Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 40

2

GREEN FISCAL REFORM


& POLICY INSTRUMENTS

FISCAL INSTRUMENTS FOR


GREENING THE ECONOMY
green fiscal reform & policy instruments
fiscal instruments
for greening the economy

Copyright © UNITAR, United Nations Institute for Training and Research, 2017, on behalf of
PAGE.

This publication may be reproduced in whole or in part and in any form for educational or non-profit
purposes without special permission from the copyright holder, provided acknowledgement of the
source is made. The PAGE Secretariat would appreciate receiving a copy of any publication that
uses this publication as a source. No use of this publication may be made for resale or for any other
commercial purpose whatsoever without prior permission in writing from the PAGE Secretariat.

Course authors:
Giuliano Montanari, Maya Valcheva, Amrei Horstbrink (UNITAR); Philip Gass (IISD)

Contributors:
Jason Dion (IISD); Sirini Withana (UN Environment); Sarwat Chowdhury, Massimiliano Riva
(UNDP).

Creative Concept:
Arturo Rago

Graphic Design:
Pilar Lagos (UNITAR)

Photo credits
Unless stated otherwise, the photos used in the journal are under a CC license.
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Introduction 5

1 main categories of green fiscal instruments 6

REVENUE COLLECTION 6
REVENUE EXPENDITURE 6
ALTERNATIVE MARKET-BASED MECHANISMS 7

2 taxes, charges and Fees 8

OVERVIEW 8
VARIOUS TYPES OF ENVIRONMENTAL TAXATION 9
USING ENVIRONMENTAL TAXATION TO FOSTER INNOVATION AND GREEN INVESTMENT 13
ENVIRONMENTAL TAX SHIFT 14
ENVIRONMENTAL TAXATION: CHALLENGES AND OPPORTUNITIES 16

3 subsidies and related instruments 18

OVERVIEW 19
SUBSIDIES AND RELATED TOOLS THAT SUPPORT GREEN ECONOMY TRANSITION 19
REFORMING HARMFUL SUBSIDIES 24

4 Alternative economic instruments 28


OVERVIEW 28
TRADABLE PERMITS 28
OFFSETS 30

5 using fiscal instruments in a policy mix 32

6 key learning points 34

references 35
ABBREVIATIONS 39
5

Introduction
A
s noted in Module 1, market failures Lesson 2 outlines how taxes, charges and
occur when environmental or social fees can be used to tackle environmental
functions are not well-reflected in externalities, foster innovation for green
market prices, which results in externalities industries, or encourage green behaviour.
affecting third parties. By using green fiscal
instruments, governments seek to correct Lesson 3 addresses the role of subsidies and
market failures and impose a price on negative subsidy reforms, especially in the context of
externalities and polluting activities to create a the energy sector. Lesson 4 covers fiscal and
change in behaviour toward more sustainable wider market-based instruments that help set
consumption and production (UNESCAP incentives for the private sector.
2012).
After completing the module, participants will
Green fiscal instruments can come in the be able to:
form of environmental taxation, harmful
subsidy reform, or alternative market - List various fiscal instruments to address
mechanisms such as pollution permits. market failures
These instruments can be used to “facilitate - Discuss how environmental taxes and fees
innovation, stimulate green markets or to can effectively support transition to a
phase out environmentally or socially harmful green economy
activities” (GGKP 2015). Domestic public - Outline how subsidy reform can advance
finance, mobilized through fiscal instruments, low-carbon development and improve
can support green economic development. public finance
- Depict market instruments based on
Module 2 looks at how different fiscal tools collaboration between the state and
can be used to change economic incentives private sector
and price signals, with a focus on practical - Provide examples of how green fiscal
examples from key sectors. reform measures can be applied in
practice.
Lesson 1 introduces the key categories of fiscal
instruments at the disposal of policymakers.
1

MAin categories of GREEN


FISCAL instruments
The green fiscal reform toolbox comprises several categories of instruments
that are used to collect revenue, manage expenditure, or mobilize action by
markets – all while advancing sustainability.

The following paragraphs provide a brief overview of three main categories of fiscal
instruments dealt with in this module.1

REVENUE COLLECTION
Instruments for revenue collection include pollution, payers are incentivized to limit
carbon taxes, usage charges, dumping and polluting activities, in order to reduce the
waste management fees, and many more. financial burden associated with this activity.

Environmental taxation targets polluting In contrary, by reducing taxation, e.g. by


industries, inefficient use of natural granting a tax rebate, on environmentally
resources, or environmentally harmful friendly practices and products, market
consumption patterns. The rationale is actors are encouraged to pursue sustainable
simple: By placing an economic cost on business and household behaviour.

REVENUE EXPENDITURE
Expenditure instruments include direct improvements. Importantly, expenditure
and indirect subsidies, grants, low-interest instruments provide fiscal support for the
loans, sustainable public procurement, green transition and help leverage private
public-private partnerships, etc. They investment. Thus, they help mobilize
can be tied closely to revenue collection domestic public and private resources for
if the funds collected through taxation investment in sustainable development in
are directed to support green industries, line with 2030 Development agenda.
research and development, or efficiency

1 Further reading on reforms and specific tools: http://www.greengrowthknowledge.org/sites/default/


files/Withana_Overcoming_obstacles_to_green_fiscal_reform.pdf, http://www.e-elgar.com/shop/
environmental-taxation-and-green-fiscal-reform, http://www.greenfiscalpolicy.org/, http://www.
unep.org/greeneconomy/Portals/88/documents/news/Issue%20Briefs/fiscal%20policy%20brief_
EN_final.pdf, http://www.greengrowthknowledge.org/theme/fiscal-instruments
7

ALTERNATIVE MARKET-BASED
MECHANISMS
There are different market approaches an economic incentive for companies to
that states can use to influence the private become cleaner and sell excess permits for
sector. economic gain.

For example, policy makers can set a scheme These can also take the form of deposit and
that allows for permits that represent a refund schemes aimed at waste avoidance.
unit of pollution or emissions, to be traded Payments for ecosystem services also
between market actors. incentivize sustainable practices my market
actors.
Each permit allows for polluting activity
to take place, however, the economic Each of the following lessons deal in greater
costs associated with pollution creates details with these categories.
2

taxes, charges and fees


One of the most fundamental ways to discourage polluting activity is to
raise its cost. Revenue collecting instruments do just that and are thus an
application of the ‘polluter pays’ principle.

Overview
Environmental taxation creates enabling Driving forces behind the political motivation
conditions to increase efficiency in the for environmental tax reform include:
economy by encouraging green innovation
and investment, while placing increased cost - Desire for stronger environmental
on polluting activities (Peters 2012). outcomes;
- Possibility to generate new government
The collected revenue can be allocated to the revenues;
general budget or directed to finance green - Increasing recognition that pricing
initiatives or lower taxation in other areas, polluting sources is more effective than
such as personal or business tax reductions. regulatory approaches;
- Possibility for increasing the
The idea of environmental taxation is not competitiveness of the economy, by
new – liberal economists and environmentalist redirecting taxes from labour and income
have been debating over its use for decades. (Heine, Norregaard and Parry 2012).
Sweden has made use of environmental
taxation and other economic instruments for There is also the motivation inherent in
environmental policy since the 1970s (Nordic meeting international obligations on the
Council of Ministers 2006). environment, such as commitments through
the United Nations Framework Convention
Since the 1990s environmental tax reform has on Climate Change (UNFCCC) or the
spread to other Nordic countries, as well as SDGs.
across much of Europe.

In more recent years, developing countries, This lesson outlines lists various types of
such as China, Vietnam, Cambodia, South tax-related instruments (2.2), describes how
Africa, Thailand, and Tunisia, are taking they contribute to innovation and green
increasing lead in applying environmental investment (2.3), and introduces the so-called
taxes (Heine, Norregaard and Parry 2012). environmental tax shift (2.4). Furthermore,
After the 2008 economic crisis, countries criticisms and responses related to
looked at green taxes with renewed interest, environmental taxes are discussed portrayed
due to the need to raise additional public (2.5).
resources.
9

ETS implemented or scheduled


for implementation
Carbon Tax implemented or
scheduled for implementation
ETS or Carbon Tax under
consideration

Carbon Tax implemented


or scheduled, ETS under
consideration
ETS and Carbon Tax
implemented or scheduled

FIG 1: Implementation of and plans for carbon taxation world-wide in 2015.3

Various types of environmental taxation

With ‘polluter pays’ as an underlying principle, more fuel efficient vehicles, use public or
different types of environmental taxation active transportation.
take a different approach to how polluters
pay for inflicted externalities. The following Consequently, taxes can help drive innovation,
paragraphs outline different taxation tools and as consumers and producers would be drawn
how they are implemented to collect revenue. toward least-costly options. Taxes also create
transparency as they are based on clear rules
TAXES as to what is taxed and when, who/what is
exempt, and what is the cost per unit of
Environmental taxes are a mechanism that pollution generated (OECD 2011). 2
gives consumers and business a “least-cost
way to reduce environmental damage” As Figure 1 demonstrates a number of
(OECD 2011). countries have implemented carbon taxes
to account for the environmental damage
That is to say, if a tax is imposed on a of carbon emissions. Other countries have
particular good, e.g. petrol and diesel, opted for emission trading systems (ETS) or a
consumers have the ability to choose not combination between taxation and ETS (ETS
to consume that good and decide to use will be tackled in lesson 4 of this module).
alternate, less costly options, e.g. purchase

2 For more information read: http://www.oecd.org/env/tools-evaluation/48164926.pdf; https://www.cbd.int/


financial/fiscalenviron/g-fiscaltaxes.pdf
3 Retrieved from the Carbon Pricing Leadership.
10

country and tax period evaluated impact

Finland 1990-2005 CO2 emissions 7 % lower than would have otherwise been.
Energy & carbon tax *A shift from carbon tax to output tax on electricity in 1997 may
have lessened impact.

Norway 1991-2007 21 % reduction in CO2 from power plants by 1995


Carbon & sulphur 14 % reduction in CO2 in 1990s, 2 % attributed to CO2 tax
dioxide taxes 12 % reduction in CO2 emissions per unit of GDP

Denmark 1992 6% CO2 emission reduction in affected sectors


Energy & carbon tax 20 % economic growth up between 1988 and 1997
5 % reduction in emission in one year as tax increased
23 % reduction in CO2 from business as usual in the 90s
26% increase in energy efficiency
*Subsidy for renewables may have accounted emissions reductions
as well

Sweden 1990-2007 0.5 million tonnes emission reduction per annum


Energy & carbon taxes 20% CO2 reduction from business as usual (baseline 1990)

The Netherlands 1999-2007 Emissions 3.5 % lower than would have otherwise been
Energy tax *Low tax rates may have limited impact
Germany 1999-2005 CO2 reduced by 15 % between 1990 and 1999 and 1 % between
Environmental tax reform, 1999 and 2005
taxes on transport, fuels & CO2 emissions 2-3 % lower than would have been
electricity *German re-unification an important factor in reductions

UK 2001-2010 2% CO2 emissions reduction in 2002 and 2.25% in 2003


Industrial energy tax Savings of 16.5 million tonnes of carbon by 2005
2.9 % reduction in UK energy demand estimated by 2010

TABLE 1: The impact of energy and carbon-based taxes in Europe up to 2009. Extracted from Green Fiscal Commission, 2009b:3

Depending on their design and However, their impact can be lessened if


implementation, environmental taxes can they include exemptions or risk mitigation
have varied impact not only on the state of measures. Table 1 gives a snapshot of some
the environment, but also on economic and of the results from energy and carbon-
social development, e.g. influence over GDP, based taxes implemented in some European
jobs creation, etc. countries between 1990 and 2009.
11

REFLECTION POINT
Has your country implemented any types of environmental taxes? Can you think of any
environmental challenges that can be addressed in this way?

If revenues are reinvested into green or the level of environmental damage (is
transition, positive environmental and social revenue needed for clean-up and restoration
outcomes can be amplified. of natural capital?).

A number of factors can influence the way Depending on the circumstances of specific
policy-makers decide to utilize revenue, such countries or regions, trade-offs between
as: concerns of stakeholder groups (e.g. are policy objectives may arise.
the poor negatively affected by the taxation?),
the state of the economy (e.g. are there Module 3 of this course will deal in
nascent green industries that need support?), greater detail with challenges related to
implementation of green taxes (see module 3).

CHARGES AND FEES

Charges and fees are payments for the use Video 1 looks at the benefits and controversies
of goods or services. They can be applied on related to the London Congestion Charge 10
quantity or content of pollutants released, use years after its implementation (see Box 1).
of specific resource, the exercise of polluting
activity, or a mixture of these (EPA 2016).

A major difference between taxes and


charges/fees lies in the use of the revenue. video
Contrary to the various possible uses of tax
revenues, charges and fees most often flow TEN YEARS ON: HAS LONDON’S CONGESTION
back to the programme or initiative, through CHARGE WORKED?
which they were imposed, to target the
environmental problem at hand or to cover
the cost of the good or service provided
(European Environment Agency 2000,
Sustainable Prosperity 2015).

WATCH THE VIDEO


12

Enforcement is a necessary ingredient of any A consumer or firm would still purchase


form of taxation. For example, the London the good or service at full price, thus the
Congestion Charge includes a sophisticated producer receives market value for their
enforcement mechanism including photo product or service. However, as the taxes
tracking of vehicles and stringent penalties for paid to the state are reduced or removed,
non-compliance (Transport for London n.d.). the net costs for production are reduced.

Charges and fees can be effective on As green products may be costlier to


changing individual behavior and consumer’s produce compared to conventional products,
preferences. For example, a fee on plastic the reduced tax costs levels the playing field
bags was introduced in China in 2008. A between green and conventional products
year later, environmental awareness had and services. The tax rebate can further drive
increased, and the country was using 50% prices of green goods or services down, thus
fewer plastic bags, generating 200 tonnes of making them more affordable for consumers,
garbage reduction and saving of roughly 40 and contributing to changing consumers’
billion a year (Jierui 2009). preferences.

There can also be cases where existing tax


TAX CREDITS credits may need to be reformed if they
contribute to unsustainable activities, e.g. tax
Tax credits (also known as tax rebates) credits for fossil fuel producers.
incentivize green behaviour by reducing the
net tax paid for a specific good or service
that is environmentally friendly.

Foregoing government Turkey offers reduced licence fees for entities for licences to
revenue construct renewable energy facilities

Municipalities in India have established a rebate in the property tax


Tax incentives
for users of solar water heaters

Accelerated In Mexico, investors in green infrastructure have benefitted from


depreciation faster rate of depreciation of the values of eligible fixed assets,
which reduces investor’s taxable income

Fig. 2: Examples of taxable rebates/credits (Gaupp 2007) (Mexico 2007) (India 2010)
13

Using environmental taxation to foster


innovation and green investment

Using taxes to price externalities can help - Lack of finance: Revenue generated
tackle several policy challenges related to through taxation can directly (through loans,
fostering innovation and green investment, as grants, etc.) or indirectly (through reduction
listed below: in labour or corporate tax) increase available
resources for firms to invest in innovation.
- Insufficient demand for green Increased public funds can also leverage
innovation: Higher prices would increase private investment through public-private
environmental awareness of consumers partnerships or subsidies. Increasing the
and producers and create a demand cost of polluting activities makes non-
for more cost-efficient and sustainable polluting activities more attractive for
options. investment as they become more cost-
competitive.
- Revert bias to incumbent technology:
The need to realize economic savings The extent of influence depends on factors such
would drive many companies to adopt as the taxation rate, implemented exemptions
efficiency improvements in their and flanking policy measures, such as support for
production methods and operations R&D.
– hence drive the switch from older
and inefficient technologies to new Examples of environmental taxation spurring
and innovative solutions. Governments innovation and competitiveness are manifold
can speed this process by reinvesting (Boxes 3 and 4) (OECD 2010).
revenues from green taxation into tax
breaks and credits to support companies
that produce green products, conduct
R&D, or adopt new and cleaner
technologies.

BOX 3:
CHINA’S RISE TO A GLOBAL INNOVATION HUB
Thanks in part to resolute public spending on between 2005-2013 to reach approximately 70
R&D, China has become one of the most dynamic billion USD (OECD 2016). Economic incentives
countries in terms of innovation in recent years. for R&D are offered in the form of income tax
In 2013, the country filed a total of 22184 patent deductions and reductions in entreprise income
applications under the Patent Cooperation Treaty tax rates. For example, eligible R&D expenditures,
(PCT), trailing only Japan (at ca. 42.000) and the including resources and environmental technology,
United States (at ca. 57.000). While the national enjoy a 150% super deduction on the tax bill.
Pollution Levy System discourages use of a wide
range of substances, the Chinese government SOURCE: Deloitte 2014
has more than tripled public expenditure on R&D
14

Environmental tax shift


As previously mentioned, states can combine Ideally, the higher costs of resource use
environmental taxation with a comprehensive will stimulate business investment into
tax shift of their fiscal systems.4 green technologies and eco-efficiency, as
companies will look for ways to reduce their
In essence, the shift entails that “taxes on the tax burden. On the other hand, decreased
things that are valued by society, like jobs, taxation on labour might incentivize
incomes and profits, are reduced and the companies to create new jobs. A reform in
lost revenue is replaced by taxes on things the tax shift would also lead to higher prices
society does not like, such as pollution and for goods that are resource intensive, while
environmental degradation” (Green Fiscal favoring those that are labour-intensive, thus
Commission 2009a).5 guiding consumers towards environmentally
and socially friendly products.
This basic principle is shown in figure 3.
The carbon tax example from British
It is important to note that the tax shift may Columbia below shows how burden-shifting
remain revenue-neutral in order to avoid can lead to triple bottom benefits for
popular concerns of increased taxation. sustainable development.

TAX BURDEN

INCOME

DETRACTS FROM SUPPORTS


GREEN ECONOMY GREEN ECONOMY

POLLUTION

REVENUE

Fig. 3: Environmental tax shift

4 Some sources use the term ‘green tax shift’ while the concept remains the same.
5
Further reading: http://www.greenfiscalcommission.org.uk/images/uploads/GFC_FinalReport.pdf;
http://www.greenfiscalcommission.org.uk/images/uploads/gfcBriefing7_PDF_isbn_v8.pdf;
http://www.greenfiscalcommission.org.uk/images/uploads/GFC_BRIEFING_2_FINAL.pdf;
http://unstats.un.org/unsd/envaccounting/londongroup/meeting14/LG14_18a.pdf;
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2013/wp13163.pdf
15

REFLECTION POINT
Can you think of a scenario in your country where there is potential for tax shifting, i.e.
reducing cost of something positive by raising it on something negative?

BOX 4:
REVENUE-NEUTRAL TAX SHIFT IN BRITISH COLUMBIA

In 2008 the Canadian Province of British Columbia legislated its carbon tax on the purchase or use of fossil
fuels. The tax was considered revenue neutral, as increased taxes in fossil fuels are returned in lower personal and
corporate taxes. When it was first introduced, the tax was set at CA $10 per ton with a mandate to increase by
CA $5 annually. In 2012 the price was set at CA$30 and has been fixed at that price since. The Government
of British Columbia estimates up to three million tons of CO2e reduction by 2020 under the carbon tax. The
carbon tax in British Columbia resulted in triple bottom line benefits, including:

- Improved competitiveness of the economy and mobilized capital from energy efficiency gains;
- Reduced fuel use (down 16% between 2008-2013), hence reduced emissions (projected 3 million tonnes
reduced annually by 2020); and,
- Reduced income tax rates (almost CAD$ 1 billion in cuts since inception).

SOURCE: (BC Ministry of Finance, 2015a, 2015b) (Elgie and Lipsey 2015) (David Suzuki Foundation et. al. n.d.)
(Deloitte 2014).
16

Environmental taxation: Challenges and opportunities


Historically environmental taxation has effective), fiscal incentives for imposing
faced (and continues to face) a number of environmental taxation might indeed be
criticisms. Some of the main ones, along undermined.
with some responses, are listed below (Green
Fiscal Commission 2009a): This scenario, can be mitigated by
progressively increasing the level of the tax
As we saw in Module 1, tensions and trade- over time (e.g. carbon tax in B.C., Canada),
offs between fiscal and environmental taxation expanding the tax base, or looking at savings
instruments might arise depending on the that may be achieved elsewhere, for example
specific objective and the national context of in health care costs due to less pollution-
each state. related illness incidence. Even if the demand
for the good or service declines, a healthy
If revenue from the tax diminishes over budgetary balance can be maintained.6
time (which should be the case if taxes are

Environmental taxation does not generate a stable Resource mobilization is a secondary objective of
revenue stream (or the stream is small) and environmental taxation. In fact, taxpayers pay the
should only be used as a way to raise funds for x cost of not pricing negative externalities in other
environmental improvement. ways, e.g. via increased health costs.

Green taxes are regarded by taxpayers as Environmental taxation can be revenue-neutral


additional taxes, due to mistrust that
governments will reduce already existing taxes.
x (see Box 4).

Insufficient, pollution practices should not be


Industry is concerned about loss of
subsidized in general but competitiveness
competitivness due to additional green taxes.
x concerns can be addresed, inter alia, via
compensatory measures, phased, implementation
or tax breaks to eligible firms to aid transition.

Environmental taxes reinforce poverty, e.g. rises in There are means to make the system more
energy prices, due to taxation, will be felt equitable, for example through exemptions for
significantly by low-income households. x low-income or subsidies for more energy efficient
products.

6 For further reading:


http://www.oecd.org/env/tools-evaluation/48164926.pdf
http://www.ieep.eu/assets/1110/Background_paper_on_EFS_in_the_7th_EAP.pdf
http://www.oecd.org/environment/tools-evaluation/48178034.pdf
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12180.pdf
17

In addition, it is important to note that, even The escalator was cancelled after severe
if the taxed activity remains stable, inflation protests in response to an accompanying
may significantly diminish the real value spike in oil prices in 2000.
of per unit taxes over time (inflation based
devaluation) (Schlegelmilch and Joas 2015). Depending on the design of the instrument,
taxation can become a win-win situation
In order to avoid frequent legislative changes, from environmental, fiscal, and social
two options are available to policymakers to standpoint.
anticipate revenue devaluation.
As noted previously, an environmental tax
By design, one may choose to automatically can generate a revenue-neutral outcome and
link the tax rate to annual changes in price does not have to become a burden for either
levels or build in pre-defined increase of the consumers or businesses.
tax from the outset.
Funds generated from taxes can be pooled
Automatic adjustments bear the risk, into the general budget and distributed back
however, to stir political unrest when into the system to benefit taxpayers, the
tax increases are perceived as untimely industry and the low-income households.
depending on economic circumstances.
Further ways to overcome and address the
The UK government introduced the “Fuel criticisms listed above will be examined in
Duty Escalator” in 1993 which foresaw greater detail in Modules 3 and 4.
annual increases in the range of 3-6 percent
(Figure 4).

40,000 0.8
tax rate for unleaded petrol [in EUR/liter]

35,000 0.7

30,000 0.6
tax revenue [in million EUR]

25,000 0.5

20,000 0.4

15,000 0.3

10,000 0.2

5,000 0.1

0 0.0
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Fig. 4: Tax revenue and tax rate for UK fuel duty (Schlegelmilch and Joas 2015)
3

Subsidies and related


instruments
Making polluters pay is not the only approach in the toolbox of fiscal
policymakers. Green fiscal reform may also encourage positive change by
rewarding firms and individuals for sustainable consumption and production
practices.This is where subsidies come into play.

Overview
Subsidies, feed-in tariffs, payment for application of existing cleaner and resource-
ecosystem services, and sustainable public efficient production methods.
procurement are some of the instruments
that governments can use to absorb a This lesson focuses on the different
portion of the cost of economic activity and types of subsidies and related tools (3.2),
render a given sector, product or service illustrates how inefficient subsidies can be
more competitive. Subsidies and related reformed (3.3) and highlights challenges
instruments play a key role in stimulating and opportunities in applying subsidy reform
innovation and research, and enabling the (3.4).

Subsidies and related tools that support green transition

A subsidy is a financial contribution by a having the government absorb a share of the


government, or agent of a government, that supply cost.
confers a benefit on its recipients.7
These can come in the form of direct
In order to know how and where to apply a payments (examined below), tax concessions
expenditure instruments, it is important to (which we reviewed in lesson 2), in-kind
differentiate types of subsidies and other support (e.g. government building roads and
available tools.8 other infrastructure), credit subsidies (public
loans or guarantees for loans), and public
Subsidies are used as a way to increase procurement (agreement to purchase a
competitiveness of a product or service, by specific product from a producer). 9

7 Definition derived from the WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures.
8
Application and viability of the tools described in this section also depend on regulations from international
agreements or bodies such as the World Trade Organization (WTO). For further information please see (IISD and
9
UNEP 2014).
These and other types of subsidies are defined in more detail by the IISD Global
Subsidies Initiative Subsidy Primer, which is useful further reading (Steenblik 2006).
19

Definitions for the term ‘subsidy’ may vary. Subsidies can also be positive or negative,
One way to distinguish between subsidies depending on the nature of externalities –
is to identify those that appear ‘on budget’ desirable or harmful– that they entail.
and those that are ‘off budget’ (European
Environment Agency 2006). 10 An example of a positive subsidy is grants to
companies to implement energy efficiency
On-budget subsidies are transfers or public improvements, which create positive
loans given directly to companies, individuals externalities due to the reduction of energy
or institutions, such as research institutes, use and related natural resources.
and appear on national balance sheets as
government expenditure. Negative subsidies – for example tax
exemption to coal power plants, create
Off-budget subsidies typically do not negative externalities (see also Box 1 from
appear on national accounts as government Module 1).
expenditure. They may include tax
exemptions, credits, deferrals, rebates and Subsidies can effectively support green
other forms of preferential tax treatment. development, however they can also be used
to promote inefficient and polluting activities.
They also may include market access In the context of green economy, subsidies
restrictions, regulatory support mechanisms can be used to support green activities, clean
such as feed-in tariffs, border measures and energy, sustainable products, etc.
access to natural resources.
Furthermore, reforming harmful subsidies,
Quantifying off-budget subsidies is complex, e.g. for fossil fuels, can prevent market
in some cases impossible. It often requires distortions and discourage waste generation,
that the benefit be calculated on the basis of pollution, and inefficient use of resources
differential treatment between competing (IMF 2013).
subsidized items or sectors.

REFLECTION POINT
Can you name any subsidy instruments in your country? Are they having positive or negative
effect on the environment?

10
In addition, there are ‘back door’ expenditures as well. This category is rarely used, however. ‘Back door’
expenditures are financed by taxes or levies that are in the budget, but that are authorized by
substantive laws outside the budget process. The main forms of these expenditures are entitlements (financial
obligations) and tax reliefs (Kraan 2004).
20

DIRECT PAYMENTS
Subsidies through direct investments can take - Compensation payments related to
many forms, including (IISD 2015a): losses to suppliers, perhaps in early
commercialization phase of a product.
- Time-limited payment at the beginning
of a project or initiative, and usually Direct payments and tax credits are similar in
in relation to a specific investment or that both effectively represent an expenditure
activity related to green transition; on the state; the latter can be understood as a
- Schemes for producers to receive a lost or foregone income.
payment per unit of production, or as a
way to compensate for any difference The video below gives an example of a project
between target price and the actual that received direct funding by the Green
market value; Fund of South Africa. 11
- Vouchers for consumers for eligible goods
and services;

video 1
The Green Fund, established by South
FARMING THE WILD - WILDLANDS
Africa in 2011, finances public and
CONSERVATION TRUST (ENVIRONMENTZA)
private green initiatives by providing
grants and loans in programs geared
toward renewable energy, waste
management, bus rapid transit, biofuels,
energy efficiency, and demand side
management

SOURCE: GGBP 2014.

WATCH THE VIDEO

FEED-IN-TARIFFS
Feed-in-tariffs (FiTs) are a package of The producers are interested in maximizing
regulatory and economic incentive policies, output and efficiency of production as
where suppliers or investors are paid through this would further increase their return on
a tariff by the government for investment in investment (UNEP 2012a).
and generation of renewable energy (see Box
5 for example). Energy producers are typically granted access
to the energy grid and paid based on the energy
The feed-in tariff is fixed, i.e. it is not open to supplied.
market competition, and is often delivered
under a long-term contract. Typically, to qualify for a FiT contract,
generators need to be able to build and connect
Thus, FiTs encourage investment by creating their power plant to the grid before they are
a guaranteed competitive return for the able to get payments.
production of renewable energy.
21

BOX 5:
MAURITIUS’ EXPERIENCE WITH
FEED-IN-TARIFFS
The secure and stable market for renewable As an island state, Mauritius predominantly imports
energy stimulates job creation, reduces coal and oil for energy generation. The transformative
uncertainties related to access and agenda Maurice Île Durable (MID, Sustainable Island
interconnection to energy grids, enhances Mauritius), in place since 2008, aims at achieving
market access, and encourages technological partial energy autonomy by increasing the share
advancements (NREL 2010). of electricity from renewable energy, as well as the
efficiency of the grid. The national feed-in-tariff is
The design of FiTs can be a complex task, geared towards small and household-level producers
as it needs to take into account a variety (50 kW maximum generation per contract). Notably,
of national market conditions, policy households and businesses are required to use
considerations and constraints, such as: generated energy for on-site consumption before
investor security, grid stability, policy cost, selling any excess to the grid. While this policy may
price fluctuations and many more (UNEP be less profitable for generators, it encourages lower
2012a). consumption at household level and helps raise
awareness. The cost of the FiT is covered by the MID
fund which is financed through carbon tax revenues.
The policy has seen strong support and the initial total
cap of 2 MW had to be raised several times to reach 5
MW.

SOURCE: Heinrich Böll Stiftung et al. 2013.

11
For its first phase 2011 and 2013, the Green Fund allocated to green projects a total of 245
million rands (approx. 15 million USD). The fund has grown to 1.1 billion rands (approx. 62 million
USD) due to its success and overwhelming demand.
22

PAYMENT FOR ECOSYSTEM


SERVICES (PES)
PES is a mechanism that puts a price on or environmental good and receives
services provided by the ecosystem, such compensation for the benefits created or
as food production, air, water resources, maintained. Set by the state, the payments
recreation. It covers beneficial activities are usually funded through environmental
such as carbon sequestration, watershed taxation and administered by a third party,
protection, biodiversity benefits, and e.g. a non-government organization, that
landscape beautification. performs independent verification of a
supplier’s, e.g. a landowner’s actions and
As a consequence, PES puts a cost their impact on the natural resource. (UNEP
to the potential loss of these services. 2008, DFID 2013) (Box 6).
These schemes aim to influence land and
natural resource use decisions by enabling PES promotes a change in economic
landholders to capture more of the value of motivation of private agents through
these environmental services than they would compensation.
have done in the absence of the scheme
(Barbier 2010). A landowner would not drain a wetland
area for agricultural purposes, if he/she is
PES works by providing a payment to the compensated to preserve it in the same
suppliers of the ecosystem service. amount, as the profit form the agricultural
The supplier (i.e. landowners) holds the practice.
property right to the natural capital

BOX 6:
THE N’HAMBITA COMMUNITY CARBON PROJECT, MOZAMBIQUE

Initiated in 2003, the project pays 1,000 intercropping food crops, planting native
smallholder farmers in the buffer zone hardwoods around the boundary, and
of the Gorongosa National Park for planting fruit trees within the homestead.
reducing emissions from deforestation and The N’hambita Community Carbon Project is
degradation (REDD) of Miombo woodlands. serving as a demonstration model, which can
Farmers are contracted to sequester carbon be replicated in other areas both within and
on their farmlands through adoption of outside of Mozambique
agroforestry practices from a ‘menu’ that
includes horticultural tree species, woodlots, SOURCE: WRI 2011.
23

Private sector can also organize and invest REDD+ (Reducing Emissions from
in the set-up and implementation of PES, Deforestation and Forest Degradation)
and in this case this instrument can also be represents a multilayer PES scheme with
considers an alternative market instrument, transfers of finance between developed and
due to the reduced state engagement and developing countries in exchange for emission
public financial support (see lesson 4). reductions.

The potential to create an international PES


scheme related to forests and carbon has
become a key focus of international climate
negotiations.

SUSTAINABLE PUBLIC PROCUREMENT


Sustainable Public Procurement (SPP) can be energy and reduction in water consumption,
defined as the process whereby government and contracting of suppliers that use clean
institutions meet their needs for goods, technology in their services.
services and utilities in a way that generates
benefits not only to the organisation, but also For example, the Transport Department
to society and the economy, while minimising of Hong Kong has retrofitted its traffic
damage to the environment. 12 lights to LED lights, resulting in increased
energy efficiency (63 percent lower energy
Public procurement at central, provincial, and consumption), cost savings (estimated
local level represents around 15-30 percent 340.000 USD over the life-span of LED
of national GDP (UNEP, 2012). In some modules), and lower maintenance costs both
developing countries it can reach as high as in replacement supplies and man-power
half of GDP (UNEP, 2015). Through SPP, (UNEP 2012b).
government spending can set an example for
private sector procurement, stimulate demand A number of countries have developed and
and create a stable market for sustainable successfully implemented SPP policies. For
products. example, Japan and the Republic of Korea
enacted specific SPP legislation covering
SPP can include products that have improved a large number of certified products that
recyclability or reduced packaging, goods that state institutions can choose from, and are
have high energy efficiency, use of renewable considered among the frontrunners of SPP
policies worldwide (UNEP 2015).

12
Based on the definition for
Sustainable Procurement accepted
by the Marrakech Task Force on
Sustainable Procurement.
24

REFLECTION POINT
Thinking about your place of work – is your procurement sustainable? What can be done to
improve the sustainability of procurement practices?

Reforming harmful subsidies


As we discussed, subsidies can promote For example, in Indonesia fuel subsidies were
activities that have negative environmental or put in place to make energy more affordable,
social impact. For example, some of the most particularly for poor people. In light of
wide-spread subsidies aim to increase the rising budget constraints, since 2005 the
competitiveness and market access of energy Indonesian government has taken steps to
products and services and can apply to both implement fuel subsidies reform, accompanied
clean energy or fossil fuels. by a cash transfer programme to help
vulnerable families cope with higher energy
Globally, the amount of fossil fuel subsidies costs.
surpasses many times the public funds used
to support renewable energies (IMF 2015a). Governments can address the issue of
Other negative subsidies can be related to environmentally harmful spending by
water use, mining, agricultural production, implementing subsidy reform with the goal
forestry, and many more. of preserving natural capital, stimulating the
adoption of efficiency measures by companies
Fossil fuel subsidies in particular can and households, and redirecting funds into
contribute to negative impacts such as fiscal priority areas for public expenditure.
deficits, excessive energy consumption,
and pollution, while diverting resources and However, subsidy reforms need to be carefully
investment from clean energy and pro-poor drafted, considering the needs of the poor,
initiatives (UNEP n.d.).13 and accounting for possible negative impact to
the competitiveness of key economic sectors.
While environmentally harmful, in many
emerging and developing countries, subsidies A reform that builds on the three pillars of
for kerosene, coal or electricity are motivated right pricing, legitimacy and mitigation of
on equity grounds because they give poor negative impacts is thus most likely to succeed
households access to basic energy resources. (Figure 5). These topics are elaborated further
As studies have shown, the benefits of most in Module 3.
fuel subsidies in emerging and developing
countries actually accrue mainly to higher
income and already well-off households
(Coady 2010).

13
For an in-depth discussion of fossil fuel subsidy reform, especially from a policymaker perspective,
please refer also to the concise guidebook (IISD 2013). The guidebook focuses on Southeast Asia
yet contains several practical reform suggestions applicable to other regions as well.
25

video 2
This video by the IISD provides a
PRICING AND TARGETING good introduction to the problems,
opportunities and recommended
approaches to fossil fuel subsidy reform.

WATCH THE VIDEO

KEY

GETTING THE PRICES BUILDING SUPPORT MANAGING THE


RIGHT FOR REFORM IMPACTS OF REFORM

Political mandate and internal organization

Communications: general
awareness raising.
Consultations: map
Explore options for pace and Project impacts and explore
stakeholders, gauge views
change of pricing system: mitigation options: direct
gradual vs. “big bang,” and indirect impacts, mix
strategic timing, consider the quantitative and qualitative
four dimensions of pricing approaches, consider three
types of mitigation measure

Fig. 5: Key pillars for success in fossil fuel subsidy reform (IISD 2013)
26

India has recently successfully reformed For example, subsidizing water irrigation may
the price of diesel, thus correcting market lead to wastefulness, inefficiency and inequality
distortion and realizing fiscal benefits while in water use (Casey 2013, IISD 2016).
addressing social concerns (Box 7).14
In addition to reforming subsidies, other green
Harmful subsidies also exist in other sectors, fiscal instruments, such as feed-in-tariffs,
such as water (IMF 2015b), fisheries (UNEP zero or low-interest loans, grants, or public-
2011) or agriculture (OECD 2014). private partnerships, can help address wasteful
spending and create a level playing field for
more efficient, low-carbon products and
services to develop and be commercialized.

14
A number of case studies and lessons learnt on fossil subsidy reform are also available through the
Green Fiscal Policy Network.
27

BOX 7:
DIESEL PRICE REFORM IN INDIA

From 2005 until 2012 diesel fuel in India reform subsidies on diesel fuel with the goal
has been heavily subsidized. Consequently, to completely remove the subsidies by 2014.
consumption of diesel grew and it became In January 2013, diesel price liberalisation
the single most consumed petroleum began. The result of this reform was a shift
product in India at nearly 44 percent from subsidizing domestic oil companies
in 2012/13. Burning of diesel fuel also to more market-based price formation in
contributes significantly to GHG emissions October 2014. India also saw associated
and air quality problems from toxic gases decreased demand for diesel fuel. The policy
and air particulates. Following record subsidy change yielded environmental and economic
expenditure coupled with fiscal deficits, the benefits while also preventing macro-
government announced a programme to economic destabilization (IISD 2015b).
4

Alternative economic
instruments
Where governments are politically or economically constrained in introducing
new taxes or subsidies, they can use a variety of alternative instruments to
address externalities.

Overview
Alternative economic instruments, such target schemes, or deposit-and-refund
as tradable permits and offset systems, do schemes.
not fall into one of the two aforementioned
categories, i.e. revenue collection or A government may choose these instruments
expenditure. if there are political barriers to environmental
taxation or subsidies, e.g. public or stakeholder
These market-based mechanisms are concern.
characterized by direct interactions between
firms, rather than between the government Another reason for setting up tradable
and private entities. permits and offsets schemes can be a desire to
mobilize market agents as a primary driver for
However, it is often governments that design, low-carbon development.
implement and regulate alternative economic
instrument, such as cap and trade, emission This lesson introduces the concepts of
tradable permits (4.2) ands offset systems

Tradable permits

Tradable permit schemes can be used, inter - Establish an overall level of pollution
alia, for carbon, water and biodiversity allowed;
protection. As opposed to taxes, which fix a - Let the open market determine the price
price for pollution and then allow the market of pollution;
to determine the level of pollution, trading - Allow firms to purchase (e.g. through
schemes: government auctions) and trade credits
to undertake polluting activities.

15 Deposit-and-refund schemes will be briefly reviewed in Module 4 of this course.


29

Emissions trading usually targets high In practice, some firms may just want to
emitting private entities within specified avoid penalties by staying below their cap,
sectors, such as transportation, oil and gas, whereas others may actively seek to realize
buildings, manufacturing. additional profits (IETA 2015) by cutting
their emissions more decidedly.
The market actors are designated a specific
amount of emissions that they are allowed The strength of such a scheme is that it
to emit. If they emit below the allowance, allows for both rationales as long as the cap is
they can sell their emissions ‘gap’ at market respected.
value in the emission trading system to
other companies that emitted above their Permits or allowances can be allocated to
allowance. businesses for free, via auctioning, or a mix
of both.
In order to comply with the annual emissions
target and avoid penalties, high-emitting Depending on the initial costs, businesses
companies may buy emission permits (see can be more or less motivate to implement
Video 3) (EDF 2016, IETA 2015). efficiency improvements in their operations.

In principle, the cap is set in a way that it Furthermore, the potential revenue of
progressively diminishes each year, thus auctioning can be considerable: In 2013, the
steadily encouraging companies to innovate total revenue of the EU Emissions Trading
or perform efficiency improvements in their System (ETS) reached 3,6 billion EUR. 16
operations and business models.

video 3
This video explains the purpose and
PRICING AND TARGETING functioning of the EU ETS (Source:
European Commission)

WATCH THE VIDEO

Cap and trade systems may target fossil more economic actors – factories, energy-
fuel producers, suppliers and distributers intense facilities, etc. (WRI 2008a). Box 7
(pollution at the point of extraction, or looks at the Western Climate Initiative (WCI)
upstream pollution). Alternatively, a cap Cap and Trade, which governs emission trading
and trade system can also focus on the in Quebec and California.
point of combustion or use, and captures

16
Click here for more information on regulations and experiences related to the EU ETS auctioning.
30

BOX 8
WESTERN CLIMATE INITIATIVE (WCI) CAP AND TRADE

The WCI trading system covers Quebec and surrender emissions allowances to their
and California and aims to reduce GHG respective governments to comply with their
emissions from the highest emitting sectors respective regulatory emissions targets. At
(>25,000 metric tons of CO2e annually). its most recent auction WCI notes the sale
The sub-national governments worked of over 75 million allowances at a price of
together for two years to harmonize their 12,73 USD per allowance indicating revenue
regulations, which were officially linked on of over 950 million USD
January 1, 2014. The linking meant that any
registered emitters from any jurisdiction can SOURCE: MDDELC 2015.
purchase (through trade, offset or auction)

OFFSETS
Offsets are credits linked to activities that The most common offset projects for carbon
lead to a quantifiable reduction in pollution, emissions include methane capture, forestry
e.g. emissions, biodiversity loss, water and agriculture projects (IETA n.d.).
impacts.
In a way, offset mechanisms resemble
Accredited firms can generate offsets by payment for ecosystem services (PES)
reducing units of pollution. Those offsets schemes, that we reviewed under lesson 3
can be bought by market or state actors
that have a mandatory or voluntary target to Purchase of offsets can be used in a cap
reduce emissions (see Figure 2). 17 and trade system as a way for regulated
companies to comply with their mandated
The type of projects, compliance standards, reduction in emission.
and the price per offsets are determined by
the specific offset scheme.

17 Individuals can now also purchase certified emissions reductions (CERs) in the context of voluntary offsetting
through “Go Climate Neutral Now!”, an online platform administered by the UNFCCC.
31

REFLECTION POINT
Are there examples in your country of generated offsets either for international (e.g. Clean
Development Mechanism, CDM) or domestic/regional markets? Do you see sectors that may
benefit from this approach?

Fig. 2: How carbon offsetting works (Carbon Clear 2015)

For example, an entity in the energy sector Credits can be traded within one
may purchase offsets from an afforestation country, such as China, Australia, or
project to make up for the amount of cross-boundary (e.g. Box 5: Western
emissions generated over its emissions cap. Climate Initiative, RGGI, and the
European Union Emissions Trading
System). 18

18 The EU ETS legislation provides for the possibility to link the EU ETS with other compatible emissions trading
systems in the world at national or regional level. The EU is currently investigating possibilities to link its
system with other large systems, i.e. China and California. In general, the bigger the ETS the more pollution
can be governed –and eventually reduced– by it. Click here for more information. See also the International
Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP), which brings together countries and regions that are actively pursuing the
development of carbon markets through the implementation of mandatory cap-and-trade systems.
5

Using fiscal instruments in a


policy mix
Policy instruments for green reform can be viewed like a toolbox - each one
has a useful purpose, but often multiple tools are needed to complete the
job.

Whether it is instruments for revenue Another example is combining a cap-and-


collection, such as taxes, fees and charges; trade system for the manufacturing sector
instruments for expenditure, such as subsidies with an offset scheme in the agriculture
and related mechanisms; or alternative sector.
mechanisms such as emission trading and
offset schemes, there are a number of fiscal Countries might also provide grants for
mechanisms that countries can employ to recycling, which has been funded by a waste
drive transition to a green economy. dumping fee.

Notably, each instrument also comes with There is a virtually unlimited array of options
a different set of financial, environmental for combining tools based on the necessities
and social risks and context specific cost- and conditions of a given country or region.
structure.
With the list of tools identified in this module,
It is possible for countries to adopt multiple the focus of Module 3 will turn to policy
fiscal tools in conjunction, in order to design and implementation, i.e. how to
implement green fiscal reform. identify and apply appropriate fiscal policy
tools in concrete circumstances.
For example, a country that implements a
carbon tax on fossil fuel emissions can use the
tax revenue to subsidize a feed-in-tariff for
small scale solar power.
34

key
learning points
1
There are a number of policy instruments for green fiscal reform. These broadly fall into the
categories of taxes (revenue collection), subsidies (expenditure) and alternative mechanisms
(such as market based instruments).

2
Taxes, charges or fees are designed to support green reform by placing an economic cost on
activities that are environmentally harmful. They address externalities and incentivize people to
choose greener products or services, while mobilizing resources which can be used to different
purposes, including green investment.

3
Subsidies, feed-in tariffs, grants and other economic support mechanisms, can provide fiscal
incentives for green investment and promote market development in areas such as clean energy,
waste management, sustainable buildings, etc.

4
Reforming inefficient and harmful subsidies can unlock significant resources for green and socially
inclusive development.

5
Alternative mechanisms such as offsets and cap-and-trade systems use market dynamics as a
driver for green transformation and provide a viable option for green fiscal reform to governments
that face political or financial constraints.

6
Fiscal policy instruments can be used in combination with each other to promote reform across
multiple sectors and in ways that recognize unique sectoral or political circumstances.
35

REFERENCES
Barbier, E.B. (2010) A Global Green New Deal: Rethinking the Economic Recovery. New York.

BBOP (2016) “Biodiversity Offsets.” Business and Biodiversity Offsets Programme.


http://bbop.forest-trends.org/pages/biodiversity_offsets.

BC Ministry of Finance (2015a) “Carbon Tax.” http://www.fin.gov.bc.ca/tbs/tp/climate/carbon_tax.htm.

— (2015b) “Tax Reductions, Funded by a Revenue Neutral Carbon Tax.” http://www.fin.gov.bc.ca/tbs/tp/climate/tax_cuts.htm.

Beaty, R, R Lipsey, and S Elgie. (2014) “The shocking truth about B.C.’s carbon tax: It works.” The Globe and Mail.
July 9. http://www.theglobeandmail.com/opinion/the-insidious-truth-about-bcs-carbon-tax-it-works/article19512237/.

Carbon Clear. (2015) “What is Carbon Offsetting?” http://www.carbon-clear.com/what-we-do/carbon-offsetting/
what-is-carbon-offsetting/.

Casey, Alyssa. (2013) “Reforming Energy Subsidies Could Curb India’s Water Stress.” Worldwatch Insitute.
http://www.worldwatch.org/reforming-energy-subsidies-could-curb-india%E2%80%99s-water-stress-0.

Clarke, Kieran. (2015) Diesel Subsidy Reform in India: Lessons learned. Winnipeg: IISD.

Climate Strategies (2008). The Role of Auctions for Emissions Trading. Cambridge.

Coady, D. et al. (2010) Petroleum Product Subsidies: Costly, Inequitable and Rising. International Monetary Fund (IMF)
Staff Position Note 10/05. Washington DC: IMF.

David Suzuki Foundation et. al. n.d. The B.C. Carbon Tax: Myths and Realities. Vancouver: David Suzuki Foundation.

Deloitte (2014) Global Survey of R&D Tax Incentives. New York.

Deutsche Bank Group (2011) “The German Feed-in Tariff for PV: Managing Volum Sucess with Price Response.”
https://www.db.com/cr/en/docs/German_FIT_for_PV.pdf

DFID (2013) Payments for Ecosystem Services: A best practices guide. London.

Ecofys, and World Bank (2014) State and trends of carbon pricing 2014. Washington, DC: World Bank Group.

EDF & IETA (2013) “Alberta - The Two World’s Carbon Market.” http://www.ieta.org/assets/Reports/
EmissionsTradingAroundTheWorld/edf_ieta_alberta_case_study_may_2013.pdf.

EDF (2016) “How cap and trade works: Learn how this key mechanism works to reduce emissions.”
https://www.edf.org/climate/how-cap-and-trade-works

Ministry of Norway (2014) Mandate for a new green tax commission. Oslo.
36

Elgie, S., and R. Lipsey. (2015). “B.C’s carbon tax shift works.” Financial Post. January 22.
http://business.financialpost.com/fp-comment/b-c-s-carbon-tax-shift-works.

EPA (2015) Renewable Energy Certificates. Washington: EPA.

— (2016) “Pollution Fees, Charges and Taxes” http://bit.ly/2mTZHXj

European Environment Agency (2006) EN34 Energy Subsidies. Brussels.

— (2000) Environmental taxes: recent development in tools for intergration. Copenhagen.


https://www.cbd.int/financial/fiscalenviron/g-fiscaltaxes.pdf.

FONAFIFO (2016) “Environmental Services Payment (PSA) Program.” http://www.fonafifo.go.cr/home/


psa_eng/index.html.

Fripp, Emily. (2014) “Payments for Ecosystem Services (PES): A practical guide to assessing the
feasibility of PES projects.” CIFOR. http://www.cifor.org/publications/pdf_files/Books/BFripp1401.pdf.

Gaupp, D. (2007) Turkey’s New Law on Renewable Energy Sources within the Context of the
Accession Negotiations with the EU. . German Law Journal, 413-416.

GGBP (2014) “South Africa’s Green Fund.” http://www.ggbp.org/case-studies/south-africa/south-


africas-green-fund.

GGKP (2015) “Fiscal Instruments .” http://www.greengrowthknowledge.org/theme/fiscal-instruments.

Green Fiscal Commission (2009a) The Case for Green Fiscal Reform. London.

— (2009b) How Effective are Green Taxes? London.

Heine, Dirk, John Norregaard, and Ian W.H. Parry. (2012) Environmental Tax Reform: Principles from Theory
and Practice to Date. Washington: IMF.

Heinrich Böll Stiftung et al. (2013) Powering Africa through Feed-in Tariffs. Nairobi.

IEA (2012) World Energy Outlook 2012. Paris: OECD/IEA.

IETA (2015) “Cap and Trade: The basics.” http://www.ieta.org/Resources/Resources/101s/cap-and-trade-the-


basics-101-april15.pdf.

IETA n.d. “Carbon Offsets Overview.” http://www.unepfi.org/fileadmin/training/climate/ieta_offsets.pdf.

IISD (2012) “A Forum for South East Asian Policy-makers - Fossil fuel subsidy reform, Challenges
and opportunities.” https://www.iisd.org/gsi/sites/default/files/ffs_gsibali_meetingreport.pdf.

— (2013) A Guidebook to Fossil-Fuel Subsidy Reform for Policy-Makers in Southeast Asia.


Winnipeg

— (2015a) “Subsidies type.” In Subsidy Primer. https://www.iisd.org/GSI/subsidy-types.

—(2015b) Diesel Subsidy Reform in India: Lessons Learnt. Geneva: IISD/GSI.


37

—(2016. “Chapter 2: The effects of subsidies.” Global Subsidies Initiative. https://www.iisd.org/gsi/effects-subsidies.

IISD, and UNEP (2014) Trade and Green Economy. A Handbook. Geneva.

IMF (2013) Case Studies on Energy Subsidy Reform: Lessons and Implications. http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/
eng/2013/012813.pdf.

— (2015a) How Large Are Global Energy Subsidies? Working Paper. Washington, DC.

— (2015b) Is the Glass Half Empty or Half Full? Issues in Managing Water Challenges and Policy Instruments. Washington,
DC.

—. n.d. “Reforming Energy Subsidies: Summary Note.” https://www.imf.org/external/np/fad/subsidies/pdf/note.pdf.

India, Ministry of New and Renewable Energy of. 2010. Annual Report 2009-2010. New Delhi.

IRENA (2013) Renewable Energy Auctions in Developing Countries. Abu Dhabi: IRENA.

Jierui, Shi. (2009) “China’s bag ban, one year later.” https://www.chinadialogue.net/article/show/single/en/3158.

Kraan, Dirk-Jan. (2004) Off-budget and Tax Expenditures. Paris: OECD.

MDDELC (2015) “California Cap-and-Trade Program and Québec Cap-and-Trade System: November 2015
Joint Auction #5 .” http://www.mddelcc.gouv.qc.ca/changements/carbone/ventes-encheres/2015-11-24/Vente-Encheres-
5-Sommaire-resultats-en.pdf.

Mexico, National Ecology Institute of. (2007) Incentivos fiscales vigentes: arancel cero y depreciación acelerada
para inversiones que reported beneficios ambientales. Mexico City.

Ministers, Nordic Council oF. (2006) “The Use of Economic Instruments in Nordic and Baltic Environmental
Policy 2001-2005.”

NREL (2010) “A Policymaker’s Guide to Feed-in Tariff Policy Design.”


http://www.nrel.gov/docs/fy10osti/44849.pdf.

OECD. (2010) Taxation, Innovation and the Environment. Paris.

— (2011) Environmental Taxation: A guide for policy makers. Paris.

— (2014) Agricultural Policy Monitoring and Evaluation 2014. OECD Countries. Paris.

— (2016) OECD Database. Science, technology and innovation: GERD by source of funds. Paris.

PAGE (2016) Introduction to Green Fiscal Reform. Geneva: UNITAR.

Pedersen, Thomas, and Stewart Elgie. (2015) “A template for the world: British Columbia’s carbon tax shift.” In Critical
Issues in Environmental Taxation, by L.A. Kresier et al. https://pics.uvic.ca/sites/default/files/uploads/publications/
Pedersen%20and%20Elgie%202015%20(in%20press)%5B6%5D.pdf
38

Peters, Sophia. (2012) The Role of Green Fiscal Mechanisms in Developing Countries: Lessons
learned. OECD. http://idbdocs.iadb.org/wsdocs/getdocument.aspx?docnum=36770314.
Schlegelmilch, K., and A. Joas. 2015. Fiscal considerations in the design of green tax reforms.
Berlin.

Steenblik, Ronald. (2006) “A Subsidy Primer.” Global Subsidies Initiative. https://www.iisd.org/gsi/


sites/default/files/primer.pdf.

Sustainable Prosperity (2015) “Environmental Taxes in Canada.”


http://www.sustainableprosperity.ca/sites/default/files/publications/files/
SP_IS-Enviro-Tax-In-Canada_FINAL.pdf.

Transport for London (2015) “Annual Report and Statement of Accounts 2014/15.”
http://content.tfl.gov.uk/annual-report-2014-15.pdf

Transport for London n.d. “Penalities & Enforcement.” Transport for London. https://tfl.gov.uk/
modes/driving/congestion-charge/penalties-and-enforcement.

Transport for London n.d. “Congestion Charge.” http://content.tfl.gov.uk/congestion-charge-


factsheet.pdf.

UNEP (2008) “Payments for Ecosystem Services.” http://www.unep.org/pdf/


PaymentsForEcosystemServices_en.pdf

— (2011) Towards a Green Economy. Pathways to Sustainable Development and Poverty


Eradication. Nairobi.

— (2012a) Feed-in Tariffs as a Policy Instrument for Promoting Renewable Energies and Green
Economies in Developing Countries. Nairobi.

— (2012b) “The Impacts of Sustainable Public Procurement.” http://www.unep.org/


resourceefficiency/Portals/24147/scp/procurement/docsres/ProjectInfo/StudyonImpactsofSPP.
pdf.

— (2013) “Fiscal Policy.” http://www.unep.org/greeneconomy/Portals/88/documents/news/


Issue%20Briefs/fiscal%20policy%20brief_EN_final.pdf.

— (2015) Fossil Fuel Subsidies. Policy Brief. Nairobi.

— (2015) Sustainable Consumption and Production: A Handbook for Policy Makers, 2nd edition.
Bangkok: UNEP.

—. n.d. Fiscal Policy. Geneva.

UNESCAP (2012) Environmental Tax Reform and Environmental Fiscal Reform. Bangkok.

WRI (2008a) Bottom Line on Cap-and-Trade. Washington, DC.

— (2008b) Bottom Line on Renewable Energy Certificates. Washington, DC.

— (2011) A Compilation of Green Economy Policies, Programs and Initiatives from Around the
World. Washington DC.
39

abbreviations
BBOP Business and Biodiversity Offsets Programme
BC British Columbia
CAD Canadian Dollar
CDM Clean Development Mechanism
CER Certified Emissions Reductions
CO2 Carbon Dioxide
CO2e Carbon Dioxide Equivalent
DFID Department for International Development
EDF Environmental Defense Fund
EPA Environmental Protection Agency
EU European Union
EU ETS European Union Emissions Trading System
EUR Euro
FiT Feed-in Tariff
GDP Gross Domestic Product
GGBP Green Growth Best Practices
GGKP Green Growth Knowledge Platfom
GHG Greenhouse Gas
ICAP International Carbon Action Partnership
IETA International Emissions Trading Association
IISD International Institute for Sustainable Development
IMF International Monetary Fund
IRENA International Renewable Energy Agency
KW Kilowatt
LED Light-emitting Diode
MDDELC Ministère du Développement Durable, de l’Environnement et de la Lutte contre les
Changements Climatiques
MID Maurice Île Durable
MW Megawatt
NREL National Renewable Energy Laboratory
OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
PES Payment for Ecosystem Services
R&D Research and Development
REC Renewable Energy Certificate
REDD+ Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation
RGGI Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative
SDG Sustainable Development Goal
SPP Sustainable Public Procurement
UK United Kingdom
UNEP United Nations Environment Programme
UNESCAP United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific
UNFCCC United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
USD United States Dollar
WCI Western Climate Initiative
WRI World Resources Institute
WTO World Trade Organization

You might also like