Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

Research Evaluation, volume 14, number 3, December 2005, pages 000–000, Beech Tree Publishing, 10 Watford Close, Guildford,

Surrey GU1 2EP, England

Economic surplus analysis

Ex ante impact assessment for research on


natural resources management: methods and
application to aquatic resource systems

Roehlano Briones, Madan Dey, Ilona Stobutzki and Mark Prein

E
Under a particular representation of the impact CONOMIC TECHNIQUES FOR ex ante im-
pathway of natural resource management (NRM) pact assessment are accepted tools for evalu-
research, economic surplus techniques can also ating agricultural research. The need to
be used for ex ante impact assessment. The identify high-impact activities is keenly felt in the
method is applied to the case of the WorldFish public and nonprofit sector of developing countries,
where funds for research are seriously constrained.
Center, an international organization specializing
Among these analytical techniques, the economic
in research on aquatic resources in developing surplus method is the most popular and arguably the
countries. A survey of expert opinion is used to most fruitful approach for impact assessment
estimate productivity improvements and adoption (Alston et al, 1995).
rates for NRM research and its application. A Applications of economic surplus analysis are
supply–demand model for aquatic commodities is widespread in the case of farm commodity research.
constructed to calculate the resulting change in Recently, with growing emphasis on sustainable de-
economic surplus. Results indicate that ex ante velopment, natural resources management (NRM)
economic impact is highest for NRM on coral has become a major category for agricultural re-
reefs and inland aquatic systems. search. Unfortunately, NRM research has so far re-
sisted economic surplus analysis and other
conventional techniques of impact assessment,
whether ex post or ex ante (Izac, 1998; Pachico,
1998; Maredia et al, 2000; CGIAR, 2000; Pingali,
2001).
The differences in evaluation performance may be
traced to the nature of the impact pathways. For
farm commodity research the impact pathway is
straightforward. As impact depends on conditions in
parceled, artificial systems (farms), and the decen-
tralized choices of many individual farmers, the law
of large numbers permits a reasonable approxima-
Roehlano Briones was a postdoctoral fellow at the WorldFish tion of productivity impacts and adoption decisions
Center, Jalan Batu Maung, Batu Maung, 11960 Bayan Lepas,
Penang, Malaysia, at the time this study was conducted. Madan over time. However, for NRM, the impact pathway
Dey, Ilona Stobutzki and Mark Prein are WorldFish Center sci- is much more complex. Impact depends on condi-
entists. Address correspondence to: Roehlano Briones, E-mail: tions in large-scale systems, for which the effects of
roehlbriones@yahoo.com human activity are poorly understood. Moreover,

Research Evaluation December 2005 0958-2029/05/030000-00 US$08.00  Beech Tree Publishing 2005 1
Natural resources management

adoption of research recommendations depends on


policy choices, set by the state under the influence of
socio-cultural and political factors. Predicting re- Impact assessment for farm
search influence and the impact of research is a dif- commodity research entails an
ficult and highly uncertain affair. estimate of potential on-farm benefit,
In practice, NRM research is evaluated or priori-
tized based on direct subjective approaches, such as measured by some indicator, for
scoring (Kelly et al, 1995; Randolph et al, 2001). example, higher yields (consistent with
While subjective approaches have their place, it is
desirable to integrate NRM into the wider ambit of
lower per unit costs)
economic analysis. Reducing impacts on production
and consumption to a common metric of economic
value makes the choice issue more transparent. Fur-
thermore, the evaluation exercise can avail of a wide
body of evaluation techniques that extend conven- farmers are largely independent. However, natural
tional economic surplus analysis, such as incorporat- resource systems are common pool resources for
ing modifiers for uncertainty, non-market economic which subdivision into individual parcels is infeasi-
values, and the like. ble or uneconomical. Common examples are wild
The main contribution of this study is to demon- fish stocks and many upland forests. Harvesting de-
strate that economic surplus analysis can be used for cisions are therefore interdependent; however, this
ex ante evaluation of NRM research. The critical interdependence is ignored by individual harvesters,
ingredient is an articulation of the impact pathway leading to resource degradation (Ostrom et al, 1994).
for NRM research, which exploits an analogy from NRM aims to regulate extraction to maintain the
the impact pathway for farm commodity research. sustainability of harvesting activities.1
The pathway suggests a procedure for eliciting ex- For farm commodity research, the impact path-
pert opinion regarding the likely supply shifts result- way is relatively straightforward: research generates
ing from research and application. These shifts are a specific innovation, such as a germplasm, a new
incorporated into a supply–demand model, which form of input, a new farm practice, and so on. The
computes the welfare impact (a generalized version innovation is then adopted by farmers (which may
of the economic surplus measure). Combined with be accompanied by local modifications by adopters;
an estimate of the required R&D investments, one these modification may themselves be the subject of
can then calculate benefit–cost ratios as an indicator further R&D.) Benefit from adoption most often
of ex ante economic impact. takes the form of improved long-term productivity.2
The method is applied to impact assessment for (Other types of benefits include higher price, due to
the WorldFish Center, an international organization better product quality, or reduced variability of
for research on aquatic resources in developing yield.) The process of adoption is a combination of
countries, and a member of the Consultative Group natural diffusion, as farmers copy one another or
on International Agricultural Research (CGIAR). share information, and deliberate dissemination
Results are presented and some implications for re- through the extension and farm support system.
search and for research planning are discussed. Impact assessment for farm commodity research
therefore entails an estimate of potential on-farm
benefit, measured by some indicator, for example,
Framework higher yields (consistent with lower per unit costs).
This is followed by an estimate of the following:
Impact pathways
• The adoption process over a particular extrapola-
Impact pathway analysis identifies causal links by tion domain;
which research achieves its intended benefits. • The average on-farm benefit upon adoption, that
Elaborating these links compels researchers to iden- is, with an adjustment for yield gap, which is the
tify key stages from research to impact, the ex- shortfall between average yield and yield under
pected effects at each juncture, the indicators for best practice (Dey et al, 2000).
measurement, and the processes securing the links
(Springer-Heinze et al, 2003). In the following an For economic surplus analysis, these estimates are
impact pathway analysis is presented for farm used to calculate supply shifts; simulation analysis
commodity and NRM research. using a supply–demand model then calculates gross
The two categories of research are distinguished benefits from the research–application continuum.
mainly by the type of resource system being studied. Given a reasonable estimate of the required invest-
Farm commodities are produced in divisible sys- ment in research and application, one can then calcu-
tems, for example, farms or ponds, for which rights late the net economic impact of farm commodity
to use are defined and enforced at an individual research.
level. Accordingly, allocation choices of individual Meanwhile for NRM research, the pathway to

2 Research Evaluation December 2005


Natural resources management

impact takes the route of resource management. A improves the quality of NRM decisions, which leads
major constraint to resource management is the lack to an increase in resource productivity. In both
of reliable information. Often the status of a particu- cases, the results of applying research become feed-
lar natural stock or ecosystem is uncertain. Further- back for later iterations of the research cycle (signi-
more, the causal relations may also be vague or fied by the upward arrow in Figure 1).
weakly established, whether in terms of the impact Based on this pathway analogy, two measures
of human activity, or the likely outcomes of various need to be estimated for NRM research: first is the
management options. Finally, the long-term eco- potential yield improvement under a best-practice
nomic importance of maintaining resource sustain- scenario (that is, proper or ideal application of NRM
ability may also be poorly understood, undermining research); second is the extent to which ideal appli-
the argument for immediate and decisive action, par- cation of NRM research is adopted over time. In this
ticularly when protecting the resource may imply study, management performance is subsumed within
serious economic dislocation. Both biological and the estimate of adoption. For example, if the adop-
social science research play a vital role in manage- tion of NRM research is 80%, but quality of research
ment support, by assessing the status and values of application is only 50% of the ideal (notionally
the resources, and by identifying the likely impacts speaking), then the adoption figure is adjusted down
of human activity, management actions, and institu- to 40%. This technique automatically incorporates
tional arrangements. the ‘management performance gap’, an indicator that
The simplified impact pathway for both farm parallels the ‘yield gap’ in the adoption of farm
commodity and NRM research is drawn in Figure 1. commodity research.
Farm commodity research generates technologies
and recommendations for farmers; farmers adopt Indicators and quantification procedure
recommendations and increase the farm productiv-
ity. Similarly, NRM research produces recommenda- The column at the right-hand side of Figure 1 sug-
tions, or an evaluation of management options; this gests indicators, at critical stages in the pathway, to

Research

Potential production gain per


Technology unit
recommendation
evaluation

Production gain per unit


Dissemination- Adoption rate (A10,Amax)
adoption
R&D cost
Improved management

Increase in supply

Change in economic surplus

Market Net economic benefit

Impact

Figure 1. Simplified impact pathway for farm commodity and NRM research
Note: Expert judgment is applied to estimate production gain per unit and to
calibrate the parameters of the adoption function (stated in text as
adoption ceiling and adoption in ten years). R&D cost is estimated by out-
put value shares based on literature review. Change in economic surplus
is evaluated using a supply–demand model; this benefit, net of cost, yields
the net economic benefit.

Research Evaluation December 2005 3


Natural resources management

be used for ex ante impact assessment. Given the International research on aquatic NRM
paucity of ex post impact assessment for NRM, es-
timation of these indicators relies on expert judg- The WorldFish Center
ment. Suppose one has defined a particular resource
system for which NRM research impact is to be The WorldFish Center is one of 16 Future Harvest
evaluated, and has obtained benchmark production Centers of the CGIAR. Its mission is to reduce pov-
data for that system. Two scenarios may be consid- erty and hunger by improving fisheries and aquacul-
ered: a ‘business-as-usual’ scenario for harvesting ture. To guide WorldFish in its research planning,
behavior and NRM performance, and a ‘best- the foregoing framework is applied to NRM research
practice’ scenario for research and applications on for aquatic resources in the developing world. The
NRM. units of assessment are the major categories of
Resource experts (preferably practicing biolo- aquatic resource systems; these resource systems are
gists) are asked to estimate production under these further disaggregated into the major regions of the
two scenarios, relative to the benchmark production. poorer areas of the developing world. The definition
The difference in production between the two sce- of units follows the WorldFish Strategic Plan
narios is the potential productivity gain from NRM (ICLARM, 1992). For aquatic resource systems the
research. categories are:
The remaining indicator to be estimated is the
adoption of the best-practice scenario. In farm com- • ‘Lakes’ — including reservoirs, are mainly
modity research, adoption dynamics are often mod- freshwater bodies, whether natural or artificial,
eled on the sigmoid curve (Alston et al, 1995). A used for irrigation, power generation, and house-
similar logistic process is assumed to hold for hold water supply.
NRM research. Let A denote the extent of adoption, • ‘Rivers’ — includes streams and floodplains;
here measured as the percentage of output pro- streams and rivers are flowing waters, while
duced under the best-practice application of NRM floodplains are low-lying areas adjacent to water-
research. Let Amax denote the maximum extent of courses, subject to periodic or near-permanent in-
adoption, or the adoption ceiling. The logistic undation.
model assumes: • ‘Coasts’ — includes estuaries and lagoons, and
critical habitats, such as mangroves. Coastal wa-
A& æA - A ö÷ ters (10 m deep or lower) encompass most fishing
= r ççç max ÷
÷ (1) grounds of small-scale fishers.
A è Amax ÷
ø • ‘Coral reefs’ — continental and island shelves in
tropical oceans, in which reef-building corals are
where r is a constant. That is, the growth of the ex- dominant features.
tent of adoption is a constant multiplied by the pro-
portional difference between the ceiling and current In this study, the developing world is limited to Asia
adoption. Here time may be measured in years, with and Africa, which hosts the bulk of the world’s poor
the beginning year of the evaluation set at zero. De- and undernourished. The regional divisions are:
note adoption at time zero as A0, and let k = r Amax .
Then the time path of A is described by the follow- • East Asia (EA)
ing equation: • South Asia (SA)
• Southeast Asia (SEA)–Island (Indonesia, Malay-
Amax A0 sia, and the Philippines);
A(t ) = (2) • SEA–Mainland (the Mekong countries, including
A0 + ( Amax - A0 )e- kt Burma);
• West Asia and North Africa (WANA);
Once Amax has been estimated, the remaining prob- • Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA).
lem is to parametrize k (or alternatively, r). Sup-
pose an estimate of adoption rate in year 10 is The countries under each region are listed in Table 1.
available. Arbitrarily setting A0 = 0.005 (one-half There are 24 region-resource system combinations
of one percent), the parameter k can be calibrated (= four resource systems × six regions), comprising
as follows: the units of assessment. Data for the resource sys-
tems and regions is partly available from the FAO
é( A - A(10)) A0 ù fisheries statistical databases on capture production.
k = - 0.1 *ln ê max ú (3)
êA(10)( Amax - A0 ) ú
ë û Eliciting expert opinion

where ln denotes the natural logarithm. Estimates of The base year is set at 2001, the most recent year
ceiling adoption and adoption in year 10 can be elic- available during the period of the study. Three ques-
ited from policy experts and socio-economists in the tionnaires were formulated, one each for coast,
field of NRM research.3 inland waters, and coral reefs. Subdivision between

4 Research Evaluation December 2005


Natural resources management

Table 1. Country groupings by region of analysis Table 3. Average annual production growth for inland
capture, by region

East Asia Sub-Saharan Africa (cont.)


China Namibia Production, Average annual growth (%)
Korea, Democratic Republic Niger 1999–2001
Mongolia Nigeria (average 1991–1995 1996–2001
South Asia Rwanda annual, in mt)
Bangladesh Reunion
Bhutan Senegal East Asia 2,243,197 12.6 7.4
India Sierra Leone
Nepal Somalia South Asia 1,960,877 3.0 6.7
Pakistan Sudan Southeast Asia – 461,219 –0.4 –2.6
Sri Lanka Swaziland Island
Southeast Asia – Island Tanzania
Indonesia Togo Southeast Asia – 684,205 2.4 12.4
Malaysia Uganda Mainland
Philippines Western Sahara Sub-Saharan 5,325,738 0.7 1.7
Southeast Asia – Mainland Zambia Africa
Cambodia Zimbabwe
Laos West Asia and North Africa West Asia and 1,303,894 7.4 2.6
Myanmar Algeria North Africa
Thailand Bahrain World 8,665,072 3.9 4.4
Vietnam Egypt
Sub-Saharan Africa Iran Source: FAO (2003)
Angola Iraq
Benin Jordan
Botswana Kuwait
Burkina Faso Lebanon
to 5% above the benchmark, 5% to 10% above the
Burundi Libya benchmark, etc. There are three time horizons: the
Cameroon Morocco short term (years 1 to 5), the medium term (years 6
Central African Republic Qatar to 10), and the long term (years 11 to 20). The re-
Chad Saudi Arabia
Congo, Dem. Rep. Syrian spondents are requested to select their best guess
Congo, Rep. Tunisia about the appropriate interval, for each time horizon,
Côte d'Ivoire United Arab Emirates and for each scenario (business-as-usual and best-
Djibouti Yemen
Equatorial Guinea Oman practice). The production estimates are then appor-
Eritrea Turkey tioned to the regions of analysis using the ratios
found in the benchmark data. Once the average es-
timate is computed for the four fish types, a simple
average of these estimates is applied for the fish
lakes and rivers is omitted in the questionnaires ow- types not elsewhere classified.
ing to absence of benchmark data. The Coasts Ques- The questionnaire for inland waters is formulated
tionnaire is subdivided into the FAO ocean areas. in a similar manner as for coasts, though estimates
For each ocean area, respondents are shown annual are elicited for only one fish type (inland freshwater
benchmark production figures, averaged over the fish). Benchmark production figures (as well as re-
period 1999 to 2001 (Table 2). gional growth rates) are shown in Table 3.
Production is divided into the four major fish The Coral Reefs Questionnaire takes a more
types (demersal fish, pelagic fish, crustaceans, and roundabout approach. First, a literature search was
mollusks). Respondents are presented with percent- conducted to find a regionally available indicator for
age intervals above and below the benchmark figure, the state of coral reefs worldwide. The search yielded
for example, 5% to 10% below the benchmark, 0% the risk category presented in the Reefs at Risk study

Table 2. Average annual production by FAO ocean area and major fish type, in mt (average for 1999–2001)

Ocean area Demersal Pelagic Crustacean Mollusk

East Central Atlantic 447,254 2,583,125 71,779 236,104


Southeast Atlantic 429,938 1,079,737 18,841 8,899
Southwest Atlantic 907,491 165,772 107,416 1,047,849
West Central Atlantic 186,230 861,797 279,138 257,098
East Indian Ocean 757,659 1,402,512 345,308 320,217
West Indian Ocean 1,123,655 1,751,436 341,446 130,634
Mediterranean and Black Sea 279,347 933,532 48,671 162,601
East Central Pacific 100,477 1,159,367 75,184 193,110
Northwest Pacific 6,301,317 6,111,455 2,882,459 3,059,146
Southeast Pacific 571,223 13,041,127 50,531 232,584
West Central Pacific 1,339,206 4,784,713 607,880 552,410
World total 12,443,797 33,874,573 4,828,653 6,200,652

Source: FAO Fishstat (2003)

Research Evaluation December 2005 5


Natural resources management

Table 4. Distribution of world coral reefs by risk status and AsiaFish model (Dey et al, 2004). It is a multi-
region
market equilibrium model of the fish sector, con-
structed for each region under analysis. The follow-
Region Coral reef Present risk status (%) ing provides a concise model description; details are
area (km2) available in Briones (2004). The model consists of
Low Medium High Total equations on supply, demand, exports, and imports.
Middle East 20,000 39 46 15 100
The model data set is constructed along the lines of
Delgado et al (2003), using FAO data. Proportional
Caribbean 20,000 39 32 29 100
supply shifts, used to represent technological change
Atlantic 3,100 13 32 25 70 and the impact of research, are incorporated by the
Indian 36,100 46 29 25 100 formalism of the ‘effective price’ (Alston et al,
Southeast 68,100 18 26 56 100 1995). Changes in economic welfare (a generaliza-
Asia tion of economic surplus) are evaluated using the
Pacific 108,000 59 31 10 100 dual approach, which is a modified version of the
World 304,260 42 31 27 100 formula in Martin and Alston (1994).
A baseline simulation is conducted over a 20-year
Source: Bryant et al (1998)
period. Variables such as income and population are
exogenous to the model; projections on income are
proxied by estimates of average annual GDP growth
(Bryant et al, 1998). The study presents the percent- by region to 2015, prepared by the World Bank
age distribution of reefs in global regions classified as (2004). Population projections are based on UN es-
‘low’, ‘medium’, and ‘high’ risk (Table 4). timates by region (UN, 2004). Supply shifts under
The respondents are asked to regard these catego- the business-as-usual scenario are incorporated into
ries as proxies for extent and severity of reef dam- the baseline simulation. Supply shifts from the best-
age. They are then requested to estimate the practice scenario, modified by the adoption rates, are
percentages of low-, medium-, and high-risk coral incorporated into the counterfactual simulation. The
reefs; as with the other resource systems, the per- measure of research benefit is the welfare impact,
centages are reckoned within an interval, rather than which is the difference in welfare between baseline
an exact number. The estimates are made by region, and counterfactual simulations.
20 years hence, under the business-as-usual and Estimation of cost is however constrained by un-
best-practice scenarios. availability of data on R&D investments by resource
Also elicited is the estimate of coral reef system and region. Instead, the cost of R&D for each
productivity, that is, metric tons of reef-related fish assessment unit is approximated as some predeter-
lost on average for every square kilometer loss of mined percentage of the total value of production
coral reefs. The estimates are made separately for under the counterfactual scenario. For farm com-
the low-, medium-, and high-risk categories, by modity research, a common rule-of-thumb is that 1%
region. These productivity estimates may then be of agricultural GDP needs to be allocated to the ag-
used to convert projections of coral reef status into ricultural research and extension system to reach a
projections for reef-related fish supply by region. typical range of benefits and rates of return to re-
search (MacIntire, 1998; Roseboom, 2004). How-
Computing economic welfare impact ever investment in NRM research and applications
are more difficult to estimate. For coastal and coral
The estimated productivity changes and adoption reef systems, Balmford et al (2004) report an esti-
rates, obtained from using the foregoing methods of mate of US$ 5 to 19 billion annual cost of placing
eliciting expert opinion, are then converted into sup- 20% to 30% of the world’s oceans under marine pro-
ply shifts over time. The supply shifts may then be tected areas. This lies within 5% to 18% of the
incorporated into a baseline supply–demand model. world’s annual value of production. For developed
The model used in this study is patterned after the countries (where productivity increases in the fisher-
ies is more likely), research-management expendi-
tures range from 5% to 30% of the value of the catch
(Arnason, 2000). This is consistent for data from
OECD countries for 1999 (OECD, 2003), except for
The estimated productivity changes a few nations with low investments (Japan, Iceland,
and adoption rates are then converted and Mexico).
These costs are associated with hypothetical man-
into supply shifts over time, which agement regimes comparable to the best-practice
may then be incorporated into a scenario assumed in the expert opinion survey. For
baseline supply–demand model developing countries one may put a more conserva-
tive cost ratio of 5% for coastal and inland aquatic
systems, further adjusted downwards by the esti-
mated adoption rate for NRM research.

6 Research Evaluation December 2005


Natural resources management

Estimates of the cost of coral reef protection estimate. For example, the business-as-usual sce-
would tend towards the high end of management nario should not show progressive improvement
costs. For example, White, Ross, and Flores (2000) over time; resource management may initially have a
report a cost of USD 21,000 for a marine sanctuary negative effect on productivity, but eventually it
in the Philippines, covering one square kilometer must have a positive and nondecreasing effect over
and producing US$ 42,000 of sustainable fisheries time. The average of the estimates for marine cap-
per year. For coral reefs the percentage is therefore ture is shown in Tables 5 and 6.
set at 10%, likewise adjusted by the adoption rate for The expected declines under the baseline scenario
NRM research on coral reefs. are seen to be modest over the first five years.
Meanwhile, within five to ten years, production
trends are expected to deteriorate, by as much as
Results 7.5%. Experts tend to be most optimistic for the East
Indian Ocean, but largely pessimistic over the other
Estimates of resource productivity gains oceans (for example, the Pacific). Finally, in the
long term (within 10 to 20 years), progressive
The expert opinion survey covered 42 respondents. worsening under business-as-usual is evident; the
Most (29) are from WorldFish, due to their familiarity decline compared to the medium term is however
with NRM research in developing countries. The 13 less severe. Overall, for most ocean areas, experts
external respondents are composed of both fishery conjecture a steep drop in annual production relative
biologists and resource managers in both developing to the benchmark.
country and advanced research institutions. To com- Meanwhile, NRM makes a modest contribution
pute supply shifts from the survey results, outliers over the short term (in the order of 5% or less over
were eliminated and several consistency assumptions the benchmark). In a few cases, ideal management is
were imposed, prior to calculating the average seen to cause an immediate decline in production

Table 5. Estimates of business-as-usual production trends, by FAO ocean area and fish type (% above benchmark production)

Ocean area Crustacean Demersal Mollusk Pelagic

A. Years 1 to 5 East Central Atlantic –2.5 –2.5 –2.5 –2.5


Northeastern Atlantic –2.5 –2.5 –2.5 –2.5
Southeastern Atlantic –2.5 –5.0 –1.3 –5.0
Southwestern Atlantic –2.5 –2.5 –2.5 –2.5
West Central Atlantic 0.0 0.0 –2.5 –1.7
East Indian 0.8 –3.8 0.6 –3.8
West Indian –2.5 –5.0 –2.5 –2.5
Mediterranean and Black Sea –2.5 –2.5 –2.5 –2.5
East Central Pacific –2.5 –2.5 –2.5 –2.5
Northwestern Pacific –2.5 –2.5 –2.5 –2.5
Southeastern Pacific –2.5 –3.8 0.6 –2.5
Southwestern Pacific 0.0 –2.5 0.0 –2.5
West Central Pacific 0.0 –3.6 –0.6 –1.1
B. Years 5 to 10 East Central Atlantic –6.3 –6.3 –6.3 –3.8
Northeastern Atlantic –7.5 –7.5 –7.5 –2.5
Southeastern Atlantic –7.5 –7.5 –3.8 –8.8
Southwestern Atlantic –7.5 –5.0 –5.0 –2.5
West Central Atlantic –2.5 –2.5 –7.5 –2.5
East Indian –3.3 –5.6 –1.9 –3.8
West Indian –7.5 –7.5 –5.0 –3.8
Mediterranean and Black Sea –7.5 –7.5 –7.5 –2.5
East Central Pacific –7.5 –7.5 –7.5 –2.5
Northwestern Pacific –3.8 –5.0 –3.8 –2.5
Southeastern Pacific –2.5 –3.1 –3.8 –6.7
Southwestern Pacific –2.5 –5.0 –2.5 –2.5
West Central Pacific –3.3 –7.9 –3.1 –1.8
C. Years 10 to 20 East Central Atlantic –8.8 –8.8 –8.8 –8.8
Northeastern Atlantic –7.5 –7.5 –3.8 –11.3
Southeastern Atlantic –7.5 –7.5 –3.8 –11.3
Southwestern Atlantic –7.5 –7.5 –7.5 –7.5
West Central Atlantic –7.5 –8.8 –7.5 –7.5
East Indian –3.3 –8.8 –7.5 –7.5
West Indian –11.3 –11.3 –5.0 –6.3
Mediterranean and Black Sea –7.5 –7.5 –7.5 –7.5
East Central Pacific –7.5 –7.5 –7.5 –7.5
Northwestern Pacific –3.8 –5.0 –3.8 –5.0
Southeastern Pacific –2.5 –6.3 –3.8 –12.5
Southwestern Pacific –3.8 –7.5 –3.8 –5.0
West Central Pacific –4.0 –14.2 –3.1 –8.3

Source: Authors’ survey

Research Evaluation December 2005 7


Natural resources management

Table 6. Estimates of production trends under the ‘best-practice’ scenario, by FAO ocean area and fish type (% above benchmark
production)

Ocean area Crustacean Demersal Mollusk Pelagic

A. Years 1 to 5 East Central Atlantic 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5


Northeastern Atlantic 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5
Southeastern Atlantic 2.5 –6.2 2.5 –6.2
Southwestern Atlantic 2.5 5 5 2.5
West Central Atlantic –2.5 3.3 8.8 0
East Indian 2.5 3.1 4.4 2.5
West Indian 1.2 2.5 1.2 1.2
Mediterranean and Black Sea 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5
East Central Pacific 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5
Northwestern Pacific 0.8 0.8 0 0.8
Southeastern Pacific 1.7 1.9 0.8 0
Southwestern Pacific 5 2.5 2.5 2.5
West Central Pacific 0.8 –1.0 2.5 1.0
B. Years 5 to 10 East Central Atlantic 13.8 16.3 16.3 20.0
Northeastern Atlantic 2.5 7.5 7.5 15.0
Southeastern Atlantic 2.5 5.0 0.0 11.3
Southwestern Atlantic 2.5 7.5 7.5 15.0
West Central Atlantic –2.5 0.0 7.5 6.3
East Indian 5.0 10.0 5.8 8.8
West Indian 1.3 3.8 3.8 7.5
Mediterranean and Black Sea 2.5 7.5 7.5 15.0
East Central Pacific 2.5 7.5 7.5 15.0
Northwestern Pacific 1.3 3.8 3.8 11.3
Southeastern Pacific 3.3 5.6 4.4 5.0
Southwestern Pacific 5.0 7.5 7.5 8.8
West Central Pacific 1.7 1.7 5.0 4.3
C. Years 11 to 20 East Central Atlantic 28.8 32.5 28.8 40.0
Northeastern Atlantic 7.5 15.0 7.5 30.0
Southeastern Atlantic 7.5 22.5 0.0 30.0
Southwestern Atlantic 7.5 15.0 7.5 30.0
West Central Atlantic 0.0 3.8 7.5 13.8
East Indian 11.3 17.5 7.5 18.8
West Indian 7.5 15.0 7.5 30.0
Mediterranean and Black Sea 7.5 15.0 7.5 30.0
East Central Pacific 7.5 15.0 7.5 30.0
Northwestern Pacific 3.8 7.5 3.8 16.3
Southeastern Pacific 5.0 7.5 4.4 4.2
Southwestern Pacific 11.3 22.5 11.3 18.8
West Central Pacific 5.6 5.0 9.4 10.4

Source: Authors’ survey

(probably as fishing pressure is reduced). In the compared to inland capture. The worst deterioration
medium term the deterioration of production is projected for East Asia, across all periods; the
(expected under the business-as-usual scenario) is mildest is for Sub-Saharan Africa, with the long-
almost completely reversed. The improvement is term production decline of less than 6% relative to
particularly sharp in the case of finfish. Interestingly, the benchmark. This may be attributed to the rela-
crustacean production on average is not expected to tively low levels of exploitation of inland aquatic
be appreciably helped by best-practice management. systems in this region, relative to other regions.
In the long term, ideal management leads to a range Interestingly, Sub-Saharan Africa shows the sec-
of improvement for every ocean area and fish type ond largest impact of resource management in the
(except for mollusks in Southwestern Atlantic). The long run. Compared to marine capture, the impact of
magnitude of the productivity gains is well below management intervention is greater. Some respon-
the shift implied by the global estimate of potential dents explained that measures for increasing produc-
yield in Pauly (1996); the estimates may therefore be tivity, such as stock enhancement, are far more
considered conservative, and probably more realistic feasible for inland fisheries compared to their marine
given the 20-year horizon of the projections and the counterparts. Supply shifters (sans adoption modifi-
ecological lags of stock recovery. ers) use this information, and allocated by a 67%:33%
For inland capture, the expert survey obtained a ratio for lakes and rivers, respectively (ICLARM,
similar pattern for the two scenarios (Table 7). 1992, 1999). The exception is Sub-Saharan Africa,
Overall, the trend deterioration (under business-as- where the ratio is 50%:50% due to the relatively large
usual) is less pronounced compared to the same sce- contribution of the great lakes in southern Africa.
nario for marine capture. Apparently, the degree of The last set of shifters is computed for fisheries
excess fishing pressure and recoverability of fish related to coral reefs. The relevant coral reef regions
stocks seem to offer worse prospects for marine are South Asia, Southeast Asia, Sub-Saharan Africa,

8 Research Evaluation December 2005


Natural resources management

Table 7. Estimates of productivity trends and NRM shifters, inland capture, by scenario, time horizon, and region (% above
benchmark production)

Scenario Business as usual Ideal management

Region 1 to 5 5 to 10 10 to 20 1 to 5 5 to 10 10 to 20

EA –5.0 –10.0 –13.8 4.4 10.6 13.8


SA 0.9 –3.3 –5.8 3.8 10.5 13.8
SEAI 1.3 –3.1 –0.6 4.4 16.3 17.5
SEAM –1.4 –6.1 –10.7 4.3 11.4 13.2
SSA –0.8 –3.3 –5.8 4.2 11.1 17.2
WANA –2.5 –6.7 –7.5 3.5 8.5 11.0

Source: Authors’ survey

and the Middle East. Expert opinion projects a steep tion. Gains are estimated to be very low, over the
decline of the percentage of low-risk reefs within 20 next ten years, for all regions and resource systems.
years (Table 8), accompanied by a surge in the high- In East Asia, owing to the policy environment, adop-
risk category. Meanwhile, ideally management does tion of ideal management is seen to be very low
make a considerable difference, even over a rela- across resource systems.
tively short period of time: a small to nonexistent Despite the low levels of development of institu-
extent of reefs in the high-risk zone are projected, tions and governance in Sub-Saharan Africa, the
while the low-risk category characterizes up to 65% highest potential adoption is projected for this region
of reefs in South Asia and the Middle East. However across all resource systems. It is matched in coral
due to lags in the coral reef recovery, even with ideal reefs and inland capture by Southeast Asia–Island,
management, less than 40% of coral reefs in South- where institutions tend to be better developed and
east Asia are classified under low risk. considerations of sustainability better articulated in
Table 8 also displays expert opinion on the quan- the policy agenda. These figures are used to param-
tity of fish per year produced, directly or indirectly, eterize the logistic adoption function, which acts as
by these reefs per unit area. For relatively pristine the modifier for the NRM shifter under the best-
coral reefs (that is, under ‘low risk’), the highest practice scenario.
productivity is estimated for Southeast Asia.
Impact on economic welfare
Adoption of best-practice management
Applying the above shifters and other exogenous
The average estimate based on expert opinion on the variables to the baseline model, one can compute the
adoption of ideal management is shown in Table 9. economic welfare impact from NRM research and
Experts tend to be very circumspect in their projec- its application. The relatively small production cov-
tions about management practice and policy applica- erage of coral reef systems in East Asia and
mainland Southeast Asia precludes the application
Table 8. Estimates of coral reef risk status in 20 years, under of a price adjustment mechanism, as errors in model
alternative scenarios, in %, and reef productivity,
in mt solution would tend to be large relative to the actual
research impact. For these units, the counterfactual
simulation assumes a production and price that is
South Southeast Sub- Middle unaffected by supply shifts from research and appli-
Asia Asia Saharan East
Africa cation of NRM.

Low risk
Business-as- Table 9. Estimates of adoption rates for best-practice
usual 0.0 7.8 0.0 15.0 management, in 10 years and ceiling, by developing
Best-practice 65.0 36.7 50.0 65.0 region and resource system
Medium risk
Business-as-
Coast Coral Inland capture
usual 20.0 24.0 20.0 46.5
Best-practice 20.0 30.8 40.0 30.0
10 Ceiling 10 Ceiling 10 Ceiling
High risk years years years
Business-as-
usual 80.0 68.2 80.0 38.5
Best-practice 15.0 32.5 10.0 5.0 EA 5.0 10.0 4.3 8.3 6.7 11.7
SA 4.3 15.0 4.0 15.0 7.5 18.8
Productivity SEAI 7.5 20.0 12.6 24.0 12.0 24.0
Low risk 25.8 32.5 18.8 25.8 SEAM 10.6 18.0 7.5 13.8 7.0 19.0
Medium risk 16.7 21.0 12.5 16.7 SSA 10.0 25.0 15.0 30.0 11.0 24.0
High risk 8.3 11.6 5.0 8.3 WANA 7.5 13.8 11.8 18.8 7.5 15.0

Source: Authors’ survey Source: Authors’ survey

Research Evaluation December 2005 9


Natural resources management

The economic welfare impact (under the Benefit to conventional economic techniques of evaluation.
column) and estimated costs are shown in Table 10. This study demonstrates that, on the contrary, NRM
The figures correspond to the net present value over research can be evaluated largely along conventional
a 20-year period, using a discount rate of 5%, a level lines. The key is to articulate the impact pathway of
recommended by Alston et al (1995). Also shown in NRM research, in a manner parallel to farm com-
Table 10 are the relative benefit–cost ratios, which modity research. With this framework, the usual
serve as the basis for ranking the R&D units in terms tools of expert opinion and economic surplus analy-
of net economic impact. sis can be applied for computing measures such as
Results indicate that coastal NRM in SEA–Island, the welfare impact, the cost of R&D, as well as the
SEA–Mainland, SSA, and coral reef NRM in SEA– benefit–cost ratio. The method is applied to inter-
Island generate the greatest gross benefits. However, national research on aquatic resources, in the case of
coral reef systems in Sub-Saharan Africa, South the WorldFish Center. The results indicate that re-
Asia, and mainland Southeast Asia offer the highest search and application of NRM yields the highest
benefit relative to cost. This holds despite the higher net benefits for the smaller aquatic systems, particu-
cost percentage assumed for coral reef systems, and larly for coral reefs. The larger systems (particularly
may therefore be seen as a fairly robust feature in the coasts) are assessed as a lower economic impact
impact ranking. Interestingly, the large coral reef once price adjustments are incorporated into the
system in island Southeast Asia ranks fifth, preceded evaluation of benefits and costs.
by rivers in East Asia. Other inland water systems Further research is needed on achieving greater
complete the top ten places; the first coastal system accuracy in estimating supply shifts and adoption
ranks 11th, for East Asia. Apparently, the larger sys- rates, particularly as the current set of assumptions is
tems are accompanied by lower supply shifts, rela- constrained by the sparseness of data, relevant case
tive to the price adjustment, which together vitiate studies, and related information. This study may be
the role of size in ranking the potential impact of seen as offering a workable method for quantitative
research. economic studies of ex ante impact of NRM
research.

Conclusion
Notes
In recent years, NRM has gained prominence along-
side farm commodities as a area of agricultural re- 1. NRM also acts to regulate externalities from various forms of
resource use, not necessarily confined to harvesting natural
search. However the ex ante impact of NRM stocks. For example, farms may use the waste disposal ser-
research is seldom evaluated, with the literature as- vices of natural systems, or expand production area by con-
sessing this type of research as particularly resistant version of natural systems (for example, mangroves).
Regulation of externality is a critical function of NRM; how-
ever this treats it as a separate quantification problem that
lies outside the scope of this study.
2. Research on innovative farming systems that promote long-
Table 10. Benefit–cost ratio for NRM research, by region– term resource sustainability, such as IPM (integrated pest
resource system management) or IAA (integrated aquaculture-agriculture),
have also been classified under NRM research. While the
ambiguous nature of this research activity is recognized, this
Benefit Cost BCR study classifies them under farm commodity research as the
technologies generated are applied on divisible resource
1 SSA – Coral 157,733 23,075 100.00 systems.
2 SA – Coral 396,959 67,731 85.74 3. Alternatively, one may calculate a discrete-time version of
3 SEAM – Coral 132,935 23,959 81.17 the logistic equation, consistent with the estimate based on
4 EA – Rivers 31,057 11,358 40.00 years. However the continuous time formulation of equation
5 SEAI – Coral 1,313,675 510,756 37.63 (3) is also perfectly acceptable.
6 SEAM – Rivers 85,930 44,304 28.37
7 SA – Rivers 81,517 43,138 27.64
8 EA – Lakes 39,093 23,074 24.78
9 SSA – Lakes 206,078 121,747 24.76 References
10 SSA – Rivers 206,078 121,747 24.76
11 EA – Coast 559,247 349,555 23.40 J Alston, G Norton and P Pardey (1995), Science under Scarcity:
12 SEAI – Rivers 33,440 21,148 23.13 Principles and Practice for Agricultural Research Evaluation
13 SEAI – Coast 1,340,028 880,224 22.27 and Priority Setting (Cornell University Press, Ithaca, USA).
14 SSA – Coast 1,207,402 857,771 20.59 R Arnason (2000), ‘Costs of fisheries management: theoretical
15 SA – Lakes 111,136 87,627 18.55 and practical implications’, 11th Biennial Conference of the In-
16 WANA – Coast 463,866 382,117 17.76 ternational Institute for Fisheries Economics and Trade 2000
17 SEAI – Lakes 51,770 43,053 17.59 Proceedings.
18 SEAM – Lakes 107,363 90,047 17.44 A Balmford, P Gravestock, N Hockley et al (2004), ‘The worldwide
19 SA – Coast 739,313 648,271 16.68 costs of marine protected areas’, Proceedings of the National
20 WANA – Rivers 149,707 137,868 15.89 Academy of Sciences, 101(26), pages 9694–9697.
21 WANA – Lakes 205,008 280,845 10.68 R Briones (2004), ‘Research priorities for the WorldFish Center’,
22 SEAM – Coast 1,312,545 2,010,982 9.55 Final Report submitted to the WorldFish Center, 3 December
23 WANA – Coral 24,574 48,531 7.41 2004.
24 EA – Coral 20,683 226,186 1.34 D Bryant, L Burke, J McManus et al (1998), Reefs at Risk: A Map-
based Indicator of Threats to the World’s Coral Reefs, World
Source: Authors’ calculations Resources Institute (WRI), ICLARM, World Conservation

10 Research Evaluation December 2005


Natural resources management

Monitoring Centre, and United Nations Environment Pro- (editors), Financing Agricultural Research: A Sourcebook (In-
gramme. ternational Service for National Agricultural Research, The
CGIAR (2000), ‘Impact assessment of agricultural research: con- Hague, Netherlands), pages 81–96.
text and state of the art’, ECART, ASARECA, CTA and GTZ Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (2004),
Workshop on impact assessment of agricultural research in The Costs of Managing Fisheries. <http://www1.oecd.org/
Eastern and Central Africa, 16–19 November 1999, Entebbe, publications/e-book/5303011E.PDF> (downloaded January
Uganda. 2004).
C Delgado, N Wada, M Rosegrant et al (2003), Fish to 2020: E Ostrom, R Gardner and J Walker (1994), Rules, Games and
Supply and Demand in Changing Global Markets (International Common-pool
Food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC, USA, and Resources (Westview Press, Boulder, Colorado, USA).
WorldFish Center, Penang, Malaysia). D Pachico (1998), ‘Conceptual framework for natural resource
M Dey, R Briones and M Ahmed (2004), ‘Disaggregated projec- management research and basic methodological issues in im-
tions of fish supply, demand, and trade: baseline model and pact assessment’, paper presented at the international work-
estimation strategy’, forthcoming in Aquaculture Economics shop on ‘Assessing the Impact of Research in Natural
and Management. Resource Management’, 27–29 April, Nairobi, Kenya.
M Dey, A Eknath, L Sifa et al (2000), ‘Performance and nature of D Pauly (1996), ‘One hundred million tonnes of fish, and fisheries
genetically improved farmed tilapia: a bioeconomic analysis’, research’, Fisheries Research, 25(1), pages 25–38.
Aquaculture Economics and Management, 4(1), pages 83–106. P Pingali (2001), Milestones in Impact Assessment Research in
Food and Agriculture Organization (2003), FAO Fishstat, the CGIAR, 1970–1999. With an Annotated Bibliography of
downloaded from: <http://www.fao.org/fi/statist/FISOFT/ Impact Assessment Studies Conducted in the CGIAR, 1970–
FISHPLUS.asp>, January 2004. 1999, prepared by Matthew P Feldmann, Mexico, DF: Stand-
ICLARM (1992), ICLARM’s Strategy for International Research on ing Panel on Impact Assessment, Technical Advisory Commit-
Living Aquatic Resources Management. tee of the Consultative Group on International Agricultural
ICLARM (1999), Aquatic Resources Research in Developing Research.
Countries: Data and Evaluation by Region and Resource Sys- T Randolph, P Kristjanson, S Omamo et al (2001), ‘A framework
tem, Supplement to the ICLARM Strategic Plan 2000–2020, for priority setting in international livestock research’, Research
ICLARM Working Document 4. Evaluation, 10(3), December, pages 142–160.
A-N Izac (1998), ‘Assessing the impact of research in natural J Roseboom (2004), ‘Agricultural research and extension funding
resources management’, Synthesis of an international work- levels required to meet the Anti-Hunger Programme objec-
shop, 27–29 April 1998, International Center for Research in tives’, paper written for the FAO, Rome, downloaded from
Agroforestry, Nairobi, Kenya. <www.fao.org/sd/dim_kn4/docs/kn4_040401a1_en.pdf>, No-
T Kelly, J Ryan and B Patel (1995), ‘Applied participatory priority vember 2004.
setting in international agricultural research: making trade-offs A Springer-Heinze, F Hartwich, J Henderson et al (2003), ‘Impact
transparent and explicit’, Agricultural Systems, 49, pages pathway analysis: an approach to strengthening the impact
177–216. orientation of agricultural research’, Agricultural Systems,
W Martin and J Alston (1994), ‘A dual approach to evaluating 78(1), pages 267–285.
research benefits in the presence of trade distortions’, Ameri- UN (2004), World Urbanization Prospects: The 2003 Revision
can Journal of Agricultural Economics, 76(1), pages 26–35. Population Database, United Nations Population Division,
M Maredia, D Byerlee and J Anderson (2000), ‘Ex post evaluation Economic and Social Affairs Department. <http://esa.un.org/
of economic impacts of agricultural research programs: a tour unup>
of good practice’, paper presented at the workshop on ‘The World Bank (2004), Global Prospects Realizing the Development
Future of Impact Assessment in CGIAR: Needs, Promise of the Doha Agenda, Washington, DC (downloadable
Constraints, and Options’, Standing Panel on Impact Assessment from <www.worldbank.org>).
(SPIA) of the Technical Advisory Committee, 3–5 May, Rome, A White, M Ross and M Flores (2000), ‘Benefits and costs of coral
Italy. reef and wetland management, Olango Island, Philippines’, in
J McIntire (1998), ‘Coping with fiscal stress in developing-country H Cesar (editor), Collected Essays on the Economics of Coral
agricultural research’, in S Tabor, W Janssen and H Bruneau Reefs (CORDIO, Sweden), pages 215–227.

Research Evaluation December 2005 11

You might also like