The Search-Theoretic Approach To Monetary Economics - Rupert, Schindler, Shevchenko & Wright

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 19

The Search-Theoretic

Approach to
Monetary Economics:
A Primer
by Peter Rupert, Martin Schindler,
Andrei Shevchenko, and Randall Wright
Peter Rupert is a senior
economic advisor at the
Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland; Martin Schindler is
a doctoral candidate in
economics at the University of
Pennsylvania; Andrei
Shevchenko is an assistant
professor of economics at
Michigan State University;
Randall Wright is a professor
of economics at the University
of Pennsylvania. This paper
was written while Schindler,
Shevchenko, and Wright were
visiting the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland.

Introduction are not public information. Such frictions are crucial


for a logically coherent theory of money; the approach
This paper presents some results in monetary theory described here helps to clarify each one’s role.
derived using very simple game-theoretic models of This approach contrasts with attempts to model the
the exchange process. The underlying model is a vari- role of money in a competitive equilibrium (Walrasian)
ant of search theory, a framework that has been used model—a difficult task that has met with mixed suc-
extensively in a wide variety of applications. This cess at best. In a competitive equilibrium model, the
approach is well suited to discussing the process of exchange process is not explicitly modeled. That is,
exchange and money’s role in the process. The ap- agents start with an initial allocation A and choose a
proach utilized here is explicitly strategic, in the fol- final allocation B so as to maximize utility, subject to
lowing natural sense: When I decide whether to ac- the latter not costing more than the former, but how
cept in trade a certain object other than one I desire for they get from point A to point B is not discussed.
my own consumption—for example, money—I must Does some unmodeled agent (maybe the auctioneer)
conjecture as to the probability that other agents will make the necessary trades with a “pick-up and deliv-
accept it from me in the future. This evidently ought ery service”? Or do the agents trade directly with each
to be modeled as a game. other? Do they trade bilaterally or multilaterally? In
In search theory, the type of game to be consid- real time, or before production and consumption activ-
ered is explicitly dynamic, and exchange takes place ity starts? Do they barter directly or trade indirectly
in real time. Also, the models allow us to focus pre- using media of exchange? The standard competitive
cisely on various frictions in the exchange process that equilibrium paradigm does not address such questions.
might give money a role in an equilibrium, or effi- Search models, in contrast, are designed with exactly
cient, arrangement. Among the frictions are these: these issues in mind and therefore are logical tools for
Agents are not always in the same place at the same studying monetary economics, as we shall illustrate.
time; long-run commitments cannot be enforced; and
agents are anonymous in the sense that their histories
11

I. The Basic Model always holds either 0 or 1 unit of money. To simplify


the presentation, we do not allow agents to freely dis-
To model anonymous trade, it is natural to start with a pose of money, but this is never binding except in one
large number of agents—formally, we assume a 0 1  


case mentioned below.


continuum. For simplicity, we assume these agents We now describe the trading process. Rather than
live forever and discount the future at rate r. There is assuming a centralized (Walrasian) market, here the
a 0 1 continuum of indivisible consumption goods.
 


agents must trade bilaterally. The simplest way to


To generate gains from trade, we need to assume that model this is to assume that they meet according to
agents are specialized. There are many ways to do this, a pairwise random matching process. Upon meeting, a
but an easy one is to assume that each agent i is able pair decide whether to trade, then part company and re-
to produce just one type of good. The unit production enter the matching process. Let α denote the (Poisson)
cost for any agent is c 0. For convenience, we as- arrival rate in the matching process—that is, the prob-
sume that these goods cannot be stored and so must be ability of meeting someone in a given unit of time.2
consumed immediately after they are produced. Obvi- For reasons discussed later, we assume the history of
ously, this means that consumption goods cannot serve any agent’s past meetings and trades is not known to
as media of exchange, allowing us to highlight the role anyone else.
of money. We want to analyze agents’ individual trading strate-
To make trade interesting in the model, we need to gies. An agent obviously should never accept a good
assume that tastes are heterogeneous. Again, there are in trade if he does not want to consume it, since goods
many ways to do this, but for simplicity we assume are not storable. Whenever possible, agents should
the following: First, given any two agents i and j, barter for a good they do want to consume (the case of
write iWj to mean “i wants to consume the good that a double coincidence). What needs to be determined
j produces”—in the sense that i derives utility u c is whether an agent should trade goods for money and
money for goods. Let π0 denote the probability that the


from consuming what j produces if iWj, and he derives


utility 0 from consuming what j produces otherwise. representative agent trades goods for money, and let π1
Then, for any randomly selected agents, we assume denote the probability that he trades money for goods.
prob iWi 0, prob jWi
 
x, and prob jWi iW j 


These must satisfy the equilibrium conditions given
y. The first assumption, prob iWi 
0, means that no below. We will say that money is used as a medium of
agent ever wants to consume his own output (which is exchange, or circulates, if and only if π π0 π1 0. 

why they trade). The second assumption parameter- Let V0 and V1 be the value functions (lifetime, dis-
izes the extent of the basic search friction: The smaller counted, expected utility) of agents with 0 or 1 units
x is, the lower the probability that a random trader has of money. Since we consider only stationary and sym-
what you want. However, the third assumption is the metric equilibria, V j does not depend on time or on the
important one, since it parameterizes Jevons’ (1875) agent’s name, only his money inventories.
famous double coincidence of wants problem: The If we think of time as proceeding in discrete peri-
smaller y is, the lower the probability that a trader who ods of length τ , we can calculate the payoff of holding
has what you want also wants what you have.1 money as follows: The probability of meeting anyone
Besides the consumption goods already mentioned, during this period is approximately ατ by the Pois-
there is another object called money, which consists of
an exogenously fixed quantity of M 0 1 indivisible
 


 

1 Several notions of specialization in the literature are


units of a storable object (of course, money must be special cases of this model. For example, in Kiyotaki and
storable to be useful). Holding money yields utility γ : Wright (1991) or Aiyagari and Wallace (1991), there are N
If γ 0, money pays a dividend, like many real assets, goods and N types of agents, where type n produces good
and if γ 0, then money has a storage cost; γ 0 de-


n and wants good n 1 mod N . Then x 1 N, and y 1 if


    

N 2, while y 0 if N 2. Alternatively, in Kiyotaki and Wright


scribes the case of pure fiat money. Although this last   

(1991, 1993) and much of the related literature, the events


case may be the most interesting, for generality we al-

iW j and jWi are independent, and so y x.


low γ 0. Initially, one unit of money is randomly




2 It is the bilateral rather than the random matching as-


allocated to each of M agents. Although we will re- sumption that is important. Corbae, Temzelides, and Wright
lax this later, for now we assume that agents holding (2000) show how to redo the model, allowing agents to choose
money cannot produce (one way to motivate this is to endogenously whom they meet, rather than meeting at ran-
dom. Their model shares the basic insights discussed here,
assume that after producing, you need to consume be- although it is complicated by the need to determine equilib-
fore you can produce again). Thus, no one can ever rium meeting patterns as well as equilibrium trades.
acquire more than one unit of money, and so an agent
12

son assumption.3 If the person you meet can produce The equilibrium conditions for π0 and π1 are
(meaning, in the version of the model that we are con-  

sidering here, he does not have money), which occurs  


1  
0
πj 0 1 as ∆ j


with probability 1 M, and you want what he can pro- 


(5) 

 
 0
duce, which occurs with probability x, and you both 0 0 

want to trade, which occurs with probability π in equi- Notice that ∆ j depends on π , so to see if some candi-
librium, then you trade, consume, and continue with- date π0 and π1 constitute an equilibrium, one simply
out money, for a total payoff of u V0 . In all other inserts the π j and checks equation (5).


events (you meet no one, you meet someone with a Consider first the case γ 0 (fiat money). This im-
good you do not want, etc.), you simply continue with plies ∆1 0 for all parameter values, so we always
your money, for a payoff of V1 . In all events, you also have π1 1. Also, ∆0 is equal in sign to π0 π̂ , where


get γτ from storing the money. Hence,


rc 1 M yu c


π̂
 

1 

(6)  

ατ 1 M xπ u 1 M u c 

V1 V0


 




 

1


 

Notice that π0 0 is always an equilibrium: Since π̂


1 ατ x 1 M π V1 γτ oτ
  

0, π0 0 implies π0 π̂ , which implies ∆0 0. Thus,




 

 

   

π0 0 satisfies the equilibrium condition. Naturally,


where o τ is the approximation error associated with there is an equilibrium in which no one accepts fiat
the Poisson process and hence satisfies o τ τ


0 as 

money. However, if
τ


0. Rearranging, we have
1 

M 1 yu 

c  

rτ V1 ατ 1 M xπ u V0 V1 γτ oτ
  

r 1 M 1 y


 

 

   

 

Dividing by τ and taking the limit as τ 0, we ar- then π̂ 1, which means π0 1 is an equilibrium as
rive at the continuous-time Bellman’s equation, well. So there is also an equilibrium where fiat money
circulates as long as c is not too big.4 Finally, if π̂ 1,
(1) rV1 αx 1 M π u V0 V1 γ there is also a mixed-strategy equilibrium in which
 

 

π0 π̂ . In this case, if other agents accept money with


  

An analogous argument implies that the value function exactly the right probability π̂ , you are indifferent as
for an agent without money satisfies to accepting or rejecting it, so randomizing is an equi-
librium.
(2) rV0 α xy 1 M u c α xM π V1 V0 c


The above model is essentially that of Kiyotaki and


   

   

Wright (1993), except that they assume c 0 in addi-


The first term in this expression represents the gain tion to γ 0. This implies that three equilibria neces-
from a direct barter trade, while the second represents sarily exist, π 0, π 1, and π y. In the mixed-
the gain from trading goods for money with probabil- strategy equilibrium, money is accepted with the same
ity π . Notice that you can only barter when there is a probability as a good (since y is the probability of
double coincidence of wants and the other person has a double coincidence), which makes you indifferent.
no money. When c 0, money must have a strictly greater prob-


ability of being accepted than a barter trade for you


II. Equilibrium to be indifferent about accepting money, because you
must incur the production cost to get the money. More
Define the net gain from trading goods for money by generally, when γ 0, we have to determine π1 en-


∆0 V1 V0 c, and the net gain from trading money


 

dogenously; for example, if γ is large, then agents may


for goods by ∆1 u V0 V1 . If we normalize α x 1 prefer to hoard rather than spend their money.


to reduce notation (which we can always do with no The results for the general case are summarized as
loss of generality by redefining units of time appropri- follows:
ately), we have:

Mπ M y u c ru γ


3 That is, the probability of meeting one person in a pe-


1
 

∆1
  

(3) riod of length τ is ατ o τ , and the probability of meeting




  

r π
 

more than one is o τ , where o τ satisfies o τ τ




  0 as      

1 M π y u c rc γ τ


0.
∆0
   

(4)   

r π


4 Alternatively, for a given c 0, we can say that r and 

M must be relatively small for a monetary equilibrium to exist


(agents must be patient and money not too plentiful).
13

Proposition 1. There are five types of equilibria, and present an alternative model, first discussed by Siandra
they exist in the following regions of parameter space: (1993, 1996), where agents with money can produce,
and we simply impose the condition that agents can
1. π0 1 and π1 0 is an equilibrium iff r r2


store, at most, one unit of money.


2. π0 0 and π1 1 is an equilibrium iff r r3 The first issue to be resolved is, what happens in
3. π0 1 and π1  0 1 is an equilibrium iff r 1
 
a double coincidence when you have money and the
r r2 other person does not—do you barter or pay with
cash?6 We resolve this by allowing agents to play the
4. π0 0 1 and π1 1 is an equilibrium iff r3
following simple game: First, with probability β the


 

r r4
agent with money is chosen and with probability 1 β 

5. π0 1 and π1 1 is an equilibrium iff r 1 


r 
r4 the agent without money is chosen to propose either
where the critical values of r are given by a barter or a cash transaction (in principle they could
also propose not to trade at all, but we ignore this op-
γ M 1 M y u c


 




tion, which will always be dominated by proposing


r1   

u barter). Second, the other agent responds either by


γ 

1 

M yu c 

accepting, which executes the proposal, or rejecting,


r2  

u which implies they part company (figure 1). A strat-


γ 

1 

M yu c 

egy for the agent with j units of money, j 1 or 0,


r3  

is denoted as ψ j , which equals the probability that he


c
γ


1 

M 1 y u  

c proposes barter (and so 1 ψ j is the probability he




r4   

proposes cash).
c 

These are the only (steady-state) equilibria. Proposition 2. In a double-coincidence meeting be-
tween an agent with and an agent without money,
Proof: See the appendix. generically the unique subgame-perfect equilibrium in
We characterized the regions where the different pure strategies is ψ0 ψ1 1.
equilibria exist in terms of r, but we could have used
some other parameter, such as c. Routine algebra im- Proof: See the appendix.
plies r1 r2 r3 r4 . Also, note that our assumption Having resolved the ambiguity that arises when both
of no free disposal is never binding, except possibly barter and cash are available, we can now derive the
when π0 0, and even then only if γ 0.5 More im- Bellman equations. Again, let time proceed in discrete
portantly, there are equilibria where π 0 and γ 0; 

that is, agents value money and use it as a medium of 

exchange despite its storage cost. We will have more 5 To be precise, we should say what agents do after dis-
to say about the economics underlying the above re- posing of their money. We assume here that they cannot
trade, as they cannot produce. Hence, agents will dispose of
sults in the next section, after we introduce a slight money and drop out of the trading process iff V1 0. Since it
variation on the model, since it will be interesting to is easy to see that V0 0 in any equilibrium and V1 V0 in any
 

compare the two versions. equilibrium with π0 0, the only case where disposal could po-


tentially occur is π0 0, which implies V1 γ r. Hence, agents


  

dispose of money if and only if π0 0 and γ 0.




III. Alternative Specification 

6 This is the only ambiguous case; every other meeting


has only one feasible transaction (that is, if you encounter a
A key assumption in the above model is that agents double coincidence and have no money, barter is the only op-
holding money cannot produce; this is what prevents tion). The issue did not come up in the previous section, be-
cause agents with money cannot barter.
them from acquiring more than a single unit of money.
The fact that agents hold either 0 or 1 unit of money
is what makes the model so tractable (see below). Al-
though the assumption that agents holding money can-
not produce is common in the literature, it has some
undesirable implications. For example, if two agents
with money meet and there is a double coincidence of
wants, they cannot trade. A related implication is that
as M increases, the productive capacity of the economy
necessarily decreases, which makes it difficult to inter-
pret the effects of changes in the money. So here we
14

FIGURE 1
Game Tree
Accept (u–c, u–c)

Barter Reject (0,0)


ψ1

1–ψ1
Cash Accept (∆1,∆0)

Buyer proposes
β Reject (0,0)

1– β Accept (u–c, u–c)

Barter Reject (0,0)


Seller proposes
ψ0
1–ψ0
Cash Accept (∆1,∆0)

Reject (0,0)

periods of length τ . Then tions for the alternative model


1 (9) rV1 yu c
ατ xy u



(7) V1 c V1






1


yπ 1 γ


1 M u V0 V1
  

  

ατ 1 M 1 y xπ u V0
  

 

y π M V1
 

(10) rV0 yu c 1 V0 c


  

   

1 ατ xy ατ 1 M 1 y xπ V1
   

   

  

γτ o τ Although the value functions are different across the


 

two models, we compute ∆ j and define equilibrium ex-




1
ατ xy u c V0


(8) V0 actly as in the last section. The results are as follows.




1 rτ


ατ M 1 y xπ V1 c






Proposition 3. In the alternative model, where agents
1 ατ xy ατ M 1 y xπ V0 with money can produce, there are five potential types


  

 

of equilibria and they exist in the following regions of





 

parameter space:
where we temporarily reintroduce α x to facilitate com- 1. π0 1 and π1 0 is an equilibrium iff r r̂2
parison to equations (1) and (2) in the previous model.


Observe, for example, that now a money holder barters 2. π0 0 and π1 1 is an equilibrium iff r r̂3
every time he encounters a double coincidence, which
occurs with probability ατ xy. Indeed, he uses money 3. π0 1 and π1  0 1 is an equilibrium iff r̂1
 

only when he encounters a single coincidence, which r r̂2


occurs with probability ατ 1 y x, and the other agent 

4. π0 0 1 and π1 1 is an equilibrium iff r̂3


does not have money and they both agree to trade,
 

r r̂4
which occurs with probability 1 M π . 

Rearranging, we let τ 0 and normalize α x 1 5. π0 1 and π1




1 is an equilibrium iff r̂1 


r 
r̂4 

as before, to write the continuous-time Bellman equa-


15

where the critical values of r are given by FIGURE 3


γ 

M 1 

y u 

c Equilibria in γ r -Space When Money Holders


r̂1  

 

u Can Produce
r̂2 γ u 

r̂3 γ c r ⵩
r4 r3



γ 1 M 1 y u c


  

r̂4   

c 

These are the only (steady-state) equilibria. π o = 0,


πo = 0 πo = 1
Proof: The proof is analogous to that of Proposition 1
π1 = 1 or
and so is omitted for brevity. πo (0,1) ∋
πo = 1
π1 = 1 π1 = 1 ⵩
r2
FIGURE 2
Equilibria in γ r)-Space When Money Holders


Cannot Produce
r1

πo = 1
r r苵4 r苵3 π1 = 0
π1 = 1
or
π 1 (0,1)
∋ πo = 1
π1 = 0
γ
–(1–M)(1–y)(u–c) 0 M(1–y)(u–c)
π o = 0,
πo = 0 πo = 1
or πo = 1
π1 = 1 π o (0,1)∋ π1 = 1
where the unique equilibrium is π 1, as well as other
π1 = 1 r苵2
regions where there are multiple equilibria: In one re-
gion, we must have π1 1, but π0 can be 0, 1, or be-
tween 0 and 1; in another region, we must have π0 1,
while π1 can be 0, 1, or between 0 and 1.7
r苵1
πo = 1 The models differ in that it is actually more difficult
π1 = 0 to get money to circulate when money holders can pro-
π1 = 1
or duce; the potential region where π 0 is larger when
π1 (0,1)
∋ πo = 1


they cannot. Intuitively, agents with money are more


π1 = 0 willing to spend it when they cannot produce, since
γ
–(1–M)(1–y)(u–c) 0 (1–M)y(u–c) [M+(1–M)y](u–c) doing so allows them to barter. If γ c 0, the dif-
ferences between the two models are especially stark:
When money holders cannot produce, there are always
three equilibria, π 0, π 0 y , and π 1; in the
The regions of γ r space where the different equi-


other model there are two, π 0 and π 1. The intu-


 

 

libria exist in the two models (those where money ition is as follows: When money holders can produce,
holders cannot produce and those where they can pro- there is no cost associated with acquiring money when
duce) are shown in figures 2 and 3. The same five types we set γ c 0, so if there is a strictly positive prob-
of equilibria exist in both models; the regions where ability of money being accepted, you should always
they exist are similar but quantitatively different— accept it. This is not true when money holders can-
unless y 0, of course, since the models are identical
when there is no barter. In either case, when γ is very 

low the only equilibrium is one in which no one ac- 7 It is well known that there is a strategic complementarity
cepts money; if γ is very high, the only equilibrium is in the decision to accept money, π0 , but it is less well under-
stood that the same is true of π1 . For some parameters, an
one in which no one spends it. Hence, money circu- agent is more willing to spend money if he believes that oth-
lates if and only if its intrinsic properties are not too ers will do the same. This only occurs when γ 0. 

bad or too good. Also, both models include a region


16

not produce, because even when γ c 0, accepting the exchange process even though money “crowds out”
money involves the opportunity cost of giving up your barter.
barter option.
The version of the model in which agents with FIGURE 4
money cannot produce is easy to motivate by saying
that one must consume before producing, since this Welfare as a Function of M
leads naturally to the result that agents in equilibrium
always hold either 0 or 1 unit of money. However, rW
S
the alternative version where money holders can pro- rW1
duce also seems more natural in some respects. For K
rW1
example, when two agents with money meet and there
is a double coincidence, they trade. Of course, this
version does require assuming directly that agents can S
rWπ
only store 0 or 1 units of money. There is not neces-
sarily a right or wrong model, and the choice should K
be dictated by how well it addresses a certain question rWπ
and how tractable it is in any given application.

rW0S
IV. Welfare
In this section, we discuss welfare, defined by W
MV1


1 M V0 (average utility). For the purpose of



rW0K
discussion, we also set γ 0. Using straightforward


algebra, in the two models we have M


O MK MS M

rW K
1 M 1 M y Mπ u c


  

   

rW S y M 1 M 1 yπ u c


  

    

where the superscript K indicates the case where This discussion ignores the fact that π 1 is not an
money holders cannot produce and the superscript S equilibrium for all parameter values. If γ 0, it is easy
indicates the case where they can. Notice first that to see that in either version of the model, π 1 is an
when we compare two equilibria in either model, other equilibrium if and only if M M 1 1 yrcu c . The



 

things being equal, W is greater in the equilibrium with true optimal policy, then, is the minimum of M and the
the higher π . This simply says that the more accept- values given above. In figure 4, we depict welfare in
able money is, the more useful it is. The next thing to each type of equilibrium by the curves W0j , Wπj , or W1j ,
notice is that across the two models, given any π we where money is accepted with probability 0, π , or 1.
have W S W K with strict inequality as long as y 0 
The superscript j K or S refers to the two different
and M 0; not surprisingly, agents are better off if we

models. The curves are drawn only for values of M
allow money holders to produce. such that the equilibria exist. Figure 5 shows welfare
We now want to focus on equilibrium with π 1 as a function of y, given that we set M to its welfare-
and consider maximizing W with respect to M. The re- maximizing level (which depends on y). These figures
sult for the model in which money holders can produce illustrate various properties, including: W is always
1
is M 2 . The intuition is simple. Money is useful higher when money holders can produce; and W in-
because it facilitates trade every time an agent i with creases with π across equilibria in either model.
money and an agent j without money meet and iWj
holds. To maximize the frequency of such meetings,
we should have half the agents holding money and half V. Essentiality of Money
of them not: M 12 . For the other model, the welfare-
At this stage, it is instructive to highlight the role
maximizing policy is M 12 2y 2y if y
1
2 , and M 0 of various frictions in the model, to understand what
1
if y 2 . Hence, the optimal M is lower in this model, makes money essential. Following Hahn (1965), we
simply because when money holders cannot produce, say money is essential if it allows agents to achieve al-
increasing M “crowds out” barter. Still, for small y the locations they cannot achieve with other mechanisms
welfare-maximizing M is positive because it facilitates that also respect the enforcement and information con-
17

FIGURE 5 commit to this arrangement ex ante, they would all


agree to do so, and there would be no need for money.
Welfare as a Function of y (optimal M) Clearly, an imperfect ability to commit to future ac-
tions is important if money is to have an essential role.
rW, M However, even in the absence of explicit commit-
ments, cooperative agreements like the credit arrange-
ment can sometimes be enforced by reputational con-
siderations if individual actions are public informa-
rWS tion. Thus, consider the arrangement: “produce for
M
苵 anyone who wants your production good as long as
everyone else has done so in the past; as soon as some-
one deviates from this, trigger to plan X,” where plan
MS
X is to be determined. Of course, plan X must be
self-enforcing (that is, it must be an equilibrium), and
we want the outcome of plan X to be sufficiently un-
MS pleasant to keep agents from deviating from the ef-
ficient arrangement. We will assume here that plan
X is to trade if and only if there is a double coinci-
rWK dence of wants, which generates expected utility Wb
MK y u c r, where the subscript b stands for barter.9





It is in individuals’ self-interest not to deviate from


y the credit arrangement in which they are supposed to
0 1 produce if and only if c Wc Wb , which sim-



plifies to r r̃ 
1 y u c c. As always, if








agents are sufficiently patient, the threat of trigger-


ing to pure barter supports the efficient outcome, and
straints in the environment.8 again money is not essential. Of course, this assumes
First, we need some sort of double coincidence of that agents’ trading histories can be observed publicly;
wants problem. For this it is important that not ev- otherwise, it is not possible for agents to use trigger
erybody can trade multilaterally. For example, con- strategies.10 When trading histories are private infor-
sider an economy with three agents, where each agent

mation, the only sustainable outcome without money
of type n 1 2 3 produces good n and wants good


 
is pure barter. But if there is money, we can do better
n 1 mod 3 . If all agents meet at the same place than pure barter, even when trading histories are pri-


and are able to make multilateral trades, it is feasible


for each agent to produce and consume in the period: 

8 For a recent treatment of this problem, see Kocher-


Agent 2 produces for agent 1, agent 1 produces for
lakota (1998).
agent 3, and agent 3 produces for agent 2. Our restric- 

9 We do not trigger to autarky because we assume that


tion to bilateral meetings, given specialized tastes and if two agents want to barter without it being observed, they
technology, is merely a convenient way to generate a can; so the worst possible equilibrium is the one where none
double-coincidence problem. In the three-agent exam- but double-coincidence trades occur. Nothing much hinges
ple, in every bilateral meeting one agent wants what on this; a similar message holds if we can trigger to autarky,
and it is, in fact, easier to support credit-like arrangements by
the other produces, while the other does not. triggering to autarky.
Second, even given a double-coincidence problem, 

10 If the number of agents was small, then even if agents


for money to be essential it is also important that did not observe all other agents’ histories but only their own,
agents cannot commit to long-term agreements. Con- we could potentially support the efficient arrangement by the
sider the following credit arrangement: “produce for following strategy: “If ever you directly observe someone de-
anyone you meet who wants your good.” This ar- viate (by not producing for you when you would like him to),
stop producing for anyone else.” This would set off a chain of
rangement resembles credit in the sense that agents re- agents who observe deviations and would eventually lead the
ceive consumption today in exchange for nothing but economy into autarky. With a large number of agents, how-
a “promise” to repay someone in kind at a future date. ever, if I fail to produce for you, there is zero probability that
It is also obviously an efficient arrangement; that is, it in the future I will meet you or I will meet someone who has
generates the maximum possible expected utility, say met you, and so the chain will never get back to me. So with
a large number of agents, to support credit it does not suffice
Wc u c r, given the normalization α x 1, where





to have agents observe (only) their own histories. See Araujo


the subscript c on Wc stands for credit. If agents could (2000) for more discussion.
18

vate. Notice that monetary exchange generates lower different ways. A typical approach is the generalized
welfare than the credit arrangement, although higher Nash bargaining solution,
than pure barter.
θ
(13) q arg max u q V0 Q T1


Money does not do as well as credit because of the




  

random-meeting technology and because money hold- 1 θ



V1 Q 


cq 


T0 

ings are bounded, leading to some meetings where I


want your good and you do not want mine, but either I where θ is the bargaining power of the buyer and T j
have no money or you already have money. In these is the threat point of the agent with j units of money.
meetings, monetary exchange will not work, while Also, the maximization is subject to u q V0 V1 and


credit could work as long as trading histories are pub- V1 c q 

V0 . Here we will set θ 12 , and T1 T2




licly observable. Even if we relax the upper bound 0. 12


on money holdings, the fact that money holdings are
bounded below by zero means that money cannot do as FIGURE 6
well as credit in a random-matching environment. We
conclude that money has an essential role in the model Monetary Equilibrium in the Divisible-Goods
for three reasons: the double-coincidence problem, the Model
lack of commitment, and private information on trad-
ing histories. For an extended discussion of these is- q
sues, see Kocherlakota (1998, 2000) and Kocherlakota
and Wallace (1998). q

VI. Prices f(Q)


This section provides an extension in which the as-
sumption of indivisible goods is relaxed, although e(Q)
money is still indivisible and so agents will always g(Q)
have either 0 or 1 units of money. Following Shi
(1995) and Trejos and Wright (1995), we will use bar-
gaining theory to determine prices endogenously. For
simplicity, we set y 0, so there is no direct barter.11
Given that goods are perfectly divisible, let u q be 

the utility of consuming q units of one’s consump-


tion good and c q the disutility of producing q units 

of one’s production good. We assume u 0 c0,  

u 0 c 0 0, u q 0, c q 0, u q 0, and e Q
q q* q1
     


q
    

   

c q
 
0, for q 0, with at least one of the weak


inequalities strict. For future reference, we define q


by u q c q . Also, there is a q̂ 0 such that





u q̂ c q̂ . When a buyer meets a seller who can


 

produce the right good, they bargain over how much q The bargaining solution in equation (13) defines a
will be exchanged for the buyer’s unit of money, im- mapping q q Q from 0 q̂ into itself. That is,
  


plying a nominal price p 1 q. Otherwise, the model 


if other agents are giving Q units of output for one
is exactly identical to that in the previous section.
Letting V1 and V0 denote the value functions and tak- 

11 This assumption makes it irrelevant whether we use


ing q Q as given, the generalizations of the dynamic the version in which money holders can produce or the one
programming equations can be expressed as in which they cannot, since they are identical when y 0. 

Shi (1995) and Trejos and Wright (1995) analyze the case
(11) rV1 1 M u Q V0 V1


  


with y 0, but only for a special bargaining solution and only




(12) rV0 M V1 V0 c Q  


for the model where money holders cannot produce. Ru-
pert, Schindler, and Wright (forthcoming) consider the general
  

case.
These can be easily solved for V1 V1 Q and V0 

12 It is also common to set the threat points equal to con-


V0 Q . Taking V1 Q and V0 Q as given, q will solve
  

tinuation values: T j V j . Both can be derived from an under-




a bargaining problem. In equilibrium, of course, q lying strategic model; see Osborne and Rubinstein (1990) for
Q. The bargaining model can be formulated in several the bargaining theory.
19

unit of money, then a particular pair bargaining bi- along. Since he discounts the future, a seller is only
laterally will agree to q q Q . An equilibrium is a 
willing to produce less than the amount that satisfies
fixed point, q q Q . In general, we must be care- u q 
c q . Indeed, to verify that frictions are driv-


ing the result, observe that when r 0 or α ∞, we


  

ful with the constraints on the bargaining problem:


When y 0, the constraints are never binding in equi- have qe q .
librium. However, if y 0 the constraints may bind; Another question to ask is how q depends on M.
One might expect ∂ qe ∂ M 0, but it is actually pos-


therefore, it is instructive to proceed allowing for the 

possibility of binding constraints. The constraints can sible to have ∂ qe ∂ M 0 for small M (at least if r is


be rewritten c q D Q and u q D Q , where 


  
also small). The explanation is that when M is close to
DQ V1 Q V0 Q . The former constraint is satis-
 



zero, very little trade occurs. In this case, increasing
fied if and only if q f Q , and the latter is satisfied if 

M increases the frequency of productive meetings be-
and only if q g Q , for increasing functions f and g. 
tween buyers and sellers, which in turn increases both
As figure 6 shows, both f and g go through the origin V1 and V0 . The net effect on the bargaining solution
in the Q q plane, and g lies below f and below the can be a higher q. However, there is some threshold
M̂ 12 such that ∂ qe ∂ M 0 for all M M̂, so we
 

45 line for all Q 0 q̂ . Also, f crosses the 45 line 

 
 

at a unique q1 0 q̂ . Hence, our search for equilibria 


 can be sure that the value of money eventually begins
can be constrained to the interval 0 q1 .  
 to fall as M increases.
The first-order condition for an interior solution to We can also ask how M affects welfare. It is clear
equation (13), taking V1 V0 Q and V0 V0 Q as  
that if a planner can choose both M and q to maximize
given, is W , he will choose M 12 and q q . This is because
M 12 maximizes the number of trades (just as in the
V1 Q cq u q uq V0 Q c q 0


previous section when y 0), and q q maximizes


 

   

        

the surplus that results from each trade. However, if


This defines a function q e Q , also shown in the 

the planner can choose only M and q is determined


figure. It too goes through the origin and intersects the
in equilibrium, then the value of M that maximizes W
45 line at a unique point qe . Hence, q q Q can be 

satisfies the first-order condition


min e Q f Q for all q 0 qe ,


written as q Q    


 


max e Q g Q for all q qe q1 . For




and q Q    


 


q q1 , it does not really matter how we define q Q , ∂W s


1 2M u q cq


which necessarily is below the 45 line, and we set it ∂M


 

   

equal to q Q 0. This makes it clear that for all pa-




∂ qe
M 1 M u q c q 0


rameter values, q q Q has exactly two fixed points:


∂M
 

 


    

a nonmonetary equilibrium q 0, and a unique mone-


tary equilibrium q qe 0.13 
As the second term is negative at M 12 , the solution is
One important property of monetary equilibrium M o 12 . This illustrates the trade-off between provid-
(that continues to hold even if y 0) is the following.  ing liquidity (making trade easier), and reducing the
Recall that q is defined by u q c q . Then it is 




value of money (lowering the surplus from each trade).


easy to show that e q q and, therefore, qe q , 

Reducing the value of money reduces welfare because,


as seen in figure 6. This is significant because q is the as we have already established, q is too low in equilib-
efficient outcome. More precisely, if we define welfare rium.
as before, W MV1 1 M V0 , after simplification


we have 

13 If y 0, one can show that for large r there are no mon-




(14) rW M 1 

M uq 

cq 
etary equilibria, while for small r there are multiple monetary
    

equilibria.


14 This is true even though bargaining is bilaterally efficient


Hence, W is maximized with respect to q at q . The
in the sense that the agreement is on the Pareto frontier in
result qe q says that in equilibrium qe is too low— each exchange, taking as given the value of Q that prevails in
or, equivalently, the price level is too high.14 other exchanges. The point is that all agents would be better
The economic intuition for this result is straight- off (in an ex ante sense) if they could get everyone to commit
forward. If a seller could turn the proceeds from his to increasing q. A stronger result is actually true: Not only is qe
too low according to the ex ante criterion W , it is also too low
production into immediate consumption, as in a static
according to the ex post criteria V0 and V1 . That is, buyers and
or frictionless model, then he would produce until even sellers would be better off if q were bigger. The result
u q

c q . But in a monetary exchange, the pro-




that qe q also can be shown for models where agents can


ceeds from production consist of cash that can only be hold any amount of money; see Trejos and Wright (1995, pp.
spent in the future when an opportunity to buy comes 133–4).
20

VII. Dynamics As in steady-state analysis, we want to eliminate the


value functions from (15). To this end, subtract (17)
We previously focused on steady states; in this section, and (18) to obtain
we consider dynamic equilibria in the model with di-
visible goods. Although one could do things more gen-
erally,15 we restrict attention to the case where θ 1 in r V1 V0 1 M uq cq γ V̇1 V̇0
 

   

     

the bargaining solution (equation [13]). This is equiv-


alent to assuming that agents with money get to make Equation (15) implies c q q̇ V̇1 




V̇0 . Inserting this


take-it-or-leave-it offers. Hence, they will demand the in the previous equation yields
quantity that satisfies
(19) q̇ F q 

(15) V1 V0 cq r 1 M cq 1 M uq γ


   

 

   

c q 

since this is the most a producer would give to acquire




currency. In the previous section’s model, this imme- Any bounded, non-negative path for q solving the
diately implies V0 0 by virtue of equation (12), so above differential equation constitutes an equilibrium.
we have V1 c q . Inserting this into equation (11) 

we have FIGURE 7
(16) rc q 
1 

M uq   


cq 



Dynamic Equilibria

An equilibrium is a q that solves equation (16). Al- q
though the model with take-it-or-leave-it offers is in-
teresting in its own right, mainly because of its sim-
plicity, we use it here to study dynamics. •
q = F (q)
We need to rederive the Bellman equations without
limiting our attention to steady state. First, write the
discrete time value of holding money at t as
–γ
1
ατ 1 M xπ u τ


V1 t V0 t
 




1


   

1 ατ x 1 M π V1 t τ γτ oτ
   

 

    

where we have reintroduced the utility of holding q


money γ . Rearranging, we have qL qH
rV1 t α 1 M xπ u V0 t τ V1 t τ
  

 

    

V1 t τ V1 t oτ


γ


  

 

τ τ 

Taking the limit as τ 0, we arrive at

(17) rV1 t αx 1 M πu V0 t V1 t


 

To keep the number of cases manageable, assume


    

γ V̇1 t γ 0. Figure 7 shows equation (19) for this case.


 

 

When γ 0 and large, there are no monetary equilib-




where V̇1 indicates the time derivative. A similar


ria; when γ 0 but not too big, there are two monetary
derivation yields
steady states, qL and qH . Clearly, qL is stable while qH
(18) rV0 t M V1 t 

V0 t 

cq 


V̇0 t is unstable. Hence, in addition to the steady states,


the set of equilibria is as follows: For all q0 0 qL ,
      

 

Note that because of equation (15), the first term on there is an equilibrium that converges monotonically
the right side of equation (18) is 0. up to qL ; for all q0 qL qH , there is an equilibrium


 

Henceforth, we will omit the time argument t when that converges monotonically down to qL . The former
there is no risk of confusion. Then an equilibrium is a
bounded time path for each of the variables V0 V1 q 

  

15 See Coles and Wright (1998) and Ennis (1999).


satisfying (17), (18), and (15) at every point in time.
21

(latter) equilibria are characterized by deflation (infla- high-storage-cost goods are used as money. Aiyagari
tion), due simply to beliefs. If agents expect prices to and Wallace (1991, 1992) generalize this to N types
change, this can be a self-fulfilling prophecy. When and consider several applications. Wright (1995) ex-
γ 0, qL coalesces with the nonmonetary equilibrium tends the model to allow agents to choose their type.
q 0. Hence, in addition to the steady states, the set Renero (1994, 1998b, 1999) considers several exten-
of equilibria includes paths starting at any q0  0 qH
 
sions of the framework. Among other things, he shows
and converging down to q 0. that equilibria in which goods with high storage costs
serve as money can have good welfare properties, per-
haps surprisingly (the intuition is that there is more
VIII. Extensions and Related Literature trade in such equilibria). Other related papers include
In this section, we provide a short overview of some Kehoe, Kiyotaki, and Wright (1993), Cuadras-Morato
extensions to and applications of the above models and Wright (1997), and Renero (1998a).
in the literature. We will discuss some of the papers There is also a literature on search models with pri-
briefly; others we will merely mention. Our intent is vate information. Williamson and Wright (1994) as-
to provide a bibliography rather than a review, so that sume there is uncertainty concerning the quality of
the interested reader at least knows where to look.16 goods. In such an environment, a generally recog-
The basic search-theoretic monetary model can be nizable money has the potential role of mitigating the
generalized along several dimensions. Specialization informational frictions and inducing agents to adopt
is endogenized in more detail in Kiyotaki and Wright strategies that increase the probability of acquiring
(1993), Burdett, Coles, Kiyotaki, and Wright (1995), high-quality output. So money may be valued even if
Shi (1997b), and Reed (1999), for example. More the double-coincidence problem vanishes (that is, even
general production structures are incorporated in Kiy- if y 1).
otaki and Wright (1991) and Johri (1999). Long-term Trejos (1997) presents a simplified version of the
partnerships, in addition to one-time exchanges, are model (essentially by setting y 0), which allows him
considered in Siandra (1996) and Corbae and Ritter to obtain analytical solutions to the model. Kim (1996)
(1997). Various extensions of bargaining are consid- endogenizes the extent of the private information prob-
ered by Engineer and Shi (1998, 1999), Berentsen, lem. Cuadras-Morato (1994) and Yiting Li (1995b)
Molico, and Wright (forthcoming), and Jafarey and use a version of this model to study commodity money.
Masters (1999). We already mentioned credit in sec- All the above papers assume indivisible goods. Tre-
tion II, and there are several papers that attempt to jos (1999) combines private information with divisi-
have money and credit in the model at the same time: ble goods and bargaining. Velde, Weber, and Wright
Kocherlakota and Wallace (1998) assume histories are (1999) and Burdett, Trejos, and Wright (forthcoming)
imperfectly observed over time; Cavalcanti and Wal- use commodity money models with private informa-
lace(1999a,b) and Cavalcanti, Erosa, and Temzelides tion to study some issues in monetary history, includ-
(1999) assume that the histories of only some agents ing Gresham’s Law. Other related papers include Wal-
are observed; and Jin and Temzelides (1999) assume lace (1997b), Williamson (1998) and Katzman, Ken-
only histories of local neighbors are observed. Follow- nan, and Wallace (1999).
ing Diamond (1990), some papers have bilateral credit Several papers attempt to model policy as follows:
and money, with repayment (explicitly or implicitly) There is a subset of agents who are subject to the
enforced by collateral. These include Hendry (1992), same search and information frictions as everyone else
Shi (1996), Schindler (1998), and Yiting Li (forthcom-
ing). 

16 A large body of work in search theory is tangentially re-


Many papers deal with commodity money, as op- lated to the approach to monetary economics presented here.
posed to fiat money. The basic idea is to determine This brief review cannot discuss all such work, but we do want
endogenously which of many possible goods become to mention Diamond (1982); although there is no money in that
model, it is in some respects quite similar to that in section II.
media of exchange. Kiyotaki and Wright (1989) con- The version in Diamond (1984) does have money, but it is im-
sider a version of the model where type i consumes posed through a cash-in-advance constraint; so although it in
good i and produces i 1, with N 3 types. The


some ways resembles the framework presented here, its spirit


goods are all storable, although at different costs. It is quite different. See also Diamond and Yellin (1985). We
is shown that goods with low storage costs may or also mention Jones (1976) as well as the extensions by Oh
(1989) and Iwai (1996), which attempt to build a model along
may not come to serve as money, depending on pa- lines similar to those presented here; see Ostroy and Starr
rameter values as well as which equilibrium the econ- (1990) for a review of this and related work. Other general
omy is in; that is, there can be equilibria in which discussions that concentrate more on models like the ones in
this paper include Wallace (1996, 1997a).
22

but act collectively. Call these agents government will find something he likes. The Shevchenko and Li
agents. The idea is to see how government agents’ papers also endogenize the number of intermediaries
exogenously specified trading rules affect the endoge- in the economy by means of a free entry condition.
nously determined equilibrium behavior of other (pri- See also Camera (2000), Camera and Winkler (2000),
vate) agents. Papers in this group include Victor Li and Hellwig (2000).
(1994, 1995a), Ritter (1995), Aiyagari, Wallace, and The framework’s most important recent extension
Wright (1996), Aiyagari and Wallace (1997), Li and is perhaps the relaxation of the strong assumptions on
Wright (1998), Green and Weber (1996), Wallace and how much money agents can hold—typically, zero or
Zhou (1997), and Berentsen (2000). For example, in one unit of money, as we assume above. Models that
Victor Li (1994, 1995a, 1997), government agents can consider such an extension can be an order of magni-
tax money holdings when they meet private agents. A tude more complicated, but they are obviously more
key result is that taxing money holdings may be ef- realistic and generate many interesting new results.
ficient. The reason is that in his model (which also They are also capable of addressing more traditional
endogenizes search intensity) there is too little search policy questions, such as the optimal rate of inflation,
by agents holding money, for standard reasons. Taxing which are difficult to study in models where agents
them increases their search effort, and this can improve hold only zero or one unit of money. Such a model
welfare. is contained in Molico (1999), who allows agents to
The matching model seems a natural one for study- hold any nonnegative amount of money and to bargain
ing issues related to international monetary economics. over the quantity of goods as well as the amount of
For example, one can think about parameterizing dif- money that is traded in each bilateral meeting. Be-
ferences in the efficiency of economic activity as well cause of the model’s complexity, however, it can only
as degrees of openness across countries in terms of ar- be solved numerically. The numerical analysis gener-
rival rates. Among the first authors to analyze this in a ates interesting results on policy, welfare, the equilib-
model with multiple currencies and multiple countries rium distribution of prices, and other issues.
are Matsuyama, Kiyotaki, and Matsui (1993). They Green and Zhou (1998b) and Zhou (1999) also
find that several types of equilibria can arise, includ- present a model with divisible money, where several
ing those in which one currency circulates only lo- results can be derived analytically. Unlike Molico,
cally while another emerges as an international cur- they assume that sellers set prices and cannot observe
rency; they find other equilibria in which all currencies buyers’ money holdings. Although such an environ-
are universally accepted. They compare these equi- ment could still have equilibria with a distribution of
libria in terms of welfare. Zhou (1997) extends their prices, they only look for equilibria where all sellers
model to study currency exchange. These models as- set the same price. Several interesting results emerge,
sume indivisible goods. Trejos and Wright (1999) en- including the existence of multiple (indeed, a contin-
dogenize prices using divisible goods and bargaining. uum of) steady states, indexed by the nominal price
Other examples of models with multiple currencies in- level. Also, there can be an endogenous upper bound
clude Kultti (1996), Green and Weber (1996), Craig for money holdings: Agents with sufficient cash will
and Waller (1999), Peterson (2000), and Curtis and not accept more. (Molico’s model can also generate
Waller (2000). this.) Related references are Green and Zhou (1998a),
Some papers consider intermediation (in the form of Zhou (1998), Camera and Corbae (1999), Taber and
middlemen, for example) as an alternative (or some- Wallace (1999), Berentsen (1999a,b), and Rocheteau
times in addition) to money. An early paper to explic- (1999). Shi (1997a) presents an analytically solvable
itly consider intermediation in a search model with- model with perfectly divisible money, but his model is
out money is Rubinstein and Wolinsky (1987). They quite different in some dimensions from the rest of the
generate a role for middlemen by specifying exoge- literature.17
nously a set of agents who may have a more effi- There are other applications and extensions that can-
cient technology for finding buyers than sellers have not all be considered in this brief review. However,
for finding buyers. Yiting Li (1998) is a very different
model, in which private information about the qual- 

17 In Shi’s model, the decision-making unit consists of a


ity of consumption goods combined with the existence family with a large number of members (formally, a contin-
of a costly quality verification technology give rise to uum), rather than a single individual. In this framework, family
a role for intermediation. In Shevchenko (2000), in- members share money holdings between periods, so every
termediation arises from inventory-theoretic consider- family starts the next period with the same amount of money
ations: Middlemen keep a stock of several goods on by the law of large numbers. Applications and extensions of
this model are contained in Shi (1998, 1999).
hand to increase the probability that a random buyer
23

we want to mention some examples of papers that


study evolution or learning in this framework, includ-
ing Marimon, McGrattan, and Sargent (1990), Sethi
(1996), Staudinger (1998) and Basçi (1999). They
are interested in determining which of the equilibria
are more robust; for example, can agents learn to use
money? Brown (1996), Duffy and Ochs (1998, 1999),
and Duffy (2001) ask the same kind of questions, but
use laboratory methods with paid human subjects to
test them experimentally. Although the results are by
no means definitive, they are interesting in that they
point to certain areas where laboratory subjects do not
behave as theory predicts. However, the most recent
experiments (Duffy, 2001) produce results that are en-
couraging from the perspective of the theory.

IX. Conclusion
In this paper, we have presented simple versions of the
basic search-theoretic models of monetary exchange.
Even these simple models allow a variety of questions
to be addressed, and there are a wide range of exten-
sions and applications. We hope this illustrates the use-
fulness of the framework for monetary economics and
will encourage the reader to pursue these issues fur-
ther.
24

Appendix functions can be written

Proof of Proposition 1: For pure strategy equilibria,


insert π0 and π1 into equations (3) and (4) and deter- rV1 yM u c 1 y 1 M ∆1


  

  

mine the region of parameter space in which the in- y1 M β ψ1 1 β ψ0 u c


 

  

equalities in (5) hold. Consider π0 π1 1. For this


   

y1 M 1 β ψ1 1 β ψ0 1 ψ0 ∆ 1 γ
 

to be an equilibrium, we require ∆0 0 and ∆1 0. In-


    

   

serting π0 π1 1 into (3) and (4), one finds ∆0 0 rV0 y1 M u c 1 y M∆0




  

  

and ∆1 0 if and only if r r1 r4 , as stated in the 

 



yM β ψ1 


1 

β ψ0 u 



c 

proposition. The other pure strategy cases are sim-


yM 1 β ψ1 1 β ψ0 1 ψ0 ∆ 0


ilar. For mixed strategies, solve ∆ j 0 for π j and


   

   

then determine the region of parameter space in which Since we are in case (ii), we have ∆1 0, ∆0 u c 

πj  0 1 . Consider π0 0 1 and π1 1. For this 

and ψ1 1. Hence, subtracting V1 and V0 and simpli-


to be an equilibrium, we require ∆0 0 and ∆1 0.
   

fying, we have
Now ∆0 0 implies
(20)
rc γ
π0 γ 1 yM y1 M 1 β


ru u c
 

y


ψ0
    

1 M u c
    

y1 M 1 β u c


 

 

  

  

It is easy to see that π0 0 iff r r3 and π0 1 iff


This equality is violated for generic parameter values
r r4 , and the condition ∆1 0 is redundant. Hence,
 

when ψ0 0. Hence there is no equilibrium where


this equilibrium exists iff r r 3 r4 , as stated. The
sellers propose cash with probability 1. A symmetric


 

other mixed-strategy cases are similar. In this way, we


argument for case (i) implies there is no equilibrium
obtain the complete set of equilibria.
where buyers propose cash with probability 1. This
Proof of Proposition 2: First note that rejecting a means that the unique pure strategy equilibrium is for
barter offer is always strictly dominated by accepting, agents to propose barter with probability 1: ψ0 ψ1
given u c. Now suppose that the seller gets to pro-

1.
pose and that he proposes a cash transaction. There are
three possibilities. First, if ∆1 0 the proposal will be
rejected, so the seller would have been strictly better
off proposing barter. Second, if ∆1 0 then the pro-
posal will be accepted, but in this case ∆0 u c (be-


cause ∆0 ∆1 u c), so again the seller would have




been strictly better off proposing barter. So a seller


would never propose a cash trade over barter except
possibly if ∆1 0. A symmetric argument implies that
a buyer would never propose a cash trade except pos-
sibly if ∆0 0. This gives us two cases to consider: (i)
∆0 0, which implies ∆1 u c, which further im- 

plies ψ0 1 (since ∆1 0 implies the seller strictly

prefers barter), which is the only case in which we can


have ψ1 1; and (ii) ∆1 0, which implies ∆0 u c 

and ψ1 1, which is the only case in which we can


have ψ0 1.
Consider case (ii), where ∆1 0, ∆0 u c, ψ0 1 

and ψ1 1 in equilibrium. Note ∆0 u c implies 

π0 1. Suppose π1 1; then the agent without money


gets π1 ∆0 π1 u c from proposing a cash transac-


tion, which is strictly less than what he gets proposing


barter. So ψ0 1 requires π0 π1 1. Now the value
25

References Matchmaking,” Macroeconomic Dynamics, vol. 4,


no. 3 (September 2000).
Aiyagari, S. Rao, and Neil Wallace. “Existence
Camera, Gabriele, and Dean Corbae. “Money and
of Steady States with Positive Consumption in the
Price Dispersion,” International Economic Review,
Kiyotaki-Wright Model,” Review of Economic Stud-
vol. 40, no. 4 (November 1999), pp. 985–1008.
ies, vol. 58, no. 5 (October 1991), pp. 901–916.
Camera, Gabriele, and Johannes Winkler. “Stores,
Aiyagari, S. Rao, and Neil Wallace. “Fiat Money
Prices, and Currency Substitution,” Unpublished
in the Kiyotaki-Wright Model,” Economic Theory,
manuscript, 2000.
vol. 2, no. 4 (October 1992), pp. 447–464.
Cavalcanti, Ricardo de O., Andres Erosa, and Ted
Aiyagari, S. Rao, and Neil Wallace. “Government
Temzelides. “Private Money and Reserve Manage-
Transactions Policy, the Medium of Exchange, and
ment in a Random Matching Model,” Journal of
Welfare,” Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 74,
Political Economy, vol. 107, no. 5 (October 1999),
no. 1 (May 1997), pp. 1–18.
pp. 929–945.
Aiyagari, S. Rao, Neil Wallace, and Randall
Cavalcanti, Ricardo de O., and Neil Wallace. “In-
Wright. “Coexistence of Money and Interest-
side and Outside Money as Alternative Media of Ex-
Bearing Securities,” Journal of Monetary Eco-
change,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking,
nomics, vol. 37, no. 3 (June 1996), pp. 397–419.
vol. 31, no. 3 (August 1999a), pp. 443–457.
Araujo, Luis. “Social Norms as a Medium of Ex-
Cavalcanti, Ricardo de O., and Neil Wallace. “A
change,” Unpublished manuscript, University of
Model of Private Bank-Note Issue,” Review of Eco-
Pennsylvania, 2000.
nomic Dynamics, vol. 2, no. 1 (January 1999b), pp.
Basçi, Erdem. “Learning by Imitation,” Journal of 104–136.
Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 23, no. 9/10
Coles, Melvyn G., and Randall Wright. “A Dy-
(September 1999), pp. 1569–1585.
namic Equilibrium Model of Search, Bargaining,
Berentsen, Aleksander. “Money Inventories in and Money,” Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 78,
Search Equilibrium,” Unpublished manuscript, no. 1 (January 1998), pp. 32–54.
1999a.
Corbae, Dean, and Joseph Ritter. “Money and
Berentsen, Aleksander. “The Optimal Distribution of Search with Enduring Relationships,” Unpublished
Money,” Unpublished manuscript, 1999b. manuscript, 1997.
Berentsen, Aleksander. “Time-Consistent Private Corbae, Dean, Ted Temzelides, and Randall
Supply of Outside Paper Money,” University of Wright. “Matching and Money,” Unpublished
Freiburg, Discussion Papers in Economics no. 1- manuscript, 2000.
2000, 2000.
Craig, Ben, and Christopher Waller. “Currency
Berentsen, Aleksander, Miguel Molico, and Ran- Portfolios and Nominal Exchange Rates in a Dual
dall Wright. “Indivisibilities, Lotteries, and Mone- Currency Search Economy,” Federal Reserve Bank
tary Exchange,” Journal of Economic Theory (forth- of Cleveland, Working Paper no. 9916, December
coming). 1999.
Brown, Paul M. “Experimental Evidence on Money Cuadras-Morato, Xavier. “Commodity Money in the
as a Medium of Exchange,” Journal of Economic Presence of Goods of Heterogeneous Quality,” Eco-
Dynamics and Control, vol. 20, no. 4 (April 1996), nomic Theory, vol. 4, no. 4 (May 1994), pp. 579–
pp. 583–600. 591.
Burdett, Kenneth, Melvyn Coles, Nobuhiro Kiy- Cuadras-Morato, Xavier, and Randall Wright.
otaki, and Randall Wright. “Buyers and Sellers: “Money as a Medium of Exchange when Goods Dif-
Should I Stay or Should I Go?” American Economic fer by Supply and Demand,” Macroeconomic Dy-
Review, vol. 85, no. 2 (May 1995), pp. 281–286. namics, vol. 1, no. 4 (1997), pp. 680–700.
Burdett, Kenneth, Alberto Trejos, and Randall Curtis, Elisabeth Soller, and Christopher J. Waller.
Wright. “Cigarette Money,” Journal of Economic “A Search Theoretic Model of Legal and Illegal Cur-
Theory (forthcoming). rency,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 45,
Camera, Gabriele. “Money, Search, and Costly no. 1 (February 2000), pp. 155–184.
26

Diamond, Peter, and Joel Yellin. “The Distribution Theory of Interest Rates, London: Macmillan, pp.
of Inventory Holdings in a Pure Exchange Barter 126–135, 1965.
Search Economy,” Econometrica, vol. 53, no. 2
Hellwig, Christian. “Money, Intermediaries and
(March 1985), pp. 409–432.
the Foundations of Cash-in-Advance Constraints,”
Diamond, Peter A. “Aggregate Demand Management Econometric Society World Congress 2000 Con-
in Search Equilibrium,” Journal of Political Econ- tributed Papers 1631, London School of Economics
omy, vol. 90, no. 5 (October 1982), pp. 881–894. Econometric Society, 2000.
Diamond, Peter A. “Money in Search Equilibrium,” Hendry, Scott. “Credit in a Search Model with
Econometrica, vol. 52, no. 1 (January 1984), pp. 1– Money as a Medium of Exchange,” Unpublished
20. manuscript, 1992.
Diamond, Peter A. “Pairwise Credit in Search Equi- Iwai, Katsuhito. “The Bootstrap Theory of Money:
librium,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 105, A Search-Theoretic Foundation of Monetary Eco-
no. 2 (May 1990), pp. 285–319. nomics,” Structural Change and Economic Dynam-
Duffy, John. “Learning to Speculate: Experiments ics, vol. 7, no. 4 (December 1996), pp. 451–477.
with Artificial and Real Agents,” Journal of Eco- Jafarey, Saqib, and Adrian Masters. “Prices and the
nomic Dynamics and Control, vol. 25, no. 3/4 Velocity of Money in Search Equilibrium,” Unpub-
(March 2001), pp. 295–319. lished manuscript, 1999.
Duffy, John, and Jack Ochs. “Fiat Money as a Jevons, William S. Money and the Mechanism of Ex-
Medium of Exchange: Experimental Evidence,” change. London: Appleton, 1875.
Unpublished manuscript, 1998.
Jin, Yi, and Ted Temzelides. “On the Local Inter-
Duffy, John, and Jack Ochs. “Emergence of Money action of Money and Credit,” University of Iowa,
as a Medium of Exchange: An Experimental Study,” Working Paper no. 99-05, 1999.
American Economic Review, vol. 89, no. 4 (Septem-
Johri, Alok. “Search, Money, and Prices,” Interna-
ber 1999), pp. 847–877.
tional Economic Review, vol. 40, no. 2 (May 1999),
Engineer, Merwan, and Shouyong Shi. “Asymme- pp. 439–454.
try, Imperfectly Transferable Utility, and the Role
Jones, Robert A. “The Origin and Development of
of Fiat Money in Improving Terms of Trade,” Jour-
Media of Exchange,” Journal of Political Economy,
nal of Monetary Economics, vol. 41, no. 1 (February
vol. 84, no. 4 (August 1976), pp. 757–775.
1998), pp. 153–183.
Katzman, Brett, John Kennan, and Neil Wallace.
Engineer, Merwan, and Shouyong Shi. “Bargains,
“Optimal MonetaryImpulse-Response Functions in
Barter and Money,” Unpublished manuscript, 1999.
a Matching Model,” National Bureau of Eco-
Ennis, Huberto M. “Bargaining When Sunspots Mat- nomic Research, Working Paper no. 7425, Novem-
ter,” Cornell University Center for Analytic Eco- ber 1999.
nomics, Working Paper no. 99-03, 1999.
Kehoe, Timothy J., Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, and Ran-
Green, Edward, and Ruilin Zhou. “Money and the dall Wright. “More on Money as a Medium of
Law of One Price: The Case without Discounting,” Exchange,” Economic Theory, vol. 3, no. 2 (April
Unpublished manuscript, 1998a. 1993), pp. 297–314.
Green, Edward, and Ruilin Zhou. “A Rudimentary Kim, Young Sik. “Money, Barter and Costly Informa-
Model of Search with Divisible Money and Prices,” tion Acquisition,” Journal of Monetary Economics,
Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 81, no. 2 (August vol. 37, no. 1 (February 1996), pp. 119–142.
1998b), pp. 252–271. Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and Randall Wright. “On
Green, Edward J., and Warren E. Weber. “Will the Money as a Medium of Exchange,” Journal of Po-
New $100 Bill Decrease Counterfeiting?” Federal litical Economy, vol. 97, no. 4 (August 1989), pp.
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review, 927–954.
vol. 20, no. 3 (Summer 1996), pp. 3–10.
Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and Randall Wright. “A Con-
Hahn, Frank. “On Some Problems of Proving the Ex- tribution to the Pure Theory of Money,” Journal of
istence of an Equilibrium in a Monetary Economy,” Economic Theory, vol. 53, no. 2 (April 1991), pp.
In Frank Hahn and Frank R. Brechling, eds., The 215–235.
27

Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and Randall Wright. “A national Currency,” Review of Economic Studies,
Search-Theoretic Approach to Monetary Eco- vol. 60, no. 2 (April 1993), pp. 283–307.
nomics,” American Economic Review, vol. 83, no. 3
Molico, Miguel. “The Distribution of Money
(March 1993), pp. 63–77.
and Prices in Search Equilibrium,” Unpublished
Kocherlakota, Narayana, and Neil Wallace. “In- manuscript, 1999.
complete Record-Keeping and Optimal Payment
Oh, Seonghwan. “A Theory of a Generally Accept-
Arrangements,” Journal of Economic Theory,
able Medium of Exchange and Barter,” Journal of
vol. 81, no. 2 (August 1998), pp. 272–289.
Monetary Economics, vol. 23, no. 1 (January 1989),
Kocherlakota, Narayana R. “Money Is Memory,” pp. 101–119.
Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 81, no. 2 (August
Osborne, Martin J., and Ariel Rubinstein. Bargain-
1998), pp. 232–251.
ing and Markets. San Diego: Academic Press, 1990.
Kocherlakota, Narayana R. “The One-Money and
Ostroy, Joseph M., and Ross M. Starr. “The Trans-
Two-Money Theorems,” Unpublished manuscript,
action Role of Money,” In Benjamin M. Friedman
2000.
and Frank H. Hahn, eds., Handbook of Monetary
Kultti, Klaus. “A Monetary Economy with Counter- Economics, Vol. I, Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp.
feiting,” Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, vol. 63, 3–62, 1990.
no. 2 (1996), pp. 175–186.
Peterson, Brian. “Endogenous Money Supply, Cur-
Li, Victor E. “Inventory Accumulation in a Search- rency Flows, and the Current Account,” Unpub-
Based Monetary Economy,” Journal of Monetary lished manuscript, 2000.
Economics, vol. 34, no. 3 (December 1994), pp.
Reed, Robert R., III. “Money, Specialization, and
511–536.
Economic Growth,” Unpublished manuscript, 1999.
Li, Victor E. “The Optimal Taxation of Fiat Money in
Renero, Juan-Manuel. “Welfare of Alternative Equi-
Search Equilibrium,” International Economic Re-
librium Paths in the Kiyotaki-Wright Model,” Insti-
view, vol. 36, no. 4 (November 1995a), pp. 927–942.
tuto Tecnológico Autonómo de México, Discussion
Li, Victor E. “The Efficiency of Monetary Exchange Paper Series no. 95-02, July 1994.
in Search Equilibrium,” Journal of Money, Credit, Renero, Juan-Manuel. “The Simple Case of
and Banking, vol. 29, no. 1 (February 1997), pp. 61– Subsidiary-Coin Shortages Driven by Deflation in
72. POW Camps,” Unpublished manuscript, 1998a.
Li, Yiting. “Commodity Money Under Private Infor- Renero, Juan-Manuel. “Unstable and Stable Steady
mation,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 36, States in the Kiyotaki-Wright Model,” Economic
no. 3 (December 1995b), pp. 573–92. Theory, vol. 11, no. 2 (March 1998b), pp. 275–294.
Li, Yiting. “Middlemen and Private Information,” Renero, Juan-Manuel. “Does and Should a Com-
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 42, no. 1 (Au- modity Medium of Exchange Have Relatively Low
gust 1998), pp. 131–159. Storage Costs?” International Economic Review,
Li, Yiting. “A Search Model of Money and Circulation vol. 40, no. 2 (May 1999), pp. 251–264.
Private Debt with Applications to Monetary Policy,” Ritter, Joseph A. “The Transition from Barter to Fiat
International Economic Review (forthcoming). Money,” American Economic Review, vol. 85, no. 1
Li, Yiting, and Randall Wright. “Government Trans- (March 1995), pp. 134–149.
action Policy, Media of Exchange, and Prices,” Rocheteau, Guillaume. “Optimal Quantity of Money
Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 81, no. 2 (August and Trade Frictions,” Unpublished manuscript,
1998), pp. 289–313. 1999.
Marimon, Ramon, Ellen R. McGrattan, and Rubinstein, Ariel, and Asher Wolinsky. “Middle-
Thomas J. Sargent. “Money as a Medium of Ex- men,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 102,
change in an Economy with Artificially Intelligent no. 3 (August 1987), pp. 581–594.
Agents,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Con-
trol, vol. 14, no. 2 (May 1990), pp. 329–373. Rupert, Peter, Martin Schindler, and Randall
Wright. “Generalized Search-Theoretic Models of
Matsuyama, Kiminori, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, and Monetary Exchange,” Journal of Monetary Eco-
Akihiko Matsui. “Towards a Theory of Inter- nomics (forthcoming).
28

Schindler, Martin. “A Re-Examination of Credit 141.


and Money in Search Equilibrium,” Unpublished Trejos, Alberto, and Randall Wright. “Toward a
manuscript, 1998. Theory of International Currency: A Step Further,”
Sethi, Rajiv. “Evolutionary Stability and Media of Unpublished manuscript, 1999.
Exchange,” Unpublished manuscript, 1996.
Velde, François R., Warren E. Weber, and Randall
Shevchenko, Andrei. “Middlemen,” Unpublished Wright. “A Model of Commodity Money, with Ap-
manuscript, 2000. plications to Gresham’s Law and the Debasement
Shi, Shouyong. “Money and Prices: A Model of Puzzle,” Review of Economic Dynamics, vol. 2,
Search and Bargaining,” Journal of Economic The- no. 1 (January 1999), pp. 291–323.
ory, vol. 67, no. 2 (December 1995), pp. 467–496. Wallace, Neil. “A Dictum for Monetary Theory,” In
Shi, Shouyong. “Credit and Money in a Search Model Steven G. Medema and Warren J. Samuels, eds.,
with Divisible Commodities,” Review of Economic Foundations of Research in Economics: How Do
Studies, vol. 63, no. 4 (October 1996), pp. 627–652. Economists Do Economics?, Brookfield, Vt.: Ed-
ward Elgar, pp. 248–259, 1996.
Shi, Shouyong. “A Divisible Search Model of Fiat
Money,” Econometrica, vol. 65, no. 1 (January Wallace, Neil. “Absence-of-Double-Coincidence
1997a), pp. 75–102. Models of Money: A Progress Report,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review,
Shi, Shouyong. “Money and Specialization,” Eco- vol. 21, no. 1 (Winter 1997a), pp. 2–20.
nomic Theory, vol. 10, no. 1 (June 1997b), pp. 99–
113. Wallace, Neil. “Short-Run and Long-Run Effects of
Changes in Money in a Random-Matching Model,”
Shi, Shouyong. “Search for a Monetary Propagation Journal of Political Economy, vol. 105, no. 6 (De-
Mechanism,” Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 81, cember 1997b), pp. 1293–1307.
no. 2 (August 1998), pp. 314–352.
Wallace, Neil, and Ruilin Zhou. “A Model of a Cur-
Shi, Shouyong. “Search, Inflation and Capital Accu- rency Shortage,” Journal of Monetary Economics,
mulation,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 44, vol. 40, no. 3 (December 1997), pp. 555–572.
no. 1 (August 1999), pp. 81–103.
Williamson, Stephen D. “Private Money,” University
Siandra, Eduardo. “A Monetary Model of Market of Iowa, Working Paper no. 98-09 1998.
Size and Specialisation,” University of Cambridge,
Economic Theory Discussion Paper no. 182, 1993. Williamson, Stephen D., and Randall Wright.
“Barter and Monetary Exchange under Private In-
Siandra, Eduardo. “Partnerships, Search and formation,” American Economic Review, vol. 84,
Money,” Unpublished manuscript, 1996. no. 1 (March 1994), pp. 104–123.
Staudinger, Sylvia. “Money as a Medium of Ex- Wright, Randall. “Search, Evolution, and Money,”
change: An Analysis with Genetic Algorithms,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,
Unpublished manuscript, 1998. vol. 19, no. 1-2 (January–February 1995), pp. 181–
Taber, Alexander, and Neil Wallace. “A Match- 206.
ing Model with Bounded Holdings of Indivisible Zhou, Ruilin. “Currency Exchange in a Random
Money,” International Economic Review, vol. 40, Search Model,” Review of Economic Studies,
no. 4 (November 1999), pp. 961–984. vol. 64, no. 2 (April 1997), pp. 289–310.
Trejos, Alberto. “Incentives to Produce Quality and Zhou, Ruilin. “Does Commodity Money Eliminate
the Liquidity of Money,” Economic Theory, vol. 9, the Indeterminacy of Equilibria?” Unpublished
no. 2 (February 1997), pp. 355–365. manuscript, 1998.
Trejos, Alberto. “Search, Bargaining, Money, and Zhou, Ruilin. “Individual and Aggregate Real Bal-
Prices under Private Information,” International ances in a Random-Matching Model,” International
Economic Review, vol. 40, no. 3 (August 1999), pp. Economic Review, vol. 40, no. 4 (November 1999),
679–695. pp. 1009–1038.
Trejos, Alberto, and Randall Wright. “Search, Bar-
gaining, Money, and Prices,” Journal of Political
Economy, vol. 103, no. 1 (February 1995), pp. 118–

You might also like