Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 15

European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

European Management Journal


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/emj

Job satisfaction and investment efficiency – Evidence from crowdsourced


employer reviews
Susanne Arvidsson a, Brigitte Eierle b, Sven Hartlieb b, *
a
Lund University, Sweden
b
University of Bamberg, Germany

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

JEL classification: This study investigates the effect of job satisfaction on investment efficiency. To operationalize job satisfaction
G30 empirically, we employ a novel measure based on crowdsourced employer reviews. Considering the as yet under-
J28 researched and less regulated private firm setting, in which internal characteristics such as employee satisfaction
M14
should play a more important role for corporate actions, we find that our measure for job satisfaction has a
M40
positive impact on investment efficiency. High job satisfaction seems to alleviate problems related to moral
Keywords:
hazard and adverse selection resulting from information asymmetries, which ultimately improves corporate
Job satisfaction
Investment efficiency
investment efficiency. We further show that high job satisfaction reduces particularly the likelihood of under­
Moral hazard investment, where profitable investment projects are not carried out. Our study demonstrates the importance of
Information asymmetry cultivating a positive workplace environment with contented employees, which does benefit fundamental
Private firms corporate actions.

1. Introduction In this study, we investigate the impact of job satisfaction on in­


vestment efficiency. Job satisfaction refers to the assessment of how the
A key success factor for corporations is whether capital is allocated to current job is perceived by an individual member of a firm (e.g., Coff,
the best investment projects (e.g., Zhang et al., 2016). In a perfect 1997; Schneider & Vaught, 1993). This attitude developed by in­
market, corporations take all profitable investment opportunities dividuals toward their job can be affected by various factors such as
(Modigliani & Miller, 1958). However, in the real world with imperfect payment, working environment, firms’ CSR activities, supervision, co­
markets, various factors militate against optimal investment levels (e.g., workers, promotion, and the work itself (Coff, 1997; Bayarcelik & Afa­
Biddle et al., 2009; Gomariz & Ballesta, 2014). In particular, agency can Findikli, 2016).
conflicts and information asymmetries resulting in moral hazard and Job satisfaction can affect investment efficiency via different chan­
adverse selection might lead to situations in which firms do not have nels. Management literature highlights that job satisfaction may reduce
access to sufficient capital for funding investment opportunities with agency conflicts and, thus, mitigate adverse behavior (Flammer & Luo,
positive net present value (NPV) (underinvestment) or in which man­ 2017). Derived from psychology theories, corporate decision-makers
agers undertake unprofitable investment projects (overinvestment) for who appreciate their job should behave in ways that foster or support
personal motives such as empire building (e.g., Biddle et al., 2009). The the firm (e.g., Judge & Larsen, 2001). Hence, opportunistic behavior
extant literature reveals that a great deal of effort has been spent on under moral hazard should play a less pronounced role in firms where
identifying factors that influence the level of investment efficiency. job satisfaction is high, as corroborated by empirical literature (e.g., Ji
These factors include the following: the executive compensation struc­ et al., 2017). However, decision-makers in firms with high job satis­
ture (Eisdorfer et al., 2013); capital structure (Pawlina, 2010); mana­ faction should not only intrinsically act less opportunistically, but the­
gerial ability (Gan, 2019); financial reporting quality (e.g., Biddle et al., ories from organizational research also indicate that a high level of
2009; Gomariz & Ballesta, 2014); board independence (Rajkovic, 2020); satisfaction within a company leads to a positive work group context (i.
external auditor characteristics (Bae et al., 2017); and corporate social e., a positive work environment), where there is a higher degree of
responsibility (CSR) (e.g., Benlemlih & Bitar, 2018; Cook et al., 2019). cohesiveness, helping behavior, and sense of morality (e.g., Kidwell &

* Corresponding author. University of Bamberg, Germany.


E-mail addresses: susanne.arvidsson@fek.lu.se (S. Arvidsson), brigitte.eierle@uni-bamberg.de (B. Eierle), sven.hartlieb@uni-bamberg.de (S. Hartlieb).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.emj.2022.10.007
Received 30 April 2021; Received in revised form 28 July 2022; Accepted 27 October 2022
Available online 31 October 2022
0263-2373/© 2022 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Please cite this article as: Susanne Arvidsson, European Management Journal, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.emj.2022.10.007
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

Valentine, 2009). Thus, job satisfaction relating to the group context employer reviews from a large online employer rating website. More
may act as a disciplining device that substitutes for external monitoring precisely, employees can comprehensively rate their employer on the
and can be associated with higher investment efficiency by reducing basis of 13 different dimensions such as teamwork, compensation, work
moral hazard. A well-documented moral hazard problem in the context climate, social responsibility, and work-life-balance, which is in line
of corporate investments is ‘empire building’, which refers to the with the definition that job satisfaction comprises a variety of factors
expansion of a firm that is not economically justified, but instead driven (Coff, 1997). For our main analyses, we compute an aggregate job
by opportunistic managerial motives such as compensation and prestige satisfaction score based on the 13 dimensions. From hand-collected re­
(e.g., Hope & Thomas, 2008). Hence, job satisfaction should constrain views, almost 9700 for 237 firms, empirical results corroborate our
overinvestment issues due to fewer problems with managerial moral hypotheses that job satisfaction is positively associated with investment
hazard, which is the basis of our first hypothesis. efficiency.
However, reduced moral hazard problems and less opportunistic We also demonstrate that this relationship is primarily driven by
managerial behavior due to job satisfaction might also lead to less un­ reduced underinvestment problems. Hence, high job satisfaction with
derinvestment. Managers who are satisfied with their job might be more motivated and contented employees seems particularly to prevent
willing to spend more effort on looking for profitable investment pro­ liquidity shortfalls by facilitating access to capital. Since job satisfaction
jects. Moreover, they are less likely to refrain from conducting a prof­ is expected to increase disclosure quality and the effectiveness of
itable investment project just to avoid the threat of personal damages communication to external stakeholders (e.g., Huang et al., 2017; Ji
with respect to reputation and job security in the unlikely event that a et al., 2017), reduced information asymmetries between firms and
project turns out to be unprofitable (Myers, 1977; Ward et al., 2020). outside capital providers, and therefore lower adverse selection prob­
Information asymmetries also exist between the firm and outside lems, seem to be the key drivers. Moreover, since satisfied employees are
capital providers, which may lead to a situation of adverse selection in expected to be more motivated to support their employer (i.e., there are
advance of borrowing transactions. Capital providers anticipating fewer problems related to moral hazard), higher firm performance and
problems of moral hazard are likely to react by charging higher corresponding easier access to capital seemingly forms a key channel.
financing fees and constraining their capital supply. It is well known that The effect of job satisfaction on overinvestment is statistically insignif­
firms with less severe moral hazard problems provide more disclosures icant, indicating that managerial opportunism to pursue self-serving
that are of higher quality (e.g., Chung et al., 2002; Hui & Matsunga, motives that are not in the interests of the firm and its stakeholders,
2015), and they have more effective communication with external such as empire building, does not play a dominant role. This is probably
stakeholders (e.g., Huang et al., 2017). Capital providers are likely to because agency conflicts in terms of opportunistic management
recognize this reduced risk and lower information asymmetry by facil­ behavior are generally less important in the private firm setting due to
itating access to capital for firms with high job satisfaction (Biddle et al., ownership structure (e.g., Gao et al., 2013).
2009; Lambert et al., 2011; Stiglitz & Weiss, 1981). In additional tests, we explore which of the individual job satisfac­
Furthermore, agency conflicts apply not only to a firm’s management tion dimensions captured by our aggregate variable are the dominant
but also its employees (Chen & Huang, 2006). Human resource theories drivers for our findings. We find that various dimensions have a signif­
suggest that in firms where moral hazard is less pronounced and em­ icant bearing on underinvestment problems, supporting the view that
ployees are more satisfied, there should be a higher motivation to job satisfaction is a very broad concept, and that there is no specific
contribute to firm success (e.g., Huang et al., 2015; Maslow, 1943), individual dimension that drives investment decisions. As one excep­
which is in line with empirical evidence (e.g., Fauver et al., 2018; Huang tion, social responsibility has no significant impact on underinvestment.
et al., 2015). Because of information asymmetries and limited moni­ This seems reasonable because CSR activities reflect in particular top
toring, capital providers use financial information (e.g., credit ratings management’s social and ethical values (e.g., Hemingway & Maclagan,
and financial covenants) to determine the cost of capital and general 2004), with any unethical managerial behavior regarding investment
access to external funding. This is why job satisfaction should also secure decisions often giving rise to empire building and overinvestment (Gul
the ability to engage in profitable investment decisions via improved et al., 2020). The negative relationship between job satisfaction and
firm performance (e.g., Adams et al., 2003; Jiang, 2008), in line with underinvestment is also robust to a variety of sensitivity tests.
empirical evidence which finds that firms with higher job satisfaction Our study extends existing literature in a number of important ways.
among employees exhibit lower cost of debt (Chi & Chen, 2021). Sum­ Firstly, to our knowledge, this is the first study that explores how job
marized, job satisfaction may also decrease underinvestment issues, satisfaction affects investment efficiency. Specifically, with our measure
which forms the basis of our second hypothesis. of job satisfaction based on crowdsourced employer reviews, we intro­
In our study, we consider a sample of German private firms to duce a relatively novel variable to corporate investment literature. This
investigate the relationship between job satisfaction and investment also means that our study differs from that of Benlemlih and Bitar (2018)
efficiency. In Germany, private firms – also known as the German who have investigated the impact of CSR. CSR is a broader concept than
‘Mittelstand’ – play a crucial role for the overall economy (e.g., job satisfaction that to some extent also comprises employee treatment
Audretsch & Elston, 1997). We exploit the institutional features of this and which should therefore be closely related to employees’ job satis­
German setting, particularly in regard to the comprehensive availability faction. (e.g., Dahlsrud, 2008; Fauver et al., 2018). In their survey study,
of private firms’ financial statement information (e.g., Bassemir, 2018). Wisse et al. (2018) show that CSR activities may have a positive influ­
Considering the effect of job satisfaction in a private firm setting pro­ ence on job satisfaction, but, at the same time, they also stress that these
vides an ideal basis for this study since corporate actions (including are two different concepts. CSR activities are primarily set by top
investment activities) are less influenced by external governance management and addressed to the public (Wisse et al., 2018), so that the
mechanisms such as stricter regulation (e.g., enforcement), financial resulting reports may contain proclaimed values only and not those that
intermediaries (e.g., financial analysts and institutional investors), and are actually present within the company.1 Measures of job satisfaction
other market forces (e.g., takeover threats) (e.g., Chen et al., 2011; Hope based on more direct surveys and employer reviews, by contrast, allow
et al., 2012; Minnis & Shroff, 2017). Accordingly, focusing on private in-depth insights into actual internal firm attributes such as social
firms is ideal for empirically investigating the effect of job satisfaction, values, coherence, and motivation among managers as well as their staff,
in that there are fewer alternative effects caused by other (external)
influencing factors, which is why for instance the threat of omitted
variable bias should be less pronounced in this setting. 1
In line with this, Benlemlih and Bitar (2018) use CSR ratings based on in­
To measure job satisfaction empirically, we follow a recent stream of formation from a number of external resources such as financial reports or
literature (e.g., Chi & Chen, 2021; Huang et al., 2015) and make use of articles in the business press.

2
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

which is particularly important when considering investment efficiency Gordon, 1992). Particularly when considering information asymmetries
that is primarily determined by internal agency conflicts. This is also under the agency framework (Jensen & Meckling, 1976), it should be
supported by Guiso et al. (2015) who argue that employee perceptions noted that firms may deviate from optimal investment levels (e.g.,
matter for actual firm performance (including investment efficiency), Biddle et al., 2009; Gomariz & Ballesta, 2014). A vast amount of liter­
while proclaimed corporate values appear as being irrelevant (Huang ature has consequently challenged the idea of perfect financial markets,
et al., 2015). where all positive NPV projects are financed and carried out (e.g., Ağca
Secondly, investment efficiency literature has – apart from a few & Mozumdar, 2008; Hubbard, 1998). Instead, market imperfections are
exceptions (e.g., Chen et al., 2011) – primarily focused on publicly listed found to induce the undertaking of negative NPV projects (over­
firms. Private firms are predominant in most economies, but as yet we investment) and profitable investments opportunities being postponed
generally know comparatively little about their corporate actions (see or omitted (underinvestment) (e.g., Biddle et al., 2009).
Chen et al., 2011).2 Private firms are significantly different from public In the presence of information asymmetries together with limited
firms with respect to various characteristics such as the nature of agency monitoring opportunities, models of moral hazard suggest that man­
conflicts, which is why we cannot simply rely on findings for public agers and employees have incentives to behave in ways that are detri­
companies when we want to understand investment efficiency within mental to shareholders and capital providers (e.g., Biddle et al., 2009;
private firms, in line with a statement from Langli and Svanström (2014, Jensen & Meckling, 1976). A well-documented managerial moral hazard
p. 149) according to whom “differences that exist between private and problem in the context of corporate investments is ‘empire building’,
public companies are so large and fundamental that without careful which refers to managers’ motives to conduct unfavorable investment
consideration we cannot rely on findings for public companies”.3 projects and grow the firm beyond its optimal size with the purpose of
Finally, whilst the role of job satisfaction measured by employer maximizing their personal welfare in regard to power, compensation,
reviews has received increased attention over recent years (e.g., Hope and prestige (e.g., Chen et al., 2012; Hope & Thomas, 2008; Jensen,
et al., 2021; Huang et al., 2015; Ji et al., 2017; Khavis & Krishnan, 2021; 1986). This can result in overinvestment, where managers of firms with
Li, 2022), this literature stream has almost entirely disregarded the ample capital select bad projects.
private firm setting. We argue that this setting is ideal for such a study Models of adverse selection also postulate that managers (ex-ante)
given that there are fewer alternative effects caused by, for example, take advantage of information asymmetries during the course of a
stricter regulations and more financial market coverage (e.g., Chen negotiation. Managers are better informed than capital providers about
et al., 2011). Hence, since investment decisions should be affected by the firm’s operating activities, financial conditions, and future prospects
fewer (external) influencing factors in this setting, from an empirical (Biddle et al., 2009). Although capital providers will carefully scrutinize
perspective it is easier to isolate the effect of job satisfaction, which as an the firms’ financial condition and can gain access to public information
internal factor might generally play a more pronounced role here. Our and information directly from the firm, there is always private infor­
investigation provides evidence that job satisfaction also matters for mation that only managers possess (Chi & Chen, 2021). Because of
fundamental corporate actions in private firms. limited monitoring capabilities, managers of constrained firms are able
Our study is structured as follows. The next section presents theo­ to exploit this advantage at the expense of capital providers, for
retical background information and hypotheses development, followed example, by engaging in earnings management or high-risk investment
by our explanation of the setting considered. We then describe the projects. However, rational capital providers anticipate this behavior
methodology employed to test our hypotheses together with the sample which is detrimental to their own interests and hence constrain their
and data analyzed. Empirical results are presented in the succeeding capital supply or provide capital only at higher rates (e.g., Biddle et al.,
section, before we close the study with conclusions and limitations. 2009; Hubbard, 1998; Lambert et al., 2011; Stiglitz & Weiss, 1981). This
in turn can result in underinvestment problems because firms are forced
2. Theoretical background and hypotheses development to bypass attractive investment opportunities that they would otherwise
have undertaken.
2.1. Investment efficiency
2.2. Job satisfaction and investment efficiency
Under the neo-classical framework, managers make corporate in­
vestment decisions to maximize firm value (e.g., Hayashi, 1982; Yosh­ Job satisfaction relates to the assessment of how the current job is
ikawa, 1980). In particular, the Modigliani and Miller (1958) theorem perceived (e.g., Coff, 1997; Schneider & Vaught, 1993). More precisely,
posits that profitable investment opportunities constitute the only driver Locke (1976, p. 1304) defines job satisfaction as “a pleasurable or pos­
of corporate investments (Benlemlih & Bitar, 2018). Under this para­ itive emotional state resulting from the appraisal of one’s job or job
digm, firms should conduct all investments with positive NPV and experiences”. This attitude developed by individuals toward their jobs
continue to invest until the marginal benefit of investment equals the can be positive or negative in terms of various factors connected with the
marginal cost. Hence, this postulates a frictionless market not only in tasks they are performing, such as payment, working environment, su­
which firms obtain financing for positive NPV projects at the prevailing pervision, coworkers, promotion, and the work itself (Coff, 1997;
economy-wide interest rate and return excess cash to investors, but also Bayarcelik & Afacan Findikli, 2016). Accordingly, job satisfaction is a
in which managers will generally act in the best interests of the firm (e. broad concept, which may be variously associated with corporate in­
g., Biddle et al., 2009; Hayashi, 1982). vestment efficiency, as we now discuss in greater detail.
However, from a Keynesian perspective, corporate investments are Management literature highlights that job satisfaction may reduce
also likely to be determined by various other factors such as financial the likelihood of adverse behavior (e.g., Flammer & Luo, 2017;
security, firm growth, and behavioral issues (e.g., Baddeley, 2017; Schneider & Vaught, 1993; Vroom, 1964). Individuals who are satisfied
with their job are less likely to quit and are usually more motivated,
identify with their employer, internalize company objectives and, thus,
2 put in more efforts to avoid being laid off (Edmans, 2011, similar
To illustrate the economic importance of private firms around the world:
Edmans, 2012). Accordingly, in cases where people perceive their cur­
Private companies generate 50% of private sector GDP in the U.S. (Minnis,
2011), and small- and medium-sized private firms represent more than 99% of rent employment to be superior in comparison to other job alternatives,
European firms (Federation of European Accountants, 2016). they are more likely to act in the interests of the firm. In a similar vein,
3
With this statement, Langli and Svanström (2014) particularly refer to the social psychology theories argue that people evaluating an attitude ob­
financial statement audit of private firms, but this can in our opinion also be ject favorable tend to behave in a way that foster or support it (Judge &
transferred to understanding investment decisions by private firms. Larsen, 2001).

3
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

In line with these arguments, empirical research finds that em­ expected to have a positive NPV. Managers might be keener to avoid the
ployees who are satisfied with their jobs are less likely to engage in theft risk of reputational damage and job security issues rather than engaging
or fraud and display higher effort as well as attentiveness (e.g., Organ & in promising investments that might also turn out to be unprofitable
Ryan, 1995; Huang et al., 2015; Trevino & Weaver, 2001). With respect (Myers, 1977; Ward et al., 2020).
to finance and accounting, Ji et al. (2017) for example report that firms Moreover, information asymmetries between the firm and outside
with higher job satisfaction among employees are less likely to be capital providers may lead to adverse selection in advance of borrowing
engaged in financial misconduct. Thus, employees who are satisfied transactions. Capital providers anticipating problems of moral hazard
with their jobs are less likely to take advantage of information asym­ will react by charging firms higher financing cost and constrain their
metries so that the moral hazard problem should be less pronounced. capital supply, which may then lead to underinvestment problems. If job
Based on this discussion, contented decision-makers should be less likely satisfaction reduces incentives to engage in value destroying activities
to consider self-serving motives but instead act in the best interests of the and take advantage of information asymmetries when raising capital, as
firm and its stakeholders. With respect to investment decisions, execu­ assumed by the discussion above, it should also reduce information
tives with high job satisfaction should in particular be less likely to asymmetries. It is well known that firms with less severe moral hazard
consider personal empire building motives to expand the firm, even if problems provide more disclosures that are of higher quality (e.g.,
the corresponding investments are not expected to be profitable in the Chung et al., 2002; Hui & Matsunga, 2015),4 and that higher disclosure
long term. quality then reduces firms’ cost of debt (e.g., Sengupta, 1998). In that
Furthermore, decision-makers in companies with high job satisfac­ regard, the empirical finding of Ji et al. (2017) is crucial. They report
tion should not only intrinsically behave more in line with companies’ that the financial reporting quality of firms with high employee satis­
interests, but job satisfaction should also affect this behavior by creating faction is indeed higher. Moreover, particularly in debt contracting,
a positive work group environment. Theories from organizational private communication also plays an important role in reducing infor­
research suggest that such an environment, where employees “… mation asymmetries (e.g., Cascino et al., 2014; Chen, 2016). Job satis­
perceive the presence of encouraging work conditions that enhance their faction is found to be significant in enhancing the accuracy and
attitudes about the workplace, including the perceived degree of cohe­ effectiveness of communication, not only within a firm but also from the
siveness, helping behavior, and peer leadership” (Kidwell & Valentine, perspective of external stakeholders (e.g., Huang et al., 2017). Hence,
2009, p. 17), has a positive impact on work behavior by reinforcing with higher quality of corporate disclosures and more efficient
normative performance and attitudes. Thus, some elements of job communication, information asymmetries between firms and capital
satisfaction related to the group context, as for example cohesiveness, providers should be lower, which alleviates the problem of adverse se­
may act as a disciplining device by constraining adverse behavior and, lection and facilitates access to external capital in order to conduct
thus, provide a substitute for external monitoring. In line with this profitable investment projects. In other words, capital providers are
argumentation, research finds that the group context influences em­ likely to recognize this reduced risk and lower information asymmetry,
ployees’ behavior and attitudes, including beliefs about work perfor­ which consequently encourages them to increase their capital supply (at
mance in general and the execution of their own jobs specifically lower cost) (Biddle et al., 2009; Lambert et al., 2011; Stiglitz & Weiss,
(Kidwell & Valentine, 2009). Besides the ‘tone at the top’ theory, which 1981).
describes an organization’s ethical climate as being established and Moreover, whilst agency theory has mainly focused on management
monitored by top management (e.g., Schwartz et al., 2005), literature behavior, the theory is applicable to any jobs within a firm that are
argues that a ‘bottom-up’ approach also needs to be considered (e.g., difficult to monitor, which also includes employee behavior (Chen &
Hess & Broughton, 2014; Hill & Rapp, 2014; McDonell, 2011). Huang, 2006). Hence, employers are confronted with the problem of
Following this latter approach, ethical behavior throughout a firm is also moral hazard associated with employee behavior, because employees
significantly established by employees (i.e., ‘blue-collar workers’). In a might exploit information asymmetries by providing lower performance
similar vein, Campbell and Shang (2022) consider the ‘tone at the bot­ if they are not adequately treated (Chen & Huang, 2006). Since the
tom’ and show that corporate misconduct can be identified on the basis problem of moral hazard is less pronounced among firms with high job
of employee comments. Hence, if a positive group context via social satisfaction, employees are expected to be more motivated and more
norms substitutes for external monitoring, it should also be associated likely to act in the best interests of firms. Employees are considered as
with lower overinvestment problems (due to empire building incentives) key organizational assets (e.g., Maslow, 1943), and human resource
by reducing moral hazard. theories argue that employee satisfaction can benefit firms by
To summarize, high job satisfaction in a company should lead to strengthening motivation and retention (Huang et al., 2015). In line
investment decisions that are less likely to be influenced by opportu­ with this, empirical research finds that firms with higher job satisfaction
nistic empire building motives linked to unprofitable investment pro­ benefit from higher firm performance (e.g., Fauver et al., 2018; Huang
jects, both because content decision makers act intrinsically more in the et al., 2015), excess long-term returns, and higher firm values in the long
interest of the firm and because satisfied personnel can act as a corporate run (Edmans, 2011, 2012). In general, capital providers will only be
governance mechanism. In other words, job satisfaction should curb willing to finance an investment project if they believe that a company is
overinvestment issues because there are fewer moral hazard problems, able to successfully implement a positive NPV project (e.g., Garcia Lara
which leads us to our first hypothesis as follows: et al., 2016). Moreover, capital providers bear a credit risk, namely that
the money borrowed will not be repaid, and they cannot perfectly
H1. Job satisfaction is negatively associated with overinvestment
monitor the debtor due to information asymmetries, which is why they
However, reduced moral hazard problems and less opportunistic heavily rely on financial information about the debtor (for instance,
managerial behavior due to job satisfaction, as discussed earlier, might aggregated in a credit rating score or key performance indicator) for
impact not only overinvestment but also underinvestment. It requires their decision to supply capital and for determining the corresponding
substantial effort by managers to continually evaluate investment pro­ cost of debt (e.g., Adams et al., 2003; Cascino et al., 2014; Jiang, 2008).
jects and look for projects with positive NPV, which is why unmotivated Financial performance not only matters during the negotiation of a
managers in high agency conflict firms might refrain from making this
effort and rather enjoy the ‘quiet life’ (e.g., Bertrand & Mullainathan,
2003; Ward et al., 2020). Since managers are evaluated in accordance 4
In fact, high-quality corporate disclosures are considered as a key instru­
with the ex-post profitability of projects instead of ex-ante mean of the ment to reduce information asymmetries, which is why enforcement of
projects’ returns and actual managerial effort, they might also refrain disclosure rules are frequently discussed in research and practice (e.g., Versano,
from investing in risky investment projects even though they are 2020).

4
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

borrowing transaction but firms also need to perform continually in more important for capital providers’ contracting decisions in the pri­
order to keep the cost of debt low and secure capital availability, for vate firm setting compared to the publicly listed firm setting.
instance, due to financial covenants integrated in lending agreements (e. Finally, as explained above, one channel for the relationship between
g., Cascino et al., 2014; Gârleanu & Zwiebel, 2009; Smith Jr. 1993). job satisfaction and investment efficiency suggests that more satisfied
Hence, job satisfaction should also secure firms’ ability to engage in decision makers are less likely to act opportunistically (such as making
profitable investment decisions via better access to capital due to inefficient investment decisions), and that people who like their jobs are
improved performance. This is in accordance with recent empirical ev­ generally more motivated and perform better in order to avoid losing
idence that firms with more satisfied employees incur lower cost of debt their valued positions. This argument should be particularly relevant in
(Chi & Chen, 2021). a private firm setting, where the labor market is less efficient than that of
To summarize, job satisfaction may also improve a firm’s access to public companies (Durand & Vargas, 2003).
capital due to mitigating problems of moral hazard and adverse selec­ However, it is also important to consider that privately held firms are
tion, thereby decreasing underinvestment issues. This leads to our sec­ usually more closely controlled by owners who often take more active
ond hypothesis as follows: roles in management (e.g., Chen et al., 2011). Indeed, partially there is
no separation between management and ownership. According to
H2. Job satisfaction is negatively associated with underinvestment
Alchian and Woodward (1988), ex-post uncertainty and contract
incompleteness are reduced to a minimum in private firms controlled by
3. Institutional setting: private firms in Germany
the owner(s) and not an assigned agent. Opportunistic behavior is
reduced because the members in such a firm setting share the same
We investigate the impact of job satisfaction on investment efficiency
conditions/wishes and therefore focus on promoting positive corporate
using a sample of German private firms. Whilst private firms dominate
actions to increase their own wealth (Fama & Jensen, 1983). This union
and play a vital role in the world economy, as yet in general terms we
of ownership and control thus reduces the (managerial) moral hazard
know comparatively little about their corporate actions (e.g., Chen et al.,
problem, the likelihood of self-utility maximization by the agents, and,
2011), for instance, for reasons of data availability. Considering private
more importantly for this study, an inefficient use of resources (Fama &
firms is therefore relevant, and we argue that for a number of reasons
Jensen, 1983). Based on this notion of reduced moral hazard, Durand
such consideration is especially appropriate for our research question.
and Vargas (2003) argue and find evidence for owner-controlled private
By definition, privately held firms do not participate in public stock
firms being more efficient than those led by agents. However, for one
markets. Such markets are highly regulated, and participants are subject
thing, not all private firms are owner-managed, and, secondly, infor­
to stringent external regulations and enforcement (e.g., Minnis & Shroff,
mation asymmetries between debt capital providers and the manage­
2017). Publicly listed firms’ activities are also more restricted by
ment and between regular staff and firms are still prevalent in the
external market forces such as takeovers threats, which help to control
private firm setting.
agency conflicts (Hope et al., 2012). Moreover, in the public firm setting,
Germany provides an ideal setting because private firms are
external financial intermediaries such as financial analysts and institu­
considered to play a more important role for the German economy than
tional investors play significant governance roles (e.g., Sun, 2009). In
in other nations such as the US or UK (Audretsch & Elston, 1997; private
the private firm setting, external governance mechanisms and regulation
firms in Germany are often also termed as the German ‘Mittelstand’ and
are less pronounced, which is why internal firm characteristics and
are considered as the backbone for Germany’s economic success). More
informal institutions, such as job satisfaction, should play more impor­
importantly, the institutional system in Germany guarantees that
tant roles for private firms in mitigating moral hazard.
financial information is publicly available for German private firms,
Furthermore, private firms’ financial reports are not as widely
with more than one million being legally required to disclose financial
distributed to the public, and they are not required to disclose as much
statements publicly on an annual basis (Bassemir, 2018). Data avail­
information as publicly listed clients (e.g., Badertscher et al., 2013;
ability is a key challenge when studying private firms (e.g., Langli &
Burkart et al., 2003; Chen et al., 2011; Hope et al., 2012). This may
Svanström, 2014) and is therefore central for conducting this study. In
impact capital providers’ monitoring abilities and in turn increase
Germany, as a typical code law jurisdiction, financial accounting is
problems of adverse selection and moral hazard. Accordingly, major
traditionally regulated by law. Legal consequences and disclosure re­
capital providers do not usually rely on published financial statements
quirements for private firms are largely dependent on a firm’s size. Large
only but also have insider access to private firms’ corporate information
private firms based on size criteria within the German Commercial Code
(e.g., Van Tendeloo & Vanstraelen, 2008; Chen et al., 2011). The rela­
(GCC) are generally required to disclose financial reports to the same
tionship between private firms and external stakeholders is therefore
extent as publicly listed clients, and the financial data is provided online
also considered as less formal, and communication is expected to be
by the Federal Gazette (in German: ‘Bundesanzeiger’). Finally, there is a
more important and efficient (e.g., Habib et al., 2018; Herda & Lavelle,
large employer rating website available in Germany that publicly pro­
2015; Hope et al., 2011). Finance theory argues that especially banks
vides employee reviews for German private firms. We use these reviews
have superior information-processing abilities and better access to pri­
for our comprehensive job satisfaction measure, which we detail in the
vate information than other capital providers (e.g., Cascino et al., 2014;
following section.
Chen, 2016; Fama, 1985). Banks are important sources of finance for
private firms (Svanström, 2013), which applies particularly to our
4. Research design
setting of private firms in Germany, that are traditionally much more
bank-oriented than in other jurisdictions such as the U.S., where equity
4.1. Measurement of job satisfaction
financing and public debt providers (i.e., bonds) play a more pro­
nounced role.5 Hence, since capital providers are less likely to rely on
To examine our hypotheses, it is crucial to utilize appropriate data
publicly disclosed financial information only and have closer relation­
for measuring job satisfaction. Such data is usually difficult to obtain and
ships to private firms with access to insider information, nonfinancial
requires either a comprehensive survey program among firm members
factors such as job satisfaction and employee motivation might become
or the implementation of many in-depth interviews (e.g., Schneider &
Vaught, 1993). We followed a recent stream of research and made use of
employer reviews from large online employer rating websites, which
5
Expressed in figures, 88.3% of the debt capital for German firms stem from have become more famous in recent decade (e.g., Chi & Chen, 2021;
bank loans while the vast majority (86.4%) of debt capital for U.S. firms is from Huang et al., 2015; Huang et al., 2017; Ji et al., 2017; Li, 2022). More
public debt (i.e., bonds) (Bendel et al., 2016). precisely, we hand-collected employer reviews from Kununu, which is

5
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

the largest website in German-speaking countries where current and we expect to find a negative estimate based on our two hypotheses. We
former employees (both regular staff and executives) can anonymously also follow prior empirical literature and include a number of control
rate their employers.6 Employees can rate companies on the basis of 13 variables for factors that are expected to have a potential impact on
different dimensions on a scale from one to five: (1) Working Atmo­ corporate investment activities (e.g., Benlemlih & Bitar, 2018; Biddle
sphere, (2) Support by Management, (3) Teamwork, (4) Challenging et al., 2009; Chen et al., 2011; Gomariz & Ballesta, 2014). As a proxy for
Tasks, (5) Communication, (6) Gender Equality, (7) Attitude Toward firm size, we use the natural logarithm of total assets (Size). Further­
Older Colleagues, (8) Career Development, (9) Fair Compensation, (10) more, we include a control variable for the number of employees (Em­
Workplace Environment, (11) Social/Environmental Consciousness, ployees). We also include a measure for firm age because more mature
(12) Work-Life-Balance, and (13) Company Image. The average across firms might carry more experience in investment activities, which could
all dimensions forms the overall rating for each review.7 In essence, increase investment efficiency (Age). We include a variable for the use of
these reviews reflect employees’ opinions/judgements and workplace debt (Leverage) since firms with higher leverage might have more dif­
experiences. As such, they can serve as a comprehensive and direct ficulties in obtaining additional debt financing, which would increase in
measurement of overall job satisfaction as experienced by firm mem­ particular underinvestment problems. We expect the same for unprof­
bers. The validity of such reviews as measures of job satisfaction was itable firms, which is why we additionally include a loss dummy (Loss).
further confirmed by prior literature (Landers et al., 2019). Our final We calculate the firm-level standard deviation in return on assets
measure (Satisfaction) is calculated as the mean across all reviews for (RoA_S) since performance persistence might affect not only the avail­
each firm and ranges from one to five (low to high satisfaction, ability of internal funds but also access to debt. Since the variance in
respectively). cash available should also have an impact on investment activities, we
compute the firm-level standard deviation in cash and cash equivalents
(Cash_S). Next, the ratio of tangible assets to total assets (Tangibility) is
4.2. Investment efficiency model included as a measure for bankruptcy costs (Biddle & Hilary, 2006). We
also control for the level of cashflows (Cashflow) because high cashflows
To measure investment efficiency empirically, we follow recent might lead to overinvestment activities (agency conflicts and empire
literature (Benlemlih & Bitar, 2018; Gomariz & Ballesta, 2014) and rely building).
on an indirect approach introduced by Biddle et al. (2009) and Chen Moreover, we include the inverse Mills (IMR) ratio generated as
et al. (2011).8 These studies predict the ‘normal’ level of investments based on a two-stage Heckman approach. With this approach, we follow
and then estimate the deviation from this expected optimum to assess prior literature (Huang et al., 2015, 2017) and aim at mitigating po­
the level of inefficiency. More precisely, they estimate the level of in­ tential selection bias for our sample firms. More specifically, there might
vestment in the following year as a function (1) of growth opportunities be concerns that our sample firms with (sufficient) employer reviews
(measured as growth in sales) in the current year, and the level of in­ available are systematically different from firms without sufficient
vestment inefficiency is captured by the residuals in the error term as employer reviews, particularly with respect to their investment effi­
follows: ciency. As a first-stage instrument, we include the industry average of
Investmenti,t = α0 + α1 Sales Growthi,t− 1 + εi,t (1) employee review availability (i.e., of the dummy variable Ind_Em­
ployee_Assessment_Indicator, which is coded one for firms with at least
Investment is defined as the net increase in tangible and intangible three reviews) to satisfy the exclusion restriction. While this instrument
assets, scaled by lagged total assets. Sales_Growth is the rate of change in should be associated with the firm-level availability of employer re­
sales between t-2 and t-1. The model is estimated cross-sectionally for views, it is unlikely to have a direct impact on the relationship between
each industry year (Fama/French 12-industry classification).9 Since in­ employer reviews and the investment efficiency in a specific firm. We
vestment inefficiency might result from both under- and overinvestment report the first-stage probit regression model in Appendix B. We find the
issues, we take the absolute values of residuals from these regressions for expected positive and significant loading for Ind_Em­
our main measure of investment inefficiency (Inv_Inefficiency). Hence, ployee_Assessment_Indicator. Furthermore, firms with a higher number of
higher values for Inv_Inefficiency denote lower investment efficiency. We employees and lower performance volatility are more likely to have
differentiate between the two scenarios (under-vs. overinvestment) in sufficient employer reviews available. The area under the Receiver
an additional test to investigate our hypotheses H1 and H2. Operating Characteristic curve (ROC) amounts to 0.77, which is above
In our main regression model (2), we then regress Inv_Inefficiency on the critical threshold of 0.70 (Hosmer & Lemeshow, 2000), confirming
our job satisfaction variable (Satisfaction) to investigate our overall the accuracy of our probit regression model. We include the Inverse
research question in the following:10 Mills Ratio (IMR) based on this model in all following second-stage re­
Inv Inefficiencyi,t = β0 + β1 Satisfactioni + β2 Sizei,t + β3 Leveragei,t gressions to control for possible systematic sample selection effects.
Finally, we add industry (Fama/French 12-industry classification)
+ β4 Tangibilityi,t + β5 Cashflowi,t + β6 Cash Si + β7 RoA Si
and year dummies to control for any unobservable time and industry
+ β8 Employeesi,t + β9 Lossi,t + β10 Agei + β11 IMRi,t + year fixed effect effects. In all tests, we use robust standard errors adjusted for hetero­
+ industry fixed effects + εi,t scedasticity and clustering of observations. More precisely, we follow
Petersen (2009) and cluster standard errors at firm level.
(2)
Our coefficient of interest in this model is β1 on Satisfaction, for which 4.3. Data and sample

In our study, we focus on (German) private firms to explore the as-yet


6
In the U.S., the employer rating website Glassdoor is more prevalent. under-researched impact of job satisfaction on corporate investment
7
In some cases, the employees did not rate all 13 dimensions. In these cases, efficiency. We hand collected all data for our job satisfaction variable
we calculated the average based on the remaining items. For firms with a high
from the employer rating website Kununu. Financial data was retrieved
number of reviews (ten or more), we remove outlier values (one percent tails).
from the Bureau van Dijk DAFNE database based on information dis­
Our results remain qualitatively the same without this procedure.
8
For an overview of empirical ways to measure investment efficiency, please closed in the Federal Gazette. The starting point for our sample selection
refer to Gao and Yu (2020). is all group accounts from privately held companies in Germany for the
9
We require at least 10 observations per industry year. period 2010–2017 (total number of firms: 721) that have disclosed
10
All variables are defined in Appendix A. To mitigate the effect of outliers, all German GAAP financial reports and have at least 80 employees each. We
continuous variables are winsorized at 0.5% tails. start in 2010 to avoid any bias caused by a substantial accounting

6
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

reform, the ‘Accounting Law Modernization Act’ (in German: ‘Bilanz­ efficient investment activities (3.400 vs. 3.312). For the individual
rechtsmodernisierungsgesetz’ – ‘BilMoG’), which became effective in satisfaction dimensions, we find significant differences for 11 of the 13
2009. Our final sample thus covers the period 2012–2017 since our dimensions, which again suggests that job satisfaction and investment
investment efficiency measure requires two prior years for the calcula­ activities are significantly associated with each other. We find the
tion of the prior year’s sales growth rate. highest difference for work climate (Efficient: 3.388; Inefficient: 3.263),
This preselection approach results in 3424 firm years from 428 whereas there is no significant difference for teamwork and work
parent companies and facilitates the comprehensive hand collection for conditions.
our job satisfaction measure, since there are unlikely to be sufficient In Table 3, we report univariate correlations among our model var­
reviews available for single firms with only a few employees. Accord­ iables. We do not find any critical correlations above/below the 0.8/-0.8
ingly, for the remaining 428 companies, we manually checked the level. To address multicollinearity concerns, we conduct further diag­
Kununu website for employee reviews. To be included in our final nostic tests in all regression models, and variance inflation factors are
sample, firms must have at least three reviews available on Kununu. generally below the critical level of 10. Multicollinearity should there­
Furthermore, each firm must have at least one review from a current fore not be a severe concern in our study. The correlation coefficient
employee. Kununu features reviews from both former and current em­ between our variables of interest Inv_Inefficiency and Satisfaction is
ployees. For our main analyses, we consider reviews from both former negative and significant both for the Pearson (− 0.088) and Spearman
and current employees, since people who have left the company also (− 0.075) correlation. This again corroborates our hypotheses that high
give important insights into job satisfaction and work environment job satisfaction should be associated with more investment efficiency.
within a firm (Graham et al., 2018). However, since reviews from former Furthermore, the pairwise correlations between Satisfaction and RoA_S
employees might generally be more negative, we did not use firms with as well as Loss are negative and significant indicating, in line with prior
reviews solely from former employees. These selections reduce the evidence, that firms with a high job satisfaction exhibit a more stable
sample to 2256 observations from 282 firms. Finally, we exclude all performance and are less likely to incur financial losses.
observations with missing data for our model variables, which leads to
our final sample consisting of 1006 observations from 237 privately held
parent companies. The job satisfaction ratings for these 237 firms are 5.2. Main empirical findings
based on 9683 hand-collected employer reviews from Kununu.
We test our hypotheses that job satisfaction is associated with the
5. Results level of investment efficiency by running our main multivariate
regression model (2), the corresponding results for which are reported in
5.1. Descriptive statistics Table 4. Following our hypotheses, the coefficient β1 for our job satis­
faction measure (Satisfaction) is negative and statistically significant at
In Table 1, we report distributional properties of our model vari­ the 0.1 level (t = − 1.88). This suggests that firms with higher levels of
ables. The mean job satisfaction for our sample firms is 3.36 on a range job satisfaction exhibit greater investment efficiency. This is in accor­
from 1 to 5. The interquartile spread of Satisfaction ranges from 2.98 to dance with our argument that high job satisfaction should reduce the
3.75, indicating some variation across our sample firms. Other problems associated with moral hazard and adverse selection resulting
descriptive statistics show, for instance, a tangibility ratio of 19% and an from information asymmetries. Accordingly, our results show that even
average leverage ratio of 40%. The mean for Loss further indicates that after controlling for a variety of other firm factors, job satisfaction has an
for 17% of our observations, firms report negative income. important effect on corporate activities in our private firm setting.
In Table 2, we show additional and more detailed descriptive sta­ Coefficients for the control variables are generally in line with prior
tistics for our job satisfaction variable. Here, we present distributional evidence (e.g., Benlemlih & Bitar, 2018; Chen et al., 2011; Gomariz &
properties not only for the aggregate variable but also for all 13 un­ Ballesta, 2014). Firms with high leverage (Leverage), negative income
derlying dimensions, for which we find highest scores as follows: (Loss), and more fluctuating cash levels (Cash_S) have less efficient in­
teamwork (3.728); attitudes toward older colleagues (3.678); along with vestments, probably because they suffer from underinvestment issues.
challenging and interesting work (3.617). The three items with the The positive coefficient for Cashflow indicates agency conflicts that in
lowest scores are as follows: management behavior (3.119); career particular might result in overinvestment problems. Moreover, our re­
prospects for growth and professional development (3.071); as well as sults suggest that larger firms (Size and Employees) are more efficient in
communication (3.014). We further show mean values for firm-year their investment decisions. Finally, in line with prior literature, Tangi­
observations classified as efficient and inefficient regarding the firms’ bility is negatively associated with investment efficiency. The co­
investment activities (based on a median split). These results provide efficients for the remaining variables (Age and RoA_S) are not
support for our hypotheses. Using univariate t-tests, we find that job statistically different from zero, which is also consistent with most of the
satisfaction is significantly higher (at the 5% level) for firms with prior evidence. Furthermore, IMR is insignificant, indicating that there
are no systematic differences between our sample firms and other firms

Table 1
Distributional properties.
Mean SD P1 P25 Median P75 P99

Inv_Inefficiency 0.03 0.04 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.22


Satisfaction 3.36 0.55 2.00 2.98 3.42 3.75 4.51
Size 11.64 1.13 9.62 10.79 11.49 12.37 14.64
Leverage 0.40 0.21 0.02 0.23 0.40 0.56 0.91
Tangibility 0.19 0.20 0.00 0.06 0.14 0.24 0.87
Cashflow 0.09 0.07 − 0.12 0.06 0.09 0.13 0.28
Cash_S 7.68 13.20 0.04 1.02 3.23 8.16 62.08
RoA_S 0.04 0.04 0.00 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.17
Employees 2.14 5.54 0.10 0.42 0.75 1.65 23.38
Loss 0.17 0.37 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.00
Age 3.78 0.78 1.79 3.30 3.78 4.26 5.12

Note: All continuous variables are winsorized at 0.5% tails. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

7
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

Table 2
Descriptive statistics cultural items by investment efficiency.
Full Sample Inefficient = 1 Inefficient = 0

Mean SD Mean Mean Difference

Satisfaction 3.356 0.551 3.312 3.400 − 0.087**


Work_Climate 3.326 0.657 3.263 3.388 − 0.125***
Management_Behavior 3.119 0.669 3.065 3.173 − 0.108**
Teamwork 3.728 0.495 3.703 3.752 − 0.049
Interesting_Work 3.617 0.590 3.576 3.658 − 0.083**
Communication 3.014 0.610 2.974 3.053 − 0.079**
Gender_Equality 3.482 0.579 3.445 3.519 − 0.074**
Older_People 3.678 0.589 3.632 3.725 − 0.093**
Career_Opportunities 3.071 0.662 3.014 3.127 − 0.112***
Fair_Compensation 3.241 0.665 3.189 3.293 − 0.104**
Work_Conditions 3.450 0.623 3.428 3.471 − 0.042
Eco_Social_Responsibility 3.351 0.633 3.302 3.399 − 0.097**
Work_Life 3.258 0.638 3.221 3.296 − 0.075*
Image 3.431 0.717 3.384 3.478 − 0.095**

Note: ***, **, and * indicate two-sided significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively.

Table 3
Correlation matrix.
A B C D E

A: Inv_Inefficiency ¡0.075 − 0.043 0.125 0.192


B: Satisfaction ¡0.088 0.112 ¡0.172 − 0.013
C: Size ¡0.065 0.094 ¡0.086 0.079
D: Leverage 0.117 ¡0.171 ¡0.072 ¡0.055
E: Tangibility 0.162 − 0.035 0.125 0.039
F: Cashflow 0.044 0.038 0.015 ¡0.249 − 0.046
G: Cash_S 0.018 0.081 0.609 ¡0.178 0.075
H: RoA_S 0.042 ¡0.078 ¡0.173 0.076 ¡0.156
I: Employees ¡0.071 ¡0.130 0.446 0.008 ¡0.116
J: Loss 0.123 ¡0.091 − 0.053 0.198 0.143
K: Age ¡0.076 0.054 0.025 ¡0.172 0.084

F G H I J K

A: Inv_Inefficiency − 0.003 0.004 0.102 − 0.027 0.182 ¡0.065


B: Satisfaction 0.054 0.143 ¡0.113 − 0.048 ¡0.112 0.083
C: Size 0.022 0.580 ¡0.290 0.709 ¡0.064 0.096
D: Leverage ¡0.277 ¡0.298 0.068 0.003 0.194 ¡0.181
E: Tangibility − 0.027 0.071 ¡0.152 0.026 0.037 0.206
F: Cashflow 0.038 − 0.015 0.114 ¡0.542 ¡0.124
G: Cash_S 0.021 ¡0.061 0.380 ¡0.054 0.177
H: RoA_S ¡0.088 0.042 ¡0.153 0.335 ¡0.215
I: Employees 0.089 0.353 − 0.036 ¡0.068 0.110
J: Loss ¡0.558 − 0.009 0.269 ¡0.059 ¡0.104
K: Age ¡0.097 0.027 ¡0.157 ¡0.104 ¡0.105

Note: Spearman (Pearson) correlations above (below) the diagonal. Bold font indicates significance at the 0.1 level. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

without (sufficient) employer ratings available regarding their invest­ In this test, we explore which of the two scenarios dominates in our
ment efficiency. setting by distinguishing between positive and negative deviations from
optimal investment levels. Positive residuals denote overinvestment,
5.3. Additional analyses while negative residuals reflect underinvestment problems. In Table 5,
we again estimate our main model (2), but this time separately for
5.3.1. Differentiation between over- and underinvestment positive and negative residuals. We have multiplied the negative re­
In our main analysis, we consider the absolute values of deviations siduals by minus one to facilitate interpretation of the results.
from optimal investment levels, and show that job satisfaction has a We find negative estimates on our job satisfaction variable for both
negative impact on this aggregate measure for investment inefficiency. regressions but only statistically significant at the 0.05 level (t = − 2.53)
However, as discussed in our hypotheses development, investment in­ for the underinvestment sample. For overinvestment, the estimate is not
efficiency might result from one of two alternative scenarios (or both): statistically different from zero (t = − 0.81). Hence, our main results are
over- and underinvestment. While underinvestment issues in particular driven particular by employee satisfaction’s negative impact on under­
arise from illiquidity problems due to restricted access to capital, over­ investment problems (i.e., in line with H2). This suggests that value-
investment issues rather result from misjudgments and self-serving de­ destroying activities, such as empire building, by self-serving corpo­
cisions (e.g., empire building and short-termism) (e.g., Biddle et al., rate decision-makers who take advantage of information asymmetries
2009). between themselves and the owners of a firm, are not the dominant

8
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

Table 4 Kununu dimensions separately.


Main results. We report the corresponding results in Table 6. Besides showing the
Dep. Variable: Inv_Inefficiency Coefficient t-statistics results for our overall investment inefficiency measure, we specifically
differentiate between over- and underinvestment scenarios. We find no
Satisfaction − 0.004* − 1.88
Size − 0.004** − 2.45 statistically significant estimates for Over_Invest, which again shows that
Leverage 0.024*** 3.89 underinvestment problems play a dominant role within the overall effect
Tangibility 0.027*** 3.16 of job satisfaction on investment activities using our setting. For
Cashflow 0.102*** 3.32 Under_Invest, 11 out of the 13 individual dimensions have a significantly
Cash_S 0.000** 2.49
RoA_S 0.001 0.02
negative impact. Hence, there is no specific job satisfaction dimension
Employees − 0.001** − 2.50 that is particularly important for mitigating problems related to moral
Loss 0.016*** 3.40 hazard and adverse selection. Instead, it is seemingly an interplay of
Age − 0.001 − 0.70 various dimensions that leads to positive job satisfaction and ultimately
IMR − 0.008 − 1.00
mitigates problems related to moral hazard and adverse selection. This is
Year-Fixed Effects Included
Industry-Fixed Effects Included also in line with the definition that job satisfaction comprises a variety of
N 1006 factors (Coff, 1997; Bayarcelik & Afacan Findikli, 2016).
Mean VIF 1.89 Social responsibility, as one of the few exceptions, has no significant
F-statistic 4.88*** bearing on underinvestment. According to Bowen (1953, p. 6), CSR
R2 0.091
Adj. R2 0.073
refers to managers’ responsibilities to make decisions that are desirable
in terms of the objectives and values of society. In line with this defi­
Note: t-statistics are robust and clustered at firm level. ***, **, and * indicate nition, social responsibility activities are found to be significantly
two-sided significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively. All vari­
determined by the personal ethical values of individual top executives
ables are defined in Appendix A.
(e.g., Hemingway & Maclagan, 2004).11 Hence, lower employee satis­
faction regarding firms’ CSR activities as measured by our employer
Table 5
reviews might in particular indicate that managers of such firms behave
Over-vs. Underinvestment. less ethically, which is for instance supported by the empirical findings
of Kim et al. (2012) who report that CSR is negatively associated with
Dep. Variable: Over_Invest Dep. Variable: Under_Invest
opportunistic earnings management. With regard to investment de­
Coefficient t-statistics Coefficient t-statistics cisions, the corresponding problems of moral hazard and managerial
Satisfaction − 0.004 − 0.81 − 0.005** − 2.53 opportunism are discussed particularly in the context of greater empire
Size − 0.006 − 1.56 − 0.004*** − 2.71 building and thus overinvestment. Specifically, Gul et al. (2020)
Leverage 0.026** 2.13 0.019*** 3.43
demonstrate empirically that CSR is negatively associated with empire
Tangibility 0.033** 2.13 0.014* 1.85
Cashflow 0.140** 2.43 0.078** 2.28
building, but it seemingly does not have an impact on
Cash_S 0.000** 2.38 0.000** 2.10 underinvestment.12
RoA_S − 0.036 − 0.77 0.035 0.95 We find the strongest influence on underinvestment problems stem
Employees − 0.001*** − 2.63 − 0.000** − 2.23 from: working climate, interesting work, communication, gender
Loss 0.018** 1.99 0.016*** 3.10
equality, compensation, and a firm’s perceived image. This perceived
Age 0.000 0.05 − 0.002 − 1.25
IMR − 0.009 − 0.65 − 0.001 − 0.08 image presumably reflects a firm’s external reputation, which might
Year-FE Included Included ease access to external capital and thereby easing underinvestment
Industry-FE Included Included problems (e.g., Cao et al., 2015). Moreover, gender equality is nowadays
N 438 568 a topic of high public interest and also important for capital providers (e.
Adj. R2 0.061 0.108
g., Pandey et al., 2020). As explained in our hypotheses development,
Note: t-statistics are robust and clustered at firm level. ***, **, and * indicate particularly in the case of debt contracting, private communication does
two-sided significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively. All vari­ play an important role in reducing information asymmetries (e.g., Cas­
ables are defined in Appendix A. cino et al., 2014; Chen, 2016), which is why it is reasonable to argue that
the communication dimension is strongly negatively correlated with
channel in our setting. This might be due to our consideration of private underinvestment. The strong impact of compensation and interesting
firms, in which managers’ moral hazard is generally expected to play a work is also in accordance with our discussion that job satisfaction re­
less pronounced role due to the ownership structure (Bargeron et al., lates to more motivated employees who are more likely to act in the best
2015; Gao et al., 2013). interests of the firm (i.e., less moral hazard problems). Fair compensa­
Instead, reduced information asymmetries with capital providers and tion schemes are identified especially as being key drivers of employee
lower financing constraints for firms with high job satisfaction levels motivation and performance (both for management and regular staff) (e.
seem to be the underlying driver of a positive association between job g., Banker et al., 2000; Jensen & Zimmerman, 1985). Furthermore,
satisfaction and investment efficiency, because this prevents liquidity Kanagaretnam and Sarkar (2011) have shown that appropriate mana­
shortfalls that might lead to firms’ eschewing of profitable investment gerial compensation schemes may reduce incentives not to invest in
opportunities. This is also in line with previous evidence that job satis­ profitable projects (i.e., underinvestment). Finally, the individual cate­
faction is negatively associated with the cost of corporate borrowing gory working climate can be considered as one of the broadest di­
(Chi & Chen, 2021). mensions, which is why it is not surprising that it has a particularly

5.3.2. Differentiation between individual job satisfaction dimensions


A huge advantage of our job satisfaction variable based on employer
11
reviews from the online rating website Kununu is that we cannot only While CSR is naturally closely related to employee satisfaction since respect
for employees is considered to be a key part of CSR in most definition ap­
use a composite measure on the general level of job satisfaction, but the
proaches (Dahlsrud, 2008), they are not identical constructs (e.g., Wisse et al.,
detailed reviews also allow to distinguish between various sub-
2018).
dimensions of job satisfaction. Accordingly, to increase our under­ 12
In line with this consideration, CSR has the highest coefficient (in absolute
standing of the association between job satisfaction and investment ef­ terms) for the model with Over Invest as the dependent variable, albeit being
ficiency, we re-run our regression model (2) for each of the 13 individual statistically insignificant (as all other individual satisfaction items).

9
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

Table 6
Individual cultural dimensions.
(1) Work_Climate (2) Management_ Behavior (3) Teamwork (4) Interesting_Work (5) Communication

Inv_Inefficiency − 0.004* (− 1.98) − 0.002 (− 1.24) − 0.001 (− 0.47) − 0.004* (− 1.95) − 0.003 (− 1.50)
Over_Invest − 0.004 (− 0.83) − 0.004 (− 0.95) 0.000 (0.00) − 0.005 (− 1.19) − 0.002 (− 0.53)
Under_Invest − 0.005*** (− 2.88) − 0.003** (− 2.00) − 0.004* (− 1.72) − 0.005** (− 2.61) − 0.005** (− 2.44)
Year-FE Included Included Included Included Included
Industry-FE Included Included Included Included Included
Controls Included Included Included Included Included
Adj. R2 0.073/0.061/0.111 0.070/0.062/0.103 0.069/0.059/0.102 0.073/0.062/0.108 0.071/0.060/0.108

(6) Gender_Equality (7) Older_People (8) Career_Opportunities (9) Fair_Compensation (10) Work_Environment

Inv_Inefficiency − 0.003 (− 1.56) − 0.002 (− 1.11) − 0.004** (− 2.05) − 0.002 (− 1.25) − 0.002 (− 0.91)
Over_Invest − 0.004 (− 0.84) − 0.002 (− 0.30) − 0.005 (− 1.11) 0.002 (0.50) − 0.003 (− 0.59)
Under_Invest − 0.005*** (− 2.75) − 0.003* (− 1.88) − 0.004** (− 2.39) − 0.005** (− 2.54) − 0.002 (− 1.21)
Year -FE Included Included Included Included Included
Industry-FE Included Included Included Included Included
Controls Included Included Included Included Included
Adj. R2 0.072/0.061/0.110 0.070/0.060/0.103 0.073/0.062/0.108 0.071/0.060/0.112 0.070/0.060/0.100

(11) Eco_Social_ (12) Work_Life (13) Image


Responsibility

Inv_Inefficiency − 0.003 (− 1.59) − 0.003* (− 1.71) − 0.003** (− 1.97)


Over_Invest − 0.005 (− 1.31) − 0.003 (− 0.55) − 0.004 (− 0.96)
Under_Invest − 0.003 (− 1.32) − 0.003* (− 1.92) − 0.004** (− 2.52)
Year -FE Included Included Included
Industry-FE Included Included Included
Controls Included Included Included
Adj. R2 0.072/0.063/0.101 0.072/0.060/0.104 0.073/0.062/0.107

Note: t-statistics are robust and clustered at firm level. ***, **, and * indicate two-sided significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively. All variables are
defined in Appendix A.

strong impact when considering the role of job satisfaction. In its online executives, and minimum 10 and 15 reviews), the effect of job satis­
guidance to users undertaking an employer review, Kununu mentions faction on investment efficiency becomes slightly insignificant for the
that this dimension is supposed to measure whether there is a general overall investment inefficiency measure. However, we still find signifi­
climate of fairness and mutual trust, which are key characteristics for cant effects from job satisfaction on underinvestment problems. The sole
low agency conflicts within a firm and pro-organizational behavior by exception is our test where only executive reviews are considered, for
all members of a firm (e.g., Brown, Gray, McHardy, & Taylor, 2015). which the coefficient is slightly insignificant (t = − 1.61; p-value =
0.11). Accordingly, this result supports the contention that, while in­
5.3.3. Sensitivity tests vestment decisions are generally made at the executive level (e.g.,
Table 7 reports several additional tests to ensure the robustness of Reichelstein, 1997), it is not necessarily only job satisfaction among
our findings. Initially, we follow Chen et al. (2011) and slightly modify firms’ top executives that can affect corporate investment efficiency.13
our investment model (1) in order to estimate any deviations from This is in line with our hypothesis development that job satisfaction
‘normal’ investment levels. More precisely, in the alternative model (3), might also affect underinvestment because moral hazard problems
we take into account for differential predictability for sales increases and related to regular staff are reduced. Based on human resource theory,
decreases by adding a dummy variable coded one if sales have decreased employees who experience greater job satisfaction should be more
in the previous year in our investment model (Negi,t− 1 ). Prior literature motivated to contribute to the firm’s success (e.g., Huang et al., 2015;
argues that the relationship between investment and sales growth might Maslow, 1943), which is in turn a key factor in promoting access to
differ for increases and decreases (e.g., Chen et al., 2011; McNichols & outside capital (e.g., Adams et al., 2003; Jiang, 2008).
Stubben, 2008). Under this assumption, the following model should lead In our final robustness test, we address concerns that firms with
to a more precise prediction of ‘normal’ investment levels and therefore positive employee reviews might be systematically different from firms
also for our variable of interest Inv_Inefficiency: with more negative reviews (e.g., Huang et al., 2017). For instance,
literature suggests that satisfaction among employees is particularly low
Investmenti,t = α0 + α1 Negi,t− 1 + α2 Sales Growthi,t− 1
(3) in financially distressed firms (e.g., Arampatzi et al., 2015). Logically,
+ α3 Negi,t− 1 *Sales Growthi,t− 1 + εi,t these firms should also be more likely to suffer from underinvestment
Next, we apply different modifications to our job satisfaction mea­ issues, given that access to capital is limited for financially distressed
sure to check that our results are robust. For instance, we test whether or clients due to both their higher credit risk for capital providers and
not our results hold when we exclude reviews from former employees greater likelihood of violating debt covenants (e.g., Habib et al., 2020).
from the computation of our job satisfaction measure, because they Based on this argumentation, one might have concerns that our findings
might be more negative than reviews from current employees. capture an effect that is not only driven by job satisfaction but other
Furthermore, we omit reviews from non-regular employees such as issues such as financial distress. Accordingly, although we consider a
trainees, interns, and other temporary workers. Regarding the remain­ variety of control variables in our main model, the results of our full
ing reviews, we then additionally differentiate between regular staff and
executives. Finally, in the calculation of our job satisfaction measure for
13
the main analyses, we require at least three reviews per firm. In our last It is important to note that this result might also be driven by a significant
drop in observations because there are less reviews available from executives.
additional tests, we check whether or not our conclusions hold if we
We have 506 observations for the regular staff analysis but only 246 for the
increase this minimum number to 5, 10, and 15 reviews.
executives’ analysis because only around 15% of the reviews hand collected
The results in Table 7 show that our main inferences remain robust from kununu.com are from executives. Naturally, t-values decrease with a
despite these alterations. For some tests (only regular staff, only lower number of observations.

10
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

Table 7
Additional tests.
(1) Alternative Investment (2) Exclude Reviews from Former (3) Exclude Interns/Trainees and Temporary Workers (i.e., (4) Only Reviews by
Inefficiency Measure Employees Only Reviews by Regular Staff and Executives) Regular Staff

Inv_Inefficiency − 0.005** (− 2.13) − 0.005* (− 1.86) − 0.003* (− 1.69) − 0.003 (− 1.21)


Over_Invest − 0.005 (− 0.93) − 0.002 (− 0.43) − 0.001 (− 0.22) 0.001 (0.20)
Under_Invest − 0.005** (− 2.46) − 0.006*** (− 2.85) − 0.005*** (− 2.72) − 0.005** (− 2.56)
Year -FE Included Included Included Included
Industry-FE Included Included Included Included
Controls Included Included Included Included
N 1006/427/579 892/394/498 953/417/536 903/397/506
Adj. R2 0.065/0.057/0.081 0.049/0.035/0.108 0.064/0.052/0.105 0.059/0.043/0.101

(5) Only Reviews by (6) Minimum 5 Reviews Per Firm (7) Minimum 10 Reviews (8) Minimum 15
Executives (Instead of 3 as in Main Test) Reviews

Inv_Inefficiency − 0.003 (− 1.20) − 0.004* (− 1.70) − 0.004 (− 1.41) − 0.006 (− 1.45)


Over_Invest − 0.002 (− 0.28) − 0.004 (− 0.70) − 0.002 (− 0.26) 0.001 (0.10)
Under_Invest − 0.004 (− 1.61) − 0.005** (− 2.17) − 0.006*** (− 2.68) − 0.008** (− 2.36)
Year -FE Included Included Included Included
Industry-FE Included Included Included Included
Controls Included Included Included Included
N 447/201/246 887/388/499 696/315/381 526/234/292
Adj. R2 0.062/0.037/0.077 0.057/0.034/0.101 0.054//0.009/0.116 0.054/0.006/0.123

Note: t-statistics are robust and clustered at firm level. ***, **, and * indicate two-sided significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively. All variables are
defined in Appendix A.

Table 8
Propensity score matching.
Panel A: First-Stage Probit Model

Dep. Variable: High_Rating Coefficient z-statistics


Size 0.266** 4.29
Leverage − 0.610*** − 2.64
Tangibility − 0.613** − 2.59
Cashflow − 0.540 − 0.68
Cash_S 0.016*** 3.24
RoA_S − 2.689** − 2.09
Employees − 0.209*** − 6.77
Loss − 0.426*** − 2.87
Age − 0.027 − 0.45
IMR − 0.631* − 1.69
Year-Fixed Effects Included
Industry-Fixed Effects Included
Wald χ2 30.43***
N 1006
Pseudo R2 0.104
Area under ROC Curve 0.70

Panel B: Matching Analysis

Matched Sample (n = 666) Full (Unmatched) Sample (n = 1006)

Mean | Mean | Difference Mean | Mean | Difference


High_Rating = 1 High_Rating = 0 High_Rating = 1 High_Rating = 0

Size 11.526 11.515 0.011 11.748 11.538 0.210***


Leverage 0.404 0.398 0.006 0.377 0.431 − 0.054***
Tangibility 0.194 0.186 0.008 0.193 0.194 − 0.001
Cashflow 0.092 0.098 − 0.006 0.094 0.091 0.003
Cash_S 6.205 4.581 1.624** 8.455 6.903 1.552*
RoA_S 0.035 0.034 0.001 0.032 0.042 − 0.010***
Employees 1.359 1.336 0.023 1.367 2.929 − 1.562***
Loss 0.162 0.108 0.054** 0.125 0.212 − 0.087***
Age 3.820 3.802 0.018 3.805 3.759 0.046
IMR 0.221 0.216 0.005 0.200 0.228 − 0.028***

Panel C: Main Regressions for Matched Sample

Dep. Variable: Inv_Inefficiency Dep. Variable: Over_Invest Dep. Variable: Under_Invest

Coefficient t-statistics Coefficient t-statistics Coefficient t-statistics

Satisfaction − 0.004 − 1.61 − 0.002 − 0.42 − 0.005** − 2.19


Controls Included Included Included
Year-FE Included Included Included
Industry-FE Included Included Included
N 666 287 379
Adj. R2 0.075 0.081 0.101

Note: t-statistics are robust and clustered at firm level. ***, **, and * indicate two-sided significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively. All variables are
defined in Appendix A.

11
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

sample might be biased because including control variables does not and moral hazard resulting from information asymmetries, which ulti­
necessarily adequately control for the covariates affecting mately leads to higher investment efficiency. Additional analyses reveal
employee-perceived job satisfaction (Huang et al., 2017). that job satisfaction affects investment efficiency particularly in its
For this reason, we use a median split for our job satisfaction measure reduction of underinvestment problems. Hence, a positive work envi­
and apply propensity score matching to a probit model predicting ronment with motivated and content employees seemingly prevents
whether a company has a high satisfaction (High_Rating = 1) or not, with liquidity shortfalls that might induce firms to eschew profitable invest­
caliper = 0.01, nearest neighbor option, and no replacements. In Panel A ment projects that they would otherwise undertake. The effect of job
of Table 8, we report the first stage profit model. The ROC (0.70) sug­ satisfaction on overinvestment is insignificant, indicating that reduced
gests that our model fits the data quite well. As a result of our strict empire building motives from managers does not play an important role
matching criteria, our matched sample only covers 666 firm years (i.e., in our setting.
our sample reduces by almost one third), but the comparison of the We acknowledge that our study is subject to some limitations. As our
mean values for our controls in Panel B documents that our matching sample consists of German private firms only, our results may not be
procedure is successful. While we find large differences between high applicable to settings in other countries or the public firm setting, which
and low satisfaction firms in our full (i.e., unmatched) sample, with differ significantly from that of private firms (e.g., Chen et al., 2011).
seven out of ten differences also being statistically significant, the dif­ Furthermore, because we consider only group accounts, our sample
ferences are lower for our matched sample and we find only two sta­ represents larger private firms in Germany. Finally, since we needed to
tistically significant differences here. hand-collect data for our job satisfaction measure, which is not available
In Panel C, we re-estimate our main regression models for our for all private firms, our sample size is rather small.
matched sample. For the aggregate investment efficiency score, we find Despite these limitations, we are aware of no other studies that
a slightly insignificant estimate (p = 0.11), but the effect of job satis­ examine the effect of job satisfaction on investment efficiency. By
faction on underinvestment remains negative and significant also for considering the private firm setting, we further contribute to the rather
this matched sample, which facilitates concerns that our results are scarce literature on corporate actions by private firms. Our findings
driven by other factors than job satisfaction. should therefore have important implications for both researchers and
In summary, these tests show that job satisfaction has a significant practitioners. We show specifically that job satisfaction does matter for
and robust impact on investment efficiency, particularly by reducing the performance of private firms. Hence, private firms should also be
underinvestment problems in our private firm setting. actively engaged in cultivating a positive work environment with a high
degree of employee satisfaction. However, our study still leaves room for
6. Conclusion future research in this important area. For instance, the question re­
mains whether job satisfaction also has a significant impact on the in­
In this study, we investigate the relationship between job satisfaction vestment efficiency of publicly listed companies, which are much more
and investment efficiency. Using a relatively novel measure for job subject to external scrutiny and regulation.
satisfaction based on crowdsourced employer reviews and a sample of
German private firms, we find that job satisfaction is positively associ­ Declaration of competing interest
ated with investment efficiency. This is in accordance with our hy­
potheses that a high job satisfaction should mitigate adverse selection None.

Appendix A. Variable Definitions

Variable Definition

Inv_Inefficiency Investment inefficiency, measured as the residuals (absolute values) from a simple investment regression model that predicts the level of
investment based on growth opportunities (e.g., Gomariz and Ballesta, Journal of Banking and Finance, 2014; Benlemlih and Bitar, Journal of
Business Ethics, 2018):
Investmenti,t = α0 + ∝α1 Sales Growthi,t− 1 + εi,t
Investment is defined as the net increase in tangible and intangible assets, scaled by lagged total assets. Sales_Growth is the rate of change in sales
between t-2 and t-1. The model is estimated cross-sectionally for each industry year.
The alternative investment inefficiency measure employed in one of the additional test uses a slightly adjusted investment model where we
differentiate between positive and negative sales changes (Chen et al., The Accounting Review, 2011):
Investmenti,t = α0 + α1 Negi,t− 1 + α2 Sales Growthi,t− 1 + α3 Negi,t− 1 *Sales Growthi,t− 1 + εi,t
Over_Invest Level of overinvestment, measured as the positive residuals from the estimating the investment model.
Under_Invest Level of underinvestment, measured as the negative residuals from estimating the investment model, multiplied by − 1.
Satisfaction Job satisfaction calculated as the mean across all Kununu reviews (average of 13 individual items) for each firm.
Employee_Assessment_Indicator Indicator variable coded 1 if a firm has at least three reviews available on Kununu, zero otherwise.
Ind_Employee_Assessment_Indicator Industry average of Employee_Assessment_Indicator.
Size Natural logarithm of total assets.
Leverage Ratio of total liabilities to total assets.
Tangibility Ratio of tangible assets to total assets.
Cashflow Ratio of cashflow to total assets.
Cash_S Firm-level standard deviation of cash and cash equivalents.
RoA_S Firm-level standard deviation of return on assets.
Employees Number of employees divided by 1000.
Loss Indicator variable coded 1 if firms report a negative net income, zero otherwise.
Age Natural logarithm of firm age in years.
High_Rating Indicator variable coded 1 if a firm’s satisfaction score exceeds the sample median, zero otherwise.

12
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

Appendix B. Heckman Correction for Sample Selection – First-Stage Selection Model

Dep. Variable: Employee_Assessment_Indicator Coefficient z-statistics

Ind_Employee_Assessment_Indicator 2.772*** 3.84


Size 0.082 0.55
Leverage − 0.463 − 0.91
Tangibility − 0.111 − 0.24
Cashflow − 1.986 − 1.41
Cash_S − 0.004 − 0.23
RoA_S − 3.958* − 1.70
Employees 0.403** 2.20
Loss 0.013 0.06
Age − 0.161 − 1.14
Year-Fixed Effects Included
Industry-Fixed Effects Included
N 1810
Wald χ2 54.18***
Pseudo R2 0.17
Area under ROC Curve 0.77
Note: z-statistics are robust and clustered at firm level. ***, **, and * indicate two-sided significance
at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

References Burkart, M., Panunzi, F., & Shleifer, A. (2003). Family firms. The Journal of Finance, 58
(5), 2167–2201. https://doi.org/10.1111/1540-6261.00601
Campbell, D., & Shang, R. (2022). Tone at the bottom: Measuring corporate misconduct
Adams, M., Burton, B., & Hardwick, P. (2003). The determinants of credit ratings in the
risk from the text of employee reviews. Management Science, 68(9), 7043–7053.
United Kingdom insurance industry. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 30
https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2021.4211
(3–4), 539–572. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-5957.00007
Cao, Y., Myers, J. N., Myers, L. A., & Omer, T. C. (2015). Company reputation and the
Ağca, Ş., & Mozumdar, A. (2008). The impact of capital market imperfections on
cost of equity capital. Review of Accounting Studies, 20, 42–81. https://doi.org/
investment–cash flow sensitivity. Journal of Banking & Finance, 32(2), 207–216.
10.1007/s11142-014-9292-9
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2007.02.013
Cascino, S., Clatworthy, M., Garcia Osma, B., Gassen, J., Iman, S., & Jeanjean, T. (2014).
Alchian, A. A., & Woodward, S. (1988). Review: The firm is dead; long live the firm a
Who uses financial reports and for hat purpose? Evidence from capital providers.
review of Oliver E. Williamson’s the economic institutions of capitalism. Journal of
Accounting in Europe, 11(2), 185–209. https://doi.org/10.1080/
Economic Literature, 26, 65–79.
17449480.2014.940355
Arampatzi, E., Burger, M. J., & Veenhoven, R. (2015). Financial distress and happiness of
Chen, P.-C. (2016). Banks’ acquisition of private information about financial
employees in times of economic crisis. Applied Economics Letters, 3, 173–179. https://
misreporting. The Accounting Review, 91(3), 835–857. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-
doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2014.931916
51222
Audretsch, D. B., & Elston, J. A. (1997). Financing the German Mittelstand. Small Business
Chen, F., Hope, O.-K., Li, Q., & Wang, X. (2011). Financial reporting quality and
Economics, 9(1), 97–110. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1007963621438
investment efficiency of private firms in emerging markets. The Accounting Review,
Baddeley, M. (2017). Keynes’ psychology and behavioural macroeconomics: Theory and
86(4), 1255–1288. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-10040
policy. Economic and Labour Relations Review, 28(2), 177–196. https://doi.org/
Chen, H.-L., & Huang, Y.-S. (2006). Employee stock ownership and corporate R&D
10.1177/1035304617706849
expenditures: Evidence from Taiwan’s information-technology industry. Asia Pacific
Badertscher, B., Shroff, N., & White, H. D. (2013). Externalities of public firm presence:
Journal of Management, 23, 369–384. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-006-9005-4
Evidence from private firms’ investment decisions. Journal of Financial Economics,
Chen, C. X., Lu, H., & Sougiannis, T. (2012). The agency problem, corporate governance,
109(3), 682–706. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.03.012
and the asymmetrical behavior of selling, general, and administrative costs.
Bae, G. S., Choi, S. U., Dhaliwal, D. S., & Lamoreaux, P. T. (2017). Auditors and client
Contemporary Accounting Research, 29(1), 252–282. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1911-
investment efficiency. The Accounting Review, 92(2), 19–40. https://doi.org/
3846.2011.01094.x
10.2308/accr-51530
Chi, W., & Chen, Y. (2021). Employee satisfaction and the cost of corporate borrowing.
Banker, R. D., Lee, S.-Y., Potter, G., & Srinivasan, D. (2000). An empirical analysis of
Finance Research Letters, 40, Article 101666. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
continuing improvements following the implementation of a performance-based
frl.2020.101666
compensation plan. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 30(3), 315–350. https://
Chung, R., Firth, M., & Kim, J.-B. (2002). Institutional monitoring and opportunistic
doi.org/10.1016/S0165-4101(01)00016-7
earnings management. Journal of Corporate Finance, 8(1), 29–48. https://doi.org/
Bargeron, L., Lehn, K., & Smith, J. (2015). Employee–management trust and M&A
10.1016/S0929-1199(01)00039-6
activity. Journal of Corporate Finance, 35, 389–406. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Coff, R. W. (1997). Human assets and management dilemmas: Coping with hazards on
jcorpfin.2015.07.012
the road to resource-based theory. Academy of Management Review, 22(2), 374–402.
Bassemir, M. (2018). Why do private firms adopt IFRS? Accounting and Business Research,
https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1997.9707154063
48(3), 237–263. https://doi.org/10.1080/00014788.2017.1357459
Cook, K. A., Romi, A. M., Sánchez, D., & Sánchez, J. M. (2019). The influence of
Bayarcelik, E. B., & Afacan Findikli, M. (2016). The mediating effect of job satisfaction on
corporate social responsibility on investment efficiency and innovation. Journal of
the relation between organizational justice perception and intention to leave.
Business Finance & Accounting, 46, 494–537. https://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12360
Procedia – Social and Behavioral Science, 235, 403–411. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Dahlsrud, A. (2008). How corporate social responsibility is defined: An analysis of 37
sbspro.2016.11.050
definitions. Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental Management, 15(1),
Bendel, D., Demary, M., & Voigtländer, M. (2016). Entwicklung der
1–13. https://doi.org/10.1002/csr.132
Unternehmensfinanzierung in Deutschland. Vierteljahresschrift zur empirischen
Durand, R., & Vargas, V. (2003). Ownership, organization, and private firms’ efficient
Wirtschaftsforschung, 43, 37–54.
use of resources. Strategic Management Journal, 24(7), 667–675. https://doi.org/
Benlemlih, M., & Bitar, M. (2018). Corporate social responsibility and investment
10.1002/smj.321
efficiency. Journal of Business Ethics, 148, 647–671. https://doi.org/10.1007/
Edmans, A. (2011). Does the stock market fully value intangibles? Employee satisfaction
s10551-016-3020-2
and equity prices. Journal of Financial Economics, 101(3), 621–640. https://doi.org/
Bertrand, M., & Mullainathan, S. (2003). Enjoying the quiet life? Corporate governance
10.1016/j.jfineco.2011.03.021
and managerial preferences. Journal of Political Economy, 111(5), 1043–1075.
Edmans, A. (2012). The link between job satisfaction and firm value, with implications
https://doi.org/10.1086/376950
for corporate social responsibility. Academy of Management Perspectives, 26(4), 1–19.
Biddle, G. C., & Hilary, G. (2006). Accounting quality and firm-level capital investment.
https://doi.org/10.5465/amp.2012.0046
The Accounting Review, 81(5), 963–982. https://doi.org/10.2308/
Eisdorfer, A., Giaccotto, C., & White, R. (2013). Capital structure, executive
accr.2006.81.5.963
compensation, and investment efficiency. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(2),
Biddle, G. C., Hilary, G., & Verdi, R. S. (2009). How does financial reporting quality
549–562. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2012.09.011
relate to investment efficiency? Journal of Accounting and Economics, 48(2–3),
Fama, E. F. (1985). What’s different about banks? Journal of Monetary Economics, 15(1),
112–131. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2009.09.001
29–39. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(85)90051-0
Bowen, H. R. (1953). Social responsibilities of the businessmen. New York, NY: Harper &
Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983). Separation of ownership and control. The Journal of
Row.
Law and Economics, 26, 301–325. https://doi.org/10.1086/467037
Brown, S., Gray, D., McHardy, J., & Taylor, K. (2015). Employee trust and workplace
performance. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 116, 361–378. https://
doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2015.05.001

13
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

Fauver, L., McDonald, M. B., & Taboada, A. G. (2018). Does it pay to treat employees Jensen, M. C., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1985). Management compensation and the
well? International evidence on the value of employee-friendly culture. Journal of managerial labor market. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7(1–3), 3–9. https://
Corporate Finance, 50, 84–108. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2018.02.003 doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(85)90025-4
Federation of European Accountants. (2016). Pursuing a strategic debate: The future of Jiang, J. (2008). Beating earnings benchmarks and the cost of deb. The Accounting
audit and assurance. Brussels: FEE. Discussion Paper. Review, 83(2), 377–416. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr.2008.83.2.377
Flammer, C., & Luo, J. (2017). Corporate social responsibility as an employee Ji, Y., Rozenbaum, O., & Welch, K. (2017). Corporate Culture and financial reporting risk:
governance tool: Evidence from a quasi-experiment. Strategic Management Journal, Looking Through the glassdoor. Working paper. George Washington University.
38(2), 163–183. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2492 Judge, T. A., & Larsen, R. J. (2001). Dispositional affect and job satisfaction: A review
Gan, H. (2019). Does CEO managerial ability matter? Evidence from corporate and theoretical extension. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 86
investment efficiency. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 52, 1085–1118. (1), 67–98. https://doi.org/10.1006/obhd.2001.2973
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-018-0737-2 Kanagaretnam, K., & Sarkar, S. (2011). Managerial compensation and the
Gao, H., Harford, J., & Li, K. (2013). Determinants of corporate cash policy: Insights from underinvestment problem. Economic Modelling, 28(1–2), 308–315. https://doi.org/
Private firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 109, 623–639. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.econmod.2010.08.017
10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.04.008 Khavis, J. A., & Krishnan, J. (2021). Employee satisfaction and work-life balance in
Gao, R., & Yu, X. (2020). How to measure capital investment efficiency: A literature accounting firms and audit quality. Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory, 40(2),
synthesis. Accounting and Finance, 60, 299–334. https://doi.org/10.1111/acfi.12343 161–192. https://doi.org/10.2308/AJPT-18-029
García Lara, J. M., Osma, B. G., & Penalva, F. (2016). Accounting conservatism and firm Kidwell, R. E., & Valentine, S. R. (2009). Positive group context, work attitudes, and
investment efficiency. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 61(1), 221–238. https:// organizational misbehavior: The case of withholding job effort. Journal of Business
doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2015.07.003 Ethics, 86, 15–28. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-008-9790-4
Gârleanu, N., & Zwiebel, J. (2009). Design and renegotiation of debt covenants. Review of Kim, Y., Park, M. S., & Wier, B. (2012). Is earnings quality associated with corporate
Financial Studies, 22(2), 749–781. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhn017 social responsibility? The Accounting Review, 87(3), 761–796. https://doi.org/
Gomariz, M. F. C., & Ballesta, J. P. S. (2014). Financial reporting quality, debt maturity 10.2308/accr-10209
and investment efficiency. Journal of Banking & Finance, 40, 494–506. https://doi. Lambert, R. A., Leuz, C., & Verrecchia, R. E. (2011). Information asymmetry, information
org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2013.07.013 precision, and the cost of capital. Review of Finance, 16, 1–29. https://doi.org/
Gordon, M. J. (1992). The Neoclassical and a post Keynesian theory of investment. 10.1093/rof/rfr014
Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 14, 425–443. https://doi.org/10.1080/ Landers, R. N., Brusso, R. C., & Auer, E. M. (2019). Crowdsourcing job satisfaction data:
01603477.1992.11489909 Examining the construct validity of Glassdoor.com ratings. Personnel Assessment and
Graham, J. R., Grennan, J., Harvey, C. R., & Rajgopal, S. (2018). Corporate culture: The Decisions, 5. https://doi.org/10.25035/pad.2019.03.006. Article 6.
interview evidence. In Working paper. Duke University. Langli, J. C., & Svanström, T. (2014). Audits of private firms. In D. Hay, W. R. Knechel, &
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2015). The value of corporate culture. Journal of M. Willekens (Eds.), Routledge companion to auditing (pp. 148–158).
Financial Economics, 60–76. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.05.010 Li, J. (2022). The effect of employee satisfaction on effective corporate tax planning:
Gul, F. A., Krishnamurti, C., Shams, S., & Chowdhury, H. (2020). Corporate social Evidence from Glassdoor. Advances in Accounting, 57, Article 100597. https://doi.
responsibility, overconfident CEOs and empire building: Agency and stakeholder org/10.1016/j.adiac.2022.100597
theoretic perspectives. Journal of Business Research, 111, 52–68. https://doi.org/ Locke, E. A. (1976). The nature and causes of job satisfaction. In M. D. Dunnette (Ed.),
10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.01.035 Handbook of industrial and organizational psychology (pp. 1297–1343). Chicago: Rand
Habib, A., D’ Costa, M., Huang, H. J., Bhuiyan, B. U., & Sun, L. (2020). Determinants and McNally.
consequences of financial distress: Review of the empirical literature. Accounting and Maslow, A. H. (1943). A theory of human motivation. Psychological Review, 50(4),
Finance, 60, 1023–1075. https://doi.org/10.1111/acfi.12400 370–396. https://doi.org/10.1037/h0054346
Habib, A., Ranasinghe, D., & Huang, H. J. (2018). A literature survey of financial McDonell, B. H. (2011). Strategies for an employee role in corporate governance. Wake
reporting in private firms. Research in Accounting Regulation, 30(1), 31–37. https:// Forest Law Review, 46, 429–446.
doi.org/10.1016/j.racreg.2018.03.005 McNichols, M. F., & Stubben, S. R. (2008). Does earnings management affect firms’
Hayashi, F. (1982). Tobin’s marginal q and average q: A neoclassical interpretation. investment decisions? The Accounting Review, 83(6), 1571–1603. https://doi.org/
Econometrica, 50(1), 213–224. https://doi.org/10.2307/1912538 10.2308/accr.2008.83.6.1571
Hemingway, C. A., & Maclagan, P. W. (2004). Managers’ personal values as drivers of Minnis, M. (2011). The value of financial statement verification in debt financing:
corporate social responsibility. Journal of Business Ethics, 50, 33–44. https://doi.org/ Evidence from private U.S. Firms. Journal of Accounting Research, 49(2), 457–506.
10.1023/B:BUSI.0000020964.80208.c9 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-679X.2011.00411.x
Herda, D. N., & Lavelle, J. J. (2015). Client identification and client commitment in a Minnis, M., & Shroff, N. (2017). Why regulate private firm disclosure and auditing?
privately held client setting: Unique constructs with opposite effects on auditor Accounting and Business Research, 47, 473–502. https://doi.org/10.1080/
objectivity. Accounting Horizons, 29(3), 577–601. https://doi.org/10.2308/acch- 00014788.2017.1303962
51091 Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the
Hess, M. F., & Broughton, E. (2014). Fostering an ethical organization from the bottom theory of investment. The American Economic Review, 48(3), 261-197.
up and the outside in. Business Horizons, 57(4), 541–549. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. Myers, S. C. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics,
bushor.2014.02.004 5(2), 147–175. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(77)90015-0
Hill, R. P., & Rapp, J. M. (2014). Codes of ethical conduct: A bottom-up approach. Organ, D. W., & Ryan, K. (1995). A meta-analytic comparison of self-reported and other-
Journal of Business Ethics, 123, 621–630. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-2013- reported organizational citizenship behavior. Personnel Psychology, 48(4), 775–802.
7 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1744-6570.1995.tb01781.x
Hope, O.-K., Langli, J. C., & Thomas, W. B. (2012). Agency conflicts and auditing in Pandey, R., Biswas, P. K., Ali, M. J., & Mansi, M. (2020). Female directors on the board
private firms. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 37(7), 500–517. https://doi.org/ and cost of debt: Evidence from Australia. Accounting and Finance, 60(4), 4031–4060.
10.1016/j.aos.2012.06.002 https://doi.org/10.1111/acfi.12521
Hope, O.-K., Li, C., Lin, A.-P., & Rabier, M. (2021). Happy analysts. Accounting, Pawlina, G. (2010). Underinvestment, capital structure and strategic debt restructuring.
Organizations and Society, 90, Article 101199. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. Journal of Banking & Finance, 16(5), 679–702. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
aos.2020.101199 jcorpfin.2010.06.010
Hope, O.-K., & Thomas, W. B. (2008). Managerial empire building and firm disclosure. Petersen, M. A. (2009). Estimating standard errors in finance Panel data sets: Comparing
Journal of Accounting Research, 46(3), 591–626. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475- approaches. Review of Financial Studies, 22(1), 435–480. https://doi.org/10.1093/
679X.2008.00289.x rfs/hhn053
Hope, O.-K., Thomas, W., & Vyas, D. (2011). Financial credibility, ownership, and Rajkovic, T. (2020). Lead independent directors and investment efficiency. Journal of
financing constraints in private firms. Journal of International Business Studies, 42, Corporate Finance, 64, Article 101690. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
935–957. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2011.23 jcorpfin.2020.101690
Hosmer, D. W., & Lemeshow, S. (2000). Applied logistic regression (2nd ed.). Hoboken, NJ: Reichelstein, S. (1997). Investment decisions and managerial performance evaluation.
John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Review of Accounting Studies, 2, 157–180. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:
Huang, M., Li, P., Meschke, F., & Guthrie, J. P. (2015). Family firms, employee 1018376808228
satisfaction, and corporate performance. Journal of Corporate Finance, 34, 108–127. Schneider, D. S., & Vaught, B. C. (1993). A comparison of job satisfaction between public
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2015.08.002 and private sector managers. Public. Administration Quarterly, 17(1), 68–83.
Huang, M., Masli, A., Meschke, F., & Guthrie, J. P. (2017). Clients’ workplace Schwartz, M. S., Dunfee, T. W., & Kline, M. J. (2005). Tone at the top: An ethics code for
environment and corporate audits. Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory, 36(4), directors? Journal of Business Ethics, 58, 79. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-005-
89–113. https://doi.org/10.2308/ajpt-51691 1390-y
Hubbard, R. G. (1998). Capital-market imperfections and investment. Journal of Sengupta, P. (1998). Corporate disclosure quality and the cost of debt. The Accounting
Economic Literature, 36(1), 193–225. Review, 73(4), 459–474.
Hui, K. W., & Matsunga, S. R. (2015). Are CEOs and CFOs rewarded for disclosure Smith, C. W., Jr. (1993). A perspective on accounting-based debt covenant violations.
quality? The Accounting Review, 90(3), 1013–1047. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr- The Accounting Review, 68(2), 289–303.
50885 Stiglitz, J. E., & Weiss, A. (1981). Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information.
Jensen, M. C. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. The American Economic Review, 71(3), 393–410.
The American Economic Review, 76(3), 323–329. Sun, J. (2009). Governance role of analyst coverage and investor protection. Financial
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, Analysts Journal, 65(6), 52–64. https://doi.org/10.2469/faj.v65.n6.2
agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.
https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X

14
S. Arvidsson et al. European Management Journal xxx (xxxx) xxx

Svanström, T. (2013). Non-audit services and audit quality: Evidence from private firms. Ward, C., Yin, C., & Zeng, Y. (2020). Motivated monitoring by institutional investors and
European Accounting Review, 22(2), 337–366. https://doi.org/10.1080/ firm investment efficiency. European Financial Management, 26(2), 348–385. https://
09638180.2012.706398 doi.org/10.1111/eufm.12232
Trevino, L. K., & Weaver, G. R. (2001). Organizational justice and ethics program Wisse, B., van Eijbergen, R., Rietzschel, E. F., & Scheibe, S. (2018). Catering to the needs
“follow-through”: Influences on employees’ harmful and helpful behavior. Business of an aging workforce: The role of employee age in the relationship between
Ethics Quarterly, 11(4), 651–671. https://doi.org/10.2307/3857765 corporate social responsibility and employee satisfaction. Journal of Business Ethics,
Van Tendeloo, B., & Vanstraelen, A. (2008). Earnings management and audit quality in 147, 875–888. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-015-2983-8
europe: Evidence from the private client segment market. European Accounting Yoshikawa, H. (1980). On the "q" theory of investment. The American Economic Review,
Review, 17(3), 447–469. https://doi.org/10.1080/09638180802016684 70(4), 739–743.
Versano, T. (2020). Enforcement of optimal disclosure rules in the presence of moral Zhang, M., Zhang, W., & Zhang, S. (2016). National culture and firm investment
hazard. European Accounting Review, 29(4), 825–849. https://doi.org/10.1080/ efficiency: International evidence. Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting & Economics, 23
09638180.2019.1696216 (1), 1–21. https://doi.org/10.1080/16081625.2015.1027714
Vroom, V. H. (1964). Work and motivation. New York: Wiley.

15

You might also like