Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Regional Science and Urban Economics


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/regec

Rural-urban migration in developing countries: Lessons from the literature


Harris Selod *, Forhad Shilpi
Sustainability and Infrastructure Team, Development Research Group, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC, 20433, USA

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

JEL classification: This paper reviews the recent literature on rural-urban migration in developing countries, focusing on three key
J01 questions: What motivates or forces people to migrate? What costs do migrants face? What are the impacts of
J61 migration on migrants and the economy? The literature paints a complex picture whereby rural-urban migration
O15
is driven by many factors and the returns to migration as well as the costs are very high. The evidence supports the
Keywords: notion that migration barriers hinder labor market adjustment and are likely to be welfare reducing. The review
Internal migration
concludes by identifying gaps in current research and data needs.
Benefits and costs of migration
Barriers to migration
Structural transformation
Urbanization

1. Introduction prevailing wage rate (an unexpected result due to induced internal
migration to the city that later became known as the Todaro paradox).
Rural-urban migration has been a key focus of economic historians Where the Lewis models and Harris-Todaro models agree is that migrants
and development economists for a long time. During the industrial rev- respond often vigorously to economic incentives (in the form of higher
olution in Europe and North America, internal migration triggered two income prospects in urban areas). The Harris-Todaro model also points to
fundamental and complementary processes: the structural trans- the peril of ignoring migration responses to government policies. Doing
formation of employment from agriculture to non-agricultural industries so in the context of place-based policies such as the employment creation
and services, and the subsequent economic growth associated with ur- program in Nairobi could just produce more unemployment due to the
banization (Kim and Margo, 2004; Kim, 2007). Not surprisingly, devel- migration response. Another important lesson from the work of Harris
opment economists in the 1950s and 1960s also placed unimpeded and Todaro is that migration might play a greater role in developing
migration from rural to urban areas at the center of their understanding countries—where rigidities and labor-market imperfections are more
of the economic development process that had begun to unfold in low common—than in developed countries with more efficient
income countries. In the seminal papers of Lewis (1954) and Ranis and labor-markets. Wage rigidity is indeed at the core of the Todaro paradox
Fei (1961), rural-to-urban migration is presented as an equilibrating flow whereby, because of a sticky wage, an exogenous increase in labor de-
of perfectly elastic supply of workers from a rural sector that has surplus mand can cause an even greater increase in labor supply from migration
labor towards a modern industrial sector located in cites, a transition to the city at the prevailing wage.1 As our review of the economic liter-
leading to capital accumulation in cities and economic growth. ature on internal migration will show, rigidities and imperfections that
In stark contrast with these views, the seminal contributions of are common in other factor markets in developing countries (credit, in-
Todaro (1969) and Harris and Todaro (1970) presented migration in a surance, land) could also play a role in migration.
quite different light. The main motivation underpinning the Todarian Keeping true to the spirit of the Harris-Todaro model on its 50th
models came from the necessity to account for the existence of unem- anniversary, this paper focuses on rural-urban migration in developing
ployment in the cities of developing countries. It is drawn from the countries. It does not attempt a critical review of the Harris-Todaro
real-life puzzle that the level of urban unemployment in Nairobi ended model, which was already provided in a previous literature survey by
up increasing rather than decreasing after the government, the private Lall et al. (2009). Instead, it takes stock of the main lessons learned,
sector, and unions joined forces in the 1960s to try and create jobs at the especially from recent academic contributions. Lucas (2016) reviewed

* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: hselod@worldbank.org (H. Selod), fshilpi@worldbank.org (F. Shilpi).
1
See Lall, Selod and Shalizi (2006) for a simple derivation of the result.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2021.103713
Received 2 October 2020; Received in revised form 22 June 2021; Accepted 24 June 2021
Available online 30 June 2021
0166-0462/© 2021 Published by Elsevier B.V.
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

empirical evidence on internal migration with a focus on migration reconstruct missing data for a large number of countries.2 It is reasonable
barriers and structural transformation. Lagakos (2020) provides a partial to assume, however, that it probably underestimates the true extent of
review of the migration literature in the broader context of analyzing internal migration given that the calculation uses areas of residence
urban-rural income gaps in developing countries. This review is orga- defined at large administrative subdivision levels.3 With the steady in-
nized around three main questions: (i) What motivates or forces people to crease in global population and intensification of some drivers of internal
migrate, making here a distinction between voluntary and involuntary migration such as climate change and conflict (see Section 3), one could
migration? (ii) What are the costs faced by migrants, with a particular reasonably deem the number of internal migrants to exceed 1 billion
focus on costs that result from travel, information and financing costs, as people.
well as policy and institutional barriers? (iii) What are the impacts of The lack of a recent estimate for internal migration at the global scale
migration on migrants, their families, labor markets, productivity and reflects the relative scarcity of measures of internal migration at national
economic development? levels, especially in developing countries. This is understandable in light
Focusing on these three broad questions allows us to capture recent of conceptual issues and data gaps, which we discuss sequentially below:
changes in internal migration processes as well as emerging evidence on First, internal migration patterns are heterogenous, with migration
barriers to migration and impacts of migration. Much of the economics simultaneously occurring from rural to urban areas but also between
literature in the past focused on voluntary migration responding to labor rural areas and from urban to rural areas. Which patterns are observed in
market conditions. There is now increasing realization among econo- a given country seems to reflect the country's development stage as
mists that rural-to-urban migration choices are not solely driven by dif- initially theorized in human geography by Zelinsky (1971). In large
ferences in labor market outcomes between destination and origin areas developing countries undergoing urbanization, especially in South Asia
and that other factors, such as amenity differences, are also important. and Sub-Saharan Africa—where the rural population is still dispropor-
Involuntary migration due to climate change, wars and conflicts is tionately large—there are significant internal migration flows from rural
becoming increasingly more frequent in developing countries. A surge of to urban areas (Brueckner and Lall, 2015). Although internal migration
involuntary migration is expected in the Africa region due to droughts, between rural areas is much less documented given the lack of data and
and across Asia due to sea level rise (Hauer et al., 2020). Conflicts around lack of attention paid to the phenomenon until recently, rural-rural flows
the world produced a sizeable number of internally displaced population are likely to also be very large and could even exceed urban-rural flows as
with 50.8 million internally displaced persons at the end of 2019, 45.7 a few studies seem to indicate (Lucas, 1997). On the contrary, in the
million due to conflict and 5.1 million due to disasters, the highest figures relatively more urbanized countries of Latin America and East Asia, it is
ever recorded (Internal Displacement Monitoring Centre and Norwegian urban-to-urban migration which predominates (Lucas, 2016). As for
Refugee Council, 2020). How these involuntary migrations are affecting urban-to-rural migration, it is much less studied in the literature but
the urbanization and structural transformation processes is thus a serious could also represent sizeable flows, especially in countries at earlier
policy concern and has motivated a number of recent studies on phases of economic development as in Sub-Saharan Africa (Cattaneo and
rural-urban migration. Robinson, 2020). Urban-rural migration is also an emerging phenome-
The outline of the paper is as follows: Section 1 of this paper discusses non in developed countries where it could be occurring as part of a
the measurement, concepts and trends of internal migration (including broader movement of relocation away from densely populated areas and
rural-urban migration), followed by Section 2 which reviews recent ev- in response to a renewed attraction by the rural lifestyle—a phenomenon
idence on the drivers of migration. Moving away from the assumption of that could be further accelerated by the COVID-19 pandemic.
costless migration retained in the very early literature, migration re- Second, the measure of internal migration is further complicated by
searchers now recognize that market failures (e.g. incomplete credit and the duration of migration spells, as migration may be temporary or
insurance markets), policy and institutional barriers are likely to be permanent. In this respect, internal migration is more likely to be per-
major sources of migration costs in developing countries. Recent evi- manent when reflecting a trend towards urbanization in the country, and
dence on the implications of these failures and barriers along with more seasonal in contexts where internal migrants keep an activity in the rural
traditional costs of migration is reviewed in Section 3. In view of the area during the agricultural season. It is worth to note that temporary
recent literature on the causes and costs on rural-urban migration, Sec- migration often takes the shape of return migration, a phenomenon that
tion 4 reviews the impacts on well-being of migrants’ families, produc- remains insufficiently studied but which is increasingly attracting the
tivity and employment transition, and labor market adjustments. A attention of demographers and economists: Using Demographic and
concluding section discusses research gaps and policy lessons. Household Surveys for 31 developing countries in different regions,
Cattaneo and Robinson (2020) find that a significant fraction of internal
2. Patterns and trends of internal migration migration from rural areas to cities results in return migration to a rural
area. They find that it is highest in Sub-Saharan African countries where
Although international migration is front and center in policy de- between 7 and 51 percent of male and between 3 and 32 percent of fe-
bates, the number of international migrants (272 million people or 2.8 male rural-to-urban migrants end up returning to a rural area at some
percent of the global population in 2019 according to the International stage of their life cycle.
Office for Migration) is dwarfed by the number of internal migrants, Third, data constraints also significantly affect measures of internal
which could be at least 3 or 4 times larger. To the best of our knowledge, migration. As already mentioned, the geographic level at which data is
the most recent figure published in the literature on internal migration at collected–and its classification in urban and rural areas–but also the
the global scale dates back to 2005, with 763 million internal migrants or temporal horizon over which migration flows are measured have sig-
11.7 percent of the world's population at the time (Bell and nificant impacts on internal migration estimates (Bell et al., 2018).
Charles-Edwards 2013). The figure is based on a measure of lifetime Because of this, lack of harmonized data makes comparison of migration
migration (defined by current residence in an area that differs from the flows across countries a rather difficult exercise. Internal migration es-
area of birth). This figure is only an estimate given that the authors had to timates can indeed be obtained from heterogenous sources: They can be
calculated from population censuses in cases where households are asked

2
Bell and Charles-Edwards (2013) explain that their global estimate was
3
obtained by calculating a population-weighted average of migration intensities To ensure comparability across countries, the authors used first-level
(the propensity of population to move across sub-divisions) across four broad administrative sub-divisions. Because people are generally more mobile across
regions using the migration intensities from 66 countries for which data were shorter distances, the figure is thus likely underestimated compared to a mea-
available. sure of internal migration at a finer geographic level.

2
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

their previous place of residence (usually at the municipality or region 3. The drivers of rural-urban migration
level) at a specified date (often one or five years before) or at birth.
Alternatively, household surveys may ask the same questions or collect In this section, we present the main insights as well as recent de-
more precise information on past migration history. Administrative data velopments from an abundant literature that focuses on the causes of
may also be used to estimate migration stocks and flows. Interestingly, migration, starting with the decision to migrate. We focus to the extent
cell phone data (Call Detail Records) offer new avenues to measure possible on rural-urban migration but also comment, when useful, on
migration at different spatial and temporal scales as demonstrated by papers that more broadly address internal migration. With the exception
Blumenstock et al. (2019) for Rwanda, Lai et al. (2019) for Namibia and of forced migration, economists view the individual or family decision to
Beine et al. (2021) for Turkey. For more detailed discussion of data and migrate as a rational choice that weighs expected benefits against costs.
measurement issues, we refer readers to Kirchberger (forthcoming). In this setting, rural-urban migration is a response to factors that affect
Unfortunately, the available data usually does not make it possible to the desirability of urban life over rural life (such as improved income,
clearly disentangle rural-urban migration from overall internal migration education quality or health services available in the city, or negative
flows. Cross-country comparisons are thus usually made for internal income shocks in the rural areas). How much these gains from migration
migration as broadly defined. Bell et al. (2015) for instance provide es- to cities are valued by migrants may in turn depend on a series of other
timates of permanent internal migration intensities around the factors, including information potential migrants may have about the
2000–2010 decade for a large number of countries but without dis- returns to migration and their expectations about those returns, the op-
tinguishing whether origin or destination areas are rural or urban. They portunities that migration provides them to diversify risk with an urban
find on average higher migration intensities in developed countries income, their aversion towards risk, or the relative social status they may
(North America, Western Europe and Oceania) than in developing derive from migrating and sending remittances. The gains from
countries. In the developing world, according to their data, Asia has the migrating to cities need to be weighed against the costs faced by migrants
lowest migration intensity and Latin America and Africa stand at inter- (which are presented in Section 3). For clarity of exposition, we present
mediate levels. Migration intensities are however very heterogeneous the drivers of migration sequentially and in isolation from one another.
within regions, with high migration intensities in Northern Africa The decision to migrate, however, is multifaceted and ultimately ac-
(Morocco) and parts of West and East Africa (Senegal, Cameroon, Guinea, counts for a combination of all these factors.
Tanzania, Kenya) and Southern Africa (South Africa and Zambia) but low
migration intensities elsewhere on the continent. As for Latin America, 3.1. Higher urban incomes
Andean countries have higher migration intensities than other countries
of the region, and in Asia, the Republic of Korea is the most mobile In the wake of the Harris-Todaro model, economists have considered
country whereas India is the least mobile of all Asian countries.4 that internal migration is mainly a response to differential labor market
A longitudinal look at the existing data over the past decades shows opportunities across space, with higher incomes in urban areas acting as
that the intensity of internal migration has not followed a single trend but a pull factor for rural dwellers.6 Numerous empirical papers have thus
has varied significantly within and across regions: Studying internal focused on estimating the role of labor market differentials between
migration flows up to 2010 in the sample of countries for which data urban and rural areas, especially in terms of labor income, as the driving
were available, Bell et al. (2018) find that internal migration mostly force leading to internal migration. This approach raises a series of
tended to decline in the 21 Latin American countries they studied—with econometric challenges, with one of the main empirical issues being to be
the exception of Brazil and Chile—; that it either stagnated or declined in able to correctly estimate counterfactual incomes for migrants (i.e., the
the 8 Sub-Saharan African countries in their sample—with the exception income of migrants had they stayed) and for non-migrants (i.e., the in-
of Mali which experienced a very strong increase—; and that there was a come of non-migrants had they moved) by correcting for migrant selec-
mix of both declining and rising intensity of internal migration in the 9 tivity. Failure to do so biases estimates of the migration's response to
Asian countries for which they had data, with the notable cases of China, income differences between urban and rural areas.7 Another issue is to be
Indonesia and Vietnam, which faced a very significant increase in their able to account for multiple destination areas. Whereas earlier studies
internal migration intensity—some of it likely due to the presence and modeled migration decisions with multinomial logits that needed to as-
effectiveness of migration policies as discussed in Bell et al. (2020)).5 sume independence of irrelevant alternatives—a rather unrealistic
These evolutions do not show a clear link on average to the level of assumption—non-parametric approaches have made it possible to
development, and no clear regional pattern seems to emerge with the circumvent this issue while also allowing to estimate individual migra-
exception of the decrease in migration intensity in Latin America and an tion decisions in the presence of numerous potential destinations (see
increase in Europe (Bell et al., 2015, 2018). To our knowledge, unfor- Dahl, 2002).8 Another problem is the appropriate measure of income to
tunately, no comparative study has been published using data from the be considered when empirically modeling migration as a response to
most recent decade so that global and regional internal migration trends income differentials. One would ideally want to use discounted expected
over recent years remain insufficiently documented. streams of real income (not unadjusted nominal wages) or at least to be
In the rest of the paper, we will mostly focus on rural-urban migra- able to account in some way for variations in costs of living across
tion, which is a core feature of economic development and has attracted geographic areas. Beyond gross income, monetary transfers and re-
the most attention in the economic literature. mittances should also be accounted for, but the data are often lacking.

6
The focus on labor markets as the main drivers of internal migration is
4
Bell et al. (2015) report aggregate crude migration intensities at 5 years prominent in the migration literature (see e.g., Stark, 1991 compilation of
(ratio of the number of internal migrants during the transition period to the migration research papers entitled The Migration of Labor).
7
population at risk of moving) that are, for instance, in the range of 5 percent in See Lanzona (1998) and McKenzie et al. (2010) for examples of corrections
India and the Arab Republic of Egypt, 10 percent in Nicaragua, the Islamic for migrant selectivity in this context.
8
Republic of Iran, and Thailand, 20 percent in Morocco, 30 percent in Cameroon, Dahl (2002)'s approach is applied to internal migration in the United States
40 percent in the United States, and 50 percent in Korea. and relies on the estimation of a wage equation for a subsample of migrants,
5
The assessment is based on internal migration intensity during 1 and 5-year correcting for selection, but without having to specify the location choice pro-
periods using population censuses until 2010. In developed countries, there are cess. The probability of migrating between locations is estimated
also heterogenous trends: In North America and Oceania, migration intensity non-parametrically using the frequency estimator for individuals that share the
unequivocally declined, whereas migration intensity stagnated or decreased in same observed characteristics (education and age), assuming that they are
some European countries but increased in other European countries. affected in the same way by the determinants of migration.

3
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

Finally, the model can be misspecified if other relevant factors that affect paved roads. It is important to note here that urban amenities that might
migrant utility are omitted and not controlled for, an issue which is likely attract migrants may extend beyond infrastructure to also include social
to arise given the multiplicity of factors affecting migration decisions. and educational opportunities in cities. In this respect, Fu and Gabriel
Spanning over several decades, economists have gradually improved (2012) who study internal migration flows across Chinese provinces in
the treatment of these issues and have produced robust evidence on the the 1990s find that high-skill migrants valued the human capital con-
role of income or wage differentials as drivers of internal migration (see centration of destination areas but that low-skill migrants did not. Such
the examples cited in Lall et al., 2006). A number of recently published heterogenous preferences can possibly be explained by the higher bar-
studies presents migration as an equilibrating force and estimates how riers faced by low-skill migrants for their own human capital investment.
internal migration flows responds to local labor market differences. This could also be because low-skill migrants in the 1990s in China had
Imbert and Papp (2019) for instance show that a large workfare program limited potential to interact with high-skill workers in destination areas.
which hired rural adults during the agricultural off-season in India—a
scheme likely to reduce the income gap between rural and urban area-
s—had a significant impact on deterring seasonal migration to cities. Two 3.3. Income shocks in rural areas (from climate change and conflicts)
other recent papers—although not explicitly focusing on rural urban
migration—provide additional insights: Studying France over the Because of an intensification in climate change and the rise in con-
long-period, Detang-Dessendre et al. (2016) investigate how internal flicts, notably in the Middle East and Sub-Saharan Africa, there is
migration across the country's roughly 300 employment zones responded renewed interest to study the impact of climatic shocks and violent
to local employment growth—alongside with other responses in terms of conflicts on rural-urban migration. Interestingly, although the literature
local labor force participation, local employment rate and commuting confirms that both can act as push factors, the mechanisms at work and
patterns across employment zones.9 The authors find that 70 to 85 the nature of migration flows can be quite different.
percent of the adjustment to changes in local employment conditions
occurred through external responses in migration and commuting. 3.3.1. Climatic shocks
Similarly, Cadena and Kovak (2016) find that local labor demand shocks A series of papers analyzes how climatic shocks can negatively affect
during the Great Recession in the United States have led to internal crops and reduce agricultural incomes in rural areas, leading to out-
migration responses. Interestingly, they find a greater migration response migration to cities. Using country-level panel data for 78 countries over 3
from Mexican-born low-skill workers than from natives, a pattern which decades (between 1960 and 1990), Barrios et al. (2006) show that
they attribute to the greater labor-force attachment of Mexican-born decline in rainfall accelerated urbanization in Sub-Saharan Africa, but do
workers and their large social networks that could have helped them not find evidence of a similar effect elsewhere in the developing world. In
more easily acquire information on where to relocate. the wake of the Barrios et al. (2006) paper, other papers have investi-
Observe that not all papers in the literature, however, find that gated the conditions under which climatic shocks cause migration to
migration occurs towards areas that exhibit better labor market out- cities, finding nuanced results. Peri and Sasahara (2019) find that rising
comes. In fact, the positive association between income differentials and temperatures do not in fact accelerate rural-urban migration in poor
migration is not required to hold in all circumstances. It may not hold for countries but rather reduce it, although they increase rural-urban
instance if realized incomes turn out to be lower than expected incomes, migration in middle-income countries, a differentiated result that is
or in the presence of imperfect information (if migrants miscalculate the consistent with liquidity constraints preventing outmigration from rural
returns on migration in their chosen location), or given trade-offs over areas in poor countries (see Section 3 of this survey). Similarly, Grace
time (if migrants accept low incomes upon arrival in the city but expect et al. (2018) who look at climatic shocks at an even finer scale (i.e.,
greater incomes in the future as they become assimilated or as they focusing on individual outmigration strategies in two rural communities
accumulate city-specific specific human capital and become more pro- in Mali), find that decreases in rainfall did not lead to outmigration,
ductive over time— see evidence of this on Spain presented by De la which they believe is due to a reduction in the resources available to fund
Roca, 2017, and De la Roca and Puga, 2017). migration and also to the lack of destination areas with better economic
prospects. The context under which climatic shocks are related to the
economic environment is studied Henderson et al. (2017) who focus on
3.2. Better urban amenities the impact of climate variability (as measured by decline in moisture) at a
fine geographic scale (districts and cities) in 29 Sub-Saharan African
Besides income opportunities, access to urban amenities can also be a countries over 5 decades (1960–2009). The authors find strong evidence
key factor motivating rural-urban migration. As matter of fact, because of that adverse changes in climate push people out of rural areas into
compensating differentials linking wages to amenities and costs of living neighboring urban areas but only in districts that have a manufacturing
(as in the models of Roback, 1982, and Diamond, 2016 10), studies of base that allows for an “escape” into export-based employment. Other
migration decisions should not only consider the role of wages but also authors have tried to compare the strength of climatic determinants to
simultaneously account for amenities and costs of living.11 To our that of other drivers in explaining internal migration. In the specific case
knowledge, however, only a few empirical studies assess the role of of the Republic of Yemen, Joseph and Wodon (2013) find that although
amenities as drivers of internal migration. An example is Shilpi et al. climatic variables (temperature, rainfall and their variability) do indeed
(2014) who confirm that internal migrants in Nepal attach a value to play a role in explaining internal migration, the magnitude of the effect
infrastructure and services, namely access to electricity and proximity to on internal migration is much smaller compared to that of
socio-economic variables.
Another line of papers investigates the nature of internal migration
9
To address the endogeneity of local employment growth, the authors in- caused by climatic shocks. Some papers argue that outmigration could
strument it with Bartik (1991) instruments, where the instruments are con- play an important role in reconstruction processes. For instance, Gr€ oger
structed assuming that national employment conditions carry over to local areas and Zylberberg (2016) find that a typhoon in Vietnam led to rural out-
based on their past industrial mix. migration of household members sending remittances to affected areas.
10
Insights from these models and the economic geography literature show Other papers ask whether there is heterogeneity in the response to cli-
that, in general, cities that attract and remunerate skills also tend to offer more matic shocks. In the case of Tanzania, Kubik and Maurel (2016) find that
amenities and command high rents.
11
From an econometric standpoint, not controlling for amenities or the cost-of-
living in a migration decision regression would introduce a correlation between
the error term and wages, biasing the estimation.

4
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

outmigration from rural areas following weather shocks is conditional on investments when incomes are volatile (in particular, due to climatic
initial wealth endowment and that selectively occurs in the middle of the risks and volatility of agricultural prices). Paradoxically, poor access to
wealth distribution (as poorer households cannot afford migration costs credit can also provide incentives to migrate out of rural areas that have
and richer households do not need to respond to shocks through spatial high production potential in order to gather the necessary funds to
diversification).12 Other papers investigate whether climatic shocks lead finance profitable investments in these areas (Katz and Stark, 1986).
to temporary or permanent relocation. This strand of literature seems to Recent studies confirm the above mechanisms with some interesting
indicate that sporadic shocks could lead to temporary migration whereas qualifications. Poelhekke (2011) studies 163 countries between 1970
long-term climatic trends (like soil salinization or desertification) could and 2000 and finds that periods of aggregate agricultural risk turn out to
lead to more permanent migration. In the case of China, Minale (2018) be robust additional predictors of urban growth. In China, grain sub-
finds that a one standard deviation in rainfall leads to a 5 percent increase sidies—which provide insurance against price volatility—are found to
in migration to cities, reflecting both new departures but also longer reduce outmigration of rural areas to cities (Meng, 2012). In Tanzania,
spells spent in cities. In view of these results, it is likely that dramatic Kubik and Maurel (2016) find that a reduction in income from weather
climatic change could accelerate permanent migration and reduce tem- shocks (measured by evapotranspiration, temperature and precipitation)
porary migration. stimulates outmigration within the following year for households whose
income is dependent on agriculture but not for those who have a diver-
3.3.2. Violent conflicts sified income. Similarly, Morten (2019), who develops a structural model
As with climate change, there is renewed interest and evidence to study the substitutability of temporary migration in India and
regarding the role of violent conflicts leading to both international and village-level risk-sharing mechanisms, finds that if risk-sharing is
internal migration (internally displaced people in Latin America, Sub- improved, temporary migration is reduced (and vice-versa). The author
Saharan Africa and the Middle East). Violence can potentially accel- also finds that the impact of India's large rural employment scheme
erate rural-urban migration in contexts where cities are safer than rural would be to substitute both for informal insurance and temporary
areas. The actual empirical evidence, however, is subject to debate as the migration by raising rural incomes. Munshi and Rosenzweig (2016) who
link is not as straightforward to establish, and because current findings study internal migration choices in the context of informal insurance
are somewhat nuanced and point to different mechanisms than in the networks provided by castes in India's rural areas present a somewhat
case of climatic shocks. In the case of the Guatemalan civil war (which different picture. The authors find that migration choices can in fact be
lasted from 1960 to 1996), Morrison (1993) finds that although political deterred by a household's fear of losing informal insurance if a household
violence against guerrillas in rural areas (assassinations) led to migration member migrates. This is because households with migrants become less
to cities, the response to economic variables was significantly larger than credible in their commitment to honor future obligations and might have
the response to violence variables.13 Studying the migration response to incentives to underreport their urban income to other caste members. In
violence in Colombia, Engel and Iban ~ ez (2007) find that violence this context the provision of formal insurance will increase rather than
accelerated urbanization. Their findings also suggest that risk aversion decrease migration.
might increase rather than decrease the propensity to migrate (as in-
dividuals with high risk aversion are more eager to leave and avoid the 4. The costs of migration
risk of violence). Poor information can also facilitate rather than deter
migration as potential refugees may not have accurate information on the When making a migration decision, potential migrants weigh the
precarious conditions that displacement would expose them to. Finally, utility gains against the costs associated with their decision. Migrants
wealth at the place of origin might provide an incentive rather than a may face significant costs both at the origin and destination besides the
disincentive to migrate as wealthier households will be at an increased actual travel cost to the destination area, including travel and subsistence
risk of violence in the origin area. In contrast, Basu and Pearlman (2017) costs during job and residence search, the psychological distress of
study the impact of homicides related to the drug war in Mexico on in- leaving family members behind and maintaining relationships from far
ternal migration but find little evidence that violence at the state and away, the difficulties of assimilation in destination areas with cultural,
municipal levels—which they instrument with highways interacted with ethnic, religious and linguistic backgrounds that differ from their own,
shocks to the cocaine supply from Colombia—led to any increased do- and opportunity costs of foregone activities in the rural area of origin.
mestic migration. Institutions (e.g., social norms and traditions) or policies may further
erect barriers which affect migrants’ returns to migration or facilitate or
restrict migration. This section reviews the literature on various migra-
3.4. Insurance against risks
tion costs, distinguishing between travel, information and financing cost,
policy barriers and institutional barriers.
Studies have highlighted the role of absent or incomplete insurance
and credit markets (i.e., capital market imperfections) and the lack of
4.1. Travel, information, and financing costs
income diversification opportunities in rural areas as causes of rural-
urban migration (Stark and Levhari, 1982). In this context, migration
4.1.1. Physical distance and monetary migration costs
plays the role of a “self-insuring” mechanism that allows for diversifi-
Invariably, all empirical studies of the migration decision control for
cation of incomes in the face of uncertainty as migrants can generate
migration costs, either by using distances between origin and destination
income for themselves or others left in the rural areas to whom they send
as explanatory variables or by introducing origin-destination fixed ef-
remittances. Interestingly, the decision to migrate is not necessarily taken
fects, which can capture a wider range of bilateral migration costs
by isolated individuals but might often involve family arrangements for
beyond the ones correlated with distance. The overwhelming evidence is
co-insurance between individuals who face risks at different times (Stark
that distance matters significantly in the migration decision as migrants
and Lucas, 1988). The absence of a credit market in rural areas might also
usually tend not to relocate far from their area of origin. The distance
encourage migration by preventing farmers to smooth their expenses and
coefficients are found, however, to differ by groups, with a negative as-
sociation that is much sharper for the relatively unskilled and poorer
12
Other papers in the literature also report that poverty hinders outmigration. workers (see evidence of this in Shilpi et al. (2018) on South Africa, Lall,
Guriev and Vakulenko (2015) for instance find that increased incomes in the Timmins and Yu (2009) on Brazil, and Shrestha (2020) on Nepal). In
Russian Federation's poorer regions increases outmigration. most specifications, the distance coefficient captures all migration costs
13 that vary with distance, such as for instance information about destina-
Of course, economic variables themselves could be influenced by violence,
which somewhat weakens the identification. tion areas. It should be noted that similarly to the distance coefficient in a

5
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

gravity equation of trade flows which not only captures trade costs but opposite direction and deters migration, especially for the poor who
also differences in comparative advantage, the distance coefficient in a depend on such networks disproportionately. In contrast, Meghir et al.
migration flow analysis reflects various costs associated with migration (2019) find evidence that randomly subsidizing outmigration of poorer
as well as the differences in migrants’ relative selectivity over distance households at the village level can end up increasing risk sharing within
(Bryan and Morten, 2019). A structural analysis is thus useful to try and the village when migration is risky.
separate out the cost component from that of the selectivity component.
In a study using structural modeling, Morten and Oliveira (2016) con- 4.1.4. Information and migration
siders the effects of road improvement in Brazil that reduced both trade There is an interesting focus in the recent literature on the way
and migration costs. They found welfare improvement due to this project migrant networks transmit information. A number of studies specifically
came mainly from the reduction in trade cost. Although reduction in focus on the cost of accessing information about jobs: In a randomized
migration cost led to smaller overall welfare gains, gains were substantial control experiment in Niger, Aker, Clemens and Ksoll (2011) find that
in some regions. individuals in a treatment group of cell-phone recipients who were able
to keep in contact with their friends in towns increased their seasonal
4.1.2. Socio-cultural distance migration to towns significantly compared with a control group with no
As with the physical and financial costs of migration, migrants face cell phone. Baseler (2021) runs an information experiment where resi-
additional costs due to differences in language, ethnicity and religion.14 dents of randomly selected Kenyan villages received information about
Fafchamps and Shilpi (2013) find that social proximity has a strong wages and prices of food in Nairobi and other urban centers and about
significant effect on migrants’ choices of destination in Nepal: Migrants the most common jobs for migrants in each potential destination. In a
move primarily to areas where many people share their language and second experiment, the author provided full information about income
ethnic background. Bauernschuster et al. (2014) report a similar and savings of families of migrants to other randomly selected villagers.
importance of cultural differences in determining the migration decision Both of these interventions raised expectations about average urban
of skilled workers in Germany. Potential for successful integration also wages and increased migration to Nairobi by 40 percent. The results from
relate to ethnic diversity at the place of destination: For instance, Bazzi this study show, however, that even though villages may have many
et al. (2019) report that migrants living in communities with diverse migrants in cities, the information about income and job prospects is not
ethnic backgrounds integrate better than those in communities domi- widely shared within the village from migrant families to non-migrant
nated by few ethnic groups. families. We should also note here that these findings are context spe-
cific. For instance, Bryan et al. (2014)–a study we discuss in more detail
4.1.3. Social networks later–did not find any impact of information provision in their random-
The social networks of migrants can play a critical role in determining ized control study in Bangladesh.
both migration flows across areas and migrant outcomes in destination The cost of acquiring information could also be substantial. Porcher
areas (see Section 4) by reducing costs associated with migration. (2020) uses a structural model applied to Brazil to show that the costs to
Importantly, social networks may not only act as a conduit of information acquire information account for about half of overall migration costs.
about jobs availability at destination but can also provide a safety net Other studies focus on the effects of access to information and how it can
through social support. On this, we refer the reader to Munshi (2020) dispel unrealistic expectation of migrants about job availability, income
who surveys the vast literature on the relationship between community and living conditions at destination, and help migrants better choose
networks and migration and only report here new insights from select their destination areas. There is evidence of this in the study by Farre and
recent work. An innovative approach to study the role of migrant net- Fasani (2013) who find that, in Indonesia, media exposure through
works in migration decisions is presented in Blumenstock et al. (2019) television reduces inter-regional migration significantly (1.7–2.7
who use a rich ‘digital trace’ dataset (CDR) in Rwanda that allows to percent). In his Brazil study, Porcher (2020) finds that by allowing
draw conclusions on the type of network that matters in driving migra- workers to make better mobility choices, expansion of internet access
tion decisions by observing the relocation choices made by millions of reduces migration flows by a magnitude similar to TV exposure in
individuals over several years, as well as the complete social network of Indonesia.
each person in the months before and after migration. The authors make
a distinction between networks that provide social and economic support 4.1.5. Credit constraints
(interconnected networks, with clustering of friends in the locality) in Whether potential migrants are able to fund migration depends on
addition to information and those that transmit mainly information their access to credit. Job search can be prolonged requiring migrants to
(expansive networks, where individuals in the network are not all con- be able to stay at the destination area during periods of job search. As the
nected with one another). While the authors confirm the findings in the poor may not have financial savings to support extended job search, this
previous literature that people tend to migrate to places with larger social should adversely affect their migration propensity. Credit constraints
networks, they are able to estimate the effects of interconnected vs should thus further hinder the migration of the poor relative to the rich
expansive network on migration, finding that migrants are more likely to who are less subject to credit constraints and should more easily be able
go to places where they have ‘interconnected’ networks but less likely to to fund their migration. In line with these mechanisms, several papers
go to places where their networks are expansive. provide robust causal evidence of the presence of credit constraints and
Another strand of recent literature confirms how social support and of how credit constraints differentially affect the rich and the poor.
mutual insurance within networks may either stimulate or curb migra- Ardington, Case, and Hosegood (2009) find that, in South Africa, the
tion. Kinnan, Wang and Wang (2018) show that a mandatory program of arrival of old age pensions in the household increases migration of
temporary migration from urban to rural areas in the 1960s and 1970s in prime-aged adults to cities as households are able to support these mi-
China created lasting linkages between sending and receiving areas, grants until they become self-sufficient. Using a regression discontinuity
subsequently explaining migration flows from rural to urban areas. design, Eggleston et al. (2018) confirm similar effects of pensions on
Focusing on India, Munshi and Rosenzweig (2016) show that whereas out-migration from rural China. Cai (2020) randomizes the rollout of a
having a strong social network at the destination area encourages microfinance program in rural Chinese villages and shows that house-
migration and creates path dependence in migration patterns, an holds receiving micro-finance loans are much more likely to seasonally
informal mutual insurance network at the origin area plays in the send migrants to nearby cities. Poggi (2019) studies the impact of the
Village Fund scheme in Thailand (a large microcredit scheme that ad-
ministers loans to households) and finds that it reduced outmigration,
14
These differences also tend to grow with migration distance. although only in the medium term. This finding suggests that in the

6
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

context of Thailand, migrants were perhaps not credit constrained. It is 4.2.2. Entitlement and subsidy policies
also possible that Village Fund may have opened up profitable employ- An additional class of barriers to migration are policies which end up
ment opportunities within the villages outweighing the effect of relaxing reducing migration even if doing so was not an intended objective.
credit constraint to fund migration. A lesson from the above studies is Entitlement programs and other policies targeted to rural residents often
that to detect credit constraints, it is preferable to rely on targeted credit have such unintended consequences. Imbert and Papp (2020) who
intervention such as in Cai (2020) than on a broad intervention such as studied the effect of India's rural public works program find that seasonal
Thai Village Fund which may have involved other mechanisms than just migration from rural districts that implemented the program decreased
the ease of constraints on funding migration.15 relative to those that were selected but did not implement it. Similarly,
using detailed district-to-district migration data from the 2001 Census of
India, Kone et al. (2018) find that average migration between neigh-
4.2. Policy barriers to migration
boring districts in the same state is at least 50 percent larger than
neighboring districts on different sides of a state border. Such large state
The previous sub-sections reviewed studies that highlighted various
border effects arise from differences in state-level entitlement schemes,
migration costs that an individual migrant may face. Public policies can
ranging from access to subsidized goods through the public distribution
play a role in relaxing some of the constraints discussed earlier. The
system to the bias for states' own residents in access to tertiary education
examples of a potential public role include transport investment to
and public sector employment.
reduce travel time and cost, cash transfer programs to relax credit con-
straints, and connecting migrants to diaspora to overcome information
4.3. Institutional barriers to migration
asymmetry. There are, however, many instances where governments in
developing countries intentionally or unintentionally create barriers to
4.3.1. Land tenure and land markets in rural areas
migration. This section reviews the recent literature on the ways gov-
Migrants may face institutional barriers at their places of origin as
ernment policies or practices may discourage or restrict migration, which
well. Most such restrictions identified in the literature relate to Property
is much more common than programs aiming at facilitating internal
rights and tenurial arrangements regarding agricultural land.
mobility.
Land inheritance practices. Cultural and institutional aspects regarding
land inheritance in rural areas can significantly influence the process of
4.2.1. Migration restrictions
rural-urban migration. The impacts of inheritance reforms are however
In developing countries, migrants face significant regulatory and
context specific. In pre-war Japan, for instance, patriarchy forced the son
institutional barriers. Among the legal barriers, perhaps the most well-
designated as heir—primarily the first-born—to stay in agriculture,
known is the Hukou household registration system, which has long
slowing migration to urban areas and structural transformation. In this
been used by the Chinese government to regulate unskilled migration
context, post-war inheritance reforms—leading to equal shares of agri-
from rural areas to cities. In China, every household has a Hukou regis-
cultural land for all children—led to a mass exodus of younger cohorts of
tration booklet which gives them one of two statuses: agricultural/rural
labor force out of rural areas, and a sharp change in employment patterns
or non-agricultural/urban. Since 1949, migration from rural areas to
which were accompanied by an increase in growth of per capita income
cities was strictly prohibited, and only weakly tolerated after 1983. Since
(Hayashi and Prescott, 2008). The findings for other countries are
2002, although the Hukou system is still in place, the national govern-
however different. Using household panel data and exogenous timing of
ment has been trying to facilitate migration, but implementation remains
land redistribution in Ethiopia, Kosec et al. (2018) find that larger ex-
very poor, with larger municipalities still imposing significant hurdles to
pected land inheritances significantly lower the likelihood of
prevent holders of agricultural Hukou from enjoying social welfare
long-distance permanent migration and of permanent migration to urban
benefits (Sun, 2019). The reluctance of cities to completely open up to
areas. Inheriting more land also leads to a significantly higher likelihood
rural-urban migration can be explained by their fear of having to bear
of employment in agriculture and a lower likelihood of employment in
significant costs to provide social services to migrants. This type of
the non-agricultural sector. Abramitzky et al. (2013) show that 19th
household registration system is also found in other developing countries
century Norwegian men who could expect to inherit wealth from their
such as Vietnam (Ho Khau) and Ethiopia. In Ethiopia, migrants are
parents (as measured by the Property tax their parents paid), especially
required to show proof of residence to access government services and
elder sons who were more likely to inherit the land, were less likely to
apply for formal jobs. Such proof, however, is often difficult to provide
migrate internally and internationally.
when migrants are staying with friends or families.
Property rights and tenure insecurity. The nature and enforceability of
Migration restrictions can impose high economic costs on migrants
property rights in origin areas can affect migration decisions. Having
and the economy as a whole. For example, in China, migrants who want
formal property rights on agricultural land could positively affect rural-
to enroll their children in schools in urban areas face additional fees and
urban migration as it makes land a more liquid asset and in turn eases
associated costs, which often force rural migrant families to leave their
financial constraints. Another reason is that formal property rights pro-
children behind, especially if they have a daughter, and instead send
vide tenure security to owners who may migrate without the risk of
remittances to pay for the education of children left behind (Dang et al.,
losing their asset, and strengthen the option migrants may have to keep a
2020).16
source of income from renting out their plot, or to return to their origin
Apart from direct restrictions such as household registration, gov-
area in case of an unsuccessful migration. When formal mechanisms to
ernments may also deter migration by investing less in the public services
secure property rights are not accessible or land transfers are restricted,
needed by migrants. For instance, during the dictatorship in Brazil, richer
migrant households may respond either by stopping migration altogether
and larger urban areas were found to withhold the provision of water and
or by deciding to leave household members behind (split migration) in
sewerage connections to smaller houses in which poorer migrants would
order to maintain their claims over family-controlled plots. On the other
live in order to discourage their in-migration and deflect them to other
hand, tenure insecurity can decrease the expected returns from land in-
localities (Feler and Henderson, 2011).
vestments in the origin area, which encourages outmigration. The liter-
ature indicates that most empirical findings point towards the first effect
15
Access to credit also affects the ability of rural dwellers to smooth their dominating the second, with tenure insecurity curbing outmigration.
incomes which would reduce the incentive for migration in case of a shock. Using the rollout of the Mexican land certification program from 1993 to
16
Migrants may also face labor market discrimination. For instance, Song 2006, De Janvry et al. (2015) find that households that obtained certif-
(2016) shows that, in China, holders of rural hukous are paid less than holders icates were subsequently 28 percent more likely to have a migrant
of urban hukous working in State Owned Enterprises in the urban sector. member. Chernina, Dower, and Markevich (2014) find that the 1906

7
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

Stolypin land titling reform—which facilitated the transition from (2020) examine the returns to migration for rural-urban migrants using
communal land rights to individual land rights in tsarist Russia- nationally representative surveys in China, Ghana, Indonesia, Malawi,
—increased the liquidity of land and had a sizeable positive effect on South Africa, and Tanzania. The authors rely on nationally representative
inter-provincial migration in Russia. In the case of Sri Lanka, Emran and panel surveys which made considerable efforts to track migrants across
Shilpi (2017) show that land sales restrictions led to an increasing space. Estimated returns average about 25 percent across these six
feminization of rural labor as women were left to take over agricultural countries, which is still substantial.
activities while men migrated. Estimated returns to migration from experimental studies are also
Interestingly, even in contexts where land rights are not contested, found to be large. In a randomized control experiment in rural Northern
the prospect of a future land reallocation—a cyclical practice that can Bangladesh, Bryan, Chowdhury and Mobarak (2014) provide an $8.50
exist in customary land regimes as well as in socialist contexts—can play incentive to households to help them temporarily send at least a member
in a similar fashion as weak Property rights and deter outmigration. In to other areas during the lean season (when many rural households in
the context of Chinese rural areas, Giles and Mu (2018), for instance, Northern Bangladesh are on the brink of starvation). The authors find
show that the expectation of land reallocation following a village leader that migration induced by this intervention increased food and non-food
election reduces the probability of households to migrate. expenditures of migrants’ family members remaining at the origin by
The way land rental markets affect migration is also context specific 30–35 percent and improved their caloric intake by 550–700 calories per
and can be ambiguous. For instance, Mullan et al. (2011) find that person per day. From the randomization of a micro-finance program in
complete rental markets increase outmigration in China as migrants can rural China, Cai (2020) estimates that migrants experienced increases in
maintain an income in the origin area. On the contrary, Kosec et al. earnings of around 36 percent relative to the mean of the control group.
(2018) find that the existence of rural land markets in Ethiopia can curb The returns estimated in these experimental studies are actually similar
migration as they argue that land markets facilitate access to land, in magnitude to those found for Tanzania by Beegle et al. (2011).
attenuating reasons for migration. Finally, Hu, Xu and Chen (2011) find There is also evidence of large gains from quasi experimental studies
that the absence of land rental markets in some Chinese rural areas favors in which population was moved voluntarily as in resettlement programs
circular migration at the expense of permanent migration. (Bazzi et al., 2016; Sarvim€aki et al., 2019; Abramitzky et al., 2020) or
because of natural disasters (Nakamura et al., 2016). For example, Bazzi
5. Migrant outcomes and migration impacts et al. (2016) studied the Indonesian transmigration program which
relocated two million migrants from rural Java and Bali to new rural
An important focus of the rural-urban literature has been to assess the settlements in the Outer Islands. They report that in the early years of the
impact on the well-being of migrants themselves, on the well-being of program, 82 percent of the resettled households reported to have equal or
their families, on areas of origin and destination, and on the economy as a higher income after migration.
whole. Returns to rural-urban migration appear to be quite large even if one
considers the lower average estimate from nationally representative
studies. Bryan, Chowdhury and Mobarak (2014) note that even with such
5.1. Returns to migration
large returns, most households do not temporarily send members to
outside areas for work. This is because the utility cost of migration ap-
A key motivator behind migration is expected income and welfare
pears to be very large: Households that are close to subsistence levels fear
gains. How large are these gains? The available evidence suggests that
taking the risk of incurring the migration cost while not being able to find
there are large income gains from migration, particularly for the families
a job with potentially serious consequences for their food security. The
left behind at the origin. In a study of rural Indian individuals that were
implication of this finding is that insurances and nudges can be used to
surveyed in 1975 and again in 2005, Dercon et al. (2013) find that
stimulate migration. Consistent with this intuition, Bryan et al. (2014)
consumption per capita was 42 percent higher for those that migrated
find that the small nudge of $8.50 they provide in their experiment
since the first survey than for those that stayed put. Using a thirteen-year
induced 22 percent of households to send a seasonal migrant, and that
panel survey from northern Tanzania, Beegle, De Weerdt, and Dercon
treated households were 8–10 percentage points more likely to
(2014) report similar findings. Among the 912 households surveyed and
re-migrate 1 and 3 years after the incentive was removed. Building a
tracked, the authors find, after controlling for education, age, and other
model to replicate the results from the same experiment, Lagakos et al.
co-variates, that those moving out of the community had 36 percent
(2018) find that the welfare gain from subsidizing migration arises
higher consumption levels than those that remained behind. Their con-
mainly from the provision of insurance opportunities in periods when
sumption gains were positive even if they stayed employed in agriculture
households are vulnerable. The findings from Bryan et al. (2014) suggest
but much larger when they switched to non-agriculture or moved farther
that small assistance on the part of the government may be sufficient to
away.17 Similar large income gains are reported for Vietnam in Nguyen
induce poorer people living in vulnerable areas to take advantage of
et al. (2015).
better opportunities in nearby urban areas through temporary migration.
Households with migrants not only experience higher income and
This finding is particularly relevant for designing policy responses in
consumption, they tend to invest in durables as well. De Brauw and Giles
places which are vulnerable to climate change and conflict.
(2018) find significant increases in consumption in Chinese rural areas,
especially for poorer households, and in investments of both poorer and
richer households. They also find that poorer households tend to invest 5.2. Effects on the health and psychology of migrants
more in housing and durable goods while richer households tend to
invest more in non-agricultural production. The large income gains from migration but low actual migration rates
The studies discussed above, however, are based on surveys which are suggest the presence of high migration costs such as monetary and psy-
not nationally representative. Empirically, there is thus a concern as to chological costs, which we discussed in Section 3. In this subsection, we
whether these surveys are subject to selection biases which may artifi- review evidence regarding the impacts of migration on physical and
cially inflate or deflate estimates of returns to migration. Lagakos et al. mental health. Impacts on health are ambiguous as positive health im-
pacts from income effects can be counterbalanced by adverse living
conditions. Lu, Kandilov and Zhu (2020) find that rural-urban migrants
17
Observe that higher incomes in urban areas compared to rural areas does not in China, especially younger ones, experience a decline in their
preclude that migrants could be discriminated against. For instance, Song self-reported health, which they attribute to changes in emotional states
(2016) shows that, in China, holders of rural hukous are paid less than holders and social trust. Elderly parents of migrants left behind in the rural areas
of urban hukous working in State Owned Enterprises in the urban sector. are also more likely to be in poor health (Xiang et al., 2016).

8
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

There is also evidence of adverse psychological costs associated with capture the benefits of greater labor pooling facilitated by migrants, an
migration. In a lab experiment in China, Afridi et al. (2015) find that important source of urban agglomeration externality. This may to some
rural-urban migrant students who are assigned a task fare worse than extent explain the difference between the productivity benefits uncov-
their urban native counterparts when they are individually or publicly ered in the economywide studies discussed above and the productivity
reminded of their rural Hukou status. This suggests that psychology could reducing effects of migration found in the firm level study by Imbert et al.
explain part of the discrepancy in economic outcomes between migrants (2018).
and locals in a system that has long stigmatized migrants to cities.
5.3.2. Labor market impacts
5.3. Economywide impacts of migration The impacts of migration on local wages and employment depend on
several structural features of the labor market itself: whether there is
Migration entails large gains and costs for the migrants themselves rigidity and duality in the labor market as emphasized in the Harris-
and their families as we have seen above. As migrants respond to dif- Todaro model; the extent to which local labor markets are spatially in-
ferences in expected returns across areas, they are expected to contribute tegrated; and whether the skills of migrants are complementary or sub-
to reducing inter-regional differences in economic outcomes. They are stitutes to that of native workers. The labor market impacts of migration
also expected to have an impact on productivity growth throughout the may also depend on the behavioral responses of local workers in terms of
economy. In line with these expectations, this section reviews the rele- labor force participation, or even in terms of potential shifts to different
vant literature focusing on two key areas: productivity, and labor market occupations or to other local labor markets. Finally, short-term and long-
impacts. term effects may differ as economies adjust in the long run to greater
labor supply and to increased demand for consumption. We review below
5.3.1. Productivity the literature focusing on these different aspects of labor markets, dis-
Rural-urban migration is expected and observed to lead to structural tinguishing between impacts of migration on labor market equilibrium
transformation simply because of the sectoral specialization of urban outcomes, and on spatial differences in earnings.
areas into non-agriculture and rural areas into agriculture (for a review, Migration, Employment and Wages. We start with a famous study
see Desmet and Henderson, 2015). Urban areas host more productive focusing on the labor market impacts of a natural experiment resulting
non-agricultural activities and not surprisingly, more educated and from the massive arrival of Cuban refugees in Florida (Card, 1990). This
skilled workers tend to migrate to urban areas. Firms in urban areas study found no impact on the unemployment rate and wages of
benefit from agglomeration externalities as well. These factors imply that low-skilled workers. Although the influx of Cuban refugees created a
migration can lead to higher productivity whereas barriers to migration large supply shock in local labor markets in Florida, the effects appeared
can hamper productivity. Au and Henderson (2006a and 2006b) find to have dissipated in the long run due to further labor movements across
that, at the end of the twentieth century, internal migration restrictions in labor markets located within and outside Florida. The interpretation is
China (due to the Hukou system) prevented Chinese cities to reach an supported by evidence on the impacts of internal migration in the short
optimal size that would maximize output per worker. As migration re- run. In a study of internal migration in the United States, Boustan,
strictions curbed agglomeration and left economies of scale unexploited, Fishback and Kantor (2010) found that migration to US cities following
this resulted in large productivity losses. Using data between 2000 and the New Deal had little impact on hourly wages but led some residents to
2013, Combes et al. (2017) estimate that rural migration in China in the shift to partial work or to move away.
2000s had a strong positive externality in the earnings of urban residents Evidence from developing countries is somewhat different. El
thanks to agglomeration effects. Similarly, Bryan and Morten (2019) Badaoui et al. (2017) who study the impacts of regional migrant inflows
estimate the aggregate productivity gains from reducing barriers to in- on labor markets in Thailand, find that although migrant inflows had no
ternal labor migration in Indonesia, accounting for worker selection and impact on hourly wages, the arrival of migrants decreased weekly
spatial differences in human capital. They find a 22 percent increase in earnings through a reduction in the number of hours worked. In the case
labor productivity from removing all migration barriers. Reducing of internal migration in Indonesia, Kleemans and Magruder (2018) find
migration costs to the US level—a high mobility benchmark—would lead that, in the short term, internal migration reduced employment, espe-
to an 8 percent productivity boost. The gains from increased migration cially in the heavily regulated formal sector where wages are rigid, and
are, however, highly heterogenous: The origin population that benefits employment is the variable of adjustment. At the same time, internal
most would see a 104 percent increase in average earnings from a migration had a negative effect on wages, especially in the more
complete barrier removal, or a 37 percent increase from moving to the US competitive informal sector. Although migrants were on average more
benchmark. In the same vein, Tombe and Zhu (2019) report that, in skilled than natives, migration had larger negative effect on the wages of
China, the decline in trade and migration costs accounted for 36 percent unskilled workers. This is likely because some of the unemployed formal
of the aggregate labor productivity growth between 2000 and 2005. Out workers joined the informal market. Confirming the finding that internal
of these 36 percent, about 10 percent were due to the decline in migra- migration reduces wages at the destination area, Imbert and Papp (2019)
tion costs alone. find that reduced migration of unskilled workers in urban areas from a
The evidence regarding the impact of migration on firm level pro- large employment program in Indian rural areas resulted in an increase in
ductivity, however, is mixed. Using longitudinal data on Chinese urban wages. Finally, Strobl and Valfort (2015) find that weather
manufacturing firms, Imbert et al. (2018) find that, when inmigration induced internal migration in Uganda reduced the probability of
increases, manufacturing production becomes more labor-intensive in employment of non-migrants in destination areas, more so in isolated
the short run. In the longer run, firms innovate less, move away from destination areas (where road density is low) where the labor supply
capital-intensive technologies, and adopt final products that use shock was less likely to spread to other areas.
low-skilled labor more intensively. While overall employment increases, The evidence above suggests that when labor markets across areas are
increased labor supply appears to be directed toward labor-scarce firms well integrated, as in the United States, internal migration has little or no
which tend to have low total factor productivity. In other words, mi- effect on local wages and employment. In contrast, in developing coun-
grants get selected into relatively lower productive firms. This finding tries with dualistic and isolated labor markets along with a predominance
may appear puzzling if we ignore China's abundant supply of relatively of unskilled workers, migration could be more likely to depress local
cheaper labor. However, a labor-intensive technology could perhaps be wages and the employment rate. This may partly explain why urban
optimal given China's comparative advantage and the fact that internal residents in developing countries are often antagonistic to rural-urban
migration does appear to have helped China take advantage of its eco- migrants. Note also that the studies on developing countries reviewed
nomic strength. Moreover, firm level studies are not necessarily able to above provide evidence mostly of short-term effects of migration, which

9
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

can be negative. In the context of international migration, there is evi- prediction for increasing inequality between coastal and interior regions
dence that unskilled migrants usually take over jobs which are at the of China due to high migration costs and the inability of local labor
bottom end of the wage distribution. This allows natives to move up the markets to adjust to economic shocks.
job ladder, benefitting both migrants and native workers. We are not In some cases, however, migration could lead to an increase in
aware, however, of any study on how these adjustments play out over the interregional inequality. For instance, if all skilled and rich workers sort
medium to longer run in the context of rural-urban migration in devel- into one region and unskilled and poorer workers into another region,
oping countries. then it mechanically leads to an increase in regional inequality even
One can expect steady internal migration to result in institutional when there is no income effect from migration. This is exacerbated when
reforms governing labor markets as well. For instance, increased flow of public goods are financed locally and/or agglomeration externalities are
migrants due to a reduction in migration costs could lead to a greater stronger for skilled workers. For instance, in our above example, people
integration of local labor markets and reduction of rigidities within local living in a richer region may have better schools and amenities, which
labor markets. The efficiency gains from these changes in labor market could potentially generate intergenerational persistence in inequality. In
institutions are expected to be large and should be topics of future this respect, Diamond (2016) reports that while local labor demand
research. changes resulted in increased skill sorting in the United States, this was
Spatial gap in earnings. Spatial differences in earnings are expected further fueled by endogenous increases in amenities within higher skill
when migration is costly. How large are these differences? Available cities. She finds that changes in cities’ wages, rents, and endogenous
empirical studies report the presence of a large urban premium in earn- amenities increased welfare inequality between high-school and college
ings relative to rural areas (Henderson et al., 2018; Young, 2013) and a graduates by more than suggested by the increase in the college wage gap
large productivity gap between agriculture and non-agricultural sectors alone. There is also evidence of migrants segregating themselves along
(Gollin et al., 2014). This begs the question of why migration between ethnic and regional lines as observed in Indian slums (Thachil, 2017).19
areas and sectors is not able to eliminate these differences. In this respect, While disparities across neighborhoods within a city are clearly evident
Bazzi et al. (2016)'s paper on resettled migrants in Indonesia shows that to observers in developing countries, research on endogenous sorting due
regional productivity differences may overstate the potential gains from to migration and its impact on inequality remains sparse and should be a
migration because of the role played by skill specificity and sorting.18 priority.
The authors find that, due to the transferability of skills and agricultural
production techniques, villages that assigned migrants from regions with 6. Concluding remarks on research gaps and policy lessons
more similar agroclimatic endowments exhibit higher rice productivity
and nighttime light intensity one to two decades down the road. In The migration literature has grown exponentially since the seminal
addition, it is possible that the observed earnings differentials are also contributions of Harris-Todaro (1969, 1970). The review of the recent
driven by sorting of more productive workers in higher paid jobs as has literature paints a complex and subtle picture of rural-urban migration.
been emphasized in Young (2013), Hamory et al. (2021) and Alvarez The evidence indicates that rural-urban migration is driven by a multi-
(2020). For a more detailed discussion of issues related to sorting, we tude of factors ranging from seeking better opportunities in life to forced
refer readers to Lagakos (2020). migration from one's native region due to climate shocks, conflicts and
Keeping the above measurement issues in mind, we now turn to ev- wars. The returns to migration are large and so are the costs of migration.
idence on whether internal migration reduces spatial wage differentials. The evidence reviewed supports the notion that migration bar-
The evidence from migration of unskilled workers suggests that migra- riers—particularly policy-induced ones—prevent labor market adjust-
tion tends to reduce differences in wages across areas. Building on the ment and hinder structural transformation, potentially leading to serious
Bangladesh experiment in Bryan et al. (2014), Akram et al. (2017) esti- negative economic consequences in terms of growth and aggregate
mate that rural wages rise by 2 percent for every 10 percent increase in welfare and are thus not desirable.
the rural out-migration rate as rural workers become scarcer. As we Our review of the literature also shed light on major gaps in research.
discussed earlier, Imbert and Papp (2019) find increases in urban wages While rural-to-urban migration has received extensive attention in the
due to reduction in migration from rural areas. Both results imply a literature, several other forms of migration remain sparsely studied.
reduction in the spatial wage difference following rural-urban migration. Evidence from developing countries suggests that rural-to-rural, urban-
Similarly, McKenzie and Rapoport (2007) who examine the impacts of to-urban, circular, and return migrations are equally if not more preva-
Mexican migrants to the United States on inequality in rural sending lent forms of migration (Cattaneo and Robinson, 2020). The current
communities in Mexico find that such migration reduces inequality literature, however, is thin on what drives these other types of migration,
across communities with relatively high levels of past migration. Finally, how migrants choose among the different types, and how these different
Howell (2017) finds that rural-urban migration in China leads to a internal migration patterns may affect productivity, welfare, structural
reduction in regional inequality. From the above, the evidence from transformation, agglomeration and economic growth.
developing countries thus suggests that migration leads to a decrease in The literature on migration in response to disasters and climate
inter-regional inequality in earnings/wages. shocks is currently growing fast, though much of this literature focuses on
Migration's role in reducing inter-regional inequality is also evident permanent migration mostly due to data limitations and the difficulty to
from studies which examined responses of regional inequality to eco- observe short duration moves. The current COVID-19 pandemic has led
nomic shocks when migration is restricted. Fan (2019) reports that due to to large return migration (from urban to rural areas) in many developing
high migration costs in China resulting from Hukou restrictions, inter- countries, notably in India. Whether these initially temporary moves will
national trade shocks increased both between-region inequality among last permanently remains to be seen as the pandemic runs through its
workers with similar skills and within-region inequality between skilled course. But this raises the interesting question of whether the type and
and unskilled workers, with the former accounting for 75 percent of the size of shocks matter to determine temporary vs permanent migration,
overall inequality increase. Hu (2002) develops a model with a similar and whether there will be persistent effects even when migration is
temporary. The work on temporary internal migration in developing
countries has been very limited though temporary international migra-
18
Gains from removing migration costs might be poorly measured by observed tion is believed to have serious financial and human capital implications
returns to migration because of selection. There will be greater gains from
lowering migration costs if those with high potential benefits from migration are
19
those who are stuck in rural areas because they happen to face even higher costs On the contrary, in the United States, Winkler and Johnson (2016) find that
(Lagakos, 2020). rural-urban migration reduced ethnic segregation across counties.

10
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

both in sending and receiving countries (Dustmann and Gorlach, 2016). restrictions and can arise from externalities, in particular due to infor-
Although climatic and other shocks may push people out of their usual mation imperfections and credit constraints. This means that migrants
residence and into urban areas, little is known regarding the extent to may need helping hands in overcoming most of these constraints. Such
which push vs pull migration might differentially affect destination areas. helping hands appear to be quite effective as recent studies based on
Is the potential for agglomeration effects in destination urban areas RCTs show that small nudges and information interventions can accel-
weaker under push than under pull migration? Are disaster-driven mi- erate migration (Bryan et al., 2014; Baseler, 2021). To ensure efficient
grants less efficiently optimizing their location choices? What is the role migration, policy makers should focus on making information about
of policy to accompany climate refugees to ensure productive impacts? destinations including job and housing opportunities easily accessible to
In many developing countries, women are geographically more mo- potential migrants. The widespread access to cell phones along with
bile than men due to customary arrangements in the marriage markets, traditional media sources can be utilized to provide this information. A
which require women to join their spouse's family upon marriage.20 With typical migrant support program should also include training for job
economic development, more women are joining the labor force and search, social assistance (including loans) to finance migration and job
moving to cities—sometimes temporarily—to avail employment oppor- search, and assistance for assimilation of migrants in the destination
tunities, for instance in garment factories. Yet, the migration literature community. It should also include provision of insurance to families at
almost exclusively focuses on the migration of young working-age men. the origin to withstand adverse shocks (Lagakos et al., 2018). Many
With the increasing feminization of labor force and women accounting countries rely on the existing diaspora to help migrants with access to
for a greater share of labor migrants, the migration patterns, causes and job, housing and other public services. An important point to emphasize
consequences of women's labor migration should be another priority area here is that a piecemeal policy of relaxing a specific constraint on
for future research. migration is not as effective as an integrated migration support program
For many developing countries, both international migration and because of presence of complementarities. For instance, in a simulation
internal migration are of very significant economic importance. How- model, Liang et al. (2020) find that reducing migration costs in China can
ever, these two types of migration are typically analyzed in complete more effectively move workers from unproductive inland regions to
isolation of each other. How migrants sort themselves between different productive coastal regions in China if restrictions on the supply of
international and internal migration and the implications such sorting housing are also attenuated (i.e., if housing supply is made more elastic)
have for economic well-being and inequality should be yet another pri- at the same time. In their assessment of the economic impact of the
ority for future research. Another area for future research will be to Chinese highway system, Bosker et al. (2018) find that constructing the
explore the intergenerational mobility of migrants and their children in highway system would have resulted in much higher welfare gains if
the context of developing countries (see e.g., Abramitzky et al., forth- combined with the removal of migration restrictions, therefore allowing
coming. for evidence on the U.S.). workers to relocate to places where they would be more productive.
In view of these research gaps, it is clear that furthering the research In most developing countries, important government policies and
on internal migration will demand much higher quality data than what is investments are implemented without regard to their consequences for
currently available. Much of the research gaps in the literature on migration. Popular examples include transport investments, restrictions
developing countries are in fact due to data unavailability. Currently, the on land transactions in rural areas or workfare programs in rural/urban
main sources of data are censuses which have relatively good spatial areas. As our review shows, these policies tend to affect migration's
resolution but insufficient frequency (as data is typically collected once benefits and costs. As a general rule, policy makers in developing coun-
every 10 years), household surveys whose spatial coverage is limited tries should take migration responses into account in designing policies
though they typically collect more detailed information, and adminis- and investment programs as migration responses could offset the effects
trative data which are still scarce and incomplete in developing countries of these policies. Researchers evaluating such policies and programs
(see Kirchberger, forthcoming) for detailed discussion on the data is- should do the same.
sues). With the exception of a few RCTs and panel surveys, migrants are
not tracked over time, making it difficult to examine temporary, return, Credit roles
and circular migration. Recent studies increasingly use cell phone call
data records (tower pings) to trace migration (Blumenstock et al. 2019, Harris Selod: Writing – original draft preparation, Writing-Reviewing
Lu et al., 2020) and trace from smartphone apps but such data lacks key and Editing Forhad Shilpi: Writing – original draft preparation, Writing-
information on individual characteristics of migrants and the population Reviewing and Editing.
coverage of currently available to researchers is extremely small, intro-
ducing the possibility of a large selection bias. The increasing availability
Declaration of competing interest
of big data on population movements from a variety of sources offers
opportunities for better tracking of migrants, which in turn will help
The authors declare that they have no known competing financial
pursue a new research agenda on rural-urban migration. Yet, there is
interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence
urgent need to also invest in periodic detailed surveys of migrants in
the work reported in this paper.
developing countries to produce data sets that will support research on
migration.
Our review shed light on some important policy implications. Studies References
show that restrictions can either lead to insufficient migration hindering
Abramitzky, R., Boustan, L.P., Connor, D., 2020. Leaving the Enclave: Historical Evidence
productivity and agglomeration (Au and Henderson, 2006a, 2006b) or on Immigrant Mobility from the Industrial Removal Office (No. W27372). National
inefficient patterns of migration. Fortunately, the policy trend seems to Bureau of Economic Research.
Abramitzky, R., Boustan, L.P., Eriksson, K., 2013. Have the poor always been less likely to
be towards removal of migration restrictions (with the end of Apartheid
migrate? Evidence from inheritance practices during the age of mass migration.
in South Africa, and the weakening of the Hukou system in China) J. Dev. Econ. 102, 2–14.
although some opposition to easing restrictions remain. Abramitzky, R., Boustan, L. P., Jacome, E., & Perez, S. (forthcoming). Intergenerational
Inefficiencies, however, are not necessarily due to migration Mobility of Immigrants in the US over Two Centuries, American Economic Review.
Afridi, F., Li, S.X., Ren, Y., 2015. Social identity and inequality: the impact of China's
hukou system. J. Publ. Econ. 123, 17–29.
Aker, J., Clemens, M., Ksoll, C., 2011. Mobiles and mobility: the effect of mobile phones
20 on migration in Niger. In: Proceedings of the German Development Economics
In the 2001 Indian census, 65 percent of women's internal migration Conference, Berlin 2011, No. 2. http://hdl.handle.net/10419/48341.
movement was motivated by marriage and only 3 percent by employment (Food Akram, A.A., Chowdhury, S., Mobarak, A.M., 2017. Effects of Emigration on Rural Labor
and Agricultural Organization, 2018). Markets (No. W23929). National Bureau of Economic Research.

11
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

Alvarez, J.A., 2020. The agricultural wage gap: evidence from Brazilian micro-data. Am. Dercon, S., Krishnan, P., Krutikova, S., 2013. Changing living standards in southern
Econ. J. Macroecon. 12 (1), 153–173. Indian villages 1975–2006: revisiting the ICRISAT village level studies. J. Dev. Stud.
Ardington, C., Case, A., Hosegood, V., 2009. Labor supply responses to large social 49 (12), 1676–1693.
transfers: longitudinal evidence from South Africa. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 1 (1), Desmet, K., Henderson, J.V., 2015. The geography of development within countries. In:
22–48. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, vol. 5. Elsevier, pp. 1457–1517.
Au, C.C., Henderson, J.V., 2006a. How migration restrictions limit agglomeration and Detang-Dessendre, C., Partridge, M.D., Piguet, V., 2016. Local labor market flexibility in a
productivity in China. J. Dev. Econ. 80 (2), 350–388. perceived low migration country: the case of French labor markets. Reg. Sci. Urban
Au, C.C., Henderson, J.V., 2006b. Are Chinese cities too small? Rev. Econ. Stud. 73 (3), Econ. 58, 89–103.
549–576. Diamond, R., 2016. The determinants and welfare implications of US workers' diverging
Barrios, S., Bertinelli, L., Strobl, E., 2006. Climatic change and rural-urban migration: the location choices by skill: 1980-2000. Am. Econ. Rev. 106 (3), 479–524.
case of sub-Saharan Africa. J. Urban Econ. 60 (3), 357–371. Dustmann, C., G€ orlach, J.S., 2016. The economics of temporary migrations. J. Econ. Lit.
Bartik, T.J., 1991. Who Benefits from State and Local Economic Development Policies? 54 (1), 98–136.
W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, Kalamazoo, Michigan. Eggleston, K., Sun, A., Zhan, Z., 2018. The impact of rural pensions in China on labor
Baseler, T., 2021. Hidden Income and the Perceived Returns to Migration: Experimental migration. World Bank Econ. Rev. 32 (1), 64–84.
Evidence from Kenya. Available at SSRN 3534715. El Badaoui, E., Strobl, E., Walsh, F., 2017. Impact of internal migration on labor market
Basu, S., Pearlman, S., 2017. Violence and migration: evidence from Mexico's drug war. outcomes of native males in Thailand. Econ. Dev. Cult. Change 66 (1), 147–177.
IZA Journal of Development and Migration 7 (1), 18. Emran, M.S., Shilpi, F., 2017. Land market restrictions, women's labor force participation,
Bauernschuster, S., Falck, O., Heblich, S., Suedekum, J., Lameli, A., 2014. Why are and wages in a rural economy. Oxf. Bull. Econ. Stat. 79 (5), 747–768.
educated and risk-loving persons more mobile across regions? J. Econ. Behav. Organ. ~ez, A.M., 2007. Displacement due to violence in Colombia: a household-
Engel, S., Iban
98, 56–69. level analysis. Econ. Dev. Cult. Change 55 (2), 335–365.
Bazzi, S., Gaduh, A., Rothenberg, A.D., Wong, M., 2016. Skill transferability, migration, Fafchamps, M., Shilpi, F., 2013. Determinants of choice of migration destination. Oxf.
and development: evidence from population resettlement in Indonesia. Am. Econ. Bull. Econ. Stat. 75 (3), 388–409.
Rev. 106 (9), 2658–2698. Fan, J., 2019. Internal geography, labor mobility, and the distributional impacts of trade.
Bazzi, S., Gaduh, A., Rothenberg, A.D., Wong, M., 2019. Unity in diversity? how Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 11 (3), 252–288.
intergroup contact can foster nation building. Am. Econ. Rev. 109 (11), 3978–4025. Farre, L., Fasani, F., 2013. Media exposure and internal migration—evidence from
Beegle, K., De Weerdt, J., Dercon, S., 2011. Migration and economic mobility in Tanzania: Indonesia. J. Dev. Econ. 102, 48–61.
evidence from a tracking survey. Rev. Econ. Stat. 93 (3), 1010–1033. Feler, L., Henderson, J.V., 2011. Exclusionary policies in urban development: under-
Beine, M., Bertinelli, L., C€omertpay, R., Litina, A., Maystadt, J.F., 2021. A gravity analysis servicing migrant households in Brazilian cities. J. Urban Econ. 69 (3), 253–272.
of refugee mobility using mobile phone data. J. Dev. Econ. 150, 102618. Food and Agricultural Organization, 2018. The State of Food and Agriculture 2018.
Bell, M., Bernard, A., Charles-Edwards, E., Zhu, Y., 2020. Internal Migration in the Migration. agriculture and rural development, Rome, p. 174.
Countries of Asia: A Cross-National Comparison. Springer. Fu, Y., Gabriel, S.A., 2012. Labor migration, human capital agglomeration and regional
Bell, M., Charles-Edwards, E., 2013. Cross-national Comparisons of Internal Migration: an development in China. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 42 (3), 473–484.
Update of Global Patterns and Trends. United Nations Department of Economic and Giles, J., Mu, R., 2018. Village political economy, land tenure insecurity, and the rural to
Social Affairs. Technical Paper No. 2013/1. urban migration decision: evidence from China. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 100 (2),
Bell, M., Charles-Edwards, E., Bernard, A., Ueffing, P., 2018. Global trends in internal 521–544.
migration. In: Champion, T., Cooke, T., Shuttleworth, I. (Eds.), Internal Migration in Gollin, D., Lagakos, D., Waugh, M.E., 2014. The agricultural productivity gap. Q. J. Econ.
the Developed World: Are We Becoming Less Mobile, Chapter 4. Routledge, 129 (2), 939–993.
pp. 76–97. Grace, K., Hertrich, V., Singare, D., Husak, G., 2018. Examining rural Sahelian out-
Bell, M., Charles-Edwards, E., Ueffing, P., Stillwell, J., Kupiszewski, M., Kupiszewska, D., migration in the context of climate change: an analysis of the linkages between
2015. Internal migration and development: comparing migration intensities around rainfall and out-migration in two Malian villages from 1981 to 2009. World Dev. 109,
the world. Popul. Dev. Rev. 41 (1), 33–58. 187–196.
Blumenstock, J.E., Chi, G., Tan, X., 2019. Migration and the Value of Social Networks. Gr€oger, A., Zylberberg, Y., 2016. Internal labor migration as a shock coping strategy:
CEPR Discussion Paper 13611. evidence from a typhoon. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 8 (2), 123–153.
Bosker, M., Deichmann, U., Roberts, M., 2018. Hukou and highways: the impact of Guriev, S., Vakulenko, E., 2015. Breaking out of poverty traps: internal migration and
China’s spatial development policies on urbanization and regional inequality. Reg. interregional convergence in Russia. J. Comp. Econ. 43 (3), 633–649.
Sci. Urban Econ. 71, 91–109. Hamory, J., Kleemans, M., Li, N.Y., Miguel, E., 2021. Reevaluating agricultural
Boustan, L.P., Fishback, P.V., Kantor, S., 2010. The effect of internal migration on local productivity gaps with longitudinal microdata. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 19 (3),
labor markets: American cities during the Great Depression. J. Labor Econ. 28 (4), 1522–1555.
719–746. Harris, J.R., Todaro, M.P., 1970. Migration, unemployment and development: a two-
Brueckner, J.K., Lall, S., 2015. Cities in developing countries: fueled by rural-urban sector analysis. Am. Econ. Rev. 60 (1), 126–142.
migration, lacking in tenure security, and short of affordable housing. In: Hauer, M.E., Fussell, E., Mueller, V., Burkett, M., Call, M., Abel, K.,, et al., 2020. Sea-level
Duranton, G., Henderson, J.V., Strange, W.C. (Eds.), Handbook of Regional and rise and human migration. Nature Reviews Earth & Environment 1 (1), 28–39.
Urban Economics, 5B. Elsevier, pp. 1399–1455. Hayashi, F., Prescott, E.C., 2008. The depressing effect of agricultural institutions on the
Bryan, G., Chowdhury, S., Mobarak, A.M., 2014. Underinvestment in a profitable prewar Japanese economy. J. Polit. Econ. 116 (4), 573–632.
technology: the case of seasonal migration in Bangladesh. Econometrica 82 (5), Henderson, J.V., Nigmatulina, D., Kriticos, S., 2018. Measuring Urban Economic Density.
1671–1748. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS8678. The World Bank.
Bryan, G., Morten, M., 2019. The aggregate productivity effects of internal migration: Henderson, J.V., Storeygard, A., Deichmann, U., 2017. Has climate change driven
evidence from Indonesia. J. Polit. Econ. 127 (5), 2229–2268. urbanization in Africa? J. Dev. Econ. 124, 60–82.
Cadena, B.C., Kovak, B.K., 2016. Immigrants equilibrate local labor markets: evidence Howell, A., 2017. Impacts of migration and remittances on ethnic income inequality in
from the Great Recession. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 8 (1), 257–290. rural China. World Dev. 94, 200–211.
Cai, S., 2020. Migration under liquidity constraints: evidence from randomized credit Hu, D., 2002. Trade, rural–urban migration, and regional income disparity in developing
access in China. J. Dev. Econ. 142, 102247. countries: a spatial general equilibrium model inspired by the case of China. Reg. Sci.
Card, D., 1990. The impact of the Mariel boatlift on the Miami labor market. ILR Review Urban Econ. 32 (3), 311–338.
43 (2), 245–257. Hu, F., Xu, Z., Chen, Y., 2011. Circular migration, or permanent stay? Evidence from
Cattaneo, A., Robinson, S., 2020. Multiple Moves and Return Migration within China's rural–urban migration. China Econ. Rev. 22 (1), 64–74.
Developing Countries: A Comparative Analysis. Population, Space and Place, p. 21. Imbert, C., Papp, J., 2019. Short-term migration, rural public works, and urban labor
Chernina, E., Dower, P.C., Markevich, A., 2014. Property rights, land liquidity, and markets: evidence from India. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 18 (2), 927–963.
internal migration. J. Dev. Econ. 110, 191–215. Imbert, C., Papp, J., 2020. Costs and benefits of rural-urban migration: evidence from
Combes, P.P., Demurger, S., Li, S., 2017. Productivity gains from agglomeration and India. J. Dev. Econ. 102473.
migration in the people's Republic of China between 2002 and 2013. Asian Dev. Rev. Imbert, C., Seror, M., Zhang, Y., Zylberberg, Y., 2018. Migrants and Firms: Evidence from
Stud. Asian Pac. Econ. Issues 34 (2), 184–200. China. CESifo Working Paper No. 7440.
Dahl, G.B., 2002. Mobility and the return to education: testing a Roy model with multiple Internal Displacement Monitoring Centre and Norwegian Refugee Council, 2020. Global
markets. Econometrica 70 (6), 2367–2420. Report on Internal Displacement, p. 136.
Dang, H.A.H., Huang, Y., Selod, H., 2020. Children left behind in China: the role of school Joseph, G., Wodon, Q., 2013. Is internal migration in Yemen driven by climate or socio-
fees. IZA Journal of Development and Migration 11 (1). economic factors? Rev. Int. Econ. 21 (2), 295–310.
De Brauw, A., Giles, J., 2018. Migrant labor markets and the welfare of rural households Katz, E., Stark, O., 1986. Labor migration and risk aversion in less developed countries.
in the developing world: evidence from China. World Bank Econ. Rev. 32 (1), 1–18. J. Labor Econ. 4 (1), 134–149.
De Janvry, A., Emerick, K., Gonzalez-Navarro, M., Sadoulet, E., 2015. Delinking land Kim, S., 2007. Immigration, Industrial Revolution and Urban Growth in the United States,
rights from land use: certification and migration in Mexico. Am. Econ. Rev. 105 (10), 1820-1920: Factor Endowments, Technology and Geography (No. W12900). National
3125–3149. Bureau of Economic Research.
De la Roca, J., 2017. Selection in initial and return migration: evidence from moves across Kim, S., Margo, R.A., 2004. Historical perspectives on US economic geography. In:
Spanish cities. J. Urban Econ. 100, 33–53. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, vol. 4. Elsevier, pp. 2981–3019.
De la Roca, J., Puga, D., 2017. Learning by working in big cities. Rev. Econ. Stud. 84 (1), Kirchberger, M. (forthcoming) Measuring Internal Migration. Regional Science and Urban
106–142. Economics, Conditionally Accepted for Publication in the Special Issue on Rural-
Urban Migration in Honor of Harris and Todaro.

12
H. Selod, F. Shilpi Regional Science and Urban Economics 91 (2021) 103713

Kinnan, C., Wang, S.Y., Wang, Y., 2018. Access to migration for rural households. Am. Morten, M., Oliveira, J., 2016. The effects of roads on trade and migration: evidence from
Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 10 (4), 79–119. a planned capital city. NBER Working Paper 22158, 43.
Kleemans, M., Magruder, J., 2018. Labour market responses to immigration: evidence Mullan, K., Grosjean, P., Kontoleon, A., 2011. Land tenure arrangements and rural–urban
from internal migration driven by weather shocks. Econ. J. 128 (613), 2032–2065. migration in China. World Dev. 39 (1), 123–133.
Kone, Z.L., Liu, M.Y., Mattoo, A., Ozden, C., Sharma, S., 2018. Internal borders and Munshi, K., 2020. Social networks and migration. Annual Review of Economics 12,
migration in India. J. Econ. Geogr. 18 (4), 729–759. 503–524.
Kosec, K., Ghebru, H., Holtemeyer, B., Mueller, V., Schmidt, E., 2018. The effect of land Munshi, K., Rosenzweig, M., 2016. Networks and misallocation: insurance, migration,
access on youth employment and migration decisions: evidence from rural Ethiopia. and the rural-urban wage gap. Am. Econ. Rev. 106 (1), 46–98.
Am. J. Agric. Econ. 100 (3), 931–954. Nakamura, E., Sigurdsson, J., Steinsson, J., 2016. The gift of moving: Intergenerational
Kubik, Z., Maurel, M., 2016. Weather shocks, agricultural production and migration: consequences of a mobility shock (No. w22392). National Bureau of Economic
evidence from Tanzania. J. Dev. Stud. 52 (5), 665–680. Research.
Lagakos, D., 2020. Urban-rural gaps in the developing world: does internal migration Nguyen, L.D., Raabe, K., Grote, U., 2015. Rural–urban migration, household vulnerability,
offer opportunities? J. Econ. Perspect. 34 (3), 174–192. and welfare in Vietnam. World Dev. 71, 79–93.
Lagakos, D., Marshall, S., Mobarak, A.M., Vernot, C., Waugh, M.E., 2020. Migration costs Peri, G., Sasahara, A., 2019. The Impact of Global Warming on Rural-Urban Migrations:
and observational returns to migration in the developing world. J. Monetary Econ. Evidence from Global Big Data (No. W25728). National Bureau of Economic
113, 138–154. Research.
Lagakos, D., Mobarak, A.M., Waugh, M.E., 2018. The Welfare Effects of Encouraging Poelhekke, S., 2011. Urban growth and uninsured rural risk: booming towns in bust
Rural-Urban Migration (No. W24193). National Bureau of Economic Research. times. J. Dev. Econ. 96 (2), 461–475.
Lai, S., Erbach-Schoenberg, E.z., Pezzulo, C., Ruktanonchai, N.W., Sorichetta, A., Poggi, C., 2019. Credit availability and internal migration: evidence from Thailand.
Steele, J.,., Tatem, A.J., 2019. Exploring the use of mobile phone data for national J. Dev. Stud. 55 (5), 861–875.
migration statistics. Palgrave communications 5 (1), 1–10. Porcher, C., 2020. Migration with Costly Information. Mimeo.
Lall, S.V., Selod, H., Shalizi, Z., 2006. Rural-urban Migration in Developing Countries: A Ranis, G., Fei, J.C., 1961. A Theory of Economic Development. The American Economic
Survey of Theoretical Predictions and Empirical Findings. World Bank Policy Review, pp. 533–565.
Research Working Paper WPS3915. The World Bank. Roback, J., 1982. Wages, rents, and the quality of life. J. Polit. Econ. 90 (6), 1257–1278.
Lall, S.V., Timmins, C., Yu, S., 2009. Connecting Lagging and Leading Regions: the Role of Sarvim€aki, M., Uusitalo, R., J€antti, M., 2019. Habit Formation and the Misallocation of
Labor Mobility. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS4843. The World Labor: Evidence from Forced Migrations. Available at SSRN 3361356.
Bank. Shilpi, F., Xu, L., Behal, R., Blankespoor, B., 2018. People on the Move: Spatial Mismatch
Lanzona, L.A., 1998. Migration, self-selection and earnings in Philippine rural and Migration in Post-Apartheid South Africa. World Bank.
communities. J. Dev. Econ. 56 (1), 27–50. Shilpi, F., Sangraula, P., Li, Y., 2014. Voting with Their Feet? Access to Infrastructure and
Lewis, W.A., 1954. Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour. Manch. Sch. Migration in Nepal. Policy Research Working Paper Series 7047. The World Bank.
22 (2), 139–191. Shrestha, M., 2020. Get rich or die tryin’: perceived earnings, perceived mortality rates,
Liang, W., Song, R., Timmins, C., 2020. Frictional Sorting (No. W27643). National Bureau and migration decisions of potential work migrants from Nepal. World Bank Econ.
of Economic Research. Rev. 34 (1), 1–27.
Lu, H., Kandilov, I.T., Zhu, R., 2020. The impact of internal migration on the health of Stark, O., 1991. The Migration of Labor. Blackwell, p. 406.
rural migrants: evidence from longitudinal data in China. J. Dev. Stud. 56 (4), Stark, O., Levhari, D., 1982. On migration and risk in LDCs. Econ. Dev. Cult. Change 31
840–855. (1), 191–196.
Lucas, R.E.B., 1997. Internal migration in developing countries. In: Handbook of Stark, O., Lucas, R.E.B., 1988. Migration, remittances, and the family. Econ. Dev. Cult.
Population and Family Economics, vol. 1, pp. 721–798. Change 36 (3), 465–481.
Lucas, R.E.B., 2016. Internal migration in developing economies: an overview of recent Strobl, E., Valfort, M.A., 2015. The effect of weather-induced internal migration on local
evidence. Geopolit. Hist. Int. Relat. 8 (2), 159–191. labor markets. Evidence from Uganda. World Bank Econ. Rev. 29 (2), 385–412.
McKenzie, D., Rapoport, H., 2007. Network effects and the dynamics of migration and Sun, L., 2019. Rural Urban Migration and Policy Intervention in China: Migrant Workers'
inequality: theory and evidence from Mexico. J. Dev. Econ. 84 (1), 1–24. Coping Strategies. Palgrave Macmillan.
McKenzie, D., Stillman, S., Gibson, J., 2010. How important is selection? Experimental vs. Thachil, T., 2017. Do rural migrants divide ethnically in the city? Evidence from an
non-experimental measures of the income gains from migration. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. ethnographic experiment in India. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 61 (4), 908–926.
8 (4), 913–945. Todaro, M.P., 1969. A model of labor migration and urban unemployment in less
Meghir, C., Mobarak, A. M., Mommaerts, C. D., & Morten, M. (forthcoming) Migration developed countries. Am. Econ. Rev. 59 (1), 138–148.
and Informal Insurance, Review of Economic Studies. National Bureau of Economic Tombe, T., Zhu, X., 2019. Trade, migration, and productivity: a quantitative analysis of
Research (No. w26082). China. Am. Econ. Rev. 109 (5), 1843–1872.
Meng, L., 2012. Can grain subsidies impede rural–urban migration in hinterland China? Winkler, R.L., Johnson, K.M., 2016. Moving toward integration? Effects of migration on
Evidence from field surveys. China Econ. Rev. 23 (3), 729–741. ethnoracial segregation across the rural-urban continuum. Demography 53 (4),
Minale, L., 2018. Agricultural productivity shocks, labour reallocation and rural–urban 1027–1049.
migration in China. J. Econ. Geogr. 18 (4), 795–821. Xiang, A.O., Jiang, D., Zhong, Z.H.A.O., 2016. The impact of rural–urban migration on the
Morrison, A.R., 1993. Violence or economics: what drives internal migration in health of the left-behind parents. China Econ. Rev. 37, 126–139.
Guatemala? Econ. Dev. Cult. Change 41 (4), 817–831. Young, A., 2013. Inequality, the urban-rural gap, and migration. Q. J. Econ. 128 (4),
Morten, M., 2019. Temporary migration and endogenous risk sharing in village India. 1727–1785.
J. Polit. Econ. 127 (1), 1–46. Zelinsky, W., 1971. The hypothesis of the mobility transition. Geogr. Rev. 219–249.

13

You might also like