understood to be appropriate:

We launched the product, and we did a brochure, and we did an in-house sales video
that won us a very prestigious award for sales education.. . And then we also
launched a formal market research program. We wanted to confirm the key vertical
66 THE JOURNAL OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Vol. ~/NO. I/ 1995

markets, and get specific customer viewpoints on what documents they are concerned
about. What we found was that there was zero customer awareness of security as
an issue. So we stopped the market research since we couldn’t find anyone to talk
to about it.. .

These people had no way to circle back and rethink one activity in light of another.
Unfortunately, the missing market assessment continued to plague the product, since
its sales were still quite modest after two years.
The penchant to proceed in a linear fashion is also clearly expressed in descriptions
of how this innovation-inhibiting pattern of thinking and acting was overcome. A
packaging expert compares his successful team’s development style, in which they
created in effect a multi-pronged, interactive network, with his normal work:

The reason the product was successful was that it was not in the usual organization.
I feel very strongly about that. You need to take all the barriers down and say: “Hey,
you guys are good at what you do, so go and do it”. . . . No one from the top bothered
us, so we could do what had to be done. What you lose in the matrix [DCO’s normal
structure] is contact. But if you are dedicated to a team, you can get involved and
spend time in other areas and understand their problems.. . Now I am back in the
matrix and I have 30 or 40 products to work on, and I can’t contribute much to
any of them.

The manager of a successful product at another firm also described a more inclusive,
comprehensive organizing mode:

At EC0 there is a lack of continuity on developing businesses. People move every


nine months.. . From the beginning we created a radically new organization. It has
two concepts. The first is that we did not want turnover, the theory being that if
you are going into a business that you know nothing about, you don’t want to keep
retraining people. Second, we had a long term incentive program installed [to
compensate for the loss of a career ladder].

These two examples highlight the use of what Yang & Dougherty (1993) label
anchoring. Anchoring is a learning process in product innovation in which the team
“drops anchor” on one problem area, working it out while working out other issues
in terms of it. The team then iterates to another multi-problem task, again anchoring
in one function but tying that to all the others. In this study as well, innovators worked
out organizational problems caused by linear progression by anchoring: creating an
alternate approach in which they could work collaboratively, revising decisions, learning
from experiments, and thinking more comprehensively and creatively. As these
examples also illustrate, the innovators had to violate the prevailing bureaucratic pattern
of linear progression to do so.

Project Evaluation By Detached Judgement

New products can consume considerable resources or easily fail, so it is important


to monitor them. Because innovation is inherently ambiguous, monitoring and
evaluating new products relies on qualitative judgements, heuristics rather than rules,
and knowledge which may be situation-specific and based on trial and error learning
67

(Nelson & Winter, 1977; Quinn, 1978). Instead of monitoring and evaluating their
innovations in this creative way, many we interviewed said that they or their managers
refied on general standards that were detached from the rich, compiex reality of
innovation. The detached judgement suppressed the ability to evaluate the unexpected
expenses, ambiguous possibilities, or uncertain knowledge of product innovation.
Perhaps the most obvious negative effect of detached judgement on innovation can
be seen in the application of short-term accounting measures to the emergent innovation
process. Decision makers attempted to abstract out from a complex reality formulaic
notions of cost/ benefit analysis, even when the necessary data were not available. This
drew people’s attention away from actual progress so that they could concoct
“numbers.” Consider the frustrations of these innovators:

The hamper to innovation is the analysis process we get into. Rather than use
judgement, they would much rather gather lots of data.. .
The business analyzers sit here day after day and get reams and reams ofprintouts,
all to see if the product is good or bad. That is nonsense. Nobody can look into
the future.
Traditionally we had to prove gO% assurance that the revenues are there. I. They
[management] want all the numbers that tell us it is profitable, with no risk taking
an their part. That takes two years. _.

The pattern of detached judgement was also embedded in the general “rules of thumb”
used by a firm to decide what is a “proper” new product. For example, one firm’s rule
of thumb was that it was a “pioneer” who entered a new market niche first and made
money from premium prices. One case in this firm was a follower product, so the
innovators had considerable trouble convincing others in the firm that the idea had
merit. Another firm had the opposite rule of thumb-it always entered markets as a
follower and standardized by emphasizing quality. Here, innovators who developed
a pioneering product had the same difficulty as those in the first firm--others were
unwilling or unable to consider the potential of their idea. This is not to say that concerns
over fit with a firm’s standard approaches were not valid, but in these cases the rules
were invoked arbitrarily.
Third, this pattern hindered the post-market phase for some products. New products
may need extensive revision after launch, but instead they were often assumed to be
ready for routine m~a~ement and evaluation (such as monthly cash flows). In one
case, the new product facilitated the cure of cancer, and thus was not fully developed.
It had been sold to several research labs and was generating modest revenue, however.
Given its “market” status, management placed the product in a %ormal business” mode,
forcing the director to focus on cash flows rather than on finishing development:

My boss is in favor of this project but he is an entrepreneur in the business sense,


not the technology sense. He looks at the project like a businessman would. Here
I am in day 59 of my new business and we don’t even know if the technology works.
But we worry about whether we will meet the profit objectives.. . Another culture
clash is that they are applying management by objectives and quantifying me by
the numbers on a monthly basis.

His marketing director also described the failure of standard budgeting processes to
take into account the emergent nature of their market:
68 THE JOURNAL OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Vol. ~/NO. l/ 1995

We do the budgeting annually. In fact, we are now in the process of coming up


with the numbers for next year. It is far too early for a start-up venture like this
to develop a budget for next year. If we were on our own we would not do this
until October, probably November, [7 months hence] because we don’t know where
we are going to be in the market. When we started this last year the funding [Federal]
for this approach to cancer treatment was on the rise so we made certain assumptions
and forecasts. When the source [shifted its priorities] our market expectations had
to be revised. Top management didn’t understand, and still holds us to those
numbers.

Some innovators broke away from the pattern of detached judgement to monitor their
efforts more realistically. In this example they relied on one another’s expertise and
judgement to “calibrate” their knowledge of the product’s progress:

I don’t see how we could ever do a new product without everyone all together. You
have to be able to share information between all of the functions.. . What good is
it to run experiments in the lab in test tubes when you really need to know what
the guy at the plant needs to produce in volume?. . . In the beginning when you don’t
know anything there is a long period where you rely strictly on baloney. By everyone
working together and asking each other what they know, we get calibrated on where
the venture is and what the potential is. The other way, when you do the product
one step at a time, you spend $5 million and you don’t have anything.

His marketing counterpart described how their interactive judgements and longer term
perspective deviated from the rest of the division:

It is important that even though this [new product organization] is set up under
the auspices of corporate R&D, the manager also has responsibilities for sales,
marketing, R&D, and manufacturing.. . We have many people in the group with
a good mix of backgrounds to draw on. I know very little about making a sale,
so I can go and ask the salesmen here about techniques. The boss is a territory
manager and knows how to run new businesses.. . The rest of the division is set
on the next quarter, so every time we go up to management we have to fight that,
and prove that our products are economical and that the risk is manageable.

Those who got around the limits of detached judgement created an alternate pattern
of thought and action which enabled them to develop useful heuristics to evaluate their
progress.

Staffing by Dislocated Responsibility

Burns & Stalker (1966) argued that innovation requires a deeper commitment than
routine work. The boundaries of responsibility must be broader and more inclusive
in the rapidly changing, ambiguous conditions of innovation. Individuals need to see
themselves as fully implicated in the discharge of the innovation task and as working
together for the common purpose of the firm, so that they can attend fully to the
“perpetual canvas of ideas and information outside the limits ordinarily set.. .” (Burns
& Stalker, 1966, p. 89). When we considered how innovators or others understood their
responsibility, we found that accountability and responsibility for innovations seemed
Bureaucracy and Product Innovation 69

dislocated and diffused, since no group of people legitimately held them. In a


bureaucracy, accountability and responsibility are ideally located in an office, not an
individual. Ironically, since innovation did not fit, responsibility for it became lodged
outside the usual system of authority, in individuals rather than in offices. This
dislocation meant that innovators could not rely on the established system to secure
broader commitment or acquire resources. Instead, they had to rely on personal
charisma and informal mechanisms.
This pattern of thought and action affected innovation in three different ways. First,
to take on a role appropriate to innovation as Burns & Stalker describe it requires that
one step outside the bounds of legitimate authority. This not only made innovators
uncomfortable, but also prompted others on whom innovators relied to refuse to
cooperate. A planner who worked on a new plastic explained how people in his firm
worked hard to avoid taking personal risk, and in so doing perhaps wasted far more
money:

People here who have a culture of “don’t screw up” don’t like to make mistakes.
They have a culture where they pull in their horns. They’ll spend 14 to 16 million
dollars a year with huge staffs on a new product and try to overwhelm any problems
that come up with people.

Another working on the same project described a widely shared attitude that individual
risk taking was simply not rewarded:

It is easier for people working here to ride the wave than to stick their necks out.
If you do stick your neck out it will be either positive or negative. You will either
succeed or fail. If you succeed, you are not much better off than if you hadn’t done
anything. If you fail, you lose-you are out.

In another firm, a person who worked in the venture unit, and whose job officially
was to innovate, described how she still felt marginal and unwilling to take risks:

My job, in a way, is to try and thread through all of the constraints [that people
in other departments put on a new product]. Sometimes I think I would like a job
where you just do the same thing everyday. Here, you have to do something new
and different every day. Since I have to work with people in other departments,
I get the sense that every time I call them they are thinking: “Oh God! Now what
does she want?!” Also, I will not develop a product idea that may cost a great deal
but bomb. I don’t have the courage or the will to push an idea that may bomb.

Second, both successes and failures were seen as the result of individual action, not
the result of normal organizational functioning. The innovators themselves were seen
in heroic terms; as champions when they succeeded or, all too often, as evil incompetents
when they failed. For example, managers in one firm attributed the success of a product
to the ability of the project leader to guide the product through the organizational
labyrinth. Two years later, a new CEO was hired to “straighten out the firm,” and he
cancelled all innovations, including this one. The project leader was still seen as
personally responsible, this time for the product’s failure. In another firm, people from
several departments formed a “board of directors” for a venture, while a marketing
70 THE JOURNAL OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Vol. ~/NO. l/ 1995

person was charged with day-today operations. When the product did not sell well
everyone (except the marketing person) attributed failure to the marketing person’s lack
of selling and interpersonal skills. They did not consider poor planning or organization
as causes for failure.
Third, dislocated accountability kept people from working effectively across both
lateral and hierarchical lines, since jobs were understood in narrow, pre-set ways. This
manufacturing manager described how established roles kept people from taking on
the broad responsibility a problem required:

When you run into a problem you say that it is someone else’s responsibility, so
you don’t ask the next question. You wait for an answer instead. In a major
corporation like this one you have professionals in the functions, and we are
intimidated by knowing that there are better experts for certain problems.. . We
had problems getting people to coordinate between engineering, research, and
suppliers on the packaging because of some deference to other people’s expertise.
They assumed it was another person’s job. It’s a turf issue, to not take another
person’s job.

Relations with senior management were equally constrained by this dislocated view
of one’s “proper” place, as in this description of how expectations precluded a frank
discussion with senior managers:

We view senior managers as adversaries so we hide our real issues from them. The
idea is, let me prove that I know more than anyone else. We will not reveal or share
our concerns since no one reveals or shares theirs, and we assume that management
won’t like it. But I really ought to say: “Here are the milestones, here is the meter
on the investment so far, and here are the three things that keep me awake at night.”
It would be nice to take advantage of their experience, but we don’t.

In another example, a woman described a meeting between the development group


and senior management. When a vice president asked an unanticipated question, she
said everyone in the room “shut up.” She was the only one brave enough to answer
“I don’t know,” she said, because getting fired did not scare her. We did not talk to
these senior managers, and cannot say if they saw themselves as uncompromising
ogres-we suspect not. However, people who have years of experience honestly felt
that they could not openly discuss the uncertainty and ambiguity of innovation across
vertical levels in their firms. People did not have the language or the framework to
discuss innovation as it really is, and felt pressured to distort their experience by
presenting it as routine to senior management.
Some innovators overcame the dislocation of responsibility by setting up direct,
personal relationships with senior managers and making public commitments to meet
certain goals that had been negotiated and agreed to by all parties. Others overcame
it by setting themselves apart in special “project groups” with broadened charges. By
stepping out of the established pattern for responsibility, these innovators were able
to create more collective commitment to the product without getting caught up in
concerns over risk or over proper boundaries to the expectations that were placed on
a job.
Bureaucracy and Product Innovation 71

TOWARD A THEORY: HOW BUREAUCRACY IS BAD FOR INNOVATION

The second research question required that we stand back from the descriptive findings
and develop a conceptual frame to explain them. From all these data, our first inference
is to agree with Weber, March & Simon, Bums & Stalker, and Schon-that an underlying
worldview or interpretive system was at play, not only structure. The illustrations above
indicate that people were aware that they (or others) approached problems with
innovation in a “wrongheaded~ manner. They could articulate that their usual approaches
to thinking and acting did not allow them to make sense of customers, react creatively
to unexpected problems, determine if a project was going well, and staff the effort, even
though they could not necessarily say why that was so. The trouble with innovation
in our data was pervasive, intractable, and affected people’s very day-today action.
Therefore, our first proposition for a theory of innovation in bureaucratic firms:

PI: Bureaucratic patterns of thinking and acting through which people


make sense of customers and understand how to organize to develop
a product inhibit their ability to innovate effectively. We predict that
among organizations with similar structures, those in which these
bureaucratic patterns do not prevail are more adept at product
innovation. Similarly, organizations that are more adept at product
innovation are less likely to have these non-innovation supporting
patterns of thinking and acting.

This proposition does not deny that structure also affects a firm’s capability to
innovate. It highlights the role of shared interpretations and understandings. We suggest
that patterns of thinking and acting are at least as important as structure in
understanding what makes an organization capable of effective product innovation.
Exactly how, when, and under what conditions structural characteristics such as
formalism, centralization, etc. affect the activities of innovation or reinforce a
bureaucratic worldview is a matter for empirical research.
Ident~ying these bureaucratic patterns of thinking and acting also remains an
important research question. Our description of these patterns is robust across our data,
we feel, but their final determination requires additional testing and clarification.
However, by connecting the four bureaucratic patterns of thinking and acting directly
to the activities of product innovation, we can explain the persistence and intractability
of problems with innovation, and provide a common thread among them. These
patterns are both consistent with and integrate a vast, disparate literature. They explain
why innovators fail to do market analyses (Cooper & Kleinschmidt, 1986), or learn
effectively (Van de Ven & Polley, 1992), or fail to break out of established technology
“architectures”(Henderson & Clark, 1990), but do fall into incremental “strategic drift”
(Johnson, 1988). To prompt research that will test and clarify our patterns:

P2: The four particular patterns described above are what hinder effective
product innovation in bureaucracies:
1) defining a product from an inward, technology orientation;
2) organizing innovation steps and activities in a linearly progressive,
incremental fashion;
12 THE JOURNAL OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Vol. ~/NO. l/ 1995

3) evaluating progress through criteria and rules of thumb that are


detached from the specific reality; and
4) staffing the effort by dislocating responsibility from the
organization to the individual.

All else being equal, we predict that failed innovation efforts are more likely to be
managed with these particular patterns of thinking and acting, white successful
innovation efforts are more likely to be managed with alternate approaches.
A third important question is where do these patterns come from? We have suggested
that bureaucracy as an organizing form induces, maintains, and reinforces these kinds
of practices rather than those more conducive to innovation. Indeed, at a general level,
our four patterns of thought and action are consistent with the dysfunctions of
bureaucracy described by Merton (1957), where procedural regulations become ends
in themselves, and the instrumental, formalistic aspects of jobs become more impo~ant
than substantive ones like good service to customers. However, our patterns connect
such generic dysfunctions in a detailed way directly to product innovation.
How bureaucracy engenders these patterns remains an important but unanswered
question. March & Simon’s (1958) early work suggested that this kind of limited,
segmented, abstracted approach to work would always occur, regardless of
organizational form, because humans are inherently limited. However, Weber (1947),
Burns & Stalker (1966), and Schon (1967) would argue that an interpretive system like
instrumental rationality creates these patterns of thinking and acting. Instrumental
rationality is a limited, narrow kind of rationality. The instrumentally rational
organization raises precision, speed, unambiguity, routinization, and knowledge of the
files to the optimum (Meyer 1990). Our four patterns are consistent with instrumental
rationality’s focus on well-connected means/ends relationships and readily calculable
activities, its privileging of the labelling, measuring, and evaluating of activities in the
same way so they can all be compared, and its reliance on rational-legal authority, which
presumes universal rules that extends to individuals only in so far as they occupy a
legitimate office (Weber 1947; Blau & Meyer, 1987). Inward attention to technology,
for example, is more amenable to “scienti~c” reason than are the shifting needs of
customers, linear progression fits the methodical perspective of instrumental rationality,
detached evaluation fits its universal rules, and dislocated responsibility fits with its
segmentation of work. To challenge others to investigate these possibilities:

P3: When it comes to product innovation, an interpretive system of


instrumental rationality is what is bad about bureaucracy.
Instrumental rationality emphasizes conformity with rules,
hierarchical control, and specialization. It orients people’s day-to-day
sensemaking toward compliance, measuring activities precisely
against standards, proceeding in a methodical, regimented manner,
and simpl~ying complex problems into discrete parts. Concomitantly,
instrumental rationality orients sensemaking away from the ability to
evaluate ambiguous conditions, respond quickly to the unexpected,
and notice possibilities not bounded by prevailing expectations. We
predict that organizations operating with an instrumentally rational
interpretive system or worldview will generate all four anti-innovative
Bureaucracy and Product Innovafion 73

patterns of thinking and acting, and innovate less successfully,


regardless of their structure.

Finally, drawing on the idea that a particular worldview causes the problems with
innovation suggests a more complete theory of how to organize for innovation. The
theory that instrumental rationality engenders anti-innovation behavior in large
bureaucracies provides an explanation for why people who are not individually
incompetent can nonetheless collectively work in a way which undermines the very goal
they are working toward. Innovation is a complex and uncertain process. It is hard
to make sense of new market opportunities or unfamiliar needs, because the information
about them is unarticulated and ambiguous. It is hard to coordinate large numbers
of people with diverse expertise. It is hard to evaluate the potential of unfamiliar ideas
and to tailor that potential to the capabilities of the firm. And it is hard to define people’s
roles and engender their commitment to such a task. Our analysis indicates that as
innovators sought to innovate, they and the people around them invoked the only
collectively shared patterns for thought and action they had-patterns derived from
instrumental rationality to foster routinization and methodical control. The inherent
difficulties of new product development were thus exacerbated at every turn by
bureaucratic instrumental rationality.
In addition, by bringing Weber and other early theorists back into the picture, we
can develop a more complete theory of the innovative organization and suggest at the
same time how large firms might start becoming more capable at innovation. If
instrumental rationality creates the anti-innovative orientation, then perhaps
substantive rationality would create an innovative one. Our data suggest that an
orientation to ends rather than instrumental means, and more value-laden goals such
as quality and customer satisfaction, helped innovators work on the ambiguous, hard-
to-measure activities of innovation. These innovators controlled the ambiguous task
of innovation, not by chopping the work up into separate bits, but by framing the overall
domain of action and then working more freely within that domain. Scholars such as
Schon (1983) Perlmutter (1984), and Etzioni (1988) have described how substantive
rationality is manifest in management, so that reflective, professional, and ethical
practice can operate. In addition, Simon (1979) advocates the development of what
he calls procedural rationality, which would enable people to deal with complex
problems which lack information.
However, we do not suggest that bureaucratic organizations should drop one narrow
kind of rationality for another. Rather, we propose that they learn to broaden their
rationality to include both kinds. Becoming more substantively rational would be easier
for the large bureaucratic firms than becoming nonbureaucratic, we think. A more
broadly rational system is still premised on “rationality,” which has meaning to
managers. As Simon (1979) points out, the dictionary definition of “rationality” refers
to being sensible and systematic, not only to measurement and precision. Burns &
Stalker (1966) argued that most firms needed characteristics of both the mechanistic
and organic form. Ritzer & LeMoyne (1990) also argue that Japanese management
ideology combines instrumental and substantive rationality, and it is the combination
which enables them to be both more productive and more innovative. In an interesting
analysis of the NUMMI plant, Adler (1993) argues that a bureaucratic efficiency can
be implemented in a way that enables learning, provided the social arrangements are
74 THE JOURNAL OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Vol. ~/NO. l/ 1995

premised on common goals, participation in defining key policies and standards, trust
and respect, and a balance of power. These, too, are substantively rational elements
of work organization. Weber (1947), however, argued that the two forms of rationality
could not coexist, since instrumental rationality would drive out substantive concerns.
Research on our last proposition would find out if Weber is still right (if ever)? Or
has the world changed significantly?

P4: An interpretive system or worldview that combines instrumental


rationality and substantive rationality would enable large,
bureaucratic firms to be efficient and adept at innovation at the same
time.

These propositions require additional study and analysis, especially the latter two.
Moreover, labeling the anti-innovation force within bureaucracy is not enough for a
practical theory. Research needs to explore the mechanisms by which instrumental
rationality becomes so deeply and thoroughly embedded in order to develop a more
complete theory about change.
In conclusion, we suggest that the tenacious problems with effective innovation are
deeply entrenched in the day-to-day culture of work and organizing in large
bureaucracies. Becoming more adept with innovation requires that organizations alter
their overall interpretive system along with their day-to-day practices. This suggestion
is disturbing, since it contradicts the popular literature which presents the innovative
organization as merely a matter of rearranging business units, adopting teams, or adding
a venture unit. However, we think that by combining classical theory with modern ideas,
we have developed some potentially useful reconceptions of bureaucracy’s relationship
with innovation that may help resolve persistent problems both in theory and in the
real world.

NOTE

I. Pairs of assistants coded subsets of interviews, with instructions to flag any problems they
disagreed over. They found only about 15 percent of the problems hard to code.

REFERENCES

Adler, P. (1993). The “learning bureaucracy”: New united motors manufacturing, inc. Research
in organization behavior, 15(pp. 11 l-194). Greenwich, CT:JAI Press.
Argyris, C., & Schon, D. (1978) Organizational learning: A theory of action approach. Reading,
MA: Addison Wesley.
Arthur D. Little (1991). World-wide survey on product innovation. Cambridge MA. Author.
Bailyn, L. (1977). Research as a cognitive process: Implications for data analysis. Quality and
Quantity, 11, 97-l 17.
Berger, P., & Luckmann, T. (1967). 7%e social construction of reality. New York: Anchor Books.
Blau, P., JL Meyer, M. (1987). Bureaucracy in modern society. New York: Random House.
Burgelman, R. (1984) Managing the internal corporate venturing process, Sloan Management
Review(Winter), 33-48.
Bureaucracy and Product Innovation 15

Burns, T., & Stalker, G. M. (1966). 7&e management of innovation (2nd ed.). London: Tavistock.
Cohen, M., March, J., & Olsen, J. (1972). A garbage can model of organizational choice,
Administrative Science Quarterly, 17, I-25.
Cooper, R. (1983). A process model for industrial new product development. IEEE Transactions
on Engineering Management, 30, 2-l 1.
Cooper, R., & Kleinschmidt, E. (1986). An investigation into the new product process: steps,
deficiencies, and impact. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 3,71-85.
Daft, R. L., & Weick, K. E. (1984). Toward a model of organizations as interpretive systems,
Academy of Management Review, 9,284-295.
Day, D. (1994). Raising radicals: Different processes for championing innovative corporate
ventures. Organization Science, 5, 148-172.
Dougherty, D. (1992a). Interpretive barriers to successful product innovation in large firms.
Organization Science, 3, 179-202.
Dougherty, D. (1992b). A practice-centered model for organizational renewal through product
innovation. Strategic Management Journal, 13,77-92.
Dougherty, D., & Heller, T. (1994). The illegitimacy of product innovation in large firms.
Organization Science, 5, 200-2 18.
Dumaine, B. (1991, June 17). The bureaucracy busters. Fortune, pp. 36-50.
Eisenhardt, K. (1989). Building theory from case study research. Academy of Management
Review, 14, 532-550.
Ettlie, J. E. (1988). Taking charge of manufacturing. San Francisco:Jossey-Bass.
Etzioni, A. (1988). The moral dimension: Toward a new economics. New York: Free Press.
Gagliardi, P. (Ed.). (1990) Symbols and artifacts: Views ofthe corporate landscape. Berlin: Walter
de Gruyter.
Galbraith, J. (1982) Designing the innovative organization, Organizational Dynamics, 10(3), 5-
25.
Hedberg, B. (1981). How organizations learn and unlearn. In P. Nystrom 8 W. Starbuck (Eds.),
Handbook of organizational design(pp. l-27).. NY: Oxford University Press.
Henderson, R., & Clark, K. (1990) Architectural innovation: The reconfiguration of existing
product technologies and the failure of established firms. Administrative Science Quarterly,
35, 9-30.
Johnson, G. (1988). Rethinking incrementalism. Strategic Management Journal, 9, 75-91.
Kanter, R. (1983). 7&e changemusters. New York: Simon and Schuster.
March, J., & Simon, H. (1958) Organizations. New York: John Wiley.
Merton, R. (1957). Social theory and social structure. New York: Free Press.
Meyer, M. (1990). The weberian tradition in organization research. In C. Calhoun, M. Meyer,
& W.R. Scott (Eds.), Structures ofpower and constrainl(pp. 191-217). Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Mintzberg, II., & McHugh, A. (1985). Strategy formation in an adhocracy. Administrative
Science Quarters, 30, 160-197.
Mohr, L. (1982). Explaining organizational behavior. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.
Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. (1977). In search of a useful theory of innovation. Research Policy,
6, 36-76.
Nord, W., & Tucker, S. (1987). Implementing routine and radical innovations. Lexington, MA:
Lexington Books.
Pearce, J., & Page, R. A. (1988). Palace politics: Resource allocation in radically innovative firms.
High Technology Mun~gement Research, I, 193-206.
Perlmutter, H. (1984). Building the symbiotic societal enterprise: A social architecture for the
future. World Futures, 19, 271-284.
Perrow, C. (1986). Complex organizations: A critical essay (3rd ed.). New York: Random House.
Pugh, D., Hickman, D., Hinings, C., & Turner, C. (1969). The context of organization structures.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 14,9 l-1 14.
76 THE JOURNAL OF HIGH TECHNOLOGY MANAGEMENT RESEARCH Vol. ~/NO. l/ 1995

Quinn, J. B. (1985) Managing innovation: Controlled chaos. Harvard Business Review, 3, 78-
84.
Ritzer, G., & LeMoyne, T. (1990). Hyperrationality: An extension of Weberian andneo- Weberian
theory. Working Paper, University of Maryland.
Rothwell, R. (1977). The characteristics of successful innovators and technically progressive firms.
R&D Management, 7, 191-206.
Schein, E. (1979). Personal change through interpersonal relationships. In W. Bennis, J. Van
Maanen, E. Schein, & F. Steele (Eds.), Essays in interpersonal dynamics. Homewood,
IL: Dorsey Press.
Schein, E. (1985). Organizational culture and leadership. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.
Schon, D. (1967). Technology and change. Oxford: Pergamon.
Schon, D. (1983). 77re rejlexivepractitioner: Howprofessionals think in action. New York: Basic
Books.
Simon, H. (1979). Rational decision making in business organizations. i%e American Economic
Review, 69, 493-5 13.
Sims, H., & Gioia, D. (1986). The thinking organization. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.
Smircich, L., & Stubbart, C. (1985). Strategic management in an enacted world. 7’he Academy
of Management Review, 10, 724-737.
Souder, W. (1987). Managing new product innovations. Lexington, MA: Lexington Press.
Starbuck, W., & Milliken, F. (1988). Challenger: Fine-tuning the odds until something breaks.
Journal of Management Studies, 25, 3 19-340.
Strauss, A. (1987). Qualitative analysis for social scientists. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Van de Ven, A. (1986). Central problems in the management ofinnovation. Management Science,
32, 590-608.
Van de Ven, A., & Polley, D. (1992). Learning while innovating. Organization Science, 3, 92-
116.
Von Hippel, E. (1986). Lead users: A source of novel product concepts. Management Science,
32, 791-805.
Weber, M. (1946). From Max Weber: Essays in sociology. In H. H. Gerth & C. W. Mills (Eds.,
trans.). New York: Oxford University Press.
Weber, M. (1947). The theory of social andeconomic organization. In A. Henderson & T. Parsons
(trans.). New York: Free Press.
Weick, K. (1979) fie sociology of organizing (2nd ed.). Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Yang, E.A., & Dougherty, D. (1993). Product innovation: More than just making a new product.
Creativity and innovation management, 2, 137-155.
Yin, R. (1989) Case study research (2nd ed.). Beverly Hills; Sage.
Zirger, B.J., & Maidique, M. (1990) A model of new product development: An empirical test.
Management Science, 36, 867-883.

You might also like