Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 56

Democracy and Stock Market Returns

Xun Lei1
Xi’an Jiaotong-Liverpool University
International Business School Suzhou
Department of Finance
111 Ren'ai Road
Suzhou, Jiangsu, 215123, China
Phone: (0086) 1396 0720613
E-mail: xun.lei@xjtlu.edu.cn

Tomasz Piotr Wisniewski


The Open University
Faculty of Business and Law
Division of Accounting and Finance
Walton Hall
Milton Keynes, MK7 6AA, UK
Phone: (0044) 1908 655020
E-mail: tomasz.wisniewski@open.ac.uk

1 Corresponding author

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Democracy and Stock Market Returns

Abstract

This paper examines the relationship between the level of democratization and
stock index returns in a sample of 74 countries. Compared with democracies,
autocratic states are characterized by lower returns despite exhibiting higher
return volatility. Even though this higher volatility can be mostly attributed to
diversifiable country-specific risk, the Capital Asset Pricing Model is unable to
explain the return differential. Instead, it is the level of investor protection that
can fully account for the phenomenon described here. Autocratic leaders are
reluctant to promulgate regulation shielding investors and the resultant risk of
expropriation depresses the returns realized by outsiders.

Keywords: Stock Returns, Political Regimes, Democracy, Autocracy, Investor


Protection
JEL Codes: G12, P16

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


I. Introduction

Do political institutions matter for the stock markets? Do the laws and regulations of so-

called true ‘democracies’ and democratic institutions have any effect on stock valuations?

Although these questions are of fundamental importance, they remain largely unexplored.

Generally, it is believed that democratic institutions are associated with better investor

protection, although the academic literature is relatively silent on this topic. If such belief could

be upheld empirically, it would provide a valid rationale for why stock markets domiciled in

democratic countries tend to thrive over time. On the other hand, one could argue that equity

investments in more autocratic states also carry a certain appeal. Stock prices in autocracies

may be less likely to move in tandem with global trends, which would present portfolio

investors with a range of attractive diversification opportunities.

For all of the reasons mentioned above, one may wonder whether democratic systems would

be preferred from the perspective of stock market investors. However, only anecdotal evidence

on this topic is available and more empirical inquiry into this matter is needed. Although degree

of democracy has been used as a political risk component by some authors (see, for instance,

Diamonte et al., 1996; Erb et al., 1996; Perotti and Van Oijen, 2001), to the best of our

knowledge there are virtually no studies examining how the evolution of democracy affects

fluctuations of stock prices. One exception is the work of Lehkonen and Heimonen (2015) who

use a sample of emerging markets spanning from 2000 to 2012 in order to show the existence

of a positive association between levels of democratization and returns. Whether this finding

is statistically significant, however, was largely dependent on their model specification. Ours

is a larger dataset in that it also includes developed markets and focuses on a longer timeframe.

Our sample comprises annual return data for 74 stock markets and covers the period between

1975 and 2015. The results reported here confirm the existence of a positive relationship

between democracy levels and stock returns. Using this expanded data set, however, enabled

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


us to reach more compelling conclusions regarding statistical significance. In fact, the return-

democracy nexus is sufficiently robust to support the design of a profitable trading strategy

based on the democracy index alone.

We also contribute to the literature by carefully examining different aspects of investment risk

across the democratic spectrum. In doing so, we not only analyze volatility risk but also

decompose it into two components. One of them arises from the covariation with the world

stock market index, while the other is diversifiable in a global portfolio and pertains to country-

specific developments. The covariation risk appears to be marginally higher for markets located

in democratic states, whereas the latter type of risk is elevated in autocracies. Inasmuch as these

results are illuminating, these risk profiles are unable to fully account for the returns gap

observed between democratic and autocratic regimes.

Confronted with this failure of the Capital Asset Pricing Model, we put forward an alternative

explanation that is fully consistent with the empirical regularities observed here. We document

that investors who commit their capital to authoritarian countries do not enjoy the same level

of legal protection that is typically encountered in mature democracies. By evidencing this, we

attempt to fill the lacunae in our knowledge on investor protection patterns. While Li (2009)

examined the issue of how foreign direct investment expropriation varies with democracy level

and political constraints, we scrutinize the situation from the vantage point of stock market

investors. We show that the extent to which investors are legally protected is predictive of

future returns and explains the higher rewards during periods of democratic government rule.

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. The next section reviews the body of

literature studying whether the democratization process and democratic institutions affect

financial markets and economic prosperity. Subsequently, we proceed to discuss our data

sources and basic summary statistics. Section IV contains the main body of our empirical

analysis and reports estimates of regressions linking stock index returns to the level of

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


democracy. Section V reflects on whether the relationship we uncovered is driven by risk

considerations, or by the strength of investor protection. A battery of robustness checks is

subsequently presented in Section VI. The paper ends with a set of conclusions and

recommendations for investors.

II. Theorizing on Democracy, Economy and Stock Markets

With the practice of democratization beginning in the early 19th century, political scientists

and economists have gradually defined the exact meaning of democracy. Schumpeter (1942)

characterizes democracy as a political system in which people can elect their national rulers in

regular competitive elections. Dahl (1982) believes that democracy is a representative

government system that runs under legal rules, in which most citizens can participate in politics

and can be effectively represented in political decision-making. Democracy, as understood by

Tavares and Wacziarg (2001), adds many poor voices to the voice of the rich few, changing

the composition of citizenry that influences the shaping of policy. Finally, Rivera-Batiz (2002)

portrays democracy as a system embracing a wide range of characteristics, such as checks and

balances mechanisms of administrative power, constitutional process and protection, free and

uncensored media, clear and effective legislature and judiciary, limited terms of office, as well

as transparency, openness, and democratic participation. Contemporary definitions of

democracy invariably incorporate elements of universal suffrage, guaranteed political rights

and freedoms, and a government policy-making process that is both inclusive and subject to

supervision. It is important to note that underpinning political systems, be they autocratic or

democratic, are a set of institutions defined by North (1981) as the sum of a country’s formal

and informal rules and the implementation characteristics of these rules.

Although we know little about how political regimes affect financial markets, voluminous

literature has been produced in the field of economics, political science, and public policy on

the link between political systems and economic growth. Since stock markets and the broader

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


economy are, at least to some degree, intertwined we present a short synopsis of this

scholarship here. Broadly speaking, researchers have failed to reach a consensus on whether

political democratization can speed up economic growth (for a literature review see Sirowy

and Inkeles (1990)). Some empirical studies discovered the existence of a positive relationship

(see, for instance, Clague et al., 1996; Kurzman et al., 2002; Acemoglu et al., 2019), which

was attributed to the fact that democratic regimes have lower barriers to entry for enterprises

(Cuberes and Jerzmanowski, 2009) and better protection of property rights, which in turn

fosters investments (Friedman, 1962; Pastor and Sung, 1995). Electoral arrangements under

democratic institutions can also result in more capable leaders being elected (Lohmann, 1999;

Comeau, 2003). One could also argue that an authoritarian regime hinders economic growth

due to internal factionalism, corruption, rent-seeking, ethnic conflict, and other contradictions

(Quinn and Woolley, 2001). These views, however, are not universally shared, with some

scholars claiming that it is democracy that hampers economic growth (see, for instance,

Landau, 1986; Tavares and Wacziarg, 2001; Wood, 2007). Acemoglu et al. (2008) robustly

estimated the relationship between income and democracy in 136 countries over the past 500

years, but their results show no significant causal relationship between them. They argue that

an increased income will not necessarily promote democracy and democracy is not a necessary

condition for income. Doucouliagos and Ulubaşoğlu (2008) produced a detailed comparative

study of 84 empirical papers examining the relationship between democracy and growth by

using meta-analysis and concluded that half of the empirical studies did not find a direct

significant relationship between democracy and economic growth.

There is also a great deal of theoretical and empirical exploration that focused on the

relationship between political regimes and foreign direct investment (FDI) flows. Here again,

consensus proves to be elusive. For example, Olson (1993), Henisz (2000) and Jensen (2003,

2006) state that through improving the protection of property rights and reducing the political

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


risk of cross-border investment, political liberalization makes host countries more attractive to

foreign capital. Putman (1998) and Oneal (1994) hold the opposite view; they believe that

democratization has a negative impact on FDI, because corporations that cooperate with

authoritarian regimes can gain certain privileges and democratization leads to the loss of these

privileges. With the theoretical disputes in the discussion unresolved, empirical studies are also

plagued by conflicting results. In a study of U.S. manufacturing investment inflows, Rodrik

(1996) found that democracy is positively related to FDI - a finding that was later confirmed

by Jensen (2003) in a sample of 144 countries. At the other end of the spectrum, Resnick’s

(2001) results suggest that democratic transition is inversely related to FDI inflows. Busse

(2004) argued that FDI inflows in the 1970s and 1980s were mainly concentrated in

dictatorship countries whereas, from the 1990s, democratic countries attracted more industrial

capital inflows. The work of Asiedu and Lien (2011) adds further nuance to the analysis by

highlighting the fact that the impact of democracy on promoting FDI is largely dependent on

whether the country is an exporter of oil and minerals.

With regard to our article, the focus is on the rewards reaped by stock market investors in

countries characterized by different shades of democracy. The only previous paper that has

considered this issue directly is Lehkonen and Heimonen (2015), who report that stock market

performance is boosted by the presence of democratic processes and institutions. We are not

only able to confirm this finding in a larger sample of countries, but also demonstrate a much

stronger degree of statistical significance. In addition, we analyze whether the return

differential is attributable to various types of risks. As the Capital Asset Pricing Model (Sharpe,

1964; Lintner, 1965 and Mossin, 1966) reminds us, investors should be compensated only for

taking on non-diversifiable risk. From the perspective of a global investor, much of the country-

specific risk will diffuse in an internationally held portfolio and the premium should be only

earnable for the covariation of the local stock market index with the global market portfolio.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


We dissect the national volatility risk into country-specific and global components and consider

them in the context of democratization.

Another element of the puzzle, which should not be overlooked, is the propensity of the state

to expropriate investors. Engagement in outright expropriation of firm assets, over-regulation,

confiscatory taxation, and solicitation of bribes could seriously undermine the chances of re-

election for politicians wielding power in democratic nations. Autocrats, on the other hand, are

largely immune from such considerations and, consequently, their incentives to expropriate are

stronger.

When rulers of states try to enrich themselves at the expense of shareholders, a number of

inimical outcomes typically follow. These outcomes are clearly outlined in the “twin agency

problem” proposed by Stulz (2005). First, corporate managers will become motivated to

engage in earnings manipulation and diversion. Earnings that have been either concealed,

misappropriated, or stolen by corporate insiders become inaccessible to the grabbing hands of

the state. Such toxic constellation become known as the “twin agency problem”, because

outside investors are subjected to predation from both corporate insiders and political leaders.

Second, the quality of disclosure suffers due to the fact that profitable firms reporting their

financial results faithfully are at a higher risk of being expropriated by the state. The optimal

reaction would be to reduce the level of transparency and governance which, in turn,

exacerbates the detrimental effect that state expropriation has on shareholder value (Durnev

and Fauver, 2011). Similarly, politicians will be opposed to promulgating and enforcing more

robust disclosure rules, as application of these rules will shed more light on their predacious

ways (Bushman et al., 2004). Third, corporate ownership in countries with state expropriation

will be more concentrated. Controlling shareholders assume the functions of managers and, in

doing so, they are able to appropriate private benefits for themselves instead of surrendering

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


them to an agent-manager. Stulz (2005) documents that dispersed ownership is inefficient in

the presence of predatory state and managerial diversion of profits.

This last observation is the focal point of a theoretical model derived by Giannetti and Koskinen

(2010) who explicitly recognize the fact that, in weak investor protection countries, investors

have additional incentives to becoming controlling shareholders. Control gives them access to

both private and security benefits arising from ownership. Consequently, affluent investors

demand more stocks and are prepared to pay more for them compared to minority investors

form whom the private benefits of control are inaccessible. The demand from controlling

shareholders drives the stock prices to high levels and, in equilibrium, the expected returns to

outside investors are diminished.

Our empirical evidence seems to cohere with the logic of arguments outlined above. We report

that autocrats, unrestrained by democratic processes and motivated by their desire to arrogate

private wealth, are unlikely to enact strong investor protection laws. We also demonstrate that

the level of investor protection is predictive of future returns and that investor protection alone

is capable of explaining the returns gap between autocratic and democratic states.

III. Data

Variables measuring stock index returns and the degree of democracy are of utmost importance

to our investigation. With regards to the former, we calculate continuously compounded dollar-

denominated returns that are inclusive of dividend payments. These returns are based on market

capitalization weighted country-level Morgan Stanley Capital International (MSCI) indexes,

which are among the most respected and widely used benchmarks in the global financial

industry. Due to the short stock market history in some countries, the dataset in this study is an

unbalanced panel.

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Our data on MSCI indices has been sourced from Thomson Reuters DataStream and covers 74

countries over the period from 1975 to 2015. Of all the markets, MSCI classed 22 as developed

(e.g., United States, United Kingdom), 23 as emerging (e.g., Brazil, China), 19 as frontier

(Bahrain, Pakistan), and 10 as standalone (e.g., Ghana, Trinidad and Tobago). A complete list

of countries and their classification is presented in Appendix A. Collectively, our sample

markets represent almost all the investable opportunity sets in the world.

Our primary democracy measure is sourced from Polity IV Project database. This source first

derives a democracy indicator measured on an eleven-point scale ranging from 0 to 10. Its

design involves gauging the ability of citizens to express their political preferences, the extent

to which civil liberties are guaranteed, and the existence of constraints on the power of

executive. Similarly, an autocracy variable, measured on eleven-point scale is constructed by

focusing on competitiveness and regulation of political participation, procedures for executive

recruitment, and the constraints imposed upon them. In the final step, a POLITY variable is

derived by deducting the autocracy score from the democracy score. We modify this POLITY

variable to reduce its skewness by firstly adding 11 to every observation in order to ensure that

all observations are positive and then applying a natural logarithm transformation. In the

regressions that follow, the resultant variable is labelled DEMOCRACY.

In our “Further Results and Robustness Checks” section, we also consider an alternative

democracy measure obtained from Freedom House - an organization that publishes annual

reports on the democracy and human rights situation in 192 countries and 14 disputed religions

in the world.2 More specifically, we use the political rights variable, which is measured on an

ordinal seven-point scale. The definition of political rights from Freedom House is that people

can freely participate in the political process by having the right to select a particular candidate

2 For more details, please refer to the Freedom House website: https://freedomhouse.org/.

10

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


in a legitimate election, to participate in political parties or organizations, and to elect a

representative who has a decisive influence on public policy-making and who is responsible

for the electorate. Since political rights in this database are measured on an inverted scale, our

variable which is taken to represent the natural log of the original Freedom House indicator is

called LACK_OF_POLITICAL_RIGHTS. Predictably, this variable is strongly and negatively

correlated with DEMOCRACY ( = -0.7248, p-value = 0.0000).

To control for the impact of economic environment on stock returns, macroeconomic indicators

were incorporated in the regressions that follow. The macroeconomic data was collected

primarily from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (WDI) database. The first

macroeconomic indicator included is labeled GDP_GROWTH and measures the annual

percentage growth rate of the gross domestic product at market prices based on constant local

currency. A significant number of studies have tested the association between financial market

performance and economic growth (see, for example, Honohan, 2004; Demetriades and

Andrianova, 2004). The second variable denoted as INFLATION reflects the annual percentage

change in the consumer price index (CPI). Hyperinflation signals mismanagement of monetary

policy and could be a good proxy for general macroeconomic policy instability. Rising prices

have also been shown to negatively impact financial sector performance in some studies (Boyd

et al., 2001). An interest rate variable is also introduced to capture the variation in the risk-free

component of discount rates, and it is expressed in real terms. This is warranted given that

nominal interest rate would be highly collinear with inflation. We also control for the economic

development of a country by incorporating data on the natural logarithm of GDP per capita.

Financial openness (de jure/de facto) is measured by the lack of restrictions on cross-border

financial flows, as quantified by the Chinn-Ito Index3. The variable corresponding to this index

has been labelled in this paper as KAOPEN. Lastly, and perhaps most importantly, our return

3 For more details, please refer to http://web.pdx.edu/~ito/Chinn-Ito_website.htm.

11

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


regressions examine how the movements of the local markets covary with the global trends.

This is done by using return on the MSCI World index as an explanatory variable. MSCI World

index captures the market value of large and medium capitalization stocks across 23 developed

markets.

Several variables have also been considered in order to assess the impact of the political and

institutional environment. The source of political and institutional data is the Database of

Political Institutions (DPI) (Cruz, et al., 2015). This database is mainly used to measure a

country's political system and election rules. It contains information regarding the electoral

system, identification of the ruling party’s affiliation and ideology, the legislative system, and

the checks and balances mechanisms, among others. Researchers at the World Bank

Development Research Group compiled the database for the first time in 2001 (Beck et al.,

2001). The current 2015 version is hosted by the Inter-American Development Bank (IDB) and

has expanded its coverage to about 180 countries observed over 40 years (1975-2015).

A number of variables sourced from the DPI dataset are employed in our empirical

investigation. Since differing political ideologies of the government might exert influence on

the stock market movements (see, for instance, Hensel and Ziemba, 1995; Santa-Clara and

Valkanov, 2003; Cahan et al., 2005), we quantify this effect by constructing RIGHT_WING

and LEFT_WING dummy variables representing the ruling party’s orientation with respect to

economic policy. A centrist orientation serves here as a benchmark. The variable RELIGION is

a binary indicator taking a value of one if the ruling party has an ideology rooted in religion

(Christian, Catholic, Islamic, Hindu, Buddhist and Jewish) and zero otherwise. In view of the

fact that several researchers have noted differential market behavior around national elections

(see, for instance, Gartner and Wellershoff, 1995; Wong and McAleer, 2009), a dummy

recording whether an executive election took place in a particular country-year is included

(ELECTION_EXE). Similarly, the ELECTION_LEG indicator takes a value of unity whenever

12

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


legislative elections occur. A summary of all the aforementioned variables can be found in

Table I.

[Insert Table I about here]

Table II presents descriptive statistics and allows us to gain more intuition about the properties

of the underlying data. In addition to reporting a conventional mean, the table also shows an

“adjusted mean” which first calculates the average for each country and then computes a mean

of these averages. Such an approach allows a decrease in the dominance of developed

economies with long time series. The average dollar-denominated total return on the MSCI

country indexes is 7.38% per annum, which is reasonably close to the average MSCI World

return of 8.55%. This result prevails despite the fact that the first average is taken over 74

markets, while the other considers only 23. Examination of the antilogged means for

DEMOCRACY and LACK_OF_POLITICAL_RIGHTS reveals that the political systems in most

of our sample countries were relatively democratic. As can also be seen from Table II, the

average growth rate of GDP is 3.31% per year, while the mean of 15.58% for annual inflation

was influenced by several hyperinflationary episodes. After accounting for inflation, the

average real interest rate stands at 5.68%. The level of economic affluence varied markedly.

By applying an exponential transformation to the LNGDPPC statistics, we can see that the 75th

percentile of the distribution was 5.49 times higher than the 25th percentile. With regard to

political factors, leftist and rightist administrations spent about 30.17% and 33.18% of the time

in power, respectively, with the rest falling under the reign of centrist governments. The mean

of the variable measuring government religious inclinations has a very low average value

(0.1204), implying that most governments do not associate themselves with any particular

religion. Finally, legislative elections appear to be more frequent than executive ones.

[Insert Table II about here]

13

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table III reports unconditional correlation coefficients among the core variables used in the

empirical investigation. The stock index returns correlate positively with DEMOCRACY ( =

0.0666, p-value = 0.0058) and negatively with LACK_OF_POLITICAL_RIGHTS ( = -0.0650,

p-value = 0.0071). This is a preliminary indication of a positive relationship between the level

of democratization and stock price movements. It can also be seen that economic prosperity, as

measured by the GDP growth, coincides with increasing value of equity. Furthermore, the

national markets tend to move in tandem with the MSCI world stock market index. The

remaining explanatory variables do not appear to be strongly associated with stock returns.

Generally speaking, the correlations between explanatory variables are not high, suggesting

that our regressions are unlikely to suffer from multicollinearity problems. Indeed, we find that

the variance inflation factors for our regressors in all of the considered model specifications

are lower than 10, attesting to the fact that multicollinearity is not present.

[Insert Table III about here]

IV. Empirical analysis

4.1 Modelling Stock Returns

A battery of specification tests has informed the design of the econometric models used to

explicate the variation in returns. Tests consistently indicate that country fixed effects in return

regressions are jointly insignificant and that their inclusion can only lead to less efficient

estimation. The Baltagi and Li (1990) version of the Lagrange Multiplier (LM) test (Breusch

and Pagan, 1980), which has been specifically developed for unbalanced panels, suggests that

the use of cross-sectional random effects is not advisable and that the random effect estimator

degenerates to the pooled estimator. Year fixed effects, on the other hand, prove to be

indispensable. The rationale behind this statistical finding it is that stock markets movements

tend to co-vary across nations and year dummies allow the global trend component to be
14

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


captured. Their inclusion in the model therefore helps to isolate the country-specific variation

in stock returns. We note in passing that the Hausman (1978) specification test suggests that

period random effects are not suitable in this context because residuals from the random effect

model are correlated with the regressors.

Specifications (1) and (2) in Table III present estimation results for models with time fixed

effects. As the reader will notice, these specifications do not incorporate World_Return as a

regressor. As both year dummies and World_Return do not change in the cross-sectional

dimension, their joint inclusion inevitably leads to a problem of perfect multicollinearity. To

overcome this predicament, time fixed effects are removed from specification (3) and return

on the MSCI World index is employed instead. This is equivalent to capturing the global trends

in an alternative way. A further complication arises, however, as the panel cross-section

heteroskedasticity likelihood-ratio tests strongly reject the null hypothesis that residuals are

homoskedastic. This could be a direct consequence of variation in investment risk profiles or

differing macroeconomic data quality across countries. To remedy this problem, we employ a

feasible GLS estimation with cross-section weights. This estimation method is also adopted in

specification (5) where the DEMOCRACY variable enters at a lag. Furthermore, column (4)

presents estimations of dynamic panels using the system generalized method of moments

(GMM) technique introduced by Arellano and Bond (1991) and further developed by Arellano

and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998). This class of models is capable of providing

consistent results, even in cases in which different sources of endogeneity are present (Wintoki

et al., 2012; Ullah et al., 2018).

[Insert Table IV about here]

The most striking observation arising from Table IV is the consistent evidence of a positive and

statistically significant relationship between stock returns and democracy level. It is worth

noting that this relationship remains stable in all specifications regardless of the econometric

15

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


approach adopted. While the importance of this regressor in undeniable from a statistical point

of view, one should also consider the economic significance of the estimates. For example, the

slope of 0.0706 on the DEMOCRACY variable in column (3) suggests that for a one percentage

point increase in the transformed POLITY IV index, the stock return of the MSCI index is

expected to go up ceteris paribus by 0.0706 percentage points. In other words, moving from

perfect democracy to a perfect autocracy (a fall of 100% in our DEMOCRACY measure)

depresses stock index returns by 7.06% per annum, all other things being equal. We will explore

the possible rationalizations underlying this returns gap in Section V of the paper. Strikingly,

column (5) suggests that democracy level has predictive power for stock market fluctuations,

which entails a number of important ramifications. Firstly, it raises questions about market

efficiency, an issue we explore in the next sub-section. Secondly, it suggests that the

relationship goes beyond a simple association and can possibly be construed as causality in the

Granger (1969) sense.

The regression results regarding the impactful control variables also merit further discussion.

Firstly, GDP growth rates show a consistent and significant positive relationship with stock

returns in all of the regressions. For example, the estimates reported in column (3) reveal that

whenever GDP growth increases by one percentage point, the stock return goes up by 0.6432

percentage points. This conclusion is in line with theoretical expectations and is also supported

by many previous studies (see, for instance, Asprem, 1989; Flannery and Protopapadakis, 2002;

Humpe and Macmillan, 2009).

When pondering inflation, one could expect a positive relationship with returns, as companies

own real assets that can act as inflationary hedges. On the other hand, when inflation reaches a

certain level, the government and central bank will tend to tighten fiscal and monetary policies,

affecting expectations regarding future corporate profitability and interest rates. Unsurprisingly,

scholarly literature has not reached a consensus on this issue. For example, Fama’s (1981)

16

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


proxy hypothesis suggests a negative link between stock returns and inflation, but this link

should not be considered a direct causal relationship, as it exerts itself through other

macroeconomic factors. Therefore, in order to obtain a more nuanced understanding of the

effects of inflation, we introduce nonlinearities into the regression equation by incorporating

both the untransformed and the squared inflation rate. While the signs of coefficients on

INFLATION and INFLATION2 terms are consistent across different specifications, their

statistical significance is not. This may reflect the fact that the impact of inflation on stock

prices is relatively complex (Flannery and Protopapadakis, 2002).

Although Santa-Clara and Valkanov (2003) show that US stock returns tended to be higher

under Democratic presidencies in the US, one wonders whether this result should be

generalized into the global context. Even if the returns under leftist executives appear to be

somewhat higher, the statistical significance of this finding could be questioned. An earlier

study by Bohl and Gottschalk (2006), which also aggregated cross-country evidence, casts

additional doubts on the importance of the left-wing premium in an international context.

A rule of government that follows a religious ideology seems to be conducive to generating a

bull market. Although this finding has not been hitherto reported in the literature, a number of

studies have made the point that religious practices can impact on the behavior of investors and

companies alike. Ariel (1990) shows that prior to holidays such as Good Friday or Christmas

mean returns are significantly higher, while Bialkowski et al. (2012) and Al-Khazali (2014)

establish that stock markets in predominantly Islamic countries tend to be more buoyant during

the period of Ramadan. Furthermore, the analysis performed by Callen and Fang (2015) sheds

light on the fact that firms headquartered in counties with higher level of religiosity are less

prone to stock price crash risk and, relatedly, are also characterized by lower variances of equity

returns (Hilary and Hui, 2009).

17

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


The variable that holds the strongest explanatory power for local stock market fluctuations is

the WORLD_RETURN, which attests to the importance of common shocks simultaneously

reverberating across all countries.

4.2. Trading Strategy

The last column in Table IV indicates that democratization of a country can be predictive of

future stock returns. We operationalize this insight practically, by designing an implementable

trading strategy. More specifically, we execute a portfolio approach using our DEMOCRACY

indicator. To that end, we produce annual rankings of countries based on their democracy level.

At each year end we select countries that record a DEMOCRACY value higher or equal to the

90th percentile of that year’s distribution and construct an equally weighted portfolio invested

in indexes of these countries. This “High Democracy Portfolio” is kept throughout the duration

of the subsequent year and is rebalanced anew at the year end. In a similar vein, we construct

a “Low Democracy Portfolio” by focusing on nations that have DEMOCRACY values lower or

equal to the 10th percentile of the distribution.

We assume an investment of one US dollar into each of the portfolios initially and plot the

evolution of portfolio values in Figure I. At the end of the sample period, the capital invested

in a “High Democracy Portfolio” grew to $4.93, representing an annualized dollar-

denominated continuously compounded return of 9.83%. At the other extreme, the “Low

Democracy Portfolio” earned an annual return of only 5.29%, bringing the terminal investment

value to $3.11. The gap in returns of 4.54% is both economically and statistically significant

(p-value = 0.0956). In absence of any transaction costs or other market frictions, a return

equivalent to the gap could be earned by embarking on a long-short strategy. Considering that

portfolio rebalancing is done annually, our profit estimate is likely to surpass any reasonable

transaction costs, especially in cases in which index futures contracts are used to carry out the

18

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


trading. Traders need to bear in mind that while such long-short strategy may be zero-cost, it

is certainly not zero-risk, as the standard deviation of the returns gap amounts to 16.85% per

annum. Taken together, these results illustrate the practical implications of our research and

confirm some degree of return predictability.

[Insert Figure I about here]

V. Possible Rationalizations

5.1. Can the findings be attributed to risk differential?

We undertake further exploration to uncover the underlying rationale behind the link between

returns and democracy. Perhaps the difference in stock returns across political regimes might

be easily explained by the level of prevailing risk. However, as postulated by the Capital Asset

Pricing Model (CAPM), only non-diversifiable risk should carry compensation to investors. A

version of this model with non-stochastic risk-free rate can be written down as:

𝐸(𝑅̃ 𝐹 ̃𝑀
𝑖,𝑡+1 ) = (1 − 𝛽𝑖 )𝑅 + 𝛽𝑖 𝐸(𝑅𝑡+1 ) [1]

where 𝐸(𝑅̃
𝑖,𝑡+1 ) is the expected return on the national stock market index, 𝛽𝑖 is the global beta

̃
of the domestic market i, 𝑅 𝐹 is a risk-free rate, while 𝐸(𝑅 𝑀
𝑡+1 ) is the expected return on the

world stock market index. The tilde () placed above a term indicates a random variable. A

regression analogue of equation [1] can be expressed as follows:

𝑅̃ ̃𝑀
𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼𝑖 + 𝛽𝑖 𝑅𝑡 + 𝜀̃
𝑖,𝑡 [2]

where 𝛼𝑖 is the intercept for country i and 𝜀̃


𝑖,𝑡 is the error term that captures country-specific

developments unrelated to movements of the global stock market index. The global index in

our case is proxied by MSCI World. Given that 𝑐𝑜𝑣(𝑅̃


𝑀
𝑡 , 𝜀̃
𝑖,𝑡 ) = 0, the following result for the

total variance can be obtained:

19

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


𝑣𝑎𝑟(𝑅̃ 2 ̃𝑀
𝑖,𝑡 ) = 𝛽𝑖 𝑣𝑎𝑟(𝑅𝑡 ) + 𝑣𝑎𝑟(𝜀̃
𝑖,𝑡 ) [3]

Equation [3] implies that total variance of national index returns can be decomposed into a part

related to co-variation with the global stock market index and a part that arises from country-

specific risk. In our inquiry, we undertake the task of such variance decomposition. More

specifically, in each country-year we run a regression equivalent to equation [2] using monthly

data. The estimates are then inserted into equation [3] in order to dissect the total variance.

Subsequently, the estimate of total variance and its two components are multiplied by 12 to

annualize them and a square root transformation is applied to derive the TOTAL_VOLATILITY,

COUNTRY_SPECIFIC_VOLATILITY, and GLOBAL_SYSTEMATIC_VOLATILITY variables.

In our sample, DEMOCRACY is negatively correlated with TOTAL_VOLATILITY ( = -0.0591,

p-value = 0.0145) and COUNTRY_SPECIFIC_VOLATILITY ( = -0.1436, p-value = 0.0000),

while the correlation with GLOBAL_SYSTEMATIC_VOLATILITY is positive ( = 0.0918, p-

value = 0.0001). To probe this issue further, we estimate a number of regression models

considering the determinants of each volatility type. Since financial series exhibit a

phenomenon of volatility clustering (Engle, 1982; Bollerslev, 1986), dynamic panel data

models are used, where lagged volatility acts as a regressor. The system GMM approach is

utilized for the purposes of estimation and the findings are reported in Table V.

[Insert Table V about here]

Different variants of regressions are considered in Table V. The evidence seems to largely

corroborate the claim that stock markets located in autocratic countries exhibit higher country-

specific volatility of returns. Although the risk arising from co-variation with global trends is

lower, the statistical significance of this finding is questionable. On balance, the total volatility

of returns appears somewhat elevated in absence of democratic institutions. Taken together,

the results unveil divergent risk characteristics across the democratic continuum. The issue of

20

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


whether the disparities in risk profiles can account for the return differential between autocratic

and democratic regimes will be revisited and pondered in greater depth in section 5.3.

5.2. Investor protection

Autocrats may have incentives to confiscate assets, repudiate their debts, and renege on

inconvenient contracts, given that in the short term such actions produce an immediate windfall

far surpassing any potential tax revenues that may have been forgone (Olson, 1993). Mature

democracies, on the other hand, constrain their leaders through a system of checks and

balances, limiting predatory behavior by the state. An independent judiciary, that is the

cornerstone of a well-functioning democracy, safeguards enforcement of contracts and protects

the rights of individuals and investors. These considerations are mirrored in the findings of Li

(2009) who shows that autocracies are more likely to expropriate foreign direct investments.

The lack of political constraints on autocrats seems, to a large extent, account for this result. In

a game-theoretic setting, Guriev and Sonin (2009) further demonstrate that, in oligarchic

economies, autocrats cannot credibly commit to both property right protection and no

expropriation. These extant findings lead us to believe that autarchic leaders may be reluctant

to introduce legal frameworks that shelter capital holders from the vagaries of the state.

To formally test this conjecture, we download data on the strength of investor protection index

from the World Economic Forum Global Competitiveness Index data set maintained by the

World Bank. Higher values of the index represent more robust protection of investors’ rights.

Our preliminary analysis shows this investor protection measure is positively correlated with

DEMOCRACY ( = 0.1969, p-value = 0.0000). While this preliminary finding may be

instructive, more rigorous panel data modeling techniques need to be employed to control for

possible confounding factors.

21

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Our tests indicate that both country and time effects are jointly significant in the investor

protection models. The importance of country effects coheres with the findings of previous

research showing that time invariant characteristics, such as legal origin, affect protection of

corporate shareholders (La Porta et al., 1998). Guided by the aforementioned specification test,

we estimate two-way fixed effect models, which are displayed in Table VI. The most striking

finding that arises from our estimations is that democracy fosters investor protection.

Autocrats, on the other hand, appear disinclined to formalize their commitment to private

property. Since they are the ultimate source of power within society and the impartiality of

courts under their rule can be questioned, the temptation to coercively exploit investors is ever-

present. Given that this is the case, an amalgamation of the “twin agency problem” (Stulz,

2005) and the theoretical model of Giannetti and Koskinen (2010) could successfully explicate

the positive relationship between returns and democracy levels reported in this paper.

[Insert Table VI about here]

5.3. Which of the rationalizations is most credible?

An important question that arises at this stage is which of the mechanisms considered above

can fully account for the democracy-autocracy return differential. A variable can be classified

as a valid underlying mechanism for the observed phenomenon only if the following three

conditions are met. Firstly, the variable should be related to the level of democratization. In

effect, this has already been demonstrated to a certain degree for the different volatility types

and investor protection. Secondly, the mechanism variable should be able to predict returns.

Thirdly, once the variable is controlled for in our return regressions, the explanatory power of

the DEMOCRACY measure should diminish, causing it to lose its statistical significance. To

verify whether the last two conditions hold, we estimate a set of models of the following form:

22

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


𝑅𝐸𝑇𝑈𝑅𝑁𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛾1 𝐷𝐸𝑀𝑂𝐶𝑅𝐴𝐶𝑌𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛾2 𝑉𝐴𝑅𝐼𝐴𝐵𝐿𝐸_𝑀𝐸𝐶𝐻𝐴𝑁𝐼𝑆𝑀𝑖,𝑡−1 +

∑𝑘𝑛=1 𝛾𝑛+2 𝐶𝑂𝑁𝑇𝑅𝑂𝐿𝑛𝑖,𝑡 + 𝑖,𝑡 [4]

The second and third requirement of our testing protocol necessitates that DEMOCRACY

becomes insignificant, while the VARIABLE_MECHANISM exhibits robust predictive power.

The four variables scrutinized in the previous two sections are taken individually to act as

VARIABLE_MECHANISM. We examine regressions that include a full set of control variables

(labelled as CONTROL in equation [4]) and report our findings in Table VII.

[Insert Table VII about here]

Interestingly, Table VII unveils a clear failure of the CAPM model, as we cannot reject the null

hypothesis that the level of systematic risk is unrelated to returns. In fact, none of the examined

volatility variables is significant or able to markedly diminish the explanatory power of the

democracy level, which rules them out as credible justifications for the democracy-autocracy

returns gap. The only rationalization that stands up to rigorous scrutiny relates to the level of

investor protection. As has been established earlier, democracies are more inclined to limit

state expropriation by protecting investors’ rights. According to the model of Giannetti and

Koskinen (2010), this raises expected stock returns to outsiders, a fact that is corroborated by

our empirical results. Furthermore, once we account for the degree to which investors are

legally shielded, the level of democratization loses its meaningfulness as a determinant of

returns. In other words, the investor protection story is the only one that meets all three criteria

of our verification procedure and can thus be viewed as a credible justification for the results

presented in this paper.

VI. Robustness Checks and Further Results

To check the robustness of our findings we perform a myriad of additional tests. Firstly, it also

needs to be stated that democracy is a complex political and social concept, which may be

23

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


difficult to quantify with a great degree of precision. Criticisms of commonly used democracy

measures have emerged (see, for instance, Munck and Verkuilen, 2002) and none of the specific

measurements can be considered perfect. Therefore, in order to make our study more

comprehensive and robust, we introduce an alternative variable capturing the absence of

democracy. It is the LACK_OF_POLITICAL_RIGHTS index described previously in our data

section, which has been sourced from the Freedom House. We replicate our return model

estimations replacing the variable sourced from the Polity IV database with the Freedom House

counterpart. Results tabulated in column (1) of Table VIII reveal a strong negative association

between the rewards reaped by outside investors and the repression of political freedom, which

supports the validity of the conclusions reached in our paper.

[Insert Table VIII about here]

Secondly, our sample includes several economies that have experienced episodes of significant

inflationary pressures. High nominal interest rate associated with an inflationary environment

could affect the expected and realized gross stock market returns. Although our baseline

specification controlled for the rate of inflation and real interest rate, we probe into this issue

further by selecting excess returns as our dependent variable. At the same time, we drop

INFLATION, INFLATION2, and REAL_INTEREST_RATE from the list of explanatory factors.

The results are shown in column (2) of Table VIII and are almost identical to those displayed

in column (3) of Table IV.

Thirdly, when dealing with the return regressions, we introduce a nonparametric covariance

matrix estimator, proposed by Discoll and Kraay (1998). This method further controls for the

effects of cross-sectional dependence on the basis of the Newey and West (1987) serial

correlation robust estimator.4 The advantage of obtaining robust standard errors derived from

4 Arellano (2003, 19) provides a more detailed discussion of this estimation method.

24

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


this approach is that the variance-covariance matrix estimators do not depend on the number

of cross-sectional units. Specifically, Discoll and Kraay (1998) average the moments of all the

cross-sectional units in the same time period, so that the heteroskedasticity and serial

correlation robust Newey and West (1987) variance estimator based on time series can be

applied to panel data. Hoechle (2007) extends this approach and makes it applicable to

unbalanced panels. The results based on this methodology are shown in column (3) of Table

VIII and reveal that the influence of the DEMOCRACY variable remains significant at the 1%

level.

Furthermore, to verify whether the relationship is stable over time, we split our data period into

two subperiods. Year 2003 constitutes the partition point, which splits the sample into two

roughly equal subsamples (582 vs 543 country-years). We estimate models in both subperiods

and report our findings in columns (4) and (5) of Table VIII. Reassuringly, the relationship

between democracy level and stock returns appears to be statistically significant in both

subperiods, substantiating the permanence of the phenomenon being described.

In light of our empirical results, it may be instructive to further explore the risk-return trade-

off conditional on the level of democratization. To this end, we split all sample countries into

three groups based on the Polity IV score. These groupings are defined as autocracies (-10 to -

6), anocracies (-5 to +5), and democracies (+6 to +10). Sharpe ratios are calculated for each of

our country-years and an average is subsequently taken within each group. Figure II depicts

our findings and shows that the average Sharpe ratio tends to increase with democracy level.

The differences between the three groups are statistically significant (F-statistic = 3.15. p-value

= 0.0422).

[Insert Figure II about here]

25

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


We also analyze whether interactions of political control variables with democracy levels can

explicate the behavior of stock markets. Our analysis employs five political indicators for a

left-wing and a right-wing party in power, a government following a religious ideology, as well

as dummies capturing the occurrence of executive and legislative elections. Of all the

interactions considered, only the term DEMOCRACY×LEFT_WING proved to be statistically

significant and exerted a positive impact on returns (see Table IX). One interpretation that

could be offered for this finding is that leftist autocrats, prompted by their ideological

inclinations, are more likely to expropriate investors’ wealth through nationalization.

Introduction of a democratic process, with all of its checks and balances, puts breaks on these

radical left-leaning impulses. And, as the theories outlined in the paper assert, a reduction in

investor expropriation increases stock returns.

[Insert Table IX about here]

We further introduce an interaction term between INFLATION and DEMOCRACY into

regression (6) of Table IX. This term bears a positive coefficient and is statistically significant.

The implication is that, in an inflationary environment, stock markets in democratic countries

perform ceteris paribus better than those in autocracies. One possible rationalization could be

that autocratic leaders may seek to finance their unmanageable fiscal deficits both through the

issuance of paper money and the nationalization of investors’ assets. In such circumstances,

the heightened risk of expropriation and elevated inflation rates coincide, profoundly

undermining the efficacy of using corporate property as an inflationary hedge.

Column (7) in Table IX considers interaction between LNGDPPC and democracy levels.

According to the estimates, high level of GDP per capita attenuates the negative influence of

autarchy on stock market returns. In some very rich but undemocratic countries (such as those

in the oil-rich Middle East), the increase in national wealth may have inflated overall stock

market pricing. Furthermore, autocratic leaders in affluent nations may not need to resort to

26

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


arrogation of investors’ wealth. Other, less objectionable, sources of finding may be at their

disposal.

Last but not least, we reflect on whether the democracy indicator is an exogenous variable, or

whether the capital market performance can affect the process of democratization. We use an

instrumental variable strategy and, inspired by Neumayer (2008), use abolition of death penalty

as an instrument for DEMOCRACY. The underidentification, weak identification, and

overidentification tests show that the instrumental variable is valid. Based on this

instrumentation exercise, Durbin-Wu-Hausman test and a C statistic (Hayashi, 2000) were

calculated. No clear evidence for the existence of endogeneity emerged, indicating that our

estimates are consistent. A complete description of the endogeneity testing process is provided

in Appendix B.

VII. Conclusions

This paper examines whether there is a link between democratic rule and stock returns in an

international sample of 74 countries spanning over four decades. One could argue that better

political institutions create investor friendly environments with secured property rights and

lower risks of expropriation by the government. Consequently, one might expect a positive

association between the level of democratization and stock returns on a priori grounds. Using

a range of methodological approaches, we present strong empirical evidence in favor of this

association. We document that dollar-denominated stock returns tend to be appreciably higher

in democratic states. However, attempts to explain away the association by observed return

volatility or insights offered by the CAPM prove futile. Instead, one factor that was able to

expound this constellation of results is the strength of investor protection. We document that

autocrats, who have historically shown a greater tendency to expropriate, are reluctant to

protect the rights of capital holders. This appears to be mirrored in the distribution of returns.

27

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


These findings have important implications for international stock investors. Since stock

investments in more autocratic countries offer lower rewards and are laden with expropriation

risk, investors may want to underweight these countries in their portfolios. This reasoning could

be taken one step forward and a long-short strategy could be operationalized. We propose a

lucrative strategy which combines investments in highly democratic countries with a short

position in the stock indices of autocratic states. Such a strategy is easily implementable, as

data on democratization around the globe is available freely. Needless to say, the notion that

performance of a portfolio could be improved by monitoring such publicly available data runs

contrary to the efficient market hypothesis (Fama, 1970).

References

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J and Thaicharoen, Y. (2003) Institutional causes,
macroeconomic symptoms: volatility, crises and growth, Journal of Monetary Economics,
50(1), 49-123.
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. A. and Yared, P. (2005) From education to democracy?,
American Economic Review, 95(2), 44-49.
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. A. and Yared, P. (2008). Income and democracy.
American Economic Review, 98(3), 808-842.
Acemoglu, D., Naidu, S., Restrepo, P. and Robinson, J.A. (2019). Democracy does cause
growth. Journal of Political Economy, 127(1), 47-100.
Aidt, T. and Jensen, P. (2012) Workers of the World, Unite! Franchise Extensions and the Threat
of Revolution in Europe, 1820-1938, CESifo working paper No. 3417.
Anderson, T.W. (1951) Estimating linear restrictions on regression coefficients for multivariate
normal distributions, Annals of Mathematical Statistics, Vol. 22, 327-351.
Arellano, M. (2003). Panel data econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo
evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies,
58(2), 277-297.
Arellano, M. and Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of
error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29-51.
Al-Khazali, O. (2014). Revisiting fast profit investor sentiment and stock returns during
Ramadan. International Review of Financial Analysis, 33, 158-170.
Ariel, R.A. (1990). High stock returns before holidays: Existence and evidence on possible
causes. Journal of Finance, 45(5), 1611-1626.
Asiedu, E. and Lien, D. (2011). Democracy, foreign direct investment and natural
resources. Journal of International Economics, 84(1), 99-111.

28

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Baltagi, B. H. and Li, Q. (1990). A Lagrange multiplier test for the error components model
with incomplete panels. Econometric Reviews, 9(1), 103-107.
Barro, R. J. (1999) Determinants of democracy, Journal of Political Economy, 107(S6), 158-
183.
Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P. and Walsh, P. (2001). New tools in comparative
political economy: The database of political institutions. The World Bank Economic
Review, 15(1), 165-176.
Białkowski, J., Etebari, A. and Wisniewski, T.P. (2012). Fast profits: Investor sentiment and
stock returns during Ramadan. Journal of Banking & Finance, 36(3), 835-845.
Blundell, R. and Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel
data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-143.
Bohl, M.T. and Gottschalk, K. (2006). International evidence on the Democrat premium and
the presidential cycle effect. The North American Journal of Economics and
Finance, 17(2), 107-120.
Bollerslev, T. (1986). Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. Journal of
Econometrics, 31(3), 307-327.
Boyd, J. H., Levine, R. and Smith, B. D. (2001). The impact of inflation on financial sector
performance. Journal of Monetary Economics, 47(2), 221-248.
Breusch, T. S. and Pagan, A. R. (1980). The lagrange multiplier test and its applications to
model specification in econometrics. The Review of Economic Studies, 47(1), 239-253.
Buera, F. J., Monge-Naranjo, a., Primiceri, G.E. (2011) Learning the Wealth of Nations,
Econometrica, 79 (1), 1-45.
Bushman, R.M., Piotroski, J.D. and Smith, A.J., (2004). What determines corporate
transparency? Journal of Accounting Research, 42(2), 207-252.
Busse, M. (2004). Transnational corporations and repression of political rights and civil
liberties: an empirical analysis. Kyklos: International Review for Social Sciences, 57(1),
45-65.
Callen, J.L. and Fang, X. (2015). Religion and stock price crash risk. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, 50(1/2), 169-195.
Clague, C., Keefer, P., Knack, S. and Olson, M. (1996). Property and contract rights in
autocracies and democracies. Journal of Economic Growth, 1(2), 243-276.
Comeau, L. (2003). Democracy and growth: A relationship revisited. Eastern Economic
Journal, 29(1), 1-21.
Cragg, J.G. and Donald, S.G. (1993) Testing Identfiability and Specification in Instrumental
Variables Models, Econometric Theory, Vol. 9, 222-240.
Cruz, C., Keefer, P. and Scartascini, C. (2015). Database of political institutions codebook,
2015 Update (DPI2015). Inter-American Development Bank. Updated version of T.
Beck, G. Clarke, A. Groff, P. Keefer, and P. Walsh, 165-176.
Cuberes, D. and Jerzmanowski, M. (2009). Democracy, diversification and growth reversals.
The Economic Journal, 119(540), 1270-1302.
Dahl, R. A. (1982). Dilemmas of pluralist democracy: Autonomy vs. control. New Haven: Yale
University Press.

29

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Davidson, R. and MacKinnon, J. (1993). Estimation and Inference in Econometrics, New York:
Oxford University Press.
Demetriades, P. and Andrianova, S. (2004). Finance and growth: what we know and what we
need to know. In Financial development and economic growth: explaining the links, 38-
65, Palgrave Macmillan: Basingstoke and New York.
Diamonte, R.L., Liew, J.M. and Stevens, R.L. (1996). Political risk in emerging and developed
markets. Financial Analysts Journal, 52(3), 71-76.
Discoll, J. C. and Kraay, A. C. (1998). Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially
dependent panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(4), 549-560.
Doucouliagos, H. and Ulubaşoğlu, M. A. (2008). Democracy and economic growth: a meta-
analysis. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 61-83.
Durbin, J. (1954) Errors in Variables, Review of the International Statistical Institute, Vol. 22,
23-32.
Durnev, A. and Fauver, L. (2011). Stealing from thieves: Expropriation risk, firm governance,
and performance. In 2nd Annual Conference on Empirical Legal Studies Paper,
downloadable at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=970969.
Ellis, Christopher J. and John Fender (2011) Information Cascades and Revolutionary Regime
Transitions, The Economic Journal, 121 (553), 763–792.
Engle, R. F. (1982). Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of the
variance of United Kingdom inflation. Econometrica, 50(4), 987-1007.
Erb, C. B., Harvey, C. R. and Viskanta, T. E. (1996). Political risk, economic risk, and financial
risk. Financial Analysts Journal, 52(6), 29-46.
Fama, E.F. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal
of Finance, 25(2), 383-417.
Fama, E. F. (1981). Stock returns, real activity, inflation and money. American Economic
Review, 71(4), 545-565.
Friedman, M. (1962). Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Gartner, M. and Wellershoff, K. W. (1995). Is there an election cycle in American stock returns?.
International Review of Economics & Finance, 4(4), 387-410.
Giannetti, M. and Koskinen, Y. (2010). Investor protection, equity returns, and financial
globalization. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45(1), 135-168.
Granger, C. W. J. (1969). Investigating Casual Relations by Econometric Models and Cross
Spectral Methods. Econometrica, 37(3), 424-438.
Guriev, S. and Sonin, K. (2009). Dictators and oligarchs: A dynamic theory of contested
property rights. Journal of Public Economics, 93(1-2), 1-13.
Hausman, J. A. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica, 46(6), 1251-1271.
Hayashi, F. (2000) Econometrics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Henisz, W. J. (2000). The institutional environment for multinational investment. Journal of
Law, Economics and Organization, 16(2), 334-364.
Hensel, C.R. and Ziemba, W.T. (1995). United States investment returns during Democratic
and Republican administrations, 1928–1993. Financial Analysts Journal, 51(2), 61-69.
Hilary, G. and Hui, K.W. (2009). Does religion matter in corporate decision making in
America?. Journal of Financial Economics, 93(3), 455-473.

30

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Honohan P. (2004). Financial development, growth and poverty: how close are the links?. In:
Goodhart C.A.E. (eds) Financial development and economic growth. British Association
for the Advancement of Science. Palgrave Macmillan, London.
Huber, E., Rueschemeyer, D. and Stephens, J. D. (1993) The impact of economic development
on democracy, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(3), 71-86.
Huntington, Samuel P. (1991) The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century,
Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.
Jensen, N. (2003). Democratic governance and multinational cooperation: political regimes
and inflows of foreign direct investment. International Organization, 57(3), 587-616.
Jensen, N. (2006). Nation-states and the multinational cooperation: political economy of
foreign direct investment. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Kleibergen, F. and Paap, R. (2006) Generalized Reduced Rank Tests Using the Singular Value
Decomposition, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 133, 97-126.
Kurzman, C., Werum, R. and Burkhart, R. E. (2002). Democracy’s effect on economic growth:
a pooled time-series analysis, 1951-1980. Studies in Comparative International
Development (SCID), 37(1), 3-33.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1998). Law and
finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113-1155.
Landau, D. (1986). Government and economic growth in the less developed countries: an
empirical study for 1960-1980. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 35(1), 35-
75.
Lehkonen, H. and Heimonen, K. (2015). Democracy, political risks and stock market
performance. Journal of International Money and Finance, 59, 77-99.
Li, Q. (2009). Democracy, autocracy, and expropriation of foreign direct
investment. Comparative Political Studies, 42(8), 1098-1127.
Lintner, J. (1975). The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock
portfolios and capital budgets. In Stochastic optimization models in finance (pp. 131-155).
Academic Press.
Lipset, S. M. (1959) Some social requisites of democracy: Economic development and political
legitimacy, American Political Science Review, 53(1), 69-105.
Lohmann, S. (1994) Dynamics of Informational Cascades: The Monday Demonstrations in
Leipzig, East Germany, 1989-1991, World Politics, 47(1), 42–101.
Lohmann, S. (1999). What price accountability? The Lucas Island model and the politics of
monetary policy. American Journal of Political Science, 43(2), 396-430.
Mossin, J. (1966). Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica, 43(4), 768-783.
Munck, G. L. and Verkuilen, J. (2002). Conceptualizing and measuring democracy evaluating
alternative indices. Comparative Political Studies, 35(1), 5-34.
Newey, W. K. and West, K. D. (1987). Hypothesis testing with efficient method of moments
estimation. International Economic Review, 28(3), 777-787.
North, D. C. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: Norton.
Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy and development. American Political Science
Review, 87(3), 567-576.

31

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Oneal, J. R. (1994). The affinity of foreign investors for authoritarian regimes. Political
Research Quarterly, 47(3), 565-588.
Pastor, M. and Sung, J. H. (1995). Private investment and democracy in the developing world.
Journal of Economic Issues, 29(1), 223-243.
Perotti, E. C. and Van Oijen, P. (2001). Privatization, political risk and stock market
development in emerging markets. Journal of International Money and Finance, 20(1),
43-69.
Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (2009) Democratic Capital: The Nexus of Political and Economic
Change, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(2), 88–126.
Putman, R. D. (1998). Diplomacy and domestic politics: The logic of two-level games.
International Organization, 42(3), 51-69.
Putnam, R. D., Leonardi, R. and Nanetti, R. Y. (1994) Making democracy work: Civic
traditions in modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Quinn, D. P. and Woolley, J. T. (2001). Democracy and national economic performance: The
preference for stability. American Journal of Political Science, 45(3), 634-657.
Resnick, A. L. (2001). Investors, turbulence, and transition: Democratic transition and foreign
direct investment in nineteen developing countries. International Interactions, 27(4),
381-398.
Rodrik, D. (1996). Labor standards in international trade: Do they matter and what do we do
about them. In Emerging agenda for global trade: High stakes for developing countries,
35-79. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Rodrik, D. (2003) In search of prosperity: Analytic narratives on economic growth. Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Rivera-Batiz, F. L. (2002). Democracy, governance, and economic growth: theory and evidence.
Review of Development Economics, 6(2), 225-247.
Santa-Clara, P. and Valkanov, R. (2003). The presidential puzzle: political cycles and the stock
market. Journal of Finance, 58(5), 1841-1872.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. London: Routledge.
Sharpe, W.F. (1964). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of
risk. Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425-442.
Shea, J. (1997) Instrumental Relevance in Multivariate Linear Models: A Simple Measure,
Review of Economics and Statistics, 79, 348-352.
Sirowy, L. and Inkeles, A. (1990). The effects of democracy on economic growth and inequality:
A review. Studies in Comparative International Development (SCID), 25(1), 126-157.
Stock, J.H. and Yogo, M. (2005) Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression. In
D.W.K. Andrews and J.H. Stock, eds. Identification and Inference for Econometric
Models: Essays. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Stulz, R.M. (2005). The limits of financial globalization. Journal of Finance, 60(4), 1595-
1638.
Tavares, J. and Wacziarg, R. (2001). How democracy affects growth. European Economic
Review, 45(8), 1341-1378.
Ullah, S., Akhtar, P. and Zaefarian, G. (2018). Dealing with endogeneity bias: The generalized
method of moments (GMM) for panel data. Industrial Marketing Management, 71, 69-78.

32

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Wintoki, M.B., Linck, J.S. and Netter, J.M. (2012). Endogeneity and the dynamics of internal
corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 105(3), pp.581-606.
Wong, W. K. and McAleer, M. (2009). Mapping the presidential election cycle in US stock
markets. Mathematics and Computers in Simulation, 79(11), 3267-3277.
Wood, B. D. (2007). The politics of economic leadership: The causes and consequences of
presidential rhetoric. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Wooldridge, J. (2000) Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, New York: South-
Western College Publishing.
Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge:
The MIT Press.
Neumayer, E. (2008). Death penalty: The political foundations of the global trend towards
abolition. Human Rights Review, 9(2), 241-268.
Neapolitan, J. L. (2001). An examination of cross-national variation in punitiveness.
International Journal of Offender Therapy and Comparative Criminology, 45(6), 691-
710.
Greenberg, D. F., & West, V. (2008). Siting the death penalty internationally. Law & Social
Inquiry, 33(2), 295-343.

33

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Figure I
Values of High and Low Democracy Portfolios

Note: This figure depicts the value of portfolios being annually reinvested in countries with low and high
democracy scores. The initial value of investment in 1975 was assumed to be one US dollar.

34

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Figure II
Average Sharpe Ratio for countries with different Polity IV scores

Note: The sample of country-years was split into three groups based on the DEMOCRACY score. The
average value of the Sharpe ratio within each group is depicted in the figure above.

35

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table I
Variable definitions
Variable Definition Source
Annual continuously compounded dollar-denominated returns on the MSCI country stock Thomson Reuters Datastream
RETURN
market index inclusive of the dividends
Combined polity score obtained by deducting autocracy score from democracy score. Polity IV
Both types of scores are reported in Polity IV dataset and are measured on an eleven-point
DEMOCRACY
scale. The composite value was rescaled by adding 11 to obtain positive numbers across
all observations and a natural logarithm transformation was subsequently applied.
Natural logarithm of the political rights indicator representing democracy level (inverted Freedom House
LACK_OF_POLITICAL_RIGHTS
scale)
GDP_GROWTH Annual GDP growth rate World Development Indicators
INFLATION Percentage change in the CPI World Development Indicators
LNGPDPC Natural logarithm of the GDP per capita expressed in current US dollars World Development Indicators
REAL_INTEREST_RATE Real interest rate World Development Indicators
The Chinn-Ito index (KAOPEN) measuring a country's degree of capital account Chinn-Ito dataset hosted on the
openness. The index was initially introduced in Chinn and Ito (2006). KAOPEN is based Portland State University website
KAOPEN on the binary dummy variables that codify the tabulation of restrictions on cross-border
financial transactions reported in the IMF's Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements
and Exchange Restrictions (AREAER).
Annual continuously compounded dollar-denominated return on the MSCI World stock Thomson Reuters Datastream
WORLD_RETURN
market index. The return incorporates dividend payments.
LEFT_WING A dummy variable indicating that a left-wing party is in power Database of Political Institutions
RIGHT_WING A dummy variable indicating that a right-wing party is in power Database of Political Institutions
A dummy variable taking the value of one whether a government follows a religious Database of Political Institutions
RELIGION
ideology and zero otherwise
ELECTION_EXE A dummy indicating whether an executive election took place in a specific country-year Database of Political Institutions
ELECTION_LEG A dummy indicating whether a legislative election took place in a specific country-year Database of Political Institutions

36

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table II
Summary statistics
Variable Mean Adjusted Mean Std. Dev. 25thPercentile Median 75thPercentile
RETURN 0.0738 0.0518 0.3504 -0.1132 0.1024 0.2822
DEMOCRACY 2.7950 2.6557 0.5485 2.8904 3.0445 3.0445
LACK_OF_POLITICAL_RIGHTS 0.5409 0.7241 0.6775 0.0000 0.0000 1.0986
GDP_GROWTH 0.0331 0.0349 0.0368 0.0149 0.0322 0.0520
INFLATION 0.1558 0.1455 1.4462 0.0180 0.0352 0.0713
LNGPDPC 9.2269 9.0335 1.2056 8.4415 9.4036 10.1442
REAL_INTEREST_RATE 0.0568 0.0586 0.0767 0.0235 0.0475 0.0751
KAOPEN 1.0090 0.8666 1.4119 -0.1540 1.3035 2.3220
WORLD_RETURN 0.0855 0.0808 0.1794 -0.0032 0.1310 0.2081
LEFT_WING 0.3017 0.2610 0.4591 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000
RIGHT_WING 0.3318 0.2886 0.4710 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000
RELIGION 0.1204 0.1138 0.3256 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
ELECTION_EXE 0.0782 0.0896 0.2685 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
ELECTION_LEG 0.2658 0.2554 0.4419 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000
Note: This table presents summary statistics for the variables used in this study. Exact definitions of variables can be found in Table I. The sample considered spans the period from 1975 to 2015
and includes 74 countries. To arrive at the “Adjusted Mean” we first calculate the average of a given variable for each country and then take the mean of these averages.

37

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table III
Matrix of correlations

POLITICAL_RIGHTS

REAL_INTEREST_

WORLD_RETURN

ELECTION_LEG
ELECTION_EXE
GDP_GROWTH
DEMOCRACY

RIGHT_WING
LEFT_WING
INFLATION
LACK_OF_

LNGDPPC

RELIGION
KAOPEN
RETURN

RATE
RETURN 1.0000

DEMOCRACY 0.0666 1.0000


(0.0058)
LACK_OF_POLITICAL_RIGHTS -0.0659 -0.7248 1.0000
(0.0071) (0.0000)
GDP_GROWTH 0.0876 -0.2913 0.3197 1.0000
(0.0003) (0.0000) (0.0000)
INFLATION 0.0171 0.0144 0.0108 -0.0740 1.0000
(0.4859) (0.5567) (0.6581) (0.0025)
LNGPDPC -0.0334 0.1661 -0.5585 -0.2344 -0.0888 1.0000
(0.1715) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0003)
REAL_INTEREST_RATE 0.0026 0.0226 0.0611 -0.1044 -0.0506 -0.1235 1.0000
(0.9277) (0.4342) (0.0346) (0.0003) (0.0858) (0.0000)
KAOPEN -0.0086 0.1277 -0.4138 -0.1527 -0.1516 0.6594 -0.0825 1.0000
(0.7283) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0047)
WORLD_RETURN 0.6078 0.0361 -0.0471 -0.0234 -0.0200 -0.0286 0.0632 -0.0183 1.0000
(0.0000) (0.1330) (0.0501) (0.3311) (0.4130) (0.2703) (0.0288) (0.4548)
LEFT_WING 0.0134 0.1297 -0.1990 -0.0266 -0.0457 0.0113 0.0697 -0.0561 0.0053 1.0000
(0.5808) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.2704) (0.0617) (0.6434) (0.0162) (0.0219) (0.8250)
RIGHT_WING 0.0249 0.2392 -0.2452 -0.0883 0.0644 0.1659 -0.0239 0.1668 0.0361 -0.4639 1.0000
(0.3045) (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0002) (0.0085) (0.0000) (0.4100) (0.0000) (0.1343) (0.0000)
RELIGION 0.0271 -0.0081 -0.0397 -0.0301 -0.0267 0.0264 -0.0110 0.0070 0.0238 -0.2075 0.2087 1.0000
(0.2634) (0.7381) (0.0992) (0.2122) (0.2761) (0.2774) (0.7051) (0.7757) (0.3228) (0.0000) (0.0000)
ELECTION_EXE -0.0065 0.0684 -0.0141 0.0007 0.0826 -0.0402 0.0933 -0.0676 -0.0193 -0.0318 0.0236 -0.0880 1.0000
(0.7901) (0.0045) (0.5584) (0.9713) (0.0007) (0.0986) (0.0013) (0.0058) (0.4234) (0.1862) (0.3267) (0.0003)
ELECTION_LEG 0.0092 0.0850 -0.0705 -0.0298 0.0167 0.0375 0.0057 0.0312 0.0012 -0.0075 0.0433 0.0067 0.2544 1.0000
(0.7058) (0.0004) (0.0034) (0.2176) (0.4962) (0.1235) (0.8451) (0.2029) (0.9598) (0.7550) (0.0724) (0.7821) (0.0000)
Note: This table reports Pearson correlation coefficients between the variables. The p-value for the null hypothesis that a specific correlation coefficient is equal to zero is reported in parentheses.

38

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table IV
Regressions linking MSCI indexes returns to democracy level and control variables
Model Time effects Pooled feasible GLS System GMM Pooled feasible GLS
Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
** *** *** **
0.0265 0.0666 0.0706 0.0685
DEMOCRACY
(0.0125) (0.0190) (0.0157) (0.0313)
0.0548***
LAGGED DEMOCRACY
(0.0201)
1.1585*** 0.6432*** 1.3077 *** 0.7313***
GDP_GROWTH
(0.3030) (0.2235) (0.4764) (0.2489)
-0.5811* -0.5990** -0.9172** -0.4226
INFLATION
(0.3354) (0.2642) (0.4679) (0.2921)
1.4556** 0.6252 1.7776** 0.3468
INFLATION2
(0.7115) (0.8814) (0.8476) (1.0321)
-0.0062 -0.0191*** -0.0180 -0.0134
LNGDPPC
(0.0073) (0.0068) (0.0133) (0.0083)
-0.0732 -0.1905* -0.2916** -0.1560*
REAL_INTEREST_RATE
(0.0932) (0.0976) (0.1349) (0.0897)
0.0035 0.0045 0.0034 0.0069
KAOPEN
(0.0059) (0.0050) (0.0086) (0.0051)
0.0349** 0.0124 0.0535** 0.0136
LEFT_WING
(0.0171) (0.0123) (0.0239) (0.0137)
-0.0083 -0.0093 0.0162 -0.0098
RIGHT_WING
(0.0170) (0.0137) (0.0268) (0.0149)
0.0380* 0.0279** 0.0270 0.0295**
RELIGION
(0.0212) (0.0124) (0.0241) (0.0124)
0.0213 0.0178 0.0292 0.0152
ELECTION_EXE
(0.0262) (0.0187) (0.0253) (0.0186)
-0.0166 -0.0122 -0.0140 -0.0116
ELECTION_LEG
(0.0152) (0.0109) (0.0159) (0.0115)

39

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


1.0791*** 1.0927*** 1.0808***
WORLD_RETURN
(0.0445) (0.0580) (0.0447)
-0.0592
RETURN LAG1
(0.0407)
-0.0786***
RETURN LAG2
(0.0272)
-0.0007 -0.0859 -0.0250 -0.0527 -0.0470
Constant
(0.0358) (0.0997) (0.0698) (0.1631) (0.0814)
No of Observations 1711 1125 1125 1052 1090
No of Countries 74 62 62 62 62
R-squared 0.4817 0.5054 0.5514 0.5502
F-statistic 37.8386 21.0637 105.0410 101.2454
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
AR(2) test -0.2411
Prob>z 0.8095
Hansen test 45.8829
Prob>chi2 0.9981
Note: The regressions reported in this table link stock market index returns to our democracy variable (or lagged democracy) and controls. Exact variable definitions can be found in Table I. The
first two specifications report results for a model with time fixed effects. Specifications (3) and (5), have no fixed effects and are estimated using feasible GLS with cross-section weights. For
these models, R-squared and F-test are reported as weighted statistics. The F-statistic is for the null hypothesis that all of the explanatory variables are jointly unable to explain the underlying
process. Specification (4) is based on system GMM estimation outlined in Blundell and Bond (1998). In these models WORLD_RETURN is assumed to be an endogenous variable and the standard
errors reported are robust with respect to cross-sectional dependence and heteroscedasticity. The AR(2) test is for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first difference regression exhibit no
second order serial correction, while the Hansen’s test verifies the validity of overidentifying restrictions in the GMM estimation. Parameter standard errors, which in the static models allow for
the serial correlation and heteroskedasticity of the error terms, are reported in parentheses. *, **, *** denote statistical significance at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.

40

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table V
Determinants of risk levels
Dependent Variable TOTAL_VOLATILITY COUNTRY_SPECIFIC_VOLATILITY GLOBAL_SYSTEMATIC_VOLATILITY
Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
* ** **
-0.0054 -0.0088 -0.0119 -0.0175 0.0118 0.0040
DEMOCRACY
(0.0081) (0.0107) (0.0070) (0.0077) (0.0054) (0.0113)
-0.7311*** -0.4752*** -0.4679***
GDP_GROWTH
(0.1967) (0.1469) (0.1559)
0.5331*** 0.3818** 0.4775*
INFLATION
(0.2181) (0.1511) (0.2408)
-0.7909** -0.2173 -0.8503*
INFLATION2
(0.3900) (0.2268) (0.4394)
0.0107* -0.0213*** 0.0067
LNGDPPC
(0.0064) (0.0059) (0.0041)
0.0102 0.0133 0.1313*
REAL_INTEREST_RATE
(0.0720) (0.0558) (0.0664)
-0.0037 -0.0069 -0.0001
KAOPEN
(0.0054) (0.0051) (0.0032)
-0.0061 -0.0094 -0.0019
LEFT_WING
(0.0114) (0.0092) (0.0124)
-0.0095 -0.0037 -0.0147
RIGHT_WING
(0.0118) (0.0097) (0.0103)
-0.0159 -0.0154 -0.0090
RELIGION
(0.0184) (0.0105) (0.0160)
0.0177 0.0163 0.0012
ELECTION_EXE
(0.0175) (0.0121) (0.0181)
-0.0035 -0.0011 -0.0025
ELECTION_LEG
(0.0077) (0.0055) (0.0078)
-0.2108*** -0.0658*** -0.2127***
WORLD_RETURN
(0.0206) (0.0195) (0.0207)

41

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


0.4136*** 0.3695***
LAGGED TOTAL_VOLATILITY
(0.0379) (0.0483)
0.5165*** 0.2334***
LAGGED COUNTRY_SPECIFIC_VOLATILITY
(0.0430) (0.0497)
0.2962*** 0.3767***
LAGGED GLOBAL_SYSTEMATIC_VOLATILITY
(0.0370) (0.0585)
0.1598*** 0.2950*** 0.1206*** 0.3965*** 0.0692*** 0.0301***
Constant
(0.0251) (0.0773) (0.0204) (0.0735) (0.0162) (0.0574)
No of Observations 1637 1089 1637 1089 1637 1089
No of Countries 73 62 73 62 73 62
AR(2) test -1.0912 -1.2794 0.4490 -1.3319 -1.4259 -0.0857
Prob>z 0.2752 0.2008 0.6535 0.1829 0.1539 0.9317
Hansen test 71.1217 52.2646 69.6202 52.3470 71.8056 54.5437
Prob>chi2 0.6672 0.9890 0.7125 0.9887 0.6459 0.9800
Note: The regressions reported in this table consider different types of volatility as a function of the democracy variable and controls. The dependent variable in specifications (1) to (2) is the annualized
total volatility of national index returns. This total volatility is then dissected into two components, namely COUNTRY_SPECIFIC_VOLATILITY and GLOBAL_SYSTEMATIC_VOLATILITY. These
components are modelled individually in columns (3) to (6). Specifications (1), (3) and (5) include no controls except for the autoregressive term, while specifications (2), (4), and (6) incorporate a full
set of explanatory variables. All of the regressions are dynamic panels estimated using the system GMM method by Blundell and Bond (1998). In these models WORLD_RETURN is assumed to be an
endogenous variable and standard errors robust to cross-sectional dependence and heteroscedasticity are reported in parentheses. The AR(2) test is for the null hypothesis that the errors in the first
difference regression exhibit no second order serial correction, while the Hansen’s test verifies the validity of overidentifying restrictions in the GMM estimation. *, **, *** denote statistical significance
at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.

42

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table VI
Strength of investor protection and democracy level
Independent Variable (1) (2)
***
0.8371 0.4015***
DEMOCRACY
(0.3185) (0.0987)
0.2098
GDP_GROWTH
(0.7029)
-3.0653*
INFLATION
(1.5842)
9.0554***
INFLATION2
(3.3638)
0.3224
LNGDPPC
(0.3295)
-0.0589
REAL_INTEREST_RATE
(0.2485)
-0.1175
KAOPEN
(0.1210)
-0.1115
LEFT_WING
(0.1346)
-0.0174
RIGHT_WING
(0.1158)
0.2048
RELIGION
(0.2466)
0.1189
ELECTION_EXE
(0.1123)
-0.0501
ELECTION_LEG
(0.0480)
3.6410*** 2.1801
Constant
(0.8540) (3.1925)
No of Observations 638 408
No of Countries 74 50
R-squared 0.9126 0.9466
F-statistic 70.6896 86.8895
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000
Note: Investor protection index from the World Economic Forum Global Competitiveness Index dataset
acts as a dependent variable in the models reported above. Exact variable definitions can be found in
Table I. The estimation method used here is the two-way fixed effect panel. Specification (1) includes
no controls, while specification (2) incorporates all controls. The F-statistic is for the null hypothesis
that all of the explanatory variables are jointly unable to explain the underlying process. Parameter
standard errors robust to heteroskedasticity and serial correlation are given in parentheses. *, **, ***
denote statistical significance at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.

43

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table VII
Return regressions exploring the rationalizations for the democracy-autocracy returns gap
Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4)
*** *** ***
0.0583 0.0584 0.0570 0.0023
DEMOCRACY
(0.0201) (0.0201) (0.0200) (0.0168)
0.0782
LAGGED TOTAL_VOLATILITY
(0.0593)
0.0963
LAGGED COUNTRY_SPECIFIC_VOLATILITY
(0.0697)
0.0494
LAGGED GLOBAL_SYSTEMATIC_VOLATILITY
(0.0625)
0.0113**
LAGGED INVESTOR_PROTECTION
(0.0053)
0.7897*** 0.7548*** 0.7697*** -0.3451
GDP_GROWTH
(0.2519) (0.2491) (0.2539) (0.2098)
-0.4117 -0.4335 -0.4022 -0.4550
INFLATION
(0.2997) (0.3002) (0.2960) (0.3880)
0.1613 0.1957 0.2385 -2.5390*
INFLATION2
(1.0770) (1.0946) (1.0479) (1.5087)
-0.0115 -0.0103 -0.0134 -0.0180
LNGDPPC
(0.0083) (0.0085) (0.0082) (0.0119)
-0.1661* -0.1753* -0.1561* -0.3870***
REAL_INTEREST_RATE
(0.0899) (0.0934) (0.0882) (0.1069)
0.0080 0.0079 0.0073 0.0062
KAOPEN
(0.0051) (0.0052) (0.0051) (0.0081)
0.0137 0.0149 0.0127 0.0590***
LEFT_WING
(0.0138) (0.0139) (0.0137) (0.0192)
-0.0095 -0.0089 -0.0100 0.0247
RIGHT_WING
(0.0151) (0.0152) (0.0150) (0.0214)
0.0319** 0.0302** 0.0312** 0.0524***
RELIGION
(0.0130) (0.0125) (0.0130) (0.0180)
0.0158 0.0178 0.0148 0.1162***
ELECTION_EXE
(0.0190) (0.0193) (0.0187) (0.0207)
-0.0118 -0.0118 -0.0121 -0.0555***
ELECTION_LEG
(0.0116) (0.0116) (0.0116) (0.0178)
1.0789*** 1.0833*** 1.0775*** 1.1720***
WORLD_RETURN
(0.0441) (0.0447) (0.0445) (0.0360)
-0.0960 -0.1038 -0.0627 0.0506
Constant
(0.0885) (0.0881) (0.0820) (0.1098)
No of Observations 1089 1089 1089 359
No of Countries 62 62 62 50
R-squared 0.5493 0.5500 0.5493 0.7973
F-statistic 93.4796 93.7799 93.4864 96.6503
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Note: The regressions reported in this table link stock market index returns to our democracy variable, a lagged variable suspected to drive
the democracy-autocracy return differential and controls. Exact variable definitions can be found in Table I. The regressions are estimated
using feasible GLS with cross-section weights and the R-squared and F-test are reported as weighted statistics. The F-statistic is for the null
hypothesis that all of the explanatory variables are jointly unable to explain the underlying process. Parameter standard errors, which in the
static models allow for the serial correlation and heteroskedasticity of the error terms, are reported in parentheses. *, **, *** denote statistical
significance at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.

44

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table VIII
Determinants of returns: Robustness checks
Model with an Model with MSCI
Discoll and Kraay Models estimated in
alternative democracy excess returns as
(1998) estimation different subperiods
variable dependent variable
Estimation Period
1975-2015 1975-2015 1975-2015 1975-2003 2004-2015
Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
*** *** **
0.0698 0.0762 0.0974 0.0551***
DEMOCRACY (0.0231) (0.0410) (0.0161)
(0.0159)
-0.0681***
LACK_OF_POLITICAL_RIGHTS
(0.0145)
0.6251*** 0.6343*** 1.2604*** 0.5687 0.7743***
GDP_GROWTH
(0.2257) (0.2214) (0.3380) (0.3706) (0.1947)
-0.6771** -0.8278** -0.3102 -0.4956
INFLATION
(0.2568) (0.3768) (0.3123) (0.3633)
0.8603 1.6537*** 0.5665 -2.6662
INFLATION2
(0.8569) (0.5233) (0.8362) (1.6982)
-0.0333*** 0.0212*** -0.0184 -0.0231* -0.0275***
LNGDPPC
(0.0083) (0.0082) (0.0153) (0.0133) (0.0084)
-0.1705 -0.1209 -0.1135 -0.2954**
REAL_INTEREST_RATE
(0.1024) (0.1397) (0.1005) (0.1202)
0.0046 0.0157* 0.0096 0.0089 0.0074
KAOPEN (0.0081) (0.0089) (0.0065) (0.0075)
(0.0048)
0.0010 0.0053 0.0412** -0.0068 0.0359**
LEFT_WING
(0.0131) (0.0137) (0.0202) (0.0222) (0.0156)
-0.0150 -0.0169 -0.0008 -0.0099 0.0011
RIGHT_WING
(0.0139) (0.0162) (0.0191) (0.0237) (0.0163)
0.0241** 0.0242 0.0367** 0.0159 0.0409***
RELIGION
(0.0110) (0.0171) (0.0174) (0.0194) (0.0138)

45

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


0.0186 -0.0114 0.0195 0.0042 0.0534***
ELECTION_EXE
(0.0180) (0.0179) (0.0274) (0.0273) (0.0159)
-0.0095 -0.0085 -0.0062 -0.0018 -0.0383***
ELECTION_LEG
(0.0109) (0.0107) (0.0172) (0.0162) (0.0122)
1.0737*** 1.0945*** 1.1312*** 0.9300*** 1.2252***
WORLD_RETURN
(0.0441) (0.0485) (0.1321) (0.0521) (0.0453)
0.3460*** -0.5246*** -0.0933 -0.0639 0.0888
Constant
(0.0835) (0.0793) (0.1849) (0.1134) (0.0920)
No of Observations 1125 1125 1125 582 543
No. of Countries 62 62 62 47 57
R-squared 0.5522 0.5258 0.4015 0.4624 0.7268
F-statistic 105.4025 123.5323 50.5800 37.5877 108.2691
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Note: Colum (1) displays regression in which MSCI returns are a function of LACK_OF_POLITICAL_RIGHTS variable and controls. Column (2) shows regression with MSCI excess returns as the
dependent variable. Column (3) estimates the baseline return regression using the Discoll and Kraay (1998) method. Columns (3) and (4) present results for the models fitted in different subperiods.
Exact variable definitions can be found in Table I. The estimation method employed here is feasible GLS with cross-section weights. Parameter standard errors allowing for heteroskedasticity and serial
correlation of the error terms are reported in parentheses. The F-statistic is for the null hypothesis that all of the explanatory variables are jointly unable to explain the underlying process. *, **, *** denote
statistical significance at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.

46

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table IX
Return models including interactive terms
Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
*** *** *** *** *** **
0.0558 0.0704 0.0732 0.0703 0.0654 0.0465 0.2062***
DEMOCRACY
(0.0186) (0.0158) (0.0172) (0.0157) (0.0149) (0.0192) (0.0752)
0.0456**
DEMOCRACY×LEFT_WING
(0.0197)
0.0785
DEMOCRACY×RIGHT_WING
(0.0884)
-0.0185
DEMOCRACY×RELIGION
(0.0235)
0.1148
DEMOCRACY×ELECTION_EXE
(0.1114)
0.0352
DEMOCRACY×ELECTION_LEG
(0.0294)
0.5186**
DEMOCRACY×INFLATION
(0.2396)
-0.0147*
DEMOCRACY×LNGDPPC
(0.0082)
0.6510*** 0.6568*** 0.6517*** 0.6454*** 0.6356*** 0.6469*** 0.6270***
GDP_GROWTH
(0.2175) (0.2243) (0.2267) (0.2242) (0.2253) (0.2201) (0.2213)
-0.6569** -0.5970** -0.6152** -0.5894** -0.5799** -2.0910*** -0.6984***
INFLATION
(0.2607) (0.2615) (0.2699) (0.2652) (0.2702) (0.7299) (0.2686)
0.7192 0.6567 0.6557 0.6084 0.5697 0.9736 0.8159
INFLATION2
(0.8678) (0.8819) (0.8841) (0.8834) (0.9078) (0.8010) (0.8589)
-0.0215*** -0.0196*** -0.0199*** -0.0191*** -0.0187*** -0.0201*** 0.0183
LNGDPPC
(0.0071) (0.0069) (0.0074) (0.0069) (0.0068) (0.0072) (0.0207)
-0.2180** -0.1847* -0.1925* -0.1862* -0.1991** -0.2261** -0.2172**
REAL_INTEREST_RATE
(0.0997) (0.1002) (0.0976) (0.0984) (0.1002) (0.1009) (0.0988)
KAOPEN 0.0032 0.0044 0.0048 0.0044 0.0043 0.0058 0.0049

47

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


(0.0049) (0.0050) (0.0051) (0.0050) (0.0050) (0.0051) (0.0051)
-0.1147** 0.0127 0.0130 0.0118 0.0111 0.0162 0.0189
LEFT_WING
(0.0511) (0.0123) (0.0124) (0.0123) (0.0123) (0.0120) (0.0129)
-0.0012 -0.2457 -0.0083 -0.0094 -0.0109 -0.0063 -0.0038
RIGHT_WING
(0.0151) (0.2677) (0.0140) (0.0137) (0.0140) (0.0138) (0.0143)
0.0283** 0.0272** 0.0820 0.0278** 0.0294** 0.0296** 0.0259**
RELIGION
(0.0126) (0.0121) (0.0685) (0.0124) (0.0127) (0.0125) (0.0127)
0.0184 0.0272 0.0179 -0.3261 0.0168 0.0177 0.0183
ELECTION_EXE
(0.0184) (0.0121) (0.0187) (0.3355) (0.0185) (0.0180) (0.0183)
-0.0130 -0.0123 -0.0128 -0.0120 -0.1150 -0.0120 -0.0134
ELECTION_LEG
(0.0110) (0.0109) (0.0111) (0.0109) (0.0872) (0.0107) (0.0109)
1.0778*** 1.0791*** 1.0785*** 1.0791*** 1.0799*** 1.0745*** 1.0773***
WORLD_RETURN
(0.0441) (0.0445) (0.0444) (0.0443) (0.0442) (0.0443) (0.0440)
0.0418 -0.0201 -0.0242 -0.0240 -0.0126 -0.0517 -0.3637*
Constant
(0.0838) (0.0708) (0.0697) (0.0703) (0.0641) (0.0819) (0.1868)
No of Observations 1125 1125 1125 1125 1125 1125 1125
No of Countries 62 62 62 62 62 62 62
R-squared 0.5503 0.5515 0.5514 0.5515 0.5529 0.5575 0.5510
F-statistic 97.0175 97.4951 97.4396 97.4756 98.2093 99.9022 97.3099
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Note: This table reports estimates of models in which MSCI returns is dependent on democracy level, interaction terms and a full set of controls. Exact variable definitions can be found in Table I. The
estimation method employed here is feasible GLS with cross-section weights. Parameter standard errors allowing for the heteroscedasticity and serial correlation of the error terms are reported in
parentheses. The F-statistic is for the null hypothesis that all of the explanatory variables are jointly unable to explain the underlying process. *, **, *** denote statistical significance at 10%, 5% and 1%,
respectively.

48

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Appendix A

The table below lists the sample countries together with the length of the MSCI stock index return series used in our analysis.

Table A1
List of countries in the sample
Developed Markets Emerging Markets Frontier Markets Standalone Markets
Australia (1975-2015) Brazil (1988-2015) Bahrain (2006-2015) Argentina (1988-2015)
Austria (1975-2015) Chile (1988-2015) Bangladesh (2010-2015) Bosnia Herzegovina (2011-2015)
Belgium (1975-2015) China (1993-2015) Croatia (2003-2015) Botswana (2009-2015)
Finland (1975-2015) Colombia (1993-2015) Estonia (2003-2015) Bulgaria (2006-2015)
Canada (1975-2015) Czech Republic (1995-2015) Jordan (1988-2015) Ghana (2009-2015)
Denmark (1975-2015) Greece (1988-2015) Kazakhstan (2006-2015) Jamaica (2009-2015)
France (1975-2015) Hungry (1995-2015) Kenya (2004-2015) Lebanon (2005-2015)
Germany5 (1975-2015) India (1993-2015) Lithuania (2009-2015) Russia (1995-2015)
Ireland (1988-2015) Indonesia (1989-2015) Mauritius (2003-2015) Trinidad & Tobago (2009-2015)
Israel (1993-2015) Korea (1988-2015) Morocco (1995-2015) Ukraine (2007-2015)
Italy (1975-2015) Kuwait (2006-2015) Nigeria (2003-2015)
Japan (1975-2015) Malaysia (1988-2015) Oman (2006-2015)
Netherlands (1975-2015) Mexico (1988-2015) Pakistan (1993-2015)
New Zealand (1988-2015) Peru (1993-2015) Romania (2006-2015)
Norway (1975-2015) Philippines (1988-2015) Serbia (2009-2015)
Portugal (1988-2015) Poland (1994-2015) Slovenia (2003-2015)

5 The data before 1990 cames from West Germany.

49

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Singapore (1975-2015) Qatar (2005-2015) Sri Lanka (1993-2015)
Spain (1975-2015) Saudi Arabia (2006-2015) Tunisia (2005-2015)
Sweden (1975-2015) South Africa (1993-2015) Vietnam (2007-2015)
Switzerland (1975-2015) Taiwan (1988-2015)
United Kingdom (1975-2015) Thailand (1988-2015)
United States (1975-2015) Turkey (1990-2015)
United Arab Emirates (2006-2015)

50

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Appendix B
Possible endogeneity?

Is the democracy indicator an exogenous variable, or can capital market performance affect the

process of democratization? Based on the economic literature, Lipset (1959) argues that

democracy must be based on economic development, because the middle class is the backbone

of democracy, and only when the middle class has grown and consolidated can the community

counter dictatorships. This is the so-called the Lipset hypothesis, supported by studies such as

Huber et al. (1993) and Putnam et al. (1994). Barro (1999) provides further empirical evidence

to document that economic growth begets democracy, and that the democratic system is

impossible to sustain without adequate economic support. On the other hand, new institutional

economists such as Acemoglu et al. (2003; 2005; 2008) and Rodrik (2003) disagree with this

viewpoint. They believe the reason why some studies have found that economic growth

promotes development of democracy is related to model bias issues like omitted variables.

They argue that there is no absolute two-way causal relationship between economic growth

and democracy. In addition to the potential reverse causality discussed above, there are the

usual omitted variable concerns. For example, bad policy decisions of nondemocratic rulers

may induce both a fall in economic growth and demands for democratization. Similarly,

political unrest paving the way for democracy might also disrupt financial market.

From an econometric viewpoint, one way to address potential endogeneity issues is to use the

instrumental variables (IV) strategy to estimate the model, which can (at least partially)

mitigate the reverse causality and omitted variable problems. The prerequisite for instrumental

variable estimation is to find valid instruments that meet several criteria. First, they should only

work through the possible endogenous independent variables to influence the dependent

variable. Second, the instruments must be exogenous and have significant effects on the

endogenous explanatory variables (Wooldridge, 2002). If the instrumental variable is valid and

51

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


the key explanatory variable is endogenous, then a two-stage least squares estimation (2SLS)

should be used, as the simple OLS would be inconsistent (Wooldridge, 2002). On the other

hand, if the instrumental variable is valid but the key explanatory variable is exogenous, then

the result of non-instrumental analysis should be accepted.

Before implementing the endogeneity tests, we need to find suitable instrumental variables for

the democracy indicator and employ the relevant statistical techniques to verify the validity of

these instruments. Our approach to selecting an instrumental variable for DEMOCRACY is

inspired by Neumayer (2008) who argues that in democratic societies the death penalty tends

to be perceived as a violation of human rights and the process of democratization renders its

abolition more likely. This result is in accordance with the previous findings of Neapolitan

(2001) and Greenberg and West (2003). Consequently, the abrogation of capital punishment

could be an attractive source of exogenous variation in democracy, which we exploit in our

testing.

More specifically, we define a dummy variable ABO∈{0,1} to measure whether a country has

abolished the death penalty or not. The data for this variable is taken from Amnesty

International. According to the extant literature, this variable should be correlated with the level

of democratization. At the same time, it is unlikely to be correlated with national stock market

returns, as countries experiencing stock market upswings may be retentionists. We consider a

country abolitionist during a given year if it abolishes the death penalty for all crimes, or for

ordinary crimes only, or de facto abolishes the death penalty 6 (ABO = 1), and regard it as

retentionist otherwise (ABO = 0). It is worth noting that the ABO dummy is highly correlated

with DEMOCRACY ( = 0.4279, p-value = 0.0000) but very weakly correlated with stock

market returns ( = 0.0101, p-value = 0.6776).

6The criterion of de facto abolitionist employed by Amnesty International is that a country has ‘not executed anyone during
the past 10 years’ and is believed to ‘have a policy or established practice of not carrying out executions’.

52

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


In the next step, we verify the effectiveness of the ABO instrumental variable by performing a

series of tests. First, a LM version of the Anderson (1951) canonical correlations test is

performed to check whether there is an underidentification issue. Underidentification test

checks whether the included instrumental variable is relevant. The null hypothesis is that the

instrumental variable is underidentified and the corresponding test statistic follows chi-squared

distribution under the null. In our data, the Anderson LM statistic is 162.91 (p-value = 0.0000),

which shows that the underidentification problem is not present. Furthermore, we apply the

heteroskedastic-robust Kleibergen-Paap (2006) rk LM test which dispenses with the i.i.d.

assumption. The value of the corresponding statistic is 113.83 (p-values = 0.0000), which

reinforces the results of the Anderson (1951) test.

Although relevant, the instruments may still be weak, which would lead to poor estimation.

The Cragg-Donald (1993) Wald F-test can be utilized to examine this issue and Stock and Yogo

(2005) provide the relevant critical values for this test. The Cragg-Donald F-statistic is 188.12,

which is higher than any of the Stock-Yogo critical values (5.53 – 16.38). Consequently, we

could reject the null hypothesis of weak instruments by accepting that the true size is no more

than 10%. We also implemented heteroskedastic-robust Kleibergen-Paap (2006) rk Wald F-test

and the corresponding statistic of 133.50 was higher than the 10% Stock-Yogo critical value,

which lends credence to our earlier conclusion.

Another issue to contend with when using instrumental variables is the possibility of

overidentification. The inclusion of lags of ABO as instruments allows us to perform a Hansen-

type overidentification test. It verifies whether instrumental variables are correlated with the

endogenous variables, but uncorrelated with the error terms (Hayashi, 2000). The null

hypothesis here is that all the instrumental variables are exogenous. The Sargan statistic turns

out to be 1.86 (p-value = 0.1732), implying that we cannot reject the null hypothesis. If we are

concerned about the presence of heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation, the Hansen's J-statistic

53

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


could be used as an alternative to the Sargan statistic (Hayashi, 2000). The Hansen's J-statistic

is 0.65 (p-value = 0.4188), which corroborates the finding that the instruments are valid, and

no misspecification is present. Based on all of the abovementioned tests, we can consider the

instrumental variable ABO to be effective.

We seek the answer the question of whether we need to use the instrumental variables strategy

by resorting to endogeneity testing. This pursuit starts with employing the most common

method, namely the Durbin-Wu-Hausman test (Durbin, 1954; Wu, 1974; Hausman, 1978). We

re-estimate the main specification by using pooled OLS and 2SLS and used the Hausman

method to test whether the estimated coefficients of the two equations were systematically

different. When we consider the heteroscedastic robust standard errors, the Wu-Hausman F-

test statistic is 0.06 (p-value = 0.8070) and the Durbin-Wu-Hausman chi-squared test statistic

is 0.06 (p-value = 0.8058). Moreover, we implemented another endogeneity test based on a C

statistic (also known as a “GMM distance” or “difference-in-Sargan” statistic). It is defined the

difference of two Sargan-Hansen statistics: one for the equation with the smaller set (subset)

of instruments, where the suspect regressor(s) are treated as endogenous, and one for the

equation with the larger set of instruments, where the suspect regressor(s) are treated as

exogenous (Hayashi, 2000). Under the null hypothesis both the smaller set of instruments and

the larger set of instruments are valid. In other words, the specified endogenous regressor(s)

can actually be treated as exogenous. In context of our sample, the chi-squared statistic7 equals

to 0.06 (p-value = 0.8058), which parallels the conclusions obtained from the Hausman test8.

Consequently, we fail to reject the null hypothesis that the Polity IV variable DEMOCRACY is

exogenous (Davidson and MacKinnon, 1993, Wooldridge, 2000). In short, there is no clear

7The test statistic is distributed as chi-squared with degrees of freedom equal to the number of regressors tested.
8Under conditional homoskedasticity, this endogeneity test statistic is numerically equal to a Hausman test statistic (Haysshi,
2000).

54

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


evidence for the presence of endogeneity and the instrumental variables strategy does not need

to be used.

We note in passing that the conclusions of the study would remain unchanged even if we

decided to proceed with the instrumentation. Table A2 reports the 2SLS regression results with

abolitionist dummy and other explanatory variables acting as instruments for DEMOCRACY.

The instrumented democracy indicator still appears to be a significant explanatory factor in the

return regressions.

[Insert Table A2 about here]

55

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561


Table A2
IV (2SLS) estimation
Independent Variable First-stage regression for IV (2SLS) estimation for
DEMOCRACY RETURN_GROSS
0.4099***
ABO
(0.0355)
0.0861**
DEMOCRACY
(0.0437)
-3.5155*** 1.3041***
GDP_GROWTH
(0.6742) (0.3698)
1.0266* -0.8349**
INFLATION
(0.6099) (0.3840)
-2.3816** 1.6701**
INFLATION2
(1.2976) (0.7420)
-0.0107 -0.0186
LNGDPPC
(0.0243) (0.3295)
-0.3577 -0.1195
REAL_INTEREST_RATE
(0.2552) (0.1306)
-0.0026 0.0096
KAOPEN
(0.0132) (0.0090)
0.1942*** 0.0383
LEFT_WING
(0.0381) (0.0243)
0.3399*** -0.0044
RIGHT_WING
(0.0366) (0.0264)
0.0037 0.0362
RELIGION
(0.0414) (0.0226)
0.1197*** 0.0178
ELECTION_EXE
(0.0352) (0.0312)
0.0525* -0.0065
ELECTION_LEG
(0.0292) (0.0187)
0.0625 1.1311***
WORLD_RETURN
(0.0716) (0.0484)
2.5522*** -0.1184
Constant
(0.2285) (0.1621)
No of Observations 1125 1125
No of Countries 62 62
R-squared 0.3332 0.4013
F-statistic 29.97
Wald chi-squared 625.88
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000
Note: The data of abolition of the death penalty (ABO) is taken from Amnesty International. Exact
variable definitions can be found in Table I. The results reported are based on IV (2SLS) estimation.
Parameter standard errors robust to heteroskedasticity and serial correlation are given in parentheses. *,
**, *** denote statistical significance at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.

56

Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3198561

You might also like