Berndt 2007

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

At the Intersection of Health, Health Care and Policy

Cite this article as:


Ernst R. Berndt, Richard Mortimer, Ashoke Bhattacharjya, Andrew Parece and Edward
Tuttle
Authorized Generic Drugs, Price Competition, And Consumers' Welfare
Health Affairs, 26, no.3 (2007):790-799

doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.26.3.790

The online version of this article, along with updated information and services, is
available at:
http://content.healthaffairs.org/content/26/3/790.full.html

For Reprints, Links & Permissions:


http://healthaffairs.org/1340_reprints.php
E-mail Alerts : http://content.healthaffairs.org/subscriptions/etoc.dtl
To Subscribe: http://content.healthaffairs.org/subscriptions/online.shtml

Health Affairs is published monthly by Project HOPE at 7500 Old Georgetown Road, Suite 600,
Bethesda, MD 20814-6133. Copyright © 2007 by Project HOPE - The People-to-People Health
Foundation. As provided by United States copyright law (Title 17, U.S. Code), no part of Health Affairs
may be reproduced, displayed, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical,
including photocopying or by information storage or retrieval systems, without prior written permission
from the Publisher. All rights reserved.

Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC
Health Tr a c k i n g

M a r k e t Watc h
Authorized Generic Drugs, Price Competition,
And Consumers’ Welfare
On balance, authorized generics are likely to benefit consumers.
by Ernst R. Berndt, Richard Mortimer, Ashoke Bhattacharjya, Andrew
Parece, and Edward Tuttle
ABSTRACT: The growing frequency of authorized generics has important implications for
the welfare of prescription drug consumers. Authorized generic entry could affect the tim-
ing of generic entry, brand-name and generic prices, and generic penetration. We reviewed
1999–2003 data and found that generic entry in the absence of short-run exclusivity re-
strictions benefits consumers through lower short-run prices. We suggest that these bene-
fits likely also result from authorized generics. We posit that long-run prices and shares are
likely essentially unaffected by authorized generics and that potential costs to consumers
from any delayed generic entry are likely small. [Health Affairs 26, no. 3 (2007): 790–799;
10.1377/hlthaff.26.3.790]

C
o n s i d e r a b l e i n t e r e s t has fo- run competition and earlier generic entry. Al-
cused recently on the effects that au- though authorized generics likely reduce these
thorized generic prescription drugs incentives to generic manufacturers, the ulti-
have on competition among generic and mate impact on consumers through drug
brand-name drugs and on consumers’ wel- prices and the timing of generic entry is un-
fare. Authorized generics are prescription clear. Here we outline issues and review data
drugs whose U.S. marketing approval derives on generic entry between January 1999 and
from the brand manufacturer’s new drug ap- December 2003 (as authorized generic entry
plication (NDA) yet are marketed and sold as began to increase), and case studies of autho-
generic versions of the brand.1 rized generic introductions from 2003 and
Authorized generics can benefit consumers 2004, to assess the impact of generic entry on
if they increase competition and lower prices. consumers under different market conditions.
However, some argue that the increased short-
run competition they create might undermine Background
incentives created by the 1984 Hatch-Waxman n Hatch-Waxman legislation and its af-
Act for generic manufacturers to challenge termath. To foster competition, the Hatch-
patents—incentives designed to foster long- Waxman Act allowed generic manufacturers

Ernst Berndt (erberndt@mit.edu) is the Louis B. Seley Professor in Applied Economics, Sloan School of
Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) and National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER),
both in Cambridge, Massachusetts. Richard Mortimer is a vice president of the Analysis Group in Boston,
Massachusetts. Ashoke Bhattacharjya is executive director, Health Outcomes and Policy, Johnson and Johnson
Medical—Asia Pacific, in New Delhi, India. Andrew Parece is a managing principal of the Analysis Group in
Boston. Edward Tuttle is a managing principal of the Analysis Group in Menlo Park, California.

790 May/ June 2007


DOI 10.1377/hlthaff.26.3.790 ©2007 Project HOPE–The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc.

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC
M a r k e t Wat c h

to file an abbreviated new drug application Agency does not believe their marketing
(ANDA) demonstrating bioequivalence to an should be delayed in this manner, as this mar-
innovator drug, rather than an NDA, which re- keting appears to promote competition in the
quires more data establishing safety and effi- pharmaceutical marketplace, in furtherance of
cacy. The ANDA could be filed before the inno- a fundamental objective of the Hatch-
vator’s patents expired. Moreover, the first Waxman amendments.”9 Several court deci-
generic manufacturer to file an ANDA with a sions have since upheld the right for autho-
successful paragraph IV certification (a patent rized generics to be marketed during the 180-
challenge or claim of noninfringement) is day exclusiv ity period. 1 0 Senators Jay
awarded a 180-day marketing “exclusivity” pe- Rockefeller (D-WV), Charles Schumer (D-
riod during which no other ANDA filers can NY), and Patrick Leahy (D-VT) introduced a
market their version of the drug dose. bill banning the marketing of authorized ge-
The frequency of paragraph IV certifica- nerics during this period.11
tions has greatly increased. Between 1984 and n Effects on consumers. Here we focus
1989, only 2 percent of ANDA submissions on the effects of authorized generics on con-
contained certifications. This share increased sumers, and only indirectly on potential impli-
to 12 percent between 1990 and 1997 and then cations for brand and independent generic
to 20 percent between 1998 and 2000.2 Grant- manufacturers. Implications for consumers
ing of 180-day exclusivity by the Food and depend on the effects of authorized generic en-
Drug Administration (FDA) also increased, trant on four developments: (1) the timing of
from none between 1992 and 1998 to 31 drugs independent generic entry; (2) relative generic
between 1998 and 2002.3 and brand shares of the molecule; (3) relative
Authorized generics rely on the brand man- generic-to-brand price; and (4) perceived
ufacturer’s NDA and have been allowed to quality of the authorized generic relative to the
compete against ANDA-based generics even brand and independent generics.
during the 180-day exclusivity period (if there A possible impact from item 1 could be to
is one). The recent increase in authorized increase long-run costs for consumers if para-
generics enables brand manufacturers to cap- graph IV certifications were less aggressively
ture some of the postpatent generic sales when filed and resulted in some brands’ facing ge-
only one independent generic is present.4 Au- neric competition later than they would have
thorized generics have long existed and have in the absence of an anticipated authorized ge-
attracted policy concern in the past.5 In the neric entrant. The combined effect of items 2
early 1990s, several brand manufacturers cre- and 3 is likely to benefit consumers in the
ated subsidiaries that marketed generics; some short term when generics are sold at lower rel-
of these have since closed.6 ative prices; over a longer time period, the
A highly publicized launch of an autho- combined effects are not as clear. The effect of
rized generic occurred with the multibillion- item 4, if material, likely would be to increase
dollar drug Paxil (paroxetine) in 2003. In Feb- generic share further, benefiting consumers to
ruary 2004, Mylan filed a citizen petition re- the extent that the price of the authorized ge-
questing the FDA to prohibit the marketing of neric is less than that of the brand.
any authorized generic drug during an ANDA- n Previous literature. Few peer-reviewed
generated exclusivity period.7 Watson and Par publications discuss authorized generic entry.
supported the availability of authorized David Reiffen and Michael Ward investigate
generics, claiming that partnering with brand the effects of authorized generic entry on ge-
manufacturers benefited consumers.8 The neric and branded segments but do not focus
FDA responded to Mylan’s arguments, stating: on potential consumer impacts. They calculate
“Not only does FDA lack authority to justify that anticipated authorized generic entry may
delaying the marketing of authorized generics raise long-run prices by roughly 1–2 percent
solely to protect 180-day exclusivity, the for small to medium-size drugs, with a smaller

H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 6 , N u m b e r 3 791

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC
Health Tr a c k i n g

effect on prices of blockbusters.12 An IMS Con- relatively large profits associated with exclu-
sulting study, supported by Pharmaceutical sivity (reflecting policies encouraging greater
Research and Manufacturers of America generic penetration during the exclusivity pe-
(PhRMA), reports that drugs experiencing au- riod and developments in patent law).16
thorized generic entry during an exclusivity The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) has
period had generic discounts to the brand reported that of fifty-three ANDA submissions
price that were sixteen percentage points containing paragraph IV certifications chal-
larger than those with no authorized generic lenged by the patent holder and for which a lit-
entry.13 igated resolution was reached, twenty-two
(42 percent) resulted in the generic applicant’s
Market Features Relevant To prevailing at trial.17 Another possible explana-
Authorized Generic Entry tion for increased patent challenges is that
We categorized market features relevant to patents protecting the brand manufacturers’
authorized generic entry into two stages: first, drugs might have been weaker than in the
whether the branded drug encounters an past, making such challenges more likely to
ANDA filing with a successful paragraph IV succeed. In the context of weak patents, some
certification; and second, the extent of inde- argue that settlements (rather than litigated
pendent generic entry with and without au- resolutions), particularly those involving pay-
thorized generic entry. Under these market ments by the brand to the potential exclusive
scenarios, below we examine the subsequent generic entrant (“negative” fixed fees), are es-
impact of authorized generic entry on con- pecially harmful to consumers.18
sumers through the timing dynamics of ge- n Extent of generic entry. A sizable liter-
neric entry, pricing, and market shares. ature considers generic entry, brand and ge-
n Paragraph IV certifications. Con- neric prices, and generic penetration for tradi-
sumer benefits from generic entry are typically tional small-molecule drugs. One recent study
more limited during the exclusivity period, relies on data from the late 1980s and early
with the sole generic entrant usually offering 1990s.19 Several other studies examine price
on average only a modest (10–20 percent) dis- trends and patterns of generic entry; almost all
count off the brand. Authorized generic entry are based on data ending before or up to the
allows for an additional generic product dur- late 1990s.20
ing the exclusivity period, potentially further This literature generally finds that having
lowering generic prices and benefiting con- more generic entrants for a drug is associated
sumers.14 For independent generics, the antici- with lower generic-to-brand price ratios and
pation of an authorized generic entrant re- higher generic shares. However, it also sug-
duces the expected profitability during the gests that after the first few entrants, the mar-
exclusivity period, thereby possibly deterring ginal effect of each entrant on generic prices
patent challenges by independent generics. If and shares tends to be negligible.21
some of those forgone challenges had been Using a data set on drugs experiencing
successful, then independent generic entry more recent generic entry, we found empirical
might be delayed in the absence of the chal- evidence consistent with these earlier find-
lenge, harming consumers. ings.22 Based on 1999–2003 data, Exhibit 1 doc-
Changes in FDA administrative law award- uments that the impact of an additional ge-
ing 180-day exclusivity offer one possible rea- neric is negligible after the fourth or fifth
son for the greater frequency of recent patent entrant. Specifically, at twenty-four months
challenges and awarding of exclusivity.15 The since initial generic entry, only one drug with
increase in patent challenges could also reflect fewer than five generic entrants (out of seven)
greater speculative behavior by generic manu- had a generic-to-brand price ratio below 0.37;
facturers, as a result of the number of top-sell- all ten drugs with more than five generic en-
ing drugs that face patent expiration and the trants had generic-to-brand price ratios falling

792 May/ June 2007

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC
M a r k e t Wat c h

EXHIBIT 1
Generic-To-Brand Price Ratio Versus Number Of Generics, Twenty-Four Months
Following Initial Generic Entry, 1999–2003
Generic-to-brand price ratio
0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0.0
0 5 10 15 20
Number of generics
SOURCE: Authors’ analysis based on IMS Retail and Non-Retail Sales Perspective data and IMS Retail National Prescription
Audit (NPA) data for drugs that experienced generic entry between January 1999 and December 2003 and for which data were
available twenty-four months following initial generic entry.

below 0.25, and no discernible downward otherwise there would have been at least one
trend in ratios appeared as the number of ge- successful certification.
neric entrants increased further.23 Below we outline theoretical arguments
Although we relied primarily on descriptive that led us to conclude that for most drugs, the
statistics, these results are essentially similar prospect of authorized generic entry during
to those reported by Reiffen and Ward using a the exclusivity period is unlikely to greatly de-
more rigorous statistical approach on data for crease incentives for paragraph IV certifica-
an older set of drugs. An important implica- tion. Moreover, a reduction in such certifica-
tion of this common finding is that a reduction tions does not delay generic entry or harm
in the long-run number of independent consumers if the deterred certifications would
generics as a result of authorized generic entry have been unsuccessful or if other timely and
is unlikely to harm consumers by raising long- successful certifications were not deterred.
run generic prices unless it results in fewer For many drugs, the expected profits ac-
than four or five generic entrants. cruing to an exclusive independent generic
might be sufficient to recoup the costs of pat-
Impact On Consumers ent challenges even with authorized generic
The primary effects on consumers of autho- entry. Both Reiffen and Ward and Aidan Hollis
rized generic entry relate to the timing and ex- place the typical cost of filing an ANDA at less
tent of generic entry, through the dynamic im- than $1 million.24 This estimate does not in-
pacts of authorized generic entry on generic clude legal costs/gains if the paragraph IV cer-
share and generic/brand relative prices. tification is challenged.25 Paragraph IV certifi-
n Timing of generic entry. By increasing cations have historically been submitted
expected competition during the exclusivity despite the presence of several factors dimin-
period, anticipated authorized generic entry ishing their expected value, including multiple
reduces expected profits for successful para- generic manufacturers’ being awarded exclu-
graph IV certifications, in turn reducing the sivity for the same drug because their ANDAs
incentives to pursue such certification. For were submitted on the same day or for differ-
some drugs, this could delay generic entry if it ent doses; competition to be the first ANDA
resulted in no successful paragraph IV certifi- filer; and the probability that the paragraph IV
cations under anticipated generic entry when certification will be unsuccessful even if the

H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 6 , N u m b e r 3 793

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC
Health Tr a c k i n g

generic manufacturer is the first ANDA filer. To date, there is no reliable empirical evi-
Even for those drugs where authorized ge- dence on the effect of anticipated authorized
neric entry discourages some patent chal- generic entry on the propensity to file success-
lenges, the timing of generic entry would not ful paragraph IV certifications and on the tim-
necessarily be affected, and consumers would ing of independent generic entry. What data
not necessarily be harmed. To the extent that are available suggest that thus far, the fre-
independent generic firms are not risk-loving, quency of paragraph IV certifications remains
when authorized generic entry deters patent high. For example, although contemporaneous
challenges, it is likely to do so where a chal- authorized generic entry has increased, the
lenge has the least likelihood of success and number of drugs facing their first certification
thus entails the lowest expected profits. averaged 4.3 per month between March 2004
Finally, for anticipated authorized generic and April 2005, compared with 4.5 between
entry to delay independent generic entry, it May 2005 and May 2006.28 Over the same time
must discourage paragraph IV certifications periods, our estimated average number of
that would be successful, and it must do so for drugs that could receive certification declined
every generic manufacturer that would file a from 267.1 to 261.7. Hence, first filings in-
timely certification for a given drug.26 If a suc- creased even as the potential number of targets
cessful certification is deterred by the prospect declined (Exhibit 2).29
of authorized generic entry, the timing of ge- We tentatively conclude, therefore, that in
neric entry will still be unaffected as long as at the long run, authorized generics are unlikely
least one generic with the resources to support to materially harm consumers through delayed
a certification (including any legal challenges) generic entry. Indeed, a recent case suggests
chooses to file as early as those that might have that the mere threat of authorized generic en-
been deterred and devotes comparable re- try likely induced independent generic entry
sources to filing and litigation.27 before paragraph IV litigation was resolved.30

EXHIBIT 2
Drugs Facing And Available For First Paragraph IV Certification, As Of May 2006
Number of drugs facing first certification Est. drugs available for first certification
12 275

10 Stock of drugs available 250


Drugs facing Paragraph IV
8 certification 225

6 200

4 175

2 150

0 125
3/04 6/04 9/04 12/04 3/05 6/05 9/05 12/05 3/06

SOURCES: Food and Drug Administration, “Paragraph IV Patent Certifications as of January 18, 2007,” http://www.fda.gov/
cder/pgd/ppiv.htm (accessed 6 February 2007); and FDA data on new molecular entities (NMEs).
NOTES: Some drugs facing paragraph IV certification may be counted more than once if the abbreviated new drug applications
(ANDAs) containing paragraph IV certifications for different doses of the drug are filed in separate submissions. Stock of drugs
available for certification is the sum of drug approvals between the previous four and twelve years. Data on drugs facing
certification are shown as bars and relate to the left-hand y axis. Data on the stock of drugs available are shown as a line and
relate to the right-hand y axis.

794 May/ June 2007

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC
M a r k e t Wat c h

n Generic share and price. For drugs have significantly lower generic-to-brand
with paragraph IV certifications, the added price ratios.31 In the twenty-fourth month, the
competition introduced by the authorized ge- average generic-to-brand price ratio for drugs
neric during the exclusivity period will gener- with successful paragraph IV certifications is
ally result in lower generic prices, benefiting 0.27, compared with an average of 0.29 for
consumers. Beyond the exclusivity period, the drugs without successful certifications.32
key issue for determining the overall impact on Exhibit 4 documents the average generic
consumers is whether the prospect of autho- share for drugs with and without successful
rized generic entry could change the long-run paragraph IV certifications at the same time
number of generic entrants and, if so, whether intervals following initial generic entry. In the
this would affect long-run generic prices and twenty-fourth month, the average generic
shares. Any changes in the long-run number of share for drugs with successful certifications
generics are unlikely to affect generic price is 85 percent compared with an average of 83
and share for the many drugs with more than percent for drugs without them.33 Interest-
four or five generic entrants (Exhibit 1). ingly, even in the third and sixth months fol-
Based on recent data on patent expirations, lowing initial generic entry, when there are
we found that the exclusivity period appears significant differences in the generic-to-brand
to significantly increase short-run generic-to- price ratios between drugs with and without
brand price ratios but has little or no long- successful paragraph IV certifications, the
term effect on these price ratios and generic shares for these two groups of drugs are very
shares. Exhibit 3 reports the average generic- similar; this similarity might reflect state and
to-brand price ratios for drugs with and with- private-sector managed care policies mandat-
out successful paragraph IV certifications at ing automated generic substitution even when
various points following initial generic entry. there is only a small price differential between
In the third month following initial generic en- the generic and the brand.
try, drugs not subject to an exclusivity period The comparisons in Exhibits 3 and 4 do not

EXHIBIT 3
Average Generic-To-Brand Price Ratios, With And Without Successful Paragraph IV
Filings, 1999–2003
Generic-to-brand price ratio With successful paragraph IV filings
0.8 7 Without successful paragraph IV filings
7
0.6
5
0.4 21 4
22
21
0.2
13
0.0
3 6 9 12 15 18 21 24
Months following initial generic entry
SOURCES: IMS Retail and Non-Retail National Sales Perspective data and IMS Retail National Prescription Audit (NPA) data for
drugs that experienced generic entry between January 1999 and December 2003.
NOTES: Number of drugs constituting the average drugs with successful paragraph IV filings are shown above the data points;
those constituting the average drugs without successful paragraph IV filings are shown below the data points. Eulexin was
excluded from the calculation of average generic share and generic-to-brand ratio for the third month following initial generic
entry because of a single outlier month where the calculated generic-to-brand price ratio was greater than 1. Difference in
means between drugs with and without successful paragraph IV filings is statistically insignificant for twelve and twenty-four
months following initial generic entry.

H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 6 , N u m b e r 3 795

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC
Health Tr a c k i n g

EXHIBIT 4
Average Generic Share Of Prescription Units, With And Without Successful Paragraph
IV Filings, 1999–2003
Generic share (percent) With successful paragraph IV filings 4
80 Without successful paragraph IV filings
5 13
7
60 21
22
7
40
21
20
3 6 9 12 15 18 21 24
Months following initial generic entry
SOURCES: IMS Retail and Non-Retail National Sales Perspective data and IMS Retail National Prescription Audit (NPA) data for
drugs that experienced generic entry between January 1999 and December 2003.
NOTES: Number of drugs constituting the average drugs with successful paragraph IV filings are shown above the data points;
those constituting the average drugs without successful paragraph IV filings are shown below the data points. Eulexin was
excluded from the calculation of average generic share and generic-to-brand ratio for the third month following initial generic
entry because of a single outlier month where the calculated generic-to-brand price ratio was greater than 1. Difference in
means between drugs with and without successful paragraph IV filings is statistically insignificant for each point in time
compared.

control for inherent differences among drugs cent of unit sales within two months and
with and without successful paragraph IV cer- about 85 percent within sixteen months.
tifications. They are also based on a relatively Exhibit 6 portrays the generic-to-brand
small sample of drugs facing successful certifi- price ratios over time for Paxil (paroxetine),
cations. However, the results are consistent along with the number of independent generic
with the finding that high generic penetration entrants. Although the reported price of the
and low generic-to-brand price ratios are authorized generic is higher than the average
achieved in the long run, regardless of whether independent generic price during the first year
successful paragraph IV certifications oc- following initial generic entry, after that, both
curred. These findings are suggestive of the po- the authorized and independent generic prices
tential impact of authorized generic entry dur- are roughly 50 percent of the brand price for
ing the 180-day exclusivity period. Paxil. The higher Paxil authorized generic
price in the first year might reflect a consumer/
Authorized Generic Entry: A physician preference for the authorized ge-
Recent Example neric over the independent generic paroxetine.
We examined data on generic shares and However, for Cipro and Ortho Tri-Cyclen, the
prices for three brand-name drugs that re- authorized generic price discount was within
cently experienced authorized generic entry: one percentage point or less of the independ-
Paxil (paroxetine), Cipro (ciprofloxacin), and ent generic price discount in all months. Rea-
Ortho Tri-Cyclen.34 For all three products, au- sons for price differences among these drugs
thorized generics competed aggressively are likely idiosyncratic but could reflect differ-
against independent generics on price, and ences in the characteristics of the generic en-
both the authorized and independent generics trants, rebates not observed in the data, mar-
captured substantial market share from the keting, and other factors.
brand. Exhibit 5 plots quantity shares over Moreover, the IMS price and quantity data
time for authorized and independent generics used in these calculations are from wholesale
following initial generic entry for Paxil transactions; an implicit assumption is that on
(paroxetine). Generics captured about 70 per- average, retail margins for brands, authorized

796 May/ June 2007

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC
M a r k e t Wat c h

EXHIBIT 5
Generic Unit Shares For Paxil (Brand), Authorized Generic, And Independent
Paroxetine, 2001–2004
Market share (percent) Authorized generic share
100 Independent generic share
Brand-name share
80

60

40
6 6 6 6 6 5
3 3 4
20 3 3 3
1 2 2
0 1
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16
Months following initial generic entry
SOURCE: IMS Retail National Prescription Audit (NPA) data, January 2001 and December 2004.
NOTES: Market shares are based on extended units from IMS data. Numbers on the graphic are the number of independent
generics.

generics, and independent generics are pro- downward pressure on overall generic prices.
portionally similar and that the wholesale Lower generic prices during exclusivity also
price ratios provide reasonable proxies for rel- reduce expected profits from successful para-
ative consumer price impacts.35 graph IV certifications. Some argue that as a
consequence, authorized generics will deter
Concluding Comments paragraph IV certifications, potentially delay-
We report evidence consistent with autho- ing generic entry and resulting in higher long-
rized generics’ benefiting consumers of drugs run generic prices.
sold during 180-day exclusivity periods, by in- Although reliable long-run data are not yet
troducing additional competition that places available, we posit that authorized generic

EXHIBIT 6
Generic (Paroxetine)-To-Brand (Paxil) Price Ratios Versus Number Of Months After
Generic Entry, 2001–2004
Generic-to-brand price ratio Authorized generic-to-brand price
1.00 Independent generic-to-brand price

1
0.75

1 3 6 6 6 6
0.50 3 3 5
2 2 3 3 6
4
0.25
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16
Months following generic entry
SOURCE: IMS Retail National Prescription Audit (NPA) data, January 2001 and December 2004.
NOTES: The generic-to-brand price ratio in the first month is constrained to 1.00 as an apparent mismatch in the timing of
revenues and units results in unreasonable average generic revenue (price) in that month. Prices are calculated monthly based
on revenues and extended units as reported in IMS data. Numbers on the graphic are the number of independent generics.

H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 6 , N u m b e r 3 797

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC
Health Tr a c k i n g

entry will disproportionately deter what oth- http://www.ftc.gov/os/2002/07/genericdrug


erwise would be unsuccessful paragraph IV study.pdf (accessed 7 October 2005).
certifications. Even when a successful certifi- 3. Ibid.
cation is deterred, generic entry is delayed by 4. An “independent” generic entrant is a generic en-
trant whose ability to be sold derives from its
anticipated authorized generic entry only if all FDA-approved ANDA.
timely and successful certifications for a drug
5. FDA, “Guidance for Industry,” June 1998, http://
are deterred. In the absence of extensive data www.fda.gov/cder/guidance/2576fnl.pdf; March
on paragraph IV filings, we put forth reasons 2000, http://www.fda.gov/cder/guidance/3659fnl
why, in our judgment, anticipated authorized .pdf; and July 2003, http://www.fda.gov/cder/
generic entry is unlikely to delay independent guidance/5710fnl.pdf (accessed 18 August 2006).
generic entry for most drugs and why any im- 6. M. Freudenheim, “All about Generic Pharmaceu-
pact on consumer prices from delayed entry is ticals; Now the Big Drug Makers Are Imitating
Their Imitators,” New York Times, 20 September
likely to be small. 1992.
We also find that should anticipated autho- 7. Mylan Laboratories, Form 8-K, Citizen Petition,
rized generic entry reduce the long-run num- pp. 13–17, 30 June 2004, http://ccbn.10Kwizard
ber of generic entrants for a drug, it still might .com/xml/download.php?format=pdf&ipage=
have little effect on long-run generic prices 2869681 (accessed 16 March 2007).
and shares. Our analysis of recent data demon- 8. M. Sipkof, “Battle over Authorized Generics
strates that additional generic entrants after Grows Increasingly Heated,” Drug Topics, 1 April
2005, http://www.drugtopics.com/drugtopics/
the first four or five do not appear to signifi- article/articleDetail.jsp?id=152726 (accessed 14
cantly affect long-run generic-to-brand price September 2005).
ratios. Furthermore, although our analysis is 9. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services,
preliminary, we find that 180-day exclusivity Docket nos. 2004P-0075/CP1 and 2004P-
does not appear to lower long-run generic-to- 0261/CP1, 2 July 2004, http://www.fda.gov/
brand price ratios or increase long-run generic ohrms/dockets/dailys/04/july04/070704/04p-
0075-pdn0001.pdf (accessed 24 August 2005).
penetration. Hence, any effect of authorized
10. See, for example, Teva Pharmaceutical Industries v.
generics on the incentives created by 180-day
FDA, no. 05-5004, U.S. Court of Appeals, D.C.
exclusivity is unlikely to greatly affect con- Circuit, 3 June 2005.
sumers through delayed generic entry or 11. See S. 3695, 109th Cong., 2d sess. (19 July 2006).
higher long-run generic prices. Finally, we 12. D. Reiffen and M.R. Ward, “ ‘Branded Generics’
note that no studies to date have provided evi- as a Strategy to Limit Cannibalization of Phar-
dence of authorized generics’ affecting the maceutical Markets,” Working Paper, May 2005,
number of paragraph IV certifications or the http://www.uta.edu/faculty/mikeward/branded
timing of generic entry. In future research, we generics.pdf (accessed 7 October 2005).
intend to address these issues. 13. See Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers
of America, “Authorized Generics Can Lead to
Lower Drug Prices,” Press Release, 20 July 2006,
Funding support from Johnson and Johnson is http://www.phrma.org/news_room/press_
gratefully acknowledged. The opinions expressed herein releases/authorized generics_can_lead_to_lower_
are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect drug_prices (accessed 6 February 2007).
those of the institutions with which they are affiliated, 14. Here we consider a single authorized generic en-
or of the research sponsor. try, although in principle there could be more.
15. FDA, “Guidance for Industry,” June 1998, March
2000, and July 2003.
NOTES 16. Grabowski suggests that generic firms are pros-
1. Authorized generic drugs may be produced and pecting in patent challenges for very large payoffs
sold by the brand manufacturer (perhaps from 180-day exclusivity periods should they be
through a subsidiary) or through a licensing successful. H. Grabowski, “Competition be-
agreement with another company that inde- tween Generic and Branded Drugs” (Unpub-
pendently distributes and prices the product. lished paper, Duke University, May 2005).
2. Federal Trade Commission, Generic Drug Entry 17. FTC, Generic Drug Entry. Of the remaining thirty-
Prior to Patent Expiration: An FTC Study, July 2002,

798 May/ June 2007

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC
M a r k e t Wat c h

one resolutions, in two cases the patent expired tories, Form 10-K (2004), 63.
prior to a litigation resolution; in twenty, the liti- 26. Razadyne recently experienced paragraph IV
gation was settled; in eight, the brand-name certifications filed by at least seven generic man-
company won the litigation; and in one, the NDA ufacturers. Par Pharmaceuticals, Form 10-K
was withdrawn before litigation was resolved. (2006).
Unlike the twenty-two case decisions resulting
27. The effect on the timing of generic entry will de-
in a win for the generic, most of the settlements
pend on the respective ANDA filing dates, time
instituted delays to generic entry.
to approval, and the time to any relevant court
18. See J. Farrell and C. Sharpiro, “How Strong Are decisions for the independent generic manufac-
Weak Patents?” Working Paper, January 2007, turer that was deterred from entering compared
http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/weak to the one that was not deterred from entering
.pdf (accessed 6 February 2007). and is the first filer.
19. D. Reiffen and M.R. Ward, “Generic Drug Indus- 28. Calculated using FDA data on the date of the first
try Dynamics,” Review of Economics and Statistics 87, ANDA filing with a paragraph IV certification
no. 1 (2005): 37–49. for drugs experiencing these filings between
20. See, for example, R. Caves, M. Whinston, and M. March 2004 and May 2006. FDA, “Paragraph IV
Hurwitz, “Patent Expiration, Entry, and Compe- Patent Certifications as of January 18, 2007,”
tition in the U.S. Pharmaceutical Industry,” http://www.fda.gov/cder/ogd/ppiv.htm (accessed
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 6 February 2007). Dates determined by data
(1991): 1–67; Congressional Budget Office, How In- availability.
creased Competition from Generic Drugs Has Affected 29. Using FDA data on new molecular entity (NME)
Prices and Returns in the Pharmaceutical Industry approvals, and assuming an average twelve-year
(Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, time span between NME approval and initial ge-
July 1998); and F.M. Scott-Morton, “Barriers to neric entry, we calculated the stock of drugs po-
Entry, Brand Advertising, and Generic Entry in tentially facing paragraph IV challenges as the
the U.S. Pharmaceutical Industry,” International total number of NME approvals between the
Journal of Industrial Organization 18, no. 7 (2000): previous four and twelve years (for example, the
1086–1104. 2004 stock is the sum of NME approvals be-
21. Using revenue divided by quantity as a measure tween 1992 and 2000). Results were similar
of average price, Reiffen and Ward found no sta- when ten- and fourteen-year time spans were
tistically significant effect of additional generic employed instead of twelve.
entrants on the generic-to-brand price ratio fol- 30. Launch of an independent generic version of
lowing the sixth generic entrant. Reiffen and Allegra might have been accelerated to preempt
Ward, “Generic Drug Industry Dynamics.” potential authorized generic entry. See FDA,
22. For a description of the data used here, see our “Teva Launches Generic Allegra ‘At Risk’ under
Online Supplement at http://content.health Barr’s Exclusivity,” Pink Sheet 67, no. 37 (2005): 17.
affairs.org/cgi/content/full/26/3/790/DC1. 31. In the third (sixth) month following initial ge-
23. Bresnahan and Reiss found that in a number of neric entry, the average generic-to-brand price
markets, it only takes three or four entrants to ratio for drugs with successful paragraph IV cer-
approximate competitive conditions. T. tifications was 0.74 (0.64), compared with an av-
Bresnahan and P. Reiss, “Entry and Competition erage of 0.52 (0.47) for drugs without successful
in Concentrated Markets,” Journal of Political Econ- certifications; the null hypothesis of no differ-
omy 95, no. 5 (1991): 977–1009. ence between these price ratios is rejected, p =
24. A. Hollis, “The Anticompetitive Effects of Brand- 0.02 (marginally rejected, p = 0.09).
Controlled ‘Pseudo-Generics’ in the Canadian 32. The null hypothesis of no difference between
Pharmaceutical Market,” Canadian Public Policy 29, these price ratios is not rejected (p = 0.90).
no. 1 (2003): 21–31. Reiffen and Ward cite a cost 33. The null hypothesis of no difference between the
of $475 thousand in late 1980s/early 1990s dol- median (not mean) price ratios is also not re-
lars. Reiffen and Ward, “ ‘Branded Generics’.” jected (p = 0.66). Similarly, the null hypothesis of
Hollis cites a cost of roughly $1 million Canadian. no difference between the median generic shares
25. Generic manufacturers’ legal costs of defending a is not rejected (p = 0.66).
challenged paragraph IV certification may be off- 34. Ortho Tri-Cyclen is a combination of three mole-
set by countersuit litigation. For example, Mylan cules and does not have a single generic molecu-
received a $15 million settlement of allegations lar name.
that the brand manufacturer violated antitrust
35. Further data details are available in the online
laws by suing Mylan for alleged infringement of a
supplement; see Note 22.
patent on the drug mirtazapine. Mylan Labora-

H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 6 , N u m b e r 3 799

Downloaded from content.healthaffairs.org by Health Affairs on April 4, 2015


at RUTGERS UNIV DISTRIBUTD TECH SVC

You might also like