Stochastic Processes With Applications To Finance 2nd Kijima Solution Manual Full Download

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 8

Stochastic Processes with Applications to Finance 2nd Kijima Solution Manual

Stochastic Processes with Applications to Finance


2nd Kijima Solution Manual

To download the complete and accurate content document, go to:


https://testbankbell.com/download/stochastic-processes-with-applications-to-finance-
2nd-kijima-solution-manual/

Visit TestBankBell.com to get complete for all chapters


Exercise 7.1 From (7.2) we have the price of call option as follows:
Cu = {uS − K}+ = 1,
Cd = {dS − K}+ = 0,
Cu − Cd uCd − dCy
∴C = + = 0.6612.
u−d (u − d)R
Similarly, we have the price of put option:
Pu = {K − uS}+ = 0,
Pd = {K − dS}+ = 0.8333,
Pu − Pd uPd − dPu
P = + = 0.2066.
u−d (u − d)R
We can obtain each side of (5.16) as follows:
K
LHS = C + Kv(0, 1) = C + = 5.2066,
R
RHS = P + S(0) = 5.2066.
Thus, the put-call parity holds.

Exercise 7.2 Substituting (7.2) into (7.6), we get


(up − dp − R + d)Cu + (uq − dq + R − u)Cd
λC = √ .
(u − d) pq(Cu − Cd )
Because 1 − p = q,
(up − dp − R)Cu + (uq − dq + R)Cd
λC = √
(u − d) pq(Cu − Cd )
(up + dq − R)(Cu − Cd )
= √
(u − d) pq(Cu − Cd )
up + dq − R
= √
(u − d) pq
= λS .

Exercise 7.3 Let p ≡ P {S(1) = uS} = 1 − p{S(1) = dS}. Then, we get the following results by some
algebra.
   
6 5 11 25
E[S(1)] = 5 × ×p+ 5× × (1 − p) = p+
5 6 6 6
   
6 11 25 5 11 25
V [S(1)] = 5 × − p + ×p+ 5× − p+ × (1 − p)
5 6 6 6 6 6
 2
11
= p(1 − p)
6
   
6 5
E[C(1)] = 5 × − K ×p+ 5× −K × (1 − p) = p
5 + 6 +
  2   2
6 5
V [C(1)] = 5× −K −p ×p+ 5× −K − p × (1 − p)
5 + 6 +

= p(1 − p)
Therefore,
    
10 p(1 − p) 11 25 11
C= × p − 11  × p+ −5×
11 6 p(1 − p) 6 6 10
80
= = 0.6612
121

1
which is the same as obtained in Exercise 7.1.

Exercise 7.4 Constructing the node model of this security movements yields the following results:
t=0 t=1 t=2 t=3
5.000000 6.000000 7.200000 8.640000
4.166667 5.000000 6.000000 .
3.472223 4.166667
2.893519
Calculating C(t, i) at each node by using (7.3) leads to
t=0 t=1 t=2 t=3
1.395645 1.919005 2.654545 3.640000
0.437129 0.661157 1.000000 .
0.000000 0.000000
0.000000
Further we can calculate the hedging portfolio at each node as follows:
Stock
t=0 t=1 t=2
0.808296 0.906086
0.523810
0.432757
0.545455
0.000000
Money Market Account
−2.66434 −2.66434 −4.54545
−1.36603 −2.06612
0.000000
where we use
Cu − Cd uCd − dCu
w= and B= . (A.7.1)
(u − d)S (u − d)R

Exercise 7.5 The price of option at each node when T = 2 is given by


C(2, 3) = max u(uS 1+α )α (uS 1+α ) − K, 0 = 5.2809,
C(2, 2) = max d(uS 1+α )−α (uS 1+α ) − K, 0 = 0,
C(2, 1) = max u(dS 1−α )α (dS 1−α ) − K, 0 = 0,
C(2, 0) = max d(uS 1−α )−α (dS 1−α ) − K, 0 = 0,
P (2, 3) = max K − u(uS 1+α )α (uS 1+α ), 0 = 0,
P (2, 2) = max K − d(uS 1+α )−α (uS 1+α ), 0 = 0.1687,
P (2, 1) = max K − u(dS 1−α )α (dS 1−α ), 0 = 0.1687,
P (2, 0) = max K − d(uS 1−α )−α (dS 1−α ), 0 = 2.3955.
When t = 1, we have
u(1, 1) = 1.4587, d(1, 1) = 0.6855, u(1, 0) = 1.3619, d(1, 0) = 0.7342
p(1, 1) = 0.5360, p(1, 0) = 0.5826.
Thus, the option price at each node when t = 1 is given by
1
C(1, 1) = [p(1, 1)C(2, 3) + (1 − p(1, 1))C(2, 2)] = 2.5734,
r
1
C(1, 0) = [p(1, 0)C(2, 1) + (1 − p(1, 0))C(2, 0)] = 0,
r
1
P (1, 1) = [p(1, 1)P (2, 3) + (1 − p(1, 1))P (2, 2)] = 0.0711,
r
1
P (1, 0) = [p(1, 0)P (2, 1) + (1 − p(1, 0))P (2, 0)] = 0.9982.
r

2
When t = 0, we have

u(0, 0) = 1.4095, d(0, 0) = 0.7094, p(0, 0) = 0.5578.

So,we have
1
C(0, 0) = [p(0, 0)C(1, 1) + (1 − p(0, 0))C(0, 0)] = 1.3050,
r
1
P (0, 0) = [p(0, 0)P (1, 1) + (1 − p(0, 0))P (0, 0)] = 0.4373.
r
Further, we can obtain

C(0, 0) − P (0, 0) = 1.3050 − 0.4373 = 0.8677,


 2
1
S− K = 0.8677,
r

which shows the put-call parity holds in this case.

Exercise 7.6 We can calculate the stock price at each node as


2 .
S(2, 3) = (1 − δ)2+α u2+α S (1+α) = 10.281 × 0.992.1 = 10.066,
2 .
S(2, 2) = (1 − δ)2−α u1−α dS 1−α = 4.831 × 0.991.9 = 4.740,
2 .
S(2, 1) = (1 − δ)2+α ud1+α S 1−α = 4.831 × 0.992.1 = 4.730,
2 .
S(2, 0) = (1 − δ)2−α d2−α S (1−α) = 2.604 × 0.991.9 = 2.555.

Therefore, the option prices at T = 2 are given by

C(2, 3) = max{10.066 − 5, 0} = 5.066,


C(2, 2) = max{4.740 − 5, 0} = 0,
C(2, 1) = max{4.730 − 5, 0} = 0,
C(2, 0) = max{2.555 − 5, 0} = 0,
P (2, 3) = max{5 − 10.066, 0} = 0,
P (2, 2) = max{5 − 4.740, 0} = 0.260,
P (2, 1) = max{5 − 4.730, 0} = 0.270,
P (2, 0) = max{5 − 2.555, 0} = 2.445.

Next, we calculate the up-factor and down-factor, and then the risk-neutral probability at t = 1:
.
u(1, 1) = u{(1 − δ)uS 1+α }α = 1.457,
.
d(1, 1) = d{(1 − δ)uS 1+α }−α = 0.686,
.
u(1, 0) = u{(1 − δ)dS 1−α }α = 1.361,
.
d(1, 0) = d{(1 − δ)dS 1−α }−α = 0.735,
R − d(1, 1) 1.1 − 0.686
p∗ (1, 1) = = = 0.537,
u(1, 1) − d(1, 1) 1.457 − 0.686
R − d(1, 0) 1.1 − 0.735
p∗ (1, 0) = = = 0.583.
u(1, 0) − d(1, 0) 1.361 − 0.735

Hence, we can get

1 − p∗ (1, 1) = 0.463,
1 − p∗ (1, 0) = 0.417,

3
and
1 ∗
C(1, 1) = [p (1, 1)C(2, 3) + (1 − p∗ (1, 1))C(2, 2)],
R
1
= [0.537 × 5.066] = 2.471,
1.1
1 ∗
C(1, 0) = [p (1, 0)C(2, 1) + (1 − p∗ (1, 0))C(2, 0)] = 0,
R
1 ∗
P (1, 1) = [p (1, 1)P (2, 3) + (1 − p∗ (1, 1))P (2, 2)]
R
1
= 0.463 × 0.260 = 0.110,
1.1
1 ∗
P (1, 0) = [p (1, 0)P (2, 1) + (1 − p∗ (1, 0))P (2, 0)]
R
1
= [0.583 × 0.270 + 0.417 × 2.445] = 1.070.
1.1
In a similar way, we get the results at t = 0 as

u(0, 0) = uS α = 1.410, d(0, 0) = dS −α = 0.709,


R − d(0, 0)
p∗ (0, 0) = = 0.558,
u(0, 0) − d(0, 0)
1
C(0, 0) = [p∗ (0, 0)C(1, 1) + (1 − p∗ (0, 0))C(1, 0)] = 1.253,
R
1
P (0, 0) = [p∗ (0, 0)P (1, 1) + (1 − p∗ (0, 0))P (1, 0)] = 0.485.
R
Then,

C + K · v(t, T ) = 5.386,
P + S = 5.485,

which shows that put-call parity does not hold when stock pays dividends.

Exercise 7.7 When d = u−1 , S(t) = Su(t+Wt )/2 d(t−Wt )/2 = SuWt . So, letting Mn∗ = max Wk , we have
0≤k≤n

C = R−T E ∗ [{M (T ) − K}+ ]



T
= R−T P {MT∗ = j|W0 = 0} max{0, Suj − K}
j=0


T
= R−T (vj (n) + vj+1 (n)) max{0, Suj − K} (∵ Exercise 6.5)
j=0


T
= R−T (n C(n+j)/2 2−n + n C(n+j+1)/2 2−n ) max{0, Suj − K}.
j=0

Exercise 7.8 Denote the option premium by C(0). Then we know that

1 
T
C(0) = {M (T ) − K}+ P ∗ {MT∗ = j | W0 = 0}.
RT j=0

4
To have C(0), we only need to calculate P  {M (n) = j | W0 = 0} for p-random walk. In this end, we use the
change of measure as follows:

P  {M (T ) = j, WT = i|W0 = 0} =E[1{M(T )=j,WT =i} YT |W0 = 0]


=E[1{M(T )=j,WT =i} m−T (θ)eθWT |W0 = 0]
=m−T (θ)E[1{M(T )=j,WT =i} eθWT |W0 = 0]
=m−T (θ)eθi P {M (T ) = j, WT = i|W0 = 0}
p
=2T (pq)T /2 ( )i/2 (vi−2j (T ) − vi−2−2j (T )) (∵ Exercise 6.5)
q
 j
p
=2T p(T +j−2j)/2 q (T −i+2j)/2 vi−2j
q
− 2T p1+j q i−1−j p(T +j−2−2j)/2 q (T −i+2+2j)/2 vi−2−2j
 j
p
= ui−2j − p1+j q i−1−j ui−2−2j .
q
Let

j
f (j, p, q) ≡ P  {M (T ) = j, WT = i|W0 = 0} = P  {M (n) = j|W0 = 0}.
i=−T

Then, we have
 
1 
T
R−d u−R
C(0) = {Su j
− K} + f j, , .
RT j=0 u−d u−d

Exercise7.9
R−d u−R
p∗ = = 0.7272, q∗ = = 0.2727
u−d u−d
When t = T = 3,

C(3, 3) = max{u3 S − K, 0} = 3.64, C(3, 2) = max{uS − K, 0} = 1,


−1
C(3, 1) = max{u S − K, 0} = 0, C(3, 0) = max{u−3 S − K, 0} = 0.

When t = 2, since

A(2, 2) = R−1 [p∗ C(3, 3) + q ∗ C(3, 2)] = 2.65428,


A(2, 1) = R−1 [p∗ C(3, 2) + q ∗ C(3, 1)] = 0.66109,
A(2, 0) = R−1 [p∗ C(3, 1) + q ∗ C(3, 0)] = 0,

and

h(S(2, 2)) = max{u2 S − K, 0} = 2.2,


h(S(2, 1)) = max{S − K, 0} = 0,
h(S(2, 0)) = max{u−2 S − K, 0} = 0,

we have

C(2, 2) = 2.65428, C(2, 1) = 0.66109, C(2, 0) = 0.

When t = 1,

A(1, 1) = R−1 [p∗ C(2, 2) + q ∗ C(2, 1)] = 1.91861,


A(1, 0) = R−1 [p∗ C(2, 1) + q ∗ C(2, 0)] = 0.43704,

5
h(S(1, 1)) = max{uS − K, 0} = 1,
h(S(1, 0)) = max{u−1 S − K, 0} = 0

and

C(1, 1) = 1.91861, C(1, 0) = 0.43704

Finally, when t = 0, we obtain

C(0, 0) = R−1 [p∗ C(1, 1) + q ∗ C(1, 0)] = 1.37672

All results show that it is optimal not to exercise until maturity.

Exercise 7.10 The followings are the results of calculation:

h(S(2, 3)) = {(1 − δ)2.1 u2.1 S 1.21 − K}+ = 3.240


h(S(2, 2)) = {(1 − δ)1.9 u0.9 dS 0.99 − K}+ = 0
h(S(2, 1)) = {(1 − δ)2.1 ud1.1 S 0.99 − K}+ = 0
h(S(2, 0)) = {(1 − δ)1.9 d1.9 S 0.81 − K}+ = 0
h(S(1, 1)) = {(1 − δ)uS 1.1 − K}+ = 1.343
h(S(1, 0)) = {(1 − δ)dS 0.9 − K}+ = 0

A(1, 1) = R−1 [p∗ (1, 1)h(S(2, 3)) + q ∗ (1, 1)h(S(2, 2))] = 1.598
C(1, 1) = max{h(S(1, 1), A(1, 1)} = 1.598

A(1, 0) = R−1 [p∗ (1, 0)h(S(2, 1)) + q ∗ (1, 0)h(S(2, 0))] = 0


C(1, 0) = max{h(S(1, 0)), A(1, 0)} = 0

C = A(0, 0) = R−1 [p∗ (0, 0)C(1, 1) + q ∗ (0, 0)C(1, 0)]


= 0.51C(1, 1)
= 0.810

Therefore, it is optimal not to exercise until maturity.

Exercise 7.11 Rearranging (7.18) yields

Cu − Cd
= ωS,
u−d
Cu − Cm
= ωS,
u−m
Cm − Cd
= ωS,
m−d
which implies (7.19) holds. In this case, by eliminating Cm , we obtain the system which determines the
option price:
Cu − Cd
= ωS,
u−d
uCd − dCu
B= .
(u − d)R

This system is (7.1) itself, and so the option price is also the same as (7.2).

6
Stochastic Processes with Applications to Finance 2nd Kijima Solution Manual
Exercise 7.12 The condition that λ becomes a risk neutral probability is 0 < λ < 1. By equation (7.23),
d(uC − Cu )
λ= . (A.7.2)
uCd − dCu
And so, we obtain
d(uC − Cu )
0< <1 (A.7.3)
uCd − dCu
and by rearranging the above inequality, we get

uC < Cu (A.7.4)
dC > Cd . (A.7.5)

Exercise 7.15 In the three-period economy, there are four types of discounted bonds. We denote each
price as
Maturity t=0 t=1 t=2 t=3
0 v(0, 0)
1 v(0, 1) v(1, 1)
vd (1, 2)
2 v(0, 2) v(2, 2)
vu (1, 2)
vdd (2, 3)
vd (1, 3) vdu (2, 3)
3 v(0, 3) v(3, 3)
vu (1, 3) vud (2, 3)
vuu (2, 3)

Let p∗∗
d the risk-neutral probability that vdu (2, 3) realizes conditional on vd (1, 3). Then, we have
−1
vd (1, 3) = R2d [(1 − p∗∗ ∗∗
d )vdd (2, 3) + pd vdu (2, 3)],

1
where R2d ≡ vd (1,2) . Therefore, we can obtain
vd (1,3)
vdd (2, 3) − vd (1,2)
p∗∗ =
d
vdd (2, 3) − vdu (2, 3)
Similarly, if we let p∗∗
u the risk-neutral probability that vuu (2, 3) realizes conditional on vu (1, 3), then
−1
vd (1, 3) = R2u [(1 − p∗∗ ∗∗
u )vud (2, 3) + pu vuu (2, 3)]

1
where R2u ≡ vu (1,2) , and
vu (1,3)
vud (2, 3) − vu (1,2)
p∗∗
u =
vud (2, 3) − vuu (2, 3)
For the risk-neutral probalibity that vu (1, 3) realizes conditional on v(0, 3), we can easily see that

v1 (0, 3) = R1−1 [(1 − p∗∗ )vd (1, 3) + p∗∗ vu (1, 3)],


1
R1 ≡ ,
vu (0, 1)
vu (0,3)
vd (1, 3) − vu (0,1)
p∗∗ = .
vd (1, 3) − vu (1, 3)
For the bond of maturity 2, we have in a similar manner that
vu (0,2)
vd (1, 2) − vu (0,1)
p∗ = ,
vd (1, 2) − vu (1, 2)
where p∗ is the probability that vu (0, 2) realizes. But apparently p∗ = p∗∗ .

Visit TestBankBell.com to get complete for all chapters

You might also like