CH-Consumer Theory

You might also like

Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 14

Total and marginal utility For example, the second cup of tea in the morning

gives you less additional satisfaction than the first


cup. The third cup gives less satisfaction still.
People buy goods and services because they get At some level of consumption, your total utility
satisfaction from them. Economists call this will be at a maximum. No extra satisfaction can be
satisfaction ‘utility’. gained by the consumption of further units within
An important distinction must be made between that period of time. Thus marginal utility will be
total utility and marginal utility. zero. Your desire for tea may be fully satisfied at
Total utility (TU) is the total satisfaction a person 12 cups per day. A thirteenth cup will yield no
gains from all those units of a commodity extra utility. It may even give you displeasure (i.e.
consumed within a given time period. Thus if negative marginal utility).
Tracey drank 10 cups of tea a day, her daily total
utility from tea would be the satisfaction derived
from those 10 cups. Total and marginal utility curves
Marginal utility (MU) is the additional
satisfaction gainedfrom consuming one extra unit If we could measure utility, we could construct a
within a given period of time. Thus we might refer table showing how much total and marginal utility
to the marginal utility that Tracey gains from her a person would gain at different levels of
third cup of tea of the day or her eleventh cup. consumption of a particular commodity. This
A difficulty arises immediately with the utility information could then be transferred to a graph.
approach to explaining demand: how do you Table 4.1 and Figure 4.1 do just this. They show
measure utility? Utility is subjective. There is no the imaginary utility that Darren gets from
way of knowing what another person’s experiences consuming packets of crisps.
are really like. Just how satisfying does Brian find Referring first to the table, if Darren consumes no
his first cup of tea in the morning? How does his crisps, he obviously gets no satisfaction from
utility compare with Tracey’s? We do not have crisps: his total utility is zero. If he now consumes
utility meters that can answer these questions! 1 packet a day, he gets 7 utils of satisfaction. (Sorry
For the moment, we will ignore this problem and if this sounds silly, but we will tackle this question
assume that a person’s utility can be measured in of measurement later.) His total utility is 7, and his
utils, where a util is one unit of satisfaction. marginal utility is also 7. They must be equal if
only 1 unit is consumed. If he now consumes a
Diminishing marginal utility second packet, he gains an extra 4 utils (MU),
giving him a total utility of 11 utils (i.e. 7 4).
Up to a point, the more of a commodity you
His marginal utility has fallen because, having
consume, the greater will be your total utility.
However, as you become more satisfied, each extra already eaten 1 packet, he has less craving for a
unit that you consume will probably give you less second.
additional utility than previous units. In other
words, your marginal utility falls, the more you
consume. This is known as the principle of
diminishing marginal utility.

The principle of diminishing marginal


utility.

The more of a product a person consumes, the


less will be the additional utility gained from one
more unit.
A third packet gives him less extra utility still: practice, other things do change – and frequently.
marginal utility has fallen to 2 utils, giving a total The utility that Darren gets from crisps depends on
utility of 13 utils (i.e. 11 2). what else he eats. If on Saturday he has a lot to eat,
By the time he has eaten 5 packets, he would rather and nibbles snacks (other than crisps) between
not eat any more. A sixth actually reduces his meals, he will get little satisfaction from crisps. If
utility (from 14 utils to 13): its marginal utility is on Monday, however, he is too busy to eat proper
negative. The information in Table 4.1 is plotted in meals, he would probably welcome one or more
Figure 4.1. Notice the following points about the packets of crisps.
two curves: Each time the consumption of other goods changed
• The MU curve slopes downwards. This is simply – whether substitutes or complements – a new
illustrating the principle of diminishing marginal utility schedule would have to be drawn up. The
utility. curves would shift. Remember, utility is not a
• The TU curve starts at the origin. Zero property of the goods themselves. Utility is in the
consumption yields zero utility. mind of the consumer, and consumers change their
• It reaches a peak when marginal utility is zero. minds. Their tastes change; their circumstances
When marginal utility is zero (at 5 packets of change; their consumption patterns change.
crisps), there is no addition to total utility. Total
utility must be at the maximum – the peak of the
curve.
The optimum level of consumption:
• Marginal utility can be derived from the TU the simplest case – one commodity
curve. It is the slope of the line joining two adjacent
quantities on the curve. For example, the marginal Just how much of a good should people consume if
utility of the third packet of crisps is the slope of they are to make the best use of their limited
the line joining points a and b. The slope of such a income? To answer this question we must tackle
line is given by the ∆formula: the problem of how to measure utility, given that in
practice we cannot measure ‘utils’.
One solution to the problem is to measure utility
with money. In this case, utility becomes the value
that people place on their consumption. Marginal
utility thus becomes the amount of money a person
would be prepared to pay to obtain one more unit:
in other words, what that extra unit is worth to that
person. If Darren is prepared to pay 25p to obtain
an extra packet of crisps, then we can say that
packet yields him 25p worth of utility: MU 25p.
So how many packets should he consume if he is to
act rationally? To answer this we need to introduce
the concept of consumer surplus.

Marginal consumer surplus


In our example ∆TU 2 (total utility has risen from
11 to 13 utils), and ∆Q 1 (one more packet of Marginal consumer surplus (MCS) is the
crisps has been consumed). Thus MU 2. difference between what you are willing to pay for
. one more unit of a good and what you are actually
The ceteris paribus assumption charged. If Darren were willing to pay 25p for
another packet of crisps which in fact only cost him
The table and graph we have drawn are based on 20p, he would be getting a marginal consumer
the assumption that other things do not change. In surplus of 5p. MCS MU – P
Total consumer surplus
Total consumer surplus (TCS) is the sum of all
themarginal consumer surpluses that you have
obtained from all the units of a good you have
consumed. It is the difference between the total
utility from all the units and your expenditure on
them. If Darren consumes four packets of crisps,
and if he would have been prepared to spend £1.20
on them and only had to spend 80p, then his total
consumer surplus is 40p.
TCS TU – TE where TE is the total expenditure
If she were to use just a few litres per year, she
on a good: i.e. P Q.
would use them for very important journeys for
Let us define rational consumer behaviour as the
which no convenient alternative exists. For such
attempt to maximise consumer surplus. How do
trips she may be prepared to pay up to £1.10 per
people set about doing this?
litre. For the first few litres, then, she is getting a
People will go on purchasing additional units as
marginal utility of around £1.10 per litre, and hence
long as they gain additional consumer surplus: in
a marginal consumer surplus of around 30p (i.e.
other words, as long as the price they are prepared
£1.10 – 80p).
to pay exceeds the price they are charged (MU
By the time her annual purchase is around 250
P). But as more units are purchased, so they will litres, she would be prepared to pay only around £1
experience diminishing marginal utility. They will for additional litres. The additional journeys,
be prepared to pay less and less for each additional although still important, would be less vital.
unit. Their marginal utility will go on falling until Perhaps these are journeys where she could have
MU P: i.e. until no further consumer surplus can taken public transport, albeit at some
be gained. At that point, they will stop purchasing inconvenience.
additional units. Their optimum level of Her marginal consumer surplus at 250 litres is 20p
consumption has been reached: consumer surplus (i.e. £1.00p – 80p). Gradually, additional litres give
has been maximised. If they continue to purchase less and less additional utility as less and less
beyond this point, MU would be less than P, and important journeys are undertaken. The 500th litre
thus they would be paying more for the last units yields 91p worth of extra utility. Marginal
than they were worth to them. consumer surplus is now 11p (i.e. 91p – 80p).
The process of maximising consumer surplus can By the time she gets to the 900th litre, Tina’s
be shown graphically. Let us take the case of Tina’s marginal utility has fallen to 80p. There is no
annual purchases of petrol. Tina has her own car, additional consumer surplus to be gained. Her total
but as an alternative she can use public transport or consumer surplus is at a maximum. She thus buys
walk. To keep the analysis simple, let us assume 900 litres, where P MU.
that Tina’s parents bought her the car and pay the Her total consumer surplus is the sum of all the
licence duty, and that Tina does not have the option marginal consumer surpluses: the sum of all the
of selling the car. She does, however, have to buy 900 vertical lines between the price and the MU
the petrol. The current price is 80p per litre. curve. This is shown by the total area between P
Figure 4.2 shows her consumer surplus. and MU up to 900 litres (i.e. the pink shaded area in
Figure 4.2).
This analysis can be expressed in general terms. In
Figure 4.3, if the price of a commodity is P1, the
consumer will consume Q1. The person’s total
expenditure (TE) is P1Q1, shown by area 1. Total
utility (TU) is the area under the

The shape of the demand curve.


The price elasticity of demand will reflect the rate
marginal utility curve: i.e. areas 1 2. Total
at which MU diminishes. If there are close
consumer surplus (TU – TE) is shown by area 2.
substitutes for a good, it is likely to have an elastic
demand, and its MU will diminish slowly as
Marginal utility and the demand consumption increases. The reason is that increased
curve for a good consumption of this product will be accompanied
by decreased consumptionof the alternative
An individual’s demand curve product(s). Since total consumption of this product
Individual people’s demand curve for any good will plus the alternatives has increased only slightly (if
be the same as their marginal utility curve for that at all), the marginal utility will fall only slowly.
good, where utility is measured in money. For example, the demand for a certain brand of
This is demonstrated in Figure 4.4, which shows petrol is likely to have a fairly high price elasticity,
the marginal utility curve for a particular person since other brands are substitutes. If there is a cut in
and a particular good. If the price of the good were the price of Texaco petrol (assuming the prices of
P1, the person would consume Q1: where MU P. other brands stay constant), consumption of Texaco
Thus point a would be one point on that person’s will increase a lot. The MU of Texaco petrol will
demand curve. If the price fell to P2, consumption fall slowly, since people consume less of other
would rise to Q2, since this is where MU P2. brands. Petrol consumption in total may be only
Thus point b is a second point on the demand slightly greater, and hence the MU of petrol only
curve. Likewise if price fell to P3, Q3 would be slightly lower.
consumed. Point c is a third point on the demand
curve. Thus as long as individuals seek to maximise Shifts in the demand curve.
consumer surplus and hence consume where P
MU, their demand curve will be along the same How do shifts in demand relate to marginal utility?
line as their marginal utility curve. For example, how would the marginal utility of
The market demand curve (and hence demand for) margarine be affected by a
The market demand curve will simply be the rise in the price of butter? The higher price of
(horizontal) sum of all individuals’ demand curves butter would cause less butter to be consumed. This
and hence MU curves. would increase the marginal utility of margarine,
since if people are using less butter, their desire for
margarine is higher. The MU curve (and hence the
demand curve) for margarine thus shifts to the
right.

Weaknesses of the one-commodity


version of marginal utility theory
The rule for rational consumer behaviour is known
A change in the consumption of one good will as the equi-marginal principle. This states that a
affect the marginal utility of substitute and consumer will get the highest utility from a given
complementary goods. level of income when the ratio of the marginal
It will also affect the amount of income left over to utilities is equal to the ratio of the prices.
be spent on other goods. Thus a more satisfactory Algebraically, this is when, for any pair of
explanation of demand would involve an analysis goods, A and B, that are consumed:
of choices between goods, rather than looking at
one good in isolation.
What is more, deriving a demand curve from a
marginal utility curve measured in money assumes To see the sense of this, say that the last unit of
that money itself has a constant marginal utility. good A you consumed gave three times as much
The trouble is that it does not. If people have a rise utility as the last unit of B. Yet good A only cost
in income, they will consume more. Other things twice as much as good B. You would obviously
being equal, the marginal utility of the goods that gain by increasing your consumption of A and
they consume will diminish. Thus an extra £1 of cutting your purchases of B. But as you switched B
consumption will bring less satisfaction than to A, the marginal utility of A would fall due to
previously. In other words, it is likely that the diminishing marginal utility, and conversely the
marginal utility of money diminishes as income marginal utility of B would rise. To maximise
rises. utility you would continue this substitution of A for
Unless a good occupies only a tiny fraction of B until the ratios of the marginal utilities
people’s expenditure, a fall in its price will mean (MUA/MUB ) equalled the ratio of the prices of the
that their real income has increased: i.e. they can two goods (PA/PB). At this point, no further gain
afford to purchase more goods in general. As they can be made by switching from one good to
do so, the marginal utility of their money will fall. another. This is the optimum combination of goods
We cannot, therefore, legitimately use money to to consume.
measure utility in an absolute sense. We can, Equation (1) is a specific example of the general
however, still talk about the relative utility that we equimarginal principle in economics, which applies
get from various goods for a given increase in to all rational choices between two alternatives,
expenditure. The following sections thus look at the whether in production, consumption, employment
choice between goods, and how it relates to or whatever:
marginal utility.
The multi-commodity version of
marginal utility and the demand
The optimum combination of goods curve
consumed How can we derive a demand curve from the above
analysis? Let us simply reinterpret equation (1) so
We can use marginal utility analysis to show how a that it relates the MU and P of good A to the MU
rational person decides what combination of goods and P of any other good. In other words, the
to buy. Given that we have limited incomes, we equation would be the same for goods B, C, D, E
have to make choices. It is not just a question of and any other good. For any given income, and
choosing between two obvious substitutes (like given prices for good A and all other goods, the
carrots and peas or a holiday in Greece and quantity a person will demand of good A will be
one in Spain), but about allocating our incomes that which satisfies equation (1). One point on the
between all the goods and services we might like to individual’s demand curve for good A has been
consume. If you have, say, an income of £10 000 determined. If the price of good A now falls, such
per year, what is the optimum ‘bundle’ of goods that:
and services for you to spend it on?
this choice of (a) a change in the consumer’s
income and (b) a change in the price of one or both
goods. It can also be used to analyse the income
the person would buy more of good A and less of and substitution effects of a change in price.
all other goods (B, C, D, E, etc.), until equation (1) Indifference analysis involves the use of
is once more satisfied. A second point on the indifference curves and budget lines.
individual’s demand curve for good A has been
determined. Further changes in the price of good A
would bring further changes in the quantity
demanded, in order to satisfy equation (1). Further
points on the individual’s demand curve would
thereby be derived.
If the price of another good changed, or if the
marginal utility of any good changed (including
good A), then again the quantity demanded of good
A (and other goods) would change, until again
equation (1) were satisfied. These changes in
demand will be represented by a shift in the
demand curve for good A.

The limitations of the marginal


utility approach to demand
Even though the multi-commodity version of
marginal utility theory is useful in demonstrating
the underlying logic of consumer choice, it still has
a major weakness.
Utility cannot be measured in any absolute sense.
We cannot really say, therefore, by how much the
marginal utility of one good exceeds another.
An alternative approach is to use indifference
analysis. This does not involve measuring the
amount of utility a person gains, but merely
ranking various combinations of goods in order of
preference. In other words, it assumes that
consumers can decide whether they prefer one
combination of goods to another. For example, if
you were asked to choose between two baskets of
fruit, one containing 4 oranges and 3 pears and the
other containing 2 oranges and 5 pears, you could
say which you prefer or whether you are indifferent
between them. It does not assume that you can
decide just how much you prefer one basket to
another or just how much you like either.
The aim of indifference analysis, then, is to
analyse, without having to measure utility, how a
rational consumer chooses between two goods. As
we shall see, it can be used to show the effect on
the other good on the other axis. Thus in Figure
Indifference curves 4.6, which is based on Table 4.2, pears and oranges
are measured on the two axes. The curve shows
An indifference curve shows all the various that Clive is indifferent as to whether he consumes
combinations of two goods that give an equal 30 pears and 6 oranges (point a) or 24 pears and 7
amount of satisfaction or utility to a consumer. To oranges (point b) or any other combination of pears
show how one can be constructed, consider the and oranges along the curve. Notice that we are not
following example. saying how much Clive likes pears and oranges,
merely that he likes all the combinations along the
indifference curve the same amount. All the
combinations thus yield the same (unspecified)
utility.

The shape of the indifference curve


As you can see, the indifference curve we have
drawn is not a straight line. It is bowed in towards
the origin. In other words, its slope gets shallower
as we move down the curve. Indifference curves
Imagine that a supermarket is conducting a survey are normally drawn this shape. But why?
about the preferences of its customers for different Let us see what the slope of the curve shows us. It
types of fruit. One of the respondents is Clive, a shows the rate at which the consumer is willing to
student who likes a healthy diet and regularly buys exchange one good for the other, holding his or her
fresh fruit. He is asked his views about various level of satisfaction the same. For example,
combinations of oranges and pears. Starting with consider the move from point a to point b in Figure
the combination of 10 pears and 13 oranges, he is 4.6. Clive gives up 6 units of pears and requires 1
asked what other combinations he would like the orange to compensate for the loss. The slope of the
same as this one. From his answers a table is indifference curve is thus −6/1 −6. Ignoring the
constructed (Table 4.2). What we are saying here is negative sign, the slope of the indifference curve
that Clive would be equally happy to have any one (that is, the rate at which the consumer is willing to
of the combinations shown in the table. substitute one good for the other) is known as the
This table is known as an indifference set. It shows marginal rate of substitution(MRS).
alternative combinations of two goods that yield the In this case, therefore, the MRS 6. Note that as we
same level of satisfaction. move down the curve, the marginal rate of
substitution diminishes as the slope of the curve
gets less. For example, look at the move from point
e to point f. Here the consumer gives up 2 pears and
requires 2 oranges to compensate. Thus along this
section of the curve, the slope is −2/2 −1 (and
hence the MRS 1).
The reason for a diminishing marginal rate of
substitution is related to the principle of
diminishing marginal utility that we looked at in
section 4.1. This stated that individuals will gain
less and less additional satisfaction the more of a
good that they consume. This principle, however, is
From this we can plot an indifference curve. We based on the assumption that the consumption of
measure units of one good on one axis and units of other goods is held constant. In the case of an
indifference curve, this is not true. As we move a higher utility than those along I2, and so on.
down the curve, more of one good is consumed but
less of the other. Nevertheless the effect on
consumer satisfaction is similar. As Clive
consumes more pears and fewer oranges, his
marginal utility from pears will diminish, while that
from oranges will increase. He will thus be
prepared to give up fewer and fewer pears for each
additional orange. MRS diminishes.

The relationship between the The term ‘map’ is appropriate here, because the
marginal rate of substitution and indifference curves are rather like contours on a
marginal utility real map. Just as a contour joins all those points of
a particular height, so an indifference curve shows
In Figure 4.6, consumption at point a yields equal all those combinations yielding a particular level of
satisfaction with consumption at point b. Thus the utility.
utility sacrificed by giving up 6 pears must be equal
to the utility gained by consuming one more The budget line
orange. In other words, the marginal utility of an
orange must be six times as great as that of a pear. We turn now to the budget line. This is the other
Therefore, MUoranges /MUpears 6. But this is important element in the analysis of consumer
the same as the marginal rate of substitution. With behaviour. Whereas indifference maps illustrate
X measured on the horizontal axis and Y on the people’s preferences, the actual choices they make
vertical axis, then: will depend on their incomes.
The budget line shows what combinations of two
goods you are able to buy, given (a) your income
available to spend on them and (b) their prices.
Just as we did with an indifference curve, we can
An indifference map construct a budget line from a table. The first two
columns of Table 4.3 show various combinations of
More than one indifference curve can be drawn. two goods X and Y that can be purchased assuming
For example, referring back to Table 4.2, Clive that (a) the price of X is £2 and the price of Y is £1
could give another set of combinations of pears and and (b) the consumer has a budget of £30 to be
oranges that all give him a higher (but equal) level divided between the two goods.
of utility than the set shown in the table. This could In Figure 4.8, then, if you are limited to a budget of
then be plotted in Figure 4.6 as another indifference £30, you can consume any combination of X and Y
curve. along the line (or inside it). You cannot, however,
Although the actual amount of utility afford to buy combinations that lie outside it: i.e. in
corresponding to each curve is not specified, the darker shaded area. This area is known as the
indifference curves further out to the right would infeasible region for the given budget.
show combinations of the two goods that yield a
higher utility, and curves further in to the left
would show combinations yielding a lower utility.
In fact, a whole indifference map can be drawn,
with each successive indifference curve showing a
higher level of utility. Combinations of goods along
I2 in Figure 4.7 give a higher utility to the
consumer than those along I1. Those along I3 give
We have said that the amount people can afford to
buy will depend on (a) their budget and (b) the
prices of the two goods. We can show how a The relative prices of the two goods are given by
change in either of these two determinants will the slope of the budget line. The slope of the budget
affect the budget line. line in Figure 4.8 is 30/15 2. (We are ignoring the
negative sign: strictly speaking, the slope should be
the same. Similarly, the slope of the new higher
budget line in Figure 4.9 is 40/20 2. But in each
case this is simply the ratio of the price of X (£2) to
the price of Y (£1). Thus the slope of the budget
line equals PX/PY.

A change in price
If the price of either good changes, the slope of the
budget line will change. This is illustrated in Figure
4.10 which, like Figure 4.8, assumes a budget of
£30 and an initial price of X of £2 and a price of Y
A change in income of £1. The initial budget line is B1.

If the consumer’s income (and hence budget)


increases, the budget line will shift outwards,
parallel to the old one. This is illustrated in the last
two columns of Table 4.3 and in Figure 4.9, which
show the effect of a rise in the consumer’s budget
from £30 to £40. (Note that there is no change in
the prices of X and Y, which remain at £2 and £1
respectively.) More can now be purchased. For
example, if the consumer was originally purchasing
7 units of X and 16 units of Y (point m), this could
be increased with the new budget of £40, to 10
units of X and 20 units of Y (point n) or any other
combination of X and Y along the new higher
budget line.
Now let us assume that the price of X falls to £1
but that the price of Y remains the same (£1). The
new budget line will join 30 on the Y axis with 30
on the X axis. In other words, the line pivots
outwards on point a. If, instead, the price of Y
changed, the line would pivot on point b.

The optimum consumption point


We are now in a position to put the two elements of
the analysis together: the indifference map and a
budget line.
has been no need to measure utility. All we have
needed to do is to observe, for any two
combinations of goods, whether the consumer
preferred one to the other or was indifferent
between them.

The effect of changes in income


As we have seen, an increase in income is
represented by a parallel shift outwards of the
budget line (assuming no change in the price of X
and Y). This will then lead to a new optimum
consumption point on a higher indifference curve.
A different consumption point will be found for
each different level of income.
This will enable us to show how much of each of In Figure 4.12 a series of budget lines are drawn
the two goods the ‘rational’ consumer will buy representing different levels of consumer income.
from a given budget. The corresponding optimum consumption points (r,
Let us examine Figure 4.11. The consumer would s, t, u) are shown. Each point is where the new
like to consume along the highest possible higher budget line just touches the highest possible
indifference curve. This is curve I3 at point t. indifference curve.1
Higher indifference curves, such as I4 and I5,
although representing higher utility than curve I3,
are in the infeasible region: they represent
combinations of X and Y that cannot be afforded
with the current budget. The consumer could
consume along curves I1 and I2, between points r
and v, and s and u respectively, but they give a
lower level of utility than consuming at point t.
The optimum consumption point for the consumer,
then, is where the budget line touches (is
‘tangential to’) the highest possible indifference
curve. At any other point along the budget line, the
consumer would get a lower level of utility.
If the budget line is tangential to an indifference
curve, they will have the same slope. (The slope of
a curve is the slope of the tangent to it at the point
in question.) But as we have seen: The line joining these points is known as the
income– consumption curve.
If your money income goes up and the price of
goods does not change, we say that your real
income has risen. In other words, you can buy more
than you did before. But your real income can also
rise even if you do not earn any more money. This
will happen if prices fall. For the same amount of
money, you can buy more goods than previously.
But this is the equi-marginal principle that we
We analyse the effect of a rise in real income
established in the first part of this chapter: only this
caused by a fall in prices in just the same way as
time, using the indifference curve approach, there
we did when money income rose and prices stayed P2 is half of P1, P3 is one-third of P1 and P4 is
the same. Provided the relative prices of the two one-quarter of P1.)
goods stay the same (i.e. provided they fall by the
same percentage), the budget line will shift
outwards parallel to the old one.

Income elasticity of demand and the


income–consumption curve
The income–consumption curve in Figure 4.12
shows that the demand for both goods rises as
income rises. Thus both goods have a positive
income elasticity of demand: they are both normal
goods.
Now let us focus just on good X. If the income–
consumption curve became flatter at higher levels
of income, it would show an increasing proportion point. The line that connects these points is known
of income being spent on X. The flatter it became, as the price–consumption curve.
the higher would be the income elasticity of
demand for X.
If, by contrast, X were an inferior good, such as Deriving the individual’s demand
cheap margarine, its demand would fall as income curve
rose; its income elasticity of demand would be
negative. This is illustrated in Figure 4.13. Point b We can use the analysis of price changes to show
is to the left of point a, showing that at the higher how in theory a person’s demand curve for a
income B2, less X is purchased. product can be derived. To do this we need to
modify the diagram slightly.
The effect of changes in price Let us assume that we want to derive a person’s
demand curve for good X. What we need to show is
If either X or Y changes in price, the budget line the effect on the consumption of X of a change in
will ‘pivot’. Take the case of a reduction in the the price of X assuming the prices of all other
price of X (but no change in the price of Y). If this goods are held constant. To do this we need to
happens, the budget line will swing outwards. We redefine good Y. Instead of being a single good, Y
saw this effect in Figure 4.10 (on page 108). becomes the total of all other goods. But what units
These same budget lines are reproduced in Figure are we to put on the vertical axis? Each of these
4.14, but this time we have added indifference other goods will be in different units: litres of
curves. The old optimum consumption point was at petrol, loaves of bread, kilograms of cheese,
j. After the reduction in the price of good X, a new numbers of haircuts, etc. We cannot add them all
optimum consumption point is found at k. up unless we first convert them to a common unit.
A series of budget lines could be drawn, all The answer is to measure them as the total amount
pivoting round point a in Figure 4.14. Each one of money spent on them: i.e. what is not spent on
represents a different price of good X, but with good X.
money income and the price of Y held constant. With expenditure on all other goods plotted on the
The flatter the curve, the lower the price of X. At vertical axis and with income, tastes and the price
each price, there will be an optimum consumption of all other goods held constant, we can now derive
part of the diagram corresponds to one of the four the demand curve for X. This is demonstrated in
points on the price–consumption curve. (Note that Figure 4.15.
We illustrate the changes in the price of X by • The good is now more expensive relative to other
pivoting the budget line on the point where it goods. Therefore consumers substitute alternatives
intersects the vertical axis. It is then possible, by for it. This is the substitution effect.
drawing a price–consumption line, to show the We can extend our arguments of Chapter 2 by
amount of X demanded at each price. It is then a demonstrating the income and substitution effects
simple matter of transferring these price–quantity with the use of indifference analysis. Let us start
relationships on to a demand curve. In Figure 4.15, with the case of a normal good and show what
each of the points a, b, c and d on the demand happens when its price changes.
curve in the lower
A normal good
In Figure 4.16 the price of normal good X has risen
and the budget line has pivoted inwards from B1 to
B2. The consumption point has moved from point f
to point h. Part of this shift in consumption is due
to the substitution effect and part is due to the
income effect.
The substitution effect. To separate these two
effects a new budget line is drawn, parallel to B2
but tangential to the original indifference curve I1.
This is the line B1a. Being parallel to B2, it
represents the new price ratio (i.e. the higher price
of X). Being tangential to I1, however, it enables
the consumer to obtain the same utility as before: in
other words, there is no loss in real income to the
consumer. By focusing on B1a, then, which
represents no change in real income, we have
excluded the income effect.
The movement from point f to point g is due purely
to a change in the relative prices of X and Y. The
movement from QX1 to QX2 is the substitution
effect.

part of the diagram corresponds to one of the four


points on the price–consumption curve. (Note that
P2 is half of P1, P3 is one-third of P1 and P4 is
one-quarter of P1.)

The income and substitution effects


of a price change
In Chapter 2 we argued that when the price of a
good rises, consumers will purchase less of it for
two reasons:
• They cannot afford to buy so much. This is the
income effect.
The income effect. In reality, the budget line has The income effect. The income effect of the
shifted to B2 and the consumer is forced to price rise, however, will be the opposite of that for
consume on a lower indifference curve I2: real a normal good: it will be positive. The reduction in
income has fallen. Thus the movement from QX2 real income from the rise in price of X will tend to
to QX3 is the income effect. increase the consumption of X, since with a fall in
In the case of a normal good, therefore, the income real income more inferior goods will now be
and substitution effects of a price change reinforce purchased – including more X. Thus point h is to
each other. They are both negative: they both the right of point g: the income effect increases
involve a reduction in the quantity demanded as quantity back from QX2 to QX3.
price rises (and vice versa). The bigger the income .
and substitution effects, the higher will be the price
elasticity of demand for good X.
A Giffen good: a particular type of
inferior good
An inferior good If the inferior good were to account for a very large
proportion of a consumer’s expenditure, a change
As we saw above, when people’s incomes rise, they
in its price would have a significant effect on the
will buy less of inferior goods such as poor-quality
consumer’s real income, resulting in a large income
margarine and cheap powdered instant coffee, since
effect. It is conceivable, therefore, that this large
they will now be able to afford better-quality goods
abnormal income effect could outweigh the normal
instead. Conversely, when income falls, they will
substitution effect. In such a case, a rise in the price
now have to reduce their living standards: their
of X would lead to more X being consumed!
consumption of inferior goods will thus rise.
This is illustrated in Figure 4.18, where point h is to
the right of point f. In other words, the fall in
The substitution effect. If the price of an consumption (QX1 to QX2) as a result of the
inferior good (good X) rises, the substitution effect substitution effect is more than offset by the rise in
will be in the same direction as for a normal good: consumption (QX2 to QX3) as a result of the large
i.e. it will be negative. People will consume less X positive income effect.
relative to Y, since X is now more expensive
relative to Y. For example, if the price of inferior-
quality margarine (good X) went up, people would
tend to use better-quality margarine or butter (good
Y) instead. This is illustrated in Figure 4.17 by a
movement along the original indifference curve
(I1) from point f to point g. The quantity of X
demanded falls from QX1 to QX2.

Such a good is known as a Giffen good, after Sir


Robert Giffen (1837–1910), who is alleged to have
claimed that the consumption of bread by the poor
rose when its price rose. Bread formed such a large
proportion of poor people’s consumption that, if its
price went up, the poor could not afford to buy so
much meat, vegetables, etc. and had to buy more
bread instead. It is possible that in very low income
countries in Africa today, staple foods such as
manioc and maize are Giffen goods. Naturally,
such cases must be very rare indeed.

The usefulness of indifference


analysis
Indifference analysis has made it possible to
demonstrate the logic of ‘rational’ consumer
choice, the derivation of the individual’s demand
curve, and the income and substitution effects of a
price change. All this has been done without having
to measure utility. Nevertheless there are
limitations to the usefulness of indifference
analysis:
• In practice it is virtually impossible to derive
indifference curves, since it would involve a
consumer having to imagine a whole series of
different combinations of goods and deciding in
each case whether a given combination gave more,
equal or less satisfaction than other combinations.
• Consumers may not behave ‘rationally’, and
hence may not give careful consideration to the
satisfaction they believe they will gain from
consuming goods. They may behave impetuously.
• Indifference curves are based on the satisfaction
that consumers believe they will gain from a good.
This belief may well be influenced by advertising.
Consumers may be disappointed or pleasantly
surprised, however, when they actually consume
the good. In other words, consumers are not
perfectly knowledgeable. Thus the ‘optimum
consumption’ point may not in practice give
consumers maximum satisfaction for their money.
• Certain goods are purchased only now and again,
and then only one at a time. Examples would
include consumer durables such as cars, televisions
and washing machines. Indifference curves are
based on the assumption that marginal increases in
one good can be traded off against marginal
decreases in another. This will not be the case with
consumer durables.

You might also like