The Wal-Mart Effect Wave of Destruction or Creativ

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 29

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/240661621

The Wal-Mart Effect: Wave of Destruction or Creative


Destruction?

Article in Economic Geography · April 2009


DOI: 10.1111/j.1944-8287.2009.01023.x

CITATIONS READS

48 4,385

3 authors:

Srikanth Paruchuri Joel A. C. Baum


Pennsylvania State University University of Toronto
22 PUBLICATIONS 1,663 CITATIONS 183 PUBLICATIONS 21,280 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

David Thomas Potere


Independent Researcher
19 PUBLICATIONS 3,666 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Strategic Organization View project

Research Practices in Management View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Joel A. C. Baum on 19 January 2018.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY
The Wal-Mart Effect:Wave of Destruction
or Creative Destruction?

Srikanth Paruchuri
Warrington College of
During the past quarter century, large multistore

abstract
Business
University of Florida retailers have experienced considerable growth. In
Gainesville, FL 32611 this article, we examine the widely held belief that
paruchur@ufl.edu the expansion of these chain stores, Wal-Mart in par-
ticular, has had a large negative impact on the small
Joel A. C. Baum locally owned retail sector. Our analysis of four
Rotman School of types of independent retailer entries and exits in
Management Florida from 1980, prior to the opening of the first
University of Toronto Wal-Mart store in the state, to 2004, reveals that
105 St. George Street Wal-Mart’s impact varies with independent retailers’ 209
Toronto, Ontario market overlap with and proximity to Wal-Mart.
Canada M5S 3E6 Notably, our findings suggest that within zip codes,
baum@rotman.utoronto.ca the Wal-Mart effect is driven by the suppression of
entry rates, but not by the increase in exit rates,

85(2):209–236. © 2009 Clark University.


David Potere while in adjacent zip codes, it is driven by exit rates
Office of Population increasing more than entry rates. Our results provide
Research empirical evidence that may help economic develop-
Princeton University ers, public officials, and owners of small businesses
Princeton, NJ 08544-2091 make informed decisions about economic develop-
dpotere@princeton.edu
ment in their communities.

Key words:
Wal-Mart
independent retailers
competition
entry
exit
www.economicgeography.org
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Acknowledgments Wal-Mart effect n. The economic effects attributable to


the Wal-Mart retail chain, including local effects such as
forcing smaller independent competitors out of business
We are grateful to Economic and driving down wages, and broader effects such as
Geography editor Amy helping to keep inflation low and productivity high.
Glasmeier and four (Sheppard and White 2005, 131)
anonymous reviewers for
their help in strengthening The structure of the retail market has changed dra-
the study.We are also matically over the past quarter century. Discount
thankful to Florida’s retailer chains, such as Wal-Mart, Kmart, Home
Department of State for Depot, and Target, have grown rapidly and captured a
providing data on business growing share of the retail market throughout the
registrations and United States. There are many suggested explanations
deregistrations and to for their success, including purchasing power and
Wal-Mart for providing skills; investments in logistics, distribution, and
administrative data on the inventory control; shared operating and advertising
dates of store openings.The costs; exposure to diverse customer demands; the
210 use of data from Wal-Mart
ability to respond to changing customer demands; and
does not imply the the combination of wholesaling and retailing opera-
endorsement of Wal-Mart, tions within the same business (e.g., Guy 1996;
Inc., in relation to the Marsden and Wrigley 1996; Thomas and Bromley
interpretation or analysis of 2002; Wrigley 1996, 1998, 2000).
the statistical data. Currently, Wal-Mart, the largest retailer in the
world, is the most successful among these chains, with
its 2005 revenues exceeding the combined revenues
of the next five largest U.S. retailers—Home Depot,
Kroger, Sears Holding Company (which includes
Sears and Kmart), Costco, and Target (Schulz 2006).
Because Wal-Mart, with more than 3,400 stores in the
United States, has a presence in so many markets,
virtually all other retailers compete with it: 67 percent
of all retail stores in the United States are located
within five miles of a Wal-Mart (Basker 2007).
Changes in the structure of the retail market result-
ing from Wal-Mart’s rise create opportunities as well
as pose challenges for local municipalities. Critics
have associated the presence of Wal-Mart (and large
discount chains more generally) with the closing of
small independent stores, the decline of downtown
shopping districts, the erosion of the tax base, lower
employment and wages, higher poverty, and commu-
nity disintegration (e.g., Freeman 2003; Goetz and
Swaminathan 2006; McGee and Gresham 1995;
Quinn 2005).1 Municipalities have varied in their
response. Some have attempted to limit Wal-Mart’s

1
See, for example, the anti-Wal-Mart website, Wal-
martsucks.com, set up to persuade the public that the retailer
is bad for communities, and the wal-martfacts.com website,
developed by Wal-Mart to counter such attacks.
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

access with zoning regulations and “living wage” ordinances, while others have wel-
comed Wal-Mart with infrastructure developments and subsidies, including site-
preparation assistance, job training grants, property tax exemptions, and sales tax
abatements. Places that have limited Wal-Mart’s entry have often cited its potential
impact on urban sprawl, traffic, and congestion, as well as its significant harm to small,
independent retailers (Rosen 2003). Places that have encouraged Wal-Mart have argued
that it is better to have a Wal-Mart open in one’s own jurisdiction than in a neighboring
jurisdiction. Although these beliefs are common (if divided), they remain largely uncon-
firmed empirically.
Wal-Mart’s biggest and most obvious effect is that it offers lower prices to consumers
(Basker 2005b) and that it has had a ruinous influence on several large retail chains (Graff
1998; Shields and Kures 2007; Stone 1995; Vias 2004) and supermarket chains (Franklin
2001). Many of its other economic effects have been less well quantified, however. There
is, for example, an ongoing debate regarding the effect of Wal-Mart on local employment
and wage rates (Basker 2005a; Bernstein and Bivens 2006; Dube, Lester, and Eidlin 2007;
Hicks and Wilburn 2007; Ketchum and Hughes 2004; Neumark, Zhang, and Ciccarella
2005). Moreover, little rigorous empirical work has directly examined how the entry of 211
Wal-Mart stores affects the entrepreneurial entry and fates of small, independent busi-
nesses, despite their local and national economic significance. Small businesses are

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


integral to the renewal process in market economies, playing a key role in experimentation
and innovation that leads to productivity and economic growth, as well as lowering
unemployment (Acs 1999; Robbins, Pantuosco, Parker, and Fuller 2000; Waite 1973).
Understanding how Wal-Mart influences patterns of entrepreneurial activity, particularly
the composition of local independent retailers, thus seems vital to illuminating Wal-
Mart’s impact on wages and employment.
Although the negative, often sizable, impact of Wal-Mart that has been reported in
many applied policy studies (e.g., Stone 1997; Stone, Artz, and Myles 2002) has garnered
widespread attention, these studies have been problematic. Econometric methods have
often not been used, making it difficult to know if observed differences between locations
with and without Wal-Mart stores are statistically significant or caused by other economic
and demographic factors. And when econometric methods have been used, they have
typically failed to account for possible endogeneity in Wal-Mart’s selection of store
locations (Basker 2005a; Dean and Sobel 2008). Furthermore, studies have frequently
analyzed only data for directly competing retail businesses within a specific location (Jia
2006). Businesses that do not compete directly with Wal-Mart have not been included in
the data, so their potential expansion has been overlooked. The reallocation of resources
to other retail sectors and other locations has thus not been considered, making it difficult
to assess the overall effect of Wal-Mart on small businesses. Finally, in some cases, large
competing retail chains, including Kmart, Target, and Home Depot, all of which have
been negatively affected by Wal-Mart, have been included in the analyses, making it
difficult to assess the impact of Wal-Mart on small, independent retailers.
We report an analysis of the short- and long-run changes in local retail market
structures that resulted from the expansion of Wal-Mart in Florida from 1980, three years
before the first Wal-Mart store opened in the state, to 2004. Given the limitations of prior
research, we used econometric techniques to control for endogeneity in Wal-Mart’s
choices of locations, examined four types of retailers that compete with Wal-Mart in
products (home furnishings) and services (photographic studios) and that do not compete
with Wal-Mart in products (antique stores) and services (beauty salons), and modeled the
effects of Wal-Mart openings within the same and neighboring zip codes separately and
dynamically. We selected these four types because each exhibits high within-category
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

homogeneity and is dominated by small, young independent retailers, rather than chain
stores.
Our analysis aims to disentangle some of the harmful and beneficial aspects of
Wal-Mart’s disruptive influence on the economy. Following Schumpeter (1942), we
view the entry of Wal-Mart into a local market as an event in the process of creative
destruction. For Schumpeter, capitalism is a system of economic change driven by
“competition from the new commodity, the new technology, the new source of supply,
the new type of organization (the largest-scale unit of control for instance)—competition
which commands a decisive cost or quality advantage and which strikes not at the
margins of the profits and the outputs of the existing firms but at their foundations and
their very lives” (1942, 84). The process is unfortunate for the failing firms but benefits
consumers and frees capital and resources for new businesses and further advancements.
Wal-Mart openings, while resulting in the failure of some small retailers, thus create
opportunities for other new retailers to enter, not only in that location but in more distant
places (Basker 2007). These dynamics are difficult to identify, however, because they
vary by type of business and proximity to the event. Nevertheless, attending to them is
212 essential to clarifying Wal-Mart’s economic impact and to developing instructive policy
recommendations.

Background: Destruction or Creative Destruction?


Although “churn” is already high in the U.S. retail sector, with more than 50 percent of
retailers operating in any given year having ceased operations within five years (Jarmin,
Klimek, and Miranda 2004), the arrival of a Wal-Mart makes an already tough competi-
tive environment even tougher. Wal-Mart stores shrink local competitors’ market shares
and profit margins, leading some to close.
To quantify this effect, Jia (2006) estimated a structural equilibrium model, in which,
first, two large discount chains (Wal-Mart and Kmart) make simultaneous moves, and,
second, small discounters decide whether or not to enter. The large chains’ entry is
assumed to depend on local economic conditions and anticipation of competitors’ (both
large and small) decisions, as well as on an incentive to locate stores close to markets to
reduce costs. Small stores’ entries are assumed to be based on observation of the entry of
large chains. Jia found that, on average, a county is served by two to three fewer small
discount stores if Wal-Mart or Kmart enter than if these large retailers stay out. Given that
the average U.S. county had fewer than four such discounters in the mid-1980s, this
represents a large percentage decline in their numbers that are attributable to Wal-Mart.
Basker (2005a) used an instrumental-variables approach to estimate the effect of
Wal-Mart’s entry and included not just general merchandisers, but all types of retailers.
She found that roughly four small competitors close in a county within five years of
Wal-Mart’s entry into the county. Since the average county has more than 200 small
retailers, these estimates suggest that Wal-Mart’s entry has only a minor effect on the
number of small retailers. Of course, those that do not close may still experience
considerable revenue losses (Singh, Hansen, and Blattberg 2006).
Wal-Mart’s net effect on the number of retailers operating in a market masks variation
across both business category and location. Within an area, some businesses fare better
than do others, and while some segments decline and others may grow (home furnishing
stores versus beauty salons, for instance), businesses that are most adversely affected are
those in direct competition with Wal-Mart. Drugstores and stores specializing in apparel,
sporting goods, home furnishings, cards and gifts, and other products that are typically
sold in a Wal-Mart store are likely to suffer the most.
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

There may also be variation geographically. Because they outcompete other retailers on
price and (often) convenience, Wal-Mart stores typically draw customers from a larger
area. For example, Holmes (2008) estimated that in rural areas (with 1,000 people within
a 5-mile radius), increasing the distance of consumers from a Wal-Mart store from zero
to 5 miles has only a small effect on the demand, which declines from 100 percent to 98
percent. Raising the distance further from 5 to 10 miles, however, lowers the demand
appreciably to 57 percent, but a substantial demand still remains. In more urban areas,
where there are more substitutes, the geographic scope of a Wal-Mart store’s demand
is narrower. In higher-density areas (with 20,000 people within a 5-mile radius), for
instance, Holmes estimated that 91 percent of consumers visit a Wal-Mart located near
their place of residence. Increasing the distance to 5 miles lowers the demand to 40
percent, and increasing the distance to 10 miles lowers the demand to 4 percent.
Neighboring communities may thus experience declines in some retail sectors as
consumers choose to travel farther for lower prices and the convenience of “one-stop”
shopping. Consumers evaluate competing stores on the basis of their overall utility, with
the probability of a consumer patronizing a particular shopping area a function of the size
and proximity of the shopping area relative to competing shopping areas (Huff 1963, 213
1964; Lakshmanan and Hansen 1965). For example, the entry of a Wal-Mart store that
does not sell groceries in Chicago increased revenue at an adjacent grocery store, but

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


reduced revenue at a grocery store two miles away (Zhu, Singh, and Dukes 2005).
Analogously, Stone (1997) found that restaurant sales in Wal-Mart towns in Iowa were 5
percent higher than the state average, while restaurant sales in non-Wal-Mart towns were
9 percent lower than the state average even 10 years after the Wal-Mart opened. Artz and
McConnon (2001) also found evidence that the entry of a Wal-Mart altered the retail
market structure by increasing sales in “host towns” in Maine and decreasing sales in
surrounding communities. Thus, people from non-Wal-Mart towns shopped in Wal-Mart
towns and, while there, patronized other businesses as well.
There is also anecdotal evidence that the composition of retailers in an area changes
following Wal-Mart’s expansion. Dean and Sobel (2008), for example, observed that soon
after a new Wal-Mart store opened, the local downtown area was replete with empty
storefronts. The small merchants that closed tended to be those that competed directly
with Wal-Mart—those selling general merchandise, groceries, apparel, electronics, home
furnishings, and building supplies. Their vacant locations, however, soon saw new small
businesses open—a women’s clothing store was replaced by a high-end restaurant, and an
electronics store was converted into an ice cream parlor. One by one, vacant stores were
occupied by new businesses, such as coffee shops, art galleries, antique stores, and
professional service firms. Only after the Wal-Mart entered did the locations of stores
selling the same type of merchandise as Wal-Mart become available and affordable to
entrepreneurs to open other types of businesses. Such recycling of resources into new
businesses is core to Schumpeter’s creative destruction process.
The money that consumers save on purchases at Wal-Mart reinforces the process by
nurturing the demand for and enabling the consumption of new kinds of goods and
services. Basker (2005b) found that the opening of a new Wal-Mart store results in
countywide price reductions of approximately 2 percent or 3 percent in the short run and
about 10 percent in the long run, giving consumers significant additional disposable
income to spend on new types of goods and services. Some of this savings will be spent
at local small businesses and some at businesses outside the local area to which consum-
ers would not have otherwise traveled. Although empirical evidence is more equivocal,
increased wages and employment resulting from the entry of a Wal-Mart store may add
further reinforcement. Hicks and Wilburn (2001), for example, found that Wal-Mart
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Wal-Mart Entry

Founding/ Entry Zip Code


Failure Rate

Founding/ Adjacent Zip Codes


Failure Rate

214

Time
Competing Business Founding Rate Noncompeting Business Founding Rate
Competing Business Failure Rate Noncompeting Business Failure Rate

Figure 1. The Wal-Mart effect.

entries had a positive impact on employment and wage benefits in a county in West
Virginia.2 Such effects on other businesses and other locations have rarely been consid-
ered simultaneously in previous studies, resulting in an incomplete picture of how
Wal-Mart influences the small retail business sector.
Because of their reliance on county-level data and emphasis on directly competing
retailers, most previous studies have not captured the process of creative destruction. If a
Wal-Mart opening prompted, for example, a local hardware store to fail and a new antique
store to open in its place, only the failure of the hardware store has typically been counted
in previous studies. The opening of the antique store was not reflected in the data because
such a store was not a direct competitor of Wal-Mart. In reality, one business was
substituted for another, but this effect was not reflected in the data because expansions in
sectors that do not directly compete with Wal-Mart were, by definition, excluded from the
analyses.
Thus, while it is clear that some small, independent businesses fail as a result of
competition from Wal-Mart, we anticipate, on the basis of Schumpeter’s theory, that
offsetting positive impacts of Wal-Mart open up opportunities for new types of businesses
to emerge. Figure 1 summarizes our expectations, particularly the positive and negative
effects of a Wal-Mart opening as a function of competitive overlap, geographic proximity,
and time.
In close proximity to the Wal-Mart (i.e., within the same zip code), the entry rate of
competing businesses is expected to decline, their exit rate is expected to rise, and thus
their net entry (i.e., entries compared to exits) is expected to fall relative to their
pre-Wal-Mart levels. These effects should be the strongest initially but then decline after

2
But see, for example, Bernstein and Bivens (2006), who found that Wal-Mart entries drive wages down
faster than prices.
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

the weakest competitors exit and cumulative exits begin to attract (brave) new competing
entrants. At the same time, the entry, exit, and net entry rates of noncompeting businesses
are expected to move in the opposite directions but more slowly as externalities emerge
and consumers shift consumption patterns over time.
In neighboring locations (i.e., adjacent zip codes), entry rates of both competing and
noncompeting businesses are expected to decline, while their exit rates are expected to
increase, and thus net entry is expected to fall. These effects are expected to develop over
time as consumers increasingly shift consumption to the Wal-Mart store and nearby
noncompeting businesses, reducing the demand for all businesses in adjacent locations,
but particularly for those that compete directly with Wal-Mart.
The question is whether the benefits that are summarized in Figure 1 outweigh the harm
that Wal-Mart causes its most direct local competitors and those in adjacent locations. The
opening of a Wal-Mart store causes various local and nonlocal businesses to fail but,
at the same time, creates opportunities for others to enter. At issue, then, is the
“net mortality” or “net entry” of different kinds of businesses in the same and adjacent
locations. With multiple, opposing effects at work, it is difficult to predict Wal-Mart’s
overall effect on the small business sector. In part, this overall effect depends on the 215
location and overlap of small businesses with Wal-Mart. In the end, it is an empirical
question, and the question to which we now turn.

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


Data
To examine the predictions outlined in Figure 1, we gathered yearly data on Wal-Mart
stores and independent retailers in Florida. The opening dates and locations of Wal-Mart
stores are based on administrative data provided by Wal-Mart. The data on the entry and
exit of independent retailers are based on annual zip code-level venture filings from 1980,
three years before the first Wal-Mart store opened in Florida, to 2004. Zip codes are
five-digit numerical codes, with the first digit representing a certain group of states, the
second and third digits together representing a region (or large city) within those states,
and the fourth and fifth digits representing a group of nonoverlapping delivery addresses
within that region (or city).
The data collection resulted in 40,050 observations (25 annual observations for 1,602
zip codes).3 Figure 2 shows the number of zip codes with a Wal-Mart store rising from 1
in 1983 to 121 (133 stores) in 2004. The figure also shows the number of zip codes with
a Wal-Mart in an adjacent zip code, as well as those facing a Wal-Mart in both their own
and adjacent zip codes. We defined adjacent zip codes as those with population centroids
within a five-mile radius of the population centroid of a zip code with a Wal-Mart. We
adopted a five-mile radius following recent work by Holmes (2008), which, we noted
earlier, indicated that the percentage of consumers who are likely to travel up to five miles
to a Wal-Mart store is substantial, but tends to fall off steeply beyond that point. By the
end of the observation period, retailers in 661 of Florida’s 1,602 zip codes (41.2 percent)
operated within a five-mile radius of one or more Wal-Mart stores.
Since 1988, Wal-Mart’s standard discount stores, which offer a wide variety of general
merchandise, including apparel, footwear, health and beauty aids, household goods, toys,
electronics, and lawn and garden products, have been supplemented by Wal-Mart-
operated specialty shops, including optical centers, one-hour photo-processing and
portrait studios, as well as independently operated alcove shops, such as beauty salons,

3
Zip codes that were merged sometime during the observation period were considered as single zip codes
throughout the observation period.
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

600

500

400
Number of Zip Codes

300

200

100

0
216 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992
Year
1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004

Local Wal-Mart Adjacent Wal-Mart Local and Adjacent Wal-Mart

Figure 2. Wal-Mart stores in Florida.

video rentals, and fast-food outlets. So, among the population of independent retailers,
we selected four categories—home furnishings (competitors in products), photo studios
(competitors in services), beauty salons (noncompetitors in services), and antique stores
(noncompetitors in products)—to compare the impact of Wal-Mart openings on different
types of retailers. As we noted earlier, we chose these four categories because each
exhibits high within-category homogeneity and is dominated by small, young indepen-
dent retailers, rather than chain stores.4
For each category of retailer, Figure 3 shows the entry, exit, and cumulative net entry
rates defined, respectively, as the annual new venture registrations, deregistrations, and
cumulative net registrations, divided by the number of retailers, for zip codes without a
Wal-Mart (see Figures 3a, 3b, 3g), with a Wal-Mart (see Figures 3c, 3d, 3h), and with an
adjacent Wal-Mart (see Figures 3e, 3f, 3i).
Entry and exit rates appear to have been comparable across the three settings during the
study period, although they were more varied in zip codes with or adjacent to a Wal-Mart.
This finding likely reflects the smaller number of observations for these locations,
particularly early in the observation period. Net entry rates were also similar, with the
exception of antique stores, which exhibited greater cumulative net entry rates in zip
codes without a Wal-Mart.
Figure 4 presents the data in a manner that is more comparable to those in Figure 1. For
each type of retailer, Figure 4 shows the entry, exit, and cumulative net entry rates for
zip codes experiencing (see Figures 4a, 4b, 4e) or adjacent to (see Figures 4c, 4d, 4f) a
Wal-Mart entry from the year before the entry to 10 years afterward.

4
In our sample, roughly 85 percent of the hair salons and antique stores had operated fewer than 10 years,
and 70 percent had operated fewer than 5 years. Among home furnishing stores and photo studios, roughly
80 percent had operated fewer than 10 years, and 65 percent had operated fewer than 5 years. In 2005, 51
percent of home furnishing stores employed fewer than 4 people, and 89 percent employed fewer than 20
people. Comparable figures are 82 percent and 97 percent for photo studios and 66 percent and 95 percent
for hair salons (U.S. Small Business Administration 2005).
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

(a) No Wal-Mart (b) No Wal-Mart


0.6
0.5

0.5
0.4
Founding Rate

0.4

Failure Rate
0.3
0.3

0.2
0.2

0.1 0.1

0 0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
Year Year
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

(c) Local Wal-Mart (d) Local Wal-Mart


0.6 0.5

0.5 0.4
Founding Rate

0.4

Failure Rate
0.3
0.3
0.2
0.2

0.1
0.1

0 0
217
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
Year Year
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


(e) Adjacent Wal-Mart (f) Adjacent Wal-Mart
0.6 0.5

0.5
0.4
Founding Rate

0.4
Failure Rate

0.3
0.3
0.2
0.2

0.1
0.1

0 0
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
Year Year
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

(g) No Wal-Mart (h) Local Wal-Mart


2.5 2

2 1.5
Cumulative Net Entry
Cumulative Net Entry

1.5 1

1 0.5

0.5 0

0 -0.5
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
Year Year
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

(i) Adjacent Wal-Mart


2

1.5
Cumulative Net Entry

0.5

-0.5
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004
Year
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

Figure 3. The founding and failure of retailers in zip codes with no, local, and adjacent Wal-Mart
stores.
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

(a) Local Wal-Mart (b) Local Wal-Mart


0.4 0.4

0.35 0.35

0.3 0.3
Founding Rate

Failure Rate
0.25 0.25

0.2 0.2

0.15 0.15

0.1 0.1

0.05 0.05

0 0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Time Since Wal-Mart Entry Time Since Wal-Mart Entry
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

(c) Adjacent Wal-Mart (d) Adjacent Wal-Mart


0.3 0.3

0.25 0.25

0.2
Founding Rate

0.2
Failure Rate

218 0.15 0.15

0.1 0.1

0.05 0.05

0 0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Time Since Wal-Mart Entry Time Since Wal-Mart Entry
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

(e) Local Wal-Mart (f) Adjacent Wal-Mart


0.2 0.2

0 0.1
Cumulative Net Entry Rate

Cumulative Net Entry Rate

-0.2 0

-0.4 -0.1

-0.6 -0.2

-0.8 -0.3

-1 -0.4

-1.2 -0.5

-1.4 -0.6
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Time Since Wal-Mart Entry Time Since Wal-Mart Entry
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

Figure 4. The founding and failure of retailers in zip codes with local and adjacentWal-Mart stores.

Entry rates for photo studios tended to decline, consistent with the expected effect of
a local entry on competing retailers, but the expected curvilinear pattern is not apparent.
For antique stores, the rate shows the expected curvilinear shape for noncompetitors, but
home furnishings did as well. Exit rates appear to have trended upward over the decade
following the entry of a local Wal-Mart, and for several types of retailers, particularly
photo studios and antique stores, they also appear to have followed a curvilinear pattern
similar to that in Figure 1. Relative to photo studios, the peak appeared later for antique
stores, which were expected to compete less directly with Wal-Mart. The peak was also
later for home furnishing stores but occurred at roughly the same time for beauty salons.5

5
Fitting linear and second-order polynomial trend lines to the data confirmed these conclusions.
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

The effects of an adjacent entry are more mixed. Entry rates tended to fall and exit rates
tended to rise for antique stores, while both rates tended to increase for photo studios.
Only the exit rates for photo studios followed a curvilinear pattern consistent with
Figure 1.
Overall, following the entry of a local Wal-Mart, antique stores, beauty salons, and photo
studios exhibited greater net entry than did home furnishing stores. Following an adjacent
entry, antique stores and beauty salons also experienced greater net entry than did photo
studios, but so did home furnishing retailers. Notably, yearly net entry was higher for
antique stores immediately following the entry of an adjacent rather than a local Wal-Mart;
in contrast, cumulative net entry was higher for photo studios following a local entry.Taken
together, the plots in Figure 3 suggest a relatively benign impact of Wal-Mart. Across types
of retailers, annual net entry rates in zip codes with a local Wal-Mart were, on average, 4
percent to 6 percent higher than in zip codes without either a local or an adjacent Wal-Mart,
and in locations with an adjacent Wal-Mart, they were zero to 2 percent higher.
Figure 3 is misleading, however. Wal-Mart does not locate its stores randomly; rather,
it places its stores in locations where it expects them to be most profitable, and these
locations should also be better for small retailers—but according to the figure, they are 219
only limitedly so. This finding suggests that net entry may be suppressed by competition
in locations with a local or adjacent Wal-Mart. What Figure 3 does not show is whether

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


net entry would be higher in zip codes with a local or adjacent Wal-Mart if the Wal-Mart
had not entered. Figure 4 is similarly biased, confounding competition from Wal-Mart
with variation in the character of zip codes that Wal-Mart locates within rather than
adjacent to.
To obtain a more accurate empirical assessment of Wal-Mart’s impact on the turnover
of small, independent retailers, we used multivariate econometric techniques that account
both for the characteristics of locations that may influence the entry and exit of indepen-
dent retailers as well as for the endogeneity in Wal-Mart’s choice of locations.

Methods
Dependent Variables and Estimation
Our dependent variables, the yearly number of entries and exits of independent retailers
in a zip code, were measured, respectively, as annual counts of registrations and dereg-
istrations of new ventures. From among the population of all independent retailers, we
distinguished specific types of retail businesses: home furnishings and photo studios,
which compete more directly with Wal-Mart, and beauty salons and antique stores, which
do not, to contrast the impact of Wal-Mart openings on these types of stores.
Because the yearly numbers of entries and exits are count variables, we used the
Poisson model,6 which provides a natural baseline for such processes (Hausman, Hall, and
Griliches 1984). The basic Poisson model for count data is

6
Geographically weighted regression (GWR) (e.g., Fotheringham, Brunsdon, and Charlton 1999) extends
traditional regression, permitting local, rather than global, parameters to be estimated. Although GWR is
intuitively appealing, it has two limitations that render it unsuitable for our purposes. The first is that it
requires specification of a matrix of geographic weights that specify the decay in the importance of data as
a function of distance. Unfortunately, we lack a theoretical basis from which to derive such weights for the
Wal-Mart effect. Moreover, it seems likely that the various factors in our empirical model are likely to
operate over different geographic ranges—some highly localized (e.g., retailer entries and exits) and others
over greater distances (e.g., Wal-Mart entries). The second, and more important in our setting, is that GWR
provides a single, weighted estimate of a given factor’s effect and thus would not permit us to distinguish
local (within zip code) and adjacent (within neighboring zip codes) effects of Wal-Mart entries. Given these
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Pr (Yt = y ) = exp λ ( xt )[ λ ( xt ) y y! ], (1)

where both the probability of a given number of events in an interval, Pr(Yt = y), and the
variance of the number of events in each interval equal the rate, l(xt). However, the
variance exceeds the mean in our data, and such overdispersion causes standard errors of
parameters to be underestimated and levels of statistical significance to be overstated.
Therefore, we used a negative binomial model, which takes such overdispersion into
account by relaxing the assumption that the conditional mean is equal to the variance. A
common formulation, which allows the Poisson process to include heterogeneity by
relaxing the assumption that the mean and variance are equal is
λt = exp ( π ′xt )εt , (2)

where the error term, et, follows a gamma distribution. The presence of et produces
overdispersion. The specification of overdispersion that we used takes the form

220 Var (Yt ) = E (Yt )[1 + αE (Yt )] (3)

We estimated a random-effects specification of this model to control for the risk of


unobserved heterogeneity, which a Hausman test (1978) indicated is appropriate for these
data.7

Independent Variables8
To estimate the local impact of the opening of a Wal-Mart on entries and exits in a given
zip code, we created an indicator variable, zip code Wal-Mart, coded 0 until a Wal-Mart
store opened in that zip code and 1 thereafter. To examine the dynamic effect of a local
entry, we used a clock variable, zip code time since Wal-Mart opened, to track the time
since a Wal-Mart opened in a zip code. We logged this clock in the analyses because we
expect the importance of a year passing to diminish over time (i.e., that the time from Year
1 to 2 is more important than from Year 11 to 12).
To model the effect of the opening of a Wal-Mart in an area adjacent to a given zip code,
we created a second indicator variable, adjacent zip code Wal-Mart, coded 0 until a
Wal-Mart store opened in a zip code whose population centroid was within five miles of
the focal zip code population centroid and 1 thereafter. We again used a clock (logged),
adjacent zip code time since Wal-Mart opened, to track the dynamic effect of a Wal-Mart
opening in an adjacent zip code.
Because a small number of zip codes in which Wal-Mart operated also had a Wal-Mart
operating in an adjacent zip code during the study period (see Figure 2), we also included
a zip code and adjacent zip code Wal-Mart indicator variable (coded 1 if this was the case
and 0 otherwise) to control for this effect and obtain accurate estimates for the local and
adjacent effects.9

limitations, we chose to operationalize the theoretically distinct local and adjacent spatial effects of
Wal-Mart entries using separate measures for within the same and adjacent zip codes to the focal retailers.
7
We also estimated models that included county dummy variables to account for the fact that there are
multiple zip codes within the same county. The findings are consistent with those reported later.
8
Detailed descriptions of the operationalization, measurement level, and sources for all of the study variables
are given in Appendix A, and descriptive statistics are presented in Appendix B.
9
We also estimated models that distinguish Wal-Mart’s standard and supercenter formats, the latter of which
are larger and more likely to offer a range of Wal-Mart-operated specialty shops (particularly grocery) and
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

Control Variables
Entries and exits of independent retail businesses in a zip code are affected by many
factors beyond openings of Wal-Mart stores, so we specified a detailed baseline model
to control for a range of such factors. Control variables were lagged one year to avoid
simultaneity problems.

Environmental munificence. Because the demand for and supply of retail busi-
nesses likely depends on local population and resource levels, for each zip code, we
included population, per capita income, governmental revenues, and intergovernmental
funds received for the county in which the zip code is located. We also included the
proportion of a county government’s infrastructure expenditures on human resource
development, economic development, and cultural activities, which likely influence the
supply of potential entrepreneurs and the survival of retailers. Because these data are not
available at the finer zip-code level, we assigned values for each county to all zip codes in
a county.10
Because metropolitan areas may differ in terms of opportunity and competitive struc-
ture (e.g., urbanization economies), we also included an indicator variable coded 1 for zip 221
codes located in metropolitan areas and 0 otherwise, to distinguish urban from rural areas

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


and to capture the increasing urbanization of particular areas over time. In addition, we
included the percentage of Democratic votes in presidential elections in the county in
which the zip code is located to capture differences in business dynamics arising from
political inclination. We interpolated the percentage linearly between elections.
We also included two macroeconomic factors to account for changing conditions in
the business environment broadly. Specifically, we included the Dow Jones Industrial
Average, aggregated at the annual level as an average for the whole year, to capture
investors’ sentiment and included a recession indicator variable, as defined by the
National Bureau of Economic Research (2008), to capture the level of business activity,
which could influence opportunities available for retailers.
Finally we included a calendar time clock to control for possible environmental trends
that may influence the rates of entry and exit of the different types of retailers (e.g., the
influence of digital photography on the fates of photographic studios or the popularity of
home makeover television programs on the fates of home furnishing stores).11

Local and adjacent business activity and turnover. The number and prior
turnover (i.e., entries and exits) of independent retailers operating in a particular area can
influence the availability and costs of resources in that area. These dynamics also provide
information to entrepreneurs about the feasibility of conducting business at a given
location. For example, certain types of retailers benefit from agglomeration economies
that accrue to organizations that locate close to each other (Graitson 1982). These
economies include shared infrastructure, notably transportation, communication, and
ease of supply, as well as reductions in consumer search costs, which increase demand at
a particular location, as with geographic clusters of antique shops, apparel, nightclubs,

alcove shops. Because this distinction rarely influenced founding and failure rates significantly and did not
alter our findings substantively, for parsimony, we do not consider it in the models reported here.
10
To check the robustness of our theoretical findings to this assignment, we reestimated our models after
(1) dropping the county-level variables and (2) adding county-level fixed effects. The estimates for the
alternative specifications are consistent with those reported later.
11
To permit more complex time variation than a linear trend, we also estimated models with year fixed effects
and obtained similar estimates for the theoretical variables.
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

theaters, restaurants, and hotels. Therefore, for each zip code, we included measures of the
number of retailers, as well as the number of entries and exits in the prior year.
Although the effects of these variables are likely to be strongest within retailer
categories, symbiotic clustering of differentiated sellers within shopping malls and
districts has also been discussed in terms of reduced consumer search and travel costs
(e.g., Stuart 1979). Therefore, for the analysis of each type of retailer, we included
separate counts of prior entries and exits and businesses for that type of retailer and all
other types (i.e., in the analysis of the entry and exit antique stores, we included counts
based on antique stores and all other types of businesses).12
The turnover of retailers can affect the age distribution of incumbents, which, in turn,
can influence the rates of entry of subsequent retailers, and particularly exits, since
younger retailers are more likely to fail. Therefore, our models also included separate
counts of the cumulative number of same-type retailer entries and exits that occurred in
a zip code since a Wal-Mart entered. Prior to a Wal-Mart entering a given zip code, we set
this variable to zero.
In addition to the number and turnover of businesses operating in the same zip code, we
222 included analogous variables for adjacent zip codes, as defined earlier. We included these
variables to account for the possible presence of spatial dependence in business activity.
To the extent that the turnover of retailers in one zip code is influenced by the level of
retailer activity and turnover in adjacent zip codes, we had to control for this dependence
to obtain unbiased coefficient estimates (LeSage and Pace 2004).
The attractiveness of particular locations can result in the clustering of “big box” retail
chains. If uncontrolled, such clustering may result in estimates that spuriously capture the
presence of large chain retailers in general, rather than Wal-Mart in particular. Therefore,
we obtained information on the locations and opening dates of Target and Home Depot
stores in Florida by contacting each store and created indicator variables, zip code Target
and zip code Home Depot and accompanying time clocks (logged) analogous to those
used to model the effect of Wal-Mart entries.

Endogeneity. Finally, we estimated our models controlling for endogeneity in the


choice of Wal-Mart store locations. Wal-Mart locates its stores in places where it expects
to be profitable, taking into consideration information about demand and cost factors, as
well as the competitive environment and how it is expected to evolve after Wal-Mart’s
entry. Holmes (2008) and Jia (2006) discussed various demographic factors that predict
Wal-Mart’s entry, such as the size and density of the population and the age and income
distributions. Slater (2003) suggested that Wal-Mart’s strategy was to locate in small
towns where the populations were increasing.
These and other variables that are more difficult to observe and measure tend to be
spatially correlated: urban counties are located near other urban counties, counties with a
given industrial composition tend to be located near other counties with a similar
composition, and so on. Such correlations partly explain why Wal-Mart stores tend to
locate near one another (Graff and Ashton 1994). On the basis of this logic, Neumark,
Zhang, and Ciccarella (2005) addressed endogeneity in Wal-Mart’s location decisions
using an interaction of time and distance of the stores to Wal-Mart’s corporate headquar-
ters in Bentonville, Arkansas. But Basker (2006) showed that this instrument does not
distinguish between counties with and without Wal-Mart stores.

12
The variables for all other types are based on all other businesses, not only on the four other types of
retailers on which we focus.
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

Because Wal-Mart stores are not randomly located, estimating Wal-Mart’s impact on
local markets without accounting for the endogeneity of Wal-Mart’s entry decisions is
subject to omitted variable and selection biases. If Wal-Mart tends to enter fast-growing
areas, then we might observe new retailers enter and few exit following a Wal-Mart’s
entry, even if the stores actually have negative effects. To account for such endogeneity, we
could adopt the popular instrumental variable approach. However, it has been shown that
this approach, while effective for linear regression systems, does not correct for endoge-
neity properly for nonlinear estimators (Davidson and MacKinnon 1993). For this reason,
Blundell and Powell (2003) and Villas-Boas and Winer (1999) proposed a control-
function approach. The endogenous variable, Wal-Mart store opened, is regressed against
exogenous instruments, and the residual from this regression, the endogeneity control
factor, is entered as an additional explanatory variable in failure and foundings analyses.
We found that local demographic factors, such as population, did not significantly predict
the opening of a Wal-Mart store, but local economic factors, including the number and
entries and exits of independent firms in a zip code, were significant predictors of the
entry of Wal-Mart. Although prior research has found that controlling for the endogeneity
of Wal-Mart store locations makes little difference in the results and has typically rejected 223
endogeneity (e.g., Hicks and Wilburn 2001; Graff 1998), using this approach, we found
strong endogeneity effects on both the entry and exit of all four types of retailers.

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


Results
Table 1 reports the random effect negative binomial regressions for the entry and exit
of each of the four types of independent retailers.13 In a preliminary analysis (unreported
to conserve space), we estimated the zip code Wal-Mart and zip code adjacent Wal-Mart
indicator variables, along with their associated time clocks, separately and together, and
without the zip code and adjacent zip code Wal-Mart indicator. Estimates for these
variables yield consistent results in the incremental models and do not differ substantively
from those we report in Table 1.14
The effects of a Wal-Mart store on the entry and exit of retailers in the same zip code
are estimated by the zip code Wal-Mart entry indicator and zip code time since Wal-Mart
opened clock variables, while the effects of a Wal-Mart store in neighboring zip codes on
the entry and exit of retailers are estimated by the adjacent zip code Wal-Mart entry
indicator and time since adjacent zip code opened.15 These effects from Table 1, plotted
in Figure 5, show estimated multipliers of the entry, exit, and net entry rates for each type
of retailer following a Wal-Mart entry in a local (see Figures 5a, 5c, and 5e) and adjacent
zip code (see Figures 5b, 5d, and 5f). The multipliers compare the estimated rate in the
year prior to the Wal-Mart entry (set equal to 0), to the estimated rate in each of the

13
The estimates of control variables are presented in Appendix C.
14
Since prior failures and prior foundings of the same type of retailer are significant in the foundings and
failures analyses, respectively, we were concerned that the errors may be correlated across the equations.
Therefore, we also estimated our models using seeming unrelated regression, a technique for analyzing a
system of multiple equations with cross-equation-correlated error terms. The results of these analyses were
consistent with those reported in the article.
15
To make the interpretation of regression results that include interaction coefficients easier, we examined
the effects of zip code Wal-Mart when adjacent zip code Wal-Mart entry was set to 0 and examined the
effects of adjacent zip code Wal-Mart entry when zip code Wal-Mart entry was set to 0. Another issue to
note is that when the interaction coefficient is significant, the significance of the main effects does not
matter in interpreting the effects. But when the interaction coefficient is not significant, the main effects
have to be interpreted according to their significance in the regression results.
224
Table 1
Random Effect Negative Binomial Regressions of the Four Types of Independent Retailers
Entries Exits

Furnishing Stores Beauty Salons Antique Stores Photo Studios Furnishing Stores Beauty Salons Antique Stores Photo Studios

Zip code Wal-Mart -.596** -.185 -.478* -.061 -.365** -.440** -.632* -.831**
(.116) (.121) (.231) (.233) (.132) (.142) (.271) (.296)
Zip code time since .251** .106* .293** .059 .262** .303** .433** .346**
Wal-Mart opened (.048) (.049) (.083) (.092) (.055) (.059) (.096) (.114)
Adjacent zip code Wal-Mart -.367** -.102 .078 .024 -.089 .090 .278* .265*
(.068) (.067) (.114) (.120) (.072) (.077) (.131) (.134)
Adjacent zip code time since .223** .140** .072 .165** .113** .100** .071 .035
Wal-Mart opened (.032) (.031) (.052) (.056) (.034) (.036) (.059) (.063)
Zip code and adjacent zip -.027 -.141 -.116 -.376* -.087 -.463** -.334 -.304
code Wal-Mart (.095) (.095) (.185) (.180) (.108) (.109) (.215) (.203)
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Log likelihood -25,172.9 -21,040.1 -11,980.8 -10,616.6 -18,555.9 -15,950.5 -9,191.9 -8,067.0
Wald chi-square 6,970.6 4,663.4 2,195.35 2,245.7 4,974.6 4,851.9 2,751.9 3,276.6
Notes: N = 40,050; number of unique zip codes = 1,602; standard errors in parentheses; + p < 0.10, * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01; two-tailed tests; estimates for control variables are presented in
Appendix C.
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

(a) Local Wal-Mart (b) Adjacent Wal-Mart


1.60 1.60

1.40 1.40

Estimated Founding
Estimated Founding

Rate Multiplier
Rate Multiplier

1.20 1.20

1.00 1.00

0.80 0.80

0.60 0.60

0.40 0.40
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Time Since Wal-Mart Entry Time Since Wal-Mart Entry
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

(c) Local Wal-Mart (d) Adjacent Wal-Mart


1.60 1.60

1.40 1.40
Estimated Failure

Estimated Failure
Rate Multiplier

Rate Multiplier
1.20 1.20

1.00 1.00

0.80 0.80

0.60 0.60 225


0.40 0.40

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Time Since Wal-Mart Entry Time Since Wal-Mart Entry
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

(e) Local Wal-Mart (f) Adjacent Wal-Mart


2.20 1.60
2.00
1.40
Estimated Net Entry

Estimated Net Entry

1.80
Rate Multiplier

Rate Multiplier

1.20
1.60
1.40 1.00
1.20
0.80
1.00
0.60
0.80
0.60 0.40
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Time Since Wal-Mart Entry Time Since Wal-Mart Entry
Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios Furnishings Salons Antiques Photo Studios

Figure 5. Regression estimates of the founding, failure, and net entry rates of retailers.

subsequent 10 years. In the figures, a multiplier of 2 indicates a doubling of the rate, and
a multiplier of 0.5 indicates a halving of the rate.

Entry Rates
Figure 5a shows the immediate drop in entry rates in a zip code following a Wal-Mart
entry for all retailers. The initial drops are dramatic for home furnishings and antique
stores and less so for beauty salons and photo studios. All these retailers, except photo
studios, have subsequent increases in entry rates and reach their pre-Wal-Mart entry rates
within 7 years. After 10 years, the founding rate of beauty salons has recovered to its
original pre-Wal-Mart entry rate, while home furnishing and antique stores rates are about
10 percent higher than the pre-Wal-Mart rates. For photo studios, the rate remains roughly
15 percent lower.
Figure 5b shows the large initial drop and subsequent increase in the entry rate of home
furnishing stores following the opening of a Wal-Mart in an adjacent zip code. After 5
years, the entry rate recovers, however; by 10 years, the rate exceeds the pre-Wal-Mart
levels by roughly 20 percent. The figure also shows the increase in the rates of entry of
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

photo studios and beauty salons over time, which, after 10 years, have increased by 50
percent and 38 percent, respectively. The entry rates of antique stores are unaffected by the
entry of a Wal-Mart store in an adjacent zip code.

Exit Rates
Figure 5c shows the immediate, often dramatic, drop and subsequent increase in exit
rates in a zip code following the entry of a Wal-Mart store for all four types of retailers.
After 10 years, the exit rate for photo studios remains marginally below its pre-Wal-Mart
rate, while the rates for all other types of retailers are higher than their pre-Wal-Mart rates:
home furnishings by 26 percent, beauty salons by 49 percent, and antique stores by 31
percent.
Figure 5d shows the initial drop and subsequent increase in exit rates for home
furnishing stores after a Wal-Mart opens in an adjacent zip code. After 3 years, home
furnishings returns to its preadjacent Wal-Mart level; after 10 years, the rate is about 17
percent higher. After an adjacent Wal-Mart entry, the exit rates of photo studios and
antique stores jump immediately (36 percent and 37 percent, respectively) and remain
226 substantially higher thereafter. The exit rate for beauty salons increases slowly and is 37
percent higher than its pre-Wal-Mart level after 10 years.

Net Entry Rates


We computed net entry multipliers as the entry rate multiplier divided by the exit rate
multiplier, so that if the entry rate multiplier is double (half) the exit rate multiplier, the
net entry multiplier is 2 (0.5). The net effects of the entry of Wal-Marts in local and
adjacent zip codes, depicted in Figures 5e and 5f, are interesting.
When a Wal-Mart opens in a zip code, net entry rates for home furnishings in that zip
code fall and continue to remain below their pre-Wal-Mart levels even 10 years after the
Wal-Mart entry. Net entry rates of beauty salons, antiques, and photo studios, although
initially higher, fall below their pre-Wal-Mart entry levels within 3 years for beauty salons
and antique stores and within 7 years for photo studios, and remain substantially below
these levels after 10 years.
When a Wal-Mart opens, the net entry rates in adjacent zip codes drop initially for all
four types of retailers, the most for antique stores and the least for beauty salons. After
10 years, the net entry rates of furnishing stores and beauty salons return to their
pre-Wal-Mart levels, and the rate is moderately higher for photo studios. Net entry does
not recover for antique stores.

Discussion
The reality of the Wal-Mart effect on independent retailers is more complex than
available theory and evidence led us to anticipate. The opening of a Wal-Mart store seems
to have varied effects on colocated and adjacent retailers, some of which diverged from
our theoretical expectations in Figure 1. In this section, we examine some of the notable
differences in the effects of opening Wal-Mart stores in local and adjacent zip codes on
entry, exit, and net entry patterns, in both the short and long term.

Wal-Mart Store in the Same Zip Code


When a Wal-Mart opened, the entry rates of all types of retailers in that zip code
followed a pattern that was expected of competitors: declining initially and then increas-
ing over time. While the product-competitor (home furnishings) had the largest initial
decline of nearly 50 percent, other types experienced substantial initial declines as well.
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

Over time, entry rates increased, however, rising above the pre-Wal-Mart levels after
seven years for all types of retailers except the service competitor (photo studios). Thus,
at least initially, potential entrepreneurs, even in noncompeting categories, were discour-
aged from entry by the presence of a local Wal-Mart store.
When a Wal-Mart opened, the exit rates of all types of retailers in the same zip code
followed a pattern that we expected of noncompeting retailers: declining initially and then
increasing over time. While the product-competitor (home furnishings) had the smallest
decline initially, the service-competitor (photo studios) had the largest initial decline. Exit
rates eventually rose above the pre-Wal-Mart levels for all types of retailers but after
different lengths of time. One explanation for this unexpected finding is that incumbent
retailers initially benefited from the increased traffic flow, but as consumers switched to
Wal-Mart over time, weaker retailers began to fail, increasing the exit rate. Another
explanation is that incumbent retailers respond to the entry of a Wal-Mart by emphasizing
service, expanding hours, strategically adapting operations and stock, and so on, and these
investments commit them to fight (rather than flee), suppressing the failure rate. Because
the success or failure of these new initiatives cannot be evaluated immediately, until a
sufficient amount of negative information about performance accumulates, incumbent 227
retailers are thus unlikely to exit and may even persist until considerable losses have been
incurred.

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


The net entry pattern for the product-competitor retailer (home furnishings) exhibited
the expected competitor pattern, but with an important difference: the initial drop in net
entry resulted primarily from suppression of the entry rate, rather than from the enhanced
exit rate. Net entry patterns for noncompetitors (antique stores and photo studios) and,
surprisingly, for the service-competitor (photo studios) exhibited the noncompetitor
pattern for the same reason, although over time exit rates for these retailers rose well
above their entry rates.

Wal-Mart Store in an Adjacent Zip Code


The entry rate patterns in locations where Wal-Mart opened a store in an adjacent zip
code bear little resemblance to those shown in Figure 1. We expected entry rates for all
types of retailers to decline steadily over time, with higher declines for competitors than
for noncompetitors. Entry rates increased over time for the competitor service (photo
studios) and for the noncompetitor service (beauty salons), rather than decreased, and the
entry rate for the noncompetitor product (antique stores) was unaffected by the arrival of
a Wal-Mart in an adjacent zip code. Only the product competitor (home furnishings)
exhibited the expected decline in the entry rate, albeit with one difference: the effect was
stronger initially, rather than developing over time, and the entry rate recovered to its
pre-Wal-Mart level after about five years.
We anticipated a steady increase in exit rates over time for all types of retailers in zip
codes adjacent to a Wal-Mart store location, with higher increases for competitors than
noncompetitors. The noncompetitor service (beauty salons) exhibited this pattern. The
product competitor (home furnishing) did as well, although the rate unexpectedly
declined initially. Rather than increasing over time, the exit rates for the competitor
service (photo studios) and the noncompetitor product (antique stores) both jumped
initially and remained well above their pre-Wal-Mart levels.
Despite the divergence patterns of entry and (to a lesser extent) exit, net entry patterns
in zip codes adjacent to a Wal-Mart store resemble the predictions in Figure 1. However,
rather than declining over time, the net entry patterns for all types of retailers showed high
initial drops, driven primarily by high exit rates except in the case of the product
competitor (home furnishings). The drop persisted for the noncompetitor product (antique
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

stores). For the other types of retailers, the net entry rate eventually recovered to the
pre-Wal-Mart levels, driven by entry rates increasing faster than exit rates except in the
case of the noncompetitor product (antique stores).

Conclusion
Motivated, in part, by local policy debates over the opening of Wal-Mart stores and, in
part, by the large size of Wal-Mart relative to the retail sector, researchers have started to
explore some of the effects of the entry of Wal-Marts, for example, on labor markets,
consumer prices, and competitors’ earnings (for a review, see Basker 2007). These studies
are becoming increasingly sophisticated and conclusive. However, little rigorous empiri-
cal work has directly examined how Wal-Mart stores affect the entrepreneurial entry and
fates of small, independent retailers. That is our focus.
Our analyses and findings advance understanding of the Wal-Mart effect for small
independent retailers in several important ways. First, whereas past studies typically
focused on changes in the number of retailers in a given location, this change is the net
228 result of retailers’ entries and exits. Consequently, we distinguished entry and exit
processes, the engine of creative destruction (Schumpeter 1942), to enhance our under-
standing of the underlying dynamics. Second, earlier studies typically focused exclusively
on the effect of Wal-Mart on competing retailers, but overlooked its effect on noncom-
peting retailers (for an exception, see Basker’s 2005a examination of employment). In
contrast, we examined the effects of Wal-Mart store openings on four types of stores:
competitors and noncompetitors in products and services. Our findings indicate not only
that entry and exit processes are affected differently by competition from Wal-Mart, but
also that the effects of Wal-Mart on the entry and exit of retailers differ by the type of
retailer, in terms of the degree of competition and whether the competition is in the
product or service category.
Third, few earlier studies examined how the effect of competition from Wal-Mart varies
with distance. Yet the question of distance seems crucial to the policy debate at the
municipal level. Our findings tend to support the view that it is better to have a Wal-Mart
open in one’s own than in a neighboring jurisdiction. At the local zip code level, across
retailer categories, a competitive Wal-Mart effect emerges but, unexpectedly, not as a
result of exit rates rising, rather, as a result of entry rates falling below the level necessary
to maintain retailer numbers. These findings are consistent with the idea that the presence
of a Wal-Mart erodes local social capital and reduces the local class of entrepreneurs
(Goetz and Swaminathan 2006). In adjacent locations, both entry and exit rates rise, but
the exit rate increases more, resulting in a net decline in independent retailers. Contrary
to the view that the arrival of a Wal-Mart store forces smaller independent retailers out of
business, our results thus indicate that the local Wal-Mart effect results more from a
“scaring off” of potential entrants than from a “killing off” of incumbents. In adjacent
locations, however, the Wal-Mart effect does indeed “kill off” incumbents; however, it
does not (unfortunately) “scare off” potential entrants.
Finally, our study contributes to an understanding of the dynamic nature of the
Wal-Mart effect over time. Locally, short- and longer-term effects tended to differ. When
a Wal-Mart store opened, retailer entry and effect rates both tended to fall initially.
However, these patterns reversed over the longer term, with both entry and exit rates
increasing above their pre–Wal-Mart levels. This increase in the turnover of retailers over
time suggests the emergence of a more dynamic competitive environment proximate to
Wal-Mart. The effects of a Wal-Mart opening on retailers in adjacent locations are more
consistent over time, however, with entry and exit rates rising above pre-Wal-Mart levels
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

initially and remaining higher over time. The transitions in the local Wal-Mart effect merit
further attention. One possibility is that potential entrants wait to observe consumers’
reactions to incumbents’ efforts to adapt and begin to enter only after successful adapta-
tions (if any) become apparent.
Are these patterns of retailers’ entry and exit over time consistent with the view of
Wal-Mart as an agent of creative destruction? Or just of destruction? Within zip codes, we
anticipated that negative net entry for retailers competing with Wal-Mart would create
opportunities for noncompeting retailers to enter and replace them. This pattern indeed
occurred, at least initially, with beauty salons and antique stores exhibiting positive net
entry at the expense of home furnishing stores. However, it resulted not from competing
retailers exiting and noncompeting retailers replacing them but from the competing
retailers being deterred more strongly than the noncompeting retailers from entering. In
adjacent zip codes, we expected negative net entry rates for both competing and non-
competing retailers as exit rates rose and entry rates fell. Although net entry is indeed
predominantly negative, particularly shortly after a Wal-Mart entry, this is not the result
of entry being deterred but, rather, of incumbent exits rising more than entrepreneurial
entries. At the local level, these findings suggest a weak form of creative destruction that 229
is driven by the relative deterrence of entry, rather than by the exit of competing retailers
creating opportunities for new noncompeting retailers. The process in adjacent locations

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


is, however, largely one of destruction. Indeed, given the increased exit rates, the added
entrepreneurial activity in adjacent locations appears unfortunate and ill fated.
But are these shifts in types of retailers beneficial or harmful to the communities in
which Wal-Mart locates? In this regard, we observed that the retailers that are most likely
to exit and be deterred from entry tend to offer staple and basic household goods. In
contrast, those that are most likely to remain open and are prompted to enter tend to offer
discretionary or luxury goods that Wal-Mart does not. Such a shift in retailers’ offerings
has both positive and negative consequences. On the one hand, it tends to diversify the
local retailer base, offering local communities a broader range of goods and services. The
higher service and skill levels that are characteristic of retailers of discretionary and
luxury goods may also increase employment and wages. On the other hand, purveyors of
discretionary and luxury goods and services are typically most vulnerable to economic
downturns, which may destabilize local economies. Whether these new businesses are
in some way “superior” or “inferior” to those they replaced is difficult to determine more
generally. Wal-Mart thus appears to have mixed consequences for the local retail
economy. Nevertheless, it has a decidedly negative effect on adjacent locations. As we
already noted, little good comes to local retailers from a Wal-Mart entering a neighboring
community.
Two important limitations of our analysis—and opportunities for future research—are
noted. First, we confined our analysis to the one retail category in each of the four types
of competitors (i.e., competitors and noncompetitors in products and services) in Florida.
Because Wal-Mart’s effect may differ across states owing to variation in state policies,
demographics, and socioeconomics, it would be useful to examine and compare findings
for the same retail categories in additional states. It would also be useful to determine
whether additional retail categories of the same type (e.g., restaurants versus beauty
salons or hardware stores versus home furnishing stores) exhibit similar local and
adjacent responses. Second, our data did not allow us to examine changes in the overall
composition of retailers in local and adjacent areas following the arrival of Wal-Mart
stores. Although the anecdotal evidence suggests it, capturing broad changes in business
composition faces the challenge of compiling data to track the composition of businesses
over time. We hope that future work will address these issues.
230
Appendix A
Description and Measurement of the Study Variables
Variable Description Level Data Source

1. Different store type entries Number of store entries in (t + 1) of that type Zip code Florida Department of State
2. Different store type exits Number of store firms ceased to exist in (t + 1) of that type Zip code Florida Department of State
3. Zip code probability of Wal-Mart opening Probability of store opening in a zip code in the year Zip code-year Calculated from regression
4. Year Calendar year Annual
5. Dow Jones Index Average annual index Annual Yahoo! Financials
6. Recession Indicator variable Annual NBER
7. County population County population in t County Census Bureau
8. County per capita Income County per capita income in t County Census Bureau
9. County revenues Total county revenue in millions of dollars in t County County governments
10. County intergovernmental funds % of county revenue from state and federal governments in t County County governments
11. County human resources expenses % of expenses on improving human resources in t County County governments
12. County economic environment development % of expenses on improving economic environment in t County County governments
expenses
13. County cultural expenses % of expenses on cultural and recreation in t County County governments
14. County % Democrats % of votes for Democrat candidates in t County Florida Election Board
15. Metropolitan area Indicator variable Zip code Census Bureau
16. Zip code same store type density Number of stores in the area in t of that type Zip code Florida Department of State
17. Zip code same store type prior exits Number of similar stores in the area that exited in t Zip code Florida Department of State
18. Zip code same store type prior entries Number of similar stores in the area that entered in t Zip code Florida Department of State
19. Zip code cumulative same type exits Number of similar stores in the area that exited since Wal-Mart entered Zip code Florida Department of State
20. Zip code cumulative same type entries Number of similar stores in the area that entered since Wal-Mart entered Zip code Florida Department of State
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

21. Zip code other store density Number of businesses in the area in t of the nonfocal type Zip code Florida Department of State
22. Zip code other store type prior exits Number of stores of the nonfocal type in the area that exited in t Zip code Florida Department of State
23. Zip code other store type prior entries Number of stores of the nonfocal type that entered in the area in t Zip code Florida Department of State
24. Adjacent zip code same store type density Number of stores in adjacent areas in t of that type Zip code Florida Department of State
25. Adjacent zip code same store type prior exits Number of similar stores in adjacent areas that exited in t Zip code Florida Department of State
26. Adjacent zip code same store type prior entries Number of similar stores in adjacent areas that entered in t Zip code Florida Department of State
27. Adjacent zip code other store density Number of businesses in adjacent areas in t of the nonfocal type Zip code Florida Department of State
28. Adjacent zip code other store type prior exits Number of stores of the nonfocal type in adjacent areas that exited in t Zip code Florida Department of State
29. Adjacent zip code other store type prior entries Number of stores of the nonfocal type that entered in adjacent areas in t Zip code Florida Department of State
30. Zip code Wal-Mart/Target/Home Depot 1 if Wal-Mart/Target/Home Depot opened a store in the same zip code Zip code Respective retail stores
31. Zip code time since Wal-Mart/Target/Home Depot Log (time since Wal-Mart/Target/Home Depot opened in the same zip code) Zip code Respective retail stores
opened
32. Adjacent zip code Wal-Mart 1 if Wal-Mart was opened in an adjacent zip code (centroid < 5 miles) Zip code Wal-Mart and Census Bureau
33. Adjacent zip code time since Wal-Mart opened Log(clock since Wal-Mart opened in an adjacent zip code) Zip code Wal-Mart and Census Bureau
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

Appendix B
Summary Statistics
Standard Standard
Variable Mean Deviation Variable Mean Deviation

Dependent Variable: Entries Zip code other type entries


Furnishings 0.49 1.34 Furnishings 67.01 146.19
Beauty salons 0.40 1.07 Beauty salons 67.11 146.30
Antique stores 0.15 0.60 Antique stores 67.37 146.85
Photo studios 0.12 0.44 Photo studios 67.40 146.81
Dependent Variable: Exits Zip code other type exits
Furnishings 0.33 0.98 Furnishings 47.79 110.89
Beauty salons 0.27 0.84 Beauty salons 47.85 110.94
Antique stores 0.10 0.46 Antique stores 48.03 111.37
Photo studios 0.09 0.39 Photo studios 48.05 111.33
Zip code environmental factors Adjacent zip code same type density
Selection factor 0.06 0.24 Furnishings 12.82 34.73
Year 1992 7.21 Beauty salons 11.29 31.56
Dow Jones Index 4.32 3.40 Antique stores 2.90 8.38 231
Recession 0.20 0.40 Photo studios 3.71 10.68
County population 0.55 0.56 Adjacent zip code same type prior entries

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


County per capita income 18.91 7.64 Furnishings 3.06 8.79
Country revenue 726.51 474.39 Beauty salons 2.68 7.73
County intergovernment funds 0.22 0.10 Antique stores 0.73 2.18
County HR expenses 0.08 0.07 Photo studios 0.80 2.47
County economic environment 0.04 0.04 Adjacent zip code same type prior exits
County cultural expenses 0.05 0.04 Furnishings 2.36 7.04
County % Democrats 0.50 0.10 Beauty salons 2.06 6.28
Metropolitan Area 0.39 0.49 Antique stores 0.57 1.78
Zip code same type density Photo studios 0.66 2.17
Furnishings 2.12 4.48 Adjacent zip code other type density
Beauty salons 1.75 3.97 Furnishings 1781.23 5005.15
Antique stores 0.64 2.25 Beauty salons 1782.76 5007.09
Photo studios 0.56 1.50 Antique stores 1791.16 5031.02
Zip code same type prior entries Photo studios 1790.35 5027.17
Furnishings 0.52 1.37 Adjacent zip code other type prior entries
Beauty salons 0.41 1.09 Furnishings 407.03 1157.70
Antique stores 0.15 0.61 Beauty salons 407.41 1158.32
Photo studios 0.12 0.45 Antique stores 409.36 1164.04
Zip code same type prior exits Photo studios 409.29 1163.40
Furnishings 0.35 1.01 Adjacent zip code other type prior exits
Beauty salons 0.30 0.88 Furnishings 312.29 929.74
Antique stores 0.11 0.48 Beauty salons 312.60 930.32
Photo studios 0.09 0.40 Antique stores 314.09 934.86
Zip code other type density Photo studios 313.99 934.25
Furnishings 304.59 690.08 Zip code/Adjacent zip code Wal-Mart
Beauty salons 304.97 690.26 Zip code Wal-Mart opened 0.06 0.23
Antique stores 306.07 692.42 Time since zip code Wal-Mart opened 0.12 0.50
Photo studios 306.15 692.17 Adjacent zip code Wal-Mart opened 0.20 0.40
Zip code Target/Home Depot Adjacent zip code time since Wal-Mart 0.43 0.90
Target 0.02 .13
Time since Target opened 0.031 .246
Home Depot 0.02 .13
Time since Home Depot opened 0.032 .245
Notes: N = 40,050.
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Appendix C
Random Effect Negative Binomial Regressions of Independent Retailers—Control Variable Estimates
Entries Exits

Furnishing Beauty Antique Photo Furnishing Beauty Antique Photo


Stores Salons Stores Studios Stores Salons Stores Studios

Endogeneity control .471** .320** .445** .587** .407** .563** .682** .769**
factor (.083) (.090) (.170) (.166) (.099) (.107) (.196) (.198)
Year .174** .150** -.001 -.264** -.117** -.062* -.162** -.118**
(.025) (.027) (.037) (.039) (.025) (.029) (.040) (.042)
Dow Jones Index -.099** -.041** -.007 -.007 -.088** -.057** .041* -.092**
(.010) (.010) (.017) (.018) (.011) (.012) (.019) (.022)
Recession -.042+ .009 -.013 -.009 .002 .045 .008 .051
(.024) (.024) (.041) (.041) (.025) (.028) (.046) (.047)
County population .170* .569** .083 .607** .186* .573** .088 .375**
(.073) (.089) (.096) (.094) (.074) (.085) (.097) (.095)
County per capita .098** .182** .211** .263** .117** .144** .127** .241**
232 income (.021) (.023) (.027) (.032) (.023) (.025) (.029) (.033)
County revenues .000** .000 -.000 .000 .000** .000 -.000 .000
(.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000) (.000)
County .854** -.533* -1.539** -1.349** -1.796** -1.269** -5.568** -1.256**
intergovernmental (.232) (.257) (.414) (.392) (.256) (.300) (.499) (.446)
funds
County human resources -1.114** -.501+ -2.066** -2.198** -1.137** -2.029** -2.214** -2.007**
expenses (.269) (.280) (.508) (.461) (.283) (.347) (.548) (.517)
County economic 1.106** .119 .238 .711 1.366** .153 1.157 1.381+
environmental (.388) (.427) (.721) (.646) (.436) (.502) (.878) (.761)
expenses
County cultural 1.814** 1.029** 1.916** .755 .023 .686 -.025 .536
expenses (.345) (.377) (.482) (.623) (.398) (.447) (.627) (.717)
County % Democratic -1.308** -1.295** -1.345** -1.094** -.817** -1.191** -.547 -.885*
presidential votes (.197) (.207) (.316) (.316) (.206) (.238) (.352) (.355)
Zip code same store .224** .054** .054** .130** .651** .399** .365** .508**
type density (.013) (.009) (.010) (.013) (.014) (.010) (.012) (.016)
Zip code same store .133** .109** .140** .150** -.025** -.041** -.003 -.074**
type prior deaths (.004) (.003) (.006) (.005) (.004) (.004) (.006) (.007)
Zip code same store .044** .111** .128** .144** .028** .448** .377** .345**
type prior foundings (.004) (.012) (.012) (.012) (.005) (.014) (.014) (.016)
Zip code other types .071** .056** .219** .132** -.058** -.039** .203** -.058**
density (.007) (.007) (.018) (.011) (.009) (.009) (.022) (.013)
Zip code other types .077** .071** .138** .097** .087** .063** .143** .068**
prior deaths (.006) (.006) (.013) (.010) (.007) (.007) (.015) (.011)
Zip code other types .048** .045** .065** .043** .038** .011* .040** .022**
prior foundings (.004) (.004) (.007) (.006) (.004) (.005) (.008) (.007)
Adjacent zip codes same .043+ -.061** .166** .121** -.027 -.166** .122** .146**
type density (.023) (.023) (.028) (.033) (.025) (.025) (.028) (.032)
Adjacent zip codes same -.016** -.010** .036** .005 -.023** -.005 .059** -.010
type prior foundings (.004) (.004) (.009) (.007) (.004) (.004) (.009) (.008)
Adjacent zip codes same -.035** -.012** -.001 -.002 -.018** .004 .063** .007
type prior deaths (.004) (.004) (.009) (.007) (.004) (.004) (.010) (.007)
Adjacent zip codes other -.110** .019+ .060** .010 -.033** -.004 .212** -.012
types density (.010) (.010) (.023) (.010) (.010) (.011) (.024) (.012)
Adjacent zip codes other -.097** -.035** -.020 -.054** -.031** .037** .002 -.011
types prior deaths (.007) (.006) (.013) (.010) (.007) (.007) (.015) (.011)
Adjacent zip codes other -.023** -.016** -.056** -.025** .008 -.018** -.029** -.002
types prior foundings (.005) (.004) (.008) (.007) (.005) (.005) (.009) (.009)
(Continued on next page)
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

Appendix C
Random Effect Negative Binomial Regressions of Independent Retailers—Control Variable Estimates
(Continued)

Entries Exits

Furnishing Beauty Antique Photo Furnishing Beauty Antique Photo


Stores Salons Stores Studios Stores Salons Stores Studios

Cumulative same type -.024** -.007 .033** .106** -.059** -.063** -.047** -.036**
foundings since (.006) (.005) (.005) (.009) (.007) (.006) (.007) (.010)
Wal-Mart opened
Cumulative same type -.060** -.059** -.012+ -.023** .038** -.023** -.090** -.002
deaths since Wal-Mart (.004) (.005) (.007) (.007) (.005) (.007) (.007) (.008)
opened
Zip code in metropolitan .800** .921** .345** .630** .833** .906** .301** .621**
area (.071) (.091) (.083) (.079) (.070) (.078) (.075) (.071)
Zip code Target .000 .142* .135 -.033 -.013 .048 .141 .181
(.073) (.067) (.116) (.131) (.081) (.081) (.127) (.143)
Zip code time since .012 -.008 -.051** .016 .021* .017 -.032+ -.004 233
Target opened (.009) (.009) (.016) (.018) (.010) (.011) (.017) (.020)

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


Zip code Home Depot -.165** .041 -.075 .074 -.007 -.064 .345** .123
(.057) (.055) (.106) (.109) (.060) (.065) (.118) (.121)
Zip code time since .013 .003 .015 .008 -.033** -.036** -.068** -.010
Home Depot opened (.008) (.008) (.015) (.016) (.009) (.010) (.019) (.019)
Constant .468** 2.146** 1.386** 3.189 2.195** 13.682 2.040** 13.518**
(.128) (.247) (.229) (1.950) (.384) (216.4) (.422) (.214)
Notes: N = 40,050; number of unique zip codes = 1,602; standard errors in parentheses; + p < 0.10, * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01;
two-tailed tests.

Acs, Z., ed. 1999. Are small firms important? Their role and impact. New York: Springer.
Artz, G. M., and McConnon, J. C., Jr. 2001. The impact of Wal-Mart on host towns
references

and surrounding communities in Maine. Paper presented at the meeting of the


Northeast Agricultural and Resource Economics Association, Bar Harbor, Maine,
10–12 June.
Basker, E. 2005a. Job creation or destruction? Labor-market effects of Wal-Mart
expansion. Review of Economics and Statistics 8:174–83.
———. 2005b. Selling a cheaper mousetrap:Wal-Mart’s effect on retail prices. Journal of
Urban Economics 58: 203–29.
———. 2006. When good instruments go bad: A reply to Neumark, Zhang, and
Ciccarella. Social Science Research Network,Working Paper Series.Available online:
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=980988
———. 2007. The causes and consequences of Wal-Mart’s growth. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 21:177–98.
Bernstein, J., and Bivens, L. J. 2006. The Wal-Mart debate:A false choice between prices
and wages. Economic Policy Institute, Issue Brief 223, 15 June.
Blundell, R., and Powell, J. L. 2003. Endogeneity in semiparametric binary response
models. Working Paper. Centre for Microdata Methods and Practice, Institute for
Fiscal Studies, Department of Economics, University of California, Los Angeles.
Davidson, R., and MacKinnon, J. G. 1993. Estimation and inference in econometrics. New
York: Oxford University Press.
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Dean, A. M., and Sobel, R. S. 2008. Has Wal-Mart buried mom and pop? The impact of Wal-Mart
on self-employment and small establishments in the United States. Economic Inquiry 46:676–95.
Dube, A.; Lester, T. W.; and Eidlin, B. 2007. Firm entry and wages: Impact of Wal-
Mart growth on earnings throughout the retail sector. Social Science Research Network,
Working Paper Series. Available online: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_
id=841684
Fotheringham, A. S.; Brunsdon, C. F.; and Charlton, M. E. 1999. Geographically weighted regression:
A natural evolution of the expansion method for spatial data analysis. Environment and Planning
A 30:1905–27.
Franklin, A.W. 2001. The impact of Wal-Mart supercenters on supermarket concentration in U.S.
metropolitan areas. Agribusiness 17:105–14.
Freeman, R. 2003. Wal-Mart collapses U.S. cities and towns. Executive Intelligence Review
30(45). Available online: http://www.larouchepub.com/other/2003/3045Wal-Mart_iowa.
html
Goetz, S. J., and Swaminathan, H. 2006. Wal-Mart and county-wide poverty. Social Sciences
Quarterly 87:211–26.
234 Graff, T. O. 1998. The locations of Wal-Mart and Kmart supercenters: Contrasting corporate
strategy. Professional Geographer 50:46–57.
Graff, T. O., and Ashton, D. 1994. Spatial diffusion ofWal-Mart: Contagious and reverse hierarchical
elements. Professional Geographer 46:19–29.
Graitson, D. 1982. Spatial competition à la hotelling: A selective survey. Journal of Industrial
Economics 31:13–25.
Guy, C. 1996. Corporate strategies in food retailing and their local impacts:A case study of Cardiff.
Environment and Planning A 28:1575–602.
Hausman, J. A. 1978. Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica 46:1251–71.
Hausman, J. A.; Hall, B. H.; and Griliches, Z. 1984. Econometric models for count data with an
application to the patents–R&D relationship. Econometrica 52:909–38.
Hicks, M. J., and Wilburn, K. 2001. The regional impact of Wal-Mart entrance:A panel study of the
retail trade sector in West Virginia. Review of Regional Studies 31:305–13.
———. 2007. Job turnover and wages in the retail sector:The influence of Wal-Mart. Journal of
Private Enterprise 23:137–60.
Holmes, T. 2008. The diffusion of Wal-Mart and economies of density. Working Paper W13783.
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass. Available online: http://papers.ssrn.
com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1091418
Huff, D. L. 1963. A probabilistic analysis of shopping center trade areas. Land Economics 39:81–90.
———. 1964. Defining and estimating a trading area. Journal of Marketing 28:34–38.
Jarmin, R. S.; Klimek, S. D.; and Miranda, J. 2004. Firm entry and exit in the U.S. retail sector:
1977–1997. Unpublished paper, U.S. Census Bureau,Washington, D.C.
Jia, P. 2006. What happens when Wal-Mart comes to town:An empirical analysis of the discount
retailing industry. Working paper, Department of Economics,Yale University.
Ketchum,B. A.,and Hughes,J. W. 2004.Wal-Mart and Maine:The effect on employment and wages.
Maine Business Indicators 42(2). Available online: http://www.usm.maine.edu/cber/mbi/
summer97/hughes.htm
Lakshmanan, T. R., and Hansen, W. G. 1965. A retail market potential model. Journal of American
Institute of Planners 31:134–43.
LeSage, J. P., and Pace, R. K., eds. 2004. Introduction to advances in econometrics. In Spatial
and spatiotemporal econometrics, Vol. 18, ed. J. P. LeSage and R. K. Pace, 1–32. Oxford, U.K.:
Elsevier.
Vol. 85 No. 2 2009

Marsden, T., and Wrigley, N. 1996. Retailing, the food system and the regulatory state. In Retailing,
consumption and capital:Towards the new retail geography, ed. N. Wrigley and M. Lowe, 33–47.
Harlow, U.K.: Addison Wesley Longman.
McGee, J. E., and Gresham, G. G. 1995. When Wal-Mart comes to town: A look at how local
merchants respond to the retailing giant’s arrival. Journal of Business and Entrepreneurship
8:43–52.
National Bureau of Economic Research. 2008. Business cycle expansions and contractions.
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass. Available online: http://www.nber.
org/cycles/main.html
Neumark, D.; Zhang, J.; and Ciccarella, S. 2005. The effects of Wal-Mart on local labor markets.
Working Paper 11782. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass. Available
online: http://papers.nber/papers/w11782
Quinn, B. 2005. How Wal-Mart is destroying America and the world: And what you can do about it.
Berkeley, Calif.: Ten Speed Press.
Robbins, D. K.; Pantuosco, L. J.; Parker, D. F.; and Fuller, B. K. 2000. An empirical assessment of the
contribution of small business employment to U.S. state economic performance. Small Business
Economics 15:293–302. 235
Rosen, R. 2003. The great Wal-Mart wars. San Francisco Chronicle, 30 June. Available online:

THE WAL-MART EFFECT


http://www.foodandfarm.org/agribusiness_records.cfm?nID=133
Schulz, D. P. 2006. The nation’s retail power players 2006. Stores, July.
Schumpeter, J. A. 1942. Socialism, capitalism, and democracy. New York: Harper [Reprint 1975].
Sheppard, L., and White, M. 2005. Flatspace: Exurbanism and infrastructural landscape. Architectural
Journal 9:126–37.
Shields, M., and Kures, M. 2007. Black out of the blue light: An analysis of K-Mart store closing
decisions. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 14:259–68.
Singh, V. P.; Hansen, K. T.; and Blattberg, R. C. 2006. Market entry and consumer behavior: An
investigation of a Wal-Mart supercenter. Marketing Science 25:457–76.
Slater, R. 2003. The Wal-Mart decade: How a generation of leaders turned Sam Walton’s legacy into the
world’s #1 company. New York: Portfolio.
Stone, K. E. 1995. Impact of Wal-Mart stores and other mass merchandisers in Iowa, 1983–1993.
Economic Development Review 13(2):60–69.
———. 1997. Impact of the Wal-Mart phenomenon on rural communities. In Increasing under-
standing of public problems and policies, 189–200. Oak Brook, Ill.: Farm Foundation. Available
online: http://Wal-Martwatch.com/img/documents/iowa_farm_study.pdf
Stone, K.; Artz, G.; and Myles, A. 2002. The economic impact ofWal-Mart supercenters on existing
businesses in Mississippi. Office of Social and Economic Trends Analysis, Iowa State University.
Available online: http://www.seta.iastate.edu/retail/publications/ms_supercenterstudy.pdf
Stuart, C. 1979. Search and the spatial organization of trading. In Studies in the economics of search,
ed. S. Lippman and J. J. McCall, 17–34. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Thomas, C. J., and Bromley, R. D. F. 2002. The changing competitive relationship between a small
town centre and out-of-town retailing:Town revival in South Wales. Urban Studies 39:791–817.
U.S. Small Business Administration. 2005. Firm size data. Small Business Administration, Office of
Advocacy,Washington, D.C. Available online: http://www.sba.gov/advo/research/data.html
Vias, A. C. 2004. Bigger stores, more stores, or no stores: Paths of retail restructuring in rural
America. Journal of Rural Studies 20:303–18.
Villas-Boas, M. J., and Winer, R. S. 1999. Endogeneity in brand choice models. Management Science
45:1324–38.
Waite, D. 1973. The economic significance of small firms. Journal of Industrial Economics 21:154–66.
ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Wrigley, N. 1996. Sunk costs and corporate restructuring: British food retailing and the property
crisis. In Retailing, consumption and capital:Towards the new retail geography, ed. N. Wrigley and M.
S. Lowe, 116–36. Harlow, U.K.: Addison Wesley Longman.
———. 1998. Understanding store development programmes in post-property-crisis UK food
retailing. Environment and Planning A 30:15–35.
Wrigley, N. 2000. The globalization of retail capital:Themes for economic geography. In The Oxford
handbook of economic geography, ed. G. L. Clark, M. P. Feldman, and M. S. Gertler, 292–314. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Zhu, T.; Singh, V.; and Dukes, A. 2005. Local competition and impact of entry by a dominant retailer.
Unpublished paper, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, Penn.

236

View publication stats

You might also like