Kumar 2018

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Food Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/foodpol

Does cooperative membership improve household welfare? Evidence T


from a panel data analysis of smallholder dairy farmers in Bihar, India

Anjani Kumara, , Sunil Saroja, P.K. Joshia, Hiroyuki Takeshimab
a
International Food Policy Research Institute, South Asia Office, New Delhi, India
b
International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC, USA

1. Introduction This paper aims to contribute to the growing literature on the role,
which dairy cooperatives play in agricultural development by identi-
The promotion of cooperatives is widely viewed as the most im- fying the factors that influence dairy farmers’ decisions to join a dairy
portant institutional arrangement for spurring dairy development in cooperative, and by estimating the impact of dairy cooperative mem-
India. The Indian government has made efforts to accelerate the sys- bership on milk yield,2 net returns per liter, and compliance with FSM.
tematic promotion of dairy cooperatives through financial and policy The study uses panel data from 148 dairy farmers in Bihar, one of the
support, especially following the launch of Operation Flood in 1970.1 most important milk-producing states in India, for empirical analysis.
Indeed, much of the success of the White Revolution in India—the It is important to understand the factors that affect farmers’ deci-
greatly accelerated growth in the country’s milk production since the sions to join the cooperatives, and to incorporate such mechanisms into
1970s—is attributed to the cooperative framework of these dairy de- estimations of the impact of cooperatives. As Section 2 of this paper
velopment strategies. The network of dairy cooperatives has expanded describes, despite the findings of positive impacts in the aforemen-
considerably since then, and in 2015–16 about 16 million dairy farmers tioned studies, Indian dairy cooperatives’ shares of milk production and
(approximately 20 percent of India’s dairy farmers) were associated marketing have remained modest. Information on the returns to joining
with 180,000 dairy cooperative societies (NDDB, 2016). Nonetheless, cooperatives may have been limited, discouraging certain farmers from
the spread of dairy cooperatives in India has been uneven, and its po- joining existing cooperatives or forming new ones. The findings in this
tential in the context of globalized markets is often questioned. Earlier study partly help to fill such gaps in understanding.
studies in India suggest that farmers’ participation in dairy cooperatives This study models a farmer’s choice to join a dairy cooperative as a
led to significant increases in milk production and yield; a decrease in selection process, where the expected higher net returns received by the
the cost of milk production; a reduction in the transaction costs of ac- cooperative members drive farmers’ decisions to join. It uses an en-
cessing inputs, information, technology, and markets; and a realization dogenous switching regression approach to account for sample selec-
of higher prices and profits (Birthal et al., 2017, 2009, 2007; Kumar tion bias (Lokshin and Sajaia, 2004). This approach analyzes both the
et al., 2011a,b; Kumar, 2010; Stockbridge et al., 2003; Berdegue, 2001; determinants of cooperative membership and the impact of member-
Singh and Pundir, 2000; Shukla and Brahmankar, 1999; Candler and ship on farm performance indicators such as milk yield, net returns, and
Kumar, 1998; Singh, 1996; Mergos and Slade, 1987; Singh and Das, compliance with FSM. The results show that dairy cooperative mem-
1984; Lele, 1981). A few studies indicate that cooperative membership bership has a positive and significant effect on milk yield, net returns,
also has had a significant impact on compliance with food safety and compliance with FSM. Further, the income gains produced through
measures (FSM) (Kumar et al., 2011b,a, 2013; Vandeplas et al., 2013; dairy cooperative membership are greater for small-scale farmers, in-
Gupta and Roy, 2012; Narrod et al., 2009; Roy and Thorat, 2008). dicating the pro-poor tilt of dairy cooperatives.
However, in examining the impact of dairy cooperative membership, Section 2 of this study gives an overview of the dairy sector and
most of these studies did not take measures to correct for sample se- dairy cooperatives in Bihar. Section 3 presents the data and the corre-
lection bias and thus may give biased results. For instance, Gupta and sponding descriptive statistics. Section 4 presents the analytical
Roy (2012), Kumar et al. (2013), and Kumar et al. (2017a) studies are methods, and Section 5 discusses the empirical results. Section 6 pro-
all based on cross-sectional data. vides conclusions and policy implications of the study.


Corresponding author.
E-mail address: anjani.kumar@cgiar.org (A. Kumar).
1
Operation Flood was launched in 1970 to accelerate dairy development in India and to ensure that the country could meet the demand for milk and milk products by linking
production to marketing. Operation Flood introduced a three-tiered model of cooperative milk production: (1) milk society, (2) milk union, and (3) milk federation. The operation was
instrumental in accelerating the growth in India’s milk production, to such an extent that this growth was deemed the “White Revolution”.
2
For better comparison, this paper converts milk yield into fat-corrected milk (FCM). The milk from cross-bred cattle, indigenous cattle, and buffalo was converted into 4 percent FCM,
following Hemme et al. (2003). The formula for FCM is as follows: FCM = (milk production × fat (%) × 0.15) + (milk production × 0.4).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2018.01.005
Received 6 September 2017; Received in revised form 8 January 2018; Accepted 15 January 2018
Available online 22 February 2018
0306-9192/ © 2018 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Table 1
Key indicators of dairy development in India and Bihar.
Source: Government of India (2016).

India Bihar

2000–2001 2015–16 2000–2001 2015–16

Milk production (’000 metric tons)


Crossbred cows 14,131(17.5) 41,931 (27.0) 99(4.0) 2579 (31.1)
Local cows 18,826(23.4) 31,714 (20.4) 651(26.2) 2302 (27.8)
Buffalo 43,428(53.9) 76,459 (49.2) 1460(58.7) 3210 (38.7)
Goats 4222(5.2) 5378(3.5) 279(11.2) 198(2.4)
Total 80,607 (100.0) 146,314 (100.0) 2489 (100.0) 8288 (100.0)

In-milk animals (’000 s)


Crossbred cows 6011(9.3) 15,412 (16.8) 55(1.9) 1104 (20.3)
Local cows 26,872(41.4) 31,753 (34.7) 1093(37.1) 1941 (35.8)
Buffalo 29,371(45.2) 41,190 (45.0) 1194(40.6) 2059 (37.9)
Goatsa 2674(4.1) 3246(3.5) 602(20.4) 322(5.9)
Total 64,928 (100.0) 91,601 (100.) 2944 (100.0) 5426 (100.0)

Yield (kg/in-milk animal)


Crossbred cows 6.4 7.5 4.9 6.4
Local cows 1.9 2.7 1.6 3.2
Buffalo 4.1 5.1 3.4 4.3
Goats 0.4 0.5 0.1 0.2

Animal health and breeding infrastructure


Veterinary institutions (number)* 52,757 62,422 2259 2717
Number of veterinary institutions per 1000 livestock population 5.4 4.8 10.2 7.0
Artificial insemination (’000 s) 21,324 120,745 22 2624
Percentage of artificial insemination to total livestock population 7.5 40.4 0.10 13.81

Number of dairy processing plants


Cooperatives 212 263 6 10
Private sector 403 765 1 2
Others 63 37 0 0
Total 678 1065 7 12

Processing capacity (’000 l/day)


Cooperatives 28,394 43,251 485 700
Private sector 32,415 73,252 120 400
Others 12,170 3046 0 0
Total 72,979 119,549 605 1100

Note: Percentage figures are given in parentheses.


a
Goats converted into equivalent cattle unit; 10 goats = 1 cattle unit.
* Veterinary institutions include hospitals/polyclinics, dispensaries, and stockmen centers.

2. Dairy sector in Bihar cattle, with a 36 percent share of the population, contribute 28 percent
of Bihar’s milk output. The average milk yield of buffalo and cattle in
With a population of about 104 million, Bihar is the third-most Bihar is low but has shown significant improvement in recent years.
populated state in India, after Uttar Pradesh (200 million) and The Bihar State Milk Cooperative Federation (COMFED) has played
Maharashtra (114 million) (Government of India, 2011) It has one of a pivotal role in developing the state’s dairy sector. It was established in
the lowest per capita incomes and highest incidences of poverty. Dairy 1983 as the implementing agency of the Operation Flood program in
is an important income-generating activity for the rural poor in Bihar; it Bihar. COMFED’s cooperative model is a three-tiered structure similar
comprises about 31 percent of the state’s agricultural gross domestic to the pattern used in Amul Model in Gujarat. The milk producers’
product (AGDP) and contributes about three-fourths of livestock gross cooperative society is positioned at the village level, the milk union is at
domestic product (GDP) (Hoda et al., 2017). Currently, Bihar is one of the district level, and the milk federation is at the state level. The
the major milk-producing states in India, contributing about 5.3 percent number of dairy cooperative members increased in Bihar from 65,600
of national milk production. Production of milk in the state increased in 1987/88 to 629,200 in 2011/12. Milk procurement by COMFED
from 2.4 million metric tons in 2000/01 to 8.3 million metric tons in increased from 71 metric tons per day in 1987/88 to around 1070
2015/16, registering a compound annual growth rate of 6.5 percent. metric tons per day in 2011/12, recording a compound annual growth
Milk production in Bihar is dominated by smallholder dairy farms. rate (CAGR) of 13.3 percent (COMFED, 2017a). Despite this robust
The average herd size is small, with a few buffalo, dairy cows, or both, growth in milk procurement, at present COMFED procures and pro-
and the herd is reared in a system that is closely integrated with crop cesses only about 10 percent of the milk produced in Bihar.
production. In 2013, about 93 percent of milk producers were marginal Milk marketing has remained a largely informal and highly frag-
or small—having fewer than 2 ha of land—and together contributed mented sector in Bihar, involving local milk vendors, wholesalers, re-
about 90 percent of the total milk production in the state (Kumar et al., tailers, and neighboring consumers. These informal milk market agents
2017b). Cattle and buffalo are the main milch species, contributing handle about 74 percent of marketed milk in the state (Kumar, 2010;
about 98 percent of the state’s milk production, with the remaining Kumar et al., 2017b). Expansion of dairy cooperatives and entry of
2 percent contributed by goats (Table 1). Buffalo compose 38 percent of formal private sector have bolstered the processing capacity of the or-
in-milk animals in Bihar and contribute 39 percent of state milk pro- ganized dairy sector, but these advancements are inadequate to handle
duction. Crossbred cattle compose 20 percent of the in-milk animal the marketed surplus generated in the state. There is considerable scope
population and contribute 31 percent of milk production. Indigenous for the organized sector to participate in milk markets in the state.

25
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Fig. 1. Map showing geographic location of the selected blocks in Patna district, Bihar, India.

3. Data and descriptive statistics members during the study period (Table 2). The analysis assumed that
these households had randomly decided to be cooperative members
The panel data for this analysis are based on the primary data col- based on unobservable characteristics, but the small sample size pre-
lected at the farm level in two rounds (2007 and 2015) in Bihar. In both cluded any econometric analysis to support this assumption. We found
rounds, we collected data using a thoroughly pretested questionnaire that milk production appeared to increase significantly after farmers
and trained enumerators. The Patna district of Bihar was selected spe- became dairy cooperative members; their net return per liter more than
cifically for this study because it is well known for milk production and doubled, due to higher milk yield.
has several different milk marketing regimes, including dairy co- The average household milk production increased from 3.2 l per day
operatives, informal traders, and private sector corporate dairy pro- in 2007 to 6.6 l per day in 2015, mainly due to a more than twofold
ducers (Kumar et al., 2011a). Patna district contributed about 6 percent increase in milk yield. The share of dairy in household income also
of the total milk production of Bihar in 2014 (COMFED, 2017b). In increased from 23 percent in 2007 to 29 percent in 2015, indicating the
2007, three blocks3 were selected randomly from Patna district (Fig. 1 increasing role of dairying in small holders’ household income. Further,
presents the geographical locations of selected blocks). From each se- the greater extent of marketed milk surplus and the increased partici-
lected block, three villages were randomly selected and 75 dairy pation of producers in milk markets indicate the enhanced commer-
households from each block were selected for the survey (Appendix cialization of these households after becoming cooperative members.
Table A.1). At the village level, we randomly selected sample house- The adoption of FSM also increased from 45.3 percent in 2007 to
holds in proportion to the village population through the random walk 52.2 percent in 2015.
method. Through this method, a total sample of 225 dairy farmers were
selected in 2007.
The sample households were first stratified into two groups: mem- 4. Methodology
bers and nonmembers of dairy cooperatives. Hereafter, to simplify the
discussion, the households are referred to as member and nonmember 4.1. Adoption of food safety practices at the farm level
households based on their association with dairy cooperatives. In 2015,
we revisited the same 225 households but could trace only 148, as the To assess the adoption status of FSM at the farm level, this study
remaining households had either migrated or left dairy farming. The identified 42 measures being practiced to ensure milk safety. These
data gathered covered a wide range of information on household measures were related to the control of chemical and microbiological
characteristics, milk production, and marketing practices, as well as hazards. To make a comparative assessment of the adoption status of
compliance with FSM in milk production at the farm level. Appendix FSM compliance, we developed an index of adoption of food safety
Table A.2 presents summary statistics of variables used in the empirical practices (FSI) based on weighted scores that align with different
model, along with the difference in each explanatory variable for components of food safety.
member and nonmember dairy farmer households. Weighted scores for the FSI were computed as follows. First, the 42
In 2007, out of 148 dairy farmers, only 21 (14.2%) were members of practices being followed by the dairy farmers were grouped under four
dairy cooperative societies. The dairy cooperative membership among categories: animal health, hygienic milking, hygienic storage, and
sample households increased to 60 (40.5%) in 2015, a more than maintenance of hygienic premises (including the surrounding en-
100 percent expansion in cooperative membership. Forty-three dairy vironment). These four categories were accorded weights of 0.25, 0.35,
farm households acquired cooperative membership between 2007 and 0.20, and 0.20, respectively, based on their relative importance in en-
2015, and four dairy farmers left the cooperatives. To examine the suring milk safety and in consultation with scientists working on milk
dynamic effects of dairy cooperative membership further, we per- safety issues (Kumar et al., 2011b, 2017a). The number of practices
formed a descriptive analysis of the 43 households that became being followed in each category was multiplied by the respective
weight and summed across all categories to obtain a weighted score
reflecting the adoption level of FSM. The FSI for ith farm was re-
3
A block is an administrative unit within a district. presented by Eq. (1):

26
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Table 2
Descriptive statistics of transition from nonmembers in 2007 to cooperative members in 2015.

Particulars Nonmember households in 2007 Nonmember households in 2007 who became members in 2015 t-value

Number 43 43 –
Age of household head (years) 51.3 56.3 0.0441ns
Household headed by male (%) 97.6 95.3 −0.6417ns
Education of household head (years) 5.7 6.7 1.5360ns
Household size (number) 9.7 9.8 0.4888ns
Dependency ratio 43.8 42.6 −0.0875ns
Size of land holding (hectare) 1.0 0.8 −1.6600*
Herd size (number) 1.5 1.6 0.4301ns
Adoption of crossbred animal (%) 18.7 77.5 8.1151***
Kutcha sheda (%) 51.1 18.6 5.9332***
Pucca/semipucca shedb (%) 48.9 81.4 5.9332***
Annual household income at current price (’000 INR) 80.7 177.4 5.4387***
Annual household income at constant price of 2004 (’000 INR) 70.2 100.1 1.7349*
Annual per capita income at current price (’000 INR) 9.1 19.8 7.4474***
Annual per capita income at constant price of 2004 (’000 INR) 7.8 11.2 1.9985**
Experience in dairying (years) 21.9 28.9 4.1865***
Contribution of dairying to household income (%) 22.7 28.6 3.1748***
Training in dairy farming (%) 0.0 7.0 1.4339ns
Animal value at current price (’000 INR) 22.6 36.7 0.0293ns
Animal value at constant price of 2004 (’000 INR) 19.6 20.7 0.2693ns
Average milk production (liters/day) 3.2 6.6 4.0379***
Milk price at current price (INR) 13.0 31.8 2.2002***
Milk price at constant price of 2004 (INR) 11.5 12.7 41.9283***
Milk-producing households selling milk (%) 30.2 76.7 5.7672***
Share of marketed milk (%) 22.7 56.5 3.5390***
Average milk sold (liters/day/hh) 1.3 5.8 3.7741***
Milk yield (liters/animal/day) 2.1 4.3 6.0560***
Net return per liter at current price (INR) 4.9 10.2 6.3584***
Net return per liter at constant price of 2004 (INR) 4.2 5.8 0.9250ns
Food safety index 0.45 0.52 0.1297ns

Note: hh: household. INR: Indian rupee.


, , and * indicate 1, 5 and 10 percent levels of significance, respectively, and ns represents “not significant.”
*** **

a
A kutcha animal shed is made from bamboo and straw and is considered to be of poorer quality than concrete sheds.
b
A pucca shed is made from concrete and considered to be a good quality shed; a semipucca shed is part concrete and part bamboo/straw.

4
That is, a dairy farmer will opt to be a cooperative member (Mi = 1) ,
FSIi = ∑ wj pj ,
if M ∗ > 0, where M ∗ represents the expected benefits of being a co-
j=1 (1)
operative member compared to not being a member.
where wj is the weight assigned to the jth FSM category, and pj is the Here, X is a vector of variables that determine a dairy farmer’s as-
proportion of FSM practiced in each category. These weights sum to sociation with a cooperative. These variables include the farmer
one, and the FSI ranges between 0 and 1. household’s characteristics, which include age, gender, education,
household size, land size, herd size, dependency ratio, experience in
dairy farming, share of dairy income, per capita income, animal value,
4.2. Impact of dairy cooperatives on farmers’ performance: Endogenous
condition of animal shed, training on livestock, and share of crossbred
switching regression
animals. In the second step, based on the results of the selection func-
tion, two regime equations are specified explaining the outcomes of
Our variable of interest, membership in dairy cooperatives, is based
interest: milk yield, net return per liter, and adoption of FSM. The re-
on individual selections and may be correlated with unobservable
lationship between a vector of explanatory variables X and the outcome
characteristics—such as a farmer’s ability to join or the extent of their
Y can be represented by Y = f(X ) . Specifically, the two regimes are
motivation to join—that also could affect their performance in dairy
represented as follows:
farming. A simple comparison of members and nonmembers may pro-
vide misleading results that attribute differences to the performance of Regime 1: Y1i = X1i β1 + ε1i if Mi = 1
cooperative and independent producers. To account for both en-
dogeneity and sample selection, we use an endogenous switching re- Regime 2: Y2i = X2i β2 + ε2i if Mi = 0, (3)
gression (ESR) framework to estimate the parameters. We account for
where Yi is the outcome of interest (i.e., milk yield, net return per liter,
the endogeneity of the association with cooperative members by esti-
or FSI) in regimes 1 and 2, and Xi represents a vector of the explanatory
mating a simultaneous equations model with endogenous switching by
variables discussed above. Finally, the error terms are assumed to have
full information maximum likelihood (FIML). The decision to be a co-
a trivariate normal distribution, with zero mean and covariance matrix.
operative member is voluntary and may be based on individual self-
If the estimated covariance between δ and ε ’s ( ρ1 and ρ2 , respectively)
selection. The dairy farmers associated with cooperatives may have
are statistically significant, then the farmer’s cooperative membership
inherently different characteristics from the nonmembers, and may
and the farm’s milk yield, net return per liter, or FSI are correlated. The
have decided to be a cooperative member based on the expected ben-
ρ1 and ρ2 are the transformation of the correlation between the errors
efits of membership. We specify the selection equation for association
from Eq. (3). Using this method, we found evidence of endogenous
with a cooperative as
switching and rejected the null hypothesis that sample selectivity bias
1 if Mi∗ > 0 was absent. This model is defined as a “switching regression model with
Mi∗ = Xi α + δi with Mi = ⎧ . endogenous switching” (Maddala and Nelson, 1975).

⎩ 0 otherwise (2)
It is important to use selection instruments in this model. The

27
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Table 3 Table 4
Treatment and heterogeneity effect—Decision stage. Impact of dairy cooperatives on milk yield.

Transitional Decision stage Treatment Endogenous switching regression Panel fixed


heterogeneity effects effect model
Member Nonmember Member = 1 Member = 0 (Member = 1,
(Dairy farmers (Dairy farmers otherwise = 0)
Member (a) E (Y1i |Mi = 1) (c) E (Y2i |Mi = 1) TT are are not
Nonmember (d) E (Y1i |Mi = 0) (b) E (Y2i |Mi = 0) TU cooperative cooperative
Heterogeneity effects BH1 BH2 TH members) members)
Dependent Milk yield Milk yield Membership Milk yield
Note: (a) and (b) represent observed expected outcome indicators; (c) and (d) represent variable→
counterfactual expected outcome indicators. Mi = 1 if dairy farm households are co- Column 1 2 3 4
operative members; Mi = 0 if dairy farm households are not cooperative members. Y1i:
Membera 1.445**
Outcome indicators if dairy farm households are cooperative members; Y2i: Outcome
(0.681)
indicators if dairy farm households are not cooperative members. TT: the effect of the
Age in years 0.095 −0.008 −0.008 0.023
treatment (i.e., dairy farm households are cooperative members) on the treated (i.e., dairy
(0.071) (0.024) (0.010) (0.025)
farm households are not cooperative members). TU: the effect of the treatment (i.e.,
Male-headed 0.688 0.649 −0.448 −0.162
cooperative members) on the untreated (i.e., not cooperative members). BHi: the effect of
house- (5.472) (1.391) (0.492) (1.268)
base heterogeneity for dairy farm households that are cooperative members (i = 1), and holda
not associated with cooperative members (i = 2). TH = (TT − TU) (i.e., transitional Education in 0.140 −0.039 −0.018 0.033
heterogeneity). years (0.148) (0.049) (0.023) (0.060)
Household 0.210 0.057 −0.048* 0.058
selection of instrumental variables should directly affect the selection size (0.157) (0.072) (0.027) (0.067)
Dependency 1.396 −1.348 −0.586 −0.605
variable but not the outcome variable. In this study, we used caste as a
ratio (3.044) (0.985) (0.521) (1.015)
selection instrumental variable. We established the admissibility of the Land holdings −0.588* 0.601*** 0.072 −0.000
instruments by performing a simple falsification test: if a variable is a in (0.340) (0.195) (0.063) (0.253)
valid selection instrument, it will affect the households of dairy farmers hectares
that are associated with a dairy cooperative but will not affect the Herd size 2.653*** 2.360*** 0.129 3.011***
(0.621) (0.457) (0.091) (0.403)
outcome variable of the households of dairy farmers that are not as-
Share of −0.021 0.003 0.007** 0.004
sociated with a dairy cooperative (Appendix Table A.3). crossbred (0.030) (0.008) (0.003) (0.007)
In addition to using the endogenous switching regression model, we animals
calculated the dairy farmers’ conditional expectations for milk yield, Experience in −0.050 −0.012 −0.015 −0.023
dairy (0.056) (0.018) (0.010) (0.018)
net return per liter, and adoption of the FSM in the four cases presented
farming
below: in years
In addition to using the endogenous switching regression model, we Share of dairy 0.052 0.034*** 0.002 0.041***
calculated the dairy farmers’ conditional expectations for milk yield, income in (0.052) (0.011) (0.005) (0.013)
net return per liter, and adoption of the FSM in the four cases presented total
income
below:
Training in −4.978 0.401 0.695 −1.768
livestocka (3.247) (1.982) (0.819) (1.742)
⎡ ⎤ 2.758*** −0.208 0.844**
a. E (Y1i |Mi = 1) = ⎢ ∑ (X1i β1 + σ1n γ1i ) ⎥ N1 Log of per 0.258
⎣ Mi = 1 ⎦ (4) capita (0.955) (0.344) (0.156) (0.373)
income
Log of animal 1.104 0.495 0.212 0.646*
⎡ ⎤
b. E (Y2i |Mi = 0) = ⎢ ∑ (X2i β2 + σ2n γ2i ) ⎥ N0 values (1.143) (0.356) (0.138) (0.361)
⎣ Mi = 0 ⎦ (5) Year dummya −2.776 2.596*** 1.452*** 1.401**
(2.541) (0.723) (0.318) (0.683)
General caste 1.368***
⎡ ⎤
c. E (Y2i |Mi = 1) = ⎢ ∑ (X1i β2 + σ2n γ1i ) ⎥ N1 (0.288)
⎣ Mi = 1 ⎦ (6) Constant −36.600* −8.861** −1.036 −15.950***
(20.249) (4.112) (1.734) (5.350)
Block fixed Yes Yes
⎡ ⎤
d. E (Y1i |Mi = 0) = ⎢ ∑ (X2i β1 + σ1n γ2i ) ⎥ N0. effect
⎣ Mi = 0 ⎦ (7) Observations 296 296 296 296
σi 1.706*** 1.116***
N1 and N0 are the number of observations with Mi = 1 and Mi = 0 , re- (0.230) (0.019)
spectively. ρj −0.750 0.207
Cases (a) and (b) in Table 3 represent the actual expectations ob- (1.009) (0.178)

served in the sample. Cases (c) and (d) represent the counterfactual
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses.
expected outcomes. However, following Heckman et al. (2001), we a
Denotes dummy variable.
calculated the effect of the treatment “cooperative members” on the *** p < .01.
treated (TT) as the difference between (a) and (c), which represents the ** p < .05.
impact of members on the outcome variable of the dairy farm house- * p < .1.
holds that are cooperative members. Similarly, we calculated the dif-
ference between (d) and (b) as the effect of the treatment on the un-
treated (TU) for the dairy farm households that did not become
cooperative members. (Carter and Milon, 2005).
We also defined the “the effect of base heterogeneity” for the group Finally, we examined the transitional heterogeneity (TH)—namely,
of dairy farm households that decided to become cooperative members whether the effect of a cooperative membership on the outcome vari-
as the difference between (a) and (d). For the group of dairy farm able is larger or smaller for the dairy farm households that are co-
households that decided not to become cooperative members, the effect operative members than for those that are not cooperative members in
of base heterogeneity was defined as the difference between (c) and (b) the counterfactual case (i.e., the difference between TT and TU).

28
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Table 5 Table 6
Impact of dairy cooperatives on net return per liter. Impact of dairy cooperatives on adoption of FSM.

Endogenous switching regression Panel Endogenous switching regression Panel fixed


fixed effect
Member = 1 Member = 0 (Member = 1, effect Member = 1 Member = 0 (Member = 1, model
(Dairy farmers (Dairy farmers otherwise = 0) model (Dairy farmers (Dairy farmers otherwise = 0)
are cooperative are not are are not
members) cooperative cooperative cooperative
members) members) members)
Dependent Net return per Net return per Membership Net Dependent FSI FSI Membership FSI
variable→ liter liter return variable→
per liter Column 1 2 3 4
Column 1 2 3 4
Membera 0.103**
Membera 0.242*** (0.048)
(0.093) Age in years 0.160 0.070 −0.015 0.001
Age in years −0.005 −0.003 −0.014 −0.002 (0.136) (0.066) (0.009) (0.001)
(0.004) (0.005) (0.010) (0.004) Male-headed −10.157 −1.944 −0.623 −0.114
Male-headed 0.129 0.040 −0.584 0.087 house- (7.499) (2.391) (0.497) (0.083)
house- (0.170) (0.186) (0.547) (0.119) holda
holda Education in 0.430 0.567*** −0.037 0.011***
Education in 0.000 0.021 −0.034 0.009 years (0.403) (0.155) (0.026) (0.004)
years (0.011) (0.016) (0.026) (0.010) Household size 0.685 −0.139 −0.044 0.002
Household size −0.003 0.001 −0.057* −0.002 (0.447) (0.218) (0.027) (0.005)
(0.016) (0.012) (0.030) (0.010) Dependency 8.802 0.100 −0.575 0.027
Dependency 0.114 0.061 −0.474 −0.002 ratio (7.487) (3.350) (0.558) (0.078)
ratio (0.261) (0.217) (0.605) (0.170) Land holdings 0.855 0.356 0.053 0.010
Land holdings −0.034 −0.077 0.066 −0.050* in hectares (0.667) (0.687) (0.051) (0.009)
in hectares (0.023) (0.059) (0.054) (0.026) Share of −0.004 −0.035* 0.008*** −0.000
Experience in 0.002 0.003 −0.008 0.002 crossbred (0.050) (0.020) (0.003) (0.000)
dairy (0.004) (0.004) (0.010) (0.003) animals
farming^ Experience in −0.149 −0.082 −0.012 −0.003**
Share of 0.001 −0.001 0.007** −0.001 dairy (0.112) (0.063) (0.009) (0.001)
crossbred (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) farming in
animals years
Share of dairy 0.006*** 0.001 0.002 0.003 Share of dairy −0.049 −0.140*** 0.002 −0.004***
income in (0.002) (0.002) (0.005) (0.002) income in (0.085) (0.037) (0.005) (0.001)
total total
Training in 0.101 0.328 0.860 0.125 income
livestocka (0.183) (0.423) (0.926) (0.141) Training in 9.610 −12.616*** 1.111 0.138
Milk 0.021 0.048*** 0.048** 0.030*** livestocka (7.558) (4.050) (0.850) (0.116)
production (0.014) (0.009) (0.024) (0.009) Log of per −1.390 −0.930 −0.284* −0.015
in liters capita (2.606) (1.068) (0.153) (0.025)
Log of animal −0.045 −0.101 0.152 −0.055 income
values (0.068) (0.087) (0.147) (0.069) Log of animal −3.006 2.744*** 0.169 0.049**
Log of per 0.014 0.043 −0.186 0.043 values (2.479) (0.995) (0.131) (0.022)
capita (0.066) (0.068) (0.173) (0.057) Milk 0.652* 0.767*** 0.040* 0.014***
income produc- (0.348) (0.223) (0.021) (0.003)
Year dummya 0.758*** 0.662*** 1.325*** 0.741*** tion in
(0.180) (0.168) (0.333) (0.138) liters
General caste 1.534*** Year dummya 1.017 −1.474 1.355*** 0.022
(0.296) (5.750) (2.407) (0.286) (0.047)
Constant 1.978 **
2.219 **
−0.211 1.351 General caste 1.599***
(0.986) (1.126) (1.865) (0.894) (0.311)
Block fixed Yes Yes Block fixed Yes Yes
effect effect
Observations 270 270 270 270 Constant 88.096*** 21.475* 0.605 3.564***
σi −1.141*** −0.431** (31.836) (12.098) (1.885) (0.267)
(0.301) (0.182) Observations 296 296 296 296
ρj −0.081 −0.092 σi 2.625*** 2.272***
(1.092) (0.167) (0.159) (0.034)
ρj −0.690 −0.494
Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. (0.745) (0.378)
a
Denotes dummy variable.
*** p < .01. Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses.
a
** p < .05. Denotes dummy variable.
* p < .1. *** p < .01.
** p < .05.
* p < .1.
5. Results and discussion

Tables 4–6 report the estimates of the ESR model estimated by cooperative membership are given in the fourth column of Tables 4–6.
FIML. As indicated earlier, the FIML approach jointly estimates both the Being estimated jointly with the outcome equations through FIML, es-
selection and the outcome equations. The outcome equations that re- timated results for selection equations differ slightly across Tables 4–6,
present the impact of cooperative membership on milk yield, net re- even though both the dependent variable and the set of explanatory
turns, and compliance with FSM for both members and nonmembers variables are the same. The final column of Tables 4–6 provide the
are given in the second and third columns of Tables 4–6, respectively. estimated impact of cooperative membership based on the coefficients
The selection equations that represent the determinants of dairy of ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions.

29
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Table 7 Table 8
Treatment and heterogeneity effects. Impact of dairy cooperative membership on milk yield, net return, and FSM adoption by
farm size.
Member Nonmember Treatment effects
Farm category Mean outcome ATT t-value Change in %
Milk yield
Member (a) 4.09 (c) 2.93 TT = 1.16*** Members Nonmembers
Nonmember (d) 2.07 (b) 1.80 TU = 0.27***
Heterogeneity effects BH1 = 2.02 BH2 = 1.13 TH = 0.89*** Milk yield
Landless 5.2 3.3 1.9 1.7102* 57.6
Net return per liter
*** Marginal 8.3 4.3 4.0 3.3245*** 93.0
Member (a) 7.16 (c) 5.20 TT = 1.96
Small and large 8.5 4.7 3.8 2.5282** 80.9
Nonmember (d) 4.87 (b) 3.52 TU = 1.35***
Heterogeneity effects BH1 = 2.29 BH2 = 1.68 TH = 0.61*** Net return per liter
Landless 8.4 8.0 0.4 0.1176ns 4.7
Adoption of FSM
*** Marginal 12.5 7.0 5.4 2.7300*** 77.1
Member (a) 0.43 (c) 0.39 TT = 0.04
Small and large 10.0 5.3 4.7 1.9171* 89.2
Nonmember (d) 0.45 (b) 0.42 TU = 0.03***
Heterogeneity effects BH1 = −0.28 BH2 = −0.29 TH = 0.01*** Adoption of FSM
Landless 0.44 0.36 0.8 2.1391** 20.4
*** Significant at the 1 percent level. Marginal 0.53 0.44 0.9 3.251*** 20.4
Small and large 0.56 0.49 0.7 2.185** 12.6

In the next section, we first discuss the determinants of dairy co-


Note: ***, **, and * indicate 1, 5 and 10 percent levels of significance, and ns represents
operative membership based on the selection equations in Tables 4–6. “not significant.”
We then discuss the impact of cooperative membership on milk yield,
net returns, and compliance with FSM, and highlight our unique find- Land holding had a positive effect on the milk yield for nonmember
ings on how FSM affects the effects of different factors on these out- farmers. Herd size, year, and share of dairy as a part of household in-
comes. Finally, we present the estimates for the average treatment ef- come also are positively associated with milk yield for nonmember
fects on the treated (ATT) in Table 7. dairy farmers. For cooperative dairy farmers, herd size and per capita
income is positively associated with the milk yield, whereas land
5.1. Determinants of dairy cooperative membership holding had a negative effect on milk yield.
These differences may arise for multiple reasons. For instance, even
The results of the participation equation given in the third column though nonmembers may continue to rely on extensive livestock
of Tables 4–6 suggest that the drivers of dairy farming households’ rearing, cooperative members may switch to more intensive rearing in
decisions to become cooperative members include herd composition, which a higher density of livestock per land holdings may reduce the
milk production, caste affiliation, household size, and per capita in- costs of monitoring livestock conditions and providing forages and in-
come. A higher share of crossbred animals, higher milk production, and tensive cares. Similarly, for cooperative members, higher per capita
belonging to a general caste category all positively influence house- incomes may translate into higher milk yield because their production
holds’ decisions to join dairy cooperatives. But per capita income and may be more capital intensive, whereas for nonmembers production
herd size have a negative influence on the probability of becoming may be more labor intensive. In the latter group, higher milk yield is
cooperative members. The probability of participation in dairy co- achieved if more family members are engaged in milk production as
operatives increased significantly between 2007 and 2015, as indicated opposed to other income-earning activities, so that their opportunity
by the positive and significant coefficient of the year dummy variable. costs are lower and dairy income is a higher share of total income.
The land size, age, gender, household dependency ratio, and regional
location variables do not significantly affect the probability of be-
coming a dairy cooperative member. 5.3. Net return effects

5.2. Milk yield effects The fourth column (OLS approach) of Table 5 investigates the effect
of cooperative membership on net return. As mentioned earlier, this
The fourth column (OLS approach) of Table 4 investigates the effect approach suggests that there is a significant difference in the net return
of cooperative membership on milk yield. This approach suggests that between members and nonmembers of dairy cooperatives. The coeffi-
there is a significant difference in the milk yield between members and cient of the member dummy variable is positive and statistically sig-
nonmembers of dairy cooperatives. The coefficient of the member nificant, but the estimated coefficient of correlation ( ρj ) is not statisti-
dummy variable is positive and statistically significant. However, the cally significant in either function. However, we found a difference
OLS approach assumes that membership in a cooperative is exogen- between the coefficient of the net return function in members of dairy
ously determined, even though such membership is endogenously de- cooperatives and their counterparts, indicating the presence of het-
termined. Therefore, using the OLS approach here will lead to biased erogeneity in the sample. The scale of milk production and the year had
and inconsistent estimates. Further, the OLS-derived estimates do not a positive effect on the net return for nonmember farmers. This may be
account for structural differences between the outcome variables of the case because nonmembers must have sufficient production scale in
cooperative members and their counterparts. To correct for these order to attract buyers that are more willing to pay for their products, as
weaknesses, the results presented in the first and second columns of well as to reduce the transactions costs per unit of milk output; co-
Table 4 provide estimates for endogenous switching in the milk-yield operative members, by contrast, can do so through jointly with other
function. The estimated coefficient of correlation ( ρj ) is not statistically members. In comparison, for cooperative dairy farmers the share of
significant in either function. This finding suggests that we failed to dairy income and year are positively associated with the net return.
reject the null hypothesis that sample selectivity bias was absent in both This may be the case because cooperative members may engage more in
equations. Nevertheless, we found a difference between the coefficient quality improvement processes (including FSM, as described in the next
of the milk-yield function in members of dairy cooperatives and their subsection) that may be more labor intensive, and households that have
counterparts, indicating the presence of heterogeneity in the sample. greater dairy income shares may have more family members available
The milk yield is significantly higher for cooperative members than for for such quality improvement activities; nonmembers may be less likely
nonmembers. to be engaged in those activities.

30
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

5.4. FSM adoption effects would be 4 percent more likely to have lower compliance with FSM if
they had not become members. Nonmember dairy farm households, by
Similarly, the fourth column of Table 6 investigates the effect of contrast, would only have been 3 percent more likely to adopt FSM if
cooperative membership on FSI score. The coefficient of the member they had been members.
dummy variable is positive and statistically significant. The estimated To gain further understanding of the impact of cooperative mem-
coefficient of correlation ( ρj ) is not statistically significant in either bership on different groups of farmers, we also examined the differ-
function. This finding suggests that we failed to reject the null hy- ential impact of membership by dividing households into quantiles
pothesis that sample selectivity bias is absent in both equations. based on farm size (Appendix Table A.4–A.6). Table 8 shows that the
Nevertheless, we found a difference between the coefficient of the FSI marginal farmers (operating on less than 1 ha of land) turned out to be
function in members of dairy cooperatives and their counterparts, in- the greatest beneficiaries of dairy cooperative membership.
dicating the presence of heterogeneity in the sample. The adoption of
FSM is significantly higher for cooperative members than for non- 6. Conclusion
members. Years of education has a positive effect on the adoption of
FSM for nonmember dairy farmers. The value of livestock assets and the This paper examines the factors that influence dairy farmers’ deci-
scale of milk production is also positively associated with the adoption sions to become members of milk cooperative societies, and the impact
of FSM for nonmember farmers. Yet the share of crossbred animals, of cooperative membership on milk yield, net returns per liter, and
share of dairy income, and training in livestock have a negative impact adoption of FSM. The study used farm-level panel data collected from a
on FSM adoption for nonmembers. This may be the case because randomly selected sample of 148 households. Simple comparisons of
crossbred animals may require more complex appropriate FSM. Simi- average milk yield, net returns per liter, and FSM adoption revealed
larly, FSM may be too costly and incur losses for nonmembers, because significant differences between members and nonmembers of dairy
unlike cooperative members they may not be able to fetch higher prices cooperatives. As these comparisons are merely descriptive and do not
from FSI (particularly if production quantities are small) and thus those account for confounding factors that affect the differences, we em-
who rely more on dairy incomes for their livelihood may be less likely ployed an ESR model that accounts for both observed and unobserved
to engage in FSI. Relatedly, training in livestock may be affecting the factors to consider the issue of selection bias. The results revealed that
returns on other types of livestock-related investments, raising the re- sample selection bias would result if the outcome specifications were
lative costs for investments in food safety. For cooperative dairy estimated without considering the membership decision.
farmers, the scale of milk production is positively associated with FSM The empirical results showed a positive and significant relationship
adoption. between dairy cooperative membership and milk yield, net returns per
These differences may be driven by the fact that, whereas non- liter, and adoption of FSM. In particular, association with a dairy co-
members’ engagement with FSM may be constrained by various factors, operative society tends to increase milk yield by 40 percent, net return
cooperative membership largely may remove these constraints. For by 38 percent, and adoption of FSM by 10 percent. The estimates, dif-
example, the findings suggest that, among nonmembers, the adoption ferentiated by farm size, revealed that the income gains brought about
of FSM is constrained by low education levels and a higher share of by dairy cooperative membership were higher for small-scale farmers.
crossbred animals in their herd size. This finding suggests that dairy cooperatives can play a significant role
in enhancing the household income of smallholder dairy farmers. The
5.5. Treatment effects study also revealed that dairy cooperatives have the potential to en-
hance milk yield and net returns and improve farmers' compliance with
Table 7 presents the expected value of milk yield, net return per liter FSM. Therefore, the government should further strengthen and promote
of milk, and adoption of FSM under actual and counterfactual condi- the expansion of dairy cooperatives in India.
tions. Cells (a) and (b) represent the expected value of outcome vari- Future studies should address a number of issues related to this
ables. The expected values for milk yield for members of dairy co- research. First, even though the analyses in this study are internally
operatives was higher than for nonmembers. This simple comparison, valid, their external validity is yet to be investigated. For example, milk
however, could be misleading in attributing the different values of milk prices might have been considerably different during the study period
yield to cooperative membership. The last column of the first panel in than in other periods, and milk market structures also have changed
Table 7 presents the treatment effects of cooperative membership on considerably during the past two decades, as was described in Table 1.
milk yield at the farm level. In the counterfactual case (c), dairy farmers Our analyses may not offer insights into what would have happened
who became cooperative members would have lower yield by 1.16 l per during the period or in areas where the changes in these market char-
day if had they not become members. The positive mean difference of acteristics were more stable. Future studies must address these issues,
(d) and (b) elicits a similar conclusion: nonmember dairy farm house- such as by examining similar issues in a broader set of locations across
holds would have increased the milk yield of their cattle by 0.27 l per India or in different time periods. Such investigations are important
day if they had become members. However, the transitional hetero- also because milk price levels and their growth might have also partly
geneity effect for milk yield is positive, meaning that the effect is affected the estimated impact of cooperative membership in ways that
greater for cooperative dairy farm households than for nonmember are not always clear. For instance, higher milk prices could lower the
dairy farming households. relative margins gained by the quality improvements induced by co-
The impact of cooperative membership on net return per liter is also operative membership, if the price premiums from such improvements
positive and significant. Milk-producing households gained from being are relatively fixed. However, if price premiums from quality im-
associated with cooperatives; their mean net return per liter was provements were proportional to the milk price, then the benefits of
37 percent higher than it would have been if they had not become joining the dairy cooperative would have been greater.
cooperative members. The positive mean difference of (b) and (d) in- Second, future studies need to investigate more closely the moti-
dicates that the nonmember households would have had higher net vations to join cooperatives, as well as perceptions of expected out-
returns per liter (38 percent) if they had become members. comes and barriers for or costs to joining cooperatives. Such informa-
Similarly, the expected level of FSM adoption for members (0.43) of tion can help researchers and policymakers assess the transaction costs
dairy cooperatives was higher than that for nonmembers (0.39). The associated with joining cooperatives, such as the roles of insufficient
last column of the third panel in Table 7 presents the treatment effects knowledge of expected returns. For instance, some studies (for example,
of cooperative membership on adoption of FSM at the farm level. In the of dairy and fishery cooperatives in the United States) have suggested
counterfactual case, dairy farmers who became cooperative members that part of the motivation for forming cooperatives was to improve

31
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

product quality by coordinating quality control across different stages Acknowledgement


in the production process (Sexton and Iskow 1988; Jardine et al. 2014).
Whether this finding holds true for dairy farmers in India as well, fur- We are grateful to the Indian Council of Agricultural Research
ther research will provide more insights into the understanding of the (ICAR) and United States Agency for International Development
role of cooperatives across diverse settings. (USAID) for extending financial support to conduct this study. We
Finally, future studies need to investigate the mechanisms of the would like to thank the farmers who provided the needed information
observed impact pathways, and how different characteristics of co- for this study. We also express our sincere thanks to the anonymous
operatives were responsible for impacts such as membership size, reviewer and editor of the journal for providing valuable comments to
membership policy, methods of finance, and decision-making pro- improve earlier version of the paper. Any opinions, findings, conclu-
cesses. Identifying the mechanisms of such impact pathways will shed sions, or recommendations expressed within this paper do not ne-
further light on what types of cooperatives (with various structures) cessarily reflect the views of the ICAR, USAID, IFPRI or any other or-
may be particularly effective. ganizations.

Appendix A.

See Tables A.1–A.6.

Table A.1
Distribution of sample households and transition to dairy cooperative membership.

Sample No. Block name No. of Old No. of matched % of matched


villages sample in households in households
2007 2015

1 Bikram 3 75 54 72.0
2 Mokama 3 75 57 76.0
3 Phulwari 3 75 37 49.3
Shariff
Total 9 225 148 65.8

Transition to dairy cooperative membership between 2007 and 2015


2007 2015

Transition Member Nonmember

Member 21 17 (81.0) 4 (19.0)


Nonmember 127 43 (33.9) 84 (66.1)
Total 148 60 (40.5) 88 (59.5)

Note: Percentage figures are given in parentheses.

Table A.2
Summary statistics comparing member and nonmember dairy farmer households.

Particulars 2007 t-value 2015 t-value t-value

M NM All (2007) M NM All (2015) Year


M - NM M - NM 2015–2007

Number 21 127 148 – 60 88 148 – –

Explanatory variables
Age of household head (years) 52.3 49.5 49.9 0.9737ns 57.0 58.1 57.6 −0.5493ns 5.4676***
Household headed by male (%) 95.2 97.6 97.3 −0.6248ns 95.3 96.4 97.3 −0.3389ns − 0.6417ns
Education of household head (years) 9.7 5.2 5.8 3.7160*** 7.8 6.1 6.8 1.9189* 1.5843ns
Household size (number) 8.5 9.1 9.0 −0.5009ns 9.4 8.2 8.7 1.5899ns −0.5897ns
Dependency ratio 32.3 45.5 43.6 −2.756*** 41.1 44.9 43.4 −1.0517 0.0875ns
Size of land holding (hectare) 3.7 0.7 1.1 5.9781*** 1.3 0.3 0.8 4.0234*** −1.5454ns
Herd size (number) 2.3 1.4 1.6 3.2646*** 1.6 1.4 1.5 0.9631ns −0.4264ns
Adoption of crossbred animal (%) 49.0 13.0 18.1 4.3796*** 78.1 41.1 57.1 5.1908*** 7.9653***
Kutcha shed (%) 23.8 54.3 50.0 2.6341*** 16.7 20.5 18.9 0.5744ns 5.9332***
Pucca/semipucca shed (%) 76.2 45.7 50.0 2.6341*** 83.3 79.5 81.1 0.5744ns 5.9332***
Experience in dairying (years) 24.0 20.0 20.5 1.3082ns 18.7 23.1 21.2 −2.0781** 0.4090ns
Contribution of dairying to household income (%) 26.7 24.8 25.1 0.3911ns 27.9 37.1 35.9 −2.3571** 3.1116***
Training in livestock (%) 4.8 0.8 1.4 1.4620ns 8.3 1.1 4.1 2.2004** 1.4339ns
Annual per capita income at current price (’000 INR) 11.8 7.8 8.4 2.9849*** 19.5 17.2 18.1 0.9405ns 7.4474***
Annual per capita income at constant price of 2004 (’000 INR) 10.3 6.8 7.3 2.9849*** 11.1 9.7 10.3 0.9405ns 3.6536***
Animal value at current price (’000 INR) 40.3 21.7 24.3 3.3973*** 37.3 15.7 24.5 4.5429*** −0.0293ns
Animal value at constant price of 2004 (’000 INR) 35.1 18.9 21.1 3.3973*** 21.1 8.9 13.8 4.5429*** 3.3260***
Household belonging to general caste (%) 100.0 28.4 38.5 7.2364*** 65.0 20.5 38.5 6.0790*** –
(continued on next page)

32
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Table A.2 (continued)

Particulars 2007 t-value 2015 t-value t-value

M NM All (2007) M NM All (2015) Year


M - NM M - NM 2015–2007

Average milk production (liters/day) 8.1 2.8 3.7 5.1594*** 7.1 5.2 6.1 1.8506* 4.1810***
Annual household income at current price (’000 INR) 96.1 68.7 72.5 1.9151* 162.6 154.1 157.6 0.2795ns 5.4387***
Annual household income at constant price of 2004 (’000 INR) 83.6 59.7 63.1 1.9151* 91.9 87.1 89.0 0.2795ns 2.7422**
Milk-producing households selling milk (%) 66.7 33.9 38.5 2.9247*** 78.1 64.3 70.2 1.8332* 5.7672***
Share of marketed milk (%) 48.1 26.4 29.5 3.8887*** 56.0 45.5 50.0 1.7258* 3.5294***
Average milk sold (liters/day/hh) 6.3 1.3 2.0 5.4023*** 5.8 3.4 4.5 2.0375** 3.7741***
Milk price at current price (INR) 13.0 13.0 13.0 – 31.9 31.7 31.8 0.8786ns 2.9871**
Milk price at constant price of 2004 (INR) 11.5 11.5 11.5 – 12.8 12.6 12.7 0.8786ns 36.5881***

Outcome variables
Milk yield (liter/animal/day) 3.9 1.9 2.3 4.4146*** 4.5 3.7 4.1 1.5961ns 6.2303***
Net return per liter at current price (INR) 6.8 4.0 4.4 2.3964** 12.5 11.0 11.7 0.6445ns 6.2625***
Net return per liter at constant price of 2004 (INR) 5.9 3.5 3.8 2.3964** 6.8 6.4 6.6 0.6445ns 3.9634***
Adoption of FSM 0.46 0.43 0.43 0.1102ns 0.53 0.41 0.46 0.4749*** 0.1866*

Note: NA: Not applicable. M: Member. NM: Nonmember. hh: household. INR: Indian rupee.
, , and * indicate 1, 5 and 10 percent levels of significance, respectively, and ns represents “not significant.”
*** **

Table A.3
Parameters estimates—Validity test of the selection instrument.

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4


Parameter Member Milk yield of Net return of Adoption of
estimates (1 = member, 0 nonmember nonmember FSM of
= otherwise) nonmember

General caste 1.265*** 0.410 −0.208 −1.200


(0.169) (0.355) (0.147) (1.871)
Constant −1.199*** 2.557*** 1.965*** 37.612***
(0.122) (0.194) (0.066) (1.653)
Wald test on Chi (2) = F-stat = F-stat = F-stat =
instrumental 55.89*** 1.33 2.00 1.72
variable
Observations 296 215 194 215

Table A.4
Impact of dairy cooperatives on milk yield across farm size.

Dependent variable—Milk yield Farm size

Landless Marginal Small and large

Membera 0.953 1.189 −0.320


(1.299) (0.995) (1.307)
Age in years 0.009 0.037 −0.037
(0.038) (0.044) (0.059)
Male-headed householda 1.056 −2.151** −30.002**
(1.875) (1.006) (12.867)
Education in years −0.168* −0.017 0.023
(0.090) (0.064) (0.161)
Household size 0.121 0.241*** −0.012
(0.141) (0.078) (0.098)
Dependency ratio −2.079* −2.274 3.367
(1.200) (1.482) (3.720)
Experience in dairy farming in years −0.023 −0.043 −0.036
(0.032) (0.033) (0.036)
Share of dairy income in total income 0.022 0.064*** 0.074
(0.017) (0.018) (0.046)
Log of per capita income 0.299 0.820** 2.459***
(0.692) (0.390) (0.905)
Log of animal values 0.075 0.813* 0.739
(0.699) (0.461) (0.778)
Herd size 2.255*** 3.173*** 3.192***
(0.820) (0.336) (0.871)
(continued on next page)

33
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Table A.4 (continued)

Dependent variable—Milk yield Farm size

Landless Marginal Small and large

Year dummya 1.052 2.789*** −0.705


(1.190) (0.934) (1.585)
Training in livestocka 6.009*** −6.046** −2.197
(1.758) (2.737) (2.359)
Share of crossbred animals 0.003 −0.006 0.026*
(0.013) (0.011) (0.016)
Block fixed effect Yes Yes Yes
Constant −4.127 −16.631*** –
(8.069) (6.398) –
Observations 90 128 78

Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses.


a
Denotes dummy variable.
*** p < .01.
** p < .05.
* p < .1.

Table A.5
Impact of dairy cooperatives on net return per liter by farm size.

Dependent variable—Net return per Farm size


liter
Landless Marginal Small and large

Membera 0.181 0.363*** 0.044


(0.180) (0.133) (0.227)
Age in years 0.001 0.002 −0.006
(0.011) (0.004) (0.008)
Male-headed householda 0.302 −0.026 –
(0.236) (0.137) –
Education in years 0.006 −0.008 0.039*
(0.022) (0.012) (0.021)
Household size −0.031 0.026** −0.011
(0.027) (0.012) (0.017)
Dependency ratio −0.302 −0.142 0.551
(0.365) (0.192) (0.576)
Experience in dairy farming in years 0.005 −0.002 −0.001
(0.006) (0.004) (0.010)
Share of dairy income in total income −0.002 0.005** 0.010
(0.004) (0.002) (0.007)
Log of per capita income 0.056 0.064 −0.060
(0.107) (0.068) (0.140)
Log of animal values 0.113 −0.182** 0.019
(0.105) (0.079) (0.156)
Milk production in liters 0.032** 0.046*** 0.015
(0.015) (0.008) (0.018)
Year dummya 0.813*** 0.425** 0.931***
(0.267) (0.179) (0.279)
Training in livestocka −0.570 −0.150 0.096
(0.503) (0.206) (0.213)
Share of crossbred animals −0.001 0.000 −0.001
(0.002) (0.002) (0.003)
Block fixed effect Yes Yes Yes
Constant −0.265 2.256** 1.416
(1.345) (1.021) (1.914)
Observations 83 115 72

Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses.


a
Denotes dummy variable.
*** p < .01.
** p < .05.
* p < .1.

34
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Table A.6
Impact of dairy cooperatives on adoption of FSM by farm size.

Dependent variable—Adoption of Farm size


FSM
Landless Marginal Small and large

a *
Member 6.304 5.860 2.811
(5.525) (3.108) (3.838)
Age in years 0.017 0.087 0.070
(0.095) (0.101) (0.129)
Male-headed householda −3.571 −5.681 92.947***
(3.911) (7.133) (34.319)
Education in years 0.128 0.566*** 0.554
(0.468) (0.199) (0.412)
Household size −0.152 0.231 −0.026
(0.497) (0.362) (0.394)
Dependency ratio 7.113 −0.576 −4.069
(5.266) (4.125) (8.986)
Experience in dairy farming in years −0.186** −0.164 −0.075
(0.085) (0.108) (0.114)
Share of dairy income in total income −0.098* −0.155*** −0.201
(0.056) (0.056) (0.146)
Log of per capita income −1.965 0.637 −7.415***
(2.502) (1.230) (2.663)
Log of animal values 3.069** 1.763 1.969
(1.298) (1.626) (2.843)
Milk production in liters 1.104*** 0.577** 0.561*
(0.350) (0.264) (0.298)
Year dummya 2.430 −0.017 7.361
(4.633) (3.206) (4.691)
Training in livestocka 28.344*** 17.497 −1.264
(6.925) (14.509) (5.429)
Share of crossbred animals −0.031 0.003 −0.022
(0.034) (0.029) (0.041)
Block fixed effect Yes Yes Yes
Constant 34.682* 27.769
(19.639) (18.614)
Observations 90 128 78

Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses.


a
Denotes dummy variable.
*** p < .01
** p < .05
* p < .1.

Appendix B. Supplementary material

Supplementary data associated with this article can be found, in the online version, at http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2018.01.005.

References Government of India, 2011. Primary census abstract, 2011. Office of the Registrar General
and Census Commissioner, India.
Government of India, 2016. Basic Animal Husbandry and Fisheries Statistics. Ministry of
Berdegue, J.A., 2001. Co-operating to compete: associative peasant business firms in Agriculture and Farmers Welfare, Department of Animal Husbandry, Dairying and
Chile. PhD thesis, Wageningen University and Research Centre, Department of Social Fisheries.
Science, Communication and Innovation Studies Group, Wageningen, The Gupta, K., Roy, D., 2012. Gains from coordination in milk-fed dairy in Punjab. J. Agribus
Netherlands. Dev. Emerg. Econ. 2 (2), 92–114.
Birthal, P.S., Joshi, P.K., Gulati, A., 2007. Vertical coordination in high-value food Heckman, J.J., Tobias, J.L., Vytlacil, E.J., 2001. Four parameters of interest in the eva-
commodities: implications for smallholders. In: Joshi, P.K., Gulati, A., Cummings, R. luation of social programs. South. Econ. J. 68 (2), 210–233.
(Eds.), Agricultural Diversification and Smallholders in South Asia. Academic Hemme, T., et al., 2003. IFCN Dairy Report 2003. IFCN Centre, Braunschweig, Germany.
Foundation, New Delhi, pp. 405–440. Hoda, A., Rajkhowa, P., Gulati, A., 2017. Unleashing Bihar’s agriculture potential:
Birthal, P.S., Jha, A.K., Tiongeo, M.M., Narrod, C., 2009. Farm-level impacts of vertical Sources and drivers of agriculture growth. ICRIER Working Paper No-336, ICRIER,
coordination of the food supply chain: evidence from contract farming of milk in New Delhi.
India. Indian J. Agric. Econ. 64 (3), 481–495. Jardine, S.L., Lin, C.Y.C., Sanchirico, J.N., 2014. Measuring benefits from a marketing
Birthal, P.S., Chand, R., Joshi, P.K., Saxena, R., Rajkhowa, P., Khan, M.T., Khan, A., cooperative in the Copper River fishery. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 96 (4), 1084–1101.
Chaudhary, K.R., 2017. Formal versus informal: efficiency, inclusiveness and finan- Kumar, A., 2010. Milk marketing chains in Bihar: implications for dairy farmers and
cing of dairy value chains in Indian Punjab. J. Rural Stud. 54 (August 2017), traders. Agric. Econ Res. Rev., Conference Issue 469–477.
288–303. Kumar, A., Staal, S.J., Singh, D.K., 2011a. Smallholder dairy farmers’ access to modern
Candler, W., Kumar, N., 1998. India: The Dairy Revolution: Impact of Dairy Development milk marketing supply chain in India. Agric. Econ. Res. Rev. 24 (2), 243–253.
in India and the World Bank’s Contribution. World Bank Operation Evaluation Kumar, A., Wright, I.A., Singh, D.K., 2011b. Adoption of food safety practices in milk
Department, World Bank, Washington, DC. production: implications for dairy farmers in India. J. Int. Food Agribus. Mark. 23 (4),
Carter, D.W., Milon, J.W., 2005. Price knowledge in household demand for utility ser- 330–344.
vices. Land Econ. 81 (2), 265–283. Kumar, A., Shinoj, P., Jee, S., 2013. Do dairy co-operatives enhance milk production,
COMFED (Bihar State Milk Cooperative Federation), 2017a. Unit wise milk procurement. productivity and quality? Evidences from the Indo-Gangetic plain of India. Indian J.
< http://www.sudha.coop/topics.aspx?mid=Physical%20Performance > (accessed Agric. Econ. 68 (3), 457–468.
7 July 2017). Kumar, A., Thapa, G., Joshi, P.K., Roy, D., 2017a. Adoption of food safety measures on
COMFED, 2017b. District wise milk production in Bihar. < http://www.sudha.coop/ milk production in Nepal: impact on smallholders’ farm-gate prices and profitability.
DataFiles/CMS/file/Districtwise%20Milk%20Production%20-%20Bihar. Food Policy 70, 13–26.
pdf > (accessed 7 July 2017). Kumar, A., Mishra, A.K., Shinoj, P., Jha, G.K., 2017b. Structure of Milk-marketing

35
A. Kumar et al. Food Policy 75 (2018) 24–36

Channels in India: The Role of Informal Outlets. International Food Policy Research Sexton, R.J., Iskow, J., 1988. Factors Critical to the Success or Failure of Emerging
Institute, South Asia Office, New Delhi. Agricultural Cooperatives. University of California, Davis, Division of Agriculture and
Lele, U., 1981. Co-operatives and the poor: a comparative perspective. World Dev. 9 (1), Natural Resources.
55–72. Singh, K., Das, V.M., 1984. Impact of Operation Flood I at the village level. Research
Lokshin, M., Sajaia, Z., 2004. Maximum likelihood estimation of endogenous switching Report No. 1, Institute of Rural Management, Anand, India.
regression models. Stata J. 4 (3), 282–289. Singh, R.K.P., 1996. Dairy co-operatives: organizations of the poor in Bihar. In:
Maddala, G.S., Nelson, F.D., 1975. Switching regression models with exogenous and Rajagopalan, R. (Ed.), Rediscovering Cooperation: Co-operatives in the Emerging
endogenous switching. Proc. Am. Stat. Assoc. Bus. Econ. Sect. 423–426. Context. Institute of Rural Management, Anand, India.
Mergos, G., Slade, R., 1987. Dairy development and milk cooperatives: The effect of a Singh, K., Pundir, R.S., 2000. Co-operatives and rural development in India. Research
dairy project in India. World Bank Discussion Paper No. 15, World Bank, Paper 17, Institute of Rural Management, Anand, India.
Washington, DC. Shukla, R.K., Brahmankar, S.D., 1999. Impact Evaluation of Operation Flood on Rural
Narrod, C., Roy, D., Okello, J., Avendano, B., Rich, K., Thorat, A., 2009. Public-private Dairy Sector. National Council of Applied Economic Research, New Delhi.
partnerships and collective action in high-value fruit and vegetable supply chains. Stockbridge, M., Dorward, A., Kydd, J., 2003. Farmer Organizations for Market Access: A
Food Policy 34 (1), 8–15. Briefing Paper. University of London, Wye College.
NDDB (National Dairy Development Board), 2016. Annual Report 2015–2016. NDDB, Vandeplas, A., Minten, B., Swinnen, J., 2013. Multinationals vs. cooperatives: the income
Government of India. and efficiency effects of supply chain governance in India. J. Agric. Econ. 64,
Roy, D., Thorat, A., 2008. Success in high-value horticultural export markets for the small 217–244.
farmers: the case of mahagrapes in India. World Dev. 36 (1), 1874–1890.

36

You might also like