Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 14

This article was downloaded by: [University of Connecticut]

On: 30 October 2014, At: 01:56


Publisher: Routledge
Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer
House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Applied Economics
Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:
http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20

Determinants of corporate capital structure:


evidence from Hungarian firms
Emilio Colombo
Published online: 05 Oct 2010.

To cite this article: Emilio Colombo (2001) Determinants of corporate capital structure: evidence from Hungarian
firms, Applied Economics, 33:13, 1689-1701, DOI: 10.1080/00036840010015057

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840010015057

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”)
contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors
make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any
purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views
of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content
should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information.
Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs,
expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in
connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content.

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic
reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any
form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://
www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions
Applied Economics, 2001, 33, 1689 ± 1701

Determinants of corporate capital


structure: evidence from Hungarian Wrms
EMILIO C OLOMBO
Dipartimento di Economia Politica, UniversitaÁ Statale Milano ± Bicocca, EdiWcio U6,
Piazza Ateneo Nuovo 1, 20126 Milano, Italy, e-mail: Emilio.Colombo@unimib.it

This paper investigates the capital structure of Hungarian ® rms using a cross-section
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

and a panel data approach. The data set is composed of balance sheet data and
information on market structure for 1100 ® rms from 1992 to 1996. Evidence is found
of imperfections that constrain ® rms in the achievement of their optimal capital
structure, but also some positive indications: there are no distortions typical of the
planned system and no signs of the presence of soft budget constraints.

I. INTRODUCTION of imperfections that characterize credit and ® nancial mar-


kets in Hungary.
Somewhat paradoxically, the theory of capital structure It is important to stress that this procedure, unlike the
has been made famous by a contribution that showed its studies that estimate investment equations,1 is not a test for
irrelevance to the value of the ® rm (Modigliani and Miller, the presence of ® nancial market imperfections; it is only an
1958). In the presence of perfect information, in fact, there empirical investigation of ® rms’ capital structure that in-
is no diŒerence between internal and external ® nance, and directly can reveal the presence of such imperfections.
therefore ® rm’s capital structure, i.e. how it allocates its There is a conspicuous literature that analyses those
® nancial position between debt, equity and other forms issues in industrialized countries (see for example Titman
of ® nance, becomes completely irrelevant. and Wessels, 1988; Rajan and Zingales, 1995), but also in
Forty years after Modigliani and Miller’ s seminal paper, the case of Eastern Europe there are several contributions:
economic theory has shown that while the frictionless neo- Cornelli et al. (1998) for Hungary and Poland, Revoltella
classical world is a useful theoretical benchmark, in reality (1998) for the Czech Republic and Carare and Perotti
there are ® nancial market imperfections, mainly due to (1997) for Romania. However, while in all the above
informational failures, that introduce a wedge between mentioned works the analysis is conducted at a cross
internal and external ® nance, creating on one hand a `peck- sectional level, both a cross-section and a panel data analy-
ing order’ of ® nancing methods (Myers and Majluf, 1984) sis are conducted. It is believed that the additional infor-
and on the other hand a precise link between investment mation and e ciency that can be extracted from a panel
and ® nancing decisions. The relationship between ® nancial can considerably improve the understanding of the rele-
structure and investment has in turn led in recent years to vance of ® nancial market imperfections in Eastern
the development of a considerable literature that underlines European economies and allows us to have a better grasp
its macroeconomic eŒects (Bernanke and Gertler, 1989; of the determinants of ® rms’ capital structure in those
Greenwald and Stiglitz, 1993). countries.
This work will investigate the factors that aŒect decisions The second qualifying aspect of the present work is con-
about the capital structure (and in particular about bank stituted by the data set: the panel analysis is in fact allowed
debt) of a sample of Hungarian ® rms. This investigation by a data set that is unique for Eastern European stan-
should reveal the existence of constraints on ® rms’ choice dards, as it gives detailed information on balance sheet
allowing the inference of some considerations on the degree and market structure for some 1100 Hungarian ® rms

1
See for example Bond and Meghir (1994) and the literature quoted in Schiantarelli (1997).
Applied Economics ISSN 0003± 6846 print/ISSN 1466± 4283 online # 2001 Taylor & Francis Ltd 1689
http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals
DOI: 10.1080 /0003684001001505 7
1690 E. Colombo
from 1992 to 1996, allowing to test precisely the relevant structure decisions, moreover tests on the static trade-oŒ
hypothesis. theories do not have su cient statistical power.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: The second and more important reason is due to the fact
Section (II) introduces the theoretical framework, Section that our data set has a limited time horizon and the meas-
(III) describes the data set and some descriptive statistics, ure of debt used is short-term debt (see Section IV). It is
Section (IV) explains the methodology used, Section (V) well known that tax rates are virtually ¯ at over short-time
presents the empirical ® ndings, Section (VI) concludes. periods and that they are more likely to aŒect long-term
debt decisions rather than short-term, therefore the proper
instruments are not available to measure the eŒects of tax
considerations on our sample.
II. THE THEORY Nevertheless also `pecking order’ theories have to be
amended in order to apply them to the context of
As stressed in the introduction, the analysis of the capital Eastern Europe. In particular the limited size of equity
structure of ® rms assumes relevance mainly in the presence markets in transitional economies has so far excluded an
of ® nancial market imperfections; it is due to such imper- important element in the choice about the capital structure;
fections that diŒerent ® nancing methods become imperfect on the other hand the widespread use, inherited from the
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

substitutes and determine the presence of an `optimal capi- planned system, of trade credit has introduced an addi-
tal structure’ . There are two very good reasons for which tional element that aŒect ® rms’ decisions. Finally, owner-
those imperfections are likely to be particularly severe in ship characteristics may also constitute an important
Eastern Europe. First, during the planned-type system variable to be considered. The next paragraphs will analyse
banks did not exercise any monitoring or risk assessment those aspects more in detail. In principle it is important to
activity: they were lending to ® rms simply because this was distinguish between demand and supply side factors deter-
what the plan stated, but they were not concerned about mining the capital structure; this distinction can be made at
the solvency of the borrower (the solvency of the whole theoretical level but, as it will be stressed later, it is very
system was guaranteed by the state itself). Therefore, di cult to be made at empirical level.
even if there existed a relationship between borrowers
and lenders, this relationship was completely uninforma-
tive. With the beginning of transition, lenders had to be Supply side
concerned about the creditworthiness of borrowers, but on
Collateral. There should be an unambiguous positive
one hand the former did not have any experience in mon-
relationship between tangibility and debt (see Harris and
itoring activity, on the other hand the latter did not have
Raviv, 1991). Assets that serve as collateral, in fact, pro-
any reputation or credit history to show. Second, is the
vide an explicit guarantee over debts and reduce the risk
economic instability that characterized the early stages of
of investment from the banks. Two measures of collateral
transition: in the presence of an unstable economic system,
are used: the ® rst is the ratio of ® xed to total assets; this
current performances are a very poor indicator for future
measure however carries the problem of the precise eva-
performances. Therefore, not only borrowers do not have
luation of assets that are classi® ed as ® xed. This problem
any reputation deriving from the past, but also they have
is particularly relevant in transitional economies where
relevant di culties in building one ex novo.
® xed assets are often inherited from the old socialist
In this situation the informational problems that are
system where prices did not represent a proper measure
likely to emerge may cause severe forms of credit rationing
of value and where it does not exist an e cient secondary
and may in general constrain ® rms in their capital structure
market where those assets can be traded. The ratio of
decisions.
inventories to total assets was therefore included as an
The following will analyse the factors that most likely
alternative measure; inventories should reduce the two
aŒect the capital structure of ® rms in the sample from the
above mentioned problems because it is easier to deter-
theoretical point of view. Theories based on tax con-
mine a `correct’ price for them and because they can be
sideration that give rise to what are called static trade-oŒ
re-sold on the primary market.
models will not be considered.2 Instead, the paper focuses
on the theories that stress the relevance of informational
failures, known also as `pecking order’ theories (see Harris ProWtability and growth opportunities . If current pro® ts
and Raviv, 1991). The reason for such a choice is twofold: are a good indication of future pro® ts a positive relation-
® rst as recently shown by Shyam-Sunde r and Myers (1999) ship between pro® ts and debt should be observed (Ross,
the pecking order theory describes extremely well corporate 1977). At the same time if a ® rm displays good growth

2
Those models de® ne an optimal capital structure that arise from trading oŒthe tax advantages of borrowing money and the bankruptcy
costs caused by an excessive level of debt, see Bradley et al. (1984).
Determinants of corporate capital structure 1691
opportunities banks should be more keen to lend to it. to them. Moreover there is the issue of the implicit bail-
The pro® tability of a ® rm is measured by the ratio of out clause that is referred to big companies and that con-
after tax pro® ts over total assets and its growth opportu- tributes signi® cantly in reducing the investment risk.
nities by the ratio of investments over total assets. Again it is a question of how strong is the risk aspect
compared to growth opportunities.
Size. It is usually assumed a positive relationship A diŒerent issue is that one of foreign ownership: foreign
between ® rm size and leverage. Big ® rms tend to have owned ® rms or ® rms in which foreign companies have a
diversi® ed activities, which reduce the risk of bankruptcy. signi® cant share should represent certainly the best possible
Moreover reputational reasons induce big ® rms to be investment opportunit y from banks perspective. Those
more averse to bankruptcy than small ® rms. In transi- ® rms in fact have a substantially lower bankruptcy risk
tional economies an important factor to be considered is and adopt faster international standards in terms of prod-
the implicit bailout clause that exists for large state uct quality and internal e ciency. Ownership is measured
owned ® rms. Often those ® rms are considered `too big to with two dummies one that represent whether or not a ® rm
fail’ both because their bankruptcy could have a destabi- is state owned and the other whether or not there is a
lizing eŒect on the whole economic system and because consistent (greater than 10% ) foreign share.
the loss in terms of employment could be socially unac-
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

ceptable. The existence of an implicit bailout clause may


Demand side
in turn trigger some perverse behaviour by the banks that
may `gamble for bailout’ re® nancing loss making state Cash Xows. If there is a `pecking order’ in ® rms’ ® nan-
owned ® rms (BergloÈf and Roland, 1995, 1997). cing decisions, the use of internal resources is certainly
Size is measured with two variables: one that captures preferred to bank debt. As a consequence ® rms with a
more the `economic’ considerations and is constituted by higher cash ¯ ows will be characterized by reduced lever-
(the logarithm of) net sales; the other captures more the age as they substitute external with internal ® nance.
`political’ considerations and is constituted by the level of This paper’s measure of cash ¯ ows is quite standard and
employment. is given by pro® ts before tax, interest and depreciation.

Market share. As for the ownership variable (see below) Interenterprise debt. The issue of interenterprise debt has
in this case it is crucial to distinguish the issue of the been controversial. At the early stages of transition sev-
growth of the ® rms from the one of the risk of the invest- eral authors (see for example Calvo and Coricelli, 1994)
ment in those ® rms. Generally speaking, in transitional argued that interenterprise arrears could be a major chan-
economies, more competitive ® rms are mainly new pri- nel through which soft budget constraints could be car-
vate ® rms which are the ® rst to react to the changing ried over. Later studies (Bonin and SchaŒer, 1995;
environment and to the new standards imposed by inter- SchaŒer, 1998) showed that ® rms learned fast how to
national competition. Those ® rms should have better pro- implement hard budget constraints in the lending posi-
spects of growth with respect to traditional state owned tions among themselves and that interenterprise debt did
enterprises; it should therefore be expected that banks not constitute a form of soft budget constraint. But inter-
will favour in their lending behaviour the former type of enterprise debt can still convey some information about
® rms over the latter. Firms which retain a consistent mar- the capital structure of ® rms. In the absence of soft bud-
ket power are conversely less dynamic state owned enter- get constraints associated with interenterprise arrears the
prises; even if their long-term perspectives are not observation of a negative correlation between bank debt
extremely attractive, in the short run their relevant mar- and interenterprise debt can be a signal of the existence
ket share often provides good pro® tability associated of a pecking order of ® rms’ ® nancial decisions (® rms with
with low risk. Whether banks’ debt is positively or nega- no access to bank credit would resort to trade credit as a
tively related to ® rms’ market power depend on how substitute). Interenterprise debt is measured as the ratio
strong is the growth eŒect compared to the risk eŒect. of the net trade credit position (payables± receivables) to
Market power is measured with the share of sales in the total assets.
four digit industry covered by the ® rm.

Ownership. With respect to the ownership issue similar


III. THE DATA SET AND SOME
considerations can be applied to those applied to the
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS
issue of market share. State owned ® rms are often big
® rms with limited ¯ exibility and ability to compete at
Data set
international level. Their growth opportunities should
therefore be limited. On the other hand the shield deter- The data set used in the analysis is constructed merging the
mined by their market power, reduces the risk of lending information from two sources. The study ® rst used a data
1692 E. Colombo
Table 1. Share of employment and sales of the sample in the manu- Descriptive statistics
facturing and service sectors.
Employment and ownership structure. The ownership
Year Employment Sales structure of ® rms in the sample changed considerably
1992 32.1 38.8 during the period 1992± 1996. As Table 2 con® rms the
1993 31.7 37.4 share of state owned ® rms dropped from 27.8% in 1992
1994 28.0 34.7 to 7.3% in 1995 while the share of private ® rms rose
1995 22.6 20.6 from 27.7% in 1992 to over 63% in 1995.9 This pattern
of ownership is quite common in transitional economies.
Total employment in the sample dropped heavily from
1992 to 1995 with a cumulative contraction of almost
29% (Table 3). The employment contraction is bigger
than the one displayed by o cial statistics on industrial
set deriving from the Hungarian Ministry of Finance that
employment which shows a cumulative contraction
contains information on all ® rms that paid corporate or
between 1992 and 1995 of approximately 20% . This
pro® t taxes from 1992 to 1995; this data set covers almost
result is probably due to a sample selection bias as
the totality of Hungarian ® rms, with the exclusion of small
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

mainly large and medium sized ® rms were considered for


shops. 3 Due to substantial changes in accounting data de® -
which labour in excess was comparatively larger than for
nitions occurred in 1992, the data set results incomplete in
other ® rms; moreover since the sample does not consider
some variables in 1994 and 1995. A second data set was
® rms that entered the market between 1993 and 1996 the
then used deriving from the Hungarian Central Statistical
growth in employment generated by such ® rms is not
O ce that contains end of year ® nancial statements of
captured.
medium-large size ® rms, from 1993 to 1996.4 Merging the
information from the two sources data was obtained on
® nancial variables (bank debt, interest payments, assets, The amount and distribution of debt. One of the features
trade credit etc.) plus information on ownership, employ- of Eastern European ® nancial markets that was most
ment and on market structure (the degree of concentration concerning was the problem of the initial stock of debt
in the four digit industry).5 The analysis was concentrated with which ® rms and banks started the transition process.
on the manufacturing and on the service sector, therefore The presence of a high stock of debt that some ® rms are
® rms belonging to the following sectors were dropped from unable to repay, may force banks to roll over the debt in
the sample: agriculture, ® nance, mining, electricity, gas, order to keep the ® rms viable and at the same time keep
water, post and telecommunication, public administration, open the option of having (part of) the debt repaid some
education and health. After some consistency checks6 the time in the future.
study was left with cross sections of approximately 1100 A simple test for the presence of debt rollover is to cal-
® rms that kept the same identi® cation number from 1992 culate the correlation coe cients between the change in
to 1996. 7 These cross sections allowed the construction of a short-term debt in period t ‡ 1 and the level of short-
balanced panel. term debt in period t. Table 4 shows those coe cients. In
The sample is fairly representative, ranging from 32.1% the presence of debt rollover the correlation is expected to
and 37.4% to 22.6% and 20.6% of respectively total be positive. In fact the correlation coe cients are all nega-
employment and sales of the manufacturing and service tive for the years considered. The correlation is greater for
sectors as a whole (see Table 1).8 small ® rms than for big ® rms;10 no clear pattern emerges

3
The total number of ® rms ranges from 35 000 in 1992 to over 90 000 in 1995.
4
The number of ® rms belonging to this samples ranges from 5000 in 1993 to approximately 7000 in 1996.
5
The data resulting from the intersection of the two data sets described above suŒers from a sample selection bias: as the small data set
contains information on medium-large enterprises, in the sample those ® rms will be over-represented. It is acknowledged that the
presence of this problem but also noted that, since large ® rms are the ones that should generally be the least constrained in the
achievement of their optimal capital structure, ® nding evidence of such constraint for those ® rms allow the conclusions to be extended
a fortiori to small ® rms.
6
Those consistency checks are described in the Appendix, which also describes the procedure used to identify outliers.
7
Using this procedure one could not avoid the following problem: when a big ® rm is split, a branch or a part of it will keep the same
identi® cation number of the original ® rm while a diŒerent identi® cation number will be assigned to the other parts or branches. While the
original ® rm and the branch that keeps the same id are de facto diŒerent ® rms, in the sample they are recorded as the same ® rm.
8
The drop in the sample’s share documented by Table 1 is explained by the fact that from 1992 to 1995 the total number of manu-
facturing ® rms increased considerably, mainly due to the birth of new ® rms.
9
The big fall in the share of co-operatives in 1994 is due to a change in the de® nition of co-operatives implemented by the Central
Statistical O ce at the end of 1993.
10
Big ® rms are de® ned employing more than 300 employees.
Determinants of corporate capital structure 1693
Table 2. Ownership structure of Wrms: share of each class on the total number of Wrms

Year State Cooperatives Joint Ventures Private

1992 27.8 20.3 24.2 27.7 100


1993 17.6 20.4 28.3 33.7 100
1994 11.2 0.8 29.4 58.6 100
1995 7.3 0.8 28.5 63.4 100

Table 3. Percentage change in sample’s employment with respect shows a `hint’ of a bimodal distribution with approxi-
to the previous year mately 9% of bank debt being concentrated in ® rms with
1993 1994 1995
heavy losses compared to total assets; to check if this small
peak is showing a real pattern or just picking up some eŒect
714.8 77.8 76.2 peculiar to 1992, Fig. 1b reports the conditional distri-
bution for 1993 which shows that the peak completely dis-
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

appears. Total debt can also be split between long-term and


short-term debt (Figs 1c± f) and in fact it is discovered that
Table 4. Correlation coeYcients between the change in short-term
debt in t1 1 and the level of short-term debt in t. The year identiWes whatever problem the `little peak’ in 1992 might cause, it is
time t not due to long-term debt, on the contrary it is due to
short-term debt (less than 1 year).
1992 1993 1994 1995 In the light of this evidence it can therefore be concluded
Total 70.28 70.38 70.28 70.21 that, at least for the sample of ® rms investigated, there was
State 70.18 70.50 70.15** 70.19* not a stock problem with huge amount of bank debt
Private 70.39 70.37 70.29 70.21 (mainly long-term debt) being concentrated among loss
Big 70.33 70.34 70.26 70.11** making ® rms, and therefore the determinants of debt that
Small 70.26 70.40 70.31 70.29
will be investigated in the next sections should be deter-
mined principally by demand and supply considerations.
The graphs used before can be a useful starting point to
for state versus private ® rms. The coe cients marked with investigate issues related to the ¯ ows of debt rather than to
a * or with ** denote respectively values that are not sig- the stock. In assessing whether or not banks are lending to
ni® cant and values that are signi® cant at 10% level. `good’ ® rms the conditional distribution of debt can be
It seems therefore that the initial stock of debt was not looked at time t ‡ 1 over pro® ts at time t, and comparing
excessively problematic, at least not to the point of trigger- diŒerent years one can determine how this conditional dis-
ing debt rollover. This is consistent with the evidence tribution changes over time, extracting some information
advanced by Cornelli et al. (1998) that ® rms in Eastern about the dynamics of the relationship between debt and
Europe were not overloaded by debt (compared to the pro® ts. This is done in Fig. 2. 11 The ® gure shows an unam-
standards of western economies) but rather underloaded. biguous pattern: the distribution of debt is progressively
Nevertheless, even if ® rms were not on average exposed to shifting the majority of the mass (and therefore the
an excessive debt burden, things can still be problematic if mean) towards higher values of pro® tability. While in
it turns out that the distribution of debt is source of con- 1993, 42.3% of total debt was allocated to ® rms that in
cern. If debt is in fact concentrated mainly among loss the previous years displayed a negative pro® t/asset ratio,
making ® rms, bankruptcy may really become a serious the percentage dropped to 22.6% in 1996.12 It seems there-
issue. fore that banks are extracting money from loss making
The conditional distribution of debt (total, short-term ® rms and reallocating their debt towards more pro® table
and long-term) was plotted over ® rms’ after tax pro® ts of ® rms; this could be interpreted as evidence against the pres-
the same year. Looking at Fig. 1a it is noteworthy that the ence of soft budget constraints.
distribution is fairly unimodal. This is in line with the ® nd- In order to be more precise on this issue the analysis of
ings of Bonin and SchaŒer (1995) and contrasts with what SchaŒer (1998) can be followed looking at the relationship
found by Gomulka (1994) in Poland where a bimodal dis- between new credit allocation and pro® tability. New
tribution was observed with a large proportion of debt credit is measured by Net Bank Financing, i.e. the change
concentrated in loss making ® rms. To be precise Fig. 1a in bank debt minus interest payments normalized by total

11
The fact that this procedure is not rigorous is acknowledged, nevertheless it is useful to get an idea of the dynamic evolution of debt.
12
Similar results are obtained with the distribution of short-term and long-term debt.
1694 E. Colombo
.4
.4
Total debt. Fraction

Total debt. Fraction


.3
.3

.2
.2

.1
.1

0
0
-.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4
-.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4

Before tax profits over total assets. 1992 Before tax profits over total assets. 1993

(a) (b)
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

.4
.4
Long term debt. Fraction

Long term debt. Fraction

.3
.3

.2
.2

.1 .1

0 0
-.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4
Before tax profits over total assets. 1992 Before tax profits over total assets. 1993

(c) (d)
.4
.4
Short term debt. Fraction

Short term debt. Fraction

.3
.3

.2
.2

.1
.1

0
0
-.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4
-.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4

Before tax profits over total assets. 1992 Before tax profits over total assets. 1993

(e) (f)
Fig. 1. Distribution of bank debt, 1992± 1993

assets; 13 this measure indicates the direction of ¯ ows between economic viable and non-viable ® rms;14 if a ® rm
between banks and ® rms (i.e. from banks to ® rms if NBF is economically non-viable it is unable to cover its operat-
is positive, from ® rms to banks if NBF is negative) and is ing costs and should not receive any injection of new loans
plotted against ® rms pro® tability. The sample is divided from the banking sector. Figure 3a shows that for the
13
The formula used in NBF i;t ˆ …Bi;t ¡ Bi;t¡1 ¡ Ii;t †=Ai;t , where B ˆ bank debt, I ˆ interest payment and A ˆ total assets, see SchaŒer
(1998).
14
Economic viability is de® ned as earnings before interest, pro® t tax, depreciation and extraordinary charges.
Determinants of corporate capital structure 1695
.4 .4
Total debt 93. Fraction

Total debt 94. Fraction


.3 .3

.2 .2

.1 .1

0 0
-.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4

Before tax profits over total assets 92 Before tax profits over total assets 93

(a) (b)
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

.4 .4
Total debt 95. Fraction

Total debt 96. Fraction

.3 .3

.2 .2

.1 .1

0 0
-.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4

Before tax profits over total assets 94 Before tax profits over total assets 95

Fig. 2. Distribution of total bank debt with respect to previous year’s proWts

majority of economically non-viable ® rms NBF is in fact Finally, one issue is analysed that has profound implica-
negative, though there are some ® rms receiving new credit. tions for the methodological approach (Section IV).
Figure 3b shows another interesting fact: the majority of Approximately 30% of ® rms in the sample do not use
® rms is economically viable and display positive pro® ts, bank debt at all as a form of ® nancing. This ® gure is
nevertheless banks are extracting money from them and quite impressive and needs further investigation.
not providing new funds. Can this be taken as evidence Firstly, ® rms that do not use debt are on average smaller
for the presence of credit rationing? The answer is di cult than ® rms which use debt: in 1994 the former have less
because to see money ¯ owing from pro® table ® rms to than a half of the number of employees of the latter and
banks is not per se evidence of credit rationing as the latter one third of the value of net sales (see Table 5). This can
arises when ® rms willing to take on loans are denied credit. signal the presence of forms of credit rationing that are
In fact in this case pro® table ® rms may be unwilling to
cutting out of the market small ® rms. However, it is also
borrow because for instance of high interest rates, prefer-
noted that ® rms that do not use bank debt are on average
ring instead internal ® nance. This interpretation, advanced
more pro® table and can dispose of a higher amount of cash
by SchaŒer (1998), is certainly part of the story.
¯ ows. This may suggest that, due to the high cost of exter-
Nevertheless performing the same analysis for each year
nal ® nance, ® rms that can do so, use internal ® nance at the
of the sample, it is noted that while the average cost of
borrowing (i.e. the real interest rate on bank loans) maximum even to the point of not using bank ® nance at
between 1993 and 1996 fell from more than 14% (1993) all. Probably the truth is in the middle, i.e. what is observed
to less than 7% (1996) (source National Bank of Hungary, is a combination of credit rationing and high cost of exter-
1997), the proportion of economically viable ® rms with nal ® nance, nevertheless the outcome is a particular distri-
positive pro® tability and characterized by negative NBF bution of debt across ® rms that in turn aŒects heavily the
increased from 42± 58% . This pattern suggests that forms methodology used in the empirical analysis. The next sec-
of credit rationing were at work during this period. tion investigates this issue.
1696 E. Colombo

30
attention was restricted to short-term bank debt. The
choice is motivated by the fact that the time horizon con-
sidered (1992± 1996) is still very close to the pre-transition
Net Bank Financing 1995

20

period where presumably the majority of decisions con-


10 cerning long-term debt have been taken. Concentrating
on short-term debt (de® ned as debt with less than 1 year
0 maturity) avoid mixing pre-transition with post-transition
decisions about the capital structure. Short-term debt is in
-10 any case the predominant form of debt for the ® rms inves-
tigated (it accounts for more than 80% of total bank debt);
-20
at the same time short-term debt has a time horizon su -
ciently limited to capture all the relevant changes one is
-30
interested in.
-50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0 10
Profitability 1994
Since a limited fraction of the ® rms are quoted, only
book value measures are available for the relevant vari-
(a) ables. It can be argued that decisions about ® rms’ capital
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

structure are taken considering market value ® gures; for-


30
tunately, as shown by Bowman (1980), the cross sectional
correlation between book and market value of debt is very
Net Bank Financing 1995

20
high, reducing the potential misspeci® cation problem
10
deriving from the use of book value measures.15
The observation that 30% of ® rms in the sample do not
0
use debt conditions heavily the econometric methodology
used. This aspect makes the distribution that applies to the
-10 sample data a mixture of a continuous and discrete distri-
bution calling for the use of a censored regression (Tobit)
-20 model. The general formulation of the Tobit model is con-
structed as follows: let y¤ be the original variable and let y
-30 be a new random variable transformed from the original
-30 -20 -10 0 10 20 30 40 one. The estimated model is:
Profitability 1994
y¤i;t ˆ ­ xi;t
0
‡ "i;t …1†
Fig. 3. Net bank Wnancing versus proWtability: (a) economically
non-viable Wrms, (b) economically viable Wrms. Data are weighted yi;t ˆ y¤i;t if y¤i;t > 0
by total debt
yi;t ˆ 0 otherwise
Table 5. Firms that use or do not use debt. Average values, 1994
Censored regressions in cross sections is now routine analy-
Firms with Debt Firms without Debt sis, but when considering panel data this estimation
method is not so straightforward. The basic problem is
Employment 480 204 that it is not possible to sweep away ® xed eŒects using
Net sales (Mil. Ft.) 2.92 0.94
Cash ¯ ows/total assets 0.051 0.073 the within transformation . The reason is that in presence
of a censored distribution the ­ and the individual eŒects
(·) are not anymore asymptotically independent (unless the
time horizon is in® nite) resulting in an inconsistent estimate
of ·i that is transmitted into inconsistent estimates of ­ i :
IV. METHODOLOGY Unlike ® xed eŒects estimates, random eŒect estimates are
consistent. Recently Honore (1993) used symmetry con-
In order to investigate the determinants of capital structure ditions for the conditional distribution of yi,t on xi,t to
choice the approaches of Rajan and Zingales (1995) and derive a GMM estimator for ® xed eŒects. This approach
Cornelli et al. (1996) were followed in estimating a reduced is not used here because of the limited time horizon.
form equation with a measure of leverage as the dependent Typically in fact GMM estimators sweep out ® xed eŒects
variable. Among the diŒerent measures of leverage that can by taking ® rst diŒerences; moreover to satisfy the ortho-
be used (total liabilities, total debt, coverage ratio, etc.), gonality conditions the natural candidates are lagged vari-

15
Virtually all studies on ® rms’ capital structure (see Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Titman and Wessels, 1988) do not ® nd any diŒerence
between using market and book value variables.
Determinants of corporate capital structure 1697
ables; this is particularly true for dynamic panel data (see Table 6. Cross-section estimates; dependent variable: sdtat1 1 (t-
Arellano and Bover, 1997) for which the process of diŒer- values in parentheses). The year refers to variables at time t.
encing and constructing lags takes between four and ® ve 1992 1993 1994 1995
time periods. For this reason, given the limited time
domain of the data set a random eŒect Tobit model lsalt 0.021 0.038 0.047 0.040
using ML estimators is estimated; to control for possible (3.98) (6.88) (8.58) (6.37)
cftat 70.048 70.139 70.264 70.105
endogeneity the explanatory variables were lagged by one (70.95) (73.07) (75.85) (72.03)
period. Individual invariant time eŒect was also controlled tatat 0.105 0.073 0.093 0.025
by using a two-way error component model. Equation 1 (3.46) (2.59) (3.14) (0.72)
becomes iatat 70.220 70.219 70.309 70.214
(75.13) (75.60) (77.80) (74.60)
invntat 0.325 0.280 0.326 0.281
y¤i;t ˆ ­ xi;t
0
‡ ·i ‡ ¶t ‡ ui;t (7.27) (6.82) (7.77) (6.05)
invtat 0.010 70.006 0.050 0.098
where ·i denote unobservable, individual, time invariant, (0.19) (70.09) (0.70) (1.39)
eŒects, ¶t accounts for any individual invariant time eŒect dfshrt 70.005 0.002 0.024 0.004
(70.41) (0.23) (2.06) (0.35)
and ui,t is the remaining stochastic disturbance.16
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

dempt 0.027 0.008 0.11 0.045


Finally to reduce the problem of heteroscedasticity the (2.12) (0.71) (0.91) (2.97)
relevant variables are normalized by total assets.17 mpshrt 0.012 70.054 70.028 70.028
The distinctions made at a theoretical level (Section II) (0.27) (71.24) (70.66) (70.47)
down t 70.041 70.047 70.012 70.008
can be very rarely carried over at the empirical level. This (73.23) (74.01) (70.77) (70.38)
problem arises also in the present work, where the esti- const 70.353 70.557 70.734 70.597
mated reduced form equations do not allow demand to (74.83) (77.41) (79.52) (76.91)
be distinguished from supply side eŒects. The cause of À2 119.78 174.66 259.96 177.94
Uncens. obs. 610 642 643 650
most concern is pro® tability: it has already been stressed Cens. obs 386 403 410 396
that supply side considerations predict a positive relation-
ship between banks’ debt and pro® ts. But pro® ts are also a
major determinant of cash ¯ ows, and demand side consid- sdta ¤i;t‡1 ˆ ¬ ‡ ­ 1 lsali;t ‡ ­ 2 cfta i;t ‡ ­ 3 tata i;t
erations predict a negative relationship between debt and
‡ ­ 4 iata i;t ‡ ­ 5 invnta i;t ‡ ­ 6 invta i;t
cash ¯ ows (if debt is more costly than internal ® nance,
® rms that have higher internal cash will try to substitute ‡ ­ 7 dfshr i;t ‡ ­ 8 mpshr i;t ‡ ­ 9 demp i;t
debt with it). Therefore the sign of the coe cient is going to ‡ ­ 10 downi;t ‡ "i;t‡1 …2†
depend on the relative strength of those two eŒects. In the
case of Eastern Europe, the shock of transition, and the The variables are identi® ed as follows: sdta 5 short-term
consequent massive change that it entailed, caused short- debt over total assets; lsal 5 logarithm of net sales, cfta 5
term performance to be a very poor indicator of future cash ¯ ows over total assets; tata 5 tangible assets over
long-term performance, while on the other hand the wide- total assets; invnta 5 inventories over total assets; invta 5
spread presence of credit rationing induced ® rms to rely investment over total assets; dfshr 5 dummy for foreign
heavily on internal ® nance. Pro® ts are therefore expected ownership (takes value of 1 if foreign share of capital is
to capture a demand rather than a supply eŒect and pro® ts greater than 10% ); mpshr 5 share of net sales over total
have been included in the regressions as part of cash ¯ ows sales in the four digit industry; demp5 dummy for employ-
ment (takes value of 1 if employment is greater than 300);
and not as an isolated regressor.
down 5 dummy for ownership (takes value of 1 if the ® rm
is state-owned); " identi® es the remaining stochastic dis-
turbance. Table 6 shows the results.18
Size (approximate d by the logarithm of net sales) is posi-
V . E M P I R I C A L R ES U L T S
tively related with debt indicating that big ® rms tend to
have an easier access to bank credit with respect to small
Cross sectional evidence
® rms. The positive eŒect of size is much more weak when
For each year t Equation 1 becomes we consider the more `political’ measure, that is the number
16
It is assumed that ui;t ¹ IID…0; ¼2u †.
17
An alternative normalization by total sales yielded the same results.
18
The table does not show a measure for Pseudo-R 2 . As it is well known the widely used formula Pseudo-R 2 ˆ 1 ¡ L1 =L0 (where L1 and
L0 are respectively the constant-only and full model Log-Likelihoods) works only in the presence of discrete distributions. It breaks down
with mixed continuous/discrete distributions like Tobit. For this reason the model À2 is reported insead.
1698 E. Colombo
of employees. The employment dummy is in fact positive which have the better growth prospects. The signalling
and signi® cant only in 1992 and 1995 but it is not signi® - eŒect of past investment do not seem to enable ® rms to
cant (with very low t statistics) in 1993 and 1994.19 It seems take on more leverage as investment turns out to be always
therefore that the eŒect of size indicates that big ® rms tend insigni® cant in the regressions.22
to be facilitated in accessing bank debt, because they are Turning now to the two `® nancial’ variables, cash ¯ ows
more diversi® ed, more than because big ® rms are `politi- and interenterprise arrears, they seem to indicate the exist-
cally’ protected by the concern on their employment level. ence of a `pecking-order’ theory of ® nance with internal
Another aspect that has to be analysed jointly with size is funds preferred over trade credit preferred over bank
the issue of ownership. As big ® rms are mainly state owned debt. The availability of internal funds is measured by
® rms which could be protected by an implicit bailout clause cash ¯ ows which display a negative coe cient (with the
by the government, they may have easier access to credit exception of 1992 when the coe cient is not signi® cant)
simply because they are state-owned. The study is reas- suggesting that ® rms substitute external with internal
sured by the fact that the dummy for ownership, when ® nance when they have the opportunity to do so (i.e. exter-
signi® cant (1992 and 1993), is negative indicating that pri- nal ® nance is more costly than internal ® nance). At the
vate ® rms are the ones that take on more debt, suggesting same time the negative coe cient on interenterprise arrears
that private ownership and not state ownership conveys a show that ® rms tend to substitute bank with interenterprise
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

positive signal to the credit market.20 debt.


Considering the other variables, except for 1995, tan- The results presented in Table 6 show, somewhat surpris-
gibility is positive and signi® cant; this is in line with the ingly, that the degree of market power of the ® rm does not
results usually obtained in western-type economies (see seem to have any eŒect on the amount of leverage. The
Rajan and Zingales, 1995) where debt has a strong positive variable mpshr is never signi® cant for the years considered;
relation with tangible assets. However, it contrasts with the some diŒerent speci® cations were also tried, replacing the
results of Cornelli et al. (1998) who ® nd a negative correla- continuous variable with a dummy and using as an alter-
tion between tangible assets and debt, in Poland and native measure of the market power the number of ® rms in
Hungary. The results of Cornelli et al. (1998) for the four digit industry. Firms’ market power does not
Hungary are probably due to the diŒerent estimation tech- determine an easier access to the credit market.
niques (they estimate a normal OLS regression): in fact if Finally, with the exception of 1994, foreign ownership
on the sample, instead of a Tobit, we run a simple OLS dummy is never signi® cant. The result seems quite robust
regression, the positive eŒect of tangibility disappears. (diŒerent cut-oŒvalues as 20 and 30% ) were tried. This
As stressed previously in transitional economies ® xed ® nding is puzzling mainly when referred to the initial years
assets are probably not a good measure of collateral as one would expect that with time and the improvement of
because they may be overvalued21 or because there may e ciency of ® nancial markets the positive signalling role of
be an ine cient secondary market. Inventories were there- foreign ownership would diminish.23
fore included in the regression as an alternative measure of On the other hand the non-signi® cance of this variable
collateral. Inventories should reduce both the problems of can indicate the inability to distinguish between demand
evaluation and of the e ciency of a secondary market. The side and supply side eŒects. From the demand side in
coe cient on inventories is in fact positive and strongly fact it was expected that banks would favour foreign
signi® cant denoting that they provide a good proxy for owned ® rms but from the supply side foreign owned
collateral. Apart for the risk of default, banks should ® rms may have access to cheaper internal (i.e. through
also be concerned for ® rms’ future prospects. In the sample the foreign owner) ® nance, reducing in this way the amount
® rms that have invested more are taken as proxies of ® rms of external ® nance.24
19
A diŒerent speci® cation was tried using the dummy at 500 employees obtaining analogous results.
20
The non-signi® cance of the ownership dummy for 1994 and 1995 is probably due to the change in the classi® cation of ® rms occurred in
1993. Stated owned ® rms were classi® ed as both co-operatives and state owned ® rms (see Table 2); the signi® cant drop in the number of
co-operatives occurred after 1993 explains therefore the nonsigni® cance of the coe cient.
21
This is very likely if ® xed assets are recorded by their book value.
22
The presence of investment as a regressor may rise doubts about the existence of possible multicollinearity with other variables, in
particular with cash ¯ ows. If a ® rm invested in the past and the investment turned out to be successful it will have higher pro® ts in the
subsequent period and therefore higher cash ¯ ows. In the sample multicollinearity between those two variables does not seem to be a
problem; more precisely the pairwise correlation is always below 30% , and neither the sign of the coe cients nor their signi® cance
change when one of the variable is deleted. The investment variable can also create a possible problem of endogeneity.
23
In fact Csermely and Vincze (1999) with a similar sample ® nd no signi® cant eŒect of foreign ownership on ® rms’ debt for the year 1996.
24
Moreover in general one has to be cautious when assessing the role of foreign ownership in capital structure decisions of Eastern
European ® rms. At least in the initial years of transition foreign ownership in fact could represent both solid Western European or also
very risky Eastern European (mainly Russian) capital. In the sample the opportunity of distinguishing foreign ownership by country of
origin is not present.
Determinants of corporate capital structure 1699
Table 7. Panel estimates: dependent variable sdtat1 1 issue: if past investment has been ® nanced by bank debt,
the estimated coe cient would eŒectively capture the
CoeŒ. Std. Std. err. t
eŒects of another (latent) variable and therefore invalidate
lsal t 0.033 0.003 8.864 the inference about the variable of interest.
cftat 70.060 0.021 72.925 However, the choice of the dependent variable should
tatat 0.033 0.017 1.925 reduce the above mentioned problem as short-term debt
iatat 70.117 0.020 75.864
invntat 0.183 0.026 7.100 is rarely used to ® nance investment projects. The correla-
invtat 0.051 0.024 2.086 tion coe cient was calculated between past debt and
À2 271.19 investment and it resulted quite low (around 30% ). In
Uncens.obs 2536 any case the results about investment should be taken
Cens. Obs. 1607 with a bit of caution. Two of the three year dummies26
(not reported in Table 7 are signi® cant, indicating the pres-
ence of some time eŒect that is individual invariant. This
The results of the cross sections suggest the presence of most likely captures the eŒects of business cycle factors on
an underlying problem of asymmetric information in the the aggregate level of leverage.
credit market; this informational problem aŒects the ability
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

of ® rms in achieving their optimal capital structure.


Evidence for this is provided by the relevance of variables VI. CONCLUSIONS
like cash ¯ ows and interenterprise debt that suggest the
existence of a `pecking order’ in ® rms’ ® nancing choices. This work used a panel consisting of approximately 1100
But on the other hand there are some positive and reassur- observations, over ® ve years, of Hungarian ® rms to inves-
ing signs, as bank debt does not seem to be related to state tigate the presence of constraints to these ® rms in achieving
ownership or market power; this in turn suggests that their optimal capital structure and more in general the
banks are correctly discriminating between ® rms’ types. `e ciency’ of the banking sector in providing credit.
There is evidence of the existence of a `pecking order’ in
Panel evidence ® rms’ ® nancing choices suggesting the presence of forms of
® nancial market imperfections that constrain them in the
The panel analysis follows the same Tobit procedure than achievement of their optimal capital structure. On the
the cross section; Equation 2 becomes now: other hand there are also reassuring signs: following the
shock of transition and in the presence of imperfections
sdta ¤i;t‡1 ˆ ¬ ‡ ­ 1 lsal i;t ‡ ­ 2 cfta i;t ‡ ­ 3 tata i;t
in the ® nancial markets, banks could have reacted in two
‡ ­ 4 iata i;t ‡ ­ 5 invntai;t ‡ ­ 6 invta i;t ways: one, the easiest and the most myopic, would have
seen banks looking for the short-term safety of large mono-
‡ ¯t‡1 ‡ ²i ‡ "i;t‡1 …3†
polistic state owned ® rms and even gamble for bailout of
All the variables are de® ned as in the cross section. loss making state owned enterprises. The second way
Ownership and market share dummies were not included would have seen banks actively trying to resolve the infor-
in the regression, as they did not add anything to the ® nd- mational problems, allocating funds where it was possible
ings of the cross section (the results of course do not to obtain adequate (and correct) collateral provisions,
change if we include those variables). Table 7 presents esti- looking at ® rms’ long-term growth opportunities ® rms,
mated coe cients, standard errors and t values. etc. The analysis conducted in this paper suggests that
The panel results con® rm fully what is found in the Hungarian banks seem to have chosen the second way
cross-section: all variables maintain their sign and degree raising hopes of a fast resolution of the problems that are
of signi® cance. There is only one diŒerence between the currently a‚ icting the ® nancial market.
cross-section and the panel estimate and it is constituted
by investment.25 Now investment is positive and signi® -
cant, suggesting that if a ® rm invested in the past it is ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
more likely to get credit from the banks. As stressed in
the theoretical part this may be due to the fact that past This research is part of the Phare-Ace Project N. P96-6151-
investment can be a signal of future growth opportunities R `The Role of Financial Markets in Transition’. Many
and therefore generate a positive relationship with debt. thanks to John Dri ll, Sally Srinivasan, Luca Stanca,
There is one consideration that has to be done on this AÂkos Valentinyi and JaÂnos Vincze for helpful comments.

25
As explained in the Appendix the estimates presented in Table 7 present a precise and reliable information on the sign and the
signi® cance but not on the size of the parameters. For this reason in interpreting the results we will only look at the sign and signi® cance.
26
One dummy (1992 in this case) had to be dropped to avoid perfect collinearity.
1700 E. Colombo
Thanks to JaÂnos Vincze for providing 1996 data. The usual HonoreÂ, B. E. (1992) Trimmed LAD and least squares estimation
disclaimer applies. of truncated and censored regression models with ® xed
eŒects, Econometrica, 60, 533± 65.
HonoreÂ, B. E. (1993) Orthogonality conditions for Tobit models
with ® xed eŒects and lagged dependent variables, Journal of
R E F E R E N C ES Econometrics, 59, 35± 61.
Arellano, M. and Bover O. (1997) Estimating dynamic limited Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (1958) The cost of capital, corpora-
dependent variable models from panel data, Investigationes tion ® nance and the theory of investment, American
Economicas, 21, 141-65. Economic Review, 48, 261± 97.
BergloÈf, E. and Roland, G. (1995) Bank restructuring and soft Myers, S. C. (1984) The capital structure puzzle, Journal of
budget constraints in ® nancial transition, Journal of the Finance, 39, 575± 92.
Japanese and International Economies, 9, 354± 75. Myers, S. C. and Majluf, N. S. (1984) Corporate ® nancing and
BergloÈf, E. and Roland, G. (1997) Soft budget constraints and investment decisions when ® rms have informations that
credit crunches in ® nancial transition, European Economic investors do not have, Journal of Financial Economics, 13,
Review, 41, 807± 17. 187± 221.
Bernanke, B. and Gertler, M. (1989) Agency costs, net worth and National Bank of Hungary (1997) Annual Report.
business ¯ uctuation, American Economic Review, 79, 14± 31. Rajan, R. G. and Zingales, L. (1995) What do we know about
Bond, S. and Meghir, C. (1994) Dynamic investment models and capital structure? Some evidence from international data,
the ® rm’ s ® nancial policy, Review of Economic Studies, 61, Journal of Finance, 50, 1421± 60.
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

197± 222. Revoltella, D. (1998) Debt ® nancing in the Czech Republic: the
Bonin, J. P. and SchaŒer, M. E. (1995) Banks, ® rms, bad debt and importance of ® rm-speci® c variables, mimeo, Bocconi
bankruptcy in Hungary 1991± 1994, Discussion Paper N.234, University.
CEP. Ross, S. (1977) The determinants of ® nancial structure: the incen-
Bowman, J. (1980) The importance of a market value measure- tive signalling approach, Bell Journal of Economics, 8, 23± 40.
ment of debt in assessing leverage, Journal of Accounting SchaŒer, M. E., (1998) Do ® rms in transition economies have soft
Research, 18, 242± 54. budget constraints? A reconsideration of concepts and evi-
Bradley, M., Jarrell, G. and Kim, E. H. (1984) On the existence of dence, Journal of Comparative Economics, 26, 80± 103.
an optimal capital structure: theory and evidence, Journal of Schiantarelli, F. (1997) Financial constraints and investment:
Finance, 39, 857± 78. methodological issues and international evidence, Oxford
Calvo, G. A. and Coricelli, F. (1994) Inter-enterprise areas in Review of Economic Policy, 12, 70± 89.
economies in transition, in Output Decline in Eastern Shyam-Sunder, L. and Myers, S. C. (1999) Testing static tradeoŒ
Europe (Eds) R. Holzmann, J. GaÂcs, and G. Winckler, against pecking order models of capital structure, Journal of
Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publisher. Financial Economics, 1999, 51, 219± 44.
Carare, O. and Perotti, E. C. (1997) The evolution of bank credit Titman, S. and Wessels, R. (1988) The determinants of capital
quality in transition: theory and evidence from Romania, structure choice, Journal of Finance, 43, 1± 19.
Discussion Paper 97/02, CERT.
Cornelli, F., Portes, R. and SchaŒer, M. E. (1998) The capital
structure of ® rms in central and eastern Europe, in DiVerent
Paths to a Market Economy: China and European Economies APPENDIX
in Transition (Eds) O. Bouin, F. Coricelli and F. Lemoine,
CEPR. The following consistency checks were applied to the data:
Csermely, AÂ. and Vincze, J. (1999) Leverage and foreign owner-
ship in Hungary, Working Paper N.1999-1, National Bank of ® rms which presented negative values for the following
Hungary. variables were dropped from the sample: sales, employ-
Gomulka, S. (1994) The ® nancial situation of enterprises and its ment, debt (short and long term).
impact on monetary and ® scal policies, Poland 1992± 1993, The procedure used to identify outliers deserves some
Economics of Transition, 2, 189± 208. attention: it is often di cult to identify in¯ uential observa-
Greenwald, B. C. and Stiglitz, J. E. (1993) Financial market
imperfections and business cycles, Quarterly Journal of tions (i.e. observations that, if removed, would change the
Economics, 108, 77± 114. estimated coe cients markedly); the di culties increase
Hadi, A. S. (1992) Identifying multiple outliers in multivariate when multivariate data is considered. In the analysis a
data, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 54, 761± 71. method developed by Hadi (1992, 1994) was employed.
Hadi, A. S. (1994) A modi® cation of a method for the detection of This method can brie¯ y be described as follows. Given p
outliers in multivariate samples, Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society, 56, 393± 6. variables the procedure de® nes an initial cluster of points
Harris, M. and Raviv, A. (1991) The theory of capital structure, de® ned as r ˆ p ‡ 1, selected minimizing a measure of dis-
Journal of Finance, 46, 297± 355. tance.27 Once the initial cluster is de® ned, it is then

27
More precisely let X be a n £ p vector representing a random sample of size n from a p-dimensonal population and let
t
D2i …C; V† ˆ …xi ¡ C† V ¡1 …xi ¡ C†, i ˆ 1; . . . ; n be an appropriate metric that measures the squared distance between the ith observation
(xi ) and a centre estimator denoted as C, relative to a measure of dispersion (V), the distance chosen by Hadi is
T
D2i …CR ; SR † ˆ …xi ¡ CR † SR¡1 …xi ¡ CR †
where CR and SR are robust estimators of the centre and covariance matrix.
Determinants of corporate capital structure 1701
expanded taking the r ‡ 1 closest points (according to the A ® nal note is referred to the panel estimator. As stressed
same measure of distance). The procedure is then repeated in the chapter the panel estimates presented in section 5.2
until some stopping rule is satis® ed. are random eŒects estimates. The way the estimators are
The programme Stata, used in the calculations, allow to derived is through a quadrature of the likelihood function.
perform such routine and also to de® ne a `signi® cance’ This procedure is sensitive to the number of quadrature
level for the outlier cutoŒ; as usual in statistical analysis points, in particular for large panels the approximation
the signi® cance level was chosen to be 5% . This procedure may become poor. It is possible to check the sensitiveness
has the big advantage that allows to deal easily with multi- of parameter estimates to the variation of the number of
variate data; the routine was compared with other methods quadrature points. It turns out that the parameters are
of identifying outliers like residuals analysis, tests based on sensitive to changes in the number of quadrature points,
however the sign and the degree of signi® cance of par-
Cook’s and Welsch distances, etc. In all cases it yielded
ameters do not change. For this reason the results pre-
better results in terms of the overall ® t of the model
sented in Table 7 should be interpreted only as an
being more parsimonious in terms of the variables identi-
indication for the sign of the coe cients and not for their
® ed as outliers.
exact value.
Downloaded by [University of Connecticut] at 01:56 30 October 2014

You might also like