Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 20

Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Economic Modelling
journal homepage: www.journals.elsevier.com/economic-modelling

The impacts of workers’ remittances on human capital and labor supply in


developing countries
SeyedSoroosh Azizi
Department of Economics, Northern Illinois University (NIU), USA

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

JEL classification numbers: This study investigates the impacts of workers’ remittances on human capital and labor supply by using data
D64 for 122 developing countries from 1990 to 2015. This topic has not been explored thoroughly at the aggregate
F22 level, mainly due to endogeneity of remittances and the difficulty in finding instruments to resolve this issue.
F24
To address the endogeneity of remittances, I estimate bilateral remittances and use them to create weighted
O15
indicators of remittance-sending countries. These weighted indicators are used as instruments for remittance
inflow to remittance-receiving countries. Results obtained in this study indicate that remittances raise per capita
Keywords: health expenditures and reduce undernourishment prevalence, depth of food deficit, prevalence of stunting,
Migration
and child mortality rate. Remittances also raise school enrollment, school completion rate, and private school
Remittances
enrollment. Although there is no difference in the impact of remittances on the health outcome of boys and
Health
Education girls, remittances improve the educational outcome of girls more than the educational outcome of boys. Further,
Human capital remittances decrease the female labor force participation rate but do not affect the male labor force participation
Labor supply rate.
Developing countries

1. Introduction ity (Acosta, 2006; Adams and Page, 2005; Li and Zhou, 2013; Bang et
al., 2016); remittances and financial development (Brown et al., 2013;
Between 1990 and 2015, the number of individuals living outside Aggarwal et al., 2011; Coulibaly, 2015; Chowdhury, 2011); environ-
their countries of birth grew from 153 million people to 244 million mental effects of remittances (Li and Zhou, 2015); the impact of remit-
people, which corresponds to 2.87% of the world population in the tances on labor productivity (Al Mamun et al., 2015); the impact of
year 1990 and 3.32% of the world population in the year 2015 (United remittances on political institutions (Williams, 2017). Although most
Nations). The total amount of remittances received has risen from $68 researchers have investigated the impacts of remittance inflows on
billion in 1990 to $553 billion in 2015. The average amount of money remittance-receiving countries, there are few studies on the impacts
each migrant remitted (in 2011 constant dollars) has risen from $688 of remittance outflows on remittance-sending countries (Hathroubi and
in 1990 to $2128 in 2015. These amounts include only remittances Aloui, 2016; Alkhathlan, 2013).
that have been sent through official channels (the World Bank, United There is a clear distinction between the remittance inflow to devel-
Nations, author’s calculations). oping countries and the remittance inflow to developed countries. In
This surge in the value of remittances has attracted the attention of the year 2015, the average workers’ remittances to GDP ratio for devel-
many researchers. During recent years, different aspects of remittances oping country was 2% and for developed countries was 0.6%. Remit-
have been under the scrutiny of researchers. One of the main aspects of tance to developed countries is not the primary interest of this paper;
remittances is impacts of remittances on remittance-receiving countries. instead, the impacts of remittances on human capital and labor supply
The inflow of remittances can affect remittance-receiving countries in in developing countries is explored in this paper. In the past few years,
a variety of subjects such as the growth impact of remittance (Rao and many researchers have examined the impact of remittances on human
Hassan, 2011; Gapen et al., 2009; Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz, 2009; capital or labor supply in a specific country or region. The primary
Ziesemer, 2012); the impact of remittances on poverty and inequal- barrier in evaluating the impact of remittances on human capital, in
case of all developing countries, is endogeneity of remittances. Remit-

E-mail addresses: sazizi1@niu.edu, seyedsoroosh.azizi@gmail.com.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2018.07.011
Received 18 February 2018; Received in revised form 9 July 2018; Accepted 11 July 2018
Available online 25 July 2018
0264-9993/© 2018 The Author. Published by Elsevier B.V. This is an open access article under the CC BY license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

tances are endogenous to education, health outcomes, and labor supply and exchange rates did not consider the endogeneity of remittances.
of those left behind. Reverse causality, common factors affecting both However, most of the recent studies about the impact of remittances
remittances and human capital, and measurement error are among the on different aspects of remittance-receiving households and countries
sources of endogeneity. Finding instruments to overcome endogeneity recognize the endogeneity of remittances and include different method-
of remittances in one country is easier than finding valid and strong ologies to resolve the problem of endogeneity of remittances.
instruments for remittances in all developing countries. The traditional and most popular method of addressing the endo-
To address the endogeneity of remittances, this research uses a geneity of remittances is to use instrumental variables. While the instru-
novel instrumental variable (IV) approach by incorporating three eco- ments must be strong, the bigger challenge to researchers is to find
nomic indicators of the remittance-sending countries as instruments: valid (i.e. not correlated with the error term) instruments. Generally,
per capita Gross National Income (GNI), unemployment rate, and real three categories of instruments are used by different authors: instru-
interest rate. Since each remittance-receiving country has many coun- ments related to remittance-receiving countries, instruments related to
tries as the sources of remittances, building the instruments requires remittance-sending countries, and instruments related to the cost of
knowing the bilateral remittances to calculate the weighted average remittances.
indicators of the remittance-sending countries. Because bilateral remit- Not many papers have addressed the endogeneity of remittances at
tances are not generally available, I estimate them and use them as the aggregate level. Adams and Page (2005) is one of the first stud-
weights to build the instruments. This estimation strategy allows me ies which addresses endogeneity of remittances in the country-level.
to utilize three valid and strong instruments, which are related to They use three instrumental variables to account for endogeneity of
remittance-sending countries, to investigate the impacts of workers’ the impact of remittances on poverty. The first instrument is the dis-
remittances on human capital and labor supply in remittance-receiving tance (miles) between the four major remittance-sending areas and
countries. I also use this IV approach to study gender-specific impacts remittance-receiving countries. The second instrument used by them
of remittances on health, education, and labor supply in developing is the percentage of the population over age 25 that has completed
countries. secondary education. This variable is correlated with education, and
The results obtained in this paper indicate that remittances raise it is not a valid instrument in this research. The third variable used
per capita out-of-pocket health expenditures and per capita total health by them is government stability. The effect of government stability on
expenditures and reduce undernourishment prevalence, depth of food remittances can be positive (if migrants have investment incentives,
deficit, prevalence of stunting, and child mortality rate. Remittances they remit more if their home countries are more stable) or negative
also raise school enrollment, school completion rate, and private school (if migrants have altruistic incentives, they remit more if their home
enrollment. As a robustness check, this paper investigates the overall countries are less stable). Government stability also can be correlated
impact of remittances on Human Development Index (HDI) and shows with educational attainment and health outcome.
that remittances increase HDI. Another contribution of this paper is This section is divided into three parts. First, a summary of papers
showing the gender-specific effects of remittances. Although there is no which study the effects of remittances on health outcomes is provided.
difference in the impact of remittances on the health outcome of boys Then, papers which investigate the impacts of remittances on educa-
and girls, remittances raise the education investment in girls more than tion are reviewed. Lastly, papers which examine the impacts of remit-
in boys. Further, remittances decrease the female labor force participa- tances on labor supply are summarized. Due to the importance of the
tion rate but do not affect the male labor force participation rate. endogeneity issue, special attention is paid to the instruments used by
Remittances can lift budget constraints, thereby providing children different authors.
in remittance-receiving households the opportunity to go to school or
have better health outcomes. While remittances can benefit households 2.1. Remittances and health
by lifting liquidity constraints, migration of a family member can have
a negative impact on the household’s well-being. Migration of a produc- Researchers who have studied the impact of remittances on health
tive family member may have disruptive effects on the life of the house- outcome mainly focused on three health measurements: health expen-
hold. These observations lead to a fundamental development question: ditures, nutrition status, and child mortality rates. In the following, I
do remittances to developing countries contribute to higher investment briefly discuss papers who consider the impacts of remittances on these
in human capital? This research examines this question by exploring the three aspects of health outcome. Note that health expenditure is not an
major factors influencing education and health outcomes in developing aspect of health outcome per se, but it has a strong impact on health
countries. outcome.
This paper addresses three main questions: To what extent can the Ambrosius and Cuecuecha (2013) test the assumption that remit-
remittances to developing countries improve health and education out- tances are a substitute for credit by comparing the response to health-
comes in terms of nutrition adequacy, mortality rates, school atten- related shocks using Mexican household panel data. They find that the
dance, and educational attainment? If the remittances can influence the occurrence of serious health shocks that required hospital treatment
children’s health outcome, school attendance, and educational attain- doubled the average debt burden of households with a member having a
ment, is there any difference between the genders? What is the impact health shock compared to the control group. However, households with
of remittances on labor force participation for men and women? As a parent, child, or spouse in the US did not increase their debts due to
major components of human capital, health and education impact long- health shocks. The authors use weighted linear regression to address the
run economic growth. Therefore, answering these questions is crucial to endogeneity problem. Therefore, in the case of Mexican families with
evaluate the overall effect of workers’ remittances on developing coun- a member facing a health shock, it can be concluded that remittances
tries. can play a substitute role for credit. Valero-Gil (2009) considers the
The rest of the paper is arranged as follows. Background and litera- effect of remittances on the share of health expenditures in total house-
ture review is provided in section 2. Section 3 discusses the data used hold expenditure in Mexico and finds a positive and statistically signif-
in this paper. Section 4 is devoted to the econometric model. Section 5 icant effect of remittances on the household health expenditure shares.
presents empirical results, and Section 6 some conclusions. The paper concludes that health expenditure is a target of remittances,
and a dollar from remittances is being devoted in part to health expen-
2. Background ditures. The author uses the percentage of return migration between
1995 and 2000 at the municipal level as an instrument for remittance.
Early studies on impacts of remittances on human capital (both Amuedo-Dorantes and Pozo (2011) find that international remittances
health and education), financial development, poverty and inequality, raise health care expenditures among remittance-receiving households

378
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

in Mexico. They select two variables to be included as instruments: remittances on child labor. The common belief is that if remittances
the road distance to the US border (from the capital of the Mexican decrease child labor, then they increase children’s education. While
state in which the household resides) and US wages in Mexican emi- school attendance frequently is used to measure investment on educa-
grant destination states. Their results suggest that 6 Pesos of every 100 tion, it represents the quantity of education and fails to capture the
Peso increment in remittance income are spent on health. Ponce et al. quality of education. Therefore, some researchers have used private
(2011) study the impact of remittances on health outcomes in Ecuador, school enrollment to demonstrate the quality of education.
and they do not find significant impacts on long-term child health vari- There are two theories about the impact of migration and remit-
ables. However, they find that remittances have an impact on health tances on education. On the one hand, as Bouoiyour and Miftah (2016)
expenditures. They use historic state-level migration rates as an instru- state, parents invest in the education of their children if they believe
ment for current migration shocks. such investment generates a higher rate of return than the return on
Some researchers have used a variety of measurements of nutrition savings. Some parents in low-income households invest too little in the
status as the factor representing health outcome. Food security level, education of their children because they cannot afford to finance educa-
household food consumption, child nutritional status, and low birth tional investments regardless of such returns. Hence, it is expected that
weight are some of the measurements of nutrition status. In the fol- the reduction of these liquidity constraints will make education more
lowing, I introduce four of these papers. accessible to children from poor families. Therefore, financial trans-
Generoso (2015) analyzes the main determinants of household food fers from family members can lift the budget constraints and allow
security using a survey conducted in Mali in 2005. The author uses a parents to invest in the education of their children to the extent that
partial proportional odds logit model and shows that the diversification is optimal for them. On the other hand, as Amuedo-Dorantes and
of income sources, through the reception of remittances, constitutes one Pozo (2010) state, the presence of family members abroad may induce
of the main ways of coping with the negative impact of climate haz- changes in school attendance of children in migrants’ households for
ards on food security. Combes et al. (2014) explore the role of remit- a variety of reasons. Children may have less time to devote to school-
tances and foreign aid inflows during food price shocks. They conclude ing because they engage in market activities to earn income to defray
remittance and aid inflows dampen the effect of the positive food price migration-related expenses of households. Alternatively, children may
shock and food price instability on household consumption in vulnera- leave school to perform necessary household chores that the absent
ble countries. Anton (2010) analyzes the impact of remittances on the migrant no longer attends to. Finally, if children get encouraged to
nutritional status of children under five years old in Ecuador in 2006. migrate in the future, they may drop out of school if the origin country’s
Using an instrumental variables strategy, the study finds a positive and education is not generally well-recognized in the destination.
significant effect of remittance income on short-term and middle-term Among researchers who consider the impact of remittances on edu-
child nutritional status. The author uses the number of Western Union cation and address the endogeneity of remittances, two instruments are
offices per 100,000 people at the province level as the instrument. Frank used frequently. Some studies that recognize the endogeneity of migra-
and Hummer (2002) find that membership in a migrant household pro- tion and remittances use migration networks as the instrument. Many
vides protection from the risk of low birth weight among Mexican-born studies have used economic indicators of remittance-sender countries as
infants largely through the receipt of remittances. They did not account instruments for remittances. The following papers have used migration
for endogeneity of remittances. networks as the instrument for remittances.
Many researchers have used child and infant mortality rates as the Bouoiyour and Miftah (2016) use the history of migration networks
factor representing health outcome. Reducing child mortality rate is and remittances costs as instruments to address the endogeneity of
one of the United Nations Sustainable Development Goals (SDG). The remittances. They find that the receipt of remittances in rural areas
goal is by 2030 to end preventable deaths of newborns and children of southern Morocco has a significant positive effect on school atten-
under five years of age, with all countries aiming to reduce neonatal dance, especially for boys. Acharya and Leon-Gonzalez (2014) explore
mortality to less than 12 per 1000 live births and under-5 mortality to the effects of migration and remittance on the educational attainment of
less than 25 per 1000 live births. In the following, some of these studies Nepalese children. Their results indicate that remittances help severely
are discussed. credit-constrained households enroll their children in school and pre-
Terrelonge (2014) examines how remittances and government vent dropouts. Also, remittances help households that face less severe
health spending improve child mortality in developing countries and liquidity constraints increase their investment in the quality of educa-
concludes remittances reduce mortality through improved living stan- tion. By using migration networks as instruments, the authors gain sim-
dards from the relaxation of households’ budget constraints. Chauvet ilar results. Acosta (2011) studies the effects of remittance receipt on
et al. (2013) consider the respective impact of aid, remittances and child school attendance and child labor in El Salvador. The paper uses El
medical brain drain on the child mortality rate. Their results show that Salvadorian municipal-level migrant networks and the number of inter-
remittances reduce child mortality while medical brain drain increases national migrants who returned two or more years ago as instruments to
it. Health aid also significantly reduces child mortality, but its impact is address the endogeneity of remittances. The author concludes insignif-
less robust than the impact of remittances. Kanaiaupuni and Donato icant overall impact of remittances on schooling; a strong reduction of
(1999) consider the effects of village migration and remittances on child wage labor in remittance recipient households; and an increase in
health outcomes in Mexico and conclude higher rates of infant mor- unpaid family work activities for children in those households. More-
tality in communities experiencing intense U.S. migration. On the other over, while girls seem to increase school attendance after remittance
hand, mortality risks are low when remittances are high. Zhunio et al. receipts by reducing labor activities, boys, on average, do not benefit
(2012) study the effect of international remittances on aggregate edu- from higher education. Alcaraz et al. (2012) study the effects of remit-
cational and health outcomes using a sample of 69 low- and middle- tances from the U.S. on child labor and school attendance in recipient
income countries. They find that remittances play an important role Mexican households. They use distance to the U.S. border along the
in improving primary and secondary school attainment, increasing life 1920 rail network as an instrument for the membership in the remit-
expectancy and reducing infant mortality. tance recipient group. By using the differences-in-differences method,
they find that the negative shock on remittance receipts in 2008–2009
2.2. Remittances and education caused a significant increase in child labor and a significant reduction
of school attendance.
To investigate the impact of remittances on the education of those As stated by Salas (2014) the common belief is that private schools
left behind, most of the researchers rely on school attendance as the provide better education compared to that provided by public schools.
main indicator of education. Many authors also examine the impact of Besides increasing school enrollment, remittances can affect the choice

379
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

of school type. The main limitation to access private education in devel- American countries. While remittances tend to have positive effects
oping countries is its cost. Remittances can lift the budget constraints on education for all Latin American countries with the exception of
and allow parents to invest in the quality of education of their chil- Jamaica and the Dominican Republic, the impact is often restricted to
dren, as well as its quantity. Salas investigates the effect of international specific groups of the population (e.g. the positive effect of remittances
migration on children left behind in Peru. Historical department-level on education tends to be larger when parents are less educated).
migration rate is used as an instrument for remittances. The model ana-
lyzes the role of international remittances on the investment decision 2.3. Remittances and labor supply
between sending children to a public school or to a private school and
finds that international remittances have a positive effect on the likeli- Researchers who study the impact of remittances on labor supply
hood to send children to private schools. in remittance-receiving countries mainly focus on two aspects of labor
While using migration networks to address the endogeneity of supply: labor force participation rate and hours worked per week.
migration allows us to assess the impact of migration on educational As argued by Cox-Edwards and Rodriguez-Oreggia (2009), an
attainment, it is not the best possible instrument if we are interested important concept underlying the labor force participation decision is
in impacts of remittances on educational attainment. Using economic the notion of the reservation wage. The reservation wage is the lowest
indicators of remittance-sending countries is more useful if we want to wage rate at which a worker would be willing to accept a particular
evaluate the impacts of remittances on investment in education. The type of job. A job offer involving the same type of work and the same
following studies use economic indicators of remittance-sending coun- working conditions, but at a lower wage rate, would be rejected by the
tries to address the endogeneity of remittances. worker. An increase in the reservation wage would reduce the prob-
Calero et al. (2009) investigate how remittances affect human cap- ability that an individual participates in the labor force. One of the
ital investments through relaxing resource constraints. They use infor- determinants of the reservation wage is non-labor income, which for
mation on source countries of remittances and regional variation in the an individual is a function of his or her own assets and the amount of
availability of bank offices that function as formal channels for receiv- income of other household members. The higher the level of income of
ing remittances. They show that remittances increase school enroll- the rest of the household (e.g. remittances), the higher the reservation
ment and decrease the incidence of child work, especially for girls wage of the individual, and the lower the probability that he or she
and in rural areas. Besides increasing school enrollment, remittances participates in the labor force. Many researchers have looked at remit-
affect the choice of school type. Remittances lead to a net substitu- tances as an additional non-labor income for recipient households and
tion from the public to private schooling, hence increasing the quality hypothesized that the presence of remittances would lead to a reduction
of human capital investments in children. Bargain and Boutin (2015) in labor force participation among recipient household members.
explore the effects of remittance receipt on child labor in Burkina Faso. In studying the impact of migration and remittances on labor supply
They use economic conditions in remittance-sending countries as instru- in recipient-households and receiving-countries, migration and remit-
ments for remittances. The authors conclude while remittances have no tances are endogenous. Migration and remittances are correlated with
significant effect on child labor on average, they reduce child labor in the error term due to a variety of factors. Reverse causality, omitted
long-term migrant households, for whom the disruptive effect of migra- variable bias (uncontrolled common factors affecting both migration
tion is no longer felt. Fajnzylber and Lopez (2008) argue that in 11 and remittances and labor supply) and measurement errors are among
Latin American countries with the exception of Mexico, children of the potential sources of endogeneity. If the migrant’s decision on how
remittances-receiving families are more likely to remain in school. The much to remit depends on whether the family members are looking for
positive effect of remittances on education tends to be larger when par- a job or not, reverse causality exists. Omitted variable bias may exist
ents are less educated. The authors use two external instruments based if remittances are related to the remittance-recipient family members’
on the real output per capita of the countries where remittances origi- wealth or ambition, which may be correlated to the labor supply by
nate. Amuedo-Dorantes et al. (2010) address the endogeneity of remit- the recipient. Many researchers use instrumental variables to address
tance receipt and find that the receipt of remittances by the households the endogeneity of migration and remittances. Particularly, migration
in Haiti lifts budget constraints and raises the children’s likelihood of networks are used frequently to address the endogeneity of migration
being schooled, and the disruptive effect of household out-migration and remittances. In the following, I review some papers which used this
imposes an economic burden on the remaining household members and approach.
reduces children’s school attendance. They use two variables as instru- Nguyen and Purnamasari (2011) apply an instrumental variable esti-
ments: weekly earnings of workers in the United States who are similar mation method, using historical migration networks as instruments for
to potential Haitian remitters, and unemployment in those geographic migration and remittance receipts and find that, in Indonesia, migration
areas in which the household is likely to have migrant networks. reduces the working hours of remaining household members. Hanson
Some other papers use other instrumental variables or do not (2007), based on rural households in Mexico in 2000, concludes indi-
address the endogeneity of remittance. Bansak and Chezum (2009) viduals are less likely to participate in the labor force if their household
examine the impact of remittances on educational attainment of school- either has sent migrants abroad or received remittances from abroad.
age children in Nepal, focusing on differences between girls and boys. The author also finds that women from high-migration states become
They use past literacy rates and political unrest by the district as instru- less likely to work relative to women from low-migration states. The
mental variables to address the endogeneity. Their results indicate that author argues that the unobserved characteristics of households that
positive net remittances increase the probability of young children affect labor supply are also likely to affect whether households choose
attending schools. Yang (2008) concludes that favorable shocks in the to send migrants abroad, and uses historical emigration rates as one of
migrants’ exchange rates (appreciation of the host counties’ currency the approaches to address the endogeneity issue. Acosta (2006) con-
versus Philippine peso) lead to enhanced human capital accumulation trols for household wealth and uses selection correction techniques and
in origin households, a rise in child schooling and educational expendi- concludes that, in El Salvador, remittances are negatively related to the
ture, and a fall in child labor. Edwards and Ureta (2003) examine the adult female labor supply. However, on average adult male labor force
effect of remittances from abroad on households’ schooling decisions participation remains unaffected. The author recognizes the endogene-
using data for El Salvador. They examine the determinants of school ity issue and uses the village migrant networks and the number of inter-
attendance and find that remittances have a large and significant effect national migrants who returned two or more years ago as instruments
on school retention. The main issue with their paper is that they do not for remittance receipts.
recognize the problem of endogeneity. Acosta et al. (2007) explore the Many authors use other instruments to address the endogeneity of
impact of remittances on poverty, education, and health in eleven Latin remittances. For example, Amuedo-Dorantes and Pozo (2006) assess the

380
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

impact of remittances on Mexicans labor supply. They use per capita Between 1990 and 2015, personal transfers constituted 66% of remit-
count of Western Union offices in the state as an instrument for address- tances, and compensation of employees constituted 34% of remittances.
ing the endogeneity of remittances. They conclude while overall male In the year 2015, these ratios were 65% and 35% respectively. As Chami
labor supply does not vary because of changes in remittance income, et al. (2009a) and Chami et al. (2009b) show, this aggregation is not
its composition by type of employment does. Unlike men, the over- appropriate since the two different types of transfers have different
all female labor supply decrease due to changes in remittance income, properties and respond differently to economic shocks. Thus, I follow
although only in rural areas. Acosta et al. (2008) conclude that in all 10 Combes et al. (2014) in using only workers’ remittances as the measure
Latin American and Caribbean countries examined, remittances have a of remittances. Therefore, the narrow definition of remittances (work-
reducing effect on the number of hours worked per week. This negative ers’ remittances) is used in this paper to record remittances. Remit-
effect is present both in urban and rural areas. Afterward, remittances tances are divided by remittance-receiving countries’ populations and
are instrumented with the share of remittance-receiving households in converted in constant 2011 international dollars. The income variable
the country interacted with household characteristics that affect their in equation (1) is per capita Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in constant
likelihood to migrate. After instrumenting for endogeneity, their neg- 2011 international dollars adjusted for purchasing power parity (PPP).
ative impact on labor force participation ceases to be significant in a In this paper, I report the impacts of remittances on two types
number of cases. They also find that the reductions in labor supply of human capital: health outcomes and educational attainment. After
caused by remittances tend to be much smaller among individuals with investigating the impacts of remittances on health outcomes and edu-
higher levels of schooling. cational attainment, as a robustness check, I examine the effect of remit-
Some researchers use other methods to address the endogeneity of tances on HDI. Finally, I estimate the impact of workers’ remittances on
remittances, or they do not address this problem at all. Guha (2013) labor force participation.
states that with an increase in the non-wage income, such as remit- To fully investigate the impacts of workers’ remittances on all
tances, the households will work less and have more leisure, as the aspects of health and education outcomes in developing countries, nine
loss in the wage income gets compensated by the remittance income. health measurements and nine education indicators have been used
The author uses international remittances to Bangladesh as the refer- as dependent variables. Using different health and education measure-
ence case, and applies Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) ments is an excellent robustness check and ensures that demonstrated
model, to show that a sudden increase in foreign remittances results in a positive impacts of remittances on health and education outcomes do
fall in the labor supply to the traded sector and a decline in the output not happen by chance.
in the traded sector. Cox-Edwards and Rodriguez-Oreggia (2009) use Nine health measurements are examined in this research: per capita
propensity score matching to separate persistent from sporadic remit- out-of-pocket health expenditure, per capita total health expenditure,
tances. They find limited evidence of labor force participation effects life expectancy at birth, undernourishment prevalence, depth of food
of persistent remittances. This implies that remittances are an integral deficit, prevalence of stunting, neonatal mortality rate, infant mor-
part of remittance recipient households’ income generation strategy. tality rate, and under-five mortality rate. Although per capita out-of-
Acosta et al. (2009) find that in El Salvador an increase in remittance pocket health expenditure and per capita total health expenditure are
flows leads to a decline in labor supply. Kim (2007) studies the reasons not measures of health, because they have direct effects on health out-
for the coexistence of high unemployment rates with increasing real comes, they are included as two of the health outcome measurements.
wages in Jamaica. The author concludes that households with remit- Seven explanatory variables are employed in health regressions as the
tance income have higher reservation wages and reduce labor supply covariates: per capita GDP, population over 65, urban population share,
by moving out of the labor force. Funkhouser (2006) uses longitudinal health expenditure to GDP ratio, food production index, government
data from 1998 and 2001 in Nicaragua to examine the impact of the expenditure on education, and newborns protected against tetanus.
emigration of household members on household labor market integra- Nine educational measurements are chosen in this paper: pre-primary
tion and poverty. The author concludes that households with emigrant gross enrollment rate, primary gross enrollment rate, secondary gross
had a reduction in labor income compared to otherwise similar house- enrollment rate, tertiary gross enrollment rate, percent of children out
holds. of primary school, private primary enrollment rate, secondary compli-
ment rate, primary compliment rate, and gender parity index for pri-
3. Data mary education. Two new explanatory variables are employed in the
education section: Labor force participation and government expen-
This study examines 122 developing (poor and middle-income) ditures on education as a percentage of GDP. Table 1 describes all
countries1 from the six major developing world regions: Latin Amer- dependent and explanatory variables alongside their descriptive statis-
ica and the Caribbean, sub-Saharan Africa, the Middle East and North tics. Table 2 provides descriptive statistics for gender-specific variables.
Africa, East Asia and the Pacific, South Asia, and Europe and Central Except for remittances and HDI, data on all dependent and explana-
Asia. The income and regional classification in this paper follow the tory variables are from the World Development Indicators. HDI data
conventions of the World Bank. This panel of countries is sufficiently are from the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP).
diverse, which means that these results are internationally applicable. This study uses three instruments to address the endogeneity of
The annual data has a time span of 1990–2015. All dollar values in this workers’ remittances: weighted average per capita GNI, unemployment
paper are constant 2011 US dollars. rate, and real interest rate of remittance-sending countries. Data on GNI
Data on remittances come from the International Monetary Fund and populations are from the United Nations. Data on unemployment
(IMF), which has defined remittances as the sum of two components: rates and real interest rates are from the World Development Indica-
personal transfers (workers’ remittances) and compensation of employ- tors. The real interest rate is defined as lending interest rate adjusted
ees. The World Bank has adopted the same definition. Compensa- for inflation as measured by the GDP deflator.
tion of employees refers to the income of border, seasonal, and other Data on out-of-pocket health expenditures and total health expen-
short-term workers who are employed in an economy where they are ditures cover the years between 1995 and 2014. The share of out-of-
not resident and of residents employed by nonresident entities. Being pocket health expenditures in total health expenditure in developing
present for one year or more in a territory or intending to do so is suf- countries has fluctuated in recent years. In 1995 and 2014 it was 40.8%
ficient to qualify one as being a resident of that economy (IMF, 2009). and 36.2% respectively. However, there has been a stable increasing
trend in the amount of per capita total health expenditure and per
capita out-of-pocket health expenditure: they went up from $131.4 and
1
The list of countries is provided in Appendix II. $53.6 in the year 1995 (expressed in constant 2011 US dollars adjusted

381
S. Azizi
Table 1
Descriptive statistics.
Variable Description N Mean SD Min Max
Per capita GDP Per capita GDP (constant 2011 US$ adjusted for PPP) 3043 5896 4845 247 29630
Per capita Remittance Per capita remittance (constant 2011 US$ adjusted for PPP) 2243 108.3 174.8 0 1577
Per capita out of pocket health expenditure Any outlay by households to health practitioners divided by total population (constant 2011 US$ adjusted for PPP) 2372 112 115.6 0.1 841.6
Per capita total health expenditure Sum of public and private health expenditure divided by total population (constant 2011 US$ adjusted for PPP) 2372 322.2 304.4 12.4 1996
Life expectancy at birth The number of years a newborn infant would live if prevailing patterns of mortality stay the same throughout its life 3069 64.1 9 27.1 79.6
Prevalence of undernourishment The percentage of the population whose food intake is insufficient to meet dietary energy requirements 2350 21.1 14.2 5 80.8
Depth of food deficit Calories needed to lift the undernourished from their status. 2276 154.1 119.6 1 744
Prevalence of stunting The percentage of children under age 5 whose height for age is more than two standard deviations below the median 565 31.4 15.4 1.2 76.7
Neonatal mortality rate The number of neonates dying before reaching 28 days of age per 1000 live births in a given year. 3146 46.9 31.8 3.4 171.2
Infant mortality rate The number of infants dying before reaching one year, per 1000 live births in a given year. 3146 24.4 13.6 1.9 67.1
Under 5 mortality rate The number of newborns dying before reaching age five per 1000 live births in a given year. 3146 67.6 55 4.6 328.2
Population over 65 Population ages 65 and above as a percentage of the total population 3044 5.1 3.1 1.7 20
382

Urban total ratio The ratio of people living in urban areas to total population 3146 45.3 20.1 5.4 91.8
Food production index Food crops that are considered edible and contain nutrients 2825 95.5 25.1 16.8 301.4
Health exp to GDP ratio Total expenditure on health as a percentage of GDP 2372 6 2.6 0.4 30.8
Newborns protected against tetanus The percentage of births by women of child-bearing age who are immunized against tetanus. 2198 72.4 18.2 5 99
Gross enrollment ratio, pre-primary The ratio of total enrollment in pre-primary, regardless of age, to the population of the pre-primary age group. 1932 39.3 29.8 0.2 159.6
Gross enrollment ratio, primary The ratio of total enrollment in primary, regardless of age, to the population of the primary age group. 2510 100.6 20.6 21.7 165.6
Gross enrollment ratio, secondary The ratio of total enrollment in secondary, regardless of age, to the population of the secondary age group. 2008 60.7 28.2 5.1 129
Gross enrollment ratio, tertiary The ratio of total enrollment in tertiary, regardless of age, to the population of the tertiary age group. 1710 20.6 18.8 0 91.1
Out of school rate at primary age The percentage of primary-school-age children who are not enrolled in primary or secondary school 1612 15.2 16.9 0 80.8
Enrollment in private primary schools rate The ratio of enrollment in private primary schools to the total number of students enrolled in primary education. 1893 12.2 16.8 0 99.2
Primary completion rate The ratio of new entrants in the last grade of primary education to the population at the entrance age. 1836 79.7 24.8 13.9 185.3
Lower secondary completion rate Gross intake ratio to the last grade of lower secondary education. 1527 59.7 29.2 0 206.6
Primary gender parity index The ratio of girls to boys enrolled at primary level in public and private schools. 2421 0.9 0.1 0 1.3
Labor force participation The proportion of the population ages 15 and older that is economically active 2964 63.6 11.5 38.2 90.6
Gov expenditures on education General (local, regional, and central) government expenditure on education as a percentage of GDP. 1343 4.3 2.3 0.5 44.3
Human Development Index (HDI) Summary measure of average achievement in key dimensions of human development 2724 0.6 0.1 0.2 0.8

Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396


S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

Table 2
Gender-specific descriptive statistics.
Variable N Mean SD Min Max
Male life expectancy 3069 61.9 8.4 24.3 77.9
Female life expectancy 3069 66.3 9.7 30 82.1
Male prevalence of stunting rate 430 33.4 15.6 1.4 76.1
Female prevalence of stunting rate 428 30.4 15.1 0.9 77.3
Male infant mortality rate 484 49.1 34.2 3.8 181.9
Female infant mortality rate 484 41.1 29.7 2.9 157.7
Male under 5 mortality rate 484 68.8 56.9 4.9 332.4
Female under 5 mortality rate 484 60.3 52.4 3.9 323.9
Male pre-primary enrollment rate 1786 39.1 30.2 0.3 158.8
Female pre-primary enrollment rate 1786 38.9 30.1 0.2 162
Male primary enrollment rate 2421 103.4 19.3 25.5 168.1
Female primary enrollment rate 2421 97.4 23 0 163
Male secondary enrollment rate 1841 61.2 26.4 5.6 132.6
Female secondary enrollment rate 1841 60 30.6 0 130.1
Male tertiary enrollment rate 1468 19.9 16.7 0 92.3
Female tertiary enrollment rate 1468 22.7 22.8 0 106
Male primary completion rate 1713 80.6 23.2 14.6 183.1
Female primary completion rate 1713 78.2 27.2 6.3 187.6
Male lower secondary completion rate 1414 59.2 27.5 0 206.9
Female lower secondary completion rate 1414 59.3 31.1 0 206.3
Male human development index 793 0.6 0.1 0.3 0.8
Female human development index 792 0.6 0.1 0.1 0.8
Male labor force participation rate 2964 76.6 8 43.8 92.4
Female labor force participation rate 2964 50.9 18.8 9.2 90.8
N indicates the number of country-year observations. The time span is from 1990 to 2015.

for PPP) to $530.3 and $191.9 in the year 2014 respectively. affect human capital or labor supply in the developing world. The rela-
In recent years there has been a remarkable decline in undernour- tionship that I want to estimate can be written as
ishment prevalence, depth of food deficit, and child mortality rates
across the developing world. Undernourishment prevalence data cover log(Hit ) = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 log(Rit ) + 𝛽2 log(Iit ) + Xit′ 𝛾 + 𝛿i + eit (1)
years 1991–2015. Average undernourishment prevalence went down
from 23.7% in the year 1991 to 12.67% in the year 2015. Depth
of food deficit data cover years 1992–2015. Average depth of food for i = 1, … , N and t = 1, … , Ti where H is a measure of health,
deficit decreased from 175.6 kilocalories in the year 1992 to 91.9 education, HDI, or labor supply in country i at time t, 𝛽 0 is the intercept,
kilocalories in the year 2015. In 1990, average neonatal, infant, and Rit is the per capita remittances received by country i at year t, Iit is the
under-five mortality rates per 1000 live births were 39.3, 69.1, 99.7 mean per capita income of country i at year t, Xit is a vector of other
respectively. In 2015, average neonatal, infant, and under-five mortal- variables that potentially affect Hit , 𝛿 i is region dummy and eit is the
ity rates declined to 20.8, 34.6, and 46.4 respectively, in the developing error term. Since all variables are in logarithm, 𝛽 1 can be interpreted
world. as the elasticity of human capital with respect to per capita remittances
As UNDP states, HDI is a summary measure of average achieve- and 𝛽 2 can be interpreted as the elasticity of human capital with respect
ment in key dimensions of human development: a long and healthy to per capita income.
life, being knowledgeable, and having a decent standard of living. The The reason that region dummies are used in this research rather
HDI is the geometric mean of normalized indices for each of the three than country dummies is that for many countries, there is just one year
dimensions. The health dimension is assessed by life expectancy at of data available, and for using country-specific effects, those countries
birth, the education dimension is measured by the mean of years of had to be dropped from the regression. To avoid dropping those coun-
schooling for adults aged 25 years and more, and expected years of tries, I used region-specific fixed effects rather than country-specific
schooling for children of school age. The standard of living dimension fixed effects. All six major developing world regions are included: Latin
is measured by gross national income per capita. The HDI uses the log- America and the Caribbean, sub-Saharan Africa, the Middle East and
arithm of income, to reflect the diminishing importance of income with North Africa, East Asia and the Pacific, South Asia, and Europe and
increasing GNI. The scores for the three HDI dimension indices are then Central Asia. The income and regional classification in this paper fol-
aggregated into a composite index using geometric mean. Data on HDI low the conventions of the World Bank. I followed Adams and Page
are adopted from UNDP. While HDI data cover the years 1990–2015, (2005) in using region-specific effects as fixed effects. However, in those
male and female HDI data cover the years 2000, 2005, and 2010 to cases that more than one year of data were available for each coun-
2015. try, as a robustness check, I also estimated the regressions by using
In recent years there has been a slight but smooth and stable country-specific effects. The results were similar in terms of sign and
decreasing trend in labor force participation rates in developing coun- significance of the parameter estimates but magnitudes were slightly
tries. In 1990, total, male, and female average labor force participation different.
rates in developing countries were 68.1%, 82.7%, and 53.4% respec- Correlation matrix between selected variables is provided in
tively. In 2015, total, male, and female average labor force partici- Appendix I. Several correlation coefficients are high, therefore, in order
pation rates in developing countries were 63.5%, 77.9%, and 48.9% to avoid multicollinearity effect arising from that, as a general rule,
respectively. I try to not include highly correlated explanatory variables in a same
regression equation. For example, in regressions corresponding to the
impact of remittances on child mortality rate, rather than the dollar
4. Econometric model
value of health expenditures, the ratio of health expenditures to GDP
is used. Also, in all regression equations for the case of the impact of
I use the panel data method to analyze how workers’ remittances
remittances on education, rather than the dollar value of government

383
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

expenditure on education, its ratio to GDP is used.2 also shows a sizable informal sector (Freund and Spatafora, 2008).
Some of the variables used in the regression models, like per capita Since poor countries usually are less financially developed, migrants
GDP, are non-stationary in the level, but they are first-difference sta- from poor countries are more likely to remit through informal chan-
tionary. Since there are non-stationary variables in the regression mod- nels. Because income is also correlated with human capital investment,
els, the results of the regressions might be spurious. To check whether measurement error is also one of the sources of endogeneity.
the results of the regressions are spurious or not, for the regressions Therefore, the least squares estimates of the impact of remittances
with non-stationary dependent variables, I implement panel cointegra- may be biased as remittance is endogenous. The traditional way, which
tion tests. If cointegrations exist, then it can be concluded that the is followed in this paper, is to resolve the endogeneity problem by using
error term is stationary, which means the results of the regressions instrumental variables. In the following, the instruments suggested by
are not spurious. Two tests are used to check whether panel cointegra- other researchers are discussed and then I introduce the instruments
tions exist: the Kao Residual Cointegration Test proposed by Kao (1999) that are used in this paper. Three kinds of instruments are proposed
(also known as the residual-based Augmented Dicky Fuller test) and the by scholars. The first category of variables is related to remittance-
Johansen Fisher Panel Cointegration Test proposed by Johansen (1988). receiving countries. The main problem with using these instruments
In both tests, the null hypothesis is that cointegration does not exist. I is that they can easily be correlated with education, health or labor
implemented both tests for all models with non-stationary dependent supply of the same country in a way other than through remittances or
variables and all p-values were less than 0.05. Therefore, based on the covariates. Therefore, they can be invalid instruments. The second cate-
results of both tests, the null hypothesis is rejected, which means that gory of variables is related to the cost of remittances (e.g. the number of
a cointegration relationship exists among the variables. In other words, branches of Western Union). These instruments are usually strong and
the error terms are stationary, and the results of the regressions are not valid, but data on these variables are mainly unavailable for most devel-
spurious. oping countries. The third category of variables is related to remittance-
Another econometric issue that arises here is that the error terms sending countries. Since these variables are not related to remittance-
are autocorrelated and also they do not have constant variance, which receiving countries, after controlling for some covariates, they are
shows the existence of heteroskedasticity. To overcome autocorrelation valid and strong. However, the main problem is that each remittance-
and heteroskedasticity, Newey-West Heteroskedasticity and Autocorre- receiving country receives remittances from many remittance-sending
lation Consistent (HAC) standard errors are used. In other words, since countries, and due to lack of information on bilateral remittances, the
I worry that there might be some serial correlation in the error terms weights of remittance-sending countries are unknown.
even after controlling for fixed effects and endogeneity of remittances, Aggarwal et al. (2011) use economic conditions in the top
I adjust standard errors to account for heteroskedasticity and autocor- remittance-source countries as instruments for the remittances flows.
relation by using autocorrelation HAC standard errors. They argue economic conditions in the remittance-source countries are
Another issue that needs to be addressed is that whether standard likely to affect the volume of remittance flows that migrants are able
errors should be adjusted for clustering. There is no cluster in the popu- to send, but are not expected to affect the dependent variables in the
lation of interest that is not represented in the sample. Moreover, except remittance receiving countries in ways other than through its impact on
for the case of Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) results which are provided remittances or covariates. However, because bilateral remittance data
in the tables only for comparison purposes, fixed effects are included are largely unavailable, they identify the top remittance-source coun-
in the regressions and there is no need to adjust standard errors for tries for each country in the sample, using 2000 bilateral migration
clustering. (Abadie et al., 2017) data. The dataset identifies the top five OECD countries that receive the
Remittances may be endogenous to education or health outcomes most migrants from each remittance-recipient country. They construct
in the remittance-receiving countries. The endogenous relationship instruments by multiplying the per capita GDP, the real GDP growth,
between workers’ remittances received and schooling decisions or and the unemployment rate, in each of the top five remittance-source
health outcomes can be explained via three reasons. First, there exists countries by the share of migration to each of these five countries.
a reverse causality between human capital (education attainment and The technique used in this paper is similar to Aggarwal et al. (2011).
health outcomes) and remittances. An individual may decide to migrate However, I use an estimation of bilateral remittances and use them as
and send remittances because he or she has school-age or sick and weights of remittance-sending countries.
undernourished children, and in turn, remittances affect educational In this research, I introduce three instruments that are correlated
investment or health outcomes by loosening liquidity constraints. The with remittances and uncorrelated with the dependent variables unless
decision to live outside the country and send remittances is deter- through explanatory variables. Workers’ remittances, by definition, are
mined simultaneously with the decision regarding health and education money sent by migrants from host countries (remittance-sending coun-
expenditures. Second, there exist unobserved characteristics included tries) to their home countries (remittance-receiving countries). The
in the error terms that may be correlated with both the decision to value of remittances hinges on both remittance-sending and remittance-
send remittances and the decision to send children to a school, or how receiving countries economic variables. Since the dependent variables
much the household spends on their nutrition and health (e.g. ability belong to remittance-receiving countries, in order to ensure the instru-
or ambition). Third, measurement error is another source of endogene- ments are valid, we should select a number of economic variables from
ity. Officially recorded remittances do not include remittance in kind, remittance-sending countries. Three variables used in this research as
unofficial transfers through kinship or through informal means such as instruments are per capita GNI, unemployment rate, and real interest
hawala operators, friends, and family members. The negative impact of rate. If the remittance-sending country’s per capita GNI increases, it
transactions costs on remittances encourages migrants to remit through means migrants’ income has increased, which means they have more
informal channels when costs are high. Transfer costs are higher when money available to spend and remit. Therefore, it can be expected that
financial systems are less developed. Evidence from household surveys remittances increase in response to a rise in the remittance-sending
country’s per capita GNI. If the unemployment rate goes up in the
remittance-sending country, some migrants will lose their jobs, and the
2
total remittances sent by migrants will decrease. If the real interest rates
While the correlation coefficient between “per capita health expenditure”
go up in the remittance-sending country, migrants have more incentive
and per capita GDP is 0.91, the correlation coefficient between “the ratio of
to invest in the host country rather than the home country, and they
health expenditure to GDP” and per capita GDP is only 0.04. Also, the correla-
tion coefficient between “dollar value of government expenditure on education”
will remit less.
and per capita GDP is 0.9 but the correlation coefficient between “the ratio of Table 3 shows the results of regressing per capita remittances
government expenditure on education to GDP” and per capita GDP is only 0.16. on these three instrumental variables while in each column different

384
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

covariates have been used. Note that in all seven columns the param- are from each specific home-country. I used this dataset,4 per capita
eter estimate for the impact of per capita GNI in remittance-sending GNI of remittance-sending countries, and per capita GNI of remittance-
countries on remittances is significant and positive, the parameter esti- receiving countries to estimate bilateral remittances. I then use esti-
mate for the impact of unemployment rate and real interest rates in mated bilateral data to construct weighted averages of per capita GNI,
remittance-sending countries on remittances is significant and negative. unemployment rate, and real interest rate of remittance-sending coun-
The IMF provides workers’ remittances data annually. Data are tries. These weighted average indicators are used as instruments to
available at the aggregate level for each country. Unfortunately, the address the endogeneity of remittances.
IMF does not provide bilateral remittance data. Bilateral remittance Before discussing the results of the regressions, I will provide some
means how much money a remittance-receiving country receives from evidence about the correctness of the estimated bilateral remittance
each specific remittance-sending country. Therefore, although we know data. Data on bilateral remittances are mostly unavailable. Even where
how much remittance each remittance-receiving country receives in any bilateral remittances are reported, they may not be accurate, because
year in total, we do not know how much of the received remittances funds channeled through international banks may be attributed to a
comes from a specific remittance-sending country. country other than the actual source country (Ratha, 2005). One rea-
The main challenge in constructing instruments is that each son why bilateral remittance data is inaccurate is that financial insti-
remittance-receiving country has more than one remittance-sending tutions that act as intermediaries often report funds as originating in
country. Therefore, rather than per capita GNI, unemployment rate, the most immediate source country. For example, the Philippines tends
and real interest rate in the remittance-sending country, weighted aver- to attribute a large part of its remittance receipts to the United States
age of the remittance-sending countries’ indicators should be used as because many banks route their fund transfers through the United States
instruments. For remittance-receiving country i, in year t, the weights (Ratha, 2005). Only a few papers have used bilateral remittances data.
of each remittance-sending country j is and only for limited recipient-country sender-country pairs (Lueth and
Ruiz-Arranz, 2008; Frankel, 2011; Docquier et al., 2012). I compare
Remittances from country j to country i in year t
Wjit = (2) the estimated bilateral remittances used in this paper with the corre-
Total remittances received by country i in year t
sponding part of the datasets they used in their studies. The actual data
For example, if remittance-receiving country A has two remittance- consists of 12 receiving countries, 16 remittance-sending countries, and
sender countries, B and C, and it receives 70% of the total remit- 1744 observations.5 The Pearson Correlation Coefficient between actual
tances from country B with $10,000 per capita GNI, and 30% of data and estimated data is 0.666 and is statistically significant, indicat-
the total remittances from country C with $20,000 per capita GNI, ing there is a strong positive linear correlation between actual data and
then weighted average per capita GNI of the host countries would be estimated data. This study uses Kolmogorov-Smirnov’s two-sample test
0.7∗10,000 + 0.3∗20,000 = 13,000. However, calculating these weights to check if the distribution of the two samples is the same or not. The
entails knowing bilateral remittances (i.e. how much remittances each null hypothesis is that the two distributions are not statistically differ-
remittance-receiving country receives from each remittance-sending ent from each other. Using the panel data, the p-value for the test is
country). Although the value of remittances each country receives is 0.17, and I fail to reject the null.
known, unfortunately, there is no comprehensive bilateral remittances For remittance-receiving country i at time t, we define
data, and we do not know the amount of remittances received from
each individual remittance-sending country. To overcome this problem, ∑
214
Y it = wjit Yjt
a specific method developed by Ratha and Shaw (2007)3 and used in j =1
Azizi (2017) and Azizi (2018) is used in this paper to estimate bilateral
remittances for all countries from 1990 to 2015. where Y it is one of the following variables: weighted average per
Fortunately, the UN has provided a comprehensive bilateral migra- capita GNI, unemployment rate, and real interest rate of the remittance-
tion data from 1990 to 2015. This means we know how many immi- sending countries. wjit is the weight as defined by equation (2) and Yjt
grants live in each host-country, and we also know how many of them is one of the following: per capita GNI, unemployment rate, or real
interest rate of the remittance-sending country j at year t. Total number
of host countries is 214. Therefore, the following variables are used as
instruments:

Zit = (PCGNI it , Unemit , RIRit )


3
Ratha and Shaw (2007) proposes a method of “Calculating
Weights Based on Migrant Stocks, Per Capita Income in the Desti- where PCGNI is the per capita GNI, Unemp is the unemployment rate,
nation Countries, and Per Capita Income in the Source Countries”. and RIR is the real interest rate.
The average remittance sent by a migrant from host country j to home Two main concerns of using instrumental variables method, to
country i (rij ) is modeled as a function of the per capita income of the home address the problem of endogeneity, are validity and strength of the
country and the host country. instruments. The reason that in this paper bilateral remittances are esti-
{
Yi if Yj < Y i mated, and economic variables related to remittance-sending countries
rij = f (Y i Yj ) = are used is to guarantee the validity of the instruments. More specifi-
Y i + (Yj − Y i )𝛽 otherwise
cally, selecting economic variables from remittance-sending countries,
where Yj is the average per capita GNI of host country j, Y i is the per capita rather than from remittance-receiving countries, as instruments is to
GNI of the migrant’s home country, and 𝛽 is a parameter between 0 and 1. ensure the validity of instruments. My identifying assumption is that
The amount sent by an average migrant is assumed to be at least as much as per capita GNI, unemployment rate, and real interest rate in remittance-
the per capita income of the home country, even when the individual migrates sending countries do not affect health outcomes, educational attain-
to a lower-income country. The rationale is that the migration occurs in the
ment, and labor force participation in remittance-receiving countries
expectation of earning a higher level of income for the dependent household
than what the migrant would earn in his or her home country. To estimate
bilateral remittances for all countries, they use the average 𝛽 (equal to 0.75)
for the top 20 remittance-receiving countries. Then, for each home country i, rij 4
The UN bilateral migration data includes just the following years: 1990,
is used to build weights for each host country j as
1995, 2000, 2005, 2010, 2013, and 2015. I used linear interpolation to estimate
rij Mij bilateral migration for the remaining years.
Wij = ∑214 5
r M
j=1 ij ij
The estimated bilateral data consists of 214 remittance-receiving countries,
214 remittance-sending countries, and 1,190,696 observations.

385
S. Azizi
Table 3
First stage regressions.
Dependent variable Per Capita Remittance
Corresponding dependent variable Per Capita Health Expenditure Education HDI Labor
in the original equations Supply
Column number (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
Instruments Per capita GDP in remittance sending 5.57∗∗∗ 6.22∗∗∗ 5.18∗∗∗ 4.81∗∗∗ 4.59∗∗∗
countries (0.356) (0.336) (0.451) (0.46) (0.411)
Unemployment rate in remittance −0.03∗∗∗ −0.11∗∗∗ −0.03∗∗ −0.035∗∗ −0.04∗∗∗
sending countries (0.0119) (0.012) (0.017) (0.017) (0.013)
Real interest rate in remittance −0.02∗∗∗ −0.03∗∗∗ −0.01∗∗∗ −0.02∗∗∗ −0.02∗∗∗
sending countries (0.004) (0.004) (0.005) (0.005) (0.004)
Exogenous Variables Per capita GDP in remittance 0.17∗∗ 0.17∗∗ 0.53∗∗∗ 0.46∗∗∗ 0.6∗∗∗ 0.8∗∗∗ −0.11
receiving countries (0.075) (0.075) (0.077) (0.077) (0.064) (0.06) (0.089)
Population over 65 in remittance 0.96∗∗∗ 0.99∗∗∗ 0.77∗∗∗ 0.85∗∗∗
receiving countries (0.112) (0.113) (0.119) (0.119)
0.42∗∗∗ 0.43∗∗∗ 0.41∗∗∗ 0.33∗∗∗ 0.72∗∗∗
386

Urban ratio in remittance receiving


countries (0.108) (0.109) (0.114) (0.115) (0.131)
Labor force participation in −2.55∗∗∗
remittance receiving countries (0.328)
Gov expenditure on education in −0.13 −0.05
remittance receiving countries (0.116) (0.12)
Primary completion rate in 1.87∗∗∗
remittance receiving countries (0.168)
Number of countries 116 116 116 116 104 106 118
Number of obs 2184 2184 2184 2184 1094 1097 1433
R-squared 0.3 0.28 0.21 0.19 0.35 0.32 0.36
F-statistic for weak instruments 133 342 98 69 65 58 82

Results are first-stage estimates of the equation log(Hit ) = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 log(Rit ) + 𝛽2 log(Iit ) + Xit′ 𝛾 + 𝛿i + eit where Hit refers to per capita health expenditures in columns (1) to
(4), education in column (5), HDI in column (6), and labor supply in column (7). First stage estimates are obtained by running log(Rit ) = 𝛽 0 + d1 (Zit ) + d2 log(Xit ) + uit
where Z is a matrix of instruments including weighted GDP per capita, unemployment rate, and real interest rate in remittance-sending countries where weights are
from estimated bilateral remittances and X is a matrix of exogeneous variable in remittance receiving countries. All parameter estimates and standard errors for per
capita GNI in remittance sending countries are scaled up by 105 .
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396


S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

other than through remittances, per capita GDP of remittance-receiving nitudes are slightly different.6
countries, or other covariates included the regressions. The other con- In the first regression, per capita out-of-pocket health expenditure is
cern about the instruments is whether they are strong or not. The whole used as the dependent variable. Population over 65 and urban popula-
process of estimating bilateral remittances and use them as the weights tion share are used as explanatory variables alongside per capita remit-
of remittance-sending countries is to ensure that instruments are strong. tances and per capita GDP. Both OLS and FE models underestimate the
To investigate the strength of the instruments, first stage regressions impacts of remittances on health expenditures and the effect captured
are examined. The results of the first stage regressions are provided in by the IV is larger than the effects captured by the OLS or the FE. The
Table 3. Note that all F-statistics for weak instruments are greater than results of IV regression suggest that, on average, a 10% increase in per
50, which indicates the instruments are very strong. capita remittances and per capita GDP will lead to a 1.5% and 6.4%
There is a clear advantage in using estimated bilateral remittances increase in per capita out-of-pocket health expenditure, respectively. In
to construct the instruments over using top 5 or 10 remittance-sending the second regression, per capita total health expenditure is used as the
countries (the method used by other researchers). This advantage can dependent variable. The results of IV regression suggest that, on aver-
be demonstrated by the substantial improvement in the F-statistic for age, a 10% increase in per capita remittances and per capita GDP will
weak instruments of this paper and similar papers. For example, F- lead to a 1.1% and 8.9% increase in per capita total health expendi-
statistic for two of the main instruments used in this paper, GNI per ture, respectively. Note that the impact of per capita remittances on per
capita and unemployment rate in remittance-sending countries, are 342 capita total health expenditure is smaller than the impact of per capita
and 98 respectively. These two F-statistics are remarkably higher than remittances on per capita out-of-pocket health expenditure. The reason
F-statistic in similar studies which use GNI per capita and unemploy- is that total health expenditure is the sum of private and public health
ment rate in just top one or three or five remittance-sending countries expenditure and remittances have almost no effect on public health
as instruments. expenditure. In the third regression, life expectancy at birth is used as
the dependent variable. The results of IV regression suggest that, on
average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances and per capita GDP
5. Results will lead to a 0.3% and 0.4% increase in life expectancy at birth respec-
tively.
This section is divided into four subsections. At first, I investi- The impacts of per capita remittances, per capita GDP, alongside
gate impacts of remittances on health outcomes in Tables 4–6 and other variables, on nutrition variables are provided in Table 5.
gender-specific impacts of remittances on health outcome in Tables 7 Undernourishment prevalence, depth of food deficit, and prevalence
and 8. Then, I explore the impacts of remittances on education in of stunting are used as the fourth, fifth, and sixth measurements of
Tables 9–11 and gender-specific impacts of remittances on education health outcomes. Due to restrictions in the availability of data, the num-
in Tables 12–14. Afterward, I look into the impact of remittances on ber of observations in each regression varies considerably. For example,
HDI in Table 15. Finally, I examine the impacts of remittances on labor in the regression with undernourishment prevalence as the dependent
supply in Table 16. variable, the number of observations is 1629, but in the regression with
In all regressions, the results of the IV approach are reported along- prevalence of stunting as the dependent variable, the number of obser-
side the results of the OLS model and Fixed Effect (FE) model. FE model vations is 412.
and OLS model are similar in all aspects except one. Unlike OLS model, Food production index and urban population share are used as
FE model includes region-specific effects and addresses time-invariant explanatory variables alongside per capita remittances and per capita
cross-country effects. However, both OLS and FE results are inconsistent GDP. The results of IV regressions suggest that, on average, a 10%
and biased. They are presented in this paper for comparison purposes. increase in per capita remittances and per capita GDP will lead to,
To address both endogeneity and time-invariant cross-country effects respectively, a 1.5% and 4.3% decline in undernourishment prevalence,
simultaneously, all IV estimates also include region-specific effects. a 1.9% and 5.9% decline in depth of food deficit, and a 1% and 2.7%
decline in prevalence of stunting. Note that the magnitude of IV coef-
ficients for per capita remittances are substantially larger than those
5.1. Remittances and health from the OLS and FE estimations in all three regressions which means
OLS and FE models underestimate the impacts of workers’ remittances
This study closely follows the literature on the choice of health on undernourishment prevalence, depth of food deficit, and prevalence
measurements. Four categories of health measurements are used here of stunting.
as dependent variables: health expenditures, life expectancy at birth, The impacts of per capita remittances, per capita GDP, alongside
nutrition status, and child mortality rates. Per capita out-of-pocket other variables, on child mortality rates are provided in Table 6.
health expenditure and per capita total health expenditure are the vari- In order to investigate the impact of remittances on child mortal-
ables representing health expenditures. Undernourishment prevalence, ity rate, health expenditure to GDP ratio, urban ratio, and newborns
depth of food deficit, and prevalence of stunting are three variables protected against tetanus are chosen as control variables. Since high-
representing nutrition measurements. Neonatal, infant, and under-five income countries are primary funders of the World Health Organization
mortality rates represent child mortality rates. The estimates for the (WHO), their economic conditions can affect WHO’s budget, which in
impacts of remittances on out-of-pocket per capita health expenditures, turn affects child mortality rates in developing countries through differ-
per capita total health expenditures, and life expectancy are presented ent global vaccination programs implemented by WHO. Controlling for
in Table 4. the variable newborns protected against tetanus can assure the validity
For many countries, just one year of data is available, and for using of the instruments used in the IV regressions.
country-specific effect, those countries had to be dropped from the Both OLS and FE models underestimate the impacts of remittances
regression. Due to this data limitation, this study controls for region- on reducing child mortality rates. Remittance has negative and sta-
specific effect rather than country-specific effect. However, for those
cases where more data are available, at least two years of data for 6
For example the parameter estimate for the impacts of remittances on out-
each remittance-receiving country, it is possible to control for country- of-pocket health expenditure is 0.15 for the regression with region-specific
specific effect. As a robustness check, I use country-specific effect in effects and 0.17 for the regression with country-specific effects. Also, the param-
those regressions and investigate the impact of remittances on health eter estimate for the impacts of remittances on undernourishment prevalence is
outcomes. The results are the same as regressions with region-specific −0.15 for the regression with region-specific effects and −0.13 for the regres-
dummies in terms of sign and significance of remittances, but the mag- sion with country-specific effects.

387
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

Table 4
Impact of remittances on health outcomes (1).
Dependent OOP health expenditure Total health expenditure Life expectancy at birth
Method OLS FE IV OLS FE IV OLS FE IV
Per capita remittance 0.09∗∗∗ 0.09∗∗∗ 0.15∗∗∗ 0.05∗∗∗ 0.05∗∗∗ 0.11∗∗∗ 0.03∗∗∗ 0.02∗∗∗ 0.03∗∗∗
(0.011) (0.011) (0.033) (0.006) (0.006) (0.018) (0.002) (0.002) (0.004)
Per capita GDP 0.64∗∗∗ 0.69∗∗∗ 0.64∗∗∗ 0.89∗∗∗ 0.92∗∗∗ 0.89∗∗∗ 0.09∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗
(0.048) (0.052) (0.054) (0.024) (0.026) (0.027) (0.005) (0.005) (0.006)
Population over 65 0.29∗∗∗ 0.08 −0.06 0.09∗∗∗ 0.1∗∗ 0.08
(0.054) (0.077) (0.081) (0.033) (0.047) (0.05)
Urban ratio 0.32∗∗∗ 0.071 0.2∗∗ 0.091∗∗ −0.07∗ −0.05
(0.073) (0.083) (0.084) (0.036) (0.038) (0.038)
Gov expenditure on education −0.01 −0.002 0.006
(0.009) (0.007) (0.006)
Number of countries 114 114 114 114 114 114 105 105 105
Observations 1811 1811 1811 1811 1811 1818 1095 1095 1095
R-squared 0.59 0.67 0.65 0.84 0.86 0.85 0.64 0.77 0.74

HAC standard errors are in parentheses. FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

Table 5
Impact of remittances on health outcomes (2).
Dependent Undernourishment Prevalence Depth of food deficit Prevalence of stunting
Method OLS FE IV OLS FE IV OLS FE IV
Per capita remittance −0.07∗∗∗ −0.08∗∗∗ −0.15∗∗∗ −0.07∗∗∗ −0.08∗∗∗ −0.19∗∗∗ −0.06∗∗∗ −0.05∗∗∗ −0.1∗∗
(0.01) (0.01) (0.034) (0.015) (0.015) (0.049) (0.015) (0.015) (0.043)
Per capita GDP −0.41∗∗∗ −0.44∗∗∗ −0.43∗∗∗ −0.58∗∗∗ −0.63∗∗∗ −0.59∗∗∗ −0.34∗∗∗ −0.29∗∗∗ −0.27∗∗∗
(0.035) (0.041) (0.041) (0.051) (0.058) (0.05) (0.046) (0.051) (0.045)
Food production index −0.21∗∗∗ −0.17∗∗ −0.06 −0.16 −0.11 0.05 −0.114 −0.14 −0.05
(0.075) (0.073) (0.086) (0.106) (0.101) (0.116) (0.1) (0.095) (0.12)
Urban ratio 0.005 0.07 0.09 −0.01 0.11 0.14 −0.25∗∗∗ −0.081 −0.07
(0.06) (0.066) (0.066) (0.081) (0.087) (0.087) (0.082) (0.099) (0.1)
Number of countries 94 94 94 95 95 95 107 107 107
Observations 1629 1629 1629 1605 1605 1605 412 412 412
R-squared 0.4 0.45 0.42 0.35 0.43 0.39 0.49 0.55 0.48
HAC standard errors are in parentheses. FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

tistically significant effects on child mortality rates. Based on the IV Gender-specific data are available only for four health outcome vari-
results, on average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances causes a ables: life expectancy at birth, prevalence of stunting, infant mortality
1% decrease in neonatal mortality rate, a 1.7% decrease in infant mor- rate, and under-five mortality rate. Table 7 provides the gender-specific
tality rates, and a 1.9% decrease in under five mortality rates. Also, on impacts of per capita remittances on life expectancy at birth and preva-
average, a 10% increase in per capita GDP leads to a 3.9% decrease in lence of stunting.
neonatal mortality rates, a 4.2% decrease in infant mortality rates, and Remittance has positive, statistically significant, and almost similar
a 4.7% increase in under five mortality rates. effects on male and female life expectancy. On average, a 10% increase

Table 6
Impact of remittances on health outcomes (3).
Dependent Neonatal mortality rate Infant mortality rate Under 5 mortality rate
Method OLS FE IV OLS FE IV OLS FE IV
Per capita remittance −0.05∗∗∗ −0.05∗∗∗ −0.1∗∗∗ −0.09∗∗∗ −0.07∗∗∗ −0.17∗∗∗ −0.11∗∗∗ −0.08∗∗∗ −0.19∗∗∗
(0.007) (0.007) (0.019) (0.007) (0.007) (0.023) (0.009) (0.008) (0.026)
Per capita GDP −0.44∗∗∗ −0.39∗∗∗ −0.39∗∗∗ −0.51∗∗∗ −0.42∗∗∗ −0.42∗∗∗ −0.61∗∗∗ −0.46∗∗∗ −0.47∗∗∗
(0.02) (0.022) (0.022) (0.02) (0.024) (0.025) (0.028) (0.027) (0.028)
Health expenditure to GDP ratio −0.2∗∗∗ −0.22∗∗∗ −0.22∗∗∗ −0.1∗∗∗ −0.14∗∗∗ −0.12∗∗∗ −0.1∗∗∗ −0.17∗∗∗ −0.14∗∗∗
(0.038) (0.031) (0.035) (0.036) (0.031) (0.038) (0.045) (0.035) (0.043)
Urban ratio 0.21∗∗∗ 0.23∗∗∗ 0.28∗∗∗ 0.22∗∗∗ 0.2∗∗∗ 0.32∗∗∗ 0.24∗∗∗ 0.19∗∗∗ 0.33∗∗∗
(0.034) (0.04) (0.048) (0.039) (0.043) (0.054) (0.046) (0.046) (0.061)
Newborns protected against tetanus −0.35∗∗∗ −0.43∗∗∗ −0.35∗∗∗ −0.4∗∗∗ −0.47∗∗∗ −0.34∗∗∗ −0.48∗∗∗ −0.56∗∗∗ −0.42∗∗∗
(0.054) (0.065) (0.059) (0.057) (0.055) (0.069) (0.071) (0.065) (0.079)
Number of countries 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85 85
Observations 1354 1354 1354 1354 1354 1354 1354 1354 1354
R-squared 0.6 0.69 0.66 0.68 0.75 0.66 0.69 0.79 0.7
HAC standard errors are in parentheses. FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

388
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

Table 7
Gender-specific impact of remittances on health outcomes (1).
Dependent Life expectancy Prevalence of stunting
Gender Male Female Male Female
Per capita remittance 0.02∗∗∗ 0.03∗∗∗ 0.02∗∗∗ 0.03∗∗∗ −0.05∗∗∗ −0.13∗∗∗ −0.05∗∗∗ −0.12∗∗
(0.002) (0.004) (0.002) (0.005) (0.016) (0.047) (0.017) (0.048)
Per capita GDP 0.04∗∗∗ 0.03∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗ −0.28∗∗∗ −0.25∗∗∗ −0.3∗∗∗ −0.27∗∗∗
(0.005) (0.006) (0.005) (0.006) (0.045) (0.038) (0.047) (0.039)
Gov expenditure on education −0.003 0.003 −0.002 0.007
(0.007) (0.006) (0.007) (0.006)
Food production index −0.154 −0.008 −0.17 −0.04
(0.095) (0.13) (0.103) (0.134)
Urban ratio −0.128∗ −0.11 −0.13 −0.11
(0.075) (0.077) (0.08) (0.081)
Number of countries 105 105 105 105 100 100 99 99
Observations 1095 1095 1095 1095 338 338 337 337
R-squared 0.73 0.7 0.78 0.76 0.58 0.53 0.56 0.53
Method FE IV FE IV FE IV FE IV
HAC standard errors are in parentheses. Both FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

Table 8
Gender-specific impact of remittances on health outcomes (2).
Dependent Infant mortality rate Under 5 mortality rate
Gender Male Female Male Female
Per capita remittance −0.07∗∗∗ −0.131∗∗ −0.08∗∗∗ −0.135∗∗ −0.08∗∗∗ −0.143∗∗ −0.08∗∗∗ −0.149∗∗
(0.019) (0.057) (0.019) (0.057) (0.022) (0.064) (0.023) (0.066)
Per capita GDP −0.41∗∗∗ −0.42∗∗∗ −0.43∗∗∗ −0.43∗∗∗ −0.46∗∗∗ −0.48∗∗ −0.49∗∗ −0.5∗∗∗
(0.066) (0.07) (0.07) (0.074) (0.076) (0.081) (0.082) (0.087)
Health expenditure to GDP ratio −0.16∗∗ −0.15∗ −0.16∗∗ −0.14∗ −0.166∗∗ −0.17∗ −0.19∗∗ −0.176∗
(0.074) (0.078) (0.075) (0.079) (0.073) (0.088) (0.084) (0.09)
Urban ratio 0.15 0.2 0.17 0.21 0.15 0.2 0.16 0.22
(0.119) (0.127) (0.123) (0.13) (0.131) (0.143) (0.137) (0.149)
Newborns protected against tetanus −0.55∗∗∗ −0.49∗∗∗ −0.55∗∗∗ −0.5∗∗∗ −0.65∗∗∗ −0.58∗∗∗ −0.67∗∗∗ −0.61∗∗∗
(0.127) (0.143) (0.132) (0.148) (0.11) (0.162) (0.154) (0.17)
Number of countries 84 84 84 84 84 84 84 84
Observations 136 136 136 136 136 136 136 136
R-squared 0.76 0.73 0.76 0.73 0.79 0.76 0.79 0.77
Method FE IV FE IV FE IV FE IV

HAC standard errors are in parentheses. Both FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

in per capita remittances causes a 0.3% increase in male and female life rate, and government expenditure on education are used as explana-
expectancy at birth. Also, on average, a 10% increase in remittances tory variables. Pre-primary enrollment rate, primary enrollment rate,
leads to a 1.3% decrease in male and 1.2% decrease in female preva- and secondary enrollment rate are the first three education measure-
lence of stunting. ments. The impacts of per capita remittances on these three variables
Table 8 provides the gender-specific impacts of per capita remit- are displayed in Table 9.
tances alongside per capita GDP, per capita health expenditure, urban A rise in workers’ remittances (which is represented by per capita
population share, and newborns protected against tetanus on infant remittances) or in income measurement (which is represented by per
mortality rates and under-five mortality rates. capita GDP) can loosen the budget constraints for households in devel-
There are negligible differences on impacts of remittances on child oping countries and motivate them to invest more in their children’s
mortality rates between two genders: on average, a 10% increase in the education. The results provided in Table 9 show how worker’ remit-
amount of per capita remittances leads to a 1.31% and 1.35% reduction tances can increase children’s school attendance in developing coun-
in infant mortality rates for males and females, respectively. Also, on tries. On average, a 10% rise in per capita remittance increases pre-
average, a 10% increase in the amount of per capita remittances leads primary and secondary enrollment by 3.5% and 0.6%, respectively.
to a 1.43% and 1.49% reduction in under 5 mortality rate for males However, based on the IV model, while a 10% rise in per capita remit-
and females, respectively. These results show that when households in tance increases primary enrollment by 0.16%, this impact is not sta-
developing countries receive remittances from their family members tistically significant. Also, on average, a 10% rise in per capita GDP
living abroad, they spend the received money almost equally on the increases pre-primary, primary, and secondary enrollment by 6.6%,
health status of their boys and girls. As we will see, this is not the case 0.7%, and 3.2%, respectively.
for the impact of remittances on education as remittances increase the When labor force participation increases, parents have more incen-
female education more than male education. tive to invest in their children’s education. If parents predict that their
children, especially their girls, will not enter the job market, then they
will have less incentive to spend on their children’s education. There-
5.2. Remittances and education
fore, it is expected that the labor force participation rate has a positive
impact on education. On average, a 10% rise in the labor force par-
In all regressions with education measurements as dependent vari-
ticipation rate increases pre-primary, primary, and secondary enroll-
ables, per capita remittances, per capita GDP, labor force participation

389
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

Table 9
Impact of remittances on education (1).
Dependent Pre-primary enrollment rate Primary enrollment rate Secondary enrollment rate
Method OLS FE IV OLS FE IV OLS FE IV
Per capita remittance 0.16∗∗∗ 0.15∗∗∗ 0.35∗∗∗ 0.02∗∗∗ 0.02∗∗∗ 0.016 0.07∗∗∗ 0.06∗∗∗ 0.07∗∗∗
(0.023) (0.024) (0.064) (0.005) (0.006) (0.012) (0.01) (0.009) (0.018)
Per capita GDP 0.83∗∗∗ 0.70∗∗∗ 0.66∗∗∗ 0.10∗∗∗ 0.10∗∗∗ 0.07∗∗∗ 0.42∗∗∗ 0.33∗∗∗ 0.32∗∗∗
(0.05) (0.073) (0.078) (0.015) (0.02) (0.019) (0.025) (0.029) (0.029)
Labor force participation 1.46∗∗∗ 0.98∗∗∗ 1.59∗∗∗ 0.64∗∗∗ 0.63∗∗∗ 0.48∗∗∗ 0.25∗ 0.41∗∗∗ 0.35∗∗
(0.333) (0.348) (0.374) (0.091) (0.102) (0.098) (0.13) (0.137) (0.141)
Gov expenditure on education 0.28∗∗∗ 0.35∗∗∗ 0.38∗∗∗ 0.06∗∗∗ 0.08∗∗∗ 0.06∗∗∗ 0.18 0.24∗∗∗ 0.25∗∗∗
(0.087) (0.093) (0.092) (0.019) (0.02) (0.02) (0.036) (0.037) (0.037)
Number of countries 96 96 96 104 104 104 98 98 98
Observations 859 859 859 990 990 990 858 858 858
R-squared 0.52 0.54 0.45 0.26 0.29 0.27 0.63 0.72 0.72
HAC standard errors are in parentheses. FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

Table 10
Impact of remittances on education (2).
Dependent Tertiary enrollment rate Out of school rate-primary age Enrollment in private primary
Method OLS FE IV OLS FE IV OLS FE IV
Per capita remittance 0.10∗∗∗ 0.09∗∗∗ 0.11∗∗∗ −0.09∗∗∗ −0.07∗∗ −0.1 0.17∗∗∗ 0.13∗∗∗ 0.23∗∗∗
(0.022) (0.02) (0.037) (0.03) (0.031) (0.063) (0.045) (0.036) (0.078)
Per capita GDP 0.85∗∗∗ 0.61∗∗∗ 0.59∗∗∗ −0.78∗∗∗ −0.47∗∗∗ −0.44∗∗∗ −0.26∗∗ −0.16 −0.2∗∗
(0.046) (0.055) (0.056) (0.069) (0.078) (0.08) (0.1) (0.096) (0.1)
Labor force participation −0.09 0.111 0.2 −1.14∗∗∗ −1.07∗∗ −1.19∗∗∗ 1.52∗∗∗ −0.32 −0.06
(0.282) (0.249) (0.268) (0.38) (0.422) (0.422) (0.457) (0.423) (0.42)
Gov expenditure on education −0.038 0.04 0.02 −0.18∗ −0.25∗∗ −0.25∗∗ −0.68∗∗∗ −0.83∗∗∗ −0.76∗∗∗
(0.084) (0.081) (0.081) (0.101) (0.01) (0.1) (0.171) (0.147) (0.13)
Number of countries 98 98 98 97 97 97 99 99 99
Observations 779 779 779 754 754 754 818 818 818
R-squared 0.6 0.71 0.71 0.33 0.39 0.39 0.10 0.51 0.5
HAC standard errors are in parentheses. FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

ment by 15.9%, 4.8%, and 3.5%, respectively. Also, when the govern- shown in Table 10.
ment expenditure on education increases, the marginal rate of return on The results presented in Table 10 show that, on average, a 10%
households’ investment in education increases. The increased marginal rise in remittance per capita increases tertiary enrollment rate by 1.1%.
rates of returns, in turn, promote households to spend more on their However, based on the IV model, while a 10% rise in per capita remit-
children’s education. On average, a 10% rise in government expen- tance decreases out of school rate of primary age children by 1%, this
ditures on education increases pre-primary, primary, and secondary impact is not statistically significant. The last dependent variable used
enrollment by 3.8%, 0.6%, and 2.5%, respectively. in Table 10 presents the impact of workers’ remittances on the qual-
The substantial difference between the impacts of per capita remit- ity of children’s education rather than the quantity. On average, a 10%
tances on pre-primary enrollment rate, primary enrollment rate, and rise in per capita remittances increases enrollment in private primary
secondary enrollment rate can be explained by considering the mean schools by 2.8% which means that a rise in remittances leads to a net
these variables: 39.3%, 100.6%,7 and 60.7%, respectively. House- substitution from public to private primary schools, hence increasing
holds in developing countries consider pre-primary education as a lux- the quality of children’s education. In contrast, a rise in per capita GDP
ury commodity. However, they consider primary education, which is leads to a net substitution from private to public primary schools. One
required in many countries, as a necessity. Therefore, the elasticity of explanation is that as per capita GDP of developing countries increase,
pre-primary enrollment rate with respect to per capita remittances or the quality of public schools also increase and parents will have less
per capita GDP is expected to be higher than the elasticity of primary incentive to send their children to private schools.
enrollment rate. However secondary education is less of a necessity in As Table 11 shows, on average, a 10% rise in per capita remittance
comparison with primary education, and tertiary education is less of increases primary completion rate by 0.6% and secondary completion
a necessity in comparison with secondary education. Therefore, it is rate by 0.9%. Once again, the difference in the impacts of per capita
reasonable that secondary enrollment rate has a higher elasticity than remittances on these two measurements of education can be explained
primary enrollment rate, and tertiary enrollment rate has a higher elas- by taking into account the average primary completion rate and lower
ticity than secondary enrollment rate. secondary completion rate: 80% and 60%, respectively. Households in
The impacts of per capita remittances on tertiary enrollment rate, developing countries consider primary education a necessity and sec-
primary age out of school rate, and private primary enrollment rate are ondary education as less of a necessity than a luxury commodity. There-
fore, it is reasonable that secondary completion rate has higher elastic-
ity than primary completion rate with respect to per capita remittances

7
Since this is a gross rate, which is defined as “the ratio of total enrollment
in primary, regardless of age, to the population of the primary age group”, it
can be over 100%.

390
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

Table 11
Impact of remittances on education (3).
Dependent Primary completion rate Secondary completion rate Gender parity index-primary
Method OLS FE IV OLS FE IV OLS FE IV
Per capita remittance 0.05∗∗∗ 0.05∗∗∗ 0.06∗∗∗ 0.09∗∗∗ 0.08∗∗∗ 0.09∗∗∗ 0.01∗∗∗ 0.01∗∗∗ 0.02∗∗∗
(0.007) (0.007) (0.015) (0.013) (0.011) (0.026) (0.002) (0.002) (0.006)
Per capita GDP 0.26∗∗∗ 0.21∗∗∗ 0.19∗∗∗ 0.42∗∗∗ 0.28∗∗∗ 0.26∗∗∗ 0.05∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗
(0.018) (0.022) (0.021) (0.032) (0.035) (0.033) (0.005) (0.006) (0.006)
Labor force participation 0.48∗∗∗ 0.56∗∗∗ 0.51∗∗∗ 0.24 0.46∗∗ 0.34∗ 0.19∗∗∗ 0.18∗∗∗ 0.19∗∗∗
(0.107) (0.106) (0.117) (0.177) (0.189) (0.2) (0.03) (0.035) (0.038)
Gov expenditure on education 0.09∗∗∗ 0.14∗∗∗ 0.14∗∗∗ 0.03 0.12∗∗ 0.12∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗
(0.026) (0.027) (0.028) (0.044) (0.05) (0.05) (0.009) (0.01) (0.009)
Number of countries 99 99 99 94 94 94 104 104 104
Observations 814 814 814 736 736 736 976 976 976
R-squared 0.55 0.64 0.63 0.53 0.67 0.66 0.3 0.35 0.31
HAC standard errors are in parentheses. FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

Table 12
Gender-specific impact of remittances on education (1).
Dependent Pre-primary enrollment rate Primary enrollment rate
Gender Male Female Male Female
Per capita remittance 0.13∗∗∗ 0.34∗∗∗ 0.15∗∗∗ 0.35∗∗∗ 0.009 0.004 0.03∗∗∗ 0.03∗∗
(0.026) (0.064) (0.023) (0.063) (0.006) (0.011) (0.007) (0.014)
Per capita GDP 0.62∗∗∗ 0.55∗∗∗ 0.71∗∗∗ 0.66∗∗∗ 0.05∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗ 0.11∗∗∗ 0.09∗∗∗
(0.074) (0.076) (0.071) (0.079) (0.015) (0.016) (0.02) (0.02)
Gender-specific labor participation rate −0.59 −0.21 0.58∗∗∗ 0.82∗∗∗ 0.07 0.14 0.38∗∗∗ 0.3∗∗∗
(0.527) (0.572) (0.168) (0.169) (0.109) (0.106) (0.057) (0.057)
Gov expenditure on education 0.33 0.35∗∗∗ 0.31∗∗∗ 0.31∗∗∗ 0.05∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗ 0.08∗∗∗ 0.06∗∗∗
(0.101) (0.1) (0.095) (0.094) (0.018) (0.018) (0.023) (0.022)
Number of countries 96 96 96 96 104 104 104 104
Observations 821 821 821 821 976 976 976 976
R-squared 0.52 0.43 0.55 0.47 0.14 0.13 0.36 0.34
Method FE IV FE IV FE IV FE IV

HAC standard errors are in parentheses. Both FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

and with respect to per capita GDP. and female pre-primary enrollment rates and primary enrollment rates.
Based on the descriptive statistics, boys’ average primary enrollment On average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances increases male
rate is 103.4%8 and girls’ average primary enrollment is 97.4%. This and female pre-primary enrollment rates by 3.4% and 3.5%, respec-
means the average households’ investment in girls’ primary education tively. In contrast, while per capita remittance has no statistically sig-
is less than their investment in boys’ primary education in developing nificant impact on male primary enrollment rate, on average, a 10%
countries. Therefore, the marginal rate of return on primary education increase in per capita remittances increases female primary enrollment
is higher for girls than boys. Hence, the inflow of remittances, which rate by 0.3%. This asymmetric impact of remittances on female and
loosens the budget constraints for households in developing countries, male primary enrollment rate is in line with the positive impact of
is invested more heavily in girls’ primary education than boys. This, remittances on the gender parity index of primary education.
in turn, raises the primary gender parity index, though just by a small There is a remarkable heterogeneity between the impact of the male
amount. On average, a 10% rise in per capita remittance increases the labor force participation rate on male education and the impact of the
primary gender parity index by 0.2%. This impact is statistically signif- female labor force participation rate on female education. While male
icant in all three models: OLS, FE, and IV. labor force participation has no effect on male education investment,
Workers’ remittances increase the gender parity index. The rise in female labor force participation has a positive and significant effect on
gender parity index means when households in developing countries female education investment. On average, a 10% increase in the female
receive remittances from the migrants, they spend a higher propor- labor force participation rate increases female pre-primary and primary
tion of it on girls’ primary education than on boys. This is particu- enrollment by 3.1% and 0.6%, respectively. The impacts of the same
larly important because, as Bansak and Chezum (2009) state, if remit- explanatory variables on secondary and tertiary enrollment rates are
tances do affect human capital positively, then not only will remittances provided in Table 13.
affect long-run growth in developing countries, but the opportunities Results provided in Table 13 show that per capita remittance has a
for women should improve as the female population becomes more greater impact on the female secondary and tertiary enrollment rates
educated in these countries. Table 12 provides gender-specific effects than on the male rates. On average, a 10% increase in per capita remit-
of per capita remittances, per capita GDP, government expenditure on tances increases male and female secondary enrollment by 0.7% and
education, and gender-specific labor force participation rate on male 0.9%, respectively. On average, a 10% increase in per capita remit-
tances increases male and female tertiary enrollment by 0.6% and
1.3%, respectively. The impacts of the explanatory variables on male

8
Since it is a gross ratio and it includes the repeaters, it can be higher than
100%.

391
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

Table 13
Gender-specific impact of remittances on education (2).
Dependent Secondary enrollment rate Tertiary enrollment rate
Gender Male Female Male Female
Per capita remittance 0.05∗∗∗ 0.07∗∗∗ 0.08∗∗∗ 0.09∗∗∗ 0.07∗∗∗ 0.06 0.12∗∗∗ 0.13∗∗∗
(0.009) (0.0176) (0.01) (0.0227) (0.021) (0.038) (0.022) (0.045)
Per capita GDP 0.26∗∗∗ 0.24∗∗∗ 0.41∗∗∗ 0.41∗∗∗ 0.49∗∗∗ 0.48∗∗∗ 0.72∗∗∗ 0.73∗∗∗
(0.023) (0.023) (0.034) (0.033) (0.053) (0.06) (0.062) (0.0625)
Gender-specific labor participation rate −0.46∗∗∗ −0.39∗∗ 0.34∗∗∗ 0.29∗∗∗ −0.12 −0.13 0.1 0.11
(0.157) (0.154) (0.082) (0.085) (0.313) (0.32) (0.157) (0.17)
Gov expenditure on education 0.13∗∗∗ 0.13∗∗∗ 0.28∗∗∗ 0.3∗∗∗ −0.08 −0.1 0.14 0.17∗
(0.033) (0.033) (0.045) (0.044) (0.081) (0.09) (0.097) (0.098)
Number of countries 97 97 97 97 96 96 96 96
Observations 817 817 817 817 709 709 709 709
R-squared 0.71 0.71 0.74 0.74 0.64 0.64 0.76 0.76
Method FE IV FE IV FE IV FE IV

HAC standard errors are in parentheses. Both FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

Table 14
Gender-specific impact of remittances on education (3).
Dependent primary completion rate Secondary completion rate
Gender Male Female Male Female
Per capita remittance 0.04∗∗∗ 0.05∗∗∗ 0.06∗∗∗ 0.09∗∗∗ 0.07∗∗∗ 0.08∗∗∗ 0.1∗∗∗ 0.12∗∗∗
(0.007) (0.0134) (0.008) (0.019) (0.011) (0.025) (0.013) (0.031)
Per capita GDP 0.17∗∗∗ 0.15∗∗∗ 0.27∗∗∗ 0.25∗∗∗ 0.23∗∗∗ 0.22∗∗∗ 0.38∗∗∗ 0.35∗∗∗
(0.018) (0.017) (0.025) (0.025) (0.029) (0.028) (0.043) (0.041)
Gender-specific labor participation rate −0.04 0.03 0.37∗∗∗ 0.36∗∗∗ −0.52∗∗∗ −0.46∗∗ 0.39∗∗∗ 0.31∗∗
(0.105) (0.1) (0.065) (0.071) (0.198) (0.196) (0.116) (0.128)
Gov expenditure on education 0.06∗∗∗ 0.07∗∗∗ 0.17∗∗∗ 0.18∗∗∗ 0.01 0.02 0.17∗∗∗ 0.19∗∗∗
(0.023) (0.023) (0.033) (0.034) (0.045) (0.045) (0.056) (0.057)
Number of countries 96 96 96 96 92 92 92 92
Observations 774 774 774 774 701 701 701 701
R-squared 0.60 0.59 0.66 0.64 0.64 0.63 0.69 0.69
Method FE IV FE IV FE IV FE IV
HAC standard errors are in parentheses. Both FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

and female primary and secondary completion rates are provided in than boys’ education.
Table 14.
The results provided in Table 14, confirm that remittance has
5.3. Remittances and HDI
a greater effect on the female primary and secondary completion
rates than on male rates. On average, a 10% increase in per capita
As a robustness check for the impact of remittances on human cap-
remittances increases the male and female primary completion rates by
ital, I examine the effect of remittance on HDI in developing countries.
0.5% and 0.9%, respectively. On average, a 10% increase in per capita
Table 15 provides the impacts of per capita remittances, per capita GDP,
remittances increases the male and female lower secondary completion
government expenditures on education, and per capita health expendi-
rate by 0.8% and 1.2%, respectively. Comparing the elasticities
tures, on total, male, and female HDI.
obtained for male and female education with respect to per capita
As Table 15 shows, on average, a 10% rise in per capita remittances
remittances in Tables 12–14 shows that households in developing
increases total HDI, male HDI, and female HDI by 0.35%, 0.3%, and
countries, upon receiving remittances, invest in girls’ education more
0.4%, respectively. Note that only limited amounts of gender-specific

Table 15
Impacts of remittances on HDI.
Gender Total Male Female
Method OLS FE IV OLS FE IV OLS FE IV
Per capita remittances 0.02∗∗∗ 0.02∗∗∗ 0.035∗∗∗ 0.03∗∗∗ 0.02∗∗∗ 0.03∗∗∗ 0.036∗∗∗ 0.029∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗
(0.003) (0.002) (0.006) (0.003) (0.003) (0.007) (0.005) (0.005) (0.01)
Per capita GDP 0.23∗∗∗ 0.18∗∗∗ 0.17∗∗∗ 0.18∗∗∗ 0.14∗∗∗ 0.14∗∗∗ 0.24∗∗∗ 0.18∗∗∗ 0.18∗∗∗
(0.006) (0.007) (0.007) (0.006) (0.007) (0.007) (0.009) (0.011) (0.011)
Gov expenditures on education 0.03∗∗∗ 0.05∗∗∗ 0.05∗∗∗ 0.007 0.03∗∗∗ 0.035∗∗∗ 0.05∗∗∗ 0.06∗∗∗ 0.06∗∗∗
(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.014) (0.011) (0.011) (0.019) (0.015) (0.015)
Number of countries 103 103 103 83 83 83 83 83 83
Observations 1069 1069 1069 394 394 394 393 393 393
R-squared 0.8 0.86 0.85 0.85 0.9 0.9 0.82 0.87 0.86
HAC standard errors are in parentheses. FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

392
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

HDI data are available. The number of observations in the first regres- developing countries.
sion is 1069, and in the second and third regressions, 394 and 393, There is an enormous heterogeneity in labor force participation
respectively. The positive impact of remittance on HDI confirms pre- between men and women in developing countries. This heterogeneity
vious findings in this paper. Workers’ remittances do improve human is clearer when we review the descriptive statistics provided in Table 2.
capital in developing countries. While average labor force participation for men is 76.6% in develop-
ing countries, it is just 50.9% for women. Due to cultural features of
5.4. Remittances and labor force participation many developing countries, reservation wage for women is more sen-
sitive to non-labor income than reservation wage for men. Therefore,
This section examines the impact of workers’ remittances on the upon receiving a greater amount of remittances some working-women
labor force participation rate in the remittance-receiving countries. will stop working. This is not the case for men in developing countries.
Remittances can affect labor force participation in remittance-receiving
countries mainly through two channels: human capital and reservation 6. Conclusion
wages.
As stated by Amuedo-Dorantes and Pozo (2006) remittances and Remittances can increase investment in human capital. This impact
the error term in equation (1) may be correlated. Remittances may be is especially important since human capital is a crucial factor in the pro-
endogenous and their coefficient estimates may be biased. There are motion of growth in developing countries in the long-run. This paper
three potential sources for this endogeneity. Omitted variable bias may uses a dataset on workers’ remittances, health outcomes, and educa-
exist if remittances are related to wealth which, in turn, may be cor- tional attainment of 122 developing countries from 1990 to 2015 and
related to the labor supply by the recipient. Additionally, there is the an innovative instrumental variables estimation strategy to examine the
potential of reverse causality as labor supply may influence migrants’ impact of workers’ remittances on human capital and labor supply in
decisions to send remittances home. The third source of endogeneity the developing world. Also, the gender-specific effects of remittances on
can be measurement errors. Therefore, in this section, I use the same health, education, HDI, and labor force participation are investigated.
five instrumental variables to address the endogeneity of remittances. The results obtained in this paper show that remittances have an
So far, we have concluded remittances increase human capital, espe- improving and statistically significant impact on health outcomes in
cially health and education outcomes, in developing countries. On the developing countries. I use instruments to address the possible endo-
one hand, increases in human capital can increase labor force participa- geneity of workers’ remittances and control for level of income, some
tion. On the other hand, remittances, as a non-labor source of income, covariates, and geographic region. The results of the impact of remit-
increase reservation wages in developing countries. Increases in the tances on health outcomes suggest that, on average, a 10% increase in
reservation wage can cause a reduction in the labor force participation per capita remittances will lead to a 1.5% increase in out-of-pocket per
rate. Therefore, the net impact of remittances on labor supply (labor capita health expenditures, a 1.1% increase in total per capita health
force participation) is a priori unclear. The important question is: does expenditures, 0.3% increase in life expectancy at birth, 1.5% decline in
the rise in the reservation wage and its negative impact on labor force undernourishment prevalence, 1.9% decline in depth of food deficit,
participation outweigh the positive impact of remittances on labor force and 1% decline in prevalence of stunting. Also, remittances have a
participation through raising human capital? If so, are the impacts of strong and statistically significant effect on reducing child mortality
remittances on male and female labor force participation rates symmet- rates in developing countries. On average, a 10% increase in per capita
ric? The impacts of remittances on total, male, and female labor supply remittances will lead to a 1% decline in neonatal mortality rate, 1.7%
are provided in Table 16. decline in infant mortality rate, and 1.9% decline in under-five mor-
In the IV model provided in Table 16, I use instruments to address tality rate. The gender-specific results show that the effects of workers’
the endogeneity of workers’ remittances and control for the level of remittances on reducing infant and under-five mortality rates are almost
income, education, the ratio of the population living in urban areas, the same for male and female children.
and geographic region. The results of the impact of remittances on Remittances also have a positive and statistically significant impact
labor force participation rate suggest that, on average, a 10% increase on education in the developing countries. I use instrumental variables
in remittances leads to a 0.17% decline in total labor force participa- to address endogeneity of workers’ remittances and control for the level
tion rate, a 0.03% decline in the male labor force participation rate, of income, government expenditures on education, labor force partic-
which is not statistically different than zero, and a 0.33% decline in ipation, and geographic region. The results of the impact of remit-
the female labor force participation rate. These results show that while tances on education outcomes suggest that, on average, a 10% increase
workers’ remittances have no impact on the male labor force partic- in per capita remittances will lead to a 3.5% increase in pre-primary
ipation rate, they reduce the female labor force participation rate in enrollment rate, 0.7% increase in secondary enrollment rate, and 1.1%

Table 16
Impacts of remittances on labor force participation.
Gender Total Male Female
Method OLS FE IV OLS FE IV OLS FE IV
Per capita remittance −0.024∗∗∗ −0.018∗∗∗ −0.017∗∗∗ −0.0001 −0.003 −0.003 −0.06∗∗∗ −0.04∗∗∗ −0.03∗∗
(0.003) (0.002) (0.006) (0.002) (0.002) (0.004) (0.007) (0.005) (0.013)
Per capita GDP −0.06∗∗∗ −0.06∗∗∗ −0.05∗∗∗ −0.01∗ −0.02∗∗∗ −0.02∗∗ −0.1∗∗∗ −0.1∗∗∗ −0.11∗∗∗
(0.014) (0.012) (0.012) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.037) (0.025) (0.025)
Primary completion rate 0.11∗∗∗ 0.1∗∗∗ 0.1∗∗∗ −0.04∗∗ −0.025∗∗ −0.02 0.32∗∗∗ 0.23∗∗∗ 0.22∗∗∗
(0.023) (0.021) (0.022) (0.014) (0.012) (0.013) (0.055) (0.055) (0.06)
Urban ratio −0.09∗∗∗ −0.05∗∗∗ −0.07∗∗∗ −0.04∗∗∗ −0.04∗∗∗ −0.05∗∗∗ −0.2∗∗∗ −0.07∗∗ −0.08∗∗
(0.021) (0.017) (0.016) (0.011) (0.011) (0.011) (0.05) (0.035) (0.035)
Number of countries 109 109 109 109 109 109 109 109 109
Observations 1386 1386 1386 1386 1386 1386 1386 1386 1386
R-squared 0.28 0.54 0.54 0.12 0.42 0.4156 0.24 0.61 0.6
HAC standard errors are in parentheses. FE and IV models include region dummies.
∗∗∗ significant at 1% level. ∗∗ significant at 5% level. ∗ significant at 10% level.

393
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

increase in tertiary enrollment rate. Remittances not only have a pos- effect on male labor force participation, they reduce female labor force
itive effect on enrollment rates but also have a positive effect on qual- participation: on average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances will
ity of education: on average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances lead to a 0.3% decline in female labor force participation.
will lead to a 2.3% increase in enrollment in private primary schools. This study contributes to the literature in a number of ways. First,
In addition to raising the enrollment rate, remittances increase school this paper uses data from 122 developing countries over the period from
completion rates: on average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances 1990 to 2015. I am not aware of any other studies which explore the
will lead to a 0.6% increase in primary completion rates and 0.9% impact of remittances on human capital and labor supply and uses such
increase in secondary completion rates. a large dataset. Second, this study uses an innovative new approach
Unlike the impacts of remittances on reducing child mortality rates for building instruments to address the endogeneity of remittances.
which were symmetric between genders, remittances improve girls’ This study estimates bilateral remittances uses them to create weighted
education outcomes more than boys. On average, a 10% increase in per indicators of remittance-sending countries. These weighted indicators
capita remittances will lead to a 0.2% increase in the primary gender are used as instruments for remittance inflow to remittance-receiving
parity index, the ratio of girls to boys enrolled at the primary level. On countries. selecting economic variables from remittance-sending coun-
average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances will lead to a 0.3% tries, rather than from remittance-receiving countries, as instruments is
increase in girls’ primary enrollment rate while it has no statistically to ensure the validity of instruments. Using estimated bilateral remit-
significant effect on boys’ primary enrollment rate. These results are tances and to construct the instruments is to ensure that instruments are
in compliance with the positive effect of remittances on primary gen- strong. This novel approach to instruments can be applied to address
der parity. Also, on average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances the endogeneity problem while exploring the impact of remittances
will lead to a 1.3% increase in girls’ tertiary enrollment rate while it on many socioeconomic variables such as education, health, labor sup-
has no statistically significant effect on boys’ tertiary enrollment rate. ply, poverty, inequality, growth, and financial development. Moreover,
The positive effect of remittances on girls’ education is greater than the this approach can be used in both country-level studies and household-
positive effect of remittances on boys’ education in all case of school level studies. Finally, this study, in addition to investigating the overall
completion rates: 10% increase in per capita remittances rises male and impact of remittances on human capital and labor supply, explores the
female primary completion rate by 0.5% and 0.9%, respectively and impacts of remittances on male and female human capital and labor
rises male and female lower secondary completion rate by 0.8% and supply using a wide range of gender-specific variables. This allows
1.2%, respectively. researchers to compare the impacts of remittances by gender.
Since remittances improve health and education outcomes in devel- In terms of policy recommendation, the high-income countries
oping countries, it is expected to have a positive impact on HDI as well. should take further steps to reduce the current transaction costs of
On average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances will lead to a remitting money to remittance-receiving countries. Based on Remit-
0.3% and 0.4% increase in male and female HDI, respectively. tance Prices Worldwide (RPW) reports, the average global cost of remit-
The net impact of remittances on labor force participation is a pri- tances went down from 9.12% in the first quarter of 2012 to 7.52%
ori unclear. On the one hand, workers’ remittances can increase human in the third quarter of 2015. Unfortunately, since the third quarter of
capital investments of poor households, hence increasing the labor sup- 2015, the cost of remittances has not been reduced any further. The
ply. On the other hand, remittances can loosen budget constraints, global cost of remittances in the first quarter of 2017 was 7.45%, stay-
raise reservation wages, and, through the income effects, reduce the ing 4.45 percentage point above the 3% UN SDG goal. The high trans-
labor force participation of remittance-receiving individuals. The results action costs act as a type of tax on emigrants from developing countries
obtained in the last section of this paper show that remittances have a who are often poor and remit small amounts of money with each remit-
negative and statistically significant impact on labor force participation tance transaction. Lowering the transaction costs of remittances would
in developing countries. not only encourage a larger share of remittances to flow through formal
I use instrumental variables to address the possible endogeneity of financial channels but will also help to improve health and education
workers’ remittances and control for the level of income, education, the outcomes in developing countries.
percentage of population living in urban area, and geographic region.
The results of the impact of remittances on labor force participation Acknowledgments
suggest that, on average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances will
lead to a 0.17% decrease in labor force participation. The results of I would like to thank Dr. Virginia Wilcox, Dr. Maria Ponomareva,
gender-specific effects of remittances on labor force participation can Dr. Meg Cheng and two anonymous reviewers for their valuable com-
be more informative. While remittances have no statistically significant ments. All errors are solely my responsibility.

Appendix I

Table A1
Correlation matrix between selected variables.
Per capita Per capita Per capita Life Expect Undernourish Under 5 Secondary HDI LFP
GDP remittance health exp prevalence Mortality enrollment
Per capita GDP 1 0.39 0.91 0.67 −0.63 −0.74 0.73 0.87 −0.44
Per capita remittance 1 0.45 0.58 −0.43 −0.56 0.50 0.50 −0.35
Per capita health exp 1 0.66 −0.65 −0.77 0.75 0.85 −0.46
Life Expectancy 1 −0.55 −0.87 0.77 0.85 −0.39
Undernourish prevalence 1 0.60 −0.56 −0.62 0.44
Under 5 Mortality 1 −0.78 −0.87 0.36
Secondary enrollment 1 0.92 −0.36
HDI 1 −0.38
LFP 1
All correlations are significant in 0.01 level.

394
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

Appendix II

Table B1
List of countries.
Afghanistan Dominican Republic Libya Sao Tome and Principe
Albania Ecuador Macedonia, FYR Senegal
Algeria Egypt, Arab Rep. Madagascar Serbia
Angola El Salvador Malawi Sierra Leone
Argentina Ethiopia Mali Solomon Islands
Armenia Fiji Marshall Islands Sri Lanka
Azerbaijan Gabon Mauritania St. Lucia
Bangladesh Gambia, The Mexico St. Vincent and the Grenadines
Belarus Georgia Micronesia, Fed. Sts. Sudan
Belize Ghana Moldova Suriname
Benin Grenada Mongolia Swaziland
Bhutan Guatemala Montenegro Syrian Arab Republic
Bolivia Guinea Morocco Tajikistan
Bosnia and Herzegovina Guinea-Bissau Mozambique Tanzania
Botswana Guyana Myanmar Thailand
Brazil Haiti Namibia Timor-Leste
Bulgaria Honduras Nepal Togo
Burkina Faso India Nicaragua Tonga
Burundi Indonesia Niger Tunisia
Cabo Verde Iraq Nigeria Turkey
Cambodia Jamaica Pakistan Tuvalu
Cameroon Jordan Palau Uganda
Chad Kazakhstan Panama Ukraine
China Kenya Papua New Guinea Vanuatu
Colombia Kiribati Paraguay Venezuela, RB
Comoros Kosovo Peru West Bank and Gaza
Congo, Rep. Kyrgyz Republic Philippines Yemen, Rep.
Costa Rica Lao PDR Romania Zambia
Cote d’Ivoire Lebanon Russian Federation Zimbabwe
Djibouti Lesotho Rwanda
Dominica Liberia Samoa

References Amuedo-Dorantes, C., Georges, A., Pozo, S., 2010. Migration, remittances, and children’s
schooling in Haiti. Ann. Am. Acad. Polit. Soc. Sci. 630 (1), 224–244.
Abadie, A., Athey, S., Imbens, G.W., Wooldridge, J., 2017. When Should You Adjust Anton, J.I., 2010. The impact of remittances on nutritional status of children in Ecuador.
Standard Errors for Clustering?. (No. w24003). National Bureau of Economic Int. Migrat. Rev. 44 (2), 269–299.
Research. Azizi, S., 2017. Altruism: primary motivation of remittances. Appl. Econ. Lett. 24 (17),
Acharya, C.P., Leon-Gonzalez, R., 2014. How do migration and remittances affect 1218–1221.
human capital investment? The effects of relaxing information and liquidity Azizi, S., 2018. Why do migrants remit? World Econ. (upcoming).
constraints. J. Dev. Stud. 50 (3), 444–460. Bang, J.T., Mitra, A., Wunnava, P.V., 2016. Do remittances improve income inequality?
Acosta, P., 2006. Labor Supply, School Attendance, and Remittances from International An instrumental variable quantile analysis of the Kenyan case. Econ. Modell. 58,
Migration: the Case of El Salvador, vol. 3903. World Bank, Development Research 394–402.
Group, Trade Team. Bansak, C., Chezum, B., 2009. How do remittances affect human capital formation of
Acosta, P., 2011. School attendance, child labour, and remittances from international school-age boys and girls? Am. Econ. Rev. 99 (2), 145–148.
migration in El Salvador. J. Dev. Stud. 47 (6), 913–936. Bargain, O., Boutin, D., 2015. Remittance effects on child labour: evidence from Burkina
Acosta, P., Calderon, C., Fajnzylber, P., López, H., 2007. Remittances and development Faso. J. Dev. Stud. 51 (7), 922–938.
in Latin America. World Econ. 29 (7), 957–987. Bouoiyour, J., Miftah, A., 2016. Education, male gender preference and migrants’
Acosta, P., Fajnzylber, P., López, J.H., 2008. Remittances and Household Behavior: remittances: interactions in rural Morocco. Econ. Modell. 57, 324–331.
Evidence for Latin America. Remittances and Development: Lessons from Latin Brown, R.P., Carmignani, F., Fayad, G., 2013. Migrants’ remittances and financial
America, pp. 133–170. development: macro and micro level evidence of a perverse relationship. World
Acosta, P.A., Lartey, E.K., Mandelman, F.S., 2009. Remittances and the Dutch disease. J. Econ. 36 (5), 636–660.
Int. Econ. 79 (1), 102–116. Calero, C., Bedi, A.S., Sparrow, R., 2009. Remittances, liquidity constraints and human
Adams, R.H., Page, J., 2005. Do international migration and remittances reduce poverty capital investments in Ecuador. World Dev. 37 (6), 1143–1154.
in developing countries? World Dev. 33 (10), 1645–1669 Chicago. Chami, R., Hakura, D., Montiel, P.J., 2009a. Remittances: an Automatic Output
Aggarwal, R., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Peria, M.S.M., 2011. Do remittances promote financial Stabilizer? .
development? J. Dev. Econ. 96 (2), 255–264. Chami, R., Fullenkamp, C., Gapen, M., 2009b. Measuring Workers’ Remittances: what
Al Mamun, M., Sohag, K., Uddin, G.S., Shahbaz, M., 2015. Remittance and domestic Should Be Kept in and what Should Be Left Out. International Monetary Fund,
labor productivity: evidence from remittance recipient countries. Econ. Modell. 47, Mimeo.
207–218. Chauvet, L., Gubert, F., Mesple-Somps, S., 2013. Aid, remittances, medical brain drain
Alcaraz, C., Chiquiar, D., Salcedo, A., 2012. Remittances, schooling, and child labor in and child mortality: evidence using inter and intra-country data. J. Dev. Stud. 49
Mexico. J. Dev. Econ. 97 (1), 156–165. (6), 801–818.
Alkhathlan, K.A., 2013. The nexus between remittance outflows and growth: a study of Chowdhury, M.B., 2011. Remittances flow and financial development in Bangladesh.
Saudi Arabia. Econ. Modell. 33, 695–700. Econ. Modell. 28 (6), 2600–2608.
Ambrosius, C., Cuecuecha, A., 2013. Are remittances a substitute for credit? Carrying Combes, J.L., Ebeke, C.H., Etoundi, S.M.N., Yogo, T.U., 2014. Are remittances and
the financial burden of health shocks in national and transnational households. foreign aid a hedge against food price shocks in developing countries? World Dev.
World Dev. 46, 143–152. 54, 81–98.
Amuedo-Dorantes, C., Pozo, S., 2006. Migration, remittances, and male and female Coulibaly, D., 2015. Remittances and financial development in Sub-Saharan African
employment patterns. Am. Econ. Rev. 96 (2), 222–226. countries: a system approach. Econ. Modell. 45, 249–258.
Amuedo-Dorantes, C., Pozo, S., 2010. Accounting for remittance and migration effects Cox-Edwards, A., Rodriguez-Oreggia, E., 2009. Remittances and labor force participation
on children’s schooling. World Dev. 38 (12), 1747–1759. in Mexico: an analysis using propensity score matching. World Dev. 37 (5),
Amuedo-Dorantes, C., Pozo, S., 2011. New evidence on the role of remittances on 1004–1014.
healthcare expenditures by Mexican households. Rev. Econ. Househ. 9 (1), 69–98.

395
S. Azizi Economic Modelling 75 (2018) 377–396

Docquier, F., Rapoport, H., Salomone, S., 2012. Remittances, migrants’ education and Kim, N., 2007. The Impact of Remittances on Labor Supply: the Case of Jamaica.
immigration policy: theory and evidence from bilateral data. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. Li, X., Zhou, Y., 2013. An economic analysis of remittance of unskilled migration on
42 (5), 817–828. skilled–unskilled wage inequality in labor host region. Econ. Modell. 33, 428–432.
Edwards, A.C., Ureta, M., 2003. International migration, remittances, and schooling: Li, X., Zhou, J., 2015. Environmental effects of remittance of rural–urban migrant. Econ.
evidence from El Salvador. J. Dev. Econ. 72 (2), 429–461. Modell. 47, 174–179.
Fajnzylber, P., Lopez, J.H., 2008. The Development Impact of Remittances in Latin Lueth, E., Ruiz-Arranz, M., 2008. Determinants of bilateral remittance flows. B E J.
America. Remittances and Development, vol. 1. Macroecon. 8 (1).
Frank, R., Hummer, R.A., 2002. The other side of the paradox: the risk of low birth Nguyen, T., Purnamasari, R., 2011. Impacts of International Migration and Remittances
weight among infants of migrant and nonmigrant households within Mexico. Int. on Child Outcomes and Labor Supply in Indonesia: How Does Gender Matter? .
Migrat. Rev. 36 (3), 746–765. Ponce, J., Olivie, I., Onofa, M., 2011. The role of international remittances in health
Frankel, J., 2011. Are bilateral remittances countercyclical? Open Econ. Rev. 22 (1), outcomes in Ecuador: prevention and response to shocks. Int. Migrat. Rev. 45 (3),
1–16. 727–745.
Freund, C., Spatafora, N., 2008. Remittances, transaction costs, and informality. J. Dev. Rao, B.B., Hassan, G.M., 2011. A panel data analysis of the growth effects of
Econ. 86 (2), 356–366. remittances. Econ. Modell. 28 (1–2), 701–709.
Funkhouser, E., 2006. The effect of emigration on the labor market outcomes of the Ratha, D., 2005. Workers’ Remittances: an Important and Stable Source of External
sender household: a longitudinal approach using data from Nicaragua. Well-Being Development Finance. Remittances: Development Impact and Future Prospects, pp.
Soc. Pol. 2 (2), 5–25. 19–51.
Gapen, M.T., Chami, M.R., Montiel, M.P., Barajas, M.A., Fullenkamp, C., 2009. Do Ratha, D., Shaw, W., 2007. South-south Migration and Remittances. (No. 102). World
Workers’ Remittances Promote Economic Growth?. (No. 9-153). International Bank Publications.
Monetary Fund. Salas, V.B., 2014. International remittances and human capital formation. World Dev.
Generoso, R., 2015. How do rainfall variability, food security and remittances interact? 59, 224–237.
The case of rural Mali. Ecol. Econ. 114, 188–198. Terrelonge, S.C., 2014. For health, strength, and daily food: the dual impact of
Giuliano, P., Ruiz-Arranz, M., 2009. Remittances, financial development, and growth. J. remittances and public health expenditure on household health spending and child
Dev. Econ. 90 (1), 144–152. health outcomes. J. Dev. Stud. 50 (10), 1397–1410.
Guha, P., 2013. Macroeconomic effects of international remittances: the case of Valero-Gil, J.N., 2009. Remittances and the household’s expenditures on health. J. Bus.
developing economies. Econ. Modell. 33, 292–305. Strat. 26 (1), 119.
Hanson, G.H., 2007. Emigration, Remittances and Labor Force Participation in Mexico. Williams, K., 2017. Do remittances improve political institutions? Evidence from
(Working Paper ITD= Documento de Trabajo ITD; 28). BID-INTAL. Sub-Saharan Africa. Econ. Modell. 61, 65–75.
Hathroubi, S., Aloui, C., 2016. On interactions between remittance outflows and Saudi Yang, D., 2008. International migration, remittances and household investment:
Arabian macroeconomy: new evidence from wavelets. Econ. Modell. 59, 32–45. evidence from Philippine migrants’ exchange rate shocks. Econ. J. 118 (528),
IMF, 2009. International Transactions in Remittances: Guide for Compilers and Users. 591–630.
Johansen, S., 1988. Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. J. Econ. Dynam. Contr. Zhunio, M.C., Vishwasrao, S., Chiang, E.P., 2012. The influence of remittances on
12 (2–3), 231–254. education and health outcomes: a cross country study. Appl. Econ. 44 (35),
Kanaiaupuni, S.M., Donato, K.M., 1999. Migradollars and mortality: the effects of 4605–4616.
migration on infant survival in Mexico. Demography 36 (3), 339–353. Ziesemer, T.H., 2012. Worker remittances, migration, accumulation and growth in poor
Kao, C., 1999. Spurious regression and residual-based tests for cointegration in panel developing countries: survey and analysis of direct and indirect effects. Econ.
data. J. Econom. 90 (1), 1–44. Modell. 29 (2), 103–118.

396

You might also like