The Politics of Nation Building Making Co Nationals Refugees and Minorities - Compress

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 282

The Politics of Nation-Building

Making Co-Nationals, Refugees, and Minorities

What drives a state’s choice to assimilate, accommodate, or exclude


ethnic groups within its territory? In this pathbreaking work on the
international politics of nation-building, Harris Mylonas argues that a
state’s nation-building policies toward non-core groups – any aggrega-
tion of individuals perceived as an unassimilated ethnic group by the
ruling elite of a state – are influenced by both its foreign policy goals and
its relations with the external patrons of these groups. Through a
detailed study of the Balkans, Mylonas shows that the way a state treats
a non-core group within its own borders is determined largely by
whether the state’s foreign policy is revisionist or cleaves to the interna-
tional status quo, and whether it is allied or in rivalry with that group’s
external patrons. Mylonas explores the effects of external involvement
on the salience of cultural differences and the planning of nation-
building policies. The Politics of Nation-Building injects international
politics into the study of nation-building, building a bridge between
international relations and the comparative politics of ethnicity and
nationalism. This is the first book to explain systematically how the
politics of ethnicity in the international arena determine which groups
are assimilated, accommodated, or annihilated by their host states.

Harris Mylonas is an Assistant Professor of Political Science and


International Affairs at George Washington University. He completed
his PhD in Political Science at Yale University and is a Scholar at the
Harvard Academy for International and Area Studies.
Problems of International Politics

Series Editors
Keith Darden, Yale University
Ian Shapiro, Yale University

The series seeks manuscripts central to the understanding of international poli-


tics that will be empirically rich and conceptually innovative. It is interested in
works that illuminate the evolving character of nation-states within the interna-
tional system. It sets out three broad areas for investigation: (1) Identity, security,
and conflict; (2) Democracy; and (3) Justice and distribution.

Titles in the Series


Şener Aktürk, Regimes of Ethnicity and Nationhood in Germany, Russia, and
Turkey
Donald Horowitz, Constitutional Change and Democracy in Indonesia
Steven Levitsky and Lucan A. Way, Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid
Regimes After the Cold War
The Politics of Nation-Building
Making Co-Nationals, Refugees, and Minorities

HARRIS MYLONAS
George Washington University
cambridge university press
Cambridge, New York, Melbourne, Madrid, Cape Town,
Singapore, São Paulo, Delhi, Mexico City
Cambridge University Press
32 Avenue of the Americas, New York, ny 10013-2473, usa

www.cambridge.org
Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9781107661998

© Harris Mylonas 2012

This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception


and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,
no reproduction of any part may take place without the written
permission of Cambridge University Press.

First published 2012

Printed in the United States of America

A catalog record for this publication is available from the British Library.

Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data


Mylonas, Harris, 1978–
The politics of nation-building : making co-nationals, refugees, and minorities / Harris Mylonas.
p. cm. – (Problems of international politics)
Includes bibliographical references and index.
isbn 978-1-107-02045-0 (hardback) – isbn 978-1-107-66199-8 (pbk.)
1. Nation-building – Balkan Peninsula – History. 2. Minorities – Government policy – Balkan
Peninsula. 3. Ethnic groups – Government policy – Balkan Peninsula. 4. Balkan Peninsula –
Ethnic relations. 5. Balkan Peninsula – Foreign relations. 6. Ethnicity – Political aspects –
Balkan Peninsula. 7. Nationalism – Balkan Peninsula. I. Title.
jn97.a38m557 2012
327.10 1–dc23 2012011707

isbn 978-1-107-02045-0 Hardback


isbn 978-1-107-66199-8 Paperback

Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of urls for
external or third-party Internet Web sites referred to in this publication and does not guarantee
that any content on such Web sites is, or will remain, accurate or appropriate.

Cover image: Artist: Udo J. Keppler, 1872–1956.


Caption: At present he works Bulgaria. A continuous performance since Peter, the Great. Summary:
Illustration shows a puppeteer labeled “Russia” with marionettes labeled “Bulgaria” and “Macedonia”
engaged in a sword fight; the Bulgarian puppet is about to cut the head off the Macedonian puppet, who
has dropped his sword. Hanging on the side of the theater, to the left, are three puppets labeled
“Roumelia, Servia, [and] Roumania.” Date created/published: New York: J. Ottmann Lith., 7 October
1903. Source: Library of Congress Prints and Photographs Division, Washington, D.C. Available at:
http://www.loc.gov/pictures/item/2010652307/.
To my parents Eleni and George, and my sister Sophia
Contents

List of Figures, Maps, Tables, Graph, and Illustrations page xi


Acknowledgments xv
List of Abbreviations xvii
Preface xix

1 Introduction 1
The Puzzle 1
The Argument 5
Why Study Nation-Building Policies? 9
Book Plan 10

part i. theory
2 The International Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation,
and Exclusion 17
Nation-Building Policies: Assimilation, Accommodation, and
Exclusion 21
Actors: Host State, Non-Core Group, External Power 23
A Geostrategic Argument: Alliances and Foreign Policy Goals 35
Conclusion 48

part ii. empirical evidence


3 Why the Balkans? 53
Ottoman Legacy in the Balkans 54
Great Powers, Balkan States, and the “Eastern Question” 57
The Balkan States Following World War I 67
4 Cross-National Variation: Nation-Building in Post–World
War I Balkans 71
Research Design: Operationalization and Measurement 72
Analysis 74

ix
x Contents

Issues of Causal Inference 91


Conclusion 95
5 Odd Cases: Analysis of Outliers 97
Time Horizon 97
Mixed Policies 102
Terminal versus Transitional Policies 105
Foreign Policy Priorities and Asymmetric Alliances 110
A “Divide and Rule” Strategy 111
Conclusion 112
6 Subnational Variation: Greek Nation-Building in Western
Macedonia, 1916–1920 113
The Context 115
Muslims 122
Christians 129
What Explains Variation in Nation-Building Policies? 138
Conclusion 140
7 Temporal Variation: Serbian Nation-Building toward
Albanians, 1878–1941 142
The Revisionist Kingdom of Serbia 144
The Status Quo Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes 153
The Role of Domestic Politics 164
Conclusion 168
8 Application of the Theory Beyond the Balkans 170
Same Region, Different Periods 171
Different Regions, Different Contexts 174
Conclusion 185
9 Conclusion 187
Three Conceptual Moves 189
Methodological Contributions 190
Policy Implications 195

Methodological Appendix 201


References 219
Author Index 245
Historical Name Index 246
Subject Index 248
List of Figures, Maps, Tables, Graph, and Illustrations

figures
2.1 Predictions of Existing Explanations page 18
2.2 Theory Predictions 37
2.3 Non-Core Group Residing in Area “Z” Is Not Supported by
Any External Power 38
2.4 Non-Core Group Residing in Area “Z” Is Supported by an
Allied Power 40
2.5 Non-Core Group Residing in Area “Z” Is Supported by an
Enemy Power, Host State Is Revisionist 42
2.6 Host State and External Power Are Contiguous and Have Each
Other’s Co-Ethnics 43
2.7 Non-Core Group Residing in Area “Z” Is Supported by an
Enemy Power, Host State Is Status Quo 44
4.1 Multinomial Logit Models 87
7.1 Serbian Nation-Building toward Albanians, 1878–1941 144
8.1 Scapegoating 173

maps
3.1 Origins of Bulgarian Revisionism 62
3.2 Competing National Aspirations in the Balkans, 1912 65
6.1 Boundary Changes after the Balkan Wars, 1912–1913 116
6.2 Greek Macedonia and Western Greek Macedonia 120
7.1 Vilayet of Kosova, 1875–1878 146
7.2 Territorial Development of Serbia, 1817–1913 149
7.3 Oblasts in the KSCS, 1922–1929 157
7.4 Banovinas in the Kingdom of Yugoslavia, 1929–1941 161

xi
xii List of Figures, Maps, Tables, Graph, and Illustrations

tables
4.1 Descriptive Statistics 76
4.2.I Language 77
4.2.II Religious Denomination 77
4.2.III World Religion 78
4.2.IV Non-Core Group Primarily Urban 78
4.2.V Nomadic Non-Core Group 79
4.2.VI Rural Non-Core Group 79
4.2.VII Non-Core Group Has Experienced Status Reversal 80
4.2.VIII Non-Core Group Has a Homeland 80
4.2.IX Non-Core Group Larger Than 1% of the Total
Population 81
4.2.X Non-Core Group Larger Than 5% of the Total
Population 81
4.2.XI Configuration I: External Support 82
4.2.XII Configuration II: External Support by Allied Power 82
4.2.XIII External Support by Enemy Power 83
4.2.XIV Host State Foreign Policy Goals 83
4.2.XV Configuration III: Exclusion of Enemy-Supported
Group in Revisionist State 84
4.2.XVI Configuration IV: Group Supported by Enemy in Status
Quo State 84
4.2.XVII Host State and External Power Contiguous and Have
Co-Ethnics 85
4.2.XVIII Host State Faces More Than One Secessionist Non-Core
Group 85
4.2.XIX Correctly Predicted 86
4.3 Multinomial Logit Estimates for Nation-Building
Policies in Post–World War I Balkans 88
4.4 Probability of Assimilation 90
4.5 Probability of Accommodation 90
4.6 Probability of Exclusion 90
4.7 Domestic Politics and Nation-Building Policies,
c. 1918–1924 93
5.1 Incorrect Predictions 98
6.1 Non-Core Groups in Greek Macedonia (c.1915) 121
6.2 Explaining Nation-Building Policies in Western
Macedonia, 1916–1918, Greece Revisionist 123
6.3 Explaining Nation-Building Policies in Western
Macedonia, 1918–1920, Greece Status Quo 124
6.4 Evaluating Existing Explanations in Western
Macedonia, 1916–1918 130
List of Figures, Maps, Tables, Graph, and Illustrations xiii

6.5 Evaluating Existing Explanations in Western Macedonia,


1918–1920 139
7.1 Serbian Nation-Building toward Albanians, 1878–1941 147
8.1 Nation-Building Policies toward China’s Largest Non-Core
Groups, 1949–1965 179
8.2 Ethnic Composition of Estonia, 1920–1989 181
8.3 Russians Living in Estonia, 1989 182
A.1 Non-Core Groups with a Population Smaller Than 1% of the
Total Population of the Host State 206
A.2 Non-Core Groups with a Population Larger Than 1% of the
Total Population of the Host State 208
A.3 Non-Core Groups with a Population Larger Than 5% of the
Total Population of the Host State 209

graph
4.1 Nation-Building Policies in Post–World War I Balkans,
1918–1923 75

illustrations
3.1 At Present He Works Bulgaria 58
3.2 Eight Members of the Ottoman Cavalry on Horseback with
Flags 63
3.3 Greek Infantry Officers 66
6.1 French General Sarrail with Prime Minister Venizelos 118
6.2 Governor Ioannis Eliakis Addresses Muslims in Florina, 1920 128
7.1 Üsküb: King of Serbia Welcomed by Mayor 150
7.2 King Zog 160
7.3 King Aleksandar 167
Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Stathis Kalyvas, who turned me into a social scientist. Keith
Darden, Ivo Banac, Juan Linz, Ioannis Evrigenis, Bill Foltz, Nicholas Sambanis,
and Andreas Wimmer were all there when I felt I had run out of inspiration. This
book would not have been written without their support and guidance. George
Mavrogordatos has been and remains my mentor for more than fifteen years
now. He has helped me in innumerable ways.
I was also fortunate to discuss and receive feedback on specific chapters and in
some cases on the whole manuscript from Robert Adcock, Dia Anagnostou, Ana
Arjona, Gina Bateson, Carles Boix, Deborah Boucoyannis, Zeynep Bulutgil,
Tim Crawford, Rafaela Dancygier, Martin Dimitrov, Kristin Fabbe, Jocelyn
Friedlander, John Glavinas, Basil Gounaris, Adi Greif, Sheena Chestnut
Greitens, Eric Grynaviski, Gabor Gyori, Casiano Hacker-Cordon, Jennie Han,
Sandy Henderson, Erin Jenne, Stephen Kaplan, Jeehye Kim, Adria Lawrence,
Pantelis Lekkas, Meghan Lynch, Nikos Marantzidis, Iakovos Michailidis,
Christopher Muller, Elias Nikolakopoulos, Liz Perry, Pavel Petrov, Andrew
Radin, Maurice Richter, Nasos Roussias, Elizabeth Saunders, Jonah
Schulhofer-Wohl, John Sides, Abbey Steele, Manny Teitelbaum, Monica Toft,
Konstantinos Tsitselikis, Constantine Tsoukalas, Elpida Vogli, Tristan Volpe,
Lisa Wedeen, Libby Wood, and Yael Zeira.
I would like to thank my colleagues Martha Finnemore, James M. Goldgeier,
Hope Harrison, Jim Lebovic, Marc Lynch, Cynthia McClintock, and Mike
Mochizuki, who participated in an extremely helpful book incubator organized
by Susan Sell. I would also like to thank Jorge Dominguez, Michael Hechter,
Mark Kramer, Terry Martin, Tim Snyder, and Susan Woodward, who partici-
pated in my author’s conference – organized by Larry Winnie and Kathleen
Hoover at the Harvard Academy – their comments helped me sharpen my argu-
ment. These events were critical in both improving the content and shaping the
final structure of the book. The insicive comments made by the two anonymous
reviewers of the book for Cambridge University Press significantly improved my
argument and the presentation of the empirics. It was at this stage of that Daphne
Halikiopoulou, Henry Hale, and Matt Kocher read the manuscript and gave me
incredibly helpful comments. I can’t thank them enough for that.

xv
xvi Acknowledgments

Very important was also the role of many experts who helped me conduct
independent coding of my dataset on nation-building policies in the post–World
War I Balkans: Sener Akturk, Erol Ulker, Holy Case, Petre Opris, Peter Wien,
Eleftheria Manta, Fuat Dundar, and Irina Culic. I would like to thank Wilder
Bullard, Justin Caton, Katarina Montgomery, Seok Joon Kim, Diane Kuhn, Lisel
Hintz, Rory Schacter, Anthony Staccone, and Edlira Nasi for being excellent
research assistants.
I also want to thank the personnel at The Museum of the Macedonian
Struggle in Thessaloniki, the Archive of Eleftherios Venizelos at the Benaki
Musuem in Athens, the British National Archives, the Gennadius Library, the
General State Archives of Macedonia in Thessaloniki, the Archive of the
Hellenic Ministry of Foreign Affairs in Athens, the General State Archives of
Florina, the General State Archives of Kozani, and The Hellenic Literary and
Historical Archive in Thessaloniki.
This is the appropriate place to also thank MIT Press for allowing me to use
parts of a chapter they previously published, the Carnegie Endowment for
International Peace for giving me permission to reprint selected maps from
their Report of the International Commission to Inquire into the Causes and
Conduct of the Balkan Wars, and the Library of Congress for providing me with
amazing illustrations.
The following institutions have supported my graduate-level education and
my research for this book: the Georg W. Leitner Program in International and
Comparative Political Economy, the European Union Studies Grant, the John
F. Enders Research Grant, the Stavros Niarchos Foundation, the MacMillan
Center for International and Area Studies at Yale, the Fulbright Foundation,
Yale University, The University of Chicago, and the National Scholarship
Foundation of Greece. I thank them for their generosity.
For making my life during my graduate school years at Yale significantly better,
I would like to thank Mina Alaghband, Farhad Anklesaria, Julia Averbuck, David
Epstein, Ileana Alkistis Giannakoura, Sara Goldblatt, Jeanne Hefez, Vasilis
Kalogeridis, George Kontos, Angeliki Louvi, Panos Manologlou, Thomas
Meaney, Theo Michael, Andreas Papadakis, Thodoris Prodromidis, and Nik
Vlahos. I would also like to thank Andreas Akaras, Demetra Atsaloglou, Steven
Bloomfield, Stefania Malamatina, Konstantina Karterouli, Artemis Seaford,
George Skoulakis, Alexandros Yannis, and Marilena Zackheos for the long
discussions we have had on nation-building and other topics. And of course it
would be inappropriate not to thank my parents George and Eleni, my sister
Sophia, and the rest of the family for tolerating me. This book is dedicated to them.
My sincere thanks, penultimately, to the community at the Harvard Academy
for International and Area Studies and the Political Science department at
George Washington University for creating such a great environment in which
to finish my book. Finally yet importantly, I would like to thank the editorial and
production teams at Cambridge University Press – especially Anne Lovering
Rounds, Mark Fox, Hillary Ford, and Stephanie Sakson – and in particular
Lewis Bateman, who ensured a smooth and constructive process, the outcome of
which is in your hands. Of course all errors remain my responsibility.
List of Abbreviations

AEV Archive of Eleftherios Venizelos


APK Arheion Pavlou Kalliga
ASEAN Association of Southeast Asian Nations
AYE Archive of the Hellenic Ministry of Foreign Affairs
AU African Union
CCP Chinese Communist Party
CIA Central Intelligence Agency
ELIA The Hellenic Literary and Historical Archive
EU European Union
FO British Foreign Office
GAK/Florinas General State Archives of Florina
GAK/Kozanis General State Archives of Kozani
GAK/Makedonias General State Archives of Macedonia, Thessaloniki
G.L. Gennadius Library
IMRO Internal Macedonian Revolutionary Organization
KSCS The Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes
MP Member of Parliament
NGOs Non-Governmental Organizations
OSCE Organization for Security and Co-Operation in Europe
PRC People’s Republic of China
UN United Nations
U.S. United States of America
USIP United States Institute for Peace
U.S.S.R. Union of Soviet Socialist Republics

xvii
Preface

My paternal grandfather arrived in Greece in the early 1920s from the Black Sea
region. His last name was “Değirmenci,” which translates as “Miller” in
Turkish; hence my name “Mylonas,” which means “Miller” in Greek.
Themistocles Mylonas was fluent in both Turkish and Pontic Greek. His
Orthodox Christian background made him a prime candidate for the obligatory
population exchange of 1923 between Greece and Turkey. His wife, also a
refugee, came from Novorossiysk in Russia and spoke only Russian when she
first arrived in the harbor of Thessaloniki (Salonica) following the Bolshevik
Revolution in 1917. She was confused on her arrival by the presence of black
soldiers along the shore. The Senegalese troops in the French Army of the Orient
did not conform to her expectations about Greece.
My maternal grandfather was from Crete. During World War II, he fought as
an officer of the Greek army against the Italians on the Albanian front. After the
armistice of April 1941, he had no money to travel back to Crete and decided
to stay in the north of the country. He settled in a rural area and married a
refugee from Pontos.
The Ottoman Empire targeted the Pontic Greek population with exclusionary
policies during World War I and the Turkish state continued these policies
during the Greek-Turkish war (1919–1922). These policies led to the ultimate
“repatriation” of my paternal grandfather and maternal grandmother to Greece.
While my grandparents were targeted by the Turkish state with exclusionary
policies, my parents were targeted by the Greek state with assimilationist poli-
cies. The two families settled in nearby villages in central Macedonia. In 1969,
having already served in the Greek Army as a reserve officer, my father moved
to my mother’s town and started an automotive dealership. Their respective
backgrounds did not prevent them from getting married three years later. Their
children – my sister and I – consider themselves Greek nationals; neither speaks
the languages that their parents or grandparents spoke; and neither identifies
strongly with any subnational ethnic identity. These policies facilitated my
parents’ marriage, which would have otherwise been controversial, and the
successful assimilation of my sister and myself into the Greek national identity.

xix
xx Preface

My family’s story is far from unique, but it gives rise to several questions of
broader interest about the making of co-nationals, refugees, and minorities.
How do states attempt to attain social order in multicultural environments? In
particular, under what conditions does a state target a non-core group1 with
assimilationist policies rather than granting it minority rights, or eliminating it
through deportation or mass killing? What is the underlying logic of political
elites in pursuing these different “nation-building” policies? These questions are
at the center of this book.
Many journalists, academics, and policy commentators have recently used
the term “nation-building” in place of what the U.S. Department of Defense calls
“stability operations.”2 In other words, by “nation-building” they mean “third-
party state-building.” They use the term to describe efforts to build roads and
railways, enforce the rule of law, and improve the infrastructure of a state.3 I part
ways with this recent usage and I use the term “nation-building” as it has been
used in the political science literature for the past five decades.4 Nation-building,
sometimes used interchangeably with national integration, is the process
through which governing elites make the boundaries of the state and the nation
coincide.5 In my framework, state elites employ three nation-building policies:
accommodation, assimilation, and exclusion.6
Accommodation refers to the ruling elites’ option to retain the non-core group
in the state, but grant the group special minority rights. Under accommodation,
the governing elites respect and even reproduce certain “differences” of the non-
core group through a legal structure and relevant institutions. Alternatively,
governing elites can pursue educational, cultural, occupational, matrimonial,
demographic, political, and other policies aimed at getting the non-core group to
adopt the core group’s culture and way of life. This is assimilation. Finally, the
ruling elites can physically remove the non-core group through population
exchange, deportation, or even mass killing. This is exclusion.7 These processes
have produced “minorities,” “co-nationals,” and “refugees.”

1
In this book, instead of “ethnic group” or “minority,” I will use the term “non-core group” to refer
to any aggregation of individuals that is perceived as an unassimilated ethnic group (on a linguistic,
religious, physical, or ideological basis) by the ruling political elite of a country. I reserve the term
“minority” only for groups that have been granted minority rights by their host state. For a more
elaborate justification of the use of this term over the alternatives, see the relevant section in
Chapter 2.
2
Dobbins et al. 2003, 2005, and 2007: v; Donohoe 2004; Fukuyama 2004 and 2006.
3
Darden and Mylonas 2012.
4
Bendix 1969; Connor 1972; Deutsch and Foltz 1963; Eisenstadt and Rokkan 1973. For a
discussion of the two definitions, see Hippler 2005; Stephenson 2005.
5
Gellner 1983.
6
Private efforts that contribute to the nation-building process are important but are outside the
scope of this book. For an important example of this kind, see Glazier 1998.
7
Listing both “mass killing” and “population exchange” under the term “exclusion” is controver-
sial; however, my definition wants to capture all policies aiming at the physical removal of a
population from a state’s territory. It is only in this sense that such different policies (practically and
ethically) are listed together.
Preface xxi

Exclusionary policies, such as ethnic deportations and mass killings,


remain a part of the repertoire of state elites around the world. Consider the
recent events in Sudan, Iraq, Somalia, Congo, Rwanda, and Bosnia. At the
same time, in western democratic states such as Canada and the United States,
policies accommodating difference are well established; such policies of
accommodation also exist in less stable states such as Lebanon. Today,
assimilationist policies are more controversial than policies of accommoda-
tion. Scholars and policy makers alike tend to discuss assimilationist policies
less openly since the end of the Cold War. They often resort to the term
“integration” instead of “assimilation.” Human rights activists tend to equate
assimilationist policies with “cultural genocide” and often ask governments to
apologize for past instances of assimilation. The most recent example is the
public apology by Canadian Prime Minister Stephen Harper “to tens of
thousands of indigenous people who as children were ripped from their
families and sent to boarding schools.”8 Still, the ranks of the assimilated
are many. All policy choices are with us today, although exclusion appears to
be improbable in the developed world.
Naturally, the social science literature has focused primarily on the decision
calculus behind the most violent state policies, such as genocide and ethnic
cleansing. As a result, scholars often end up overaggregating the different
“peaceful” outcomes under the residual category of “non-violent.” Yet the
conditions under which states pursue less violent policies such as assimilation
or accommodation remain undertheorized. This book develops a theory of
nation-building that focuses equally on violent and non-violent policies.
Moreover, while extensive work exists on the success or failure of the various
nation-building policies, there is relatively little analysis of how governments
decide to pursue such policies in the first place. Scholars focus on policy
outcomes not policy outputs. My theory makes predictions about policy out-
puts, the selection of policies, and specific plans for assimilation, accommo-
dation, or exclusion.
Modernization theories, constructivist arguments, and primordialist notions
are valuable but incomplete since they cannot account for important shifts in
nation-building policies across space and over time. In my framework, the
emergence of nationalism is the result of an interaction between strategic choices
made under the structural conditions of international competition within the
Westphalian system of states, technological innovations, and intellectual cur-
rents that emerged during the Enlightenment. This interaction produced what
Michael Hechter has called “state-building nationalism.” In my view, national-
ism is more a contingent outcome of a strategic response by statesmen to modern
conditions of geopolitical competition than the product of industrialization or
print capitalism per se.

8
Brown 2008. For a comparison of these policies in Australia, Canada, and New Zealand, see
Armitage 1995.
xxii Preface

The Politics of Nation-Building moves beyond explanations that emphasize


ethnic hatred between groups, the importance of different understandings of
nationhood, the focus on kin states, or various versions of the modernization
theories to identify the geostrategic conditions under which certain policies
become more likely with respect to different types of non-core groups. Ethnic
group relations vary widely over time, countries with the same understandings of
nationhood do treat similar groups differently, a homeland may or may not act
as a homeland toward its ethnic kin, and a great or regional power may decide to
act as an external backer for a group it shares no attributes with. In my account,
it is the politics of ethnicity in the international arena, rather than ethnic
attributes per se, that structures nation-building choices.
This book asks the reader to make a conceptual leap from the misused term
“minority” to that of “non-core group,” from focusing on “homelands” as the
only external actor to the more inclusive concept of “external power,” and
from the dichotomous – and narrow – conceptualizations of nation-building
policies such as “inclusion/exclusion” or “violent/non-violent” to that of
“assimilation, accommodation, and exclusion.” I focus on a novel dependent
variable – the selection of nation-building policies – and in my effort to explain
the observed variation I straddle the divide between not only history and
political science, but also between comparative politics and international
relations. The empirical sections of the book rely, as much as was feasible, on
archival material and sources that allow me to get as close as possible to elite
perceptions of and intentions toward non-core groups. This focus on elite
perceptions and intentions is a conscious attempt to incorporate constructivist
principles about ethnicity into my data collection process and to bring inten-
tions back to political science. To be sure, the realities on the ground are messy
and nonlinear; moreover, information on state policies toward non-core
groups is often twisted and ambiguous. But what is at stake is an important
choice: infer the intentions from the observation of behavior or attempt to get
as close as possible to an understanding of the intentions themselves. Whenever
I could I chose the latter path.
In writing this book I have three goals: first, to explore the effects of external
involvement on the politicization of cultural differences; second, to broaden
and deepen our understanding of the logic of state-planned nation-building
policies toward non-core groups and generate a conversation that spans dis-
ciplines and geography; and third, to develop a set of policy recommendations
to prevent the occurrence of ethnic cleansing while highlighting the trade-offs
between policies of accommodation and assimilation. A rethinking of the
process of nation-building is much needed today: continuous migration
flows, increasingly protectionist tendencies in global markets, and inefficient
international institutions can potentially undermine the accommodationist
consensus that exists – at least among academic circles – in the developed
world and unleash exclusionary policies in many developing countries. If
these sorts of possibilities are to be avoided, we need to rethink the incentive
structure of ruling political elites with homogenizing tendencies governing over
Preface xxiii

multiethnic states. The accommodation consensus may have blinded our eyes
to the unintended consequences and the hazards involved in uncritically pursu-
ing certain norms by supporting non-core groups against governments that do
not share the West’s understanding of human rights.

Harris Mylonas
Washington, D.C.
September 2012
1

Introduction

the puzzle
Why were the Armenians living in the Ottoman Empire accommodated until
1875, but targeted with exclusionary policies thereafter, including mass killings?
This empirical puzzle from the last decades of the Ottoman Empire remains
unresolved. For most of the nineteenth and early twentieth century, the
Ottomans still occupied significant parts of Southeastern Europe, North
Africa, and the Middle East. During the early nineteenth century, the
Tanzimat reform institutionalized the pre-existing accommodation of religious
difference within the context of the Empire through the millet (religious com-
munity) system. However, external involvement by the Great Powers and the
diffusion of nationalist ideas put pressure on the Ottoman way of managing
diversity, undermining its multiethnic character and pushing it toward
homogenization.
Armenians and Turks had lived in relative harmony in the Ottoman Empire
for centuries. The Ottoman administrators treated the Armenians as the “most
loyal millet” in the Empire. This was justified, since many different peoples in the
Empire had already rebelled during the nineteenth century (e.g., the Greeks,
Serbs, and Bulgarians), while the Armenians had not. By the 1890s, however, the
Ottoman ruling elite’s views had changed significantly, and systematic persecu-
tion of the Armenians began. Two decades later, during World War I, the Young
Turks1 – then ruling over the Ottoman Empire – perceived the Armenians as
being used as a fifth column2 and thus threatening their country’s security and

1
Hanioğlu 2001.
2
According to Encyclopædia Britannica, a fifth column is a “clandestine group or faction of
subversive agents who attempt to undermine a nation’s solidarity by any means at their dis-
posal.. . . A cardinal technique of the fifth column is the infiltration of sympathizers into the entire
fabric of the nation under attack and, particularly, into positions of policy decision and national
defense. From such key posts, fifth-column activists exploit the fears of a people by spreading
rumours and misinformation, as well as by employing the more standard techniques of espionage

1
2 The Politics of Nation-Building

targeted them with mass killings and deportations. The result was the Armenian
genocide.3
This puzzle gives rise to a broader question: What explains variation in state
policies to manage social diversity and attain order? Despite the voluminous
literature on more or less successful national integration histories,4 as well as
theories explaining a state’s choice to exclude or include non-core groups,5 there
is no theory that accounts for the conditions under which a state is likely to
assimilate, accommodate, or exclude a non-core group. Different paths to
national integration have been proposed,6 but no systematic theory that
accounts for variation in nation-building policies.
Since World War II, modernization theorists have discussed national integra-
tion as a by-product of industrialization, urbanization, and political develop-
ment.7 According to these scholars, national sentiments were the result of
people’s residence/location as well as increased social mobilization, which linked
peripheries to metropolitan centers.8 Over time, it is argued, the initial passive
identification turns into a more conscious and active one.9
Early modernization theorists have devoted little attention to direct state
involvement in the process of nation-building. For example, according to the
“melting pot” theory, members of the non-core group choose assimilation for
material reasons. Thus, assimilation is a byproduct of economic development
and does not require much state intervention.10
These theories do not specify who pursues nation-building policies and in what
fashion. As Smith puts it, in this set of theories “the role of the state is simply to act
as a handmaid of history, whose goal is a world of large-scale nation-states or
regions.”11 Another problem with this set of theories is that they cannot account for
the cases of non-core groups that are targeted with assimilation campaigns in
states that are not undergoing modernization, or for cases of non-core groups
that are kept segregated or are deported instead of assimilated in modernizing
states. Moreover, these theories – developed primarily with the U.S. context
in mind – were focused on the factors that may determine the success or failure of

and sabotage.” Accessed on 06 Apr. 2009: http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/


206477/fifth-column.
3
For more, see Akcam 2006; Dündar 2010; Hovannisian 1986; Melson 1986; Suny et al. 2011.
4
Deutsch and Foltz 1966; Eisenstadt and Rokkan 1973; Snyder 2003; Weber 1976.
5
Bulutgil 2009; Downes 2008; Mann 2005; Naimark 2001; Rae 2002; Snyder 2010, Straus 2006,
Valentino 2004, Wimmer 2002.
6
Greenfeld 1993.
7
Anderson 1983; Bendix 1969; Huntington 1968; Anderson et al. 1967.
8
Deutsch 1965.
9
The diffusionist theory of social integration makes similar predictions with the other moderniza-
tion theories with respect to state preferences toward non-core groups. This theory was proposed
by Parsons, Eisenstadt, and Smelser. According to them the culture of the core group trickles
down to the people at the periphery. Part of Deutsch’s argument captures this process with social
communication doing the work (1965).
10
Alba and Nee 2003; Glazer and Moynihan 1970; Gordon 1964.
11
1986: 232.
Introduction 3

state policies. My argument, presented below, focuses instead on explaining the


initial selection of policies, not their successes or failures.
Later generations of social scientists provided microfoundations for the var-
ious modernization theories.12 These studies also embraced the unplanned
character of national integration strategies posited by the modernization theo-
rists. Their work, inspired by methodological individualism, provided micro-
foundations focusing on the calculations individuals make with respect to
identity choices.13 But individual level decisions are always structured within
the context of state policies. Without a theory that accounts for variation in
state-planned policies toward non-core groups, we cannot have a complete
theory of nation-building; the “supply side” of the phenomenon is underthe-
orized. This book provides such a theory.
Most arguments by contemporary comparative politics scholars focus on domes-
tic dynamics to explain state policies toward non-core groups. Group size, territorial
concentration, and especially rootedness have been suggested as crucial character-
istics on which governments focus when they plan their nation-building policies.14
The logic is that large, territorially concentrated, and indigenous groups are more
likely to demand autonomy or even fight for self-determination than small, dis-
persed, and recently settled groups. Moreover, countries with more such groups are
less likely to accommodate them than countries with fewer such groups.15
Primordialist arguments hold that a state’s treatment of non-core groups is
based on cultural differences. The larger the perceived difference between the
culture or race of the non-core group and the core group, the more likely it is that
the non-core group will be excluded.16 Conversely, if the groups are similar, then
the non-core group will be targeted for assimilation. Scholars in this camp have
also emphasized the importance of past relations between the core and the
non-core group.17 I incorporate some of these findings in my theory but with a
twist, namely injecting external involvement by interested powers in the mix.
According to ethnic antipathy and status reversal theories, past relations
between the dominant group and the non-core group condition state policies.
Groups are constantly competing for status and self-esteem. A previously
disadvantaged group is likely to target the previously advantaged group with
exclusionary policies once the roles are reversed.18 However, such arguments

12
Gellner 1983; Hechter 1975; Laitin 1995 and 1998.
13
Laitin 1998. According to this account, populations adapt to the hegemonic constitutive story in
order to secure upward social mobility. Thus we should not observe any group-specific assim-
ilation policies since people will gradually integrate. The basic incentive structure should suffice.
Laitin’s theory largely neglects the supply side. But often individuals are not even given the option
to assimilate, while others are given incentives to do so. Laitin does address the supply side with
respect to Jews and Roma in his article “Marginality: A Microperspective” (1995).
14
Brubaker 1993; Toft 2003.
15
Van Evera 1994; Walter 2009.
16
Armstrong 1982; Isaacs 1975; Kaplan 1993.
17
Horowitz 1985; Kaufman 2001; Van Evera 1994: 23–25.
18
Horowitz 1985; Petersen 2001 and 2002.
4 The Politics of Nation-Building

cannot account for variation in the treatment of the same non-core group/state
dyad over time.
An equally prominent theory in sociology focuses on a state’s understandings
of nationhood, civic versus ethnocultural.19 According to this argument, elites in
states with a civic understanding of nationhood are more likely to target all non-
core groups with assimilationist policies. In contrast, elites in states with an
ethnic understanding of nationhood will exclude any group that does not fit the
ethnocultural criteria for nationhood.20 However, while this argument may
capture important country level differences, it cannot account for the important
subnational variation that exists in most states.
Scholars studying genocide and ethnic cleansing have also advanced explan-
ations underlining the importance of domestic political considerations, arguing
that insecure regimes are likely to target certain non-core groups with exclu-
sionary policies as a way to consolidate their power. In certain cases, this is an
argument that emphasizes security threats coming from the non-core groups.21
In other cases, the groups have not challenged their government but are just
scapegoats.22 Although such arguments illuminate certain cases they do not
make any predictions with respect to assimilation or accommodation.
International dynamics have also been considered in the literature by sociol-
ogists and political scientists alike. Michael Mann and Jack Snyder, among
others, have highlighted structural international factors such as the spread of
democracy to account for variation in nation-building policies.23 According to
this logic, structural transformations at the international level produce societal
frictions when they are introduced. Again, these country-level factors are impor-
tant to understand broader trends, but they are not calibrated enough to account
for subnational group-specific variation.
Finally, other scholars have drawn attention to the impact of the non-core
group having a national homeland on nation-building.24 They argue that elites
in a national homeland make credible commitments to their co-ethnics
abroad.25 This commitment in turn makes the non-core group assertive toward
the state they live in and can lead to a secessionist war.26 The implicit prediction
with respect to nation-building policies is that non-core groups with national
homelands are likely to escalate their demands and thus are more likely to be
targeted with exclusionary policies by the state whose sovereignty they chal-
lenge. The shortcomings of the various versions of the homeland argument have
to do with the emphasis on the ethnic affinity between the external power and the

19
Brubaker 1992.
20
Brubaker’s theory builds on the older distinction between ‘ethnic’ and ‘civic’ nationalism,
see Kohn 1945.
21
Gagnon 2004; Harff 1987; Straus 2006.
22
Brass 1997; Martin 2001; Snyder 2000.
23
Mann 2005; Snyder 2000.
24
Brubaker 1996; Weiner 1971.
25
Jenne 2007; Salehyan 2009; Van Houten 1998.
26
Thyne 2009.
Introduction 5

non-core group and the inability to account for the variation in the behavior of the
“homeland” over time. Many external powers supporting non-core groups have
no ethnic ties with the non-core group and, as King and Melvin have pointed out,
many homelands do not act as homelands today but may do so tomorrow.27

the argument
My argument builds on existing explanations but focuses on the importance of
international and geostrategic concerns for nation-building policies. It accounts
for the variation in nation-building policies as a result of the interaction between
host states and external powers rather than non-core groups and host states.28
In the stylized presentation of my argument there are three actors: a host state,
a non-core group, and an external power. The ruling political elites of a host
state want to reproduce their power and ensure the sovereignty of their national
state. Non-core groups want to maximize their well-being and avoid state
repression. Moreover, depending on how salient the non-core group’s identity
is the group members may also seek anything from recognition and basic
minority rights all the way to autonomy or even independence. External powers
often cultivate relations with non-core groups in other states to destablilize them,
to increase their bargaining power, or because of ethnic ties. External powers
usually – but not always – choose to support non-core groups that reside in
geopolitically important areas, are large, territorially concentrated, and close to
the borders.
I posit that this external involvement, whether clandestine, covert, or overt,
drives not only the mobilization and politicization of the non-core group’s
identity, but also the host state’s perception of the non-core group and the state’s
nation-building policies toward the group. Hence, the foreign policy goals of the
host state and its interstate relations with external powers drive a host state’s
choices of nation-building policies toward non-core groups.
The interstate relations between the host state and the external power sup-
porting the non-core group can take the form of rivalry or alliance.29 These

27
King and Melvin 1999/2000.
28
The term “host state” in my framework is shorthand for the political elites ruling in the name of
the core group. I use the term “host state” to distinguish it from the external power that supports
the group that is more often than not also a state. The term “host” is used to signify the state where
a non-core group resides and it does not imply anything about the legitimacy of the core group
rights over the land versus the rights of a non-core group. In fact, often non-core groups are
indigenous to the land they reside when core groups are not. For more on the definitions of the
actors in my argument, see the relevant section in Chapter 2.
29
I follow Walt’s (1997: 157) definition of alliance: “An alliance is a formal or informal commit-
ment for security cooperation between two or more states. Although the precise arrangements
embodied in different alliances vary enormously, the defining feature of any alliance is a commit-
ment for mutual military support against some external actor(s) in some specified set of
circumstances.”
6 The Politics of Nation-Building

relations in turn are influenced by – but are independent from – international


alliance blocs. The nature of these interstate relations ultimately structures the
relationship between the non-core group and the host state.
Domestic factors matter as well. The foreign policy goals of the host state are
of great importance. A host state may have revisionist or status quo foreign
policy goals.30 The elites of a state can come to adopt revisionist goals because
the military and economic power of their state is rapidly increasing relative to
their competitors, because of ideological convictions, or because they have lost
territories in a recent war and want to regain them. Regardless of the causes of a
state’s revisionism, the foreign policy goals of the ruling political elites are
focused on overturning the international status quo. Alternatively, state elites
may favor the international status quo. This, again, might be because their
power is declining relative to their competitors, because their ideological
convictions have changed because of a defeat or exhaustion, or because they
have recently expanded their territory and want to consolidate it.
There is a significant debate in the international relations literature over
whether all states,31 no states,32 or some states are revisionist.33 My argument
falls in the third camp, recently baptized “neoclassical realism,”34 but it comes
with a twist. In contrast to neoclassical realism, where domestic incentives affect a
state’s foreign policy behavior,35 I suggest a reversed-neoclassical realism, where
foreign policy goals interact with the nature of interstate relations with the
external patrons of non-core groups to condition nation-building policies.
Revisionism in my framework refers to a state’s ex ante stated foreign policy
goals, not necessarily its behavior.36
Four configurations that lead to different policy choices flow from a set of
assumptions I discuss in Chapter 2, and have so far been neglected in the
literature. First, a policy of assimilation toward that non-core group is likely if
a group has no external support. Second, a host state is likely to pursue assim-
ilation through internal colonization if the state favors the status quo and an
enemy is supporting the non-core group. Third, a host state is likely to accom-
modate a non-core group if an ally is supporting that group. Finally, a host state
is likely to exclude a non-core group when the state has revisionist aims and an
enemy is supporting that group.

30
Wolfers 1962: 90, 92.
31
Mearsheimer 2001.
32
Waltz 1979.
33
Schweller 2004 and 2006.
34
See Lobell et al. 2009; Rathbun 2008; Rose 1998.
35
Many studies of neoclassical realism focus on the importance of domestic variables in explaining
foreign policy outcomes. Jack Snyder shows the role of compact interest groups on expansionist
foreign policy (1991); Jason Davidson shows that fascist Italy’s revisionism in the interwar years
was driven by domestic political opportunities (in Davidson 2002). Taylor Fravel (2008) argues
that internal threats can account for China’s policy with respect to territorial disputes.
36
Davidson 2002.
Introduction 7

My argument is applicable to cases that satisfy the following conditions. First,


the ruling political elites represent a core group that is well defined and there is a
clear criterion of inclusion – a “national type” in the age of nationalism.37
Second, part of the population has not yet been successfully assimilated and
there is no “caste structure” in place.38 Third, the state has the capacity to
directly rule the population.39 In other words, my argument would require
modification to account for variation in states that do not have a well-defined
core group – maybe because they are ruled by a multiethnic coalition or their
organization is based on an organizing principle that defies such definition;
states where there are no non-core groups; states where there is a hierarchical
ethnic structure that is considered fixed or sacred; and/or states that do not have
the capacity to directly rule their population – that is, failed states.
These scope conditions render the Balkans states following World War I an
ideal set of cases to study. The area at the time was ethnically heterogeneous,
with many unassimilated ethnic groups; the ruling elites of these states had a
clear national type in their minds; and all of these states had the capacity to
pursue nation-building policies.40 Moreover, we can control for important
factors. All states were primarily agricultural societies with low urbanization
levels, they faced the same international system of minority rights protection,
they had experienced similar forms of past rule – as parts of the Ottoman
Empire – and they had a similar understanding of nationhood. Importantly,
there is significant variation in nation-building policies across and within these
states. Finally, studying cases from the interwar period is less difficult than
studying recent cases where the historiography has not matured and archival
materials have not been declassified.
One might argue that the interwar Balkans experience belongs to the distant
past, that the era of nation-building and assimilation has reached its limits, and that
the time when citizenship is no longer connected to ethnicity is – or ought to be –
near.41 Indeed, there might be a threshold of economic development beyond which
the citizens of a state become immune to nationalist ideology. And yet political
realities around the world challenge the euphoria of the early 1990s regarding the
prospects of multiculturalism and cosmopolitanism. Issues of ethnicity, nation-
hood, and citizenship remain complexly bound up with one another throughout

37
Within multiethnic empires, that by definition are not driven by a homogenizing imperative,
accommodation rather than assimilation is the default option. In such situations, external support
by an ally is definitely not required for a group to be accommodated. I borrow the expression “age
of nationalism” from Hobsbawm’s work (1990 and 1991).
38
In such cases assimilation is by definition impossible, see Weber 1978. These systems involve an
“ideology of inferiority for the subordinate groups” and thus an almost fixed ethnic structure that
is perceived as natural. For more on hierarchical systems, see Horowitz 1985: 21–32.
39
For the distinction between direct and indirect rule, see Hechter 2000.
40
To be sure, there was plenty of instability in Albania and Turkey during the first years after World
War I but calling them failed states would be wrong.
41
Benhabib 2004; Joppke 2005; Kymlicka 1995; Young 1993.
8 The Politics of Nation-Building

the globe – even in developed countries, as evidenced by the recent policy debates in
France, Germany, the United Kingdom, Belgium, Slovakia, and Switzerland.42
While it is true that exclusion seems inconceivable in contemporary
consolidated democracies, even liberal states are likely to deviate from their
multiculturalist arrangements under certain geopolitical and economic condi-
tions. I argue that consolidated democracies can afford to accommodate non-
core groups because of their participation in powerful alliances such as NATO
or the EU, which significantly reduce threat perceptions and provide security
protection. In other words, in the absence of these alliances or if faced with
imminent security threats even consolidated democracies will pursue exclusion-
ary policies when confronted with enemy-backed non-core groups, as the intern-
ment of Japanese-Americans during World War II illustrates.43
Moreover, the increased security measures that states pursued following the
terrorist attacks on 11 September 2001 and the intensifying efforts to control
illegal immigration have further strengthened border controls. Thus we are faced
with a paradox: “people are at the same time both more closely united [because
of globalization] and more carefully divided through increased physical and
legal barriers.”44 All in all, the forces of globalization far from supersede the
role of the nation-state both within and beyond its territorial limits.
In a world where territory is important and border changes are possible, we
must consider external support for non-core groups. Despite the well-known
arguments that territory is becoming increasingly less important in our global-
ized world, that border changes are – or will be – rare events in our international
system, and that borders are increasingly obsolete,45 territorial disputes, border
changes, and strict border controls are with us and will be with us in the future.46
For territorial disputes, one just needs to ask people in Cyprus, Mali, India,
Israel, China, Armenia, and Azerbaijan, to name just a few countries with
ongoing disputes. For border changes one needs to look in the former USSR,
former Yugoslavia, Eritrea, East Timor, South Ossetia, Georgia, and Sudan, to
name just a few recent cases. When we add to the list above the scores of “nations
without a state”47 or “stateless nations”48 then we get a sense of the potential for
territorial conflicts in the near future.
Returning to the initial puzzle, my theory suggests that in order to understand
the shift of Ottoman policies toward Armenians from accommodation to exclu-
sion, we need to pay attention to the patterns of external involvement and

42
Akturk 2011; Caldwell 2009; Howard 2009.
43
Harth 2001; Robinson 2009.
44
Ganster and Lorey 2005: xi.
45
Camilleri 1990; Friedman 2000 and 2007; Sassen 1996, 1998, and 2002; Schaeffer 2003; Strange
2000.
46
Buchanan and Moore 2003; Doremus et al. 1998; Fearon and Laitin 2011; Vasquez and Henehan
2001; Wilson and Donnan 1998.
47
Guibernau 1999.
48
For example, Minahan (2002) documents 300 developed or emerging national groups without
their own state worldwide. For Europe alone, see Bodlore-Penlaez 2010.
Introduction 9

interstate relations. The Armenian genocide was neither destined to happen due
to a long-standing ideological conviction by the Young Turks to eliminate the
Armenians nor strategically provoked by Armenian armed groups in order to
force the Great Powers of the time to intervene on their behalf.49 It was the
increasing Russian, and later French, military and diplomatic support of the
Armenians – rather than merely the cultural or religious difference between
Armenians and Turks per se – that transformed the perception of this group in
the eyes of the Ottoman ruling elites and set the stage for the persecution of the
Armenians. And this transformation was happening in parallel with the trans-
formation of the Ottoman Empire itself from a multiethnic to a homogenizing
empire.50 Once the international conditions for exclusionary policies were there,
and the Ottoman Empire under the Young Turks was no longer driven by the
multiethnic precepts of the past, then ethnic differences and local conditions
became operative. Variables such as cultural or religious differences take a long
time to change, but nation-building policies can – and often do – shift at a faster
pace. In order to account for the variation in nation-building policies across
space and over time, we need a theory that incorporates variables that change at
a pace similar to these policies. In this book I present such a theory.

why study nation-building policies?


The primary reason to study and understand the logic of nation-building policies
toward non-core groups is that inter- and intra-state wars often result from conflict
over such policies.51 For example, Imperial Russia used the pretense of protecting
therights oftheOrthodoxChristianmillettointerveneinthe affairsoftheOttoman
Empire. The politics between the Kingdom of Serbia and Austria-Hungary sur-
rounding the Serb minority in Bosnia and Herzegovina spurred World War I.52
Similarly, Hitler referred to the political unification of the German Volk residing
outside Germany’s borders as the driving principle behind his military moves that
led to World War II.53 The Turkish government justified its 1974 military inter-
vention in Cyprus based on the principle of the protection of its co-ethnics.54 More

49
Suny et al. 2011.
50
Findley 2010; Reynolds 2011; Üngör 2011.
51
There is an extensive empirical and theoretical literature establishing this connection. For more on
this, see Ambrosio 2001; Brown 1996; Byman and Van Evera 1998; Carment et al. 2006; Connor
1972; Davis and Moore 1997; Goertz and Diehl 1997; Heraclides 1990 and 1991; Horowitz
1985; Lake and Rothchild 1998; Saideman 1997 and 2002; Saideman and Ayres 2000; Sambanis
2001; Snyder and Walter 1999; Taras and Ganguly 2002; Woodwell 2004.
52
Another theory is that Franz Ferdinand’s assassins wanted to prevent the reorganization of the
Habsburg Empire on a trialist basis (a plan to include the Slavs in the Dual Monarchy in order to
check the Hungarians), which would have severely undermined Serbian aspirations in Bosnia and
Croatia (Sowards 1996).
53
Weinberg 1995: 95–146.
54
Stern 1975: 38, 78; Coufoudakis 1976: 469–471.
10 The Politics of Nation-Building

recently, Russia used similar justifications in its military intervention in Georgia in


support of South Ossetia and Abkhazia.55
This trend is not unique to the Balkans or post-communist Europe. In the
Middle East a potential Kurdistan threatens four sovereign states: Iraq, Turkey,
Syria, and Iran. In Kashmir, a nuclear confrontation between India and Pakistan
is a real possibility. In Asia, Tibetans and Uyghurs are becoming more assertive
toward the Chinese government. In Africa, hundreds of ethnic groups straddle
existing state borders. The fates of these peoples and many others with similar
statuses depend very much on the international politics of nation-building.
Ironically, so do the fates of their host states.
Beyond anecdotal evidence, scholars studying the onset of civil wars statisti-
cally have found that political competition among ethnic groups is central to our
understanding of armed conflict. Cederman, Min, and Wimmer show that specific
ethnic power configurations at the state’s center are more likely to lead to conflict
than others. In particular ethnic groups that are excluded from state power, have a
mobilizational capacity and have experienced conflict in the past are much more
likely to rebel.56 Studying how the abovementioned configurations emerge in the
first place is thus crucial.
Understanding the logic of state-planned nation-building policies can help deci-
sionmakers at the United Nations (UN) or in regional organizations such as the
European Union (EU), the African Union (AU), or the Association of Southeast
Asian Nations (ASEAN) anticipate political developments and devise incentives to
prevent ethnic cleansing, encourage accommodation, or foster national integration.
Granted, this understanding is not enough on its own; it has to be coupled with
effective monitoring and enforcement mechanisms by international organizations.
But the latter can be better calibrated if based on a deeper understanding of the logic
of nation-building policies.
At least three policy implications flow from my argument. First, one way to
prevent exclusionary policies is by upholding the principle of state sovereignty.
Second, ethnic cleansing and exclusionary policies may be prevented – along with a
whole host of unintended consequences such as spill over of conflict, refugee flows,
and humanitarian crises –57 if governments are particularly judicious when they
venture to assist non-core groups in enemy host states. In such cases they either need
to commit as many resources as needed to help the non-core group or not interfere
at all. Finally, for the probability of accommodation to increase, we need to increase
interstate alliances through regional integration initiatives and international and
regional institutions such as the EU and ASEAN.

book plan
The book comprises eight chapters and a methodological appendix. In Chapter 2,
I present the building block concepts and the basic logic of my theory. I also situate

55
King 2008.
56
Cederman et al. 2010.
57
Kuperman 2008; Salehyan and Gleditsch 2006; Weiner 1996.
Introduction 11

my argument in the existing literature. The first empirical chapter, Chapter 3,


introduces the Balkan region and the six states under study to the reader. Besides
the methodological justifications for studying the Balkans after World War I, which
I briefly discussed above, and the parallels one can draw with the wars and extreme
nation-building policies pursued in the same region during the 1990s, I hold that
many of today’s developing countries are experiencing challenges analogous to
those faced by the Balkan states in the interwar years, including incomplete nation-
and state-building; weak political institutions unable to accommodate increasing
political participation; unconsolidated democracy; religiously, linguistically, and
culturally heterogeneous populations; people accustomed to a world of corporate
privileges; external involvement; and economic “backwardness.”
Chapter 4 tests the theory using a cross-national dataset I compiled on all
non-core groups residing within the recognized boundaries of Balkan states
immediately after World War I. Results from the statistical analysis corroborate
the success of my argument in predicting nation-building policies in the Balkan
region. Overall, my argument correctly predicts 81 percent of the cases. Holding
alternative explanations to their mean value and varying my main variables of
interest produces thought-provoking results.
Consistent with my theory, assimilation is most likely for non-core groups
supported by enemy powers and residing in status quo host states.
Accommodation has the highest mean probability for non-core groups that are
supported by allied powers – or do not have any external support – and reside in
states that favor the international status quo. In contrast, non-core groups that are
supported by an enemy power and live in revisionist host states face a zero mean
probability of being accommodated. Finally, exclusion is most likely for enemy-
supported non-core groups in host states dominated by revisionist politics. Again, a
non-core group that is not supported by an enemy power has a practically zero mean
probability of being targeted with exclusionary policies. These findings confirm my
intuitions and nicely illustrate the substantive effects of the variables of interest while
controlling – both by design and statistically – for a multitude of variables.
Beyond the support for my argument, significant patterns emerged from the
statistical analysis. In the special case when a host state and an enemy external
power are contiguous and both have each other’s co-ethnics with whom they
cultivate links, exclusionary policies become more likely than assimilationist
policies toward these non-core groups. However, this variable is not as helpful
when we are looking at the choice between accommodation and assimilation.
Whether a non-core group had an external homeland or previously dominated
the current core group does not appear to have an impact in deciding between
policies – at least not in the post–World War I period. Turning to demographic
characteristics we observe that group size does not help us distinguish amongst
nation-building policies either. Cultural characteristics do matter but in ways
that undermine the ethnic antipathy arguments. A difference in religion and
language between the core and the non-core group makes accommodation more
likely than assimilation. This statistically significant finding goes against the
prediction of exclusion that cultural distance arguments would make.
12 The Politics of Nation-Building

In Chapter 5, I take a close look at cases from post-World War I Balkans that do
not conform to the predictions of my theory and identify some interesting dynamics
that illuminate counterintuitive aspects of nation-building and set up a new
research agenda. Looking at the outliers of my statistical analysis, four methodo-
logical issues emerge: (a) determining the appropriate time horizon for analysis,
(b) dealing with mixed policies followed by governments, (c) distinguishing termi-
nal from transitional policies, and (d) considering the role of external powers’
foreign policy priorities and the degree of symmetry in alliances in the decision
making process of host states. Finally, I identify a “divide and rule” strategy that
Balkan governments pursued both to fragment large non-core groups and to
prevent the subnational assimilation of smaller non-core groups to larger ones.
The findings from the cross-national study support my argument. However,
to get a better picture of the mechanisms at work and test the microfoundations
of my argument I rely on case studies using archival evidence and extensive
secondary sources. In Chapter 6, I conduct a subnational study of Western
Greek Macedonia using archival material I collected on nation-building policies
pursued toward eight non-core groups for a four-year period (1916–1920). This
chapter is based on archival research conducted in Greece in 2005 and 2006 at
the Museum of the Macedonian Struggle, the Gennadius Library, the General
State Archives of Macedonia, ELIA (The Hellenic Literary and Historical
Archive), and the Diplomatic and Historical Archives of the Hellenic Ministry
of Foreign Affairs.
To reconstruct the nation-building policies followed by the Greek adminis-
tration at the time, I rely mostly on confidential reports written by the General
Governor of Western Macedonia, Ioannis Eliakis. To be sure, this individual had
his own agenda in mind when writing these reports. Nevertheless, the confiden-
tial nature of these reports and the richness of the material, coupled with the
historical context within which I place it, add texture to our understanding of the
phenomenon. Eliakis’s reports provide us with a unique opportunity to access
the reasoning behind the planning of nation-building policies.
More importantly, this region is particularly fruitful for study because of the
extremely heterogeneous population that was incorporated into a state with a
clear national character, in the midst of many competing national programs
from neighboring countries. In this small region we observe all types of nation-
building policies (including mixed ones), as well as significant variation in my
main variables of interest – interstate relations between external powers and the
host state, foreign policy goals, homeland politics, cultural distance, and status
reversal. Crucially, my access to various types of archival material as well as
local newspapers allowed me to trace elite decision-making in this region.
In Chapter 7, I move north and test the argument in Serbia and later on the
Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes (KSCS) over several decades. I use
newspapers, memoirs, and archival material, as well as an extensive secondary
literature, to trace the logic underlying the policies followed by the Serbian ruling
political elites toward Albanians from 1878 to 1941. Studying nation-building
policies over time allows me to keep important regional, state- and group-level
Introduction 13

factors constant and isolate the effect of my main variables of interest, external
power involvement and host state foreign policy goals.
The findings from the subnational studies in Greek Macedonia and in Kosovo
support my theory. In both chapters, variation in external support for non-core
groups and foreign policy goals of the host state help us explain nation-building
policy shifts. Existing arguments alone cannot account for the variation, with
most of their predictions remaining constant over time.
In Chapter 8, I conduct an out-of-sample test relaxing some of the assump-
tions described in Chapter 2. The cases I discuss in this section, ranging from
China to Estonia, explore whether the argument still applies – or how it needs to
be modified in order to apply – in situations where the states involved are Great
Powers, Communist regimes, or consolidated democracies, as well as in different
international systems and norm standards.
I conclude, in Chapter 9, with a discussion of main findings and methodo-
logical lessons. I lay out a research agenda on nation-building and recapitulate
the caveats I experienced including: (a) the politics of “counting people”; (b) the
conflation of intentions, policy choices, policy implementation, and policy out-
comes; and (c) the principal-agent problems involved in the implementation of
nation-building policies. Finally, I discuss the policy implications that flow from
my argument and conclude with some thoughts on the impact of the interna-
tional system structure on the future of nation-building policies.
part i

THEORY
2

The International Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation,


and Exclusion

Three hundred years ago, the existence of a state did not necessarily presuppose
any national sentiments among the population.1 Other forms for legitimizing
authority – cultivating the belief that the governing institutions have the right
to rule2 – were prevalent around the world. States existed long before the age
of nationalism, but only during the past two hundred years has the cultivation of
nationalistic sentiments become an important part of an increasing number of
political leaders’ repertoire for establishing order and securing sovereignty
within their borders.3 Since the rise of nationalism as an organizing principle
of political communities,4 national sentiments have countered dissent (including
the evasion of conscription), enhanced the taxing abilities of states, fostered
compliance with the laws, and prevented separatist movements. However, these
same nationalist sentiments have also led to inter- and intrastate conflict, the
deaths of many civilians, population displacements, and even genocide.5
Legitimate authority in modern national states is connected to popular rule,
to majorities. Nation-building is the process through which these majorities are
constructed. In this context, foreign powers that want to destabilize a state
attempt to undermine its legitimacy by encouraging and nurturing linguistic,
ethnic, or religious differences and regional identities within its borders. Thus,
governing elites see benefit in harmonizing the political and the national units
through the construction and propagation of a common national identity among

1
Following Weber, I define a state as a political organization whose “administrative staff success-
fully upholds the claim to the monopoly of the legitimate use of physical force in the enforcement of
its order” (1978: 54).
2
Weber 1978.
3
Spruyt 1994; Tilly 1975, 1992, 1994.
4
For more on this transformation, see Anderson 1983; Deutsch 1965; Emerson 1960; Gellner 1983;
Hroch 2000; Kohn 1945; Snyder 2003 and 2008; and Wimmer 2012.
5
According to Wimmer (2012, chapter 1) “over three quarters of all full-scale wars – those conflicts
costing more than 1,000 battle deaths – were fought, at the end of the twentieth century, either by
nationalists who seek to establish a separate nation-state or over the ethnic balance of power within
an existing state.”

17
18 Theory

Explanations Predictions

Populations that do not share the same pre-modern


H1. Primordialism/ ethnic community with the core-group are more likely to be
Cultural Distance excluded or accommodated than targeted with assimilationist
policies.
Domestic

Once a previously disadvantaged group takes control of the


H2. Status Reversal/
state its ruling political elites are likely to target the previously
Ethnic Antipathy
advantaged group(s) with exclusionary policies.
Governments faced with few secessionist non-core groups are
more likely to pursue exclusionary (or assimilationist) policies
H3. Reputation
than governments with fewer non-core groups in order to signal
resolve and discourage future challengers.
The international diffusion of the ideal of popular rule during
democratization puts pressure to convert demos into ethnos, this
H4. “The Dark side of
in turn generates organic nationalism, and it ultimately
International

Democracy”
encourages ethnic cleansing of those that do not fit the
definition of the ethnos.

Non-core groups with an external homeland are more likely to


H5. National
be targeted for exclusion than assimilation because of the
Homeland
security threat they pose and the high cost of assimilation.

figure 2.1. Predictions of existing explanations.

the population of their state.6 Now, how do ruling political elites decide who to
assimilate, who to accommodate, and who does not belong in their state?
There are two broad categories of arguments in the social science literature
that speak to this question: theories that account for nation-building policies
based on national-level characteristics of the host state or the attributes of the
non-core groups (domestic); and theories that account for nation-building
policies based on international structural conditions (international). Figure 2.1
summarizes the existing explanations.
According to advocates of primordialism, people’s identities do not change;
ethnicity is fixed, predetermined.7 Nation-state formation would not be possible
without some ethnic origins, or what Geertz calls “primordial sentiments,” that
are transformed into national ones.8 This intellectual group includes “the new
ethnicists” such as Daniel Moynihan, Nathan Glazer, Walker Connor, and
Wendell Bell. The pith of their argument is that people who do not want to
lose their ethnic identities and core communities do not want to contaminate the
purity of their groups.9 Thus, according to this group of scholars, core groups

6
Gellner 1983.
7
Van de Berghe 1981. With respect to primordialist theory I am in agreement with Darden’s work,
which argues that identities are malleable but under certain conditions operate as if they are fixed;
see Darden forthcoming.
8
Geertz 1963.
9
Birch 1978.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 19

are more likely to exclude or accommodate populations that do not share the
same pre-modern ethnic identity with the core group than target them with
assimilationist policies.
Many accounts in the literature focus on the ethnic character of politics.
They posit a direct link between ascriptive characteristics and ethnic identities.
The latter produce ethnic politics and ultimately lead to ethnic conflict.10 In
this context, an ongoing “struggle for relative group worth” is the driving
mechanism that leads to conflict.11 Backward groups are likely to be hostile
toward advantaged groups in an effort to restore their self-esteem and reduce
their own anxiety. Horowitz argues that the backward population also has the
impression that the advantaged group thinks of it as inferior. The masses
follow their leaders against the advantaged group, in order to “retrieve their
self-esteem.”12 Research in social psychology provides a mechanism support-
ing this hypothesis – namely, that individuals seek to maximize their self-
esteem, and that creating a positive social identity (usually at the expense of
some “other”) is one way of reaching the desired goal.13 In sum, according to
this type of explanation, in cases where the dominant group was previously
dominated by the non-core group, the relations will be conflict-ridden and we
should observe no assimilation or accommodation attempts; on the contrary,
exclusion is more likely.14
The third important line of argument in the “domestic” camp highlights the
importance of opportunities for the non-core group. Prominent political scien-
tists and sociologists have argued that ethnic group size, territorial concentra-
tion, grievances, rootedness, and past experiences of accommodation are all
crucial characteristics that determine the propensity of a group to challenge the
host state.15 This argument of course presupposes the political salience of
cultural differences between core and non-core groups. The logic is that large,
territorially concentrated, indigenous groups are more likely to demand
autonomy or even fight for self-determination than small, dispersed, and/or
recently settled groups. In sum, groups with such characteristics are more threat-
ening and thus more likely to be repressed.16 Governments focus on such
characteristics when they plan their nation-building policies.

10
Gurr 1993; Horowitz 1985: 17–18, 53; Kaufman 2001.
11
Horowitz’s work is the most cited in support of the ethnic antipathy theory (1985: 143). David
Laitin (2001) tests Horowitz’s theory and demonstrates that explanations based on “cultural
antipathies” in several post-Soviet territories did not allow us to make correct predictions about
which republics would experience rebellion, and also failed to predict the timing of those
rebellions which did occur.
12
1985: 181. Horowitz acknowledges that the leaders of these backward groups are thinking of the
resources that they will obtain if they are successful.
13
Hechter 2000: 99.
14
Petersen 2001 and 2002.
15
Brubaker 1993; Fearon and Laitin 2003; Toft 2003; Treisman 1997.
16
Fein 1993; Harff 1987 and 2003.
20 Theory

Walter builds on this line of research and argues that governments facing
many large and territorially concentrated groups are more likely to be bellicose
than governments that face fewer such groups. The logic is that they have to
crack down heavily in order to build reputation, discourage, and signal resolve
to other potential challengers.17 Treisman’s findings from his study of post-
Soviet Russia are in line with Walter’s logic; indeed Treisman suggests that
when non-core group elites observe benefits from separatist activities of other
groups, they are likely to follow their example.18 Thus, states with few large,
mobilized, and territorially concentrated and potentially secessionist groups are
more likely to pursue exclusionary or assimilationist policies than states with
one or none such groups.
I now turn to theories that account for nation-building policies based on
international factors. According to several scholars, systemic transformations
such as the emergence of the modern state, industrialization, modernization, and
democratization have provided motives and rationalizations for the pursuit of
violent policies toward specific ethnic groups.19 Mann in particular argues that
exclusionary policies are the product of the spread of democratic norms, which
equate demos with ethnos. Similarly, Straus argues that the Rwanda genocide
was the result of the Hutu leadership’s strategy to remain in power in a post-
Cold War environment of liberalization and democratization.20 Thus, the inter-
national diffusion of the ideal of popular rule during a period of democratization
puts pressure to convert demos into ethnos, generates organic nationalism, and
ultimately encourages ethnic cleansing of those who do not fit the definition of
the ethnos.
Weiner has underlined the importance of the triangular relationship among a
nationalizing state, a national minority, and the national homeland (i.e., a state
whose core group is considered to be of the same ethnic background as the ethnic
group abroad).21 Building on Weiner, Brubaker has argued that if a national
minority does not have a national homeland it is more likely to be targeted for
assimilation.22 To be sure, Brubaker suggests that he is not interested in pre-
diction but from his work we can deduce that a nationalizing state is not likely to
target for assimilation a national minority with a homeland, because the costs
are high and the likelihood of success low. Deportation, population exchange, or
mass killings are more likely in such cases.
Pieter van Houten, inspired by this line of research and Fearon’s work,23 has
proposed a different version of the homeland argument.24 Elites in a national
homeland make credible commitments to co-ethnics abroad, and these

17
Walter 2009; Van Evera 1994.
18
Treisman 1997: 246.
19
Bartov 1996; Mann 2005; Snyder 2000.
20
2006.
21
1971.
22
Brubaker 1996: 66–67.
23
Fearon 1998.
24
1998.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 21

commitments in turn make the ethnic group assertive. At the same time, the core
group does not offer a credible commitment to accommodating the non-core
group’s demands. This situation can lead to a secessionist war.25 The implicit
prediction with respect to nation-building policies is that ethnic groups with
national homelands are likely to be mobilized along ethnic lines against the host
state, and thus will be targeted with exclusionary policies. Thus, non-core
groups with an external homeland are more likely to be targeted for exclusion
than assimilation.
The above arguments capture important elements of the process but make
inconclusive predictions with respect to the full range of nation-building policies.
This is not surprising given the fact that none of them directly addresses the
variation I have set out to explain. Overall both theories that emphasize domes-
tic factors and theories that emphasize international factors conceptualize policy
variation narrowly (e.g., exclusion versus inclusion), while in some cases are
only interested in explaining the occurrence of just one policy (e.g., assimilation
or not, violence or not). Thus, they do not provide a comprehensive account of
nation-building policies. I attempt to complement these accounts and explain
dynamics they have neglected.
In what follows, I describe my dependent variable and the relevant actors.
Next, I discuss the motivations and consequences of different types of external
involvement (clandestine, covert, and overt). In the third section, I present my
theory of nation-building. Finally, I conclude with a discussion of various causal
paths that can lead to observationally equivalent nation-building policy choices;
some paths that are compatible with my argument and some that are not.

nation-building policies: assimilation,


accommodation, and exclusion
There are multiple ways that one can conceptualize nation-building policies. The
dichotomy of inclusion versus exclusion is a common way of categorizing
policies. I hold that this categorization does not capture the full range of the
observed variation. On the other hand, McGarry and O’Leary’s important
contribution26 goes too far disaggregating policies. In order to better capture
the options available to nation-builders, I conceptualize nation-building policies
by constructing a categorical variable that can take the following possible values:
assimilation, accommodation, and exclusion.
“Assimilationist policies” refer to educational, cultural, occupational, matri-
monial, demographic, political, and other state policies aimed at the adoption of
the core group culture and way of life by the targeted non-core group. These
policies usually directly target a specific group (or part of a specific group), but

25
For more on this, see Grigoryan 2010; Jenne 2004; Thyne 2009.
26
For a useful taxonomy of eight macro-methods of conflict regulation, see McGarry and O’Leary
1994; for other conceptualizations, see also Heraclides 1991; Koppa 1997; Mavrogordatos 1983
and 2003.
22 Theory

might be presented under the guise of an impartial law. I also include under this
category “nation-wide assimilation” policies that aim at the acquisition of
certain traits such as language, dress, or behavioral patterns by the whole
population; the ultimate goal of such policies is national integration. “Nation-
wide” policies differ from group-specific ones because they do not target any
group in particular, though in reality they often end up disproportionately
affecting a specific group (or part of a specific group).
Assimilation can also take more violent forms. I identify two such types:
Colonization of the territories inhabited by a non-core group – often coupled
with internal displacement of its members; and/or exclusion of the elites of a
non-core group and assimilation of the rest of the members.27
All in all, the goal of assimilationist policies is to secure the loyalty of an
individual or a community by “conquering” their belief system and ensuring
their obedience to the national state. An implicit normative assumption of such
policies is that the core group’s culture is superior to the non-core group’s
culture. States use assimilationist policies to create co-nationals.
“Accommodation” refers to situations where the “differences” of a non-core
group are more or less respected and institutions that regulate and perpetuate
these differences are put in place. The host state grants the status of “minority”
to that non-core group. The latter is allowed to have certain separate institu-
tions such as schools, churches, cultural associations, and so forth. This
“minority” status does not mean that the host state is indifferent toward the
loyalty of the non-core group’s members. The state requires political loyalty to
central state institutions and obedience to general laws. Finally, the fact that
“difference” is accepted and perpetuated does not necessarily mean that the
non-core group does not still face discrimination both by state institutions and
by individual members of the core group. Accommodation produces national
minorities.
“Exclusionary policies” refer to policies that aim at the physical removal of a
non-core group from the host state (or specific areas of it). Policies under this
category include population exchange, deportation, internal displacement, pog-
roms, or even mass killing. Exclusion can also take the form of segregation,
which does not involve the physical removal of the non-core group as the
experiences of apartheid in South Africa and Jim Crow in the United States
indicate.28 Although such policies constitute instances of exclusion they do not
physically remove the population from the state’s territory but they might
involve internal displacement. Exclusionary policies produce refugees and vic-
tims of state violence.

27
One may wonder, where do affirmative action policies fit in my typology? We can only answer this
question empirically and on a case-by-case basis. If the ruling elites’ policies aim at preserving the
difference between the non-core and the core group then affirmative action policies fall under the
accommodation category. If the ruling elites’ policies aim at eroding that difference then they fall
under the assimilation category.
28
Marx 1999.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 23

There are many ways in which we can rank these three policy choices. An
important dimension is whether the state uses physical violence or not.
Exclusionary policies are the most violent. Assimilationist policies are usually
non-violent (based on a definition of violence that focuses on physical vio-
lence),29 but they often are coercive. Accommodation refers almost exclusively
to non-violent policies.30 In order to best understand and distinguish between
these policies, however, we must consider the different governmental goals that
lie behind each in specific instances, and not merely whether they involve the use
of violence or not.
Another dimension is the cost involved in implementing each policy. In
general, it is hard to produce an abstract ranking of the three policies, since the
strategic nature of these decisions often overrides the mere monetary cost of
implementing them. The ranking of policy choices in terms of monetary cost has
to be contextual. The cost of assimilation, for example, depends on the parti-
cular attributes of the non-core group that differentiate it from the core group.
The cost of accommodation depends on the type of institutions that will be used
by the state, and the cost of exclusion depends on the methods used.
The cost-benefit analysis of a nation-builder has to take into account the
strategic and security costs of failing to pursue the appropriate policy toward a
non-core group as well. For example, if the security threat posed by a certain
non-core group can put in jeopardy a host state’s survival in the future, then I
would expect the government to pursue assimilationist policies – assuming it is in
favor of the international status quo – despite the fact that the monetary cost of
such policies may be higher than accommodating the same non-core group.
Ruling political elites always consider the strategic trade-offs between the elim-
ination of a security threat posed by a non-core group, and the amount and
availability of resources needed for the host state to eliminate the threat.

actors: host state, non-core group, external power

Host State: The Core Group and Its Ruling Political Elites
Let’s now turn to the actor that pursues these nation-building policies, the “host
state.” When I refer to a host state, I mean the elites governing the national state
in the name of the “core group” – the members of the ruling political organ-
ization that has the military and administrative capacity to enforce its decisions
within the borders of a state. But what is the core group?
Naturally, in order to speak of non-core groups we first have to define the core
group.31 For example, in the case of Germany, the core group can be identified as

29
For different definitions of violence, see Žižek 2008.
30
To be sure, terrible instances of warfare, ethnic cleansing, and scapegoating were preceded by
accommodationist arrangements. In other words, the purpose of this discussion is not to suggest
that accommodation is morally superior to assimilation or vice versa.
31
Hollingshead 1952: 685.
24 Theory

white people of German ancestry whose native language is German. Similarly, in


Greece the core group can be identified as white Orthodox Christians of Greek
origin and/or national consciousness who speak Modern Greek. Thus, my argu-
ment applies in cases where the core group has a clear “national type” and the
latter is being actively propagated within the territorial borders of the state.32
Indicators of a well-defined national type include one or more of the following:
an official language, a national historiography that attains a high degree of
consensus among the core group members, an official (or state-favored) religion,
common cultural customs and practices or some form of phenotypic stereotype
(a combination of physical attributes). There is no restriction in terms of which
markers are the most important ones (e.g., race, religion, language, shared
culture).33
The term “core group” refers to all the inhabitants of a country who share a
common national type in one or more of the ways just outlined. Often the core
group forms a demographic majority. Whether the core group is a majority or
not, it is represented by the ruling political elites of the state.34
The ruling political elites of the host state do not necessarily coincide with the
economically dominant class or with the intellectuals of the state.35 The ruling
political elites aim at the survival of the state and the preservation of their own
position in it. They may be – and often are – supported or controlled by external
powers.36
Moreover, I use the term “ruling political elites” rather than “nationalizing
state”37 because the latter term suggests a specific set of policies – nationalizing –
and operates as a characterization of the state as a whole. The term “ruling
political elites,” on the other hand, does not imply a specific policy. The ruling
political elites can exclude, assimilate, or accommodate a non-core group and
can pursue different policies toward disparate non-core groups in the country.
As I mentioned in my introduction, to these elites nation-building is not consi-
dered complete until there are no threatening non-core groups within their state.
They are driven by a homogenizing imperative.
Finally, there may be – and often is – disagreement within the ruling political
elites of a host state with respect to the definition of the core group as well as the
nation-building policies pursued toward non-core groups.38 In such instances I
give primacy to the views and policies of the dominant section of the ruling elites.

32
Deutsch 1965. The national type may change over time. In fact it often does.
33
An interesting research question is if some kinds of markers are more powerful in achieving
national integration than others and why? In my cases there is no important variation along these
lines.
34
We can assume that the ruling political elites of the core group at any given point try to determine
the constitutive story of the “nation” in such a way that it ensures the legitimacy of their hegemony
over any competitors.
35
For a distinction between ruling and political classes, see Aron (1966: 204) and Weber (1978: I, 56).
36
This is especially true for small powers in a bipolar or unipolar international system.
37
Brubaker 1996: 63–66.
38
For an elaborate discussion on this, see Shevel 2011.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 25

State Capacity
One of the scope conditions of my argument in Chapter 1 referred to the
capacity of a state to directly rule the population. However, this is a require-
ment that deserves further discussion. There are at least two ways in which
state capacity (captured by measures of administrative, policing, and military
capabilities of a state) influences nation-building policies choices: relative and
absolute.39 The first one has to do with the power balance between the external
power(s) supporting the non-core group and the host state and its external
patrons.40 The second one has to do with state capacity in absolute terms, that
is, whether a government has the capacity to implement its ideal set of nation-
building policies or not.
Taking a closer look at state capacity in a relative sense, we find at the one
extreme a situation where the power balance is clearly in favor of the external
power(s) supporting the non-core group. In this case, a successful secessionist
movement or the capture of the host state is likely. My argument predicts that the
host state is likely to respond with exclusionary policies if the external power is
an enemy, but predictions are almost trivial in this situation since the host state is
likely to be defeated quickly. A relevant example is that of the Sudeten Germans
in Czechoslovakia during 1938. The Czechoslovak government did impose
martial law in the area and persecute the German nationalist elites but Hitler’s
Germany annexed the Sudetenland and five months later occupied the rest of
Czechoslovakia.
Turning now to the cases where the power balance is clearly in favor of the
host state, enemy external powers will hesitate to support non-core groups
within such a state for two reasons: the prospect of a destructive interstate
war will operate as a deterrent,41 and the likelihood of such mobilization
succeeding is extremely small. In the event that an external power attempts to
mobilize a non-core group within a powerful state, its effort is likely to fail, as
the non-core group members will probably choose to side with the powerful
host state. Non-core groups in hegemonic states such as the United States are
such examples.
Finally, state capacity in absolute terms is very important. A host state may
want to target a specific non-core group with assimilationist policies but because
of a weak state apparatus it might pursue accommodationist policies first and
wait until it can pursue more ambitious policies.42

39
For more on military power balance and nationalism, see Van Evera 1994.
40
For brevity, when I refer to the host state in the text I will not explicitly mention the possibility of
an external patron backing it. Such instances are very common. I consider this backing as part of
the host state’s capacity.
41
This consideration is only enhanced if the host state has powerful backers of its own.
42
A number of outliers from my statistical analysis in Chapter 4 are partially explained in this
manner in Chapter 5.
26 Theory

Non-Core Group
The mere existence of a culturally distinct group within a national state does not
necessarily entail a competing claim to the political allegiance of this population.
Cultural distinctiveness per se is politically irrelevant unless there is a group-
formation process, which would increase the salience of the difference with the
core group, cultivate group solidarity among the non-core group’s members,
and turn it into a social identity.43 As Hechter puts it, “one can only identify with
a given group when such a group actually exists.”44
This begs the question, when is a non-core group unlikely to have a politically
salient social identity? Nomadic groups, groups that are territorially dispersed,
or small isolated communities are not likely to have any political identity linked
to their cultural, linguistic, religious, or other type of distinctiveness. Moreover,
research findings in social psychology indicate that individuals from such non-
core groups are likely to quickly assimilate into a “higher status” group in order
to maximize their self-esteem.45 As a result, over time many of these groups have
been absorbed by neighboring larger groups; they have been “selected out” by
the structure of the system. In contrast, groups that are large, sedentary, and
territorially concentrated (e.g., the Kurds in Iraq) are more likely to build local
institutions and link their cultural, linguistic, religious or other distinctiveness to
a political identity. Non-core groups of the latter kind are also more likely to be
selected by external powers trying to destabilize or weaken the host state.

A Statist Perspective
I follow a statist perspective for the identification of non-core groups. By the
term “non-core group,” I mean any aggregation of individuals that is perceived
as an unassimilated ethnic group (the relevant marker can be linguistic, religious,
physical, or cultural) by the ruling political elites of a country at the beginning of
a period analyzed. The non-core group members may or may not be citizens of
the state, but are certainly not considered members of the nation before they are
targeted with assimilationist policies.
Importantly, prevailing perceptions with respect to the loyalties of a non-core
group do not always reflect the reality and are often formed by considerations
that are independent of the actual preferences/attitudes of non-core group
members. For example, a non-core group could be perceived as posing a security
threat because its homeland (or aspiring homeland) has engaged in an act of
aggression against the host state. The Serbs in Croatia in the early 1990s are such
a case. A great percentage of them did not share – then – Serbian President
Milošević’s views; however, they were equally likely to be targeted by Croatian
anti-Serbian policies.

43
For more on how ethnic markers do not always correlate with salient ethnic identities, see
Chandra 2001; Giuliano 2011; Posner 2003 and 2004. For more on the concept, see Barth 1998.
44
2000: 97.
45
Hechter 2000: 99.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 27

But why not use the term “minority”? Do we really need a new term? In the
literature the term minority is commonly used to refer to:
[A] group numerically inferior to the rest of the population of a state, in a non-dominant
position, whose members – being nationals of the State – possess ethnic, religious or
linguistic characteristics differing from the rest of the population and show, if only
implicitly, a sense of solidarity, directed toward preserving their culture, traditions,
religion or language.46

I refrain from using the term “minority” for a variety of reasons. First, the non-
core group category is broader than that of a minority, since it includes aggre-
gations of people who are conscious of their difference from the dominant
national type without necessarily being mobilized around this difference.
Second, the term “minority” usually refers to “numerically inferior” groups,
while the term non-core group does not imply anything about size. Third, the
term “non-core group” allows us to view even stereotypical members of the
demographic core group as targets of assimilationist policies by the ruling
political elites and not necessarily assume their national loyalty. In the initial
stages of nation-building even people who fit the criteria of inclusion in the core
group are often not conscious of their national identity and in that sense have
to be assimilated. Finally, and most importantly, terming a non-core group a
minority often implies either a legal status, recognition from the host state, or the
existence of a claim by the non-core group. Thus, referring to “non-core groups”
as “minorities” carries a wide range of assumptions that are often unwarranted.
In sum, a minority is a non-core group that has been targeted with accommo-
dationist policies or at the very least aspires to get minority status.

Organization
There is wide variation in the types of non-core groups across space and time.
This variation is a function of the content of the national constitutive myth47 of
each country and the relevant attributes of the groups that reside within it. A
non-core group could be an ethnic or tribal group, or a religious, linguistic,
racial, or even cultural group.
The organization of non-core groups can take various forms. They can have
formal institutions such as cultural associations and political parties, or simply
informal institutions such as family and/or clan networks. They can be more or
less hierarchical and more or less cohesive.48
In the period I am studying, the formality and complexity of the organiza-
tional structure of the various non-core groups can be approximated by consi-
dering whether a group was nomadic, rural, or urban. Nomadic groups were less
likely to have formal institutions than urban and rural groups.49 Moreover,

46
Capotorti’s definition of a minority quoted in Clogg 2002: xii.
47
For more on this, see Smith 2001 and 2003.
48
Hechter 1987.
49
For more on nomadic groups, see Khazanov and Wink 2001.
28 Theory

while churches, mosques, and synagogues existed in both urban and rural
settings, cultural associations and societies existed mostly in cities. Over time,
the organizational structure of non-core groups has become more formal: today,
the proliferation of nongovernmental organizations has led to the formal organi-
zation of many previously informal groups. Prominent examples are the abori-
ginals in Australia and New Zealand and the indigenous people in various Latin
American countries. In my framework, variation in non-core group organization
might account for the variation in the type of measures a host state pursues once
a policy choice has been made, but not for the choice of the policy per se.

Political Demands
The host state’s nation-building policy is directly linked to the non-core group’s
political demands. Non-core group demands can be either territorial or non-
territorial. Nonterritorial demands range from legal recognition of the non-core
group by the host state, to institutionalized political representation at the
national level. Territorial demands range from claims for local autonomy to
calls for independence.50
What is the origin of the non-core group’s political demands? Non-core group
demands are often theorized as endogenous to size and geographic distribution
of a group, to history of past autonomy, or to host state policies.51 In accordance
with my general thesis I proceed from the axiom that non-core group demands
are also influenced by the geopolitical situation and the preferences of external
powers. Non-core groups supported by allies of the host state or with no
external links may demand recognition and/or accommodation of their differ-
ences but not much more. Non-core groups supported by external enemies are
more likely to demand autonomy or self-determination than those without
external support.52
To be sure, as I have mentioned above, large populations that differ from the
core group and are concentrated close to border areas may be more likely to
make territorial claims and be supported by external enemies. By contrast, non-
core groups that are small and dispersed are less likely to be supported by
external powers and more likely to make nonterritorial demands, such as ask
for minority rights and equal treatment. Similarly, non-core group demands can
change based on the host state policies. For instance, violent state policies might
lead to an escalation of non-core group demands, unless the state manages to
completely suppress the group.
Whether the demand for self-determination or minority rights is the outcome
of external involvement or not is an empirical question. In my model, I endogen-
ize non-core group demands to the external power’s preferences in cases where a
non-core group wants to attract the interest of an external power. The external

50
See Kliot 1989; Mikesel and Murphy 1991.
51
Gurr 1993; Toft 2003.
52
It is understood that a non-core group that seeks self-determination is also demanding
recognition.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 29

power preferences are in turn endogenous to interstate relations with the host
state and the broader geopolitical situation. But what is of paramount impor-
tantance is the decision on behalf of the external power to get involved.53 We do
not know what percentage of external interference is a product of “dragging in”
effects. Moreover, there are many cases where the external power acts without
any prior agency from the non-core group. An interesting empirical question is
the extent to which non-core group variation in homegrown mobilization
impacts external powers’ decisions to get involved.54
Ideally, I would have data on the actual demands of the non-core groups. In
the absence of such data, tracing the origin of non-core group demands and
identifying whether they were genuinely developed by non-core group members,
or were superimposed by an external actor (or were the outcome of some
combination of the two) would greatly enhance our understanding of the process
of nation-building. Non-core group demands are not always reducible to the
machinations of external powers.

External Power
The third actor in my framework is the “external power” – a neighboring state, a
great power, a diaspora group, or a combination55 – that is involved with the
political fate of a non-core group in the host state. The external power does not
need to be territorially contiguous to the host state. Having said that, contiguous
countries are more likely to interfere in each other’s internal politics than
countries that are continents apart.56 Great Powers and increasingly non-state
actors are the main exception to this rule. The external power can provide
financial, military, political, or other support to the non-core group.57
Moreover, the support can be covert or overt and the intensity varies greatly
from case to case. What is important from the perspective of my argument is the
perception of external support by the ruling political elites of the host state. At
different points in time, the external power can be an enemy or an ally of the host

53
For more on the “marketing of rebellion,” see Bob 2005.
54
For a more elaborate discussion, see the sections on motivations and effects of external involve-
ment below.
55
Today, non-state actors are becoming increasingly important in this process. Diasporas, large
refugee groups, terrorist organizations, nongovernmental organizations, religious networks, and
even powerful corporations can substitute for the role of states in this configuration. In the rest of
the book I discuss states as the main actor that provides external support; however, my argument
still applies in cases of non-state actors. The main difficulty lies in discerning whether the external
non-state actor is actually an “ally” or an “enemy” of the host state. For more on transnational
dynamics, see Salehyan 2009.
56
Miller 2007: 9.
57
As I mentioned above, host states can also be – and often are – supported by external powers that
are usually allies of the country. This was especially the case during the Cold War, where there
would be a government supported by one side and a non-core group supported by the other side. I
discuss such examples in Chapter 5.
30 Theory

state, depending on changing international alliance blocs and shifts in foreign


policy choices between successive governments.58
Support by an enemy power is different from support by an ally although
both involve maintaining ties with the non-core group that sustain and/or
nurture the difference between the core and the non-core group. Support by an
ally, however, by definition is not aiming at provoking secessionist goals or
providing an alternative to the host state. Some – but definitely not all – instances
of enemy support definitely have the latter goal in mind. I assume that the host
state elites are going to err on the safe side and prepare for the worst. Thus, in this
book I do not attempt to quantify the type or the actual level of support but just
identify whether the ruling elites of the host state perceive a non-core group as
externally supported or not and the status of the interstate relations between the
external power and the host state.
How should my theory be modified when there are competing external
powers? For example, during the Cold War the United States and the USSR –
as well as regional allies of the two – each backed several movements and non-
core groups in their efforts to enlarge their respective blocs by establishing
friendly regimes around the world.59 There are cases where there are multiple
external supporters. The Tibetan case mentioned above is such an example,
where the United States, United Kingdom, India, and Nepal all acted as external
supporters for the Tibetans.
Things get complicated if a non-core group is backed both by an ally and an
enemy. In such situations my theory would have to be modified in a different
manner depending on the empirics of the case. If the ally external power supports
a different faction than the one that the external enemy is supporting then I treat
these subgroups as “separate” non-core groups. In the rare event of the ally and
the enemy external powers both supporting the same non-core group, my argu-
ment is inconclusive; however, the host state’s response will most likely depend
on which relationship is most valuable and the relative state capacity of these
external powers. The host state is likely to accommodate the non-core group if
the ally is strong and the alliance is asymmetrical or exclude and/or assimilate the
non-core group if the ally is weaker and the alliance is symmetrical.
But what accounts for the variation in external support across non-core
groups? Do external powers choose to support specific non-core groups based
on the geopolitical importance of the territory they reside in; their ethnic identity;
their size; their location?

Motivations for External Involvement


External support and sponsorship of movements in foreign states is a very old
practice in the international system. In the modern era, the Napoleonic Wars
stand out as the first concerted effort to use non-core groups in enemy states

58
Alliances can take many forms ranging from informal alliances all the way to confederations, see
Weber 1997.
59
Barnet 1968; Chomsky 1985 and 1993/1994; Weiner 2007.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 31

to enhance the chances of conquering these states as the case of Poland


exemplifies.60 The Russian Empire had pursued this policy even earlier against
the Ottoman Empire. During one of the many Russo-Turkish Wars of the
eighteenth century (1768–1774), Russian Empress Catherine II (Catherine the
Great) attempted to use the Greeks in the Peloponnese as a fifth column in
order to distract the forces under the command of Sultan Mustafa III and to
create a pro-Russian state in the Mediterranean.61 It was during the war, in 1770,
that count Orlov62 successfully mobilized some Greeks in the Peloponnese. To be
sure, this did not happen overnight. Tensions between Greeks and the Ottoman
administration in the Peloponnese pre-existed. Importantly, emissaries from the
Russian Empire operated in the region as early as the 1760s recruiting support for
a potential movement against the Ottomans. By the time Count Orlov’s warships
arrived in Mani things were ready for the revolt.
Indeed, external involvement in ethnic minority politics is not a phenomenon
that belongs to the past by any means. During both the Cold War and the post–
Cold War eras, states never ceased to interfere with “minority politics” in other
states. We have ample evidence that the Soviet Union promoted the accommo-
dation of various non-core groups within the communist bloc during the Cold
War. Various non-core groups were supported by the USSR and were thus
targeted with assimilationist or exclusionary policies by United States-friendly
host states and vice versa.
But even in the post–Cold War era the same practices take place. The list of
examples from around the world is long. Seymour Hersh publicized the Bush
administration’s secret moves against Iran;63 the Russian Federation actively
supported South Ossetia in its secessionist efforts against Georgia during the
1990s and interfered on behalf of Ossetians in 2008 ultimately fighting a Russo-
Georgian War;64 and Bahrain’s King recently suggested that Iran may have been
covertly fomenting the Shi’a protests in Bahrain.65 However, the post–Cold War
cases of nation-building are more difficult to study since the necessary archival
material has not been declassified.
There are many different motivations behind a state’s adoption of a policy
that sponsors a movement in a distant land that falls short of annexing the land

60
For more on the role of the Polish legions, see Biskupski 2000: 23–24.
61
Comstock 1828, Rotzokos 2007.
62
Count Aleksey Grigoryevich Orlov (1737–1808) was a Russian military officer and statesman,
who served in the Russian Army. He defeated the Ottoman fleet at the battle of Çeşme.
63
Hersh wrote in 2008: “Late last year, Congress agreed to a request from President Bush to fund a
major escalation of secret operations against Iran, according to current and former military,
intelligence, and congressional sources. These operations, for which the President sought up to
four hundred million dollars, were described in a Presidential Finding signed by Bush, and are
designed to destabilize the country’s religious leadership. The clandestine activities involve sup-
port of the minority Ahwazi Arab and Baluchi groups and other dissident organizations. They
also include gathering intelligence about Iran’s suspected nuclear-weapons program” (The New
Yorker, July 7, 2008).
64
King 2008.
65
“Bahrain Hints at Iranian Role over Country’s Shia Uprising,” 2011.
32 Theory

in question. The motivations of an external power to support a non-core group


in another state range from destabilizing the host state to securing resources or
precipitating a regime change. An important distinction should be made between
external interference, which refers mainly to covert or clandestine operations
during peacetime, and external intervention, which refers to overt operations
that take place once there is a conflict between a host state and a non-core group.
In this book I highlight the importance of the former type of external involve-
ment, although I recognize that it is often hard to distinguish between the two
empirically. Often – how often is an empirical question – the external power that
clandestinely supports a non-core group ends up intervening overtly once a
conflict escalates.
Most scholars of international conflict focus on the motivation for external
involvement once a conflict is under way – in other words, they focus on external
intervention. Understandably, very little work exists on the early clandestine
actions taken by external powers, since the documentation of such cases is very
difficult.66 In this section, I will provide an overview of the various motivations
for external involvement that have been advanced by scholars to date, and
discuss the hypothesized effects external intervention has on political outcomes.
How can we best explain what motivates a state to adopt a policy of external
involvement? Many scholars of international relations posit that external
involvement is an outcome of ethnic ties between the non-core group and the
external power.67 According to Hale,68 based on the psychology of groups,
ethnicity connotes a sense of common/shared fate. This may be a reason for
supporting co-ethnics abroad. For example, Saideman argues that ethnic ties
influence the decision of an external power to support a non-core group more
than the threat a non-core group poses for the host state’s sovereignty or the
relative power dynamic between the external power and the host state.69
Several non-realist scholars argue that the motivation behind external
involvement in another state’s minority politics might be democratization or
humanitarian considerations.70 Some scholars argue that external powers inter-
vene once conflicts have erupted, in order to stop the fighting;71 but more recent
work suggests that intervention could be motivated by a desire to promote the
external power’s preferred outcome, above and beyond the goal of increasing
the likelihood of a settlement.72
Realist thinkers emphasize security and geopolitical considerations. For
example, Byman et al. write: “when ethnic kin or religious brethren do receive
support, it is often done to further realpolitik ambitions as opposed to being

66
For a discussion of this problem, see Gullather 2006.
67
Davis and Moore 1997; Gartzke and Gleditsch 2006; Saideman 1997; Saideman and Ayres 2000,
2008.
68
2008.
69
Saideman 2002; see also Miller 2007.
70
Heraclides 1990: 371. For a history of humanitarianism, see Barnett 2011.
71
Regan 2000: 2; De Maio 2005: 57.
72
Gleditsch 2007: 295.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 33

an end in itself. Ethnic and religious justifications are often mere window
dressing.”73 Heraclides, focusing on support for secessionist groups, suggests
as causes for external intervention “the existing constellation of states for and
against the secessionists, strategic gains, the positions of allies, great and
middle powers and friends, and relations with the state (government) threat-
ened by secession.”74
My reading of the historical record is closest to the realist worldview. Great
Powers and states around the world strategically select which non-core groups to
support. Non-core groups in geopolitically important areas – that is, economi-
cally or militarily important regions and regions with valuable resources – have
a higher probability of receiving external support from interested powers.
External powers – operating in the age of nationalism – attempt to find popu-
lations in such areas that share a common marker (such as language, religious
affiliation, race) with their own core group, or organize propaganda teams
across the border with the aim of forging a common national consciousness.
Examples are many; in Chapter 6, I discuss the policies of Bulgaria, Greece, and
Serbia in geographic Macedonia during the early twentieth century.
To be sure, non-core groups that can be presented as co-ethnics abroad are
more likely to be supported since such an endeavor is easier to legitimize in the
domestic arena under the banner of nationalism. Nevertheless, non-core groups
that reside in geopolitically unimportant areas are unlikely to enjoy external
support, regardless of their ethnic ties with neighboring states or the level of
human rights abuses against them. For example, in Chapter 5 I describe the
relative neglect of the Greek community of Monastir (today’s Bitola) by the
Greek government following World War I compared to the resources devoted to
the Asia Minor campaign at the same time.
I argue that external support for non-core groups is an inherent feature of the
international system. External support itself does not disappear although its
shape and form, as well as its intensity, varies over time and is shaped by
technological change, the configuration of the international system, and the
norms of intervention.75 Accordingly, during the Cold War, the United States
and the USSR were the most prominent external supporters of non-core groups,
and in the post-Cold War period, the number of regional powers using this tactic
has increased.76 All in all, cultural affinity is neither a necessary nor a sufficient
condition for external support – though together with other events it can become
a sufficient but unnecessary condition.77

73
Byman et al. 2001: 23.
74
Heraclides 1991: 207.
75
For more on the changing norms of intervention, see Finnemore 2004.
76
Byman et al. (2001: xvi) highlight another important trend in outside support for insurgent
movements, the rise of non-state actors such as diasporas, “refugees, foreign guerilla movements,
religious organizations, wealthy individuals, and even human rights groups.”
77
For more on causality, see Mackie 1988.
34 Theory

Effects of External Involvement


Having discussed the various motivations for external involvement, I turn now
to its effects. I divide these effects into two sets, “early” and “late.” The former
refer to instances of overt, covert, and cladestine external involvement that
include the politicization of the non-core group’s identity and the initial mobi-
lization of its members. This process is crucial in the development of many
movements and has not been given the appropriate attention even in seminal
works on the topic such as Hroch’s Social Preconditions of National Revival in
Europe.78 The “late” effects refer to instances of overt external intervention and
its impact on the outcome of state/non-core group conflicts.
In his work on proto-insurgencies, Byman summarizes the “early” effects of
external involvement. He emphasizes the importance of external power sup-
port across a wide range of issues – from offering a safe haven, money, training,
and help with political mobilization, to fostering political legitimacy and
international recognition.79 In my own work I have demonstrated that external
involvement is an important path to national mobilization and the politiciza-
tion of ethnic differences in the Balkans.80 Recently, Jenne has argued that
“external actors – and particularly regional players – influence minority beha-
vior at the substate level.”81 Jenne argues that if an external power is suppor-
tive of the claims of a minority, then the minority will radicalize its demands
against the host state. In turn, the host state can be repressive or nonrepressive.
The combination of these two dimensions accounts for the different outcomes
of state–minority relations: interethnic cooperation, repression, concessions,
and conflict. The important lesson to draw from Jenne’s work for our purposes
is the central role that outside support plays in non-core groups’ decisions to
radicalize their demands.82
The “late” effects refer to the impact of overt external intervention on the
accomplishment of a non-core group’s stated goals. External support is a sig-
nificant predictor of the onset of civil war and may actually determine which side
wins.83 A survey of insurgent movements around the world conducted by
RAND’s National Security Research Division in 2001 concludes that many
rebel movements have received external support for their insurgencies since the
end of the Cold War. Various external powers have supported insurgencies in
Asia, Africa, Europe, and the Middle East. In particular, external support played
an important role in initiating and sustaining insurgencies, as well as bringing
victory to the rebels in 44 out of 74 post-Cold War insurgencies surveyed.84

78
Hroch 2000.
79
Byman 2007: viii; Salehyan 2009.
80
Mylonas 2010.
81
Jenne 2007: 5. See also Grigoryan 2010; Thyne 2009; van Houten 1998.
82
Ibid., pp. 38–53.
83
Gleditsch 2007; Horowitz 1985: 230.
84
Byman et al. 2001: xiv; Regan (2002: 55) finds that third-party interventions to end intrastate
conflicts tend to extend expected durations rather than shorten them, unless they are biased in
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 35

The abovementioned figures depict the situation with respect to external


support and violent rebel movements with more than 1,000 battle deaths per
conflict. If the researchers used a lower threshold of battle deaths, then the
number of cases of external support included in Byman et al.’s work would
definitely increase since many cases do not reach that threshold. Salehyan,
following a much more inclusive definition of civil war, suggests that 55 percent
of all active rebel groups since 1945 “had undertaken extraterritorial operations
in countries beyond their target state.”85
Salehyan focuses on transnational rebel groups, which by definition require at
minimum sanctuary by neighboring states – unless the neighbor is a failed state.
In his framework “safe haven” is the main good that foreign states can provide
to rebel groups. This is what “critically affect[s] the bargain between states and
challengers by altering the apparent internal symmetry of force.”86 This external
mobilization and support makes bargaining failure and the outbreak of violent
conflict more likely.87
Furthermore, if one considers the extent of external support for non-violent
movements across the world, it becomes clear that external involvement for non-
core groups around the world is actually a much more prevalent and conse-
quential practice than the above statistics indicate.
The purpose of this discussion is not to claim that national movements are the
ex nihilo product of external powers’ machinations. Homegrown movements
are equally a reality. However, an unanswered empirical question is how most
national movements in the past two centuries came into being. The purpose is to
demonstrate that external involvement is an important path to national mobi-
lization and the politicization of ethnic differences. Host states, non-core groups,
and external powers interact in a dynamic process forming multiple configura-
tions that give rise to different nation-building policies.

a geostrategic argument: alliances and foreign


policy goals
Nation-building entails a parallel process whereby the ruling political elites
maintain and often reinforce differences with “nations” in surrounding states
and either accommodate or eliminate differences within their own boundaries.
Although people have been conscious of national or ethnic differences for many
centuries, in modern times this consciousness became intertwined with what has
been broadly labeled the political program of self-determination.88
favor of either the government or the rebels. For more on third-party interventions and the
duration of intrastate conflicts, see Elbadawi and Sambanis 2000.
85
2009: 5.
86
Ibid., p. 7.
87
Ibid., p. 24.
88
Banac’s (1984: 27) definition captures this well: “nationalism should only indicate an ideology, a
comprehensive, modern world view, distinguished by its all-inclusive penetration of national
consciousness into every going pursuit. . . . The old national consciousness was not necessarily
concerned with specific cultural or political goals.”
36 Theory

My argument is based on the interaction between host states and external


powers on the one hand, and host states and non-core groups on the other. I
link international geopolitical dynamics to subnational state policies through
the mechanism of interstate alliance. To account for the conditions under
which ruling political elites of a host state assimilate, accommodate, or
exclude different non-core groups, I rely on six assumptions about beliefs
held by the host state’s ruling political elites:89 First, assimilating non-core
groups makes future interference by external powers less likely.90 Second, a
non-core group supported by an ally is less of a security threat than a group
supported by a state that is part of an enemy alliance bloc.91 Third, the
strategic benefits coming from the alliance with an external power are greater
than the cost of accommodating the non-core group supported by that
power.92 Fourth, exclusionary policies are more likely than either accommo-
dation or assimilation to lead to a new interstate war that can jeopardize the
status quo.93 Fifth, accommodating a non-core group that is mobilized by an
enemy state could threaten the host state’s territorial integrity in the future;
some form of ethnic engineering is required and internal colonization with
core group members is a common policy.94 Sixth, an externally supported
movement working against the state may only constitute a fraction of the non-
core group population, but host state leaders are likely to assign threat to the
whole non-core group community since they treat the group as a category,
exaggerating homogeneity within it and differences between it and the core
group.95
Given these assumptions, I present four configurations that lead to different
policy choices, and have so far been neglected in the literature. First, a policy of
assimilation toward the non-core group is likely if the group has no external
support. Second, a host state is likely to accommodate a non-core group if an ally
is supporting that group. Third, a host state is likely to exclude a non-core group
when the state has revisionist aims and an enemy is supporting the non-core

89
These assumptions about beliefs should be considered together with the assumptions discussed in
the Introduction and within the scope conditions of my overall argument.
90
This assumption is consistent with Darden’s argument that the initial round of assimilation of a
population into a national identity through Western-style mass schooling leads to extremely fixed
identities (forthcoming). For the benefits coming from state homogeneity, see also Alesina and
Spolaore 2003.
91
The host state worries that harsh treatment of the non-core group could embitter its alliance with
the patron and harm its external security position.
92
An auxiliary assumption is that the alliance is symmetrical. However, if the alliance is asym-
metrical in favor of the host state then assimilationist policies may ensue. In Chapter 5, I relax this
assumption.
93
For more on how war can erupt from the oppression of minorities, see Van Evera 1994: 14.
94
Accommodation in such cases can only be a transitional policy before assimilationist pressures or
exclusion follows. For more on transitional policies, see Chapter 5.
95
This assumption is consistent with Hale’s work on ethnicity (2008).
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 37

External Power Support

Yes No

Interstate Relations

Ally Enemy

Revisionist
(Lost Territory
and/or Rose in Accommodation Exclusion
Power Relative to
Competitors)
Host State’s
Foreign Policy 1
Goals Assimilation
Status Quo
(Gained
Territory and/or 2
Accommodation Assimilation
Declined in
Power Relative
to Competitors)

figure 2.2. Theory predictions.


1
Sometimes takes the form of assimilation through accommodation.
2
Takes the form of internal colonization or displacement.

group.96 Finally, a host state is likely to pursue assimilation through internal


colonization if the state favors the status quo and an enemy is supporting the
non-core group (see Figure 2.2).
I have built my argument following the work of many scholars whose work
emphasizes the importance of looking at international dynamics in order to
understand minority policies.97 In my framework, however, the external actor
does not have to be a national homeland, ethnic kinship does not have to be the
motivation or even the excuse for external involvement, and the distinctiveness
of the non-core group does not have to be politically relevant or salient before
the external actor interferes. In fact, I argue that external involvement often
drives the politicization of the targeted non-core group’s identity and, more
importantly, the host state’s perception of the non-core group and the group’s
demands. This process is key to the understanding of nation-building policies.
In what follows, I illustrate the hypotheses discussed above through various
configurations that result in different nation-building policies toward non-core
groups. The real world is more complex and factors such as the military

96
Below, I also discuss a special case where both the host state and the external power have co-
ethnics within their boundaries.
97
Bob 2005; Brubaker 1996; Byman et al. 2001; Heraclides 1991; Jenne 2007; Koppa 1997;
Kuperman 2001; Rosenaue 1964; Saideman 2002; Salehyan 2009; Van Evera 1994; Van
Houten 1998; Weiner 1971.
38 Theory

capabilities of states, the nature and/or intensity of external support, non-core


group characteristics, and the quality of political leadership can in special cases
become the most important determinants of the actual policy decisions of the
ruling political elites of host states. Nevertheless, my argument captures a great
deal of the action of nation-building, despite the fact that some of its assump-
tions may need to be relaxed in individual cases.98

Configuration I: Immunization Through Assimilation


All non-core groups are potential targets for mobilization and support by
external powers. Thus, in the “age of nationalism,” the ruling political elites of
the host state have incentives to target non-core groups that are not mobilized by
any external power with assimilationist policies rather than accommodate or
exclude them.99 The absence of external interference in some cases may be the
outcome of group-level characteristics, but in many cases it results from a long-
term regional status quo that allows the host state to complete its national
integration (see Figure 2.3). The majority of non-core groups fit this configura-
tion and this explains why we have not heard much about them.
The assumption here is that the non-core group is weak relative to the core
group,100 does not have ethnic organizations, and thus is an easy target for
assimilation. Moreover, assimilationist policies produce co-nationals and with
that more and deeper bonds among the population of the state.101
Assimilationist policies function as an “immunization” of the population from
future agitation projects of external powers.102

Country Y

figure 2.3. Non-core group residing in area “Z” is not supported by any external
power.

98
I relax some of these assumptions in Chapters 5 and 8.
99
Exceptions do exist. The ruling political elites might accommodate a non-core group even when it
does not enjoy external support when the non-core group’s economic skills are linked to its
“difference.” Such cases include nomadic trading groups, groups with specific linguistic exper-
tise, or peripheral groups that perform a specific function in the internal division of labor
(Hechter 1975; Laitin 1995).
100
The fact that the non-core group may be weak does not necessarily mean that it is numerically
inferior. Similarly, the size of area “Z” in the figures of this chapter does not suggest a specific
group size.
101
In some of today’s developed states, a policy of assimilation may appear as a policy of accom-
modation since the pluralist assimilation model does not require acculturation. For a discussion
of assimilation in the United States, see Alba and Nee 1997 and 2003.
102
Darden forthcoming.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 39

Following the above logic, we should not observe a strategy of instigating


nationalist propaganda by either Great Powers or neighboring states toward
nationally integrated states that are comprised of literate, nationally conscious
citizens. In such cases Great Powers or neighboring states are more likely to
pursue alternative strategies such as ideological penetration (e.g., communism,
fascism, etc.) or direct interstate war.

Configuration II: Accommodation of Non-Core Groups Supported by Allies


Non-core groups that are mobilized by external powers are more likely to develop
a distinct political identity than the ones that are not. I have argued above that
external powers around the world do not randomly select which non-core groups
to mobilize and support. Non-core groups in geopolitically important areas have a
higher probability of being mobilized. Overall, states are more likely to target non-
core groups that are in the periphery of the host state, since they are usually harder
to control, making for easier targets. This implies, conversely, that a non-core
group is less likely to be mobilized by an external power if it is residing in a
geopolitically unimportant area, is far from the borders, and/or has already been
assimilated by the host state and is thus a “former non-core group.” The degree to
which this political identity will be perceived as threatening by the host state,
however, will depend on interstate relations.
I already discussed the different justifications that an external power can use to
interfere – ranging from a common marker (e.g., the Russian empire claimed that
it was assisting its co-religionists in the Balkans) to an international norm, such as
claims to be protecting a non-core group’s human rights, or just naked material
interest. But, under what conditions is a non-core group likely to be considered an
internal threat by the host state? I single out challenges to a state’s sovereignty as
most important. Challenges to a government’s claim to authority and secessionist
movements can be the result of external involvement by an external power that
wants to weaken, or obtain concessions from, a specific host state. For example,
Israel supported the Maronites against the Palestinians in Lebanon during the
Lebanese civil war. One rationale for this support was that the Maronites were an
under-siege minority, like the Israelis. However, it is hard to imagine that alliance
forming without the Palestinian-Israeli conflict and the utility of this support
within this broader context. Finally, challenges can and do result from independ-
ent or homegrown national movements.103 A non-core group can be perceived as
disloyal and constitute a security threat independently of receiving support by an
external power – although external support might follow in due time.

103
There is a large set of cases comprised of all “potential” non-core groups; within this set there are
two smaller sets: non-core groups mobilized by external powers and non-core groups mobilized
independently, they are “homegrown.” A movement is homegrown when it has developed
without external support or direct instigation from abroad. For a discussion of the factors that
may account for the emergence of such movements, see Connor 1973; Horowitz 1985; Hroch
2000; Sambanis and Milanovic 2009; and Treisman 1997.
40 Theory

Not all nationally conscious communities, however, are perceived as threats


to the host state. As my hypothesis above suggests, homegrown non-core groups
are likely to be targeted with assimilationist policies.104 The question remains for
the ones supported by an external power – irrespective of whether they are
homegrown or not. I argue that in such cases the policy choice will depend on
the interstate relationship – alliance or rivalry – between the host state and the
external power supporting the group.
The host state government perceives non-core groups either as challengers to
the government’s claims to authority, or as loyal groups, based on its interstate
relations with the external power supporting the non-core group. If external
support for the non-core group comes from an allied power, then the group is
not perceived as a threat. The assumption is that allied powers are not likely to
push a non-core group to challenge the host state. At the same time, the host state
is not likely to assimilate or exclude a non-core group that is supported by an
allied state, since this would jeopardize the alliance.
Why would an allied power support a non-core group? Often states cultivate
relations with non-core groups abroad for economic reasons. For example,
following World War I, Romania kept ties with Vlachs living in Greece – an
ally at the time. In an article published in a Romanian newspaper, Renasterea
Romana, by one of its chief editors we find out that Romania is cultivating these
ties “not just because of feelings toward Romanians beyond the Danube River
but also because of economic considerations, since these Romanians are very
bright, hard working, and phenomenal merchants.”105 Alliances do change and
the links that have developed between a non-core group and an external power
are sometimes hard to sever. Moreover, two states might end up in the same
international alliance bloc for reasons unrelated to their bilateral relations (e.g.,
Bulgaria and Romania during the Cold War).
All in all, non-core groups supported by an ally are likely to be accommodated by
the host state (see Figure 2.4). This prediction refers to the first round of interaction
between the non-core group and the host state. In the long run, having accommo-
dated a non-core group may operate as a precedent that decisively impacts

Country X Country Y
Support by ally
Z

fig ure 2.4. Non-core group residing in area “Z” is supported by an allied power.

104
In such cases, accommodation could be a transitional policy with assimilation being the terminal
one. This might be the result of state capacity constraints, domestic politics, or a strategic choice
dictated by special geopolitical circumstances. For a discussion of specific cases, see Chapters 5 to 8.
105
Quoted in AYE, 1921, 32/6, Report by the Greek delegation in Bucharest to the Greek Ministry
of Foreign Affairs, Bucharest, 5 January 1921.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 41

the future interaction between the host state and the non-core group. Having now
acquired the legal status of a “minority” the non-core group becomes an easier
target for external powers but also homegrown demands may develop more easily.
The situation changes drastically when the host state faces a group with outside
support from an enemy power. Things may turn even more explosive if the minority
has been given some form of territorial autonomy.106

Configuration III: Exclusion of Enemy-Supported Groups in Revisionist States


Nation-building is not considered complete until there are no disloyal groups in
a nation-state. In particular, when a host state is threatened by an enemy-
supported group, the ruling political elites will definitely not accommodate it,
because they will anticipate a future fifth column situation. Whether a host state
will pursue assimilation or exclusion toward a non-core group supported by an
external enemy power will depend on the foreign policy goals of the government,
as well as the immediacy of the threat to its rule by that group. These factors in
turn are influenced by the broader geopolitical situation and the readiness of
host state resources.107 For example, in a situation where there are two non-core
groups supported by enemy powers, then we may get differential responses
reflecting gradations of threat by each group and the need to conserve resources.
But what determines the government’s foreign policy orientation? The ruling
political elites of a state are likely to be motivated by revisionist foreign policy
goals if they have lost territories in war and have received a large number of
refugees or have a significant number of co-ethnics in nearby states as a result.
The loss of territory radicalizes domestic politics in a rather direct manner
through the collective disappointment experienced by all core group members
and the resulting feelings of revenge and anger.108 However, there is a more
indirect way for radicalization to occur. Lost territories usually create refugee
flows, and these refugees in turn are likely to demand more revisionist policies
from the ruling political elites. This was the case for example in Bulgaria
following the Balkan Wars. When this domestic pressure is coupled with the
imperative for defending the state against an external power that is linking up
with an internal “fifth column,” we get exclusionary policies.
A few clarifications are necessary at this point. Irredentism is a variant of
revisionism, and becomes the foreign policy goal when a state has recently lost
territory in war and/or has “unredeemed co-ethnics.”109 Revisionism in my

106
Brubaker 1996; Roeder 1991 and 2007; Triesman 1997.
107
In this decisionmaking process, the core group members who are not part of the ruling political
elites only indirectly influence decisions, even in democratic settings. Decisions with respect to the
non-core groups are usually made behind closed doors, on behalf of the “nation” but without its
direct approval. Nevertheless, there is an important way that core group members matter in the
process. Their prejudices, discriminatory views, and desire for revenge may derail the policy
pursued by the ruling political elites. Such developments are particularly hard for nation-builders
to anticipate.
108
Petersen 2002.
109
For different varieties of irredentism, see Van Evera 1994: 12–13.
42 Theory

framework refers to a state’s ex ante stated foreign policy goals, not necessarily
its behavior.110 Nazi Germany, for example, was a revisionist state because it
harbored revisionist aims, not because it attacked allied powers. Analogously, I
argue that Serbia was a limited-aims revisionist state before 1918 because its aim
was to enlarge its borders, not because it fought Bulgaria and Austria-Hungary.
Additionally, revisionism can be the result of a pure expansionist desire,
which may be instigated either by population growth or military strength and
technological innovations. The motivations behind expansionism could be stra-
tegic ones, such as access to sea, expropriation of resources, or more defensible
borders.111 Moreover, a host state can become more assertive in its revisionist
claims when it obtains the approval and support of one or more of the Great
Powers. Finally, the pressure from the external enemy state could be so great that
it might actually lead to the transformation of a status quo state into a revisionist
state (i.e., a radical party wins the elections). Regardless of the origins of such
foreign policy goals, revisionist elites want to alter the international status quo.
From the considerations I have just now outlined, I derive the following
hypothesis: when the host state has revisionist foreign policy goals, its ruling
political elites are likely to pursue exclusionary policies toward non-core groups
that are supported by an enemy power (see Figure 2.5). This is to prevent a “fifth
column” situation and to discourage elites of other non-core groups from
pursuing such schemes.112 Importantly, exclusionary policies involve extreme
measures that might jeopardize the international status quo and lead to a war. A
revisionist host state is more likely to undertake such policies than a status quo
one – despite the fact that this state’s foreign policy may not “track objective
material power trends closely or continuously.”113 Within this subset of cases,
ethnic cleansing becomes more likely in wartime when the stakes are high, the
time horizon is short, and international monitoring is absent.

Country X Country Y:
Support by enemy Revisionist

figure 2.5. Non-core group residing in area “Z” is supported by an enemy power,
host state revisionist.

110
Davidson 2002. See the relevant discussion in the Introduction and earlier in this chapter
111
There is an important distinction to be made between revisionist and irredentist policies. Both
aim at territorial expansion; however, the latter usually involve contiguous territories and a
willingness to nationally integrate the desired territories into the core nation–state. Imperialist
policies, by contrast, need not involve contiguous territories, and are premised on an hierarchical
exploitative relationship with their dominions.
112
This auxiliary hypothesis is consistent with Walter’s argument that I discussed above (2009).
113
Rose 1998: 147.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 43

Country X Support Country Y

Ys Xs

figure 2.6. Host state and external power are contiguous and have each other’s co-
ethnics.

Given this prediction, we should observe few non-core groups willing to


accept support from enemy powers. Indeed, most non-core groups do not seek
enemy support and when they do they try to cover it as much as possible (e.g., the
CIA involvement in Tibet after 1956 was not advertised by the Tibetan move-
ment).114 Other times, only a small part of the non-core group collaborates with
an enemy power but the host state – incapable of distinguishing between the
various factions – ends up perceiving the whole non-core group as disloyal. Why
would an enemy external power pursue such a policy? First of all, external
powers usually try to keep these operations secret. Alternatively they may try
to justify it based on an international norm.115 However, often the goal of the
external enemy is to provoke the most destabilizing situation possible for the
host state. The external power does not worry as much about the fate of the non-
core group.
Irredentism (a special form of revisionism) could be provoking tit-for-tat
retaliation on the part of the neighbor state. This is more likely for contiguous
states that both have co-ethnics within their boundaries, which is a plausible
scenario but also a special case where mutual deterrence is likely and where tit-
for-tat pushback could play out. Thus, the prediction based on the configuration
shown in Figure 2.6 is mutual deterrence, and a lower likelihood of exclusionary
policies.
However, the option of population exchange is also available in such a
configuration, as the cases of Bulgaria and Greece in 1919 or Greece and
Turkey in 1923 suggest. Thus it is difficult to make a clear prediction just
based on this setup.116

Configuration IV: Assimilation of Enemy-Supported Groups in Status


Quo States
Status quo host states, in contrast, do not seek border changes. Status quo
foreign policy goals may be the result of the host state declining in power relative
to its competitors, or because it has recently expanded its territory and needs to

114
Knaus 1999; McGranahan 2010.
115
Kuperman and Crawford 2006.
116
In order to test this argument in my statistical analysis I add a dichotomous variable coding for all
of these cases in my dataset; see Chapter 4.
44 Theory

Country X Country Y:
Support by enemy Status Quo

figure 2.7. Non-core group residing in area “Z” is supported by an enemy power,
host state is status quo.

consolidate. The logic here is that such developments will have either signifi-
cantly decreased the number of “unredeemed” co-ethnics, or moderated the core
group’s aspirations and thus decreased the salience of irredentist politics. At the
same time, however, a territorial expansion usually brings with it additional
non-core groups that already are considered – or could potentially become –
internal threats. An example is Romania after World War I.
When the host state wants to preserve the status quo in newly-acquired
regions, it is likely to pursue assimilationist and internal colonization policies
toward the members and political exclusion toward the elites of a non-core
group supported by an enemy power, rather than exclusionary policies for all
that could easily trigger a new round of hostilities and a breakdown of the status
quo (see Figure 2.7).117 To be sure, assimilation is more likely than exclusion if
there is enough time for it, but otherwise more brutal, decisive measures may be
taken. For instance, in wartime a status quo host state may pursue exclusionary
policies if it faces a non-core group supported by an enemy simply because it has
no time for assimilationist policies. Finally, under such circumstances, accom-
modating the non-core group is not an option since it would allow for future
manipulation of the “minority issue” by the external enemy power in an oppor-
tune moment.118 Internal colonization also dilutes the territorial concentration
of the non-core group thus making the group a less appealing target for external
powers to support.
What happens when external support of a non-core group ceases? The effects
of external power support for a group are hardly reversible precisely because
they operate in the realm of ruling political elite’s perceptions. In other words,
there are lingering effects of supporting a non-core group that do not simply go
away when the actual support ceases. The main development that can alter this
dynamic has to do with a change in the alliance structure that renders the
external power and the host state allies from enemies. If an ex-supporter ceases
to be an enemy and becomes an ally, we are likely to observe a move from
assimilation or exclusion – depending on the host state’s foreign policy goals – to
accommodation.

117
This is consistent with Van Evera’s hypothesis 1.4. “The more severely nationalities oppress
minorities living in their states, the greater the risk of war” (1994).
118
Weiner 1971.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 45

In all the predictions above, I assume that there is enough time to pursue the
government’s favorite policy. Time limitations – including the variation in
governments’ time horizons – do exist, however, and impact the decisionmaking
process. As we will see in Chapters 5 to 8, such pressures are present primarily
during wartime and may account for the higher frequency and/or intensity of
exclusionary policies in certain cases.

Possible Causal Paths


The causal path discussed above assumes that a host state takes the initiative and
chooses its policies toward a non-core group based on whether an external
power is actively engaged in mobilizing it or not, as well as in light of its relations
with the external power in question. However, one could think of many other
causal paths that would be consistent with my argument. For example, a non-
core group might be the first to act, asking for more local autonomy. An external
actor may have secretly instigated this demand. The host state might then
implement harsh policies against the group, an escalation that leads to a conflict.
The elites of the non-core group might then turn to outside powers and ask for
their support against the host state. In this case, the external power(s) would
have to decide whether to overtly intervene or not. In this scenario my argument
would still explain the variation in nation-building policies.
What if there is mobilization in the absence of clandestine or overt support
from external powers? Many studies of international relations posit that outside
support is the outcome of violent nation-building policies pursued by nationaliz-
ing host states, rather than something causally prior to such policies.119 According
to this view, external intervention is the outcome of a security dilemma that non-
core groups face at the domestic level that motivates them to request external
support: they seek help only after they have reason to feel insecure. In this scenario
non-core groups choose their allies based on the existing alliance structure follow-
ing the logic: “the enemy of my enemy is my friend.”120
According to my argument, non-core groups that have no external support
are more likely to be targeted with assimilationist policies by the host state. It is
possible, however, that the assimilationist campaign escalates into conflict and
the non-core group elite seeks external intervention.121 In reaction, the host state
may then resort to preemptive exclusionary measures (e.g., the case of Serbia in
the 1990s). This causal path is different from, though not inconsistent with, my
general argument. My argument would be fundamentally undermined only if
host states more often than not accommodate or pursue exclusionary policies122
toward non-core groups that are not supported by any external power.

119
Lake and Rothchild 1998; Posen 1993b; Snyder 1991.
120
For more on negative association, see Evrigenis 2008.
121
For an argument of how direct rule leads to peripheral nationalism, see Hechter 2000.
122
A possible causal path involves power-hungry leaders who may engage in scapegoating of
specific non-core groups when they believe this is a popular strategy; see Brass 1991; Gagnon
46 Theory

To be sure, there are prominent cases of homegrown movements that have


not been targeted with assimilationist policies by their governments but I would
argue that they are the exceptions that prove the rule. The majority of non-core
groups that had no external support have been targeted with assimilationist
policies and, more often than not, have been successfully assimilated.
Another possible causal path is one in which the host state’s policies are
merely reactions to observed past behavior of the various non-core groups.
For instance, many scholars argue that a history of past violence makes exclu-
sionary policies more likely. If this past behavior is influenced by external power
involvement, then my framework still applies. If, however, the non-core groups’
past (and current) behavior is unrelated to external support or instigation, then
my argument predicts assimilation rather than exclusionary policies.
The actual causal mechanism at work in each situation is an empirical ques-
tion; nevertheless, the empirical record of “unsolicited” external involvement is
vast and renders my main causal path a plausible – yet neglected – one. One of
the difficulties related to adjudicating this empirical question is that much
external involvement occurs secretly, thus shielding the myriad relevant facts
from inspection by social scientists; often the declassified archival material that
is available does little to remedy this problem. Thus, scholars need to rely on the
few cases where enough useful archival material has been made available as to
permit them to unravel the complete causal story. For example, after the end of
the Cold War, both the United States and Russia released a series of confidential
documents that unveiled many “secret histories” of such clandestine action
around the globe. A couple of decades ago we would categorize many cases of
ethnic conflict differently than we do nowadays, after this new wave of evidence
has come to light.123
But maybe alliances are endogenous to nation-building policies. One might
argue that the pattern of alliances between the external power and the host state
is caused by the nation-building policies of the host state rather than being
causally prior to them. In this way, there could be an endogeneity problem.
Whether a country is an enemy or an ally might be endogenous to nation-
building policies in the first place – especially if these policies target a non-core
group that can be construed as an “ethnic kin.” This is questionable both
theoretically and empirically.
Theoretically speaking, this consideration does not even come up in the
literature on alliances – except perhaps as part of the arguments highlighting
ideological or cultural affinities between states.124 The primary considerations

1994/1995 and 2004; Harff 1987; and Snyder 2000. It is an empirical question how common
such a strategy is. For a more extensive discussion of scapegoating, see Chapter 8.
123
Gaddis 1997.
124
An exception is Steven David’s work and his concept of “omnibalancing” (1991). David suggests
that state elites often have to balance internal and external threats. In fact, he goes further to
argue that in Third World contexts external alignment is often a function of internal threats to
the regime ruling a state and intergroup relations. I am positing that causality, more often than
not, runs in the other direction.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 47

behind the formation of alliances explored in the literature are either balancing a
threatening state (or bloc of states) by siding with its enemies, or else siding with
a strong threatening state (or bloc of states) – a practice known as
bandwagoning.125
Empirically, Walt has shown that states form alliances principally to balance
external threats.126 One might argue that states try to side with the likely winner;
however, this cannot always be easily discerned and even when it is alliances do
not automatically shift. For instance, Walt reminds us that during World War I
the alliance of Great Britain, France, and Russia controlled around 28 percent of
world industrial production, while Germany and Austria-Hungary controlled
19 percent. In 1917, with Russia facing the October revolution and the United
States joining Britain and France, the percentage opposing the Central Powers
went above 50 percent but the international alliance structure during World
War I did not change significantly during the war.127
Moreover, external powers rarely intervene solely to protect national mino-
rities from nation-building policies pursued by host states. Empirically we know
that the motivations behind external involvement (covert or overt) vary signifi-
cantly from case to case. Some external powers support non-core groups solely
in order to destabilize a neighbor or to precipitate a regime change; others claim
to do so in order to support the separatist goals of their co-ethnics or co-
religionists (often a cover up for expansionist intentions); while others aim to
secure resources and regional influence. King and Melvin, focusing on the post-
Soviet states, conclude that:

[I]n the realm of ethnicity and international relations, identity politics is often more about
politics than about identity. Disputes over the allocation of scarce resources, competing
visions of foreign policy directions, domestic political contests, and other prosaic features
of political life frequently trump any putative duty that political elites might feel toward
individuals who share their language or culture beyond their own frontiers.128

Furthermore, in a recent survey of insurgent movements in the post-Cold War


era, Byman et al. find that “states are primarily motivated by geopolitics rather
than ideology, ethnic affinity, or religious sentiment” when they support non-
core groups in other states.129 Such findings provide additional support to my
theoretical framework. I maintain that more often than not, “vertical escala-
tion”130 of ethnic conflict is an outcome of prior covert external involvement
that has occurred for reasons unrelated to the treatment of the relevant non-core
group by the relevant host state.

125
Snyder 1991.
126
Walt 1985, 1987, and 1988.
127
Walt 1985: 9.
128
1999: 109.
129
2001:23.
130
Vertical escalation refers to increases in the intensity or level of violence within a conflict; see
Lake and Rothchild 1998: 24.
48 Theory

conclusion
In this chapter I developed a theory that accounts for the variation in nation-
building policies resulting primarily from the interaction of host states and
external powers, rather than non-core groups and host states. I argued that a
host state’s foreign policy goals, as well as its interstate relations with external
powers that may be supporting its non-core groups, drive nation-building
choices. The presence of external support for a non-core group and the interstate
relations between the external power and the host state determine whether the
group will be perceived as threatening or not. A non-core group supported by an
enemy external power and residing in a revisionist host state is more likely to be
excluded than targeted with assimilation or accommodation; if a similar group
were to reside in a status quo state, it would most likely be targeted with
assimilationist policies; taking the form of colonization by core group members
and internal displacement of non-core group members. Finally, non-core groups
supported by allied states are more likely to be accommodated than be assimi-
lated or excluded.
From the discussion above, it becomes clear that the attributes of non-core
groups are secondary in the process I am describing. “Ethnicity” matters, but
only when it is activated in the international arena. Similarly, the existence of a
“homeland” is also endogenous to interstate relations with the host state, since
an external power chooses when to act as a homeland based on these very
relations and its strategic interests.
Unlike Gellner or Anderson, who emphasize the importance of industriali-
zation and print capitalism for the spread of nationalism, or Kedourie and
Kohn, who highlight the causal priority of willful idealism in the process, I
hold that the emergence of nationalism is the result of an interaction between
strategic choices made under the structural conditions of international com-
petition for territory and resources within the Westphalian system of states, on
the one hand, and the technological innovations131 and intellectual currents
that emerged during the Enlightenment, on the other.132 One of the strategies
that external powers used to weaken their rivals has been to support ethnically
homogeneous populations, residing in geopolitically important locations,
preferably at the periphery of their competitor state. The process I described
above has contributed to the spread of nationalism and has even had an
ethnogenetic role in many cases. My argument helps us understand the host
state’s motivation to adopt assimilationist policies133 – to fend off future
external involvement – and likewise helps us understand many cases of

131
Posen 1993a; Hobsbawm 1990 and 1991.
132
Fichte 1968; Herder 2004; Kedourie 1993; Kitromilides 1994; Kohn 1945; Renan 1996;
Rousseau 1985.
133
Hechter 2000.
The Politics of Assimilation, Accommodation, Exclusion 49

ethnogenesis where external agitation and support turned non-core groups


into “awakened nations.”134
In the following chapters (Chapters 3 through 7), I focus on the politics of
nation-building in those states that emerged from the gradual dissolution of the
Ottoman Empire in Europe. These cases provide an excellent context in which to
study nation-building policies for a number of reasons: protracted intermingling
of peoples, common experiences of past rule, similar modernization trajectories,
a great deal of external involvement, and variation in the timing of their state-
building experiences. I test my theory next to various prominent arguments such
as cultural distance, status reversal, and homeland at multiple levels of analysis
and using a variety of data sources. In Chapter 8, I move out of the southeast
corner of Europe in order to test the generalizability of my argument.

134
Hroch 2000.
part ii

EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
3

Why the Balkans?

This book focuses on the Balkans,1 that is, those areas of Southeastern Europe
that were part of the Ottoman Empire.2 Studying one region during a specific
period of time allows me to make some credible assumptions about actors’
preferences, increase my analytical leverage, and control for several macro-
historical and geopolitical factors that affect the planning of nation-building
policies. Moreover, choosing a region and studying all non-core groups inhabit-
ing it allows me to avoid the most common form of selection bias, namely
focusing on the most prominent and well-studied cases.
Overall, the Balkan states provide an excellent laboratory in which to study
nation-building policies because of the protracted intermingling of heterogene-
ous populations and the variation in the timing of their state-building experi-
ences. This set of cases is also a crucial test for some of the most prominent
explanations in the literature.3 The Balkan states have been considered as stereo-
typical cases of deep-rooted “ethnic hatreds”4 or symbolic politics.5
“Balkanization” is still used by journalists and academics as a pejorative term
describing a range of processes from political fragmentation to irrational ethnic
violence and chaos.6 All in all, the Balkan Peninsula is typically considered as the
most turbulent and nationalistic part of Europe;7 thus it should be harder to

1
For historical surveys of the region, see Janković 1988; Jelavich and Jelavich 1965 and 1977;
Mazower 2001; Pavlowitch 1999; Quataert 2005; Roudometof 1996 and 2001; Stavrianos 1957;
Sugar 1977.
2
Southeastern Europe is the neutral term that many scholars use today as an alternative to
politically/culturally loaded and anachronistic terms such as “the Balkans” and “Turkey-in-
Europe,” respectively. Specifically, I include in the analysis any country of Southeastern Europe
following World War I that was a part of the Ottoman Empire for more than two centuries. In
particular: Greece, The Kingdom of Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes, Romania, Bulgaria, Albania, and
Turkey.
3
Gerring 2007: 86–150.
4
Kaplan 1993.
5
Kaufman 2001.
6
Glenny 2001: xxi–xxvi; Mazower 2001; Todorova 1997.
7
Pavlowitch 2000.

53
54 Empirical Evidence

discern a geostrategic logic in nation-building policies here than anywhere else.


Finding a pattern would question the validity of analyses that treat the Balkans
as an exception, an aberration of sorts, and improve our understanding of the
process of nation-building.
In what follows I critically discuss the Ottoman legacy in the Balkans, intro-
duce the reader to the geopolitics of the Balkan Peninsula, and conclude with a
brief introduction of the six states under study in Chapter 4.

ottoman legacy in the balkans


Broadly speaking, the Ottoman system was comprised of nonterritorial religious
communities (millets) that had varying degrees of autonomy in terms of the
administration of justice and local affairs. Thus, certain things were common
across the whole of the Ottoman Empire but, then again, not throughout the
entire period of Ottoman rule.8 This realization complicates things. After initial
conquest, the local ruling classes of the Balkan peoples were crushed or incorpo-
rated into the Ottoman system (depending on whether they resisted or not,
respectively).9 As a result, the local population was “left leaderless, anonymous,
and silent.”10 These were all predominantly agricultural societies that lived in a
world of corporate privileges for religious groups rather than individual rights.
The merchants were very few. Stavrianos summarizes this well: “The typical
Ottoman subject thought of himself primarily as a member of a guild if he lived
in a city or as a member of a village community if he lived in the countryside. If he
had any feeling of a broader allegiance, it was likely to be of a religious rather
than of a political character.”11

The Millet System


An institution that many scholars highlight as an important Ottoman legacy
across the Balkans is the millet system. This system of managing difference has
been identified as the main reason behind the salience of religious identities in the
minds of ruling political elites in the new Balkan states.12 While it is true that the
millet system did have an impact on identity formation across the Balkans, both
its implementation and its effects varied.
For example, the Ottoman Empire did not engage in assimilation or religious
conversion campaigns on a systematic or massive scale. But there is significant
variation since the Ottoman state did pursue religious conversion in “Albania,
Bosnia, Herzegovina, parts of Bulgaria, and the island of Crete.”13 Thus, when

8
For more on the Ottoman Legacy, see Hajdarpašić 2008; Hartmuth 2008; Mylonas 2011 and
2012; Philliou 2008; Sabatos 2008; Yilmaz and Yosmaoğlu 2008.
9
Mazower 2004.
10
Stavrianos 1957: 96.
11
1957: 338.
12
Katsikas 2009; Roudometof 2001; Tsitselikis 2007.
13
Stavrianos 1957: 335; Todorov 1983.
Why the Balkans? 55

the “Age of Nationalism” came at its door there was a myriad of differences that
had survived Ottoman rule and could be politicized. Religion was one of them.
Allowing for an important degree of local communal autonomy (especially in
everyday matters), keeping urban centers religiously segregated, and eliminating
local aristocracies (instead of using them to control the local peasants) facilitated
the perpetuation of most communities and their cultures.14 Moreover, as Göçek
notes, although legally speaking everybody in the Ottoman Empire had the same
inheritance and land-use rights these rights were only applicable within each
millet and not across.15 This social barrier between Muslims and non-Muslims
structured many of the independence movements and patterns of alliance at the
local level during the nineteenth century.
National categories such as “Greek,” “Bulgarian,” or “Turkish” did not
signify the same thing to everybody. It was common to refer to Orthodox
Christians as “Rum (or Romioi)” – a term that has been used interchangeably
with the term “Greek” – regardless of their native languages or ethnic back-
grounds. Christians would use the term “Turk” to refer to Muslims of all types
of ethnic and linguistic background; thus they could mean an Albanian, a Bosnian
Muslim, a Pomak, a Donmeh, or a Muslim Vlach. The majority of the population
still identified themselves in religious terms. When somebody was called
“Bulgarian” in geographic Macedonia, it basically meant that the person had
joined the Bulgarian Exarchate, a church organization established with Russian
backing as recently as 1870.16 Until the early twentieth century, most people
collapsed religious and national categories in very counterintuitive ways, from a
modern point of view. As Mazower put it, “[t]he illiterate Slav-speaking peasants
tilling the fields outside the cities rarely felt strongly about either Greece or
Bulgaria and when asked which they were, many insisted on being known simply,
as they had been for centuries, as ‘Christians.’”17 This is not to say that there were
no national identities in the Balkans, but just to highlight the fluid character of
these identities in the minds of many inhabitants of the Balkan Peninsula.18

The Emergence of New Nation-States


Another thing that is usually referred to as common among Balkan states is that
they all got their independence through secession from the Ottoman Empire
during the age of nationalism.19 As a result, they all emulated the homogeneous
European nation-state model (which was obviously just a programmatic goal
rather than a reality even in Western Europe).20 Nationalism largely based on an

14
Stavrianos (1957: 339) illustrates this point through a comparison between the Venetian and
Ottoman rules over Crete and other parts of the Balkans.
15
1993: 515.
16
Meininger 1970.
17
2004: 257.
18
Friedman 1999 and 2001.
19
Hobsbawm 1991; Mylonas 2006.
20
Todorova 1997.
56 Empirical Evidence

ethnocultural understanding of nationhood – with strong religious undertones –


was the face of modernity in the Balkans.21 To be sure, the understanding of
nationhood in the various Balkan states has been contested. Most Balkan states
had – and most still have – a predominantly ethnocultural understanding of
nationhood. However, all of them have been flexible with their definition when
their foreign policy goals and domestic expediency required them to do so.
New states emerged in Southeastern Europe in the nineteenth century:22 Serbia
between 1815 and 1830, Greece in 1830, Romania in 1862, and Montenegro and
Bulgaria in 1878. Serbia, Greece, and Bulgaria fought secessionist wars against the
Ottomans to carve out their lands from the pre-existing vilayets (territorial admin-
istrative units) of the Empire. Romania (Moldavia and Wallachia) and
Montenegro developed into independent states after being vassal-states of the
Ottoman Empire for centuries. Albania and Turkey were the last two states to be
established in the European territories of the Ottoman Empire in 1913 and 1923,
respectively. This marked the end of the Ottoman Empire.
The state-building experience of each of these states has been different. The
path each state took in order to achieve its independence and the events that took
place during that period have a lasting impact on the constitutive story of each
nation and shape the actual effect and perception of the Ottoman legacy itself.
All of these nation-states had unredeemed co-ethnics outside their borders.23
Some states were left with a significant number of co-ethnics abroad while others
were not. Some had constitutive myths that urged the re-establishment of
medieval or ancient borders regardless of ethnic demography. As I theorized in
Chapter 2 and as we will see in the empirical chapters that follow, these “facts”
in turn influenced the foreign policy goals of the ruling political elite of the
country and were often codified in some type of a revisionist ideology or a
“Great Idea.” Until the goals stated in this ideology were satisfied these states
were under the spell of these nationalist programs.24 But what did nation-
building look like in the nineteenth century?

The Antecedents of Nation-Building in the Balkans


Studying nation-building policies in the nineteenth century reveals that the
newly established states more or less ignored the national consciousness of

21
Banac 1995.
22
Jelavich and Jelavich 1977; Koppa 2002.
23
Mazower captures this reality well: “All states could point to ‘unredeemed’ brethren or historic
lands which lay outside the boundaries apportioned them by the Powers: Romanians in
Hungarian Transylvania, Serbs in Habsburg Croatia and Ottoman lands; Bulgarians in the
lands of the San Stefano state they had been cheated of; Greeks – in thrall to the ‘Great Idea’ of
a new Byzantine Empire – redeeming Hellenism across the Ottoman Empire from Crete to the
Black Sea. Popular irredentism mobilized public opinion, financed cross-border incursions by
bands of irregulars, and often forced unwilling Balkan monarchs into rash adventures against the
advice or wishes of the Powers” (2000: 101–102).
24
For more on the variation in the scope of the desired state borders by nationalist movements, see
Mylonas and Shelef 2012.
Why the Balkans? 57

their rural populations regardless of its ethnic, religious, linguistic, or cultural


background. Nation-building policies were linked to the processes of state central-
ization and modernization. Wherever these latter processes occurred in the Balkans,
national integration policies also took root. Group-specific nation-building policies
were largely linked with the creation of the new Balkan states and the Ottoman
reactions to these movements. The pattern involved exclusionary policies followed
by the rebels toward Muslims and Ottoman reprisals toward the co-ethnics of each
secessionist group within the Empire.25 Consistent with modernization theories,
assimilation was mainly an unintended consequence of migration to the urban
centers as well as church-run schooling. In this manner, people of “low cultures”
assimilated into “high cultures” and enjoyed upward social mobility.26
In the case of Ottoman Europe, the choice between different high cultures was
more or less determined by religious affiliation, which was institutionalized by the
millet system. For example, a Vlach from the Pindos mountains or a Slavophone
from the plains of Macedonia – both members of the Rum millet by virtue of their
Christian Orthodox faith – would assimilate into Greek “high culture.” This
Ottoman form of accommodation was based solely on religious, not national,
grounds. Toward the end of the nineteenth century – and especially after the 1878
Russo-Turkish war – competing national programs collided and the stage was set
for the enactment of a series of nation-building campaigns throughout the peninsula.
Especially during the late nineteenth century, amidst an intense Great Power
competition, assimilationist policies intensified but were primarily focused on
contested borderland areas rather than inside the borders of Balkan states.
These cases constitute special cases of nation-building policies taking place within
the Ottoman Empire.27 The most common strategies were the establishment of
schools,28 the control of churches, and the organization of armed bands, which
would ultimately imprint the “correct” national consciousness in the hearts and
minds of the local population.29 Urban centers and groups of the dominant
Muslim faith were largely left out of this competition but were exposed to
Ottomanization and later on Turkification campaigns. Moreover, exclusionary
policies pursued by the aspiring Balkan nationalist movements could be used only
selectively on individuals since the Ottomans still controlled these territories.

great powers, balkan states, and the “eastern


question”
The six states I focus on were all engaged in the “Eastern Question,” namely
Great Power competition for spheres of influence,30 instigated by the gradual

25
Ilicak 2011.
26
Gellner 1983.
27
Akhund 2009.
28
Vouri 1992.
29
Aarbakke 2003; Dakin 1966; Gounaris 1996; Livanios 1999; Perry 1988. For more, see my
discussion of these policies in geographic Macedonia in Chapter 5.
30
The Powers involved include Britain, France, Austria-Hungary, Russia, and later Imperial
Germany and Italy.
58 Empirical Evidence

disintegration of the Ottoman Empire. During the nineteenth century, the


Ottoman Empire was relatively weak and the Great Powers of Europe were
directly trying to achieve a settlement of the Eastern Question; at the same time,
they were pre-occupied with their colonial scramble for land and political
influence elsewhere. Initially, Great Power competition for spheres of influence
in the Ottoman Empire took the form of the establishment of “friendly,” and
preferably Christian, states. Russia was the first to move in the process of
national agitation of peoples inhabiting neighboring Empires (both Ottoman
and Austro-Hungarian) just as France had played that role since Napoleonic
times in the West (see Illustration 3.1).31 As a response to these pressures from
abroad the Ottoman Empire undertook the Tanzimat reforms (1839–1876), an

illu stration 3.1. “At present he works Bulgaria.” Source: Library of Congress
Prints and Photographs Division, Washington, D.C.

31
Driault 1921.
Why the Balkans? 59

attempt to modernize the administration and the army that resulted in the
apogee of direct rule in the Balkans.32
Pavlowitch describes well the international context within which the Balkan
states emerged. He highlights the importance of great powers in the foreign
policies of Balkan states. “They were encouraged and manipulated. Their size,
shape, stage of growth, even their existence in final analysis was regulated by the
Powers in the hope of gaining influence.”33 Pavlowitch, however, reminds us
that the small Balkan states were not without agency; they also exploited the
mutual jealousies of the Powers.
The joint production, by the Great Powers and the local Balkan elites, of both
the Balkan states and the main policy initiatives of these states is an undisputed
fact in Balkan historiography. According to Janković, the Eastern Question was
the product of conflict between the Great Powers over their interests in these
areas. It was these plans that “caused problems everywhere or kept them
simmering to serve as pretexts for intervention or bargaining for compromises
and divisions of spheres of interest.”34
During the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, competition between
Bulgaria and Serbia, and later between Bulgaria and Greece,35 aimed at linguis-
tic assimilation, religious conversion (when necessary), and the instillation of
“correct” national feelings in the people inhabiting the Ottoman vilayets of
Selanik, Monastir, and Kosova.36 Linguistic differences were present, but were
not as entrenched and politicized as religious institutions. The millet system was
ever-present in daily lives and peoples’ imagination, yet national identities and
ideas were not broadly held. For the new Balkan national movements to succeed,
the Orthodox millet had to be fragmented into “national churches.”37
In this regard, the establishment of the Bulgarian Exarchate in 1870 was
very significant for developments in the region.38 The Sultan issued a firman39
in 1870 that recognized a separate millet status for the Bulgarian-speaking
Orthodox Christians – the Bulgarian Orthodox Exarchate. The Sultan’s goal
was to appease the Bulgarians, who were supported by the Russians, and to
check Greek aspirations.40 The Bulgarization of the massive Slavic-speaking
peasant population in geographic Macedonia, which until then was grouped
under the Orthodox Christian millet, began around 1835 with the

32
Shaw 1974: 73; Hechter 2000.
33
2000: 144.
34
1988: 7.
35
Romania and Italy were involved as well, but to a lesser extent; they primarily claimed the loyalty
of the Vlach-speaking populations in the region.
36
Koliopoulos 1987; Perry 1988; Yosmaoğlu-Turner 2005. Catholic and protestant missions
operated in the region in the nineteenth century, but with limited success; see Vouri 1994: 54–56.
37
Kitromilides 1994.
38
For the role of Russian diplomacy in this affair and the politics surrounding the event, see
Meininger 1970.
39
Firmans were decrees, edicts, or special licenses issued by the Sultan.
40
Meininger 1970.
60 Empirical Evidence

introduction of Bulgarian-speaking schools. That was in large part a response


to the growing assimilation of these people and many of their elites into Rum
or Romioi, the Orthodox Christian millet loyal to the Patriarch in Istanbul.41
Although this was originally presented as a struggle over the language used in
church within the Rum millet, in the end it became a struggle for jurisdiction
over territories. Article ten of the firman stated that “the Exarch shall be
allowed to send a Bishop to any district where at least two-thirds of the
Christian inhabitants shall have been proved to be Bulgarians.” This article
immediately spurred competition among the Greeks, Serbs, and Bulgarians
over disputed territories.
After the promulgation of the firman, Bulgarian bishops were appointed by
the Exarch to various dioceses and were sanctioned by the Porte. As a result: “In
these newly-constituted dioceses nearly all the churches, schools, cemeteries, and
other ecclesiastical property with their revenues, although virtually belonging to
the Greeks,42 were seized and appropriated by the Bulgarians; and consequently,
the Greek bishops, finding themselves deserted by the Christian population, had
to remove their residences elsewhere.”43 It was clear from the beginning that this
state of affairs would ultimately lead to some form of autonomous Bulgarian
self-rule, or even an independent state.
The competition over the Christian population of these territories intensified
after the Russo-Turkish War and the San Stefano and Berlin Conferences (1878) –
both of which were clear signals that the Ottoman territories in Europe would be
up for grabs in the near future.44 It is no coincidence that a few years later, in 1886,
the Society of St. Sava was established to “spread Serbian national propaganda
among the Slav-speaking Macedonians.”45 Propaganda and political killings by
state-sponsored guerrillas of the competing states were common (especially
between Bulgarians and Greeks).46 These proxy armies also staged a handful of
local revolts against the Ottomans. At the same time, efforts to gain the loyalty of
the peasants through schooling and church catechism, as well as by explicit threats
by armed bands, were systematically pursued.47
Up until the Russo-Turkish War of 1877–1878 (fought to establish a kind
of a Russian protectorate in the heart of the Balkan Peninsula and gain access

41
The term was often used interchangeably with the term “Greek” at the time, especially by
outsiders to the region. For more on this Hellenization process, see Aarbakke 2012.
42
Technically they belonged to the Orthodox Ecumenical Patriarchate in Istanbul. Consul-General
Blunt, however, equates the “Rum” millet with the term “Greeks” in this document.
43
Enclosure 1 in No. 54, Consul-General Blunt to Sir W. White, 8 December 1888 [FO 287/13].
44
Karavas 2010.
45
Kontogiorgi 2006: 27.
46
For more on the use of propaganda in the Balkans, see Ilchev 1996.
47
For the competition over Macedonia, see Aarbakke 2003; Brailsford 1906; Dakin 1966; Danforth
1995; Gerolymatos 2002; Gounaris 1996; Karakasidou 1997; Kofos 1964; Koliopoulos 2003;
Livanios 1999; Michailidis 2003; Panaiotov 1946; Perry 1988; Wilkinson 1951. Specifically for
educational issues, see Vouri 1992, 1994, and 2005.
Why the Balkans? 61

to the Aegean Sea) Austria-Hungary and Russia were the main Powers directly
caught up in the Balkans.48 At that juncture, Great Britain viewed the preser-
vation of the Ottoman Empire as the best way to ensure unmitigated access to
India and Egypt and thus strived for its independence and territorial
integrity.49
After the Russo-Turkish War and the Treaty of San Stefano (1878), all of the
Great Powers got directly involved in the “solution” to the Eastern Question.
The Berlin Conference convened by Bismarck ensured that the new Bulgarian
Principality would be much smaller than the one described in the San Stefano
Treaty and that it would have no access to the Aegean Sea (see Map 3.1).
Following the Berlin Treaty (1878), Bulgaria became an autonomous princi-
pality. Austria-Hungary occupied Bosnia and Herzegovina and put guards at the
Sanjak of Novi Pazar (then part of the Kosova vilayet). Three years later, Greece
peacefully annexed Thessaly, and the same year Romania, Serbia, and
Montenegro formally achieved their independence (1881). Seven years later
the Bulgarian principality caught the Ottoman Empire by surprise and annexed
Eastern Rumelia (1885).
These boundary changes left the Ottoman Empire with a relatively small but
geopolitically important area in the Balkan Peninsula. Broadly speaking, this
region coincided with the geographic regions of Epirus, Macedonia, and
Thrace.50 Epirus was important for Italy in its quest to control the Adriatic.
Geographic Macedonia was a passageway of important trade routes, had the
“largest and most protected harbor of the northern Aegean Sea
[Thessaloniki],” and large fertile plains.51 Thrace was vital for the protection
of Istanbul and control of the Straits. More importantly, access to the Aegean
for both Serbia and Bulgaria, and indirectly Russia, would require the annex-
ation of parts of southern Macedonia or Thrace.
With some Christian Balkan states already established, the Great Powers
had to negotiate and form alliances in order to pursue their respective agen-
das. The old argument of helping the local Christians in their struggle against
the Muslims was no longer as convincing. The Russians wanted access to the
Aegean, but Britain wanted to prevent such access. Austria-Hungary and Italy
wanted to create an as-large-as-possible Albanian state in order to check
Serbian and Greek expansion in the region. The Greek-Ottoman War of
1897, which ended with the defeat of Greece and a certain boost for the
Ottoman Empire, was yet another instance of Greek irredentism in action, a
failed effort to emulate the successful Bulgarian annexation of Eastern
Rumelia a decade earlier.52

48
Jelavich 1991.
49
For perceptive analyses of the Eastern Question by Marx and Engels, see Kondylis 1985.
50
The vilayets of Shkodër, Kosova, Janina, Monastır, Selanik, and Edirne.
51
Kostanick 1948: 6.
52
Giannoulopoulos 1999.
Bucharest
Craiova
Negotin Constanta

Glunglu
Kragujevac (Gyurgevo)
Zajecar Vidin Silistra

Ruse
Lom
ia
gar
Kruševac Svishtov

ul
fB
Niš Berkovitsa Pleven Varna
o
ality Veliko Tamovo
Vratsa Lovech Shumen
Pirot
nci p
Dimitrovgrad
Pri Troyan Gabrovo

ea
Priština (Tsaribrod)
Vranje

ck S
Sofia Kamobat
(Vranya) Sliven

Yambol Burgas
Kyustendil
a

Bl a
eti
Samokov Pazardzhik Stara Zagora

Ru m
Kumanovo
Plovdiv
EasternHaskovo
Skopje
Kocani Gorna Dzhumaya
Veles (Blagoevgrad)
Kardzhali
Melnik
Durres Edime
(Drach) Strumica (Odrin)
Ohrid Bitola
Drama
(Bitolya) Kilkis Xanthi
Edessa (Kukush)
Senes Kavala Komotini Istanbul
Flórina (Voden) (Tsarigrad)
(Syar) (Gyumyurdzhina)
Korçë Kastoriá (Lerin)
(Kostur)
Thessaloniki
(Solun)

Bulgaria after
Liberated Bulgaria (1878). the Treaty of San Stefano
Principality of Bulgaria (autonomous)
Treaty of San Stefano and Congress of Berlin.
Eastern Rumelia (Ottoman province)
Macedonia (Ottoman )

map 3.1. Origins of Bulgarian revisionism. Available at: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Treaty_of_San_Stefano.


Why the Balkans? 63

illustration 3.2. Eight members of the Ottoman cavalry on horseback with


flags. Source: Library of Congress Prints and Photographs Division, Washington, D.C.

The Ottoman Empire was in the midst of the Young Turk Revolution when
Bulgaria declared its independence (1908);53 subsequently, Austria-Hungary
annexed Bosnia, and Crete was on the threshold of unifying with the Greek
Kingdom. But the Ottoman Empire was almost completely pushed out of the
Balkan Peninsula with the Balkan Wars.54 After a war with the Ottoman Empire
in 1911, the Italians claimed and occupied the Ottoman provinces of
Tripolitania and Cyrenaica as well as the Dodecanese (see Illustration 3.2).
That same year the Russian Empire advised Serbia and Bulgaria – its two
quasi-protectorates in the region – to reach an agreement on their respective
claims in Macedonia and attack the Ottoman Empire.55 Once this was accom-
plished, Russia managed to convince Greece to enter the conflict on their side.
With the Tripolitania War in the background, a successful Albanian revolt
followed by Ottoman atrocities in the spring of 1912 provided an opportunity
for Montenegro to declare war on the Ottoman Empire and then Serbia,

53
For more on the Young Turks, see Hanioğlu 2001.
54
The First Balkan War involved Serbia, Bulgaria, Greece, and Montenegro against the Ottoman
Empire, 1912–1913. The Second Balkan War involved Bulgaria against (mainly) Greece and
Serbia, 1913.
55
Mijatovich 1917: 235.
64 Empirical Evidence

Bulgaria, and Greece to follow suit.56 The first Balkan War was an attempt by
these states to solve the last phase of the Eastern Question by military conquest.
Bulgaria hoped to achieve the borders described in the Treaty of St. Stefano;
Serbia was dissatisfied by the incorporation of Slav-majority territories by
Austria-Hungary57 and claimed parts of geographic Macedonia;58 Greece, for
its part, was pursuing the Megali Idea (Great Idea) of turning the Aegean Sea into
a “Greek lake” (see Map 3.2).
The Ottoman Empire lost the war and was forced to sign a peace treaty on
30 May 1913, with the four Christian states. This marked the end of more than
four centuries of Ottoman rule over these territories. The Greek Army entered
Thessaloniki on 26 October/8 November 1912,59 just a few hours before the
Bulgarian troops did (see Illustration 3.3). This military success, which took
place within the context of the first Balkan War, was the culmination of the
prolonged and multifaceted competition between Greece and Bulgaria (and to a
lesser extent Serbia) over the European parts of the Ottoman Empire.
Bulgaria, however, was not content with the proposed terms in the peace
negotiations held in London after the First Balkan War, and fought the Second
Balkan War against Greece and Serbia.60 It was eventually defeated. With the
Treaty of Bucharest (July 1913), Greece incorporated Crete, a part of Epirus,
southern Macedonia, and the eastern Aegean islands – though not yet finally;
Bulgaria incorporated Western Thrace and northeastern Macedonia but had to
cede Eastern Thrace back to the Ottoman Empire; Serbia incorporated Kosovo
and northwestern Macedonia.61 However, this delimitation of frontiers never
satisfied all sides equally.
In the early twentieth century, and especially during the Balkan Wars, we
observe a drastic intensification of nation-building policies in the newly
annexed territories by five belligerent peoples: Serbs, Greeks, Bulgarians,
Montenegrins, and Ottomans. Serbs pursued exclusionary policies against
Albanians in Kosovo, Bulgarians against Greeks in Eastern Macedonia, and
Greeks against Bulgarians in Central Macedonia.62 During the Balkan Wars, all
Christian Balkan nations pursued exclusionary policies to a certain extent

56
According to a memorandum written by the Central Department of the Foreign Office, “the actual
pretext [for the first BalkanWar] was the demand of the Balkan League for the enforcement of
article 23 of the Treaty of Berlin, which . . . had remained a dead letter.” BNA, FO 371/14317
[C5316,/82/7] “The Origins of the Macedonian Revolutionary Organization and its History since
the Great War,” 1 July 1930, p. 7.
57
The annexation of these territories to Serbia would entail access to the Adriatic Sea.
58
This would guarantee Serbian access to the Aegean Sea.
59
Julian and Gregorian calendar date respectively.
60
The Serbs did not respect the secret agreement with respect to the claims on Macedonia and
Austria-Hungary encouraged the Bulgarians to antagonize Russian interests and fight Serbia and
Greece. For a vivid description of this period, see Mijatovich 1917: 236–241.
61
For a detailed history of the diplomatic affairs, see Helmreich 1938, Psomiades 1968; for the
military events of the period, see Gerolymatos 2002, General Staff of the Army 1940; finally, for
the relationship between external dependence and internal politics, see Leon 1974.
62
Kennan 1993.
map 3.2. Competing national aspirations in the Balkans, 1912. Source: Report of the International Commission to Inquire into the Causes
and Conduct of the Balkan Wars, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 1914. www.CarnegieEndowment.org.
66 Empirical Evidence

illu stration 3.3. Greek infantry officers. Source: Library of Congress Prints and
Photographs Division, Washington, D.C.

against Muslims. According to estimates, somewhere between 15,000 to 41,000


Muslims (noncombatants) either fled or lost their lives in Greek Macedonia
alone.63
During the early twentieth century, Bulgaria received refugees from various
parts of geographic Macedonia, Thrace, and Dobrudja.64 Following World War
I, Greece received refugees from Asia Minor, the Black Sea, the Caucasus, South
Russia, Bulgaria, and various parts of geographic Macedonia. Turkey received
refugees from all over the Balkans.65 Albania received refugees from Kosovo and
Greece. Romania and the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes both
expanded to include most of their ethnic kin and thus received a much smaller
numbers of refugees.
By the time of the Balkan Wars, the various national programs had already
crystallized and internal nation-building intensified.66 The alliance pattern of the
Second Balkan War was preserved during World War I. This fact – which could
have been otherwise – solidified these cleavages. Before we turn to the cross-
national analysis of nation-building policies in Chapter 4, it is important to

63
Glavinas 2008: 13.
64
According to the secretary of the Macedonian National Committee of Sofia, in 1934, there were in
Bulgaria 480,000 refugees. FO 371/18370, R6757, 24/11/1934. Cited in Livanios 2008: 35.
65
See Pallis 1925; McCarthy 1995. In my estimates I am not including the refugees from Bulgaria
following the 1878 war or the refugees from 1881.
66
Carabott 1997; Gounaris 2005; Karakasidou 1997; Michailidis 1998 and 2003.
Why the Balkans? 67

provide the reader with a brief sketch of the situation in all of the countries under
study.

the balkan states following world war i

The “Defeated”
The “Sick Man of Europe,”67 the Ottoman Empire, had sided with the Central
Powers68 and collapsed after the end of World War I. The Empire had been
gradually transforming into the modern Turkish republic during this time.69
A revisionist Turkish National Movement emerged from the ashes of the
Ottoman Empire with Mustafa Kemal as its leader.70 On 23 April 1920, an
assembly gathered and made Mustafa Kemal its first president and Ismet Inönü
Chief of General Staff. Kemal assumed full governmental powers and estab-
lished the Turkish Parliament (Grand National Assembly) in Ankara in May of
the same year. He was the national hero and leader of the Turks during the
interwar period. Mustafa Kemal secularized and westernized Turkey.
The other defeated power in the Balkans was Bulgaria, which entered
World War I on the side of the Central Powers in an effort to undo the
unfavorable outcome of the Second Balkan War. By the end of the Great War
it had lost yet another war. In the postwar environment, however, it needed a
leader who had opposed the Central Powers. It found such a leader in
Aleksander Stamboliiski, a man who was arrested for his anti-German stance
during World War I. The same motivation lay behind King Ferdinand’s abdica-
tion in favor of his son Boris. In the summer of 1919, Stamboliiski emerged from
hiding and won the national election by a small margin. His Peasant Party was
devoted to advancing peasant interests. He was in power for four years. During
his rule, he enacted extensive land reform, reformed the legal system, signed the
Treaty of Neuilly, and tried to form an alliance with the Kingdom of Serbs,
Croats, and Slovenes, though to no avail. Stamboliiski’s diplomatic efforts
turned the Internal Macedonian Revolutionary Organization (IMRO)71

67
This term, referring to the state of the Ottoman Empire during the mid-nineteenth century, first
appeared in print in an 1860 New York Times article and was attributed to Czar Nicholas I of
Russia; see “Austria in Extremis,” New York Times, 12 May 1860, p. 4.
68
The Central Powers in World War I consisted of the German, Austrian-Hungarian, and Ottoman
Empires and Bulgaria.
69
For more on this transformation in Turkey, see Findley 2010; Kasaba 2008; Zürcher 2004.
70
Mustafa Kemal Atatürk (1881–1938) was an Ottoman army officer and the founder of the
Republic of Turkey. For more on Kemal, see Mango 1999.
71
The Macedonian Revolutionary Organization, as it was initially named, was founded in 1893 by
Slav Macedonians in Thessaloniki initially claiming autonomy for the vilayets of Kosova, Selanik,
and Monastir. A few years after its establishment the organization was captured by Bulgarian
nationalists and was renamed IMRO following World War I; see Kofos 1964; Mylonas and Shelef
2012; Perry 1988.
68 Empirical Evidence

and the Slav Macedonian refugees from Serbia and Greece against him. IMRO
supporters ultimately assassinated him.

The “Victors”
Romania entered the war on the side of the Allies late. Marghiloman’s pro-
German government gave way to Brǎtianu’s pro-Entente Liberals toward the
end of World War I.72 Bratianu resigned and Aleksandar Vaida-Voevod took
over when the former was dissatisfied with the post-War settlement that
Romania was getting. King Ferdinand of Romania dismissed Vaida because
he was planning to collaborate with the Peasant Party. The King chose
Marshal Averescu as a successor. Averescu, a war hero, won elections and
subsequently pushed for an extensive land reform, particularly in Bessarabia.
In 1922, the Liberals, who dominated Romanian politics until 1928, suc-
ceeded Averescu. Having incorporated Transylvania, Bukovina, and
Bessarabia the Kingdom of Romania was now in favor of the international
status quo.
Another victor was Greece. Greece was literally divided over whom to side
with in World War I.73 Finally, Greece – reunified – was on the side of the Allies
after 1917. Venizelos’s Liberal Party was in power until the end of 1920. There
was an interim of Anti-Venizelist rule by the Popular Party, which collapsed
after the Asia Minor Catastrophe in 1922. A Venizelist coup replaced the
previous government and executed those held responsible for the military
defeat.74
The creation of the Kingdom of the Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes resulted from
the victory of the Allies in World War I and the consequent collapse of Austria-
Hungary and the Ottoman Empire. The kingdom’s unification took place under
the Serbian Karadjordjević dynasty in 1918 and was recognized by the Paris
Peace Conference in May 1919. The new state, on the side of the winners in
World War I, was in favor of the international status quo. The Serbian elites,
especially Pašić and his Radical Party, dominated the political scene. This was a
radical party that was based on the Serbian middle class and the peasantry.
As Protić put it, “[the party’s] commitment to constitutionalism, the middle-class
background of its leadership and a class alliance affirmed in its programme made
it a party of the centre. Its emphasis on democracy, its struggle for social justice
and its socialist roots made it a party of the left.”75

72
The Entente powers in World War I consisted (mainly) of Great Britain, France, Italy, and the
United States. The Russian Empire, Belgium, Serbia, Canada, Australia, Italy, Romania, and
Greece also fought on this side.
73
Mavrogordatos 1983.
74
See discussion in Chapter 6. For more on this, see Leon 1974; Mavrogordatos 1982.
75
For a more detailed account, see Protić 2007: 189. For more on the politics in the KSCS, see the
relevant section in Chapter 7.
Why the Balkans? 69

A Bystander
Prince William of Wied76 was nominally at the helm of the Principality of
Albania at the outbreak of World War I77 and fought as an individual on the
side of the Central Powers. Albania, however, was neutral in World War
I. Albania remained a geographical concept during World War I that both
sides of the conflict occupied. Early in World War I, Greece, Italy, Serbia, and
Montenegro occupied most of Albania, which according to the secret Treaty of
London (May 1915) was to be dismembered after the war with only a small
autonomous state surviving in central Albania. Early in 1916 the Central Powers
prevailed in the region, with Austria-Hungary and Bulgaria taking control over
Albania. Toward the end of 1916, Entente powers, especially the Italians,
occupied significant parts of southern Albania. By the end of the war Italian,
Greek, French, and Serbian troops were on Albanian soil. These powers wanted
to partition Albania, but the American president Woodrow Wilson successfully
opposed their plans. As a result of the peculiar situation Albania was in – with a
prince who had fought on the side of the Central Powers and a territory under
occupation during most of the War – the Albanians were not officially repre-
sented in the Paris Peace Conference in 1919.78 In 1920, Albanians drove out the
Italian troops and received international recognition. However, their border
concerns were not resolved until 1923.79
The Albanian system of government following World War I was based on a
council of regents and a bicameral parliament. The actual power lay with
powerful individuals (heads of various Albanian tribes).80 As Fischer put it,
“the system, as it worked out in practice, was a combination of the principality
constructed by the Great Powers in 1912 and traditional tribal autocracy.”81 As
expected, such a system was vulnerable to manipulation by neighboring states.
A liberal government gave way to a populist one.
The state was in disarray until Ahmed Zogolli82 gained power in the mid-
1920s with Yugoslav support.83 For most of the interwar period, Albania’s elites

76
Prince William of Wied (1876–1945), whose actual name was Wilhelm Friedrich Heinrich, was a
Lutheran Prince born in Neuwied, Germany.
77
The Prince ruled from 7 March 1914 to 3 September 1914. His reign officially ended on 31
January 1925, when Albania was declared a Republic. However, he never really exercised power
since the Entente powers would not allow someone who fought against them in the war to rule
over Albania. For more, see Heaton-Armstrong 2005.
78
Kola 2003: 18–19.
79
For more information on this period, see Chapter 5.
80
Zickel and Iwaskiw 1994.
81
2007: 25.
82
Ahmet Zogolli (1895–1961) was the most influential political figure in interwar Albania. Before
becoming Prime Minister in 1924 he held various influential positions including that of Minister
of Interior (1921–1924). He was Prime Minister (1922–1924) and President of Albania (1925–
1928). He was also King of the Albanians from 1928 to 1939, when Mussolini ousted him. For
more on King Zog, as he was later called, and this period, see Fischer 2007: 19–49.
83
For more on this period, see Chapter 7.
70 Empirical Evidence

were driven by revisionist foreign policy goals. The main focus of their energies
was the mobilization of Kosovo Albanians more so than those living in Tetovo.
As we will see in Chapter 7, Zog rather quickly forgot about the Yugoslav
support and turned Albania into a vassal state of Italy.
All in all, the Balkan states following World War I meet my scope conditions.
Their ruling political elites represented well-defined core groups, part of the
population in each country was not assimilated, and all of the states had
the capacity to impose direct rule over their territory – with Albania being the
weakest in this respect. Up to this point I have introduced the region and justified
the case selection; let me now turn to the empirical test of my theory.
4

Cross-National Variation
Nation-Building in Post–World War I Balkans

Analyzing nation-building policies toward non-core groups across Balkan states


following World War I reveals strong support for my argument. Non-core
groups supported by enemy powers and residing in states that favored the
international status quo were most likely to be targeted with assimilationist
policies. Exclusion was most likely for the non-core groups supported by exter-
nal enemies, but which resided in states dominated by revisionist politics.
Finally, non-core groups supported by allied powers were most likely to be
accommodated.
Group size and the presence of a homeland did not significantly affect states’
nation-building strategies in the post–World War I Balkans. A difference in
language and world religion between the non-core and core groups in a state
made accommodation of the non-core group more likely than assimilation, but
such differences do not help predict policy choices between exclusion and
assimilation. The latter finding is rather surprising considering the well-
established millet system and national historiographies that emphasize the role
of religion in the nation-building process. Finally, whether a non-core group had
been previously dominant does not seem to be a good predictor of nation-
building policies. For instance, this finding implies that Christian states in the
Balkans were not more likely to target Muslims, the previously dominant group
of the Ottoman Empire, with exclusionary policies after World War I – when
controlling for my argument.1 These findings qualify both status reversal and
cultural distance arguments.
This chapter should not be read in isolation from the rest of the book. It
summarizes multiple individual cases in a systematic manner but is no substitute
for the archival detail of Chapter 6 or the dynamic narrative in Chapter 7. In
what follows, first, I describe my research design, the data, and the operation-
alization of the variables. In the next section, I present the results from my

1
To be sure, exclusionary policies against the Muslim population were pursued during the nine-
teenth century Balkan rebellions as well as during the Balkan Wars but even after World War I a
large number of Muslims lived in the Balkan Peninsula (Glavinas 2008; McCarthy 1995).

71
72 Empirical Evidence

analysis and consider the explanatory power of domestic and international level
factors I could not test statistically.

research design: operationalization


and measurement
I test my theory of nation-building against alternative explanations on a dataset
I have compiled on ninety non-core groups in post–World War I Balkans. My
universe of cases includes all ethnic groups, which were perceived as unassimi-
lated by the ruling political elites, that resided within the recognized boundaries
of national Balkan states and satisfy my scope conditions. Indeed, elites aiming
at securing the national loyalty of the population of their country ruled in all
nation-states under study. Importantly, there were plenty of non-assimilated
non-core groups in every country and ruling elites had a clear definition of the
core group in their minds.
The combination of secondary sources, archival material, and exchanges with
experts allowed me to identify and document ninety non-core groups in the six
Balkan states after World War I.2 All my independent variables presented below
were coded for 1918 or earlier in order to guarantee exogeneity to the nation-
building policies pursued by governments after the war.3

The Dependent Variable: Nation-Building Policies


For each country under study, I identify all groups perceived as non-core groups
by the various governing elites in the Balkans at the end of World War I (T0).
When ruling political elites accommodate a non-core group, I assign the value
“0”; when they pursue assimilationist policies I assign the value “1”; finally,
when they adopt exclusionary measures, I assign the value “2.” For this cross-
national test I assume that the policies pursued toward non-core groups are a
reliable indicator for coding state intentions. In the rest of the empirical chapters,
I rely on archival material, confidential reports of governmental officials, and
relevant legislation in order to identify and analytically distinguish between state
intentions and pursued policies.
A problem I faced while coding these cases was the presence of mixed policies
where, for example, part of a group was targeted with assimilationist policies
while the majority was excluded (or vice versa). To address this problem in the
statistical analysis, I necessarily simplified the picture and focused on the

2
For a discussion of this difficult task and the caveats involved in this process, see Appendix A: The
Politics of “Counting People.”
3
For more, see the Codebook in the Methodological Appendix. The coding of these variables is
based on archival material as well as extensive secondary sources listed in a special section of my
bibliography. I also conducted a coding reliability test with regional experts in Southeastern
Europe. I describe this process and the problems associated with it in the Methodological
Appendix.
Cross-National Variation 73

“dominant” policy. I call a policy dominant when it is employed with respect to


at least 80 percent of the non-core group. Thus, if a country targets 81 percent of
a non-core group with assimilationist policies and 19 percent with exclusionary
policies, I infer that the “dominant” policy of the government toward that group
was assimilation. I hold that this threshold is sufficiently high to capture the
state’s intentions. The difficulty lies in distinguishing between cases where the
mixed policy is either the result of principal-agent and local implementation
problems or the result of a state intentionally pursuing a “mixed policy.”4

Independent Variables
Most of my explanatory factors (language, religion, urban/rural location, group
size) were relatively easy to code. The terms “Revisionist host state” and non-
core group “supported by external enemy” as well as “homeland” deserve
further attention. I code a non-core group as “externally supported” when the
host state has proof or is otherwise convinced that the group’s leaders are
logistically and/or diplomatically supported by an external power and as “not
externally supported” otherwise.5 This coding is not capturing the non-core
group member’s subjective preferences; rather it is more attuned to the percep-
tions of the ruling political elites of each state with regard to the matter. This
emphasis of my argument in the role of perceptions is the reason that I am not
coding for the intensity or type of external support. Besides, with the exception
of overt military intervention that is easy to code, most external involvement
takes place secretly. Thus, this asymmetry of information forces governments to
err on the safe side when they have reasons to doubt the loyalty of a group.
Similarly, I code a non-core group as “supported by ally” when the external
power perceived as supporting a group is in the same international alliance bloc
or the countries are in a bilateral alliance. I refer to a non-core group as “enemy
supported” if the external power perceived as supporting that group is in
competition with the host state (i.e., a power belonging to the enemy alliance
bloc during World War I).
For the purposes of the statistical test conducted in this chapter, the relation-
ship between the external power and the non-core group must have originated
during World War I or immediately afterward. Similarly, within the post–World
War I Balkan context I code a host state as “revisionist” if it lost territory in
World War I, and as “status quo” otherwise. To test for the special case
(depicted in Figure 2.6) where two contiguous states have non-core groups
that are co-ethnics of the two countries, respectively, I construct a variable

4
In Chapters 5 to 8, I consider genuine “mixed policies.” In fact my argument predicts such cases.
Although I decided to not include this category in my statistical analysis here, I am working on a
paper conducting a statistical analysis where “mixed policy” is included as a separate category
from assimilation, accommodation, and exclusion.
5
For brevity I will use the term “external support” in the text to refer to the “perception of external
support by the host state.”
74 Empirical Evidence

assigning the value “1” if a non-core group is supported by an external patron


that has a non-core group of the host country within its territory, “0” otherwise.
I now turn to the operationalization of the variables derived from the existing
literature that I can test for in the Balkan context. I code a non-core group as
having a “homeland” if both the non-core group elites and the “kin state”
recognize a relationship of ethnic kinship, “no homeland” otherwise. This is
not always an easy task. This coding problem is related to a problem inherent in
the logic of this argument. In particular, although it sounds unlikely that “the
nationalizing state’s preferences” over the treatment of a non-core group can
produce a homeland, it is not impossible. For example, a country can sign a
treaty or make a concession that allows another country to conduct nation-
building (i.e., mobilize the non-core group and cultivate its national awareness)
within the former’s territory. As a result of this arrangement, we might get a non-
core group that comes to identify with this country and thus comes to have an
external homeland. For example, the treaty of Bucharest in 1913 provided
Romania with such a nation-building opportunity across the Balkans.
The argument that governments may be harsh on secessionist groups for
reputational reasons is operationalized in the following way. I assign the value
“0” to a country if there is less than one large, territorially concentrated seces-
sionist non-core group, and the value “1” if there are more.
To operationalize cultural distance one has to discern whether a group of
people is different from the dominant definition of the nation, the “national
type” (with respect to, e.g., language, religion, race), and study the statements of
the ruling political elites of the state. Criteria for membership in a nation,
however, do change in response to territorial or demographic changes. Very
careful process tracing is the only way to make sure that the relevant definition of
the nation has been in place before the incorporation of the new territory or non-
core group, and that the definition did not shift as a consequence of this change.
The “status reversal” hypothesis is relatively easy to operationalize. I code a
non-core group as having experienced a status reversal if they were included in
the definition of the dominant group prior to the period of study, but are no
longer included during the period under study.
I have also constructed three measures of non-core group size, the percentage
of total population and two dummies, one capturing whether the group is above
1 percent and another for groups above 5 percent of the total population.
Finally, I attempt to capture residential patterns and organizational character-
istics with the variable “urban” coded as “1” if the non-core group was primar-
ily urban, “0” otherwise.

analysis

Patterns: Descriptive Statistics


Despite the fact that World War I was fought based on the principles of
nationalism, the region was still ethnically heterogeneous at the end of the
Cross-National Variation 75

Exclusion

Accommodation

Assimilation

43% Accommodation 47% Assimilation


10% Exclusion

graph 4.1. Nation-building policies in post–World War I Balkans, 1918–1923.

war. Looking at the distribution of nation-building policies, we see that contrary


to present day perceptions about the Balkans, the most common strategy toward
non-core groups in the immediate period following World War I was assimila-
tion (see Graph 4.1). Forty-seven percent of the non-core groups were targeted
with assimilationist policies, while only 10 percent were subject to exclusionary
ones; the remaining percentage was accommodated. Most of the literature
focuses on this 10 percent, and neglects the remaining 90 percent of the cases.
However, a theory of nation-building has to be able to explain both violent and
non-violent policies.
The above patterns characterize the post–World War I Balkans. The
descriptive statistics of another period would look different. In particular,
before the Balkan Wars, assimilation was much more prevalent whereas exclu-
sionary policies were ubiquitous during the Balkan Wars and World War
I. This pattern is consistent with my theory. In the nineteenth century, prior
to the Balkan Wars, the various Balkan nation-states did not border each other,
and external interference amongst them was less prominent. As a result, exclu-
sionary policies within Balkan states were very infrequent.6 Right before the
Balkan Wars, during the Macedonian Struggle in 1903–1908,7 states escalated
their support for non-core groups residing in contested territories, resulting in

6
Prominent exceptions involve the Ottoman reactions to the various secessionist movements that
were externally supported. This dynamic is also consistent with my argument.
7
For more, see Gounaris 2005; Livanios 1999; Perry 1988.
76 Empirical Evidence

table 4.1. Descriptive Statistics

Variable Observations Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

Policy 90 0.66 0.65 0 2


Revisionist 90 0.43 0.49 0 1
External enemy 90 0.26 0.44 0 1
Status 90 0.15 0.36 0 1
Homeland 90 0.47 0.50 0 1
Urban 90 0.32 0.46 0 1
World religion 90 0.3 0.46 0 1
Religion 90 0.61 0.49 0 1
Language 90 0.74 0.43 0 1
Contiguous 90 0.28 0.45 0 1
Reputation 90 0.56 0.49 0 1
Primarily urban 90 0.67 0.46 0 1
Population in 1918 90 2.62 3.81 0.03 23.77

an increase in exclusionary policies. It was during the Balkan Wars, however,


that we observe the most violent policies vividly described in the Carnegie
Report.8
Turning to my main explanatory variables, 74 percent of the groups in my
analysis spoke a different language and more than half, 61 percent, had a
different religious denomination from the core group. The average size of a
non-core group was around 2.6 percent of the total population, with the
smallest group being 0.03 percent and the largest 23.77 percent. Only one
third of the groups were primarily urban and around half had an external
homeland. Finally, one quarter of the non-core groups in my analysis were
supported by an enemy state while 43percent lived in revisionist states (see
Table 4.1).9
The different variables I have discussed are assumed to operate cumulatively,
thus multivariate statistical analysis is the best way to capture the effects of these
factors on nation-building policy choices. Yet since the number of non-core
groups is small relatively to the number of variables, it is useful to examine the
bivariate relationships through cross-tabulations first and then turn to the
analysis of the multinomial logit regression results.
One third of the non-core groups that had a different language from the core
group of their host state were targeted with assimilationist policies (see
Table 4.2.i). Certainly, groups with a different language were more likely to be
excluded or accommodated than groups sharing a principal language with the

8
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace 1914.
9
These are the non-core groups living in Bulgaria, Turkey, and Albania.
Cross-National Variation 77

table 4.2.i. Language

Policy Same Different Total

Accommodation 3 (13%) 36 (54%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 19 (83%) 23 (34%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 1 (4%) 8 (12%) 9 (10%)
Total 23 (100%) 67 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 16.0809 Pr = 0.

table 4.2.ii. Religious Denomination

Policy Same Different Total

Accommodation 8 (23%) 31 (56%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 26 (74%) 16 (29%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 1 (3%) 8 (14%) 9 (10%)
Total 35 (100%) 55 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2(2) = 17. 2538 Pr = 0.

core group, but the fact that one third of them were targeted with assimilationist
policies contradicts cultural distance arguments. Not surprisingly – from the
conventional point of view, non-core groups that shared a common language
with the core group were more often targeted with assimilationist policies than
with accommodation or exclusion.
As shown in Table 4.2.ii, non-core groups that had the same religion10 as the
core group were targeted more often with assimilationist policies than with
accommodation or exclusion. Non-core groups of different religious denomina-
tions were more likely to be accommodated than targeted with assimilation or
exclusion. However, contrary to the predictions of primordialist arguments, 16
non-core groups (29%) with a different religion were targeted with assimila-
tionist policies. This pattern is surprising for the Balkans, where religion has
traditionally been such a salient cleavage.
We do find some support for the cultural distance logic when we look at
exclusionary policies. Non-core groups with a different religion were more likely
to be excluded by the core group. Fifteen percent of the non-core groups with a
different religion faced exclusion compared with 3 percent of the non-core
groups with the same religion. Nevertheless, this effect is mitigated when we
look at the breakdown by world religion.

10
This variable captures differences within world religions as well. For example, Christian
Orthodox loyal to the Ecumenical Patriarchate in Istanbul, Christian Orthodox loyal to the
Bulgarian Exarchate, Christian Catholic, etc.
78 Empirical Evidence

table 4.2.iii. World Religion

Policy Same Different Total

Accommodation 24 (38%) 15 (56%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 33 (53%) 9 (33%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 6 (9%) 3 (11%) 9 (10%)
Total 63 (100%) 27 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 2.8467 Pr = 0.241.

table 4.2.iv. Non-Core Group Primarily Urban

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 20 (33%) 19 (65%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 36 (59%) 6 (21%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 5 (8%) 4 (14%) 9 (10%)
Total 61 (100%) 29 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 11.6618 Pr = 0.003.

Conducting a cross-tabulation with “world religion,”11 rather than religious


denomination, as the breakdown category we see in Table 4.2.iii that the
relationship between religion and policy choice is statistically insignificant.
Non-core groups were almost equally likely to be targeted with exclusionary
policies whether or not they were members of the same world religion as the core
group. This empirical record directly contradicts cultural distance arguments,
implying that there must be some other process that accounts for the variation in
nation-building policies. All in all, cultural distance theories overpredict exclu-
sionary policies and preclude the possibility of accommodation. But both assim-
ilation and accommodation are very common.
Looking at Table 4.2.iv, we see that primarily urban non-core groups were
three times less likely to be targeted with assimilationist policies than others. In
fact they were two times more likely to be accommodated. This empirical pattern
is consistent with the logic of my argument about non-core groups that live in
peripheries of a host state. The latter are more likely than other groups to be (or
become) targets for national agitation and/or support by external powers, lead-
ing ruling political elites to – sometimes even preemptively – pursue assimila-
tionist policies. Exclusionary policies were almost equally likely, but ruling
political elites were more likely to accommodate primarily urban groups.
Again this is consistent with my argument’s logic that it is easier for external
enforcers of minority rights to monitor the fate of urban non-core groups.

11
Muslim, Christian, Jewish.
Cross-National Variation 79

table 4.2.v. Nomadic Non-Core Group

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 33 (43%) 6 (46%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 37 (48%) 5 (39%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 7 (9%) 2 (15%) 9 (10%)
Total 77 (100%) 13 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 0.6877 Pr = 0.709.

table 4.2.vi. Rural Non-Core Group

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 32 (58%) 7 (20%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 17 (31%) 25 (71%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 6 (11%) 3 (9%) 9 (10%)
Total 55 (100%) 35 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 14.8377 Pr = 0.001.

In Table 4.2.v, we see that the relationship between nation-building policies


and whether a non-core group is nomadic or not is not statistically significant.
Nevertheless, looking at the descriptive statistics we see that almost half of the
nomadic non-core groups were accommodated. This pattern might be capturing
the difficulty involved with targeting nomadic groups with assimilationist poli-
cies or the fact that these groups were not threatening to states, as they were
small, unconnected to any specific territory,12 and as such less likely to be
externally supported.
Rural non-core groups were more likely to be targeted with assimilationist
policies than other types of non-core groups (see Table 4.2.vi). The logic here is
that a group residing in rural areas is a better target for an external power since
state control of rural areas is harder to maintain than control of urban centers.13
Accommodation was more prevalent for non-core groups that were not rural,
confirming the intuitions of my argument.
Looking at Table 4.2.vii, we see that non-core groups that used to be part of
the once dominant group are two times more likely to be excluded by the host
state than non-core groups that were not dominant in the past. This is consistent
with the status reversal logic. However, we also see that previously dominant
non-core groups were accommodated by the host state in 57 percent of the cases.

12
Toft 2003.
13
Kocher 2004.
80 Empirical Evidence

table 4.2.vii. Non-Core Group Has Experienced Status Reversal

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 31 (41%) 8 (57%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 39 (51%) 3 (21.5%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 6 (8%) 3 (21.5%) 9 (10%)
Total 76 (100%) 14 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 5.1579 Pr = 0.076.

table 4.2.viii. Non-Core Group Has a Homeland

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 15 (32%) 24 (56%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 29 (62%) 13 (30%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 3 (6%) 6 (14%) 9 (10%)
Total 47 (100%) 43 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 9.0122 Pr = 0.011.

For example, the Greek government’s choice of accommodation as a policy


toward Muslims after World War I contradicts the status reversal logic.
Looking at the tabulation in Table 4.2.viii, we see that non-core groups with a
homeland were more likely to be accommodated than those who lacked one.
Consistently with Brubaker’s work, groups without a homeland were most likely
to be targeted with assimilationist policies. These policy choices are also consistent
with my argument: Groups with no external support are targeted for assimilation
in order to immunize the population from future propaganda. Interestingly, 13
non-core groups that had a homeland (30%) were nevertheless targeted with
assimilationist policies. The homeland argument circulating in the literature would
be hard-pressed to explain this pattern since, according to this argument, non-core
groups with a homeland are not expected to be targeted with assimilationist policies.
Turning to non-core group size, according to Table 4.2.ix, there is no differ-
ence in a host state’s nation-building policies whether a non-core group is larger
than 1 percent of the total population of the host state or not. Small groups were
as likely to be accommodated as groups larger than 1 percent. Non-core groups
larger than 1 percent were slightly more likely to be targeted with exclusionary
policies than smaller groups. This pattern is consistent with the security logic
that underlies my argument since a larger group is more likely to be mobilized by
an external power and the host state is more likely to perceive it as threatening.
Using a higher percentage produces, again, a statistically insignificant rela-
tionship. According to Table 4.2.x, a non-core group being larger than 5 percent
Cross-National Variation 81

table. 4.2.ix. Non-Core Group Larger Than 1% of the Total Population

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 17 (46%) 22 (42%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 17 (46%) 25 (47%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 3 (8%) 6 (11%) 9 (10%)
Total 37 (100%) 53 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 0.3308 Pr = 0.848.

table. 4.2.x. Non-Core Group Larger Than 5% of the Total Population

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 30 (40%) 9 (60%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 38 (51%) 4 (27%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 7 (9%) 2 (13%) 9 (10%)
Total 75 (100%) 15 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 2.8967 Pr = 0.235.

of the total population of the host state does not have a statistically significant
impact on the choice of nation-building policies. Groups larger than 5 percent of
the total population were a little more likely to be accommodated than groups
smaller than 5 percent. Non-core groups larger than 5 percent were less likely to
be targeted with assimilationist policies than smaller groups but were almost
equally likely to be targeted with exclusionist policies.14 Overall, these patterns
contradict several demographic arguments and put into question the convention
of the 1 percent threshold in data collection that currently dominates the quan-
titative research in political science.15
Turning to my main explanatory variables, in Table 4.2.xi, we see that
non-core groups that had no external support were never targeted with exclu-
sion. Non-core groups that had external support were targeted with exclusion
in 19 percent of the cases; a high percentage, given how rare exclusionary
policies are overall. Consistent with Configuration I, assimilation was more
likely for non-core groups without external support – 77 percent compared
with 19 percent for groups with external support. Nevertheless, the ten cases
of accommodation for non-core groups that did not have external support
require further research. Are these outliers due to the relative cost of assimilation
compared to the cost of accommodation? Are they capturing a “marginality”

14
In the regression analysis I use a continuous measure of group size instead of a dichotomous
coding of groups as larger or smaller than 1 or 5% of the total population.
15
For more, see the section “The Politics of ‘Counting People’” in the Methodological Appendix.
82 Empirical Evidence

table 4.2.xi. Configuration I: External Support

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 10 (23%) 29 (62%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 33 (77%) 9 (19%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 0 (0%) 9 (19%) 9 (10%)
Total 43 (100%) 47 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 31.8558 Pr = 0.

table 4.2.xii. Configuration II: External Support by Allied Power

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 18 (26%) 21 (95%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 42 (62%) 0 (0%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 8 (12%) 1 (5%) 9 (10%)
Total 68 (100%) 22 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 32.7088 Pr = 0.

dynamic,16 according to which a group is accommodated because it has valuable


economic skills that are linked to its cultural distinctiveness? Is this an Ottoman
legacy? I pursue this inquiry in Chapter 5.
As expected, non-core groups supported by allies of the host state were almost
always accommodated (see Table 4.2.xii). In particular, a non-core group sup-
ported by an ally was accommodated in 95 percent of the observations but one
that was not supported but an ally was accommodated only in 26 percent of the
cases. Importantly, a non-core group supported by an ally was never targeted
with assimilationist policies. Also consistent with Configuration II, non-core
groups not supported by allies were almost three times more likely to be targeted
with exclusion than non-core groups that were supported by allied powers.17
Non-core groups supported by external enemies of the host state were
20 times more likely to be targeted with exclusionist policies than groups
without enemy support (see Table 4.2.xiii). A non-core group supported by an
enemy power was excluded in one third of the observations but one that was not
supported by an enemy power was excluded only in one case (1.5%).18
Consistent with my argument, non-core groups not supported by enemy states

16
Laitin 1995.
17
I should note here that all groups that have “no external support” are also included in the category
of “no ally support” and this probably explains the high percentage assimilation in that column.
18
I pursue this outlier – Greeks in the KSCS – in Chapter 5.
Cross-National Variation 83

table 4.2.xiii. External Support by Enemy Power

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 32 (48.5%) 7 (29%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 33 (50%) 9 (38%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 1 (1.5%) 8 (33%) 9 (10%)
Total 66 (100%) 24 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 19.9232 Pr = 0.

table 4.2.xiv. Host State Foreign Policy Goals

Policy Status Quo Revisionist Total

Accommodation 27 (53%) 12 (31%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 22 (43%) 20 (51%) 42 (42%)
Exclusion 2 (4%) 7 (18%) 9 (10%)
Total 51 (100%) 39 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (2) = 7.1697 Pr = 0.028.

were almost two times more likely to be targeted with accommodation than non-
core groups that were supported by enemy powers.19
Turning to Table 4.2.xiv, we observe that non-core groups residing in
revisionist host states were almost five times more likely to be excluded than
groups living in status quo states. Moreover, we see that assimilation was
slightly more likely in revisionist states than in status quo states. This may be
partly due to the fact that revisionist states were more likely to have received
refugees – which they definitely intended to assimilate – since they lost terri-
tories in World War I. Nevertheless, as my argument suggests, to understand
this distribution more fully we need to focus on the nature of the external
support that these non-core groups enjoyed together with the foreign policy
goals of their host states.
Most of the non-core groups in my dataset were either residing in status quo
states, supported by allied powers, or had no external support at all (80 out of 90
non-core groups; see Table 4.2.xv). However, 10 groups were supported by an
enemy power and lived in revisionist host states. In such circumstances my
theory predicts exclusion. Indeed, consistent with Configuration III, from
Table 4.2.xv, we see that 70 percent of these groups were excluded.

19
Again, I should note here that under the category of groups that have “no external support by
enemy power” both cases of “no enemy support” and of “allied support” are included. This
explains to a large extent the high number of cases of assimilation in that column.
84 Empirical Evidence

table 4.2.xv. Configuration III: Exclusion of Enemy-Supported Group in


Revisionist State

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 38 (47.5%) 1 (10%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 40 (50%) 2 (20%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 2 (2.5%) 7 (70%) 9 (10%)
Total 80 (100%) 10 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2(2) = 45.0989 Pr = 0.

table 4.2.xvi. Configuration IV: Group Supported by Enemy in Status Quo State

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 33 (44%) 6 (40%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 34 (45%) 8 (53%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 8 (11%) 1 (7%) 9 (10%)
Total 75 (100%) 15 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2(2) = 0.4176 Pr = 0.812.

Only fifteen out of the ninety non-core groups in my dataset were residing in
status quo host states and were supported by enemy powers (see Table 4.2.xvi).
Consistent with Configuration IV, more than half of these non-core groups were
targeted with assimilationist policies. However, the relationship does not come
up as statistically significant. Primarily this has to do with the six non-core
groups that were supported by an enemy power and lived in status quo host
states that were accommodated instead of being targeted with colonization or
other intense assimilationist policies. I discuss these outliers in Chapter 5.
Turning to the special case where the host state and the external power are
contiguous and have each other’s co-ethnics we see that exclusion is nine times
more likely than in other cases (Table 4.2.xvii). Thus there is important evidence in
favor of this hypothesis. This is capturing the population exchange dynamic that
occured in such instances.20 Regardless, accommodation was the most common
policy within this special category. This may be capturing a strategy of accom-
modating a non-core group in fear of retaliation on your co-ethnics abroad.21
In Table 4.2.xviii, there appears to be a relationship between states that face
multiple secessionist non-core groups and nation-building policies. According to
the cross-tabulation, governments that faced more than one secessionist group

20
Eberhardt 2003.
21
Divani 1995; Mavrogordatos 2003.
Cross-National Variation 85

table 4.2.xvii. Host State and External Power Contiguous and Have Co-Ethnics

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 28 (44%) 11 (42%) 39 (45%)


Assimilation 34 (53%) 8 (31%) 42 (44%)
Exclusion 2 (3%) 7 (27%) 9 (10%)
Total 64 (100%) 26 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2(2) = 12.4601 Pr = 0.002.

table 4.2.xviii. Host State Faces More Than One Secessionist Non-Core Group

Policy No Yes Total

Accommodation 12 (31%) 27 (53%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 17 (51%) 22 (43%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 7 (18%) 2 (4%) 9 (10%)
Total 39 (100%) 51 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2(2) = 7.1697 Pr = 0.028.

did not use exclusionary policies more than governments that faced just one or no
such groups. In particular, governments that faced one or no such groups were four
times more likely to use exclusionary policies. Given this operationalization, the
pattern contradicts the logic of the reputation argument. To be fair, this may not be
the best test for this argument. In order to test it correctly we would need more
archival evidence mapping out the logic behind the various policies.
Before I turn to the regression results, it is useful to look at a simple cross-
tabulation of my theory predictions and the actual policies pursued toward the non-
core groups in my analysis (Table 4.2.xix). Overall, my argument correctly predicts
81 percent of the cases (73 out of 90 observations in the dataset). Assimilationist
policies are correctly predicted in 41 out of 55 cases (75%). In most incorrectly
predicted cases, my theory indicates assimilation but the non-core groups
were granted minority rights instead. Exclusionary policies are also correctly
predicted in seven out of the nine cases (78%). My theory fares even better with
respect to accommodationist policies, correctly predicting 96 percent of the cases,
all but one. I pursue an analysis of the incorrectly predicted cases in Chapter 5.

Explaining Variation in Nation-Building Policies


While the cross-tabulations and statistical significance tests are useful for iden-
tifying strong relationships between variables, they are not allowing us to isolate
86 Empirical Evidence

table 4.2.xix. Correctly Predicted

Predicted Policy

Actual Policy Accommodation Assimilation Exclusion Total

Accommodation 25 (96%) 13 (23%) 1 (11%) 39 (43%)


Assimilation 0 (0%) 41 (75%) 1 (11%) 42 (47%)
Exclusion 1 (4%) 1 (2%) 7 (78%) 9 (10%)
Total 26 (100%) 55 (100%) 9 (100%) 90 (100%)

Pearson χ2 (4) = 93.5632 Pr = 0.

the effect of each one of the variables of interest in a multivariate context. In this
section I attempt to achieve this through a multinomial logit regression and a
series of simulations.
Given the case selection and the regional character of the data, a few impor-
tant existing explanations are controlled for.22 For example, there is very little
variation in the modernization levels, the geopolitical context, the norms sur-
rounding the treatment of minorities, the level of political development, and the
understandings of nationhood across the states included in my analysis. As
described in Chapter 3, all nation-states in the Balkans were mostly agricultural
societies whose ruling political elites were motivated by a homogenizing imper-
ative. Moreover, Balkan states were at comparable levels of political develop-
ment and shared the Ottoman legacy.
Beyond these commonalities there was a great deal of heterogeneity within
the Balkans that the dataset I have compiled attempts to capture. Using this
dataset we are able to test a few group-level hypotheses such as the impact of
cultural distance (measuring differences in language and religion), the effect of
having an external homeland or not, a version of the status reversal argument,
the importance of being an urban group as opposed to a rural or a nomadic one,
and the impact of group size on the choice of nation-building policies.23 The
model specification that I used is depicted in Figure 4.1.
The results from the multinomial logit regression confirm my intuitions.24
Non-core groups that are supported by enemy external powers are less likely to

22
Still, there is no doubt that my model specification has omitted variable bias. This bias is in the
error term of my model specification. Some variables of importance that I was not able to code
include the personalities of leaders, political ideologies, and the impact of public opinion. I discuss
these explanations at the end of this chapter and in the other empirical chapters.
23
A correlation table of the variables shows that none are correlated above 0.45.
24
A fundamental assumption underlying the multinomial logit is the independence of irrelevant
alternatives (Hausman and McFadden 1984; Ray 1973). In my case this means that I assume the
following: If assimilationist policies are preferred to accommodation with respect to a non-core
group, then introducing the alternative strategy of exclusion will not make accommodation
preferred to assimilationist policies. Nevertheless, I also ran a multinomial probit regression,
which does not rely on this assumption, and the results were practically the same.
Cross-National Variation 87

Model 1

assimilation
Nation-building policy accommodation =
exclusion
β0 + β1 [Host State Revisionist] + β2 [Non-Core group Supported by Enemy] + β3 [Status
Reversal] + β4 [External Homeland] + β5 [Primarily Urban] + β6 [World Religion] + β7
[Language] + β8 [Group Size] + ε

Model 2

assimilation
Nation-building policy accommodation =
exclusion
β0 + β1 [Host State Revisionist] + β2 [Non-Core group Supported by Enemy] + β3 [Status
Reversal] + β4 [External Homeland] + β5 [Primarily Urban] + β6 [World Religion] + β7
[Language] + β8 [Contiguous] + β9 [Group Size] + ε

figure 4.1. Multinomial logit models.

be accommodated than targeted with assimilation (Model 1 in Table 4.3).


Similar non-core groups are more likely to be excluded by ruling political elites
of revisionist host states than targeted with assimilation. Whether a non-core
group has an external homeland does not have any statistically significant
impact on nation-building choices. Whether a non-core group was previously
dominant does not appear to have an impact in deciding between policies – at
least in the post–World War I period. Clearly strategic considerations that my
argument highlights were important in this decisionmaking process.
Before I discuss the impact of demographic and cultural characteristics of
non-core groups, let me discuss the special case where the host state and the
external power are contiguous and have each other’s co-ethnics. Contiguous
states sharing co-ethnics are more likely to pursue exclusionary policies than
assimilationist policies toward their non-core groups when at least one of them is
perceived as actively supporting its co-ethnics in the near abroad (Model 2 in
Table 4.3). However, this variable is not helping us account for variation when
we are looking at the choice between accommodation and assimilation. The rest
of the results hold up with one exception.25

25
In particular, whether a non-core group resides in a revisionist host state or not ceases to be
statistically significant when deciding between exclusion and assimilation. This is probably due to
the fact that much of the explanatory power of the “revisionist” variable is absorbed by the
“contiguous” variable.
88 Empirical Evidence

table 4.3. Multinomial Logit Estimates for Nation-Building Policies in Post–


World War I Balkans

Model 1 Accommodation Exclusion

Variable
Revisionist Host State −1.11 2.25
Group Supported by Enemy −2.04 3.85
Status Reversal 0.47 0.37
External Homeland 0.97 −0.4
Primarily Urban 1.45 1.37
World Religion 1.7 0.47
Language 2.42 0.74
Non-core Group % 0.08 −0.03
_constant −2.6 −6
Comparison Group: Assimilation

Model 2
Variable
Revisionist Host State −1.13 1.22
Group Supported by Enemy −2.26 4.17
Status Reversal .44 3.19
External Homeland 1.2 −1.01
Primarily Urban 1.3 3.04
World Religion 1.07 2.18
Language 2.48 −2.22
Contiguous −.31 5.25
Non-core Group % .1 −.5
_constant −2.6 −6.41
Comparison Group: Assimilation

Results are log ratios. They signify the log ratio between the Probability of Accommodation/
Probability of Assimilation in the first column and the log ratio between the Probability of Exclusion/
Probability of Assimilation in the second column. For example, looking at whether a non-core group
is supported by an enemy power we find that a one-unit change decreases the log ratio of the Pr
(accommodation)/Pr(assimilation) by 2.04.
Bold signifies 10% significance level. Bold and italics signifies 5% significance level.
Number of Obs. = 90; LR Chi-Squared (16) = 63.38; Prob>Chi-Sq. = 0; Pseudo R-Sq. = .37.

Turning to demographic and cultural characteristics, we observe that group


size, measured as percentage of the total population, does not help us distin-
guish amongst nation-building policies. Primarily urban non-core groups were
more likely to be accommodated than targeted with assimilationist policies.
I also ran a model including a “territorial concentration” variable that came up
Cross-National Variation 89

as statistically insignificant and thus do not present these results here. This
finding may be due to measurement error since data on non-core groups’
territorial concentrations were not easy to collect for that period.26
Having a different world religion than the core group increases the likelihood
of accommodation compared with assimilation; however, quite surprisingly for
the Balkans, it does not have an impact when comparing exclusionary to
assimilationist policies.27 Similarly, having a different language than the core
group increases the likelihood of accommodation compared to assimilation,
although it does not have any effect when comparing exclusion and assimilation.
In the next chapter, I take a closer look at the outliers of this analysis including
cases of culturally different groups that were accommodated, trying to discern
whether they were accommodated for reasons that are consistent with my theory
or with the cultural distance argument.

Simulations
To demonstrate my findings in a more straightforward way than the presenta-
tion of regression coefficients, I employ Clarify.28 I run simulations changing just
my two principal explanatory variables, interstate relations between the host
state and the external power supporting a non-core group and a host state’s
foreign policy goals, holding all other variables to their mean values. In
Tables 4.4, 4.5, and 4.6, I report the mean predicted probabilities for each
nation-building policy as my two main explanatory factors vary.
Consistent with my theory, assimilation is most likely for non-core groups
supported by enemy powers and residing in status quo host states (mean prob-
ability 0.60). Accommodation has the highest mean probability (0.66) for non-
core groups that are supported by allied powers – or do not have any external
support – and reside in states that favor the international status quo. In contrast,
non-core groups that are supported by enemy powers and live in revisionist host
states face a zero mean probability of being accommodated. Finally, exclusion is
most likely for non-core groups supported by enemies in host states dominated
by revisionist politics (mean probability 0.68). Again the mean probability of a
non-core group that is not supported by an enemy external power to be targeted
with exclusionary policies is practically zero. These findings confirm my intu-
itions and nicely illustrate the substantive effects of the variables of interest while
controlling for a host of variables.

26
The rest of the results remain the same with one exception. The homeland argument is now
statistically significant, suggesting that a non-core group that has a homeland is more likely to be
accommodated than assimilated. The variable “homeland” remains statistically insignificant in
distinguishing between the policies of exclusion and assimilation.
27
Running a model including “religious denomination” instead of “world religion” does not signifi-
cantly change the results. The main difference is that “revisionist state” and “primarily urban” are
not as statistically significant in distinguishing between accommodation and assimilation.
28
Clarify is a program developed by King, Tomz, and Wittenberg (2000) that uses stochastic
simulation techniques to help researchers interpret statistical results. See also Tomz et al. 2003.
90 Empirical Evidence

table 4.4. Probability of Assimilation

Non-Core Group

External Support Not Supported


by Enemy Power by Enemy Powera

Host State Revisionist 0.28 0.56


(0.07−59) (0.32−78)
Status quo 0.60 0.33
(0.28−87) (0.17−54)

a
Includes non-core groups with external support from ally as well as groups with no external
support.

table 4.5. Probability of Accommodation

Non-Core Group

External Support Not Supported


by Enemy Power by Enemy Power

Host State Revisionist 0.03 0.38


(0.0−11) (0.17−63)
Status quo 0.18 0.66
(0.4−42) (45−82)

table 4.6. Probability of Exclusion

Non-Core Group

External Support Not Supported


by Enemy Power by Enemy Power

Host State Revisionist 0.68 0.05


(0.35−92) (0−21)
Status quo 0.21 0
(0.3−60) (0−03)
Cross-National Variation 91

issues of causal inference

Direction of Causality
Despite my treatment of the problem of endogeneity from a theoretical stand-
point in Chapter 2, there may still be concerns with respect to the direction of
causality. One might argue that the pattern of alliances in the Balkans during
World War I was actually caused by the nation-building policies of neighbor-
ing states rather than causally preceding them. Host states may have chosen
which side to take in the Great War based on concerns related to the treatment
of non-core groups in neighboring countries. However, this is not the case.
Mijatovich, for instance, informs us that the British believed up to the last
moment “that Bulgaria could be won.”29 But, Bulgaria fought on the side of
the Central powers in the end mainly because it was still bitter from the out-
come of the Balkan Wars, not because of the policies that Greece or Serbia
pursued toward Bulgarians in these places. Ιn a confidential memorandum on
the “macedonian question” written long after the war was over, in 1930, the
Central Department of the British Foreign Office clearly states that “[n]or is it
surprising that the Bulgarians should sympathize with and perhaps greatly
exaggerate the sufferings of, the Bulgarophone population of Macedonia” and
goes on to highlight the geostrategic considerations of the various Balkan states
as the primary source of animosity and mistrust between these states.30
According to the memorandum, the Bulgarian government was disgruntled
and blamed particularly Great Britain for not supporting her against the Turks
in the second Balkan War; “this made her [Bulgaria] ready to turn to Germany
and influenced her in 1915 when she seized the chance to revenge herself on
Serbia, hoping to regain Macedonia, of which she considered she had been
unjustly defrauded.”31
Based on the historical record, in the case of the Balkan states under study
here, the choice of allies was an outcome of a combination of calculations about
who is going to win and strategic considerations concerning which side will
provide more territory (after the war) and support (during the war) in return for
the alliance, not of nation-building policies of neighboring states. For example,
during the late nineteenth century Russia supported Bulgaria’s claims in
Macedonia to the detriment of Serbia and for that period Austrian influence in
Serbia prevailed. However, as we will see in Chapter 6, by 1913 this picture had
been completely reversed. Now Serbia was supported by Russia and Bulgaria
was closer to Austria-Hungary.32

29
1917: 243.
30
BNA, FO 371/14317 [C5316,/82/7] “The Origins of the Macedonian Revolutionary
Organization and its History since the Great War,” 1 July 1930, p. 12.
31
Ibid., 8.
32
Mijatovich 1917: 244–245.
92 Empirical Evidence

Regime Type, Ideologies, Core Group Size, and the League of Nations
But what was the effect of the political system and the ideological predispositions
of the various governments in question? Such factors were difficult to incorpo-
rate into the quantitative analysis, but nonetheless bear on the present discus-
sion. For instance, it could be the case that variation in nation-building policies is
explained by the ideological differences of the ruling political elites across the six
states under study rather than by the strategic logic I am proposing.
The foreign policy orientation variable in my model specification is certainly
country-specific, taking a value based on whether a given state was on the side of
the “victors” in World War I or not. Although this variable is, as we have seen,
an important country-specific determinant of the nation-building intentions of
ruling elites, it may be capturing other factors such as the content of political
ideologies of the ruling elites or the effect of regime type. Below I take a closer
look at regime type, political deologies, core group size, and the role of the
League of Nations following World War II in all the six states under study in an
attempt to evaluate whether any of these factors can account for the variation in
nation-building policies across non-core groups.

Regime Type and Political Ideologies


Could the political ideologies of each state and the differences in regime type
account for the variation in nation-building policies? Looking at Table 4.7 we
see that, consistent with my argument, states that were on the losing side in
World War I were much more likely to use exclusionary policies, whereas states
that were on the winning side were more likely to follow accommodationist
policies. The occurrence of assimilationist policies was more or less equal for
both groups of countries.
Most of the Balkan states had some form of representative government.
Turkey and Albania were still engaged in fighting for their territorial
borders the first years after World War I, but Greece – a winner in World
War I – was also engaged in the territorial conflicts. Moreover, neither
Albania nor Turkey had a king following World War I. But Greece only
nominally had a king until 1920, when Venizelos lost the elections. All
of the states under study had a Western orientation and pursued moderniza-
tion policies albeit with different degrees of success. Most governing parties
were motivated by either liberal or popular political ideologies. But there
does not seem to be a systematic state level pattern linking political ideology
with nation-building policies within the post–World War I Balkans.33 Most

33
It is of course possible that arguments focusing on political ideologies may account for variation
across regions or over time. For an argument focusing on domestic political processes – with an
emphasis on ideologies – and a different conceptualization of “Regimes of Ethnicity” ranging
from “mono-ethnic, to multi-ethnic, to non/anti-ethnic regimes,” see Akturk 2007 and 2011.
For an argument linking Liberalism to a specific type of treatment of non-core groups, see
Joppke 2005.
table 4.7. Domestic Politics and Nation-Building Policies, c. 1918–1924

Core Group % of
Country Population Total Pop.a Ruling Party # of Groups Assimilation Accommodation Exclusion

Albania 825,000 86 Liberal/ Popular 7 4 (9.5%) 3 (8%) 0 (0%)


Bulgaria 4,500,000 70 Agrarian 16 5 (12%) 7 (18%) 4 (44%)
Greece 5,500,000 65 Liberal/ Popular 16 7 (17%) 8 (20.5%) 1 (11%)
KSCS 14,798,000 38 Radical 19 10 (24%) 9 (20.5%) 1 (11%)
Romania 16,250,000 56 Peasant/ Liberal 16 5 (12%) 11 (28%) 0
Turkey 13,000,000 50 Republican 16 11 (26%) 2 (5%) 3 (33%)

a
Not including the refugees from the Balkan Wars and World War I.
94 Empirical Evidence

likely security and national interest considerations trumped any impact


that the various political ideologies may have had on the treatment of non-
core groups. All in all, a pattern does not appear to emerge from these country
level differences.

Core Group Size


What if the size of the core group in each of these Balkan states is causally related
to the nation-building policies pursued in each case? Kaufmann and Haklai, for
example, suggest that dominant minorities are having a hard time legitimizing
their rule.34 Following this logic, the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes
(KSCS) could be viewed as such a case since the Serbs – the largest group – in
1918 did not form more than 38 percent of the total population. If one takes the
regime’s declarations at face value, then Serbo-Croats – a linguistic category –
constituted an absolute majority with 63 percent of the total population.35 In the
statistical analysis, I treat the Serbs as the core group and include the Croats and
the Slovenes as non-core groups. Given such a small core group size accommo-
dation may have been an overdetermined outcome. For instance, one of my
outliers, the Slovenes in the KSCS, had both a different language and religion
from the Serbs, were territorially concentrated, and resided in the periphery of
the KSCS. These factors together with the small percentage of the core group in
the KSCS may have precluded assimilationist policies in this case. However, we
see that the KSCS did not pursue accommodationist policies more often than
Bulgaria and Greece did, both countries with demographically large core
groups.
Albania also stands out since its core group was comprised of Albanian
speakers of Muslim, Christian Orthodox and Catholic faiths. Nevertheless,
most scholars studying the Albanian case use language as the most important
marker and suggest that the core group was approximately 86 percent of the
total population.36 Ironically, the very construction of the core group in Albania
in a way that overcomes religious cleavages serves as a counterargument to
several versions of the cultural distance argument.
All in all, core group size does not appear to explain the cross-national
variation in nation-building policies any better than regime type or political
ideology, although it definitely matters in multiple other ways.

International Norms, the League of Nations, and Minority Treaties


Before concluding this chapter, it is important to note that the system that
resulted from World War I was obliging small nations and only the defeated
Great Powers to respect the rights of national minorities – or racial, linguistic,
and religious minorities as the treaties called them to avoid defining the term

34
2008.
35
Banac 1984:58.
36
Clayer 2008: 128–129; Great Britain, Foreign Office 1920; Marmullaku 1975; Skendi 1967.
Cross-National Variation 95

“nationality.”37 Moreover, the establishment of the League of Nations influ-


enced the incentive structure for both non-core groups and nation-states. For
example, revisionist states tried to use the League of Nations to avoid the
assimilation of their co-ethnics abroad and destabilize enemy states.38 States
that were satisfied with the status quo tried to preserve it by assimilating most
non-core groups – except the ones supported by allied powers – within their
territory before revisionist powers undermined this process or attempted to alter
the borders. These dynamics are consistent with the general logic of my
argument.
Finney writes, “[T]hese states were weak and insecure, and feared that
toleration would perpetuate the existence of distinct, aloof and alienated groups
whose allegiances were deeply suspect; hence they were reluctant to treat the
minorities generously.”39 According to Finney, the principle of self-
determination had explosive consequences and was the main flaw of the
World War I peace settlement. The emphasis that the Allies put on this principle –
at least rhetorically – led most states to either deny the existence of minorities
within their borders or to resort to repressive measures in order to prevent the
development of secessionist movements.
The consensus in the literature is that the League of Nations despite its initial
optimism and limited success could not and did not enforce the World War I
treaties.40 The victors of the war believed that the system of minority protec-
tion put in place by the League of Nations would initially accommodate the
differences of certain non-core groups so that they could in the near future
assimilate into their core societies. However, the minority protection regime
constituted a perverse incentive structure undermining this – primarily British –
expectation of assimilation. Overall, this system did not significantly impact
the policy intentions of Balkan states but it may have influenced the form many
policies took.

conclusion
From the study of post–World War I Balkans certain patterns emerge. Outside
support for non-core groups had an effect on the nation-building policies that
host states pursued. Whether a non-core group is perceived to be externally
supported or not and the interstate competition between the host state and the
external power are important variables when we try to account for nation-
building policies. Contiguous states that share co-ethnics were more likely to
pursue exclusionary policies than non-contiguous states or states without each
other’s co-ethnics. Urban non-core groups with a different language and/or

37
Azcárate 1945: 3; Mazower 1997 and 2009.
38
Divani 1995: 36.
39
1995: 536.
40
Azcárate 1945; Barros 1970; Divani 1995; Mazower 2009.
96 Empirical Evidence

religion from the core group were more likely to be accommodated than
assimilated.
Admittedly, my theory does not perfectly predict all of the Balkan cases.
There are some incorrect predictions (19% of the cases).41 In Chapter 5
I discuss the outliers of my statistical analysis. Chapters 6 and 7 provide a
subnational and a temporal test of my theory in different regions of the
Balkans. However, even though my argument does very well in explaining
variation in the early twentieth-century Balkans, such success does not neces-
sarily imply that it can travel across space or time. In Chapter 8, I focus on the
generalizability of the argument and look at cases beyond the interwar Balkans
including Cold War Asia and post–Cold War Estonia in order to address these
challenges.

41
See Table 5.1.
5

Odd Cases
Analysis of Outliers

Why did the Turkish state initially accommodate the Jews of Istanbul only to
target them with assimilationist policies in the late 1920s? Why did the Greek
state accommodate the Muslims in Northen Greece following World War I
only to oblige them to move to Turkey after 1923? How come the Romanian
state accommodated the enemy-backed Hungarian minority rather than follow
intense assimilationist policies as my argument predicts? Why did revisionist
Albanian elites not target the Greek-backed communities in the south of their
country with exclusionary policies but rather accommodated them? What
accounts for the accommodation of most Eastern European Jewish commu-
nities immediately after World War I? Why were they not targeted with
assimilationist policies as my theory predicts? Why were the Bulgarian-backed
Slav Macedonians in status quo Greek Macedonia targeted with exclusionary
policies rather than intense assimilationist ones? These and some more puzzles
emerge from the incorrectly predicted cases from Chapter 4’s statistical ana-
lysis (see Table 5.1).
Examination of these outliers reveals a few pertinent issues: the sensitivity of
results to the time horizon of the study, the presence of mixed policies that
undermine scholars’ efforts to classify them, the distinction between nation-
building policies that are terminal versus those that are transitional and actually
have a different ultimate goal, as well as the role of external powers’ foreign
policy priorities and how symmetrical alliances are in the decision making
process of host states. I also identify a divide-and-rule strategy that Balkan
governments pursued both to fragment large groups and to prevent subnational
assimilation of small non-core groups to larger ones. I discuss all of these issues
in separate sections directly addressing each case but also using other examples
from the twentieth-century Balkans.

time horizon
The time horizon of an analysis affects the conclusions we draw from it. Many
existing works in political science evade this important issue. Hypotheses are

97
98 Empirical Evidence

table 5.1. Incorrect Predictions

Non-Core Group Larger


Country Group Than 1% Prediction Policy

Albania Greeks Yes Exclusion Accommodation


Montenegrins/ No Exclusion Assimilation
Serbs
Bulgaria Gypsies Yes Assimilation Accommodation
Jews No Assimilation Accommodation
Greece Jews, Yes Assimilation Accommodation
Sephardim
Muslims Yes Assimilation Accommodation
(Turks)
Pomaks No Assimilation Accommodation
Slavs, Yes Assimilation Exclusion
“Bulgarian
leaning”
Romania Germans Yes Assimilation Accommodation
Hungarians Yes Assimilation Accommodation
Jews Yes Assimilation Accommodation
The Kingdom of Germans Yes Assimilation Accommodation
Serbs, Croats
and Slovenes
Greeks No Accommodation Exclusion
Hungarians Yes Assimilation Accommodation
Slovenes Yes Assimilation Accommodation
Jews No Assimilation Accommodation
Turkey Jews No Assimilation Accommodation

tested in specific places and historical instances but sometimes processes take
time to unfold. How can one decide the appropriate time horizon for testing
certain hypotheses? Is it a year, a decade, or a generation? These are difficult but
pertinent questions in the social sciences.
The short answer is that the appropriate time horizon for testing hypotheses
depends on the phenomenon under study. If we want to test a theory about the
rate of assimilation, then the appropriate time horizon is probably a generation
or more. If our research question concerns the rate of acculturation – the
acquisition of certain traits by a specific group – then a decade might be enough.
Similarly, in the study of state-planned nation-building policies the time horizon
depends on the aspect of the process on which we focus. If our aim is to under-
stand policy choices by the ruling political elites of a state, our efforts should
focus on the period of policy planning immediately after a critical event such as
an annexation, a war, or a regime change. However, if our aim is to evaluate
which nation-building policies are successful and under what circumstances,
then we would have to allow for several decades to pass.
Odd Cases: Analysis of Outliers 99

In this book I seek to identify the logic of state-planned nation-building


policies toward non-core groups across states and over time. The research
strategy I followed in Chapter 4 was to look at state policies immediately after
World War I, an event that affected all societies in the region. This research
strategy works well in cases where the initial conditions that propelled the policy
do not change during the period of study. However, there are cases in my
analysis where the initial conditions change profoundly during the first five
years after the end of World War I.
For example, the Greek-Turkish War of 1919–1922 and the subsequent
Turkish victory had a significant effect on the nation-building policies of the
two states involved. In particular, whereas the Muslims in Northern Greece –
foremost candidates for agitation by Turkey – were more or less accommodated
until 1923, they became part of an obligatory population exchange thereafter.1
Depending on the time horizon of our analysis we would code this case differ-
ently. This shift was not because the Greek government just changed its mind but
rather because the values of important independent variables changed after
Greece’s defeat in the Greek-Turkish War.
Another example is that of the Jews in Turkey. According to my argument
the Jews in Turkey should have been targeted with assimilationist policies since
they did not enjoy the external support of any state and resided in a status quo
state. However, the Jews were initially accommodated. As a result, this case is
one of the outliers in my analysis. The first systematic effort for assimilation of
the Jews in Turkey did not begin until late into the 1920s. In this example, if
I had chosen a ten-year period for coding I would have coded the Jews in
Turkey as being targeted with assimilationist policies – which is consistent with
my prediction – but having chosen a five-year period I coded it as a case of
accommodation.
A similar situation emerges when we look at the policies toward the
“Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs in northern Greece (an enemy supported non-core
group in a status quo state).2 I predict assimilationist policies but code the case as
one of exclusion. Again, a change in the time horizon of the analysis would result
in different coding. This non-core group was initially targeted with assimilation-
ist policies. However, with the treaty of Neuilly a voluntary population
exchange led to the emigration of a significant part of this population to
Bulgaria between 1919 and 1924. By 1924, the number of people who had
emigrated was high enough to consider this a case of exclusion. But in 1919 or
1920, this was not the case and we would still code it as a case of assimilationist
policies.
The Greeks in Albania (a non-core group supported by a hostile state and
residing in a revisionist host state) should have been targeted with exclusionary

1
Clark 2006; Hirschon 2003; Ladas 1932; Pentzopoulos 1962; Yıldırım 2006.
2
I describe this category in more detail in Chapter 6. Eliakis referred to this group as Boulgarizontes,
I translate this term as “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs.
100 Empirical Evidence

policies according to my argument, but they were accommodated instead.


Albania was a new state whose existence was not guaranteed after the end of
World War I. Italy had been promised significant portions of Albania in order to
enter the war, Greece claimed the southern provinces, and the Serbs were
occupying territories bordering Kosovo. The Allies – with the exception of the
United States – were sympathetic to these plans. The Albanian reaction to these
partitioning plans was decisive.
Early in 1920 the pro-Italian government was overthrown and replaced by a
new government determined to secure the independence of Albania. At this point
the Albanian authorities put pressure on the Greek community to declare that
they preferred Albanian to Greek rule. According to the Greek General
Governor of Epirus, Achilleas Kalevras,
[B]eing in a helpless situation these Christians are obliged, in order not to be subjugated
by force, to flee their homes; thus the first significant exodus to the villages on our side of
the border.3

However, Albania – or better the ruling elites in the south of the country – shifted
from an enemy to an ally within a couple of days. In late May 1920, Prime
Minister Venizelos was waiting for the final approval from Britain before he
ordered the Greek military to annex southern Albanian territories –promised to
Greece by the Allies during the January talks of the same year. Southern Albania
had been under French administration up to that point. On 27 May 1920 the
British government advised Venizelos not to occupy these territories because
such an occupation would enrage the Albanians.4 According to Kontis, the
discovery of oil was the reason behind the British change of policy over
Albania.5 Considering that Venizelos was at that time negotiating for the
Dodecanese Islands and Thrace and fighting in Asia Minor it is understandable
that Greece was not in a position to occupy southern Albania without British
approval. A principle emerges from this case: The ally of my ally is my friend.
The main concern of the Albanians at the time was ousting the Italian troops
from Albanian soil. Albanians knew that Greece had military superiority and the
Greek government did use its leverage to secure rights for the Greek community.
In the absence of the British mediation and the consequent accord between
Greece and Albania, the enemy-supported Greek population would have been
left unprotected against the revisionist Albanian authorities and may have been
targeted with exclusionary measures.6
As a result of Greek diplomatic maneuvering, however, a protocol was indeed
signed on 28 May 1920 declaring friendly relations between Albania and Greece
and obligations on the Albanian side to respect the Greek population in Albania

3
AYE, 1920, A/5, no. 312, Achilleas Kalevras, General Governor of Epirus to Ministry of Foreign
Affairs, Ioannina, 28 March 1920 (quoted in Kontis 1994: 123).
4
Kontis 1994: 136.
5
1994: 137.
6
Ibid., p. 139.
Odd Cases: Analysis of Outliers 101

and allow the unobstructed operation of schools and churches.7 This sudden
change in diplomatic relations between the two countries surprised the Italian
consul in Ioannina who wrote to the Greek Governor-General of Epirus:
We Italians are surprised by the Albanian pro-Greek demonstration at a moment when
Greece has not given up her claims on Northern Epirus and has no interest in following a
bunch of foolish Albanians in their anti-Italian policy.8

On 5 June 1920, a few days after the Albanians began their fight against the
Italians, the Albanian government sent “a confidential circular announcing to
the local Albanian authorities that the relations with Greece were cordial and
that the Greek government was friendly.”9 The British intervention in favor of
Albania and Venizelos’s compliance prevented a military confrontation between
the two states. Acting as a Great Power, Britain was trying to include the new
Albanian state into its sphere of influence; thus, by extension, its allies would
become Albania’s allies.
To be sure, the balance of power between Greece and Albania also affected
the interstate relations between the two countries. For example, as soon as the
Albanians managed to successfully contain the Italians they also altered their
diplomatic approach toward Greece. The emerging international context under-
mined Greek claims in Albania. By August 1920 the Albanians signed a protocol
with the Italians that resulted in the latter withdrawing their troops from
Albania and recognizing its independence. As a result of this Italian-Albanian
reconciliation, the Albanians ended up refusing the validity of the Greek-
Albanian protocol signed in May 1920. By December 1920, Albania had
become a member of the League of Nations and in October 1921 its representa-
tive, Fan Noli, declared that his country would respect the rights of the Greek
population. It is worth noting, however, that the Albanian government recog-
nized a Greek minority only in the province of Argyrokastro (Gjirokastër) and
not outside of that area.
From the discussion of the above cases it becomes clear that the values of
crucial independent variables do not all change at the same time or with the same
pace for every observation. This problem can be addressed in the context of a
case study through meticulous process tracing; however, it is much harder to
resolve when we conduct a cross-national analysis. Often important explanatory
variables are not held constant over arbitrarily chosen periods of time. Five- or
ten-year period intervals are commonly used for testing hypotheses but they are
open to such problems. I address the problem of time horizons in this book by
combining the cross-national test in Chapter 4 with carefully selected case
studies in all other empirical chapters.

7
Ibid., p. 143.
8
AYE, 1920, A/5, no. 7122, Kalevras to Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Ioannina, 11 June 1920
(quoted in Kontis 1994: 145).
9
AYE, 1920, A/5, no. 7154, Kalevras to Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Ioannina, 10 June 1920
(quoted in Kontis 1994: 145).
102 Empirical Evidence

mixed policies
Another issue that stems from the analysis of the outliers is that ruling political
elites did not always apply policies uniformly to all the members of a non-core
group. Although non-uniform application of nation-building policies was
unusual, it did occur. In some cases, the application consisted of a strategy of
divide and rule, which I discuss separately in the last section of this chapter. In
other cases, variation in application was merely a function of capabilities and
military expedience.
The Slav Macedonians in Greek Macedonia (discussed as “Bulgarian leaning
Slavs” in Chapter 6) are a case of nonuniform application of nation-building
policies by the ruling political elites. The policies toward this non-core group
were harsher for those living close to the borders with Bulgaria, many of whom
were internally displaced.10 Moreover, young people were targeted with inten-
sive assimilationist policies while older ones were not. According to my theory,
“Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs in Greece should have been targeted with intense
assimilation policies and indeed they were for a couple of years before the
Treaty of Neuilly was signed (1919) and the voluntary population exchange
between Greece and Bulgaria began.
Archival research allowed me to study this case in depth. As I discuss in
Chapter 6, my theory correctly predicts the intentions of the Greek administra-
tion. “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs were supported by a revisionist enemy power
while the Greek administration wanted to preserve the international status quo
in Greek Macedonia. Consequently, assimilationist policies, taking the form of
colonization and internal displacement of the non-core group, were the pre-
ferred choice. After World War I, however, a voluntary population exchange
between Greece and Bulgaria under the treaty of Neuilly was decided upon by
the respective governments. As a result, about 56,000 Bulgarians left Greece for
Bulgaria, “in many cases being forced to emigrate by the Greek authorities.”11
However, the picture is complicated by IMRO’s efforts to discourage
“Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs from leaving in order to preserve Bulgarian territorial
claims in Greek Macedonia and further complicated by some voluntary depar-
tures to Bulgaria. Nevertheless, the members of the group who remained in
Greece continued to be targeted with assimilationist policies and were not
granted minority status. Thus, this case has elements of both exclusion and
assimilation.
This case highlights an important caveat for my argument. Governments may
intentionally follow mixed policies toward non-core groups. How often this is
the case is an empirical question. In my statistical analysis I necessarily simplified
the picture and focused on the “dominant” strategy. However, as the case of the
“Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs in Greece shows, the ruling political elites might

10
This is consistent with James Ron’s argument; see Ron 2003.
11
Michailidis 2005: 94.
Odd Cases: Analysis of Outliers 103

choose to follow a mixed strategy of assimilation toward one part of a non-core


group and exclusion of another part of the same group.
Turning to another of my outliers, the Hungarians in Romania, we see a
similar pattern. Coding this case was challenging, as the initial intentions of the
Romanian elites seemed to be rather assimilationist – if not exclusionary – in an
effort to “Romanize” Transylvania, but their consequent policies were accom-
modationist. Romanians granted minimal minority rights to the Hungarian
population that remained in Romanian Transylvania. Nevertheless, around
200,000 Hungarians from Transylvania fled to Hungary between 1918 and
1922, followed by another 170,000 over the remainder of the interwar period.12
But the majority of Hungarians stayed in Romania and their differences were
perpetuated through separate schools, associations, and their own political
party. The case of Hungarians in Romania again raises the issue of coding
policies based on an arbitrarily chosen threshold.
The threshold one sets in coding is crucial in such cases. Almost 23 percent of
the total population of Hungarians left Romanian Transylvania for Hungary
during the interwar period. Thus 77 percent of the Hungarians stayed in
Romania but 23 percent fled the nationalizing policies of the Romanian state.
If we set a coding threshold of 20 percent we could conclude that the Hungarians
were targeted with exclusionary policies. I set a higher threshold and thus code
this as a case of accommodation. Actually, the intentions of the Romanian
administration were – at least initially – assimilationist but the policies granted
minority rights to the Hungarians. Hungarians were discriminated against and
targeted with nationalizing policies but ultimately they were accommodated.
This was of course related to the treaties that Romania had signed after World
War I that required accommodation as a policy toward the Hungarians. This
international constraint definitely mattered. But at the same time as I show later
accommodation was a transitional policy, not a terminal one.13
Moving from Romania to the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes we find
another community of Hungarians. Again in this case we have a relatively large
group supported by an enemy state14 and living in a host state that wants to
preserve the international status quo. As Sajti put it, “Hungarian governments
never gave up hopes of securing a revision of the terms of the Treaty of Trianon,
although they were all too aware that the international climate for attaining that
was unfavourable.”15 Given that the newly-founded kingdom of the Serbs,
Croats, and Slovenes was on the side of the winners and wanted to preserve

12
Kovrig 2000: 34.
13
For more on this distinction, see the next section.
14
“In order to provide support for Hungarian communities outside the country’s borders, Bethlen
[Prime Minister of Hungary from 1921 to 1931] in 1921, established a supposedly secret ministry
to exercise political influence on those communities through an openly operating blanket organ-
isation called the Federation of Social Associations (TESZK), through which fairly generous
financial support was given to Hungarian political and cultural organisations in Slovakia,
Transylvania and the Voivodina” (Sajti 2006: 117).
15
2006: 116.
104 Empirical Evidence

the status quo, my argument predicts that the Hungarians should have been
targeted with assimilationist policies.
Indeed, after the annexation of Vojvodina to the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats
and Slovenes, primary and secondary level Hungarian-language schools were all
closed down.16 The extensive land reform implemented in the new Kingdom was
very much felt in Vojvodina as well. “[T]he avowed goal of such resettlements
was to populate the territories lying along the northern borders of Yugoslavia
with ‘reliable Slavs’ to offset the majority, the ‘unreliable Magyars.’”17
Nevertheless, the Hungarians of Vojvodina had their own party and cultural
associations, and some Hungarian-speaking schools reopened in the region. Sajti
provides an explanation of the public accommodation of Hungarians in the
interwar period:
The League of Nations mechanism for the protection of minorities may have offered some
safeguards of minority rights (elementary education in the mother tongue, etc.) and, as a
creation of the post-1918 European order, Yugoslavia18 was in no position to reject the
basic principles of the international regime for the protection of minorities that the
victorious Allies had established.19

But the Hungarian population living in Vojvodina was also targeted with an
extensive colonization campaign as well as some measures aiming at the nation-
alization of the economy and of the administration of the region. The Kingdom
of Yugoslavia, however, did not try to eradicate the cultural differences and way
of life of this non-core group. A mixed policy was pursued.
Although I extensively discussed the case of the Greeks in southern Albania
in the previous section, it also deserves treatment here. The Albanian govern-
ment’s policies toward the Greeks, during the Greek-Albanian dispute over
the delimitation of the territorial borders of Albania, were exclusionary. As
we have seen, however, as soon as the interstate relations between the two
countries changed, the policy shifted to one of accommodation. Notably,
when Fan Noli referred to the Greek population and its accommodation he
meant only the Greeks inhabiting a specific region in southern Albania. The
Albanian government tried to assimilate Greeks living outside the designated
area and accommodated only the ones concentrated within that area.
According to Kontis:

16
Ramet 2006: 51. As Sajti put it, “Hungarian civil servants and railwaymen were dismissed en
masse, the judiciary was replaced, and the Hungarian secondary school system was dismantled,
followed by the primary system. The nationalist character of the Yugoslav land reform, which
dragged on to the end of the 1930s, weakened the traditional Hungarian gentry class while doing
nothing to help the peasantry, who made up the bulk of the population in the Voivodina: landless
agricultural labourers of Hungarian ethnicity were not given any land” (2006: 112).
17
Sajti 2006: 112.
18
King Aleksandar changed the name of Kingdom of Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes into Kingdom of
Yugoslavia in the beginning of 1929. In an effort to avoid anachronisms, I use the appropriate
name for the period I am discussing.
19
Sajti 2006: 117.
Odd Cases: Analysis of Outliers 105

The Albanian government allowed the operation of Greek schools only in the areas where
the presence of a Greek population was officially recognized and prohibited Greek
language instruction in all other Albanian-speaking areas. . . . Concerning education, the
goal of the Albanians was to ban private education and to impose an absolute state
monopoly.20

These efforts were not limited to the educational establishments of the Greek
community but extended to its religious organization as well. Albanian nation-
alists tried to establish an Autocephalous Christian Orthodox Church of Albania
in order to prevent either the Greek-dominated Ecumenical Patriarchate in
Istanbul or the Autocephalous Orthodox Church of Greece from interfering in
the domestic politics of Albania.21 The attempts to assimilate the Greek popula-
tion, though largely unsuccessful, were indicative of the Albanian government’s
intentions.
But the Albanian government had also undertaken certain obligations under
the supervision of the League of Nations in order to achieve international
recognition of its independence in the early 1920s; it had to respect the minority
rights of the Greek non-core group, among other things. As a result of this
commitment the Albanian government did recognize a Greek minority in
Albania but only in designated parts of the country. The members of this non-
core group that resided outside of those parts were targeted with assimilationist
policies that potentially aimed at forcing them to return to Greece. This latter
point brings us to the issue discussed in the next section.

terminal versus transitional policies


A third insight arises from a careful study of nation-building policies in the
Balkans, the distinction between terminal and transitional policies. We should
therefore try to discern when long-term goals and short-term policies coincide
and when not. This distinction between terminal and transitional policies is
linked to a broader consideration concerning the impact of the international
standard of minority rights protection in each era. For example, following
World War I Britain was a proponent of the League of Nations and the protec-
tion of minority rights but its ultimate goal at the time was not the creation of
multinational states. The British government’s rationale was that such guaran-
tees for national minorities would facilitate the initial coexistence of core and
non-core groups and would pave the way for future assimilation to the dominant
culture.
Ruling political elites in the Balkans were attuned to these realities and
international norms surrounding nation-building. Given this context, in some
cases Balkan states chose to follow a policy of accommodation for a certain
period before they applied assimilationist policies. Cases of this sort include the
Jews in Turkey, who were initially accommodated but toward the end of the

20
1994: 154–155.
21
Kontis 1994: 157–158.
106 Empirical Evidence

1920s were targeted with assimilationist policies, as well as the Muslims in


Greek Macedonia, who were initially accommodated but with an intention to
ultimately assimilate them as Greek officials indicated in their confidential
reports (see Chapter 6). The important point to note here is that in both cases
the host state’s intention was assimilationist from the beginning.
According to my theory, the Muslims in Greece should have been targeted
with assimilationist policies after World War I since they were members of an
enemy-supported group living in a state that favored the international status
quo. In the five-year period before the obligatory population exchange between
Greece and Turkey occurred we observe a policy of accommodation and only a
few selectively targeted exclusionary measures. Without archival material it
would have been impossible to discern whether the ultimate goal was their
assimilation or not. However, from the evidence I have gathered,22 we find
that accommodation in this case was in fact mainly a transitional policy.
It is in this connection that my incorrect predictions with respect to the five
Jewish communities in the Balkans are not surprising. According to my coding
criteria the Jews in the Balkans were a non-core group with no external state
supporting them and as such they should have been targeted with assimilationist
policies. In reality, they were all granted minority rights – at least in the period
under study. This clearly contradicts my predictions. What accounts for the
accommodation of most Eastern European Jewish communities immediately
after World War I? Why weren’t they targeted with assimilationist policies?
Coding the Jewish communities in the Balkans as a non-core group with no
external support – as I did in Chapter 4 – is problematic. My hypothesis is that
the Jews were actually accommodated because they were perceived as being
supported by the British – the victors of World War I – as well as a rapidly
growing Zionist movement. Here, I briefly probe this hypothesis, but a compre-
hensive answer to this set of questions is beyond the scope of this book.
Around seven million Jews lived in Eastern Europe at the time and the fact
that there was no Jewish homeland yet complicated the picture and added to
the uncertainty surrounding the future fate of Jews in Europe.23 The parti-
cipants in the Paris Peace Conference in 1919 knew well that the British had
promised to support the creation of a Jewish state. Everyone was familiar with
Balfour’s Declaration.24 The endorsement of the declaration by the Supreme
Council of the Peace Conference during the first days sent a clear signal to
everyone that the Jews were to be treated as a national minority in the post–
World War I world.25
Let us take a closer look at this transformation of the Jewish people from
religious to national minority. A characteristic incident dates as far back as 1912

22
See Chapter 6.
23
For more on the link between the Jewish Question and the protection of minority rights in Europe,
see Janowsky 1966.
24
“Palestine for the Jews. Official Sympathy,” The Times, 9 November 1917.
25
MacMillan 2002.
Odd Cases: Analysis of Outliers 107

when Dr. Adolf Friedemann26 traveled to Vienna – sent by the Berlin-based Zionist
Actions Committee – to lobby on behalf of the Jews of Thessaloniki. There he met
with the First Director of the Ministry of Foreign Affairs of Austria-Hungary, Baron
Karl Macchio, and argued for the coincidence of interest between the Austro-
Hugarian Government and of the Jews in the internationalization of
Thessaloniki.27 In his presentation, Dr. Friedemann informed the Baron, “[w]e
[the Zionist Actions Committee] are interested in the Salonikan Jews from a
nationalist point of view.”28 The Baron, baffled by the treatment of the Jews as
a nationality, asked for an explanation. Dr. Friedemann replied:

The Jews of Salonika are Sephardim. They have never assimilated and have always
retained their particular characteristics and maintained contacts with the Jews of
Palestine. Incidentally, we are interested in the Jews of the East [in general] from the
stand-point of nationality.29

The internationalization of Thessaloniki did not materialize but on 18 January


1913, Dr. Friedemann was informed that “the joint Austro-Hungarian cabinet
had decided to demand at the peace conference political guarantees for the Jews
in the captured territories.”30
The combination of Zionist activism illustrated above and Balfour’s
Declaration – endorsed by the Supreme Council of the Paris Peace
Conference – invited state elites to consider the Jewish communities in Europe
as “national minorities” supported by the victors of the war. Mark Levene notes
that already in October 1918, the Zionist leadership had voiced its demands for
“national autonomy in the diaspora” as a necessary corollary to “a national
home in Palestine” next to the demand that the Jewish people should be admitted
to the League of Nations.31
The fate of Jews in the Balkans would more or less be decided at the Paris
Peace Conference. The solution first developed with respect to the Jews in Poland
functioned more or less as a prototype for the other cases. One of the national
autonomy clauses of the Minorities Treaty signed in Paris mentioned the Jews by
name.32 This arrangement was to be protected in two ways: First, international
treaties and safeguards provided civil and political rights as well as cultural

26
“The Berlin lawyer Dr. Adolf Friedemann (1871–1932) . . . An aide of Herzl, he was a member of
the Zionist Action Committee and the co-founder of the ‘Kommittee fur den Osten.’ He published
Reisebilder aus Paldstina (Berlin 1904), Herzl’s first biography, Das Leben Theodor Herzls
(Vienna 1919) and Dawid Wolffsohn. Biographie (Berlin 1915)” (Gelber et al. 1955: 107).
27
Austria supported this plan in an effort to preserve the rights it had secured from the Ottoman
Empire to connect Vienna with Thessaloniki by a railroad passing through Budapest. For a
thorough presentation of the involvement of the Zionist movement in this affair, see Gelber
et al. 1955.
28
Zionist Archives, Jerusalem, Files of the Berlin Zionist Bureau [=ZBB], 538, Quoted in Gelber
et al. 1955: 111.
29
Ibid.
30
Gelber et al. 1955: 112.
31
1993: 520.
32
Levene 1993: 523.
108 Empirical Evidence

rights to the Jews and other minorities in all the new states, guaranteed by the
League of Nations. The Jews and other recognized minorities had the right to
run their own schools and cultural organizations in their own language.33
Second, “a series of negotiations leading to private arrangements with senior
East European statesmen” also protected this arrangement.34
The British Foreign Office had already endorsed this latter method since
November 1918 with the following guidelines:
In all countries with Jewish inhabitants but especially in East and South-East Europe
where the Jews form a large and more separate element in the population than elsewhere,
the spokesmen of this Jewish element, if they put forward demands for cultural autonomy
as well as individual citizen rights, should be recommended in the first instance to discuss
the question with the government or other representative parties of their respective
countries. They should be discouraged from referring this question to outside Powers of
the Peace Conference before they have done their utmost to arrive at a settlement with
peoples among whom they respectively live.35

From the discussion it becomes clear that the various governments – at least in
Eastern Europe – had plenty of reasons to treat the Jews as a national minority.
For example, it was in an effort to impress the peacemakers that the governments
of Ukraine and Lithuania introduced national autonomy programs for the Jews
in their lands. With similar ends in mind they included Jewish elites in their
delegations at the Peace Conference.
Eastern European leaders reacted negatively to what they perceived as favori-
tism toward a newly constructed Jewish national minority mostly using state
sovereignty arguments. The new system lacked the means to enforce its decisions
but in many cases it accounted for the initial accommodation of Jewish com-
munities. Despite these policies of accommodation, however, the pogroms of
Jews in Ukraine that took place in 1919 were instructive. As Lucien Wolf,36 a
British journalist and Jewish leader, put it in his diary of the Paris Peace
Conference:
For us [British Jewry] to give any advice to the Jews of the Ukraine is impossible. We
cannot advise them to be good Ukrainians without the risk that we are setting them
against the Entente and asking them to be traitors to Russia. We cannot ask them to
support the cause of an undivided Russia without pillorying them as enemies of their
country’s national cause. We cannot recognize them to be neutral without recognizing a
Jewish nationality and setting both Russians and Ukrainians and probably also

33
Ibid., 523–524.
34
Ibid., 524.
35
Quoted in ibid., 530.
36
“Lucien Wolf (1857–1930), English historian and Jewish leader, was editor of the Jewish World
(1874–93) and of the Daily Graphic (1890–1909). He was a founder of the Jewish Historical
Society of England in 1893 and secretary of the Conjoint Foreign Committee.” “The Conjoint
Foreign Committee of the Board of Deputies of British Jews and of the Anglo-Jewish Association
was established in connection with the Congress of Berlin (1878) and was most active during the
peace conferences after World War I” (Gelber et al. 1955: 114).
Odd Cases: Analysis of Outliers 109

Bolshevists, Poles and Rumanians against them . . . the problem is an extremely difficult
one. It shows how dangerous it is to mix up raison d’etat with a politique des principes.37

A closer look at one of the Jewish communities in the Balkans – that of


Thessaloniki, Greece – can prove instructive. The center of Jewish life in the
Balkans was Thessaloniki. Up to the annexation of Thessaloniki to the Greek
state, the Greek authorities perceived the Jews as Turcophiles, “anti-Greek, dis-
loyal, and untrustworthy”38 and plans for the internationalization of the city were
popular amongst the Jewish community.39 Following the annexation three camps
emerged within the Jewish community of Thessaloniki: the Zionist, the Socialist
(later Communist), and that of the supporters of assimilation.40 The first two
camps constituted the overwhelming majority and opposed assimilation.
According to my argument the Jews of Thessaloniki should have been tar-
geted with assimilationist policies since they had no external state supporting
them and the Greek state was dominated by ruling political elites with a clear
national character in mind. However, immediately after Greece annexed
Thessaloniki the Jews were accommodated, although the terminal policy was
assimilation.41
Although it seems counterintuitive that the Greek government did not pursue
at first assimilationist policies, upon consideration of the international context
described above the case becomes less puzzling. Greece was an ally of the Entente
powers and its territorial expansion had been supported and legitimized by
Britain and France. Britain was arguably the most important external supporter
of Venizelos and by extension of Greece at the time. Once again, your ally’s ally
is your friend.
According to the Balfour Declaration in 1917, the Jews were promised their
own national home in Palestine and therefore had been officially discussed as a
national minority.42 Greece did not want to jeopardize its alliance with Britain.
Greece had to recognize minority rights for the Jews in order to retain support
from its allies. Moreover, the Greek government could not say one thing and do
another because the Jewish community lived in an urban center with many
consuls and much international attention. Moreover, the Chief Rabbi had
important international connections himself – aside from the international
Zionist movement.43 Regardless, the Greek administration had a clear view at
the time: its ultimate goal was assimilation.

37
1919: 510–11.
38
Fleming 2008: 57.
39
Mazower 2004.
40
Mavrogordatos 1983: 263.
41
Rena Molho. The Jerusalem of the Balkans: Salonica 1856–1919. The Jewish Museum of
Thessaloniki: http://www.jmth.gr/web/thejews/pages/pages/history/pages/his.htm. URL accessed
23 April 2008.
42
For the reasons behind the Balfour declaration, see Friedman 1973, Sanders 1984, Stein 1961.
43
For more information on the important activities of the Zionist movement on behalf of the Jews of
Thessaloniki, see Gelber et al. 1955.
110 Empirical Evidence

Finally, we have to further distinguish transitional policies from policy


changes resulting from a learning process. Ruling political elites might con-
sciously pursue one policy toward a group with the ultimate intention of another
as described by the Governor-General of Macedonia in his report to the Ministry
of Foreign Affairs.44 However, there are cases where the ruling political elites
have tried assimilation, decided at some point that it cannot work, and, as a
result, changed their policy to exclusion or even accommodation. It is very
difficult to discern which of these different paths is at play without detailed
archival research. Such an effort is nonetheless worthwhile, as it is the only way
to resolve these instances of observational equivalence. A failure to address this
problem could lead to policies predicted correctly, but for the wrong reasons,
which in turn would keep us from falsifying incorrect hypotheses and conse-
quently improving our understanding of the process of nation-building.

foreign policy priorities and asymmetric alliances


The Greeks in the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes were a non-core group
supported by an ally and residing in a status quo host state. According to my
argument they should have been accommodated. Instead, the Greek community
of Monastir was targeted with intense assimilationist policies that led to the
ultimate migration of most of the group to Greece. This counterintuitive case
highlights two important dimensions of the dynamics of external support that
were not directly discussed in my theory chapter: foreign policy priorities and
asymmetrical alliances.
Greece at the time was operating as an external supporter of a few non-core
groups in the near abroad. The Greek government had to make choices about
which of these groups were the most strategically important. In this calculation the
preservation of a Greek minority in Southern Serbia was not a priority for the
Greek government when compared with the Greek community in Asia Minor.45
The Greek government had given up any effort to preserve a Greek minority in
Southern Serbia by the end of World War I. Prime Minister Venizelos was looking
primarily eastward to Asia Minor and Thrace and northwest to Northern Epirus
(or Southern Albania). In both cases Venizelos relied on Greece’s alliance with the
Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes to achieve these goals.
An additional consideration is that Greece may have been relying on this
alliance more than Yugoslavia. This raises another important point about the
nature of interstate relations. It suggests that the role of an alliance, that is,
accommodation of non-core groups supported by allies, may depend on the
extent to which this alliance is symmetrical. As Walt points out: “Alliances
may . . . be symmetrical or asymmetrical, depending on whether the members
possess roughly equal capabilities and take on broadly identical commitments

44
AYE, 1921, 41/2, Governor-General of Macedonia to Ministry of Foreign Affairs, 29 August
1919, Thessaloniki.
45
Llewellyn-Smith 1998.
Odd Cases: Analysis of Outliers 111

to each other.”46 Thus, we may need to relax that assumption for cases of
asymmetrical alliances or cases where the commitments and goals of the allies
diverge.
Given the situation, the Serbian authorities – operating within the context of a
status quo Kingdom – pursued assimilationist policies toward most non-core
groups in southern Serbia including the Greeks.47 This option was available
because of the asymmetric nature of the alliance with Greece but also because
Greece had clearly signaled that it would not go out of its way to protect the
rights of this group. The actual implementation of these policies was harsher
than planned because of principal-agent problems between the Serbian political
elites and the military establishment.48 This, coupled with the limited interest of
the Greek government in this minority ultimately led to the mass migration of
Greeks to their “homeland” across the border.

a “divide and rule” strategy


A few groups that should have been targeted with assimilationist policies
according to my theory were accommodated instead. In half of these cases (six
out of twelve) a “divide and rule” dynamic appears to be operative. With this
term I refer to the counterintuitive minority proliferation aiming either at the
fragmentation of a large group or the reversal of a subnational assimilation
pattern. For example, Seton-Watson points out that the Romanians granted
minority rights to the Germans in order to reverse the process of Magyarization
that had taken root within the German community of Romania.49
This divide and rule policy was a systematic pattern in the twentieth-century
Balkans with respect to Muslims in Christian-dominated countries. Scholars
have discussed the accommodation of Gypsies (nowadays referred to as
Roma) and Pomaks – Muslims speaking a Bulgarian dialect – in Greece and
Bulgaria at specific periods during the twentieth century as an attempt to weaken
the Muslim communities in both countries and prevent the subnational assim-
ilation of these groups into their respective Turkish minority.50
This pattern was not special to the interwar period. For example, in 1962
after a trend of Turkification of Gypsies had emerged, the Bulgarian Politburo
decided to intensify its assimilation policies. The first step it took was to stop the
Turkification trend by ensuring that Gypsies, Tatars, and Bulgarian-speaking
Muslims were “registered with their real nationality”; prohibiting Turkish
language instruction of non-Turkish children, banning their internal migration
to Turkish-dominated villages, and so on. Following this Politburo decision,

46
1997: 157.
47
Vasiliadis 2004. BNA, FO 371/14317 [C5316,/82/7] “The Origins of the Macedonian
Revolutionary Organization and Its History since the Great War,” 1 July 1930, p. 9,
48
For more on principal-agent problems in nation-building, see Chapters 7 and 8.
49
1962.
50
Kostopoulos 2009; Tsitselikis 2012.
112 Empirical Evidence

around 100,000 Gypsies who had identified themselves as Turks in the census
were forced to change their names to Bulgarian ones.51
Similarly, during the 1990s and after the collapse of the Soviet bloc the Greek
government once again recognized the presence of Pomaks in Western Thrace as
a non-core group separate from that the rest of the “Muslims.” For most of the
Cold War the Pomaks were submerged into the larger “Muslim” minority of
Western Thrace. This submersion was a way to prevent the Pomaks from being
used by the Bulgarian government (member of the Soviet bloc) in order to
interfere in Greek (member of NATO) internal affairs. After the collapse of the
Soviet Union the Greek government was no longer considering Bulgaria an
enemy power and could thus recognize the Pomaks as a distinct Muslim group
and thus fragmenting the Turkish-dominated Muslim minority of Western
Thrace.52 More empirical work is necessary to study this pattern through the
archives in Bulgaria and Greece.53

conclusion
In Chapter 4, I have shown that whether a non-core group enjoys external
support or not and the interstate relations between host states and external
powers account for the variation in nation-building policies in the interwar
Balkans. But here I focused on the incorrect predictions of my theory and
identified important methodological caveats in the study of nation-building
policies. To sum up, the periodization we choose affects the results we get;
policies are not always mutually exclusive; a mix of policies can be pursued in
some cases toward the same non-core group; often the initial policy pursued by
governments is merely a transitional strategy aimed at achieving a distinct long-
term objective; and external powers’ foreign policy priorities and the degree to
which alliances are asymmetrical significantly impact the decision making pro-
cess of host states with respect to nation-building. Furthermore, from the ana-
lysis of the outliers, a counterintuitive “divide and rule” strategy also emerges.
Balkan ruling elites often chose to strategically accommodate certain non-core
groups in order to prevent their subnational assimilation to larger and more
threatening non-core groups. Finally, there are a few cases where change of
policy is the result of learning through failure of a previous policy but a longue
durée approach is necessary to explore such patterns.54

51
Eminov 1997.
52
Kostopoulos 2009.
53
Aarbakke 2000; Anagnostou 2005 and 2007; Troumbeta 2001.
54
Braudel 1980.
6

Subnational Variation
Greek Nation-Building in Western Macedonia, 1916–1920

How well does my theory explain state policies toward non-core groups at the
subnational level? What accounts for variation in nation-building policies
toward different non-core groups within one state? Using both secondary sour-
ces and archival material, I focus on the province of Western Macedonia,
annexed by Greece during the Balkan Wars, and account for the variation in
the nation-building policies planned by the ruling political elites administering
the region. I find that the Greek government chose its nation-building policies
based not on objective measures of cultural distance or deep-rooted ethnic
hatred, but on security and geostrategic concerns. The diplomatic relations
between competitor states and Greece within the context of World War I largely
determined both the perception of the non-core groups inside Greece and their
consequent treatment.
My analysis is based on archival research conducted in Greece in 2006 and
2007. For the purposes of this chapter, I rely mostly on a compilation of reports
written by Ioannis Eliakis between 1916 and 1920. To contextualize Eliakis’s
reports I use both secondary sources and archival material.1 Ioannis Eliakis was a
close friend of Prime Minister Venizelos from the island of Crete. Born in 1878, he
was an MP in autonomous Crete, worked in Venizelos’s newspaper, and pub-
lished his own newspaper “Crete” from December 1912 to August 1913. Prime
Minister Eleftherios Venizelos sent Eliakis to the recently annexed Macedonia in
July 1916 as a representative of the Liberal Party. On 16 September 1916 he led
the Revolutionary movement in Western Macedonia. A month later the
Provisional Government in Thessaloniki appointed Eliakis as their representative
in Kozani and Florina prefectures and later on Governor-General of

1
For this chapter I conducted research in Greece at the Museum of the Macedonian Struggle, Pavlos
Kalligas Archive (PKA), Thessaloniki; the Historical and Diplomatic Archives of the the Ministry
of Foreign Affairs; Municipal Library, Kozani; the Eleftherios Venizelos Archive, Benaki Museum,
Athens; General State Archives, Florina; General State Archives, Kozani; General State Archives of
Macedonia, Thessaloniki; Gennadius Library, Athens; and the Hellenic Literary and Historical
Archive, Thessaloniki. All translations from the archival material are mine.

113
114 Empirical Evidence

Western Macedonia.2 He remained there until 1 November 1920, when Venizelos


was defeated in the election.3
From 1916 to 1920, Eliakis was the ultimate authority in that region. His
decisions overrode those of any other state official, including military officers. His
reports had a wide range of recipients: the Prime Minister, the Ministries of the
Interior, Foreign Affairs, and, last but not least, the Ministry of Military Affairs.4
More importantly, Eliakis was part of a like-minded political elite surround-
ing Venizelos at the time including Governor-General of Epirus Aristeidis
Stergiadis,5 Governor-General of Eastern Thrace Harisios Vamvakas, Minister
of Interior and Deputy Prime Minister Emmanuel Repoulis, Minister of Foreign
Affairs Nikolaos Politis, member of the Greek-Bulgarian Mixed Commission
Alexandros Pallis, Governor-General of Macedonia Adosidis and many more.6
The focus of Eliakis’s work was the national integration of Western Macedonia
to the Greek nation-state. This nation-building effort took place during the
turbulent period following the Balkan Wars and during World War I in a region
that was under the Ottoman administrative system for centuries and was com-
posed of a linguistically, religiously, and culturally heterogeneous population.
The scope conditions of my argument are met, but more importantly from
the perspective of testing my argument Greece’s foreign policy goals shifted
over this period. During World War I, Greece was fighting for the preservation
of its gains from the Balkan Wars and for redeeming its co-ethnics in Asia
Minor.7 Following World War I, Greece was trying to secure its territorial
gains. Moreover, some non-core groups had no external links, while some were
supported by allied states and others by enemy states.
The combination of the rich archival material I have unearthed and the
important variation in my main independent variables render this region an
ideal location to study the politics of nation-building and test my theory. This
type of analysis has two key benefits: first, the material allows me to detect the
intentions behind the inception and planning of the various policies concerning
the non-core groups residing in this region; second, it serves as a test for the
micro-foundations of my theory. We rarely have the opportunity to access the
reasoning behind the planning of such measures. Yet this type of evidence is
crucial to address issues of observational equivalence and allows me to test the
causal mechanisms I laid out in Chapter 2.

2
Western Macedonia is delimited by mountains: Pindos and Grammos in the west; Vitsi, Peristeri,
and Kaimaktsalan in the north; Olympus, Kambounia, and Chassia in the south; and Vermion in
the east. The largest cities at the time were Florina, Kastoria, Kozani, and Grevena (see Map 6.2).
See Kontogiorgi 2006, p. 13.
3
Eliakis also became the President of the Council of Greek Scouts during the short-lived Pangalos
dictatorship and later on the representative of the Mount Athos Monasteries to Athens (from 1929
to the late 1930s). For more information on Eliakis and his life, see Eliakis 1940.
4
PKA, Eliakis to Greek Ministry of Foreign Affairs, 22 January 1920.
5
Later on Stergiadis became the High Commissioner in Smyrna (1919–22).
6
For more, see Glavinas 2008 and Llewellyn-Smith 1998.
7
Llewellyn-Smith 1998.
Subnational Variation 115

Studying a specific region in depth allows me to trace the logic behind the nation-
building policies proposed by the Greek administration. Focusing on one region I
can control for many state- and regional-level hypotheses such as levels of economic
development, regime type, elite understandings of nationhood, and international
norms, and test the plausibility of my argument against three main alternative
arguments: the cultural distance, status reversal, and homeland arguments.

the context

World War I and the National Schism in Greece


When World War I broke out, geographic Macedonia – “a distinct geographic
region of rugged mountains, high intermontane basins, and fertile lowland
plains”8 – once again became the center of controversy (see Map 6.1).9 As
described in Chapter 3, Serbia and Bulgaria had entered World War I on
opposite sides of the conflict. Bulgaria allied with the Central Powers, and in
October 1915 Entente forces landed in Thessaloniki to assist Serbia.10
Around the same time, a national schism had developed in Greece, which was
the culmination of an ongoing domestic conflict between pro-German King
Constantine and pro-Entente Venizelos. Venizelos’s government pushed for the
entry of Greece in the war on the side of Entente; King Constantine’s plan was to
stay out of World War I and to sustain a “small but honorable Greece.”11 This
disagreement between Venizelos and the King led to the resignation of the former in
February 1915 and the formation of a government led by the Anti-Venizelists. The
elections of 31 May 1915 turned into a referendum to decide Greece’s position in
World War I. Venizelists, Independents, and Anti-Venizelists exchanged accusa-
tions with regard to promises – especially in terms of land rights – made to Muslim
voters in order to gain their electoral support.12 The result was an overwhelming
support for the Anti-Venizelists in Greek Macedonia and the dispute of the
electoral result by the Venizelists. The central claim of the latter was the fact that
the Muslims voted regardless of their citizenship status.13
However, Venizelos’s victory in the 31 May elections did not suffice and a
new round of bickering led to his second resignation within a year in September.
New elections were scheduled for 6 December but the Venizelists decided not to
participate. With the Entente powers already operating in the north of Greece

8
Kostanick 1948: 6.
9
Barker 1950.
10
During World War I, Russia aimed for Istanbul and, according to many observers of the day,
wanted to conquer the southern shores of the Black Sea as well. Italy wanted to secure control of
both sides of the Adriatic. Germany supported Austria-Hungary in its effort to weaken Serbia and
hold its Slavic lands in the Balkans. For the military events of the period, see General Staff of the
Army 1958.
11
Mavrogordatos 1982 and 1983.
12
For more on this, see Glavinas 2008: 230.
13
Ibid., 231.
116 Empirical Evidence

map 6.1. Boundary changes after the Balkan Wars, 1912–1913.


Source: Report of the International Commission to Inquire into the Causes and Conduct
of the Balkan Wars, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 1914. www.
CarnegieEndowment.org.
Subnational Variation 117

and Venizelos’s Liberal Party not participating, the 6 December elections were
peculiar to say the least. Regardless, in Western Macedonia they turned into a
headcount between the Anti-Venizelist party led by Gounaris – that kept court-
ing the Muslims – and the National Slate (Ethnikos Syndyasmos) Party – a
splinter of the Anti-Venizelist coalition together with some Independents –
which claimed to represent the Greeks of the area and tried to polarize the
vote along ethnoreligious lines.14 The Anti-Venizelists won, of course, but so
did abstention. In Kozani, the capital of Western Macedonia and later Eliakis’s
post, only 7,000 out of 25,000 registered Greeks voted in the election following
Venizelos’s request to abstain.15
Skouloudis formed an Anti-Venizelist government following the 6 December
1915 election; however, Great Britain and France reacted to the capitulation of
Fort Roupel – an important military stronghold – to German and Bulgarian
forces in May 1916 by demanding the demobilization of the loyalist elements in
the Greek army and pushing for new elections in the fall.16 To enforce their will
they also implemented blockades on Greek ports.17 In the midst of these devel-
opments Ioannis Eliakis moved to Greek Macedonia in July 1916, as a repre-
sentative of Venizelos’s Liberal Party, and was faced with a challenging
situation.
Entente forces had been stationed in northern Greece since September 1915,
and yet another pre-election period began. The non-core groups of the area
supported the Anti-Venizelists in the 1915 elections. Foreign propaganda had
been extremely active in the recent past in an attempt to influence the vote of the
local population. But in the end, none of Eliakis’s campaigning efforts was put
into test – not until 1920 – since the planned election never took place.
In August 1916, Bulgarian and German troops occupied both Eastern and
much of Western Greek Macedonia. This was a final blow to the territorial
integrity of Greece. The internal fighting between Venizelists and Anti-
Venizelists and the Entente reactions led to the National Defense revolt, orches-
trated by Venizelist forces in Thessaloniki, and to the peculiar situation of two
governments in Greece. In fact, Eliakis had already led a revolutionary move-
ment in Western Macedonia on 16 September 1916 in response to fears con-
cerning Serbian plans for Greek Macedonia.18 Eliakis knew that Greece’s
neutrality under King Constantine had allowed discussions between the Allies
and Serbia concerning the future role of Serbia in Macedonia. This is yet another
example of how precarious alliances can be and how they change in ways that
are not endogenous to nation-building policies.

14
Glavinas 2008: 232–238.
15
Iho tis Makedonias, 9 December 1915.
16
Leon 1974: 362–369.
17
Tucker et al. 1999: 103.
18
Ibid. A combination of factors worried Eliakis. The exiled King of Serbia had moved to
Thessaloniki with his government and in May 1916 more than 100,000 Serbian troops arrived
from Corfu to Greek Macedonia to fight in the Macedonian front. This situation was the result of
the Serbian Army retreat following the Serbian Campaign.
118 Empirical Evidence

illu stration 6.1. French General Sarrail with Prime Minister Venizelos.
Source: Library of Congress Prints and Photographs Division, Washington, D.C.

A month later the provisional government in Thessaloniki appointed


Eliakis as its representative in Kozani and Florina prefectures and later on
Governor-General of Western Macedonia. Eliakis’s party was pro-Entente, so
a cooperative relationship was initially formed with the French Army and
General Sarrail in particular (see Illustration 6.1).19 By 1917, the Entente
forced King Constantine to leave Athens and Venizelos governed over the
reunified Greek Kingdom. Venizelos’s agenda had prevailed: Greece, on the
side of Entente forces, regained Eastern Macedonia in September 1918 and,
with the Treaty of Sevres in 1920, annexed Eastern Thrace and formed a
_
provisional administration in Smyrna/Izmir. Until November 1920, when
Venizelos lost the elections, Eliakis remained the Governor of Western
Macedonia. These events form the general context within which Eliakis
operated in Western Macedonia.

19
Eliakis 1940: 51. Maurice-Paul-Emmanuel Sarrail (1856–1929) was a French general in World
War I. He was in command of the French Army of the Orient deployed in Thessaloniki in October
1915. In January 1916 he became the commander of all Allied forces in the Macedonian front
where he stayed until December 1917. Sarrail did not hide his support for Venizelos and actively
supported the Venizelist camp. General Guillaumat (1863–1940) replaced General Sarrail in the
end of 1917. Guillaumat was in turn replaced in June 1918 by the last commander of the Allied
armies in Thessaloniki General Franchet d’Esperey (1856 –1942).
Subnational Variation 119

Integrating Western Macedonia: Intentions and Policies


The population residing in Greek Macedonia was far from being linguistically,
ethnically, religiously, or culturally homogeneous. The inhabitants were mostly
peasants who lived in a world of corporate privileges for religious groups rather
than individual rights. More specifically, in Western Macedonia, industrial
development was almost nonexistent (see Map 6.2).20 The inhabitants were
mostly illiterate, living in more or less homogeneous villages but overall cultur-
ally, religiously, and ethnically mixed eparchies.21
National identities were present in the Balkans, but we should also not
forget the fluid character of these identities at the time. The Greek admini-
stration, for instance, discussed the various groups in their confidential reports
and often referred to people of “fluid national consciousness.” Table 6.1
provides us with a categorization of non-core groups in Greek Macedonia at
the time. Despite the fluidity of identities and the superficial character of some
identifications, Greek policymakers were convinced that in the 1910s the “pure
Greek element” was a minority in Western Macedonia. According to Eliakis,
with the exception of the eparchies of Servia and Anasselitsa, in all eparchies
when you combined the non-core groups Greeks were a minority. In Kozani,
the Muslims were predominant and in Kailaria – today’s Ptolemaida – Muslims
and Bulgarians prevailed. In the eparchies of Kastoria and Florina, the majority
was of the Bulgarian element together with a group of people with a fluid
national consciousness. In the eparchy of Grevena, according to Eliakis, the
influence of “Romanian-leaning” Vlachs was so great that one was not sure if
there were any “pure Greeks” there.22
Given the ethnic makeup of Western Macedonia, nation-building policies were
a top priority. The Greek government had been thinking of nation-building
policies for the population of these lands for over forty years before their actual
incorporation; however, officials had to finalize and recalibrate them after 1913.23
As Mazower put it, “Much time, money and effort was required by disciples of the
new nationalist creeds to convert its inhabitants from their older, habitual ways of
referring to themselves, and to turn nationalism itself from the obsession of a
small, educated elite to a movement capable of galvanizing masses.”24
But what was the dominant understanding of nationhood in Greece at the
time? The definition of the national type had crystalized around the end of the
nineteenth century. To be Greek, one had to be born in Greece or be of Greek

20
Gounaris 1996; Karavidas 1931; Kontogiorgi 2006: 19.
21
An eparchy (eparcheia) is a political subdivision of a prefecture (nomos) of Greece.
22
PKA, Other Peoples, Eliakis to the Venizelos, Abstract of No. 5359 report 18 October 1917. See
also PKA, The State of Affairs of the Population in Western Macedonia, Eliakis to the President of
the Council of Ministers, Abstract of No. 7861 report, 19 October 1918). For detailed statistics of
the regions, see Aarbakke 2003 and Glavinas 2008.
23
Carabott 1997: 59–78; Gounaris 1996: 409–425; Karakasidou 1997; Michailidis 1998: 9–21;
and Michailidis 2003.
24
Mazower 2004: 256.
120 Empirical Evidence

Florina
Thessaloniki
Kastoria
Kozani

Grevena

Athens
B

map 6.2. (A) Greek Macedonia, http://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:PosGreek


Macedonia.png; (B) Western Greek Macedonia, http://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/
File:Periferia_Dytikis_Makedonias.png.
Subnational Variation 121

table 6.1. Non-Core Groups in Greek Macedonia (c. 1915)

Non-Core Groups Religion Languagea

Koniareoi Muslim Turkish


Valaades Muslim Greek
Albanians Muslim (and Christian) Albanian
Muslim Vlachs Muslim Vlach
Pomaks, Çitaklar Muslim Slavic
Donmehs Muslim Ladino/Turkish
“Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs Christian (Exarchate) Slavic
“Greek-leaning” Slavs Christian (Patriarchate) Slavic
“Romanian-leaning” Vlachs Christian (Romanian) Vlach
“Greek-leaning” Vlachs Christian (Patriarchate) Vlach
Greeks Christian (Patriarchate) Greek
Greek Refugees Christian (Patriarchate) Greek
Sarakatsans Christian (Patriarchate) Greek
Armenian Christian (Gregorian) Armenian
Gypsies Christian (Patriarchate) and Muslim Gypsy/Romany
Jews (Sephardim) Jewish Ladino

Note: Italicized non-core groups are not discussed in Eliakis’s reports.


a
I list the primary language of the group. Many members of these groups were bilingual or even
trilingual at the time using different languages for different purposes and in different contexts.

ancestry, had to usually speak Greek, and had to be an Orthodox Christian.


During the Balkan Wars, and faced with the heterogeneity of the “New Lands”
they were incorporating, Greek ruling political elites strategically emphasized
the importance of national consciousness over language or religion. The views of
the Greek elites around Venizelos concerning the matter were very close to
Ernest Renan’s ideas as expressed in his 1882 lecture at the Sorbonne.25
Venizelos clearly stated his understanding of nationhood both before and
after he became Prime Minister. The first instance goes back to October 1906
when Venizelos, addressing the Second Constituent Assembly of Cretans,
argued that “it is of great interest for Hellenism to propagate that its under-
standing [of nationhood] is so broad and so foreign to religious doctrines so
that within Hellenism can fit not only Christian believers, but also the
believers in any other known or unknown religion.”26 Venizelos remained
on message following World War I, at the Paris Peace Conference in 1919,
saying, “[R]eligion, race, language cannot be considered as reliable indica-
tions of nationality. The only unmistaken indicator is national consciousness,
the purposeful desire of individuals to self determine their luck and to decide
which national family they desire to belong to.”27 Finally, even after the Greek
defeat in the Greek-Turkish War following World War I, Venizelos insisted

25
Renan 1996.
26
Stephanou 1965: 288–290 and 1969: 282–283 .
27
Quoted in Glavinas 2008: 289.
122 Empirical Evidence

that an important element of the foundations of a society is “respect of all


religious doctrines, even those that oppose all religious doctrines.”28 The
political elites surrounding him, and definitely Eliakis, shared this under-
standing of nationhood.29
In the rest of this section, I describe Eliakis’s thoughts and policy recommen-
dations about each non-core group under his jurisdiction. I structure the dis-
cussion based on the religious divide between Muslims and Christians, which
was the oldest and most salient cleavage in the region.30 Within each religious
group, there were groups speaking different languages and having different
national leanings (see Table 6.1). Moreover, some non-core groups had no
external links, some were supported by allied powers, such as Romania, and
others were supported by enemy states, such as Bulgaria. During this four-year
period, from 1916 to 1920, Greece moved from being a revisionist state to a
status quo state within the context of the Macedonian front, and in certain cases
Eliakis’s recommendations changed as well (see Tables 6.2 and 6.3).

muslims
In 1915 more than one third of the inhabitants of Greek Macedonia were
Muslims, prime candidates for external support by the Ottomans.31 According
to a census, Muslims in Western and Central Macedonia were more equally
divided between mixed (225) and pure (288) settlements, while in Eastern
Macedonia Muslims were mostly living in pure settlements (250 to 112).32 In
terms of the type of settlement, 20 percent lived in urban centers while 80 percent
lived in rural areas.33 Turning to Western Macedonia, in its two prefectures of
Kozani and Florina Muslims formed 27 percent and 20 percent of the total
population, respectively.
After the incorporation of southern Macedonia into the Greek kingdom in
1913, Muslims had to choose the Ottoman or the Greek nationality. In particular,
the Treaty of Athens provided for a period of three years to choose a nationality.34
This was a policy clearly differentiating the Muslim religious community from the
other communities by “encouraging” the Muslims who felt strong attachments to

28
Eleftheron Vima, 18 February 1929.
29
Glavinas suggests that the Greek administration was downplaying the importance of linguistic
differences but he is more skeptical about religion (2008: 44). However, Eliakis’s and Venizelos’s
private and public statements contradict this view. I draw a similar conclusion by looking at other
confidential reports from the period. For example, see the report written by Adosidis describing a
meeting he had with the Chief Rabbi of the Jewish Community of Thessaloniki, AYE, 1921, 41/2,
Report of the Governor-General of Macedonia to Ministry of Foreign Affairs, 20 August 1919,
Thessaloniki.
30
Braude and Lewis 2000; Tsitselikis 2007: 354–372.
31
Glavinas 2008: 13, 261.
32
Ibid., p. 20.
33
Ibid., p. 15.
34
The Treaty of Athens was signed between Greece and the Ottoman Empire on 14 November
1913. For more on this treaty, see Glavinas 2008: 133–139. See also Tsitselikis 2012.
table 6.2. Explaining Nation-Building Policies in Western Macedonia, 1916–1918, Greece Revisionist

External External Power:


Non-Core Groups Support? Enemy or Ally? Predictions Intentions Policy

“Greek-leaning” Slavs No – Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation


“Greek-leaning” Vlachs No – Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation
Sarakatsans No – Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation
Valaades No – Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation
Albanians Yes Neutral Accommodation Accommodation Accommodation
“Romanian-leaning” Vlachs Yes Ally Accommodation Accommodation/ Assimilation Accommodation
Koniareoi Yes Enemy Exclusion Exclusion/ Assimilation Exclusion/ Accommodation
“Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs Yes Enemy Exclusion Exclusion/ Assimilation Exclusion/ Assimilation
table 6.3. Explaining Nation-Building Policies in Western Macedonia 1918–1920, Greece Status Quo

External External Power:


Non-Core Groups Support? Enemy or Ally? Predictions Intentions Policy

“Greek-leaning” Slavs No – Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation


“Greek-leaning” Vlachs No – Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation
Sarakatsans No – Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation
Valaades No – Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation
Albanians Yes Future Ally Accommodation Accommodation Accommodation
“Romanian-leaning” Vlachs Yes Ally Accommodation Accommodation/ Assimilation Accommodation
Koniareoi Yes Enemy Assimilation Assimilation Accommodation/ Assimilation
“Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs Yes Enemy Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation/ Voluntary
Exchange
Subnational Variation 125

the Ottoman Empire to leave. There was variation in the effectiveness of this
mechanism of “ethnic unmixing.”35 To begin with, the Greek administration did
not pursue its implementation.36 The emigration of Muslims to the Ottoman Empire
could – and many times did – lead to a justification of further persecution of Greeks
in Asia Minor. At the same time, keeping the Muslims in the “New Lands”37 was
beneficial in two more ways: first, it was good for agricultural production, and
second, it demonstrated the administration’s competency in governing over many
more Muslims in light of the Greek territorial aspirations in Asia Minor.38
On top of this contradictory set of incentives from the state’s perspective, the
status of Muslims during the elections of 1915 was in flux and their Anti-
Venizelist vote invited the criticism of the Venizelist newspapers and supporters.
When Eliakis arrived in the summer of 1916, he attempted to divide the Muslim
vote by forming alliances with personal enemies of the Muslim candidates from
the Anti-Venizelist party. The Entente powers were also natural allies of the
Venizelist party in this campaign and were used in order to keep Anti-Venizelist
Muslims in check.39
In Western Macedonia, fewer Muslims chose the Ottoman nationality than
did Muslims in other parts of northern Greece.40 Eliakis attributed this fact to
the timely arrest of the Mufti41 in Kailaria and of certain Beys42 by the French
Army in 1916, as well as to his own personal efforts. He summoned all the
Mukhtars43 of the region and explained the program of the Greek authorities,
and asked them to accept Greek rule. These Mukhtars submitted to the new
sovereign, and Eliakis promised to protect their human and community rights
from both Greek and foreign authorities.44

35
I have adopted this term from Brubaker 1998.
36
For example, between 1914 and 1915 Muslim emigration was prohibited. Moreover, when the
deadline arrived in November 1916 the treaty was not enforced because of World War I. In
general, with the exception of cases where there was evidence of anti-Greek activity (see Glavinas
2008: 286–287), even Muslims who had chosen the Ottoman citizenship were allowed to change
their status and remain in Greece just by filing out their papers for Greek citizenship. For more, see
Glavinas 2008: 105–106.
37
This is the designation that the Greek government used for the territories annexed in the Balkans
Wars and World War I.
38
For more, see Llewellyn-Smith 1998.
39
Glavinas 2008: 240–241.
40
And fewer issues emerged with the emigration of Muslims after the end of World War I.
41
A Mufti is a Muslim cleric who gives opinions on Islamic law.
42
A Bey was a provincial governor in the Ottoman Empire. By the end of nineteenth century,
however, the term Bey is used for local notables, and military officials.
43
Mukhtar was the Turkish word for community leader, later mayor. They were appointed by the
Ottomans in each community and were usually wealthy. The Mukhtar was responsible for
enforcing law and order, collecting taxes, and calling the police when necessary. His house also
functioned as the base for any visiting government officials.
44
PKA, The Attitudes of Aliens toward the Movement: Voting Rights, Eliakis to the Provisional
Government, Abstract of No. 564 report, 11 November 1916. To be sure, Eliakis wrote this
report in 1916. Glavinas informs us that the Provisional Government replaced Anti-Venizelist
Muftis with the help of the Entente troops.
126 Empirical Evidence

It is important to remember that Eliakis – just like Prime Minister Venizelos –


was from the island of Crete where he had experienced the coexistence of Muslims
and Christians. This experience informed Eliakis’s attitude toward the Muslims.
More importantly, the Greek Prime Minister shared this experience and attitude.
Venizelos, as we have demonstrated, had a very inclusive understanding of
Hellenism. Just after the end of the second Balkan War he argued, “it is to our
great interest to keep the Muslim population of the recovered territories. They are
an excellent group, a first class agricultural group, exemplar and obedient citi-
zens.”45 Thus, despite the fact that there were many negative stereotypes against
Muslims in Greek society, an important part of the Greek administration and ruling
political elites, both Venizelist and Anti-Venizelist,46 shared a positive view, the
former based on principles and the latter possibly for electoral purposes.
In a report to the Ministry of Military Affairs in 1917, Eliakis wrote:
With respect to the Muslims of my jurisdiction I am in the pleasant position to stress that
because of my stance toward them, although they have been asked to satisfy many
military needs, they understood that the State is protecting everyone irrespectively of
race or religion, and this made them even more loyal subjects of our State. Holding the
view that we should not grant political rights to the Muslims, since this would corrupt
them, I have always argued we will not be able to sever their bonds with the Ottoman
State unless we respect their human rights and their religious beliefs. Following this policy
will allow us to use them as an important factor in every respect, but more importantly, it
will prove that we are able to govern alien people, something necessary in order to enforce
order in Macedonia.47

Not much later Eliakis noted that the above policy produced amazing results.
The Muslims had demonstrated their trust to the state by enthusiastically enlist-
ing in the Greek army. The benefits from this were clear, because the army
needed these “obedient and healthy soldiers.” Eliakis drew a parallel between
them and the “Moroccan Spahis”48 fighting for the French and suggested
specific policies to ensure the success of this endeavor:
1. create Muslim battalions with their own flag, which should include the half moon in
one of its corners; 2. allow each battalion to have an Imam49 for prayer; 3. promote the
best to non-commissioned officers; 4. allow them to wear the fez; 5. insert Greek soldiers
fluent in Turkish to monitor the behavior of these battalions and spy on them if
necessary.50

In general, Eliakis believed Muslims were easy to deal with because of their
religion. It was enough to protect their life, honor, and property, respect their
religion, and treat them equally. Having political rights was not a concern for

45
Ai Agoreuseis tou Ellinikou Koinovouliou, 1909–1956 1957: 46.
46
Glavinas 2008.
47
PKA, Conscription of Muslims, Eliakis to the Ministry of Military Affairs, 25 August 1917.
48
Spahis regiments were light cavalry regiments in the French Army recruited primarily from the
indigenous populations of French Morocco. The name comes from Sipahi, an Ottoman cavalryman.
49
An Imam is a Muslim prayer leader.
50
PKA, Conscription of Muslims, Eliakis to the Ministry of Military Affairs, 25 August 1917.
Subnational Variation 127

them, he believed, as long as they could freely regulate their communal affairs.
According to Eliakis, if the policy he outlined were to be followed, the Muslims
would gradually become “civilized” and understand themselves to be an indis-
pensable part of the Greek nation. This would happen especially after the
Muslims realized that the Ottoman state would not be able to recapture these
territories. No government ever implemented his proposal restricting Muslims of
their political rights, but it was clearly regarded as a possibility – at least during
the turbulent times of World War I. A prominent alternative to what Eliakis
suggested was the establishment of separate electoral colleges.51 Regardless, in
the 1920 election that overlapped with Venizelos’s defeat and Eliakis’s removal
from office, none of the above took effect and 38 Muslim MPs were elected.52
The Muslims of Western Macedonia were not a homogeneous ethnic group.
Eliakis distinguished between three main non-core groups: Koniareoi, Valaades,
and Albanians. Koniareoi were the Turkish speaking conquerors of Macedonia
who came from Anatolia and, according to Eliakis, were still in an “animal
state.” The ones that felt closer to the Ottoman Empire would choose the
Ottoman nationality and would be “encouraged” to leave. For the rest, he
believed that they could be ruled easily through the Koran. During the Balkan
Wars and World War I exclusionary policies were pursued but not fully imple-
mented toward this group. The “state of siege” law,53 instituted by the 1864
constitutional revision and reaffirmed in the 1911 one, and the 1871 law “on the
persecution of banditry,” which was extended to the “New Lands” in December
1913, provided the legal basis for the selective exclusionary policies.54 Glavinas
informs us that the Provisional Government replaced many Muftis with the help
of the Entente troops and Muslims that exhibited “Anti-Greek” activity were
deported or internally displaced.55
The second group was Valaades, Greek speakers who had converted to Islam
and lived in villages near Anasselitsa. According to Eliakis, many of them were
aware of their Greek origin and most did not even speak Turkish. They would be
easy to assimilate. As Eliakis put it: “Their assimilation will be complete once
they are convinced that religion is not the attribute of Nations, but national
consciousness and origin.”56

51
See Glavinas 2008: 257.
52
Glavinas 2008: 255. After the Greek defeat in Asia Minor and the Venizelist takeover in 1922,
separate electoral colleges were established for the Muslims of Macedonia and Thrace that could
elect only 19 MPs; see Mavrogordatos 1983: 239.
53
The “state of siege” law was voted on 20 July 1917 and with the Law 755 voted on 18 August
1917 the Greek authorities could internally displace individuals that provided information on
Greek military affairs to the enemy, instigate desertion, or was otherwise causing suspicion to the
authorities. Similar laws were in effect during the Provisional Government’s rule in Thessaloniki.
The “state of siege” law was officially lifted after the Sevres Treaty was signed in 1920.
54
Law “on the persecution banditry” TOD 27 February 1871 and the law that extended the 1871
law to the New Lands was Law 121, voted on 31 December 1913.
55
2008: 85–86, 423–424.
56
PKA, Eliakis to the President of the Council of Ministers, Abstract of No. 7861 report, 19 October
1918.
128 Empirical Evidence

After World War I, Eliakis’s intentions with respect to Valaades and


Koniareoi were far from exclusionary. Valaades were perceived and treated as
if they were Greek. Koniareoi were accommodated in the short term, but the
ultimate goal was to assimilate them within an expanded Greece. Given that they
were perceived as a group supported by an enemy power, the Ottoman
Empire,57 and that Eliakis wanted to preserve the favorable status quo, my
theory also predicts assimilationist policies. Moreover, the exclusionary land
and property policies followed by Venizelos’s government toward the Muslims
during World War I were, consistent with my argument, reversed in their favor
following the end of the war. Thus Eliakis and the Greek administration at large
shifted their policy following World War I toward one of assimilationist long-
term objectives, even though the actual policies they pursued initially looked
more like accommodationist than assimilationist (see Illustration 6.2).
Finally, there was also the third group, the Muslim Albanians.58 According to
Eliakis, religion did not matter to them and their Albanian consciousness pre-
vailed.59 The Albanians differed from the Koniareoi, since the latter were look-
ing toward Istanbul for protection. Many Albanians had economic interests in
the Greek territories, emphasized the common origins of Greeks and Albanians,
and worked for Greek-Albanian cooperation.
Two factors made Eliakis suggest a different treatment of Albanians: his
desire to ensure friendly relations with the newly born state of Albania, and
the distinct Albanian consciousness of this population, which dissociated them

illustration 6.2. Governor Ioannis Eliakis addresses Muslims in Florina, 1920.

57
According to confidential reports cited by Glavinas, Istanbul and Ankara also got involved
supporting the Anti-Venizelist camp encouraging the Muslims to vote Muslim candidates and
against Venizelos (2008: 249).
58
There were three other groups of Muslims that lived in Greek Macedonia at the time: the Muslim
Vlachs (primarily from Meglen region), the Gypsies, and the Slavic-speaking Muslims (Pomaks).
Eliakis, however, does not refer to them.
59
He also noted there were few Christian Albanians sharing this Albanian consciousness.
Subnational Variation 129

from other Muslims and thus diminished the likelihood of external support by
the Ottomans. He wrote:
If there is an Albanian State after the War it is to our benefit that this State is friendly to us.
Thus, I think we should not take the same measures toward the Albanians ruled by our
regime that we take against the other Muslims. We should not for example confiscate
their land as if it was abandoned, even if it really is, as long as they do not emigrate to
Turkey. The confiscated land of the Albanians, who emigrated for a while but came back
and declared their loyalty to our regime has to be returned to them even if their loyalty is
not sincere.60

Albania, established in 1913 but not yet a functional entity due to the outbreak
of World War I, would be a new state that Greece had many reasons to
befriend.61 The Albanians in the Greek kingdom could operate as guarantors
of friendly relations with Albania. The national interest would be better served
by making this small material sacrifice of not confiscating Albanian land.
Eliakis’s proposal was implemented by the government a year and a half later.
Thus the Albanians, members of a non-core group supported by a neutral power
in World War I and a prospective ally, were accommodated by the Greek
administration, consistent with my theory.
The alternative hypotheses (see Tables 6.4 and 6.5) all incorrectly predict exclu-
sionary policies toward the Albanians because they spoke a different language and
had a different religion, had a newly minted homeland, and had been traditionally
allied with the Turks within the dominant Muslim millet during Ottoman times.
Similarly, all three alternative hypotheses predict that the Greek administration
should have excluded the Koniareoi population because it was Muslim, spoke a
different language, and had a privileged position during Ottoman times. While this
was partially true during the Balkan Wars and World War I, it certainly does not
appear to be in Eliakis’s intentions and actions following World War I. Of course,
the Greek defeat in Asia Minor changed these calculations.

christians

Slavic-Speaking Christians
Having tested my theory on non-core groups with a different world religion
from the core group, I now turn to non-core groups that shared the same religion
(although not necessarily the same denomination) with the core group, but in
many cases spoke a different language. The largest Christian group in the area
was the Slavic-speaking population. This group consisted of “Bulgarian-

60
PKA, Alvanistai, Eliakis to the Provisional Government, Abstract of No. 389 report, 27 January
1917. Note: The date for Abstract of No. 389 report appears as 1918 in the original document but
this must be a mistake. First, the report is addressed to the Provisional Government, which did not
exist in 1918; second, this Abstract appears between reports from 1916 and 1917.
61
According to Eliakis, the Albanians could be Greece’s allies in case of a pan-Slavic alliance in the
Balkans.
130 Empirical Evidence

table 6.4. Evaluating Existing Explanations in Western Macedonia, 1916–1918

Non-Core Status
Groups Language Religion Reversal Homeland Policy

“Greek- Exclusion Assimilation Assimilation Exclusion Assimilation


leaning”
Slavs
“Greek- Exclusion Assimilation Assimilation Exclusion Assimilation
leaning”
Vlachs
Sarakatsans Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation
Valaades Assimilation Exclusion Exclusion Assimilation Assimilation
Albanians Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion Accommodation
“Romanian- Exclusion Assimilation Assimilation Exclusion Accommodation
leaning”
Vlachs
Koniareoi Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion/
Accommodation
“Bulgarian- Exclusion Exclusion Assimilation Exclusion Exclusion/
leaning” Assimilation
Slavs

Note: Incorrect predictions are shown in italics.

leaning” Slavs,62 loyal to the Bulgarian Exarchate and considered a Bulgarian


national minority by the Bulgarian state, and “Greek-leaning” Slavs, loyal to the
Orthodox Patriarchate in Istanbul.

“Bulgarian-Leaning” Slavs
Although Eliakis was not as worried about the loyalty of the various Muslim
groups, he was less optimistic with respect to the Christian Orthodox, “Bulgarian-
leaning” Slavs. These were people who sided with the Bulgarian Exarchate after its
establishment in 1870. His reasoning, however, was not one of cultural differences
or affinities but rather of diplomatic relations and war dynamics. He believed that if
there had been no Second Balkan War in Macedonia, then:
the local Bulgarians would be so audacious that [Greek] Macedonia would be everything
but Greek, since the “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs would be able to freely express their
Bulgarian feelings. However, the second war followed and the local “Bulgarian-leaning”
Slavs were discouraged and converts to the schism [the Exarchate] presented themselves
as orthodox [loyal to the Patriarchate] and Greeks, supposedly forced to convert reli-
giously and consequently to change their nationality as well. In the midst of that terror,
our state should have put aside everything else and focused its efforts on cementing in the
hearts of the population these [national] ideas. . . . It did almost nothing instead.63

62
The term Eliakis uses is Boulgarizontes.
63
PKA, The State of Affairs of the Population in Western Macedonia, Eliakis to the President of the
Council of Ministers, Abstract of No. 7861 report, 19 October 1918.
Subnational Variation 131

Eliakis criticized the Greek government because it did not send its best civil servants
and educators to Macedonia. He strongly believed that if there were schools in
every village and Greek priests took the place of those backing the Bulgarian
Exarchate, then the population would have been assimilated quickly. However,
the civil servants were below average and many of them came in order to make a
fortune; moreover, only a few schools started operating right away, and no priests
were sent to the villages which returned to the jurisdiction of the Patriarchate.
Despite all of these complaints, Eliakis was optimistic following World War I:

[I]f we try to change the souls of the population, it should be easy to do, since they are used
to being changed. They tell me that in one trial which took place in Florina during Turkish
rule . . . a witness was asked by the President of the Court what his nationality was and he
replied that eight years ago he was Bulgarian, two years later he became a Greek and
remained such for three years, after which he became Bulgarian again. . . . And he found
this identity change unproblematic and really believed in each period that he was what
[nationality] he thought he was. Thus if we work not spasmodically . . . but systematically,
it would be possible to make the local population believe they have become Greeks and if
they maintain this conviction for a long time it will be possible that they will really become
such.64

The grave results from the government’s inaction with respect to the assimilation
of the local population were obvious during the Bulgarian attack in Western
Macedonia, when many Slavic speakers welcomed Bulgarian soldiers as libera-
tors. A further indicator of the pro-Bulgarian sentiment from a part of the local
population was that even when the Entente (French and British) forces pushed
out the Bulgarian troops, many believed they would come back. Some of them
followed the defeated troops, hoping they would return as victors.
Following the Bulgarian defeat in the area, the Entente forces treated the
people residing in Western Macedonia badly because they had demonstrated
pro-Bulgarian feelings. The only refuge for these people was to adopt the Greek
national identity and demonstrate their loyalty to the Greek state. According to
Eliakis, this was an opportune moment for the Greek administration to achieve
in two years what it would otherwise not be able to achieve in ten. The Slavic-
speakers of Western Macedonia were trying to prove their “Greekness” by
protesting the lack of schools. Once again, the Greek government did not act
upon this opportunity because of administrative failures. While Eliakis was
writing his report in 1918, most schools remained closed and Athens did not
provide schoolbooks.
Eliakis was not optimistic about assimilating the older Slavic-speaking popu-
lation in the region, and he suggested that most policies should focus on the
younger generation. He expected the best results to come from orphanages and
girls’ boarding schools. He also insisted that, based on experience, the assimi-
lation of “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs could not entail solely cultural and educa-
tional measures; it had to entail terror as well.

64
Ibid.
132 Empirical Evidence

During World War I, methods such as deportations, arrests, and even killings
were legitimized by the fact that Bulgaria was an enemy power fighting on the side of
the Central Powers (the German, Austro-Hungarian, and Ottoman Empires).
During peacetime – when Eliakis was writing this report – violent measures were
harder to justify and pursue without attracting the attention of the international
community. Furthermore, Greece was in favor of the international status quo and
did not want to jeopardize it. Nevertheless, Eliakis suggested that selective violent
measures were essential even in peacetime in order to neutralize any obstruction to
peaceful assimilation policies.
Indeed, the Greek government had passed a law during World War I that
facilitated the deportation of individuals considered dangerous to the public
order.65 Eliakis built on that law and suggested it had to be enforced when
necessary. He thought that Greek authorities should deport not just the guilty
party but their whole family. Moreover, the deportation and the reasons for it
should be made known to the community.
The possibility of deporting all of the “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs from
Macedonia was suggested and described as a more “radical” measure of nation-
alizing the territory. However, Eliakis quickly dismissed this idea because “on
the one hand, this would make a terrible impression to the liberal people of the
civilized world, and, on the other, because we do not have those [Greeks], with
whom we could replace them.”66 In 1919, the emigration of Greeks from
Anatolia was unlikely, especially because their presence was the primary justi-
fication for the Greek campaign to the Asia Minor.67 Under such circumstances,
a mass deportation of all the Bulgarian-speakers would lead to a severe depop-
ulation of Macedonia. This would make Greece look weak.
Moreover, the Greek government had to act as a civilized liberal polity in the eyes
of the international community. This was the first concern of the Governor-General
of Western Macedonia. Before the Treaty of Neuilly was signed and while consider-
ing a deportation proposal made by Alexandros Mazarakis-Ainian,68 Eliakis writes:

In case of a deportation of “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs there will be a terrible manipulation


of the affair. If we listen to the advice of the [local] Greeks then there is a danger either of
turning Northern [Greek] Macedonia into a deserted land, which would call for the
intervention of Europe and would damage our reputation in the eyes of the civilized
world, or of providing the opportunity to these Greeks of all sorts of blackmail that would
disturb human consciousness.69

65
See n. 54.
66
PKA, The State of Affairs of the Population in Western Macedonia, Eliakis to the President of the
Council of Ministers, Abstract of No. 7861 report, 19 October 1918.
67
Venizelos 1919.
68
Alexandros Mazarakis-Ainian (1874–1943) participated in the Macedonian Struggle and later on
in the National Defense Movement. During the Peace Conference he served as special advisor to
Prime Minister Venizelos.
69
PKA, Deportation of Bulgarians, Eliakis to the Ministry of Interior, Abstract of No. 4164 report,
12 June 1919.
Subnational Variation 133

For the above reasons, Eliakis concluded that the most sensible policy was
assimilation. He argued that if the right measures were taken only a few would
not be assimilated:
We are obliged to follow the hard and rough way of proselytizing, through good and expensive
administration, systematically in all sectors of the administration. I am certain that with such
administration we will rapidly have results. And instead of transplanting the local population
with the danger of not replacing them, through this kind of administration, we will implant in
them our ideas and turn them into fanatic Greeks, more fanatic than the old Greeks.70

All in all, with respect to the “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs, my theory correctly


predicted Eliakis’s preferred policies. During World War I, terror and intensive
assimilationist policies would have achieved the exclusion of the pro-Bulgarian
population and successfully assimilated the rest of the Slavic-speaking popula-
tion. “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs were agitated and mobilized by an enemy power
while the Greek administration was fighting a war to recapture its lost territories.
Following World War I, Greece wanted to preserve the international status quo
in Macedonia, thus intensive assimilationist policies were the preferred choice
and exclusionary policies would only target specific families of agitators.71
For the whole period under study, 1916–1920, external interference never
stopped. Bulgarian agitators were present in all of Macedonia. Toward the end
of the period under study, as I discussed in Chapter 5, a voluntary population
exchange between Greece and Bulgaria was decided under the Treaty of Neuilly
in 1919. After 1919, a mix of assimilationist and selectively targeted exclu-
sionary policies was the actual policy followed toward this group.
All but one of the alternative hypotheses predict exclusionary policies toward the
“Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs since they spoke a different language; were organized
under a different religious organization, the Exarchate; and had a national home-
land. The status-reversal argument is the only one that predicts assimilationist
policies, because the “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs were also disadvantaged during
the Ottoman times, along with the rest of the Christians. Because of the mixed
strategy followed toward the “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs, one way or another all
hypotheses find support, although the mechanisms they posit do not appear to be
operative. Significantly for my argument, however, the group was not
accommodated.
“Grecomanoi” or “Greek-Leaning” Slavs
“Grecomanoi” was a term used to indicate Slavic speakers with Greek national
consciousness. These people had sided with Greek guerrilla bands during the
Macedonian Struggle (1903–1908) and had opposed the influence of the
Exarchate.72 They were not perceived as mobilized by a competing claim and
were, as expected, targeted with assimilationist policies. In fact, the dominant

70
PKA, On the Ownership of the Fertile Lands, Eliakis to the Ministry of Interior, Abstract of No.
4164 report, 12 June 1919.
71
Hassiotis 2005.
72
Dakin 1966.
134 Empirical Evidence

ideology amongst the Greek ruling elites was that these people were only
linguistically Slavicized but ethnically Greek.
Looking solely at the cultural differences of this non-core group from the core
group could lead to a prediction of exclusion, because they spoke a different
language and most likely were of Slavic origins. The homeland argument like-
wise incorrectly predicts exclusion because Bulgaria could be understood as their
homeland. The status-reversal argument accurately predicts this policy, because
“Greek-leaning” Slavs were a politically disadvantaged group under Ottoman
rule.

Vlach-Speaking Christians
Another Christian non-core group that Eliakis discussed is that of the Vlachs.
Many Vlachs were primarily herders living a nomadic life, while others were
sedentary farmers. A few had settled in larger towns in the Balkans and had
become merchants or artisans. They spoke a Latin dialect akin to modern
Romanian. Most of them lived in the Pindus mountain range, but some also
resided in the hills near trading centers such as Monastir, Grevena, Kastoria,
Koritsa, Moskopol, Veroia, and Edessa.73 Looking at the archival material we
find that the Vlachs were divided into two subgroups by the Greek administra-
tion: “Romanian-leaning” and “Greek-leaning” Vlachs.74

“Romanian-Leaning” Vlachs
The Romanian government began its efforts to “awaken” a Romanian identity
in the Vlachs of Macedonia in the late 1860s. To gain Romania’s support during
the conference in Bucharest, Prime Minister Venizelos declared in 1913 that
Greece would provide autonomy to the Koutsovlach75 schools and churches in
the newly acquired Greek lands.76 The group was recognized as a national
minority, and their schools and churches were funded by the Romanian
state.77 This was the first time that minority provisions of a treaty signed by
Greece referred to a national minority. It was up to the different Vlach commu-
nities to decide if they were “Romanian” or “Greek.” Despite their alliance, the
governments of the two countries competed for their allegiance.
In the eparchy of Grevena there were a few “Romanian-leaning” Vlachs, who
during Ottoman times were under the protection of Romania. Their main
incentive to identify with Romania was to facilitate herding and commerce

73
For more on this area, see Alvanos 2005.
74
The terms Eliakis uses are Roumanizontes and Hellinovlachoi, respectively.
75
Koutsovlachs is another name used for Vlachs in Greece. The language of this group was Vlach, a
Latin based language close to modern day Romanian. Most of these people were bilingual at the
time and most of them only speak Greek in contemporary Greece.
76
For more on the Romanian support for and links with this population, see Vlasidis 1998.
77
Mavrogordatos 2003: 16. In Chapter 2, I discussed the logic behind externally supporting a non-
core group in an allied state with special reference to the case of Romania in the Balkans.
Subnational Variation 135

with Romania.78 Romania had pursued a national agitation campaign in


European Turkey during the late nineteenth century, and with the Treaty of
Bucharest in 1913, Romania achieved the recognition of Romanian minorities in
Serbia, Bulgaria, and Greece. Romanian propaganda in Macedonia waned
immediately after its occupation by the Greek army, despite the treaty provi-
sions; however, it was spurred during World War I under the temporary French
military administration. The civil servant for finance at Grevena, Askarides,
wrote to Eliakis:

If the French Administration lasts longer and if the National Defense [government] does
not incorporate the eparchy of Grevena soon, then they [“Romanian-leaning” Vlachs]
will prevail over the Greek element since they are working systematically and intensely in
order to establish a precedent which I hope will not be recognized as a permanent
situation.79

During World War I Eliakis was mostly worried about the spread of “Romanian
propaganda.” Unlike most Muslims and “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs, who were
perceived to be supported by enemy powers, Romania was an ally; therefore, the
only reasonable policy toward the pro-Romanian Vlachs was to accommodate
them while presenting Greece as a better and more prestigious protector of their
rights. Eliakis firmly believed that as soon as the “Romanian-leaning” Vlachs
realized that they no longer had a need for external protection, then with the help
of school, military service, and church, they would become “pure Greeks.”
In 1917, Eliakis warned Venizelos’s government that the Italian authorities
there had approached the “Romanian-leaning” Vlachs in Grevena in order to
change them into “Italian-leaning” Vlachs. The Italians presented the idea of
self-determination to the Vlachs living in the Pindus mountain range, and while
the Italian troops were withdrawing, many locals expressed such desires. The
Greek police arrested some of the rebels who were against Greek sovereignty.
However, the ambassadors of both Italy and Romania protested to the Greek
government over these arrests. Eliakis interfered and asked to meet with the
prisoners before they were taken to the court-martial in Thessaloniki.

I asked them why they were arrested and they pretended that they had no clue or
attributed their arrest to defamations by their enemies. I asked them if they are Greek,
and they hesitated to deny the Greek national identity; some even said “if only more were
like us.. . .” Following these questions, I talked to them for a long time in this manner: I
told them, that since I hear that they speak Greek, I consider them Greek. And they should
boast for being Greek since they have the most glorious history in the world.80

78
PKA, “Romanian-leaning” Vlachs, Eliakis to Venizelos, Abstract of No. 5359 report, 18 October
1917.
79
PKA, “Romanian-leaning” Vlachs, Eliakis to the Provisional Government, Abstract of No. 389
report, 27 January 1917.
80
PKA, “Romanian-leaning” Vlachs, Eliakis to Venizelos, Abstract of No. 5359 report, 18 October
1917.
136 Empirical Evidence

This is a typical example of Eliakis’s cultivation of the local population. He


would emphasize the superiority of Hellenism and Greek culture in general,
while at the same time he would attempt to convince them of their Greekness.
Sometimes he highlighted the linguistic attributes of the population he
addressed, other times their religious affiliation, and sometimes even their
dress, like in the following report:

The inhabitants of upper Grammatikovon, where the liturgy is in the Romanian lan-
guage, are “Romanian-leaning” Vlachs and almost Romanians. The potential military
recruits of this village are so fanatical that they did not enlist in the last draft; instead they
went to work for the English service station. Because of this, the committee of grain
storage in Kailaria did not want to supply grain to this village. So the head of this village
came to complain. I asked him if he is a Greek and he replied “Don’t you see what I am
wearing?” pointing to his dress. I answered that I saw him wearing the Greek fustanella81
and that I heard him speak Greek, which means that he is Greek, and one of the best for
that matter, since the Evzones that also wear the fustanella are the best soldiers of the
Greek Army. On this basis and with the above spirit I spoke to him and I could tell the
powerful impression it produced. I made him wonder how he could have been unaware
that he is Greek.82

More important for my argument, Eliakis moderated his assimilationist tend-


encies because of the geopolitical situation. Although he tried to instill Greek
feelings in the “Romanian-leaning” Vlachs, he also told a group of them:

If any of you has Romanian feelings, if he is Romanian, I respect his feelings, because
Romania is a friend and allied power. We share both friends and enemies with her and we
have no conflicting interests since Romania is not considering jumping over the Balkan
Peninsula to come and conquer the territories you inhabit.83

Eliakis was willing to respect their Romanian feelings, both because he had to,
and because he considered them to be geopolitically harmless, because Romania
was an ally. Accommodation was the policy toward the “Romanian-leaning”
Vlachs. A population exchange between Greece and Romania was not consi-
dered at all. Greece needed Romania as an ally, and Bulgaria was the common
enemy. Finally, the absence of a common border with Romania minimized the
perception of threat for the Greek side.

“Greek-Leaning” Vlachs
“Hellenovlachoi” was the term used to refer to the second Vlach-speaking non-
core group identified by the Greek administration that had Greek national
consciousness; it stood for “Greek-leaning” Vlachs. These people had sided

81
A fustanella is a skirt-like garment worn by men in the Balkans up to the end of the nineteenth
century. It was the uniform of the Evzones (light infantry) until World War II; today it is worn by
the Greek Presidential (formerly Royal) Guard in Athens.
82
PKA, “Romanian-leaning” Vlachs, Eliakis to Venizelos, Abstract of No. 5359 report, 18 October
1917.
83
Ibid.
Subnational Variation 137

with the Greek guerrilla bands during the Macedonian Struggle (1903–1908)
and had either resisted or escaped the influence of the Romanian and Italian
propaganda. They were not mobilized by a competing claim and were thus good
candidates for assimilationist policies. The policies toward both subgroups con-
form to the expectations of my theory.
Looking at the Vlach-speaking population and its two subgroups, we observe
that focusing on cultural differences alone does not help us account for the variation
in nation-building policies. Both groups spoke a Latin-based language and they
should thus be excluded. Instead, the former non-core group, the “Romanian-
leaning” Vlachs, was accommodated while the latter, the “Greek-leaning”
Vlachs, was targeted with assimilationist policies. Moreover, the homeland argu-
ment cannot help us distinguish between the two subgroups of Vlach-speakers
either, because Romania viewed both groups as potential co-ethnics. The status-
reversal argument correctly predicts a policy of assimilation toward the “Greek-
leaning” Vlachs, but is incorrect in the case of the “Romanian-leaning” ones, who
were accommodated instead. Both groups were disadvantaged during the Ottoman
times, and based on this fact, we would expect the Greek administration to pursue
assimilationist policies toward both of them.
Finally, focusing on the religious affiliation of the two subgroups leads to
similar predictions. Because both groups were Christian Orthodox, they should
be targeted with assimilationist policies; however, only the “Greek-leaning”
Vlachs were targeted while the “Romanian-leaning” ones were accommodated.
To be sure, assimilationist tendencies were expressed by Eliakis, but the policy
during that period was one of accommodating their differences of the latter group
through the state’s acceptance of Romanian schools and Romanian churches
operating in Greece.

Greek-Speaking Christians
Within the “Greeks,” the Greek-speaking or Greek dialect-speaking Christian
Orthodox population, there was a group referred to by Eliakis as “Skenitai” or
“Sarakatsans.” They dressed like Vlachs and lived nomadic lives, but they were
considered by everyone, including Eliakis, to be Greeks. There were approxi-
mately 40,000 in Greek Macedonia, referred to as Skenitai (tent-people) for
their way of life. In the winter they settled in the lowlands, especially
Chalkidiki, while in the summer they tented up in the mountains. This group
apparently made no claims to the communal property of the places it inhabited
and it did not interfere with their administration.84 Eliakis suggested the
settlement of this population among groups who had foreign national leanings
and recommended its conscription into the Greek army.85 Not surprisingly, all

84
In contrast to the Sarakatsans, according to Eliakis, the explanation behind the emergence of
“Romanian-leaning” Vlachs was that they were people who emigrated to Romania, but when
they came back they were in constant competition with the sedentary local population.
85
PKA, Skenitai, Eliakis to Venizelos, Abstract of No. 5359 report, 18 October 1917.
138 Empirical Evidence

theories make the same prediction for the Sarakatsans: assimilation. They were
indeed targeted with standard assimilationist policies such as schooling and
military conscription.

what explains variation in nation-building


policies?
The evidence provided largely supports my geostrategic argument. Granted, a
set of reports written by a particular administrator over a four-year period is not
a representative sample of the Greek government as a whole – not to mention
governments in general; however, this level of analysis is crucial if one wants to
test the microfoundations of an argument. A theory might make the right
predictions, but fail to identify the correct causal mechanisms at work. In this
chapter, historical contextualization coupled with rich archival material allowed
me to test both the predictions and the causal logic underlying my theory.
The different combinations of interstate relations with external powers and
foreign policy goals, lead to different predictions of my theory. Looking at
Tables 6.2 and 6.3 we see that, consistent with my argument, non-core groups
without any external power supporting them and claiming their allegiance were
targeted with assimilationist policies, and were the least likely to get minority
rights protection. Groups supported by current or prospective allies were accom-
modated (“Romanian-leaning” Vlachs and Albanians, respectively).
During World War I, we find that Eliakis’s goal was securing Western
Macedonia for the Greek kingdom by neutralizing both internal and external
enemies (see Table 6.2). Besides dealing with direct security concerns, he had to
counteract the propaganda of the various competitors in the region. Under these
circumstances, exclusionary policies were pursued toward enemy-supported
non-core groups (Koniareoi and “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs). Toward the end
of World War I, however, Eliakis became more optimistic about the assimil-
ability of certain non-core groups.
Following World War I, the Greek administration was in favor of the
international status quo and adopted an assimilationist policy toward enemy-
supported non-core groups with an emphasis on political equality and egali-
tarianism toward the population regardless of cultural, religious, or linguistic
differences (Koniareoi and “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs). Consistent with my
theory, the perception of these non-core groups was to a great extent endoge-
nous to the external interference by competing states. The past political behav-
ior of the various non-core groups vis-à-vis the Greek cause in the region prior
to the annexation of the territories was also central in the planning of nation-
building policies.
Another shortcut the Greek administration used in order to determine
whether a non-core group was assimilable was not the particular marker that
differentiated it from the core group but rather the incentives and constraints put
in place by international and bilateral treaties with neighboring states and
Great Powers (France and Britain). For instance, the linguistic assimilation of
Subnational Variation 139

Koniareoi is a quite different case from that of “Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs since,


first, the linguistic and educational rights of the Muslims were protected by
international treaties and, second, the Greek state was in the process of annexing
more areas with significant Muslim population and thus had to prove itself to
them and the Great Powers. Even though Muslims could get an education
in Turkish, Greek was also introduced as an obligatory language in their
curriculum. To be sure, besides the constraints – which my theory emphasizes –
there were also perceived opportunities, as in the case of the Albanians.
Interstate alliances had an effect on the planning of nation-building policies in
two ways: through a retrospective assessment based on existing alliances, and a
prospective one based on future opportunities for useful alliances.
How well do alternative arguments do in this context? State- and regional-
level hypotheses such as levels of economic development, regime type, under-
standings of nationhood, international norms, and so forth are held constant by
design. There is, however, group level variation. Looking at Tables 6.4 and 6.5,
we see that cultural-distance arguments cannot explain most of the variation.
For example, with respect to the “Bulgarian-leaning Slavs” and “Romanian-
leaning” Vlachs, Eliakis’s reasoning was not one of cultural differences or
affinities, but rather on diplomatic relations and war dynamics. The former
group was supported by an enemy power and was thus targeted with intense
assimilationist and ultimately exclusionary measures, while the latter was

table 6.5. Evaluating Existing Explanations in Western Macedonia, 1918–1920

Non-Core Status
Groups Language Religion Reversal Homeland Policy

“Greek- Exclusion Assimilation Assimilation Exclusion Assimilation


leaning”
Slavs
“Greek- Exclusion Assimilation Assimilation Exclusion Assimilation
leaning”
Vlachs
Sarakatsans Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation Assimilation
Valaades Assimilation Exclusion Exclusion Assimilation Assimilation
Albanians Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion Accommodation
“Romanian- Exclusion Assimilation Assimilation Exclusion Accommodation
leaning”
Vlachs
Koniareoi Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion Exclusion Accommodation/
Assimilation
“Bulgarian- Exclusion Exclusion Assimilation Exclusion Assimilation/
leaning” Voluntary
Slavs Exchange

Note: Incorrect predictions are shown in italics.


140 Empirical Evidence

supported by an ally and was accommodated. Even where such arguments make
correct predictions, it is for the wrong reasons. Koniareoi were not targeted with
exclusionary policies during World War I due to their cultural difference, but
because of their links to the Ottoman Empire, which was fighting on the side of
the Central Powers.
The status-reversal argument does better. This argument, however, can only
differentiate between conflict and no conflict and thus has little to say about
instances of assimilation or accommodation. For example, although the
Koniareoi were members of the dominant group before the Greek occupation,
Eliakis pursued a policy of accommodation in terms of their culture and lan-
guage. This policy directly contradicts the status-reversal argument. It also
contradicts my argument, which predicts exclusion during and assimilation
after World War I for this group, but the archival material helps us to understand
this policy choice. As Eliakis stated, this phase of accommodation (coupled with
a certain degree of internal displacement and colonization) was just a step before
assimilationist policies.86
The homeland argument does worse than the status-reversal argument.
Whether a non-core group has an external homeland or not is important, but
it does not help us predict which nation-building policy the host state will
pursue. My theory suggests that looking at the degree to which the homeland
interferes with the fate of its “ethnic kin,” as well as the interstate relations of the
host state with the homeland, is crucial. Moreover, besides the existence of
external involvement (covert or overt), the foreign policy goals of the host
state are an important factor in the planning of nation-building policies.

conclusion
Overall, while the members of the core group were less tolerant of previously
dominant groups and tried to undermine their assimilation so that they would
not have to share the national wealth with them, the ruling political elite pursued
policies according to geopolitical and security concerns.
Non-core groups without an external power supporting them and claiming
their allegiance were targeted with assimilation and were the least likely to
receive minority rights protection. External interference and support for specific
non-core groups by competing states affected the core group elites’ perception of
threat and the nation-building policies they pursued. When interstate relations
changed, policy changes followed suit.
The devastating military defeat of the Greek army by Mustafa Kemal’s forces
in 1922, however, led to the Agreement of Moudania in October, which resulted
in the incorporation of Eastern Thrace into Turkey. The Lausanne Conference
(December 1922–May 1923) brought about the largest “peaceful” compulsory
population exchange in history.87 The 1922 disaster in Asia Minor symbolized

86
For a discussion of the distinction between transitional versus terminal policies, see Chapter 5.
87
Clark 2006; Ladas 1932; Yıldırım 2006.
Subnational Variation 141

the end of Greek irredentist politics, but not of Greek nation-building.


Territorial expansion was no longer on the agenda; however, national integra-
tion was.88 National, religious, ethnic, and cultural minorities, as well as refu-
gees from Turkey, had to be integrated into the society and assimilated into the
Greek nation.
The borders drawn after the Balkan Wars, World War I, and the Greek-
Turkish War and the treaties that followed them brought most Christians, who
were previously under Ottoman Muslim rule, under the jurisdiction of Christian
nation-states (the KSCS, Greece, or Bulgaria). However, the population was so
mixed, the territorial competition so bloody, and the propaganda so intense that
non-core groups still existed. People who sided during the war with the “wrong”
side were acutely aware that they were perceived by their host state as disloyal.
This situation of mutual distrust in and of itself would have been hard to over-
come with even the best-planned policies, but it was worsened by continued
external involvement, even after the signing of the peace treaties, by revisionist
states dissatisfied with the international status quo. Building trust was a chal-
lenging enterprise.

88
Mavrogordatos 1983.
7

Temporal Variation
Serbian Nation-Building toward Albanians, 1878–1941

[F]or us Serbs Kossovo is much less a geographical and strategical term than a term
of our national psychology, a term announcing a historical synthesis, proclaiming
to the world that the Serbs have been able to transform a military defeat into a
moral victory, to develop a national tragedy into a national glory.1

We have explored the explanatory power of my argument across the Balkan states
immediately following World War I and probed it at the subnational level in one
Greek province during and after World War I, but how well does my argument
explain variation over longer periods of time? In this chapter, I trace the logic
underlying the policies followed by the Serbian ruling political elites2 toward the
Albanians in Toplica and Kosanica at the end of the nineteenth century and in
Kosovo and Metohija3 from 1912 to 1941. I test my theory against archival
material, secondary sources, and memoirs, as well as available newspapers and

1
Mijatovich 1917: 219.
2
Serbia did not formally exist as an administrative unit within the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and
Slovenes or later within the Kingdom of Yugoslavia. However, we can definitely talk about the
Serbian political elites as well as the “Serbian lands” during the Interwar period. For more, see
Petranović 2002: xxiii-48.
3
Under the Ottomans modern-day Kosovo was part of three vilayets: Bosna, Kosova, and Monastir
before 1877 and part of Kosova vilayet after 1878 (Magocsi 2002: 85, 119). During the early
twentieth century this territory was split between Serbia (Zvečan, Kosovo, and southern Metohija)
and Montenegro (northern Metohija). In 1922 internal borders changed again and Kosovo was split
between three oblasts: Priština/Kosovo, Čačak/Raška, and Cetinje/Zeta. In 1929, with the trans-
formation of the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes (KSCS) to the Kingdom of Yugoslavia,
Kosovo was divided among three banovinas: Zeta Banovina, Morava Banovina, and Vardar
Banovina. This is the area that corresponded to the Autonomous Province of Kosovo and
Metohija part of the constituent republic of Serbia in Communist Yugoslavia. The “Metohija”
part was dropped in the 1974 Constitution, and thus the Socialist Autonomus Province of
Kosovo. Today this territory is still claimed by the Serbs, but a new state, the Republic of Kosovo,
has declared its independence in 2008 as a result of the 1999 Kosovo War. In this book, when I refer
to Kosovo I refer roughly to the present-day territory of Kosovo unless otherwise stated in the text.
For more on the changing boundaries of Kosovo and Metohija, see Krstić-Brano 2004: 27–34. For
more on ethnographic maps of the region during Ottoman times, see Grimm 1984: 41–53.

142
Temporal Variation 143

journals from the period under study. I find that nation-building policies were
not chosen based on objective measures of cultural distance, non-core group
preferences, domestic political developments in the host state, or deep-rooted
ethnic hatred between the non-assimilated and the core-group but rather based
on a combination of other factors: the level of danger of secessionist claims by
externally backed non-core group elites as perceived by the host government,
bilateral state relations of the latter with the external power supporting the
group, and the foreign policy goals of the host state.
Studying Serbian policies toward Albanians for a period of fifty years allows
me to keep important regional-, state-, and group-level characteristics constant
and isolate the effect of my main variables of interest. The region experienced
successive annexations and the Albanian population residing there was exposed
to a variety of nation-building policies, ensuring variation in both my dependent
and independent variables. Many historians and political analysts read this
period – if not the whole modern history of Serb–Albanian relations – as a
period of repression and do not analyze the fluctuations in policy.4 I offer a
novel interpretation of events.
The main independent variables – perceived level of external support for the
non-core group, interstate relations between the host state and the external
power, and foreign policy preferences of the host state – vary during this period.
In particular, there was important variation in external support of the non-core
group under study. Initially, the Albanian national movement agitated parts of
the population; later on the Albanian state took over that role. For a short period
when the interstate relations between the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes
(KSCS) and Albania normalized, external involvement in Kosovo ceased. But
once again the Italian involvement during the late 1920s in the region – through
the capture of Albania – and its plans to undermine the Yugoslav state brought
about a new era of externally sponsored agitation in Kosovo. Interstate relations
between the external backers of the Kosovo Albanians (Albania and Italy) and
the Serbian ruling elites (Kingdom of Serbia and, later, within the KSCS) varied
over time and so did the latter’s perception of the involvement by external
powers in their internal affairs.
Serbian elites’ foreign policy goals also shifted during this period: from
dissatisfied with the international status quo – no access to the Adriatic and
unredeemed co-ethnics – before World War I, to working for its preservation
after the “Great War” – when they achieved both South-Slav unification and
access to the Adriatic. The important variation in my dependent and main
independent variables together with the host of variables that are held constant
by design render this region an ideal location to study the politics of nation-
building and test my theory.
I organize this chapter in four sections. In the first, I describe the exclusionary
policies of the expansionist Serbian Kingdom toward Albanians before World

4
For example, see Babuna 2000; Malcolm 1998; Poulton 2003; Stefanović 2005.
144 Empirical Evidence

External Power Support

Yes

Interstate Relations No

Ally Enemy

Exclusion
Lost Territory
Accommodation 1878−1912
(Revisionist) 1912−1915
Host State
(Foreign Assimilation
Policy Goals)

Gained Assimilation/Colonization
Accommodation
Territory 1918−1923
c.1924
(Status Quo) 1925−1941

figure 7.1. Serbian nation-building toward Albanians, 1878–1941.

War I (see Figure 7.1). In the second, I describe the assimilationist policies that
were implemented in the KSCS after World War I, when the Serbian elites were
in favor of the international status quo. I also focus on a fascinating turn of
events that transformed interstate relations between Albania and the KSCS circa
1924 and as a result led to a brief period of accommodation of Kosovo
Albanians. In the third section, I explore the effect of internal political develop-
ments in the Kingdom of Yugoslavia on the choice of nation-building policies
toward the Albanians in Kosovo. Finally, I conclude with a discussion of the fit
between my theory and the patterns identified in the previous sections in light of
alternative explanations.

the revisionist kingdom of serbia

Serbian-Albanian Relations Prior to 1912: Exclusion


The Serbian national revival focused on language and Orthodox Christianity,
both of which separated them from their Ottoman rulers. Before Serbia’s inde-
pendence in 1878, Serbian elites focused largely on two categories of Muslims:
the Islamized Slavs, who in their view should convert back to Christianity or be
excluded from the nation, and the Turkish speaking Muslim settlers, who had
come into the area after the conquests of the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries and
who should return to Anatolia.
During the nineteenth century Serbian animosity toward Muslims – and
primarily the urban Muslims who were seen as exploiting the rural Serbs and
as an obstacle to national independence – manifested itself in various writings
Temporal Variation 145

but also in Serbian uprisings.5 However, this animosity was rarely channeled
toward Albanian Muslims until late in the nineteenth century – except when
Albanians would offer their military services to the Ottomans against Serbs.6
Toward the end of the nineteenth century, the Serbian army – pursuing a
Greater Serbia – decided to deport the Albanian population living in Toplica
and Kosanica, two regions incorporated into the newly independent Serbian
state in 1878 (see Map 7.1).7 The Albanian national movement claiming the
loyalties of these Albanians had competing territorial claims to Serbia and thus
accommodating the Albanians was also precluded as a possibility. The Albanian
national awakening was in full swing8 and the Serbs would not allow a potential
security threat within their newly drawn borders.9 Consistent with my theory,
exclusion was the policy pursued by the Serbian ruling political elites (see
Table 7.1).
As an upshot of these exclusionary policies in the late nineteenth century,
“The Albanians expelled from these regions moved over the new border to
Kosovo, where the Ottoman authorities forced the Serb population out of the
border region and settled the refugees there.”10 Consequently, relations between
Albanians and Serbs deteriorated to unprecedented levels. According to
Stefanović this was the turning point that influenced all future interactions
between the two groups.11 We will see that this view of the interethnic relations
in Kosovo, although consistent with the events in 1912, cannot account for
variation in state policies toward Albanians in the first half of the twentieth
century.

The Initial Occupation of Kosovo: Exclusion


After the occupation of Kosovo and part of Metohija by the Serbian forces
the ruling elites had to come to a decision about how to treat the
Albanians living there.12 The Serbian elites at the time were still motivated
by revisionist foreign policy goals13 aiming at the creation of a Greater

5
Edwards 1969; Garašanin 1998; Karadžić 1972; Njegoš 1930.
6
For more on the nineteenth-century history of the relations, see Banac 1984; Stefanović 2005:
465–492.
7
Horvat 1988: 71; Stefanović 2005: 469.
8
Austin 2004: 235- 253; Skendi 1967. The Albanian national movement first developed in modern-
day Kosovo during the Great Eastern Crisis of 1875–1878. For more, see Zavalani 1969: 55–92.
9
Bogdanović 1986.
10
Popović 1987: 80.
11
Stefanović 2005: 470.
12
For the Serbian perspective, see Jagodić 2009 and 2010. For the Austrian perspective, see the
reports of a Jewish Parliamentarian member of the Social-Democratic Party in Vienna, Freundlich
1997: 332–360.
13
To put it in International Relations terms, Serbia was a limited aims revisionist, see Schweller
2006: 88. Unlike Hitler, Napoleon, or Alexander the Great, Serbia was not a major power and
therefore was incapable of becoming an unlimited aims revisionist state where the complete
domination of all of the Great Powers is the aim. For a Croatian perspective, see Beljo 1992.
146 Empirical Evidence

map 7.1. Vilayet of Kosova, 1875–1878. Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:


Kosovo02.png.

Serbia.14 In particular, the goal of the Serbian government was the annexation
of parts of the Kosova vilayet15 and parts of geographic Macedonia,16 but also

14
Serbian nationalism had taken a hold of the soldier’s imagination as well. Čedomilj Mijatović
(1842–1932), a Serbian statesman and leader of the Progressive Party who served as Minister of
Finance and Minister of Foreign Affairs, informs us in his memoirs that Serbian leaders did not
have to make long and stirring speeches in order to motivate their soldiers; they only uttered, “Let
us avenge Kossovo!” Mijatovich 1917: 220; for an Albanian perspective, see Verli 1999.
15
Bataković, “Kosovo and Metohija: A Historical Survey.”
16
Wilkinson 1951; Stefanidis et al. 2010.
Temporal Variation 147

table 7.1. Serbian Nation-Building toward Albanians, 1878–1941

Period State Host State Albania Prediction Policy

1878–1912 Kingdom of Revisionist No Exclusion Exclusion


Serbia State
1912–1915 Kingdom of Revisionist Enemy Exclusion Exclusion
Serbia
1918–1923 KSCS Status Enemy Assimilation Assimilation
Quo
c.1924 KSCS Status Ally Accommodation Accommodation
Quo
1925–1937 KSCS/ Status Enemy Assimilation Assimilation
Yugoslavia Quo
1937–1941 Yugoslavia Status Enemy Assimilation Plans for
Quo Exclusion

of a significant part of contemporary Northern Albania, which would guaran-


tee access to the Adriatic Sea.17
Albanians in Kosovo were mobilized by the Albanian national independ-
ence movement, which actually began in the Kosova vilayet in the late nine-
teenth century with the support of Austria-Hungary and Italy.18 Albanian
territorial aspirations, expressed by the Prizren League in 1878, extended to
territories from four different vilayets, including that of Kosova.19 Austria-
Hungary and Italy were prepared to do anything to prevent Serbian access to
the Adriatic Sea, while Russia and France operated as protectors of Serbia in
the international scene. The Serbian government realized that it had to change
the ethnic balance of the population in the region in order to legitimize its
territorial aspirations.20
Given this setting, my theory predicts that nation-building policies toward
the Albanians should have been exclusionary (Table 7.1). Indeed, in the period
following the annexation (1912–1915), it is estimated that around 25,000
Albanians were killed and approximately 120,000 were forced to flee from
Kosovo as a result of acts of intimidation and violence pursued by the Serbian
army.21 Many of the existing explanations that I discussed above would also

17
Statements indicating this desire can be found from the early twentieth century in the work of
Jovan Cvijić (1865–1927), a famous Serbian geographer. Cvijić served as president of the Serbian
Royal Academy of Sciences and was also rector of the University of Belgrade.
18
Kola 2003; Skendi 1967; Zavalani 1969.
19
Hadri 1995; Skendi 1967.
20
Mazower 2001: 124.
21
Malcolm 1998: 254, 258. Freundlich (1997) claims that the Serbian government aimed at the
extermination of the Albanians in the lands they were annexing.
148 Empirical Evidence

predict exclusion in this situation; however, as we will see below, Albanians


were also targeted with assimilationist policies and even granted minority
rights in subsequent periods. Existing arguments cannot account for this
variation since their predictions remain constant over time. My argument
does account for these shifts because it focuses on variation in interstate
relations and host states’ foreign policy goals.
To understand the logic of this policy choice and test the microfoundations of
my argument it is necessary to take a closer look at the events that preceded this
exclusionary policy decision. By the beginning of the twentieth century, nation-
alism as an ideology was at its peak. During the Balkan Wars, Serbia expanded
significantly. Not surprisingly, armies of nation-states that wanted to secure
territories had to ensure the right “ethnic balance” on the ground. Serbian
nationhood – like that of most Christian Balkan states at the time – had been
built in opposition to the Ottoman Muslims. In the case of Kosovo, which was
primarily inhabited by Albanian Muslims but annexed by Serbia, the initial
strategy was a mix of violence and intimidation. This was the first time that
the Serbian expansion reached a region inhabited primarily by an alien popula-
tion (see Map 7.2).22
The situation was not that different from what took place in 1878. The
Albanians, however, had a more developed national movement by 191223 and
were embittered by the centralization efforts of the Young Turks that also aimed at
their assimilation into the stillborn Ottoman identity.24 In the meantime, Albanian
militants – pursuing their own nation-building project – had been attacking and
intimidating Serbs living in the Ottoman Empire around the turn of the twentieth
century under the protection of the Sultan. According to Jovan Cvijić, as many as
150,000 Serbs fled from Sandžak and Kosovo during that period, 1876–1912.25
These developments guaranteed an explosive mix.
Despite this background, faced with the Ottoman forces during the first
Balkan War, Pašić – the Serbian Prime Minister at the time and a close friend
of the Tsar and the Russian Government26 – tried to take the Kosovo Albanians
on his side by offering in return guarantees for religious freedom and cultural
rights within the Serbian state. The Albanian leaders refused to collaborate;
many were backed by Austria-Hungary,27 and a few actually fought on the side
of the Ottomans.28 It is hard to know what would have happened if Albanian
leaders had decided to collaborate with the Serbs during the first Balkan War.

22
Banac 1984: 293.
23
Skendi 1967.
24
Findley 2010; Ülker 2005: 617.
25
Stefanović 2005: 472.
26
Mijatovich 1917: 232. For more on Pašić, see Djokić 2010; Dragnich 1974.
27
Vickers 1998: 77.
28
Bataković 1991: 173; Lampe 2000: 92, 97; Stefanović 2005: 474.
Temporal Variation 149

map 7.2. Territorial development of Serbia, 1817–1913. Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/


wiki/File:Serbia1817_1913.png.

Assuming that Pašić’s offer was sincere, the fact that Pašić made this offer
suggests that things could have turned out otherwise and ethnic cleansing
might have been averted. Not surprisingly given the situation, the policy of the
Serbian forces when they annexed Kosovo in 1912 was to kill or force to
emigrate as many Albanians as possible and colonize the territory with Serbs.
150 Empirical Evidence

illu stration 7.1. Üsküb: King of Serbia welcomed by mayor. Source: Library of
Congress Prints and Photographs Division, Washington, D.C.

The Serbian authorities were trying to establish control, disarm disloyal groups,
and force unwanted aliens to leave (see Illustration 7.1).29
In a memorandum that Mary Edith Durham30 compiled for Aubrey
Herbert31 – a British MP for Somerset – we read that at least 25,000
Albanians were killed in the vilayet of Kosova. According to McCarthy, between
7,000 and 10,000 Albanians were killed in the areas of Kumanovo and
Pristina,32 while over 25,000 refugees fled to Northern Albania.33 Durham
reported that:

The Servian [sic] officers declared in the intoxication of victory that the best way to pacify
Albania was to exterminate the Albanians. Between Koumanoval and Üsküb, they

29
Naturally, there were dissenting voices to almost all of the Serbian and Albanian strategies I am
discussing in this chapter; but for the sake of brevity and a more coherent narrative I do not cover
them here. For more on alternative Serbian views, see Banac 1984: 296–297 and Stefanović 2005.
30
Mary Edith Durham (1863–1944) was an English reporter on the Balkans and Albanian and
Montenegrin affairs in particular. She was also a relief worker and a lobbyist for the Albanian
cause. For more, see Harry Hodgkinson’s introduction in Durham 2001: i–xx.
31
Aubrey Nigel Henry Molyneux Herbert (1880–1923) was a conservative member of Parliament
for the southern division of Somerset from 1911 to 1918 and for Yeovil from 1918 to 1923. He
was a supporter of Albania and often corresponded with Edith Durham. Twice he was offered the
throne of Albania.
32
McCarthy 1995: 141.
33
Durham 2001: 29, Nikolić 2003.
Temporal Variation 151

massacred over three thousand people; in the vicinity of Prishtina five thousand Albanians
were killed.34

Although this seems like evidence of deep-rooted ethnic hatreds at work, con-
temporary observers suggested that these efforts had little to do with religious or
cultural difference. In a confidential report by the British chargé in Belgrade
Dayrell Crackanthorpe35 to the Foreign Secretary Sir Edward Grey36 we find
further evidence supporting my argument.37 Crackanthorpe, reporting on civil
and religious freedoms in the new territories of Serbia, writes:

The signal lack of religion noticeable among the large minority of Servians precludes the
possibility of this uncompromising attitude being due to religious intolerance; the real
explanation seems to be that Servians look upon their national Orthodox Church as a
means of propagating not the Kingdom of Heaven, but the Kingdom of Servia.38

The dominant policy was one of exclusion as the archival material demonstrates
and as eyewitness accounts such as those included in the Report of the Carnegie
Endowment for International Peace and even that of Trotsky testify to.39 The
Carnegie Report quotes a letter of a Serbian soldier to the Socialist paper
Radnitchké Noviné:

Appalling things are going on here.. . . Liouma (an Albanian region along the river of the
same name), no longer exists. There is nothing but corpses, dust and ashes. There are
villages of 100, 150, 200 houses, where there is no longer a single man, literally not one.
We collect them in bodies of forty and fifty, and then pierce them with our bayonets to the
last man.40

From the available accounts, Serbian violence toward the local Albanian popula-
tion appears to have been strategic rather than motivated by ethnic hatred or
antipathy. The Kaçaks41 were a serious security concern. The Carnegie Report
mentions that these incidents were part of an effort to repress the Albanian revolts
instigated by Albanians from autonomous Albania and/or by Bulgaria.42
Crackanthorpe corroborated this logic of Serbian policies when he wrote in
May 1914:

34
Memorandum researched by Mary Edith Durham for Aubrey Herbert, MP for Somerset: “The
Albanians must be exterminated,” 1913 Somerset Records Office (DDR/0).
35
Dayrell Crackanthorpe (1870–1950) was a diplomat and at the time British Chargé d’Affaires at
Belgrade.
36
Sir Edward Grey (1862–1933) was British Secretary of State for Foreign Affairs from 1905 to
1916.
37
For the views in the British Foreign Office at the time, see Evans 2008: 105–107.
38
Dayrell Crackanthorpe, Belgrade, to Sir Edward Grey, 26 May 1914, civil and religious freedoms
in the new territories of Servia [FO 371/2110].
39
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace 1914; Lampe 2000: 97; Trotsky 1980: 267.
40
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace 1914: 149.
41
Albanian rebel group. From the Turkish word “kaçaklar,” which means outlaw.
42
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace 1914: 149.
152 Empirical Evidence

It is this constant dread of political propaganda that has coloured, and is still colouring,
the attitude of the Servian Government toward religious minorities in the annexed
territories.. . . It seems . . . that their attitude toward the Moslems has been considerably
coloured by apprehensions lest the indigent Moslem population may become a prey to
political propaganda and a dangerous element of unrest in the event of further trouble
with Albania or Bulgaria, and the desire therefore is to force them to emigrate.43

In a later report, Crackanthorpe adds more information that he received from


the Vice-Consul in Monastir. Interestingly, Crackanthorpe hesitates to believe
this additional information wholeheartedly, as he recognizes that a great deal of
it could be the product of political propaganda. He writes:

I cannot personally guarantee, from information gathered here, the accuracy of the lurid
horrors Greig describes. I think some account should be taken of local exaggeration and
of the fact that the Moslem population, led by Albanian priests, have undoubtedly been
painting things in the blackest colours in the hopes of promoting autonomy. I have found
even the Austrian Legation inclined to accept these reports with a grain of salt, and I
cannot conscientiously recommend their publication in a despatch to be laid before
Parliament.44

Less-studied aspects of these events have to do with the degree of control of the
Serbian administrative apparatus in the newly annexed territories as well as the
quality of implementation of state policies. In other words, it is unclear what
percentage of the actions observed on the ground in Kosovo were dictated by
Belgrade and what was part of a micro-level story of opportunism on the part of
individuals pursuing their private agendas. With respect to administrators, we
do know that they were often selected on the basis of patronage and were not
trained at all. Overall, the conditions of relative anarchy on the ground coupled
with low salaries from the Serbian government were conducive to abuses of
office. Crackanthorpe again illuminates this aspect:

Testimony has reached me from every source of the corrupt and venal character of Servian
administration, the one endeavour of Servian subordinate officials being apparently to
supplement their insufficient pay by every means within their grasp. The principal suffer-
ers have been the Moslems, who, if local reports are to be believed, have been subjected
for some time past to systematic persecution of a callously cruel description by the local
officials. It is difficult to say how far this persecution has taken place with the consent and
connivance of the Central Government.45

43
Mr Dayrell Crackanthorpe, Belgrade, to Sir Edward Grey, 26 May 1914, civil and religious
freedoms in the new territories of Servia [FO 371/2110].
44
Mr Dayrell Crackanthorpe, Belgrade, to Sir E. Crowe, Asst. Under Secretary for Foreign Affairs, 2
June 1914, covering Mr Dayrell Crackanthorpe, Belgrade, to Sir Edward Grey, Foreign Secretary,
2 June 1914, enclosing despatch from Vice-Consul Greig, Monastir, 25 May 1914, on Serbian
occupation and its effects [FO 371/2110].
45
Mr Dayrell Crackanthorpe, Belgrade, to Sir Edward Grey, 26 May 1914, civil and religious
freedoms in the new territories of Servia [FO 371/2110].
Temporal Variation 153

A report by Peckham, British Vice-Counsel in Üsküb, however, suggests that the


Serbian government directed a great deal of what was going on in Kosovo.
Reporting on 14 December 1913, he writes:
I learn on reasonably good authority that a former prefect of Prishtina was relieved of his
duties because he had too much conscience to carry out the Government policy of the
removal of the Albanian population. This, coupled with other indications given in my
previous reports, seems to me to fix the responsibility in pretty high quarters.46

Given the number of killings and forced migrants on the Albanian side following
the annexation of Kosovo (25,000 and 120,000, respectively, according to most
estimates)47 we can conclude that Serbia’s initial nation-building strategy was
that of physical removal of Albanians and colonization with Serbian settlers.48
The Kingdom of Serbia was a small revisionist state faced with a relatively large
and enemy-backed non-core group, which it perceived as a potential threat to its
future territorial integrity. As a result, exclusionary policies ensued.49
Forced assimilation – although not the dominant policy in this period – was
also pursued toward Albanians. According to Banac, Serbian propaganda
“simultaneously dehumanized Albanians, presenting them as utterly incapable
of governing themselves and as the sort of element that ought to be exterminated,
and elevated them to the standing that warranted their assimilation.” The
justification behind the assimilationist policies followed toward some of the
Kosovo Albanians was that many of them were Islamized Serbs who had
eventually become Albanians. The fundamental belief behind this policy was
that the “Albanians had no nationhood and their nationalism was the product of
Austrian and Italian intrigue.” World War I followed soon thereafter, Kosovo
was occupied by Bulgaria and Austria-Hungary, and the Serbian ruling political
elites had to deal with more pressing concerns until 1918.

the status quo kingdom of serbs, croats


and slovenes

Albania Supporting the Kaçak Movement: Assimilation and Colonization


In 1918, the Serbian army assumed control over Kosovo once again. The KSCS
was in favor of the international status quo and wanted to consolidate it.50 The
implementation of exclusionary policies, like the ones pursued during the Balkan
Wars, toward the Kosovo Albanians would not serve this purpose. It would just
add another front. Albanians in Kosovo were still mobilized by a secessionist

46
Vice-Consul Peckham, Üsküb, to Mr Crackanthorpe 14 December 1913, reporting on Serbian
Government policy of the removal of the Albanian population [FO 421/286].
47
Malcolm 1998: 254, 258.
48
For an Albanian perspective, see Verli 1995.
49
Banac 1984: 293–295.
50
Petranović 2002: 11.
154 Empirical Evidence

movement linked to their “brothers” in Albania (the Kaçak movement),51 which


was supported financially by Italy. Given this context, my theory predicts
assimilation (see Table 7.1).52
Indeed, the policies followed by the new government of the KSCS were not as
violent as those of the 1912–1915 period. State policy toward the Albanians was
one of assisted assimilation through the Serbian language education system.53
The elites of the new state wanted to preserve the favorable international status
quo and decided to colonize the territory by giving land to Serbs who wanted to
move there and also used the political system to co-opt local elites.54
Let us take a closer look at the events that took place during this period. After
World War I and the brief administrative split of Kosovo, with Austria ruling in
the north and Bulgaria in the South,55 the territory was incorporated into the
newly formed KSCS. The creation of the KSCS was the outcome of World War I
and the consequent collapse of Austria-Hungary and the Ottoman Empire.56 In
particular, the Slovenian and Croatian fears of Italian domination, coupled with
the long-lasting Serbian desire to unite all of the Serbs into a single state, led to
the unification of the South Slavs.57 The unification took place under the Serbian
Karadjordjević dynasty in 1918 and was recognized by the Paris Peace
Conference in May 1919. The new state, on the side of the winners in World
War I, was in favor of the international status quo.
Before World War I, irredentism and the pursuit of a Greater Serbia clearly
drove Serbian politics. After the end of the war, the political situation was quite
different. Nearly all of the Serbs in the Balkans were included in one state, which
finally had access to the Adriatic. Serbian revisionist goals subsided; however,
the energies of Serbia’s political leaders were now focused on turning the new
kingdom into a centralized state under Serbian hegemony.58
The newly established Kingdom engaged in several territorial disputes with
its neighbors: Italy, Austria, Hungary, Bulgaria, Romania, and Albania – in
other words with all of its neighbors except Greece. Italy supported extremist
movements of Croatians, Slav Macedonians, and Albanians, “hoping to stir
unrest and hasten the end of the new kingdom.”59 Bulgaria supported the
“Macedonian” movement in Southern Serbia. Hungary also envisioned reclaim-
ing its lost territories. Unrest broke out in Vojvodina as early as 1919. And, of

51
For more on the complicated domestic situation in Albania at the time, see Fischer 2007: 21–28;
Kola 2003: 18–19; Pearson 2004: 110–224.
52
For an account of KSCS policies toward minorities during the interwar period, see Janjetović 2005.
53
Poulton and Vickers 1997: 146.
54
Banac 1984: 155–156; Krstić-Brano 2004: 80–81.
55
Austrian rule was clearly accommodative to the Albanians; see Vickers 1998: 261.
56
For more on the Kingdom of the Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes (later Yugoslavia) in the interwar period,
see Banac 1984; Biondich 2007: 203–213; Djilas 1991; Djokić 2003 and 2007; Dragnich 1983;
Lampe 2000; Petranović 2002; Ramet 2006.
57
Sørensen 2009: 70.
58
Tomasevich 1955; Banac 1984.
59
Curtis 1992.
Temporal Variation 155

course, Albania supported the Kaçak movement in Kosovo. The main task of
Yugoslav Ministers of Foreign Affairs in the interwar period was addressing
these threats with the help of Balkan (Little Entente60 and later on the Balkan
Entente61) and European alliances (primarily with France and the Great Britain)
in an effort to secure the favorable status quo.
Exclusionary policies would have jeopardized this status quo. Intimidation,
persecution, and assassinations of Kosovo Albanians were prevalent, but targeting
was selective. Between 1918 and 1921 a small-scale war occurred in Kosovo
between the Serbian military forces and its četas,62 on the one hand, and the
“Committee for the National Defense of Kosovo” and its Kaçaks, on the other.63
The Kosovo Committee, which fought for the liberation of Kosovo and the uni-
fication of all Albanian lands, “was assisted financially by Italy and led by Hoxha
Kadriu from Pristina, and consisted mainly of political exiles from Kosovo.”64
According to the 1921 census there were 436,929 inhabitants in Kosovo at
the time. Sixty-four percent of them (280,440) were Albanian speakers.65 Given
this context, the KSCS government had good reasons to fear the development of
a secessionist movement in Kosovo. The Kosovo Albanians were backed by
Albania and could have threatened the territorial integrity of the KSCS,66 thus
accommodation was also out of the question.67
The Serbs reacted to what they perceived as an externally supported seces-
sionist non-core group,68 which had killed “since the liberation in December
1918 until the present day 800 Orthodox Serbs . . . more than were killed in
Turkish days during a full ten years.”69 In the summer of 1920 the KSCS waged
a small war against Albania.70 Extensive internal displacement of suspected
Kaçaks and their families took place but the KSCS government offered an
amnesty in early 1921.71 The consequent internationalization of this crisis
forced the Great Powers to speed up the delimitation of the Albanian-
Yugoslav border process, which was fueling the conflict.
The KSCS was a status quo power that was faced with a non-core group, the
Kosovo Albanians, supported by an enemy power, Albania. Exclusion might
have led to a war where Italy – and maybe a revived Austria in the future – would
back Albania against the KSCS. Accommodation would only prolong – if not

60
Czechoslovakia, Yugoslavia, and Romania.
61
Greece, Yugoslavia, Romania, and Turkey.
62
Četas were small paramilitary units.
63
Banac 1984: 298, 303–304.
64
Vickers 1998: 93.
65
The Albanian side claims that there were around 700,000 Albanians in Kosovo at the time; see
Ramet 2006.
66
For more on the KSCS concerns regarding the foreign invasion of the country, see Todorović 1979.
67
Austin 2004: 241.
68
Banac 1984: 304.
69
Mr. W. Strang, Belgrade to Earl Curzon 30 August 1921, reporting on colonization under
government auspices in Southern Serbia (FO 371/5725).
70
Banac 1984: 298.
71
Malcolm 1998: 275.
156 Empirical Evidence

exacerbate – the problem. The Kosovo Albanians could be used as an “enemy


within” to destabilize the KSCS. Consistent with my argument, assimilationist
policies – in the form of colonization and internal displacement – were the only
available responses to address this situation (Table 7.1).
The use of Albanian was prohibited for any official purposes,72 Albanian
schools were closed down,73 Albanian children were sent to Serbian schools, and
mosques were used for military and government purposes. “To aid [the assim-
ilation] Bosnian Serbo-Croat-speaking Muslim teachers were used” in the
schools.74
Electoral politics were also marshaled in the assimilationist project. The
Radicals “supplanted the assimilationist role of the Serbian church under new
increasingly secular circumstances and stimulated a Serb consciousness in newly
acquired southeastern Serbia, where it formerly had not existed.”75 The Radical
Party co-opted the local Muslim organization Cemiyet.76 However, this only
lasted until the late 1920s when the Cemiyet ceased to exist because its leader
was accused of plotting a secessionist movement.77 Parallel to these measures,
the government arranged the electoral districts in such a way that Serbs were the
majority in all of them (see Map 7.3).78
Finally, as predicted, the KSCS followed a colonization policy. On 24
September 1920 the government launched its colonization effort in Kosovo
with the Decree on Settlement.79 Serbs and Montenegrins were encouraged to
move into Kosovo and by 1921 “[n]early 7,000 families ha[d] received grants of
land in Southern Serbia, the total area of their holdings being 57,531 hectares, or
about 8 hectares per family.” The selective implementation of the land reform in
the areas contributed to the grievances of the local Albanian population.80 The
same year William Strang81 informed the British government that

This colonization is doubly advantageous from a national point of view: regarded as


economic redistribution, it should bring contentment to many who have either lost their
homes or who have found it impossible to subsist without distress on the barren lands
they have hitherto occupied . . . and in the second place it establishes a sound and loyal
population in a region where races and religions are mixed and loyalty doubtful.. . . At
whose expense these lands are found, it is not easy to say.. . . It is certain, however, that in

72
Vickers 1998: 103.
73
Banac 1984: 298–299.
74
Poulton and Vickers 2007: 146.
75
Banac 1984: 155–156.
76
Islam Muhafazai Hukuk Cemiyet (Society for the Preservation of Muslim Rights) was a Muslim
organization for the Turks and Albanians of Southern regions of the KSCS.
77
Banac 1984: 378.
78
Stefanović 2005: 479.
79
For more on the colonization policy, see Banac 1984: 299–301; Krstić-Brano 2004: 80;
Marmullaku 1975: 138.
80
Sørensen 2009: 70.
81
William Strang (1893–1978) served in the British embassy in Belgrade from 1919 to 1922.
Temporal Variation 157

map 7.3. Oblasts in the KSCS from 1922 to 1929. Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/
File:Podjela_Kraljevine_SHS_na_33_oblasti.jpg.

some cases a deliberate attempt has been made to drive out or destroy Albanian
Mussulman population and install loyal Serbs in their place.82

Ahmet Zogolli (later renamed King Zog) became Prime Minister of Albania
in 1922 but his rule encountered intense opposition. A great deal of the dis-
contentment had to do with his lack of enthusiasm on the Kosovo issue, that is,
liberating Kosovo and annexing it to Albania. He favored focusing first on
domestic problems that Albania faced and then pursuing an irredentist agenda
with respect to Kosovo.83 This position earned him many enemies. According to
others84 his position on the Kosovo issue was the result of his rivalry with leaders
such as Hasan Prishtina.85

82
Mr. W. Strang, Belgrade to Earl Curzon 30 August 1921, reporting on colonization under
government auspices in Southern Serbia (FO 371/5725).
83
Fischer 2007: 19–49.
84
Kola 2003: 19.
85
Hasan Prishtina (1873–1933) was an Albanian national leader and briefly became Prime Minister
of Albania in 1921. Hasan Prishtina together with Hoxhë Kadriu, Bajram Curri, and others
created the Committee for the National Protection of Kosovo.
158 Empirical Evidence

Regardless, Bishop Fan Noli86 and his Democratic Party managed to take
over the government for six months and forced Zog to flee to Yugoslavia. As we
will see in the next section, accommodation of the Kosovo Albanians – contrary
to the predictions of all alternative arguments – became possible when Zog
reestablished his rule and ceased supporting the Kosovo Albanian secessionist
movement, but only for a little while.

Albania from an Enemy to an Ally: Accommodation


For a couple of years during the mid-1920s the KSCS remained in favor of the
status quo and Albania ceased supporting the Kaçak movement in Kosovo and
was an ally of the KSCS. Under such circumstances, my theory predicts that
Albanians in Kosovo should be accommodated (Table 7.1). Indeed, as we will
see below, in the mid-1920s Belgrade issued an extensive amnesty decree,
permitted religious schooling conducted by Muslim imams in Muslim mektebs
(primary schools) and medreses (secondary schools), and permitted the use of
the Albanian language.87
A closer look at this counterintuitive shift is warranted. In December 1924,
Zog invaded Albania with the help of the Yugoslav army – and Wrangelite
White Russian troops – and managed to overthrow Fan Noli.88 Zog prevailed
over the Kosovo politicians in Albania and persecuted his enemies.89 Kola
describes the situation well:
Zog chose Yugoslavia, of all places, to retreat to. There he was supplied with money and
men and returned to stage a coup six months later. From then onwards, he became a
virtual vassal of the Serbs, and the question of Kosova was buried.90

By the mid-1920s the Kaçak movement had been almost eradicated. At that
moment, Albania ceased acting as a national homeland. Albania was now a
friendly state that did not interfere and Kosovo Albanians were no longer
perceived as a threat by the government in Belgrade.91 In response to these
developments in Albania – and consistent with my argument – the government
in Belgrade “issued a sweeping amnesty decree.”92
At around the same time that Zog reestablished his power in Albania, the
Cemiyet elected fourteen members in the Yugoslav parliament and was in a
coalition with the ruling Serb-dominated Radical Party.93 As an otherwise

86
Fan Noli (1882–1965) was the founder of the Albanian Orthodox Church and serve as a Prime
Minister and Regent of Albania from June 1924 to December 1924. For more, see Austin 1996: 154.
87
Vickers 1998: 103.
88
Banac 1984, pp. 302, 305; Fischer 2007: 31–32; Swire 1971: 445.
89
Kola 2003: 19.
90
Ibid., p. 20.
91
Burgwyn 1997: 25.
92
Vickers 1998: 101.
93
Banac 1984: 377.
Temporal Variation 159

scathing Albanian memorandum to the League of Nations put it, “[t]he


Albanians hoped for one moment in 1925–1926 that they would be as free as
the other citizens of Yugoslavia to occupy political positions in the country.”94
Given the geopolitical situation and domestic politics in Albania, however,
the Yugoslav favoritism in Tirana did not last for long. Zog faced an Italian-
backed revolt in 1926 but managed to crush it.95 Faced with externally sup-
ported opposition and a difficult economic situation Zog decided to change his
stance toward Italy.96 As we will see, Italy successfully penetrated Albanian
political life in the late 1920s and changed Albanian foreign policy toward the
Kosovo Albanians and the KSCS once again.

Albania from Ally to Enemy Again: Back to Assimilation


The alliance with the KSCS did not last long under the increased pressure from
financial problems that led Zog closer to Italy.97 For the KSCS soon enough
Albania turned into an enemy power agitating the Kosovo Albanians once again.
Assimilation policies ensued (Table 7.1).
By 1929, Zog’s turn from the KSCS to Italy98 and King Aleksandar’s dictator-
ship altered the geopolitical situation. According to Burgwyn’s research in the
Italian archives, Zog “was ready to turn to the Italians, but only on the condition
that they provide him substantial support for Albania’s irredentist claims on the
Kosovo region.”99 Zog signed the Pact of Friendship and Security in November
1926 and since then Albanian foreign policy ceased being independent.100 A
second pact, signed a year later, solidified the alliance and thus the dependence
on Mussolini’s Italy.101 Zog was also tellingly named “Zog I, King of the
Albanians” in August 1928 (see Illustration 7.2).102 The Yugoslavian govern-
ment feared that Zog’s new title meant that secessionist claims would once again
be propagated amongst the Albanians in Kosovo.103
The dictatorship imposed by King Aleksandar on 6 January 1929 brought
with it a new approach of the nation-building policies in Kosovo and the KSCS
as a whole. The period that followed was marked by strict internal security

94
Bisaku et al. 1997: 389.
95
Fischer 2007: 35–36.
96
Andrić 1997: 444.
97
Kola 2003: 20.
98
According to Fischer, Zog could not trust Belgrade and relying on Italy had the advantage that
they had no common land borders and that Italy could help Albania financially (2007: 37). For
more on Mussolini’s foreign policy in the Balkans, see Burgwyn 1997; Steed 1927; Villari 1956.
99
Burgwyn 1997: 40.
100
Burgwyn 1997: 41; Miller 1927; Sereni 1941.
101
Armstrong 1928.
102
Documenti Diplomatici Italiani (DDI), Series 7, Vol. 6, document no. 41, 22 January 1928;
Longworth 2007.
103
Italy was aiding at the same time the Croatian movement and the Internal Macedonian
Revolutionary Organization (IMRO); see Burgwyn 1997: 44–48.
160 Empirical Evidence

illu stration 7.2. King Zog. Source: Library of Congress, Prints and Photographs
Division, Washington, D.C.

measures and the curtailment of civil liberties. On 3 October of the same year the
Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes was renamed the Kingdom of
Yugoslavia; the banovine (administrative units) were created, conveniently
dividing Kosovo into three new banovine,104 (see Map 7.4); and the various
legal systems were unified. Leaders of various non-core groups (ranging from
Muslims to Slovene) were imprisoned and persecuted for sedition and terrorist
activities. This was, in other words, the apogee of centralization under Serbian
hegemony that ultimately solidified Croatian – and in general minority – oppo-
sition. The royal dictatorship lasted up until 1931 when King Aleksandar
promulgated a new constitution. The 1931 attempt at democratic governence
was a parody, with only one electoral list participating in the election. Thus,
while the royal dictatorship formally ended in 1931, the subsequent period
cannot be considered as democratic. Only in 1935 were there the first regular
elections.
During this transformation, colonization and assimilation policies ensued
toward Kosovo Albanians. This policy change also coincided with the increasing

104
Lampe 2000: 167.
Temporal Variation 161

ÖSTERREICH
UNGARN
DRAU
ITALIEN
Laibach Zagreb
RUMÄNIEN
DONAU
SAVE
Novi Sad

VRBAS Belgrad

Banja Luka

DRINA
Sarajevo
KÜSTE
Split MORAVA
Niš
ZETA

Cetinje
Die Banschaften BULGARIEN
im Skopje
Kgr. Jugoslawien
1929 VARDAR
Kroatische
Banschaft 1939 ALBANIEN
GRIECHENLAND

map 7.4. Banovinas in the Kingdom of Yugoslavia, 1929–1941. Source: http://upload.


wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/e/eb/K%C3%B6nigreich_Jugoslawien.jpg.

influence of Italy on Albanian internal affairs and the proclamation of Zog as


“King of the Albanians.” Longworth summarizes this process well:

Italy financed a national bank for him [Zog]; arranged to lend Albania 50 million gold
francs at 13 per cent, but interest-free for five years; provided a moratorium on the interest
for 1925 and 1926 and paid over further large sums in 1928 and 1935, including £1
million for economic development. There were concessions in return, of course. The
Friendship and Security Pact signed at Tirana in November 1926 heralded Albania’s
descent to the status of an Italian vassal. Step by step Italy not only gained the right to
intervene at Albania’s request (a device to keep Zog in power), but influence in military
affairs, control over national assets, the replacement of British by Italian gendarmerie
officers, acceptance of Italian advisers in a range of fields from civil engineering to
physical training, control of air communications and Lebensraum provision for some
of Italy’s excess population. Cultural affiliation was indicated by provision for Italian in
schools and the foundation of a fascist youth movement.105

105
2007: 163.
162 Empirical Evidence

This increased influence of Italy in Albania was directly linked with the intensifica-
tion of the Serbian colonization efforts in Kosovo. Decrees were passed in 1931
“forcing Albanians out of their lands, with . . . new regulations requiring all land to
pass into state property unless the owner could produce Yugoslav title-deeds.”106
Naturally, the Albanians in Kosovo were less likely to produce the necessary
documentation. According to Verli, by 1938 every Albanian-inhabited area had
been targeted with this policy.107 Dérens reports that by 1939 around 59,300 Serbs
had settled in the region, which accounted for approximately 9 percent of the total
population.108 Other estimates bring this number up to 100,000.109
From a memorandum presented to the League of Nations in 1930 we learn,
among other things, that the Albanian private school in Skopje closed in 1929,
the last in a series of private schools that were closed down. Albanian cultural
associations were prohibited around the same time, and in regard to public
schools “there is not a single school or a single class among the 545 referred to
by the Yugoslav Government in which teaching is conducted in Albanian.”110
As if this was not enough, the economic situation in Yugoslavia was difficult
in the beginning of the 1930s as a result of the global financial crisis. This was
exacerbated by the fact that France – the main patron of Yugoslavia – stopped
absorbing Yugoslavian exports. Geopolitically, things were not much better;
both Britain and France attempted cooperative relations with Hitler’s Germany
and Mussolini’s Italy. The result of these efforts was an agreement of the “Big
Four” for the preservation of the territorial status quo in Europe (June 1933).
Yugoslavia, surrounded by unfriendly states (with the exception of Greece)
attempted to counteract the unfavorable geopolitical developments described
above by entering in the Balkan Entente in 1934 together with Greece, Turkey,
and Romania.
Following the assassination of King Aleksandar in 1934,111 France was no
longer as interested in Yugoslav affairs. Germany had already bought French
and American interests in the country.112 As a result, Yugoslavia signed trade
agreements with Germany and became more and more dependent on it econom-
ically. In the spring of 1937 Yugoslavia signed a Pact of Friendship with Italy.
On top of everything else, the Anschluss between Germany and Austria created a
very difficult situation for Yugoslavia since it was now bordering Germany.

106
Kola 2003: 21.
107
1995: 15.
108
Dérens 2008: 65.
109
Verli 1995.
110
Bisaku et al. 1997: 395.
111
King Aleksandar was assassinated by a member of Ivan Mihailov’s Internal Macedonian
Revolutionary Organization (a Bulgarian-backed separatist organization) in cooperation with
Ante Pavelić’s Ustaše (a Croatian separatist organization) – an action backed by Italy, Bulgaria,
and Hungary – brought about fears of a breakup of Yugoslavia. Aleksandar was succeeded by his
eleven-year-old son Peter II and a regency council headed by Aleksandar’s cousin Prince Paul (or
Pavle).
112
Sørensen 2009: 78–79.
Temporal Variation 163

Plans for Exclusion


During the late 1930s the Serbian elites became increasingly concerned about the
prospects of their nation-building policy in Kosovo. The colonization process
did not achieve its goal of altering the ethnic balance in the region since the
settlers were not adequate for the task, the administration was not efficient, and
the land reform was following a pattern of dispersed settlement and not “the
known model of taking possession of land piece by piece,” thus not altering the
demographic balance anywhere in particular.113 Moreover, the national ques-
tion in Yugoslavia – encapsulated in the Serb-Croat antagonism – became more
pressing and the geopolitical situation untenable. It was in this context that the
resettlement of Kosovo Albanians in Turkey surfaced as an option. However,
this plan never materialized (Table 7.1).
As I discussed in the previous section, the geopolitical situation was changing
rapidly in ways unfavorable to the Yugoslav Kingdom. Early in 1936, Turkey
had expressed interest in signing an agreement with Yugoslavia for the resettle-
ment of about 200,000 Muslims.114 A year later, Vaso Čubrilović115 suggested a
radical solution to the Albanian question in a policy paper he presented to the
Yugoslav government:

There is no possibility for us to assimilate the Albanians. On the contrary, because their
roots are in Albania, their national awareness has been awakened, and if we do not settle
the score with them once and for all, within 20–30 years we shall have to cope with a
terrible irredentism, the signs of which are already apparent and will inevitably put all our
southern territories in jeopardy.116

According to Čubrilović, the expulsion of the Albanians was necessary in order


to “reestablish” the connection with the Slavs in South Serbia. Importantly for
my argument, Čubrilović makes clear the geopolitical reasoning underlying his
proposal. He was mostly concerned with the block of eighteen districts where the
Albanians were concentrated and formed a compact settlement. Albanians and
other national minorities in “other parts of the south are scattered and therefore
constitute less of a threat to the life of our nation and state,” he wrote in 1937.117
Nationalizing the regions around the Shar mountains would prevent Albanian
irredentism once and for all, and secure Kosovo forever. But his reasoning did
not stop there: “[W]ith the elimination of the Albanians, the last link between
our Moslems in Bosnia and Novi Pazar and the rest of the Moslem world will

113
Krstić-Brano 2004: 82.
114
Banac 1984: 301.
115
Vaso Čubrilović (1897–1990). In 1914, he was a participant in the conspiracy to assassinate the
Archduke Franz Ferdinand. During the 1930s, he was a professor of history in Belgrade and a
political adviser for the government of Yugoslavia. After World War II, he became a member of
the Communist Party and served as a Minister of Forests in Tito’s government. He was a member
of the Serbian Academy of Arts and Sciences.
116
Čubrilović 1997: 407.
117
Ibid., p. 405.
164 Empirical Evidence

have been cut,”118 and then the remaining Muslims would be an isolated
religious minority ready for assimilation.
A year after Čubrilović’s proposal, the Yugoslav Military Headquarters also
“advocat[ed] the resettlement of the ethnic Albanians into Turkey”119 because
of growing security concerns. According to my argument, what should have kept
the KSCS from pursuing exclusionary policies toward the enemy-backed Kosovo
Albanians should have been their desire to preserve the international status quo.
Indeed, Prime Minister Milan Stojadinović,120 in his first term, had tried to keep
Yugoslavia as a status quo power attempting to turn it into a neutral power – the
Switzerland of the Balkans.
Late in the 1930s, however, when the international status quo was directly
challenged and Italy’s grip over Albania had reached its peak, the Serbian elites
contemplated seriously pursuing exclusionary policies. As Andrić121 put it, “[t]
he presence of any of the great Powers in the Balkans means opening the flood-
gates to intrigue and invasion.”122 In this turbulent context, Stojadinović signed
an agreement with Turkey – the latter aiming at its own ethnic engineering – in
1938 for the relocation of about 40,000 Muslim families – excluding nomads
and Gypsies – over a period of six years (1939 to 1944).123 However, this plan
never materialized due to lack of funds and the outbreak of World War II.124 In
1939, Andrić even considered the annexation of northern Albania to Yugoslavia
in case of a partition. His rationale was consistent with the rationale of my
argument: “[after the annexation of northern Albania] Kosovo would lose its
attraction as a centre for the Albanian minority which, under the new situation,
could be more easily assimilated.”125 All in all, consistent with my argument,
assimilation was the dominant policy during this period but the geopolitical
circumstances did provide incentives to contemplate exclusionary policies for
significant parts of the Albanian population.

the role of domestic politics


Could the variation in nation-building policies be explained by the nature of
domestic politics? A more systematic look at political life in the kingdom of

118
Ibid., 406.
119
Stefanović 2005: 482.
120
Milan Stojadinović (1888–1961), a Serbian Politician who served as Prime Minister of
Yugoslavia from 1935 to 1939.
121
Ivo Andrić (1892–1975) was awarded the Nobel Prize for literature in 1961. Andrić joined the
diplomatic service of the KSCS after World War I, his most important post being Ambassador of
the Kingdom of Yugoslavia to Germany just before World War II (1939–1941).
122
Andrić 1997: 446.
123
For more on the Yugoslav-Turkish convention, see “Convention. Regulating the Emigration of
the Turkish Population from the Region of Southern Serbia in Yugoslavia (1938),” in Elsie 1997;
Institute of History 1993; Krstić-Brano 2004: 82–83.
124
Lampe 2000: 192; Stefanović 2005: 482; Krstić-Brano 2004: 83.
125
Andrić 1997: 448.
Temporal Variation 165

Yugoslavia is necessary to test this hypothesis.126 King Aleksandar127 was a central


figure in the interwar politics of the Kingdom and did not hesitate to intervene in the
political process. Three main political parties existed during the interwar period: The
Radical Party under Pašić and the Democratic party under Davidović on the Serbian
side, and the Peasant Party under Radić (and later Maček) on the Croatian side.
There were also many smaller parties – some regional, others ethnic – vying for the
majority in the Assembly. However, the main cleavage was that between the Serbs
and the Croats, those in favor of centralization and those against it respectively.128
According to the Corfu Declaration in 1917, the Latin and Cyrillic alphabets
as well as the three national names (Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes) and their flags
were to be equally recognized. Moreover, the predominant religions
(Orthodoxy, Catholicism, and Islam) were also officially recognized. However,
the most problematic issue was whether the Kingdom would be centralized – a
position supported by Pašić – or federalized – a position favored by Trumbić129
and Radić.130 In other words, the state was weak not because of its multinational
character per se131 but rather because of the disagreement between the three
largest groups on the level of centralization of government. In addition, the
largest political parties were all “ethnic” parties. As Ramet put it: “one could
safely assume that only Croats joined the Croatian Peasant Party, only Slovenes
joined the Slovene People’s Party, only Serbs joined the (Serbian) Radical Party,
and only Muslims joined the Yugoslav Muslim Organization (JMO) . . . a ‘loyal’
Croat was expected to vote for Radić, a ‘loyal’ Slovene to vote for Anton
Korošec, leader of the Slovene People’s Party, and a ‘loyal Muslim’ to vote for
JMO leader Mehmed Spaho.”132
A defining moment in the history of the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and
Slovenes was the Serbs’ adoption of a centralist constitution in 1921 while all
of the anti-centralist political forces boycotted the constituent assembly. The
murder of the Minister of Interior and the Communists’ attempted murder of
King Aleksandar immediately after the new constitution’s adoption were
indicative of the political climate in interwar Yugoslavia. As a result of the
violence the Communist Party was outlawed and many of its members
persecuted.

126
See Banac 1984; Djokić 2003 and 2007; and Troch 2010.
127
King Peter I Karadjordjević was succeeded by his son Aleksandar in 1921, who had been already
in control basically since the unification.
128
Banac 1984.
129
A Croatian leader who established the “Yugoslav Committee” in London during World War
I. In 1918 he became foreign minister in the first government of the Kingdom but resigned in
1920. For more on Trumbić, see Djokić 2010.
130
The leader of the Croatian Peasant Party.
131
In the Kingdom there were Serbs (39%), Croats (23%), Slovenes (8.5%), Bosnian Muslims (6%),
Macedonians/Bulgarians (4.8%), Germans (4.27%), Hungarians (3.98%), Albanians (3.68%),
Turks, Greeks, and many smaller non-core groups (Banac 1984).
132
2006: 37.
166 Empirical Evidence

The Croatian Peasant Party continued to voice its demands for regional
autonomy and returned to the National Assembly only in 1924. In the meantime,
the Radical Party had managed to reorganize the country into thirty three admin-
istrative districts (see Map 7.3), which undermined the pre-existing provincial
administration in Croatia, Slovenia, Bosnia-Herzegovina, and Vojvodina.
In 1924, for the first time after unification, an anticentralist – but still
Serbian – Prime Minister, Davidović, was appointed by the King. A coalition
of Croats, Slovenes, Muslims, and Serbian Democrats had managed to wrest
control from the Radical Party, but their control would not last for long
(Davidović resigned on 17 July 1924); Pašić soon took over once again and led
the country to new elections in February 1925.
On 2 July 1925 negotiations between the Radical and the Peasant Parties
began, leading to the formation of a new government under Pašić. Radić became
a Minister of Education on 17 November 1925.133 The renunciation of any
autonomist plans for Croatia by Radić had preceded this coalition.134
But even the coexistence of Serbs and Croats in the same government was
shortlived. Pašić had to resign because of a corruption scandal, and a period of
unstable political coalition governments under Uzunović – the new leader of the
Radical Party – followed.
Given this narrative, one might argue that the short period of accommodation
of Albanians in Kosovo around 1924 could have been the outcome of the
influence that the Croatian Peasant Party had achieved through its participation
in the government. However, these governments were dysfunctional and passed
few important pieces of legislation. Moreover, the Serbian establishment in the
military and the administration, with the king’s support, did not allow non-Serbs
to interfere with their policies within what was still viewed as “Serbian lands,”
which more or less corresponded to the pre-World War I Kingdom of Serbia.135
Nevertheless, despite the intense political conflict – especially between the Croats
and the Serbs – democratic institutions lasted until 1929 when King Aleksandar
imposed a royal dictatorship and renamed the state as the Kingdom of Yugoslavia
(see Illustration 7.3). The dictatorship was a reaction to prolonged political insta-
bility. A critical event was the assassination of Radić – and two more Croatian
deputies – by a Montenegrin deputy on 20 June 1928.136
Although the intense political conflict between Croats – and to a lesser extent
Slovenes – and Serbs formed the main political cleavage in the country, it did not

133
The government was formed on 18 July, the same day Radić was released from prison (Ramet
2006: 67).
134
Radić was imprisoned during the elections in 1925 but immediately afterwards he renounced the
autonomist plans for Croatia, accepted the Vidovdan Constitution (the first Constitution of the
KSCS in 1921) and the dynasty, and declared his commitment to the unity of the state (Ramet
2006: 66).
135
To be sure, hegemony in the political sphere did not prevent Croatian and Slovenian domination
in the economic sphere; see Petranović 2002: 21.
136
Radić actually succumbed to his wounds in August 1928.
Temporal Variation 167

illustration 7.3. King Aleksandar. Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Kralj_


aleksandar1.jpg.

impact the planning of Serbian policies toward the Albanians in Kosovo, at least
not directly. Most of the decisions relevant to nation-building were made by the
king’s court and the army’s high command rather than the parliament. Issues of
national security, such as Kosovo, were not to be decided by the parliament that
had many members with questionable loyalties and who themselves had often
fallen under the provisions of the Law on the Protection of Public Order and the
State.137 Moreover, Serbian politicians dominated the political scene almost
exclusively in the interwar period.
Serbian hegemony over the Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes mani-
fested itself beginning with the adoption of a centralist constitution in 1921 and
later with the administration of the state and the army, the way the institution of
the Monarchy functioned, and the pre-eminence of the Serbian Orthodox
Church. It is also captured in the following statistics:

[T]he prime minister’s job went to Serbs for 264 of the 268 months that the interwar
kingdom lasted (going to a Slovene for the other four months), the ministry of the army

137
Ramet 2006: 64.
168 Empirical Evidence

and navy was run by Serbs for all 268 months, the minister of internal affairs was a Serb
for 240 out of 268 months, the minister of foreign affairs was a Serb for 247 months, and
the minister of justice was a Serb for 237 of those months.138

Only very late in the interwar period, in 1939, the government negotiated the
Sporazum (Agreement) with Maček, the Croatian leader who succeeded Radić,
and created a semi-autonomous Croatian province (see Map 7.4).139 Even then,
although the new province was granted autonomy in internal matters, foreign
policy, security, and taxation remained under the control of Belgrade. Maček
actually became a Deputy Prime Minister in 1939 but World War II put a violent
end to this cooperative period in Serb-Croat relations without any policy
changes toward the Kosovo Albanians occurring during the Sporazum.
Before we turn to the conclusion of this chapter, it is worth discussing whether the
Serbian nation-building policies pursued toward Kosovo Albanians were inspired
by ethnic differences that generated mistrust. My findings indicate that the Serbian
policy was attuned to the population’s national loyalties rather than ethnic differ-
ences. The secondary importance of religious beliefs is demonstrated by the fact that
the KSCS did not pursue the same policies toward Slav-speaking Muslims and
Albanian-speaking Muslims.140 The secondary importance of ethnicity is also
supported by the fact that the Serbs pursued colonization in both Albanian
Muslim-dominated Kosovo – which was under Albanian influence – and in Slav-
dominated Orthodox Christian Vardar Macedonia – which was under Bulgarian
influence. National loyalty and patterns of external involvement were key to
government policies, not some specific set of ethnic attributes of the various
non-core groups.

conclusion
In this chapter, I used archival material as well as an extensive secondary
literature on the history of interwar Yugoslavia in order to trace the logic
underlying the policies followed by the ruling political elites in Belgrade toward
Albanians from 1878 to 1941. Studying this case over time allowed me to keep
many state- and group-level characteristics constant and isolate the effects of my
main variables of interest, host state foreign policy goals and interstate relations
between the non-core group’s external power and the host state.
While Serbia fought for territorial expansion and redeeming its co-ethnics it
pursued exclusionary policies toward the recently “nationally awakened” and
externally supported Albanians. Following World War I, the Serbian elites had
more or less achieved their national goals of territorial expansion. However, the
Albanian nationalists continued to enjoy external support and to make

138
Ibid., 38.
139
This development was of course related to international pressures and events such as the German
annexation of Sudetenland in 1938 and the growing economic dependence of the Kingdom on
Germany; see Petranović 2002: 37 and Sørensen 2009: 70.
140
Poulton and Vickers 1997: 146.
Temporal Variation 169

autonomy demands. In response to these circumstances the Serbian elites fol-


lowed a policy of assimilation toward Kosovo Albanians.
Less than six years after the annexation of Kosovo by the KSCS, Ahmet Zog
olli consolidated power in Albania – with Yugoslav help – and suppressed the
Kaçak movement. Albania was now a friendly state and Albanians in Kosovo
were no longer perceived as a threat. My theory predicts that Albanians should
be accommodated. Indeed, in the mid-1920s Belgrade permitted religious
schooling conducted by Muslim imams in Muslim mektebs and medreses.
By the end of the 1920s Italy’s renewed interest in Albania altered the
situation. King Zog was now “King of the Albanians,” secessionist claims
were once again propagated amongst the Albanians in Kosovo, and the Italian
influence increased rapidly in Albania. For Yugoslavia, Albania was an enemy
power once again. Assimilationist policies ensued. Due to the geopolitical
changes in Europe prior to World War II, plans for exclusion emerged aiming
at the resettlement of Kosovo Albanians to Turkey. However, these plans never
materialized.
Overall, the choice of nation-building policies was not based on objective
measures of cultural distance or deep-rooted ethnic hatred between the non-
assimilated Albanians and the core group Serbs. Indeed, it was based on an
interaction of the perceived danger of secessionist claims by the externally
backed Kosovo Albanian elites and state relations between Albania and
Serbia. In turn, the latter changed over time based on the geopolitical context
and Serbia’s foreign policy goals. None of the alternative explanations could
have predicted all these shifts in policy since they either are time invariant or
change at a much slower pace than the dependent variable. Lastly, macro-
historical explanations such as the rise of Fascism in Europe141 or the impact
of “Europeanization” on the Balkans142 – although useful to understand the
context – cannot account for the variation in the policies over time and across
groups, either.

141
See Alter 1994: 16–38; Stefanovic 2005: 483.
142
Todorova 1997: 13.
8

Application of the Theory Beyond the Balkans

Can my argument help us shed light on shifts in nation-building policies


toward non-core groups in other parts of the world? Does it provide us with
insights beyond the interwar period? In Chapters 4 through 7 I have provided
empirical support for my argument based on evidence from the early
twentieth-century Balkans, a place described as chaotic, captivated by ethnic
hatreds where there is a strong presumption against the logic of my argument.
In this section I explore the extent to which the theory can help us explain
variation in nation-building policies beyond the Balkan region and outside the
interwar period.
The ideal – but hardly feasible or ethical – test would require me to conduct
an experiment. A second best would be to construct a global panel dataset on
nation-building policies toward all non-core groups living in states with ruling
political elites of clearly defined core groups that were motivated by a homog-
enizing imperative. However, in order to identify the extent to which my
argument may apply across space and time, challenging causal links have to
be established. For example, we would need to determine whether there was
external involvement in support of a non-core group – a particularly challeng-
ing task especially when dealing with covert or clandestine operations.
Moreover, we would need data on whether this external involvement actually
affected the choice of nation-building policies toward the non-core group.
Existing secondary literature on nation-building policies is very limited and
in most cases archival research is necessary to establish these causal links for a
global dataset. Moreover, archival material is rarely accessible; most govern-
ments keep such information confidential for many years while others destroy
it altogether.
Data collection problems are more pronounced in the most violent cases
when the host government has pursued exclusionary policies. In such cases,
there are incentives for both external supporters and host states to obscure the
picture and forge the data in a way that absolves them of their responsibility.
Cases of assimilationist policies are relatively easier to study but even this work
has become increasingly difficult within an international environment that

170
Application of the Theory Beyond the Balkans 171

views assimilationist policies as “cultural genocide.” Under such pressures,


governments have incentives to disguise their policies and destroy evidence of
such policies. Cases of non-core group accommodation are the easiest to study
today. On the one hand, host states get an opportunity to publicize their multi-
cultural arrangements; on the other, external supporters are eager to get credit
for such progressive outcomes.
In addition to the lack of reliable data on such sensitive issues, researchers are
often faced with propagandistic material. This type of material is most prevalent
among secondary sources. Frequently, governments create “institutes of
national history” or more specific centers studying certain periods or regions
in an attempt to propagate their view of history and legitimize their claims.
Moreover, such works are likely to be published in places where intense nation-
building has taken place and this leaves us with very little data on cases that were
less violent. Archival material is less likely to include propagandistic overtones,
although researchers have to be careful of the biases – ideological or other – of
the individuals writing the reports. In sum, sources on nation-building policies
are difficult to find; even when they are available, they are often part of a nation-
building strategy themselves. Researchers need to be cautious in their use of
secondary sources and critical of primary ones.
With these limitations in mind, in the rest of this chapter I explore the extent
to which my argument regarding policies toward non-core groups may be
generalized to non-core groups which have inhabited different regional systems
and highly diverse geopolitical environments over the last two hundred years.
The cases I discuss below serve as illustrations of my argument outside of the
interwar Balkans.

same region, different periods


Two lessons emerge from the study of the Greek War of Independence in the
early nineteenth century and ethnic relations in post–Cold War Balkans:
Scapegoating is a special case of false accusation by the host state, and, with
regard to the importance of one of my scope conditions, elites must be motivated
by a homogenizing imperative for my argument to apply.

Nation-Building in Nineteenth-Century Balkans


Based on my scope conditions, the mechanisms I discussed in Chapter 2 should
be operative only in the modern era. Thus, it is appropriate to look for the first
instances of the Politics of Nation-Building in one of the first national awaken-
ings that occurred in the Balkans: the Greek national awakening and the war of
independence against the Ottomans.
The Rum millet within the Ottoman Empire was definitely accommodated
in terms of its religious identity with the Orthodox Patriarch as its leader.
Granted this was not the type of accommodation that is in place in
Western liberal democratic states today; it was a rather hierarchical form of
172 Empirical Evidence

accommodation.1 At the same time, however, the Ottoman Empire was not
targeting the Rum millet with assimilationist – with the exception of the
Devşirme system2 – or exclusionary policies.
The Greek War of Independence followed the Serbian revolts, first against
their local notables and then against the Ottoman Empire itself. The Ottoman
Porte was now facing “the first all-out Christian uprising aiming at complete
independence from the Imperial superstructure.”3 These events had a trans-
formative impact on the nature of the Ottoman Empire itself. The religious
cleavage became more and more salient and conflict ridden. At the same time,
Ottomanism slowly emerged as a proto-national identity.
The Sultan, probably based on past experience,4 operated under the assump-
tion that the Russians were supporting the Greeks but he was wrong. Regardless,
according to Ilicak, “one of the most determining factors in the Sublime’s Porte’s
responses to the Greek Revolution was the Ottoman administrators’ perception
of a Russian conspiracy behind the insurgency.” According to official Ottoman
documents, the Sultan was convinced that Russia was “provoking and secretly
assisting the Greek insurgents and that the Fanariots were a Russian fifth
column.”5 The background of Alexandros Ipsilantis, the leader of the revolt in
Moldowallachia, was seen as enough proof of the Russian connection. Ipsilantis
was a Major General in the Russian army since 1817, a personal friend of Tsar
Alexander I, and the son of a Phanariote who had been voyvoda of Wallachia
and had defected to Russia.
The Russians tried to credibly signal that they were not backing this revolt in a
variety of ways ranging from the discharge of Ipsilantis from the army to offering
help in crushing the rebellion. These assurances and related actions did not
appease the Ottoman administration. Ilicak unearthed from the Ottoman
archives the Sultan’s private notes during the first months of the rebellion. The
Sultan wrote, “had the [Russians] not promised to help and interfere, the Greeks
could not have dared [to revolt].” The reprisal on the Greeks of the Empire was
extensive and brutal. Despite the fact that external support was not initially
present, the Sultan perceived it as such and thus his reaction is consistent with my
theory. To be sure, the Sultan would have reacted even if he was not convinced
about the Russian involvement in the matter, but the extent of the reprisals
would definitely have been smaller.
This case allows us to think about the ontology of scapegoating. A non-core
group may be externally supported by an enemy or not and a host state
may really perceive the group as threatening or not. In Figure 8.1 we may

1
Kymlicka 2012.
2
“A compulsory separation of [a select group of] boys from their families, their conversion to Islam
and recruitment into the Ottoman service, a practice that extended well into the seventeenth
century.” Bieber 2000.
3
Ilicak 2011, Chapter 3.
4
See section “Motivations for External Involvement” in Chapter 2, where I discuss Russian Count
Orlov’s involvement in the Pelloponnese during the late eighteenth century.
5
Ilicak 2011.
Application of the Theory Beyond the Balkans 173

Perceived Threat
Enemy External Support
Truthful Pretense

Yes Not scapegoating Rare Event


False Accusation
No Not scapegoating
(scapegoating)

figure 8.1. Scapegoating.

discern two combinations that are clearly not cases of scapegoating: first, there is
external support by an enemy and the host state perceives the non-core group as
a threat; second, there is no external support but the host state still considers the
group as a threat – this was the case of the Greeks in the early nineteenth century.
In a situation where there is no external support or any anti-government
mobilization but the host state acts as if there were a real threat posed by the non-
core group regardless, then this is a case of false accusation. Scapegoating is a
special case within the category of false accusation and it refers to instances when
the host state blames unfairly a non-core group for the problems faced by the
host state. Finally, there is a small possibility that there is external support for a
group by an enemy and the host state is unaware of that but has – for its own
reasons – decided to act as if there is a real threat posed by the non-core group.
This is a rare event since more often than not the external involvement soon
enough manifests itself.

Nation-Building in Post–World War II Balkans


Attempts to account for variation in nation-building policies within the Post–Cold
War Balkans also corroborate my interwar findings but highlight the importance
of the international structure and the motives of the core group elites.6 The rise of
ethnic conflict in the Balkans, and the breakup of the former federal states in the
1990s (Yugoslavia and USSR), opened a lively debate among political scientists
and commentators on what accounts for variations in the treatment of non-core
groups.
For instance, why did Bulgaria pursue a forced assimilation policy in the mid-
1980s while Greece, by recognizing a Muslim minority, facilitated the
“Turkification” of its members? Why did Greece treat the Muslim minority as
a unitary actor in the 1980s but not in the 1990s? Why did Bulgaria abandon its
assimilationist policy in 1989 in favor of a policy of minority rights protection?
Putting Greek and Bulgarian policies toward their Muslim minority groups in a
comparative perspective reveals a pattern consistent with my theory.7 The
structure of the international system (unipolar, multipolar, bipolar) affected

6
For more on this, see Chapter 9.
7
For a thorough treatment of these cases, see Mantouvalou and Mylonas 2010.
174 Empirical Evidence

interstate relations between these countries and ultimately impacted the treat-
ment of the relevant non-core groups. I described some of these cases in
Chapter 5 while discussing “divide and rule” policies in the Balkans.
Later on in the 1990s and into the 2000s Albanians in Kosovo and the former
Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia were affected by very different policies from
their respective governments.8 These states both involve a South Slav core group
and an Albanian non-core group; in both cases the non-core group was restless,
large, and territorially concentrated; and both places have been parts of the
Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia. This is where similarities end; while the
government in Skopje assumed a relatively accommodating stance toward its
restive Albanian minority, the Serbian government switched from accommoda-
tion to repression. Why? Consistent with my argument, the absence of an enemy
external power supporting the non-core group gave the government in Skopje no
incentive for engaging in outright exclusionary policies. In fact the non-core
group enjoyed support from the United States, a country that at the same time
supported the government in Skopje. In contrast, in the case of Serbia, the fact
that a similar non-core group started receiving external support from the United
States toward the end of the 1990s resulted in Serbian ethnic cleansing since
United States–Serbia relations had deteriorated significantly after the war in
Bosnia. The differential patterns of external power support and interstate alli-
ances between the host state and these backers best explain the treatment of these
non-core groups.
Up to the 1980s accommodation was the dominant strategy toward Kosovo
Albanians. However, in the 1990s things changed. This stark difference once
again makes us appreciate the centrality of scope conditions, namely that for my
argument to operate the core group must be clearly defined and its elites must be
driven by a homogenizing imperative. Since World War II and until Tito’s death
in 1980, Yugoslavia was hardly conforming to my argument’s scope conditions.
Beginning in the 1980s and into the 1990s, however, the representation of
nationalist core groups by leaders such as Milošević, Tud̄man, and Gligorov,
and the pursuit of homogenizing imperatives, emerged across the constituent
republics of Yugoslavia.9 This transformation was key to the logic of my argu-
ment to become operative.

different regions, different contexts


Up to this point, the cases I have discussed have all been from the Balkans. Thus,
although I have demonstrated that the argument applies in the Balkans all
through the modern era, I have yet to show that it applies to other regions of
the world. To examine whether my argument can be generalized beyond the
Balkans, I focus on People’s Republic of China’s (PRC’s) nation-building poli-
cies during the Cold War and on Estonia’s post–Cold War policies toward

8
For a thorough treatment of these cases, see Jenne and Mylonas 2011.
9
Banac 2006; Snyder 2000.
Application of the Theory Beyond the Balkans 175

Russian-speakers. Three important conclusions may be drawn from these cases:


the relative capacity of the external power versus the host state has a significant
impact on the mobilization of the non-core group and the host state’s perception
of threat; the understanding of the term assimilation varies widely across cases
and over time, ranging from loyalty to the state without any demands for
acculturation all the way to loyalty to the state and complete acculturation,
language acquisition, religious conversion, and so forth; and, in line with my
argument, regional integration projects often operate as channels that
propagate and enforce international human rights norms and ultimately facili-
tate accommodationist policies.

PRC Nation-Building during the Cold War


Turning to the Cold War context, first, I conduct a comparison between the
treatment of the Uyghurs and Tibetans under Mao’s10 rule from 1949 to 1965.11
Second, I trace PRC policies over time focusing on the Tibetans from 1949 to the
present.12 Finally, I briefly discuss a comparison across the eighteen largest
groups in China (see Table 8.1 below).13

Tibet and Xinjiang


The first empirical puzzle from Cold War Asia is why the Chinese government
cracked down on the Tibetan movement in 1959 but repressed the Uyghur move-
ment later, in 1962. What accounts for this timing given that Han antipathy,
cultural differences, and unrest were present in both cases? I find that although the
Chinese government was following the 1952 program for regional autonomy in
both Xinjiang and Tibet, different patterns of external involvement and interstate
relations can help us explain the variation in the timing of nation-building policy
shifts in the two regions. In particular, the limited external support that Tibetans
received during the 1949–1956 period14 did not derail the uneasy but functioning
coexistence with the Chinese until 1956–1959.15 A transitional policy of accom-
modation was pursued while the terminal goal was assimilation.16
Beijing allowed Tibetans to run their own affairs through the first half of the
1950s, but not outside of political Tibet. In the latter areas that were not
accommodated the Khampas organized revolts. This situation in the context of
the Cold War reignited U.S. interest in Tibet, and the CIA began its operations by

10
Mao Zedong or Mao Tse-Tung (1893–1976) was a Han Chinese and the leader of the People’s
Republic of China from 1949 until his death in 1976.
11
Jenne and Mylonas 2011.
12
Mylonas 2008.
13
Han and Mylonas 2011.
14
“Supply of arms for Tibet,” January 1950, FO 371/84465. “Assistance for Tibet to help combat
the Communist Threat,” January 1950, FO 371/84451.
15
For a description of this period, see Goldstein 1989; Shakya 2002; Wang 2002.
16
The CCP initially accommodated rather than assimilated the Tibetans since PRC capacity at the
time was limited. Tibet’s location was also an important factor in this choice; see Fravel 2008.
176 Empirical Evidence

airdropping arms for the rebels and sending agents into Tibet to disrupt Chinese
efforts to control the region.17 However, accommodation policies continued in
political Tibet.
U.S. policy toward Tibet was motivated by a desire to contain the influence of
Communist China in the region and around the world.18 Consistent with my
argument, the Chinese government faced with an enemy-supported non-core
group adopted exclusionary policies toward the Tibetan leadership and resist-
ance. As Fravel put it, “Chinese leaders’ knowledge of external support, espe-
cially from the United States, no doubt had a strong psychological impact on
their sense of China’s internal vulnerability to external influence.”19 Mao tight-
ened Beijing’s grip over the internal affairs of Tibet, leading the Dalai Lama and
his supporters to flee into exile in 1959.
In the case of the Uyghurs – a Muslim Turkic-speaking group living in the
northwestern province of Xinjiang20 – the most significant support came from
the Soviet Union.21 With the Chinese Communist Party having risen to power,
Soviet support for Uyghur independence ceased although Uyghur ties with the
Soviet Union remained. In 1955, the territory was given the status of Xinjiang
Uyghur Autonomous Region. As expected, Sino-Soviet relations greatly influ-
enced the Chinese government’s policies toward the Uyghurs. Initially, the
relationship was a cooperative one and this led to an accommodationist minority
policy. The Soviet Union was involved in the industrialization of the province
and the PRC permitted access to Xinjiang’s oil and minerals.22 The Chinese
authorities also approved the adoption of a Cyrillic-based Uyghur script in 1954
on the advice of the region’s Soviet advisors. Usage of the language in Xinjiang
“reached its peak between 1955 and 1958, when it was introduced into a
number of schools and employed in academic publications.”23
As soon as Sino-Soviet relations became confrontational,24 the Soviets pulled
out of the region, began to distribute Soviet passports in the area, and used their
influence in the region to destabilize the PRC.25 For more than twenty years the
border between the PRC and the Soviet Union was closed down and guarded by
PLA troops.26 Given this context, my argument predicts exclusionary policies
pursued by the PRC toward the Uyghurs. Indeed, the Chinese government
implemented a policy of purging pro-Soviet Uyghur elites and engaged in wide-
spread persecution of anyone suspected of having ties to the Soviets. The

17
McGranahan 2010. The United States was not the only power involved but it was the most significant.
18
Grunfeld 1987; Knaus 1999; Weiner 2007.
19
2008: 81.
20
Dillon 2004; McMillen 1979.
21
Wheeler 1963.
22
Millward 2007: 225.
23
Dwyer 2005: 18–19.
24
MacFarquhar 1997: 128; Schecter 1963; see also “Communists: One-Third of the Earth,” Time
Magazine, 27 October 1961, vol. 78(17).
25
Roberts 1998. See also Kamalov 2009: 117.
26
The USSR also sided with India in the 1962 Sino-Indian War.
Application of the Theory Beyond the Balkans 177

crackdown intensified in the spring of 1962, with more than 60,000 Uyghurs
and Kazakhs fleeing across the border to the Soviet Union. The newly adopted
Cyrillic scripts for the Uyghur language were also replaced by a new writing
system that was similar to the Chinese pinyin system.27
Keeping many factors relatively constant in both Tibet and Xinjiang, we still find
that PRC treated the regions differently at the same point in time – accommodating
one minority while repressing the other. Therefore, my argument helps us explain
variation in the timing of the shift from accommodation to exclusion in Tibet and
Xinjiang and adds another layer to the existing interpretations of these events.

Tibet Over Time


Even when we take a look at the over time variation in the treatment of Tibetans,
the fluctuations of repression are better understood when we take into account
changes in external support and interstate relations between China and the
United States. For instance, following the Cultural Revolution the treatment of
Tibetans improved significantly. I argue that this was causally related to the
normalization of U.S.–China relations under the Nixon administration in 1972.
The U.S.–PRC rapprochement in 1972 transformed U.S. Cold War strategy
and “created a new set of foreign policy conditions that quickly marginalized the
U.S. government’s ‘pragmatic’ interest in Tibet.”28 The CIA’s final missions in
Tibet occurred in 1974 and with Mao’s death in 1976 the path was now clear for
a return to accommodationist policies. The PRC began encouraging a cultural
renaissance in Tibet with the “reopening of monasteries, permission to recruit
new monks, greater leeway to use written Tibetan, and the replacement of large
numbers of ethnic Chinese cadres with Tibetans.”29 Wang describes this shift:
On December 28, 1978, less than a week after taking power, Deng . . . indicated his
willingness to start a dialogue with the Dalai Lama. . .. The 376 participants in the 1959
Rebellion still serving prison sentences were freed. Over 6,000 others who had been
released after completing their sentences but were still branded as “rebels” and kept under
“supervised reform” had these labels removed.30

This cultural revival however was not a policy targeting just Tibet, but it was
rather carried out throughout China after the Cultural Revolution. This nation-
wide policy was linked more to leadership change within the CCP from Mao to
Deng than just PRC’s relationship with the United States. Thus the two argu-
ments at this point are observationally equivalent. The way to adjudicate
between the two arguments would be to observe how the PRC would react to
a new wave of external support for the Tibetans.
Indeed, Western involvement resurfaced in the late 1980s and shifts in Chinese
nation-building policies followed suit. The Dalai Lama made an appearance in

27
Millward 2007: 235–36.
28
Goldstein 2006: 155; for more on this, see Weiner 2007: 350.
29
Goldstein 2006: 155.
30
2002: 100.
178 Empirical Evidence

the U.S. Congress in 1987 and proposed some bold steps in front of the U.S.
Congressional Human Rights Caucus.31 Following this speech the first demon-
strations in favor of independence since 1959 erupted in Lhasa, Tibet. Things
escalated and Han were targeted in retaliation to the crackdown of the Tibetan
demonstrations. Clearly, the PRC perceived the Dalai Lama’s address as the main
reason for this unrest. The fact that this address was given at the U.S. Congress
further worried the Chinese government. As a result of this external instigation
and apparent U.S. support for Tibetan independence, the accommodationist
policy had to be put aside for a more repressive policy. No wonder “the next
seventeen months saw an increasingly bloody pattern of disturbances, leading
ultimately to the imposition of martial law in March 1989, which remained in
effect for 419 days.”32
My argument is not that the conflict in Tibet or Xinjiang was the mere outcome
of interference by interested external powers. It was not. The conflict had its roots
in the aversion of the Tibetans and Uyghurs toward Han Chinese domination and
self-determination ideas, as well as the interests of local elites to preserve their
traditional social structures and religious practices. For example, years before the
United States decided to interfere, the Tibetan government had expelled all
Chinese as well as Tibetan communists in anticipation of Chinese plans to incor-
porate Tibet after the end of the Chinese civil war.33 My argument is that external
support by enemy powers of non-core groups that turn against the Communist
Chinese state both provided these non-core groups with more resources and
triggered a more violent reaction from the People’s Republic of China.
My theory helps us explain the timing of the shifts in nation-building policies
toward Tibetans and Uyghurs within the context of Cold War competition. It
also helps explain the shifts in Beijing’s minority policy toward Tibetans over
time from assimilation (through accommodation) to exclusion to accommoda-
tion and back to assimilation through a mix of repression and colonization.
However, in both cases the external power has been a strong state. No doubt
there are cases where the external power is relatively weaker than the host state. I
have explored this possibility elsewhere,34 but I think that for the purposes of the
argument I developed in this book this issue deserves further discussion. I turn to
it in the section that follows.

Subnational Variation
Table 8.1 depicts a two-by-two that captures the variation in interstate relations
and the relative strength of the external power when compared to the host state.
The main corrective that emerges from studying the eighteen largest non-core
groups in China during the first years of Mao’s rule is that when we relax the
assumption that the host state and the external power are symmetrical, my

31
Dalai Lama 1987.
32
Wang 2002: 105.
33
Goldstein et al. 2004.
34
Han and Mylonas 2011.
Application of the Theory Beyond the Balkans 179

table 8.1. Nation-Building Policies toward China’s largest Non-Core Groups,


1949–1965

Group’s
Perceptions of Non-Core Group Enjoys External Support
External
Power’s Strength Yes No

Enemy Ally or Neutral


Strong State Tibetans (U.S. 1959–1965) Tibetans (India Zhuang, Manchu,
Uyghurs (USSR 1949–1958) Yi, Hui, Miao,
1960–1965) Uyghurs (USSR Tujia, Buyi,
Kazaks (USSR 1960–1965) 1949–1959) Dong, Yao,
Group: Mobilization Kazaks (USSR Bai, Hani, Li
Host State: Exclusion 1949–1959) Group: No
Group: Exit/ Mobilization
Autonomy Host State:
Host State: Integration
Accommodation
Weak State Mongols (MPR Mongols (MPR
1960–1965) 1949–1959)
Group: Weak Mobilization Koreans (DPRK)
Host State: Integration/ Dai (Thailand and
Mix Burma)
Group: No
Mobilization
Host State:
Accommodation/
Mix

Source: Han and Mylonas 2011.

theory must be slightly modified. Allowing for an asymmetrical relationship,


that is, a weak external power supporting a non-core group, greatly influences
the non-core group’s agency and the level of threat for the host state. Thus, the
non-core group is less likely to mobilize against the host state and the latter is
also less likely to react violently to any form of mobilization since the threat is
low. Allowing for variation in the relative capacity of the external power versus
the host state is an important addition to my theory that brings back non-core
group’s agency to the fore.
In particular, from these eighteen groups, six either had external patrons
during the period under study or external kin relations with neighboring coun-
tries, while twelve of these groups were either indigenous to China alone or did
not enjoy any external support. For example, the Uyghurs and Kazaks have kin
relations with Central Asian states. Mongolia is a kin state for the Mongols, as
are both North and South Koreas for the Koreans. Non-core groups located in
180 Empirical Evidence

the Southwestern border areas – such as the Miao, Yao, Hani, and Dai – all have
external kin in mainland Southeast Asia but did not receive any external sup-
port. The Tibetans have extensive relations with groups in Bhutan, Nepal, and
India. Finally, as we have seen above, Tibetans and Uyghurs received external
support by Great Powers.
This variation often goes unnoticed in studies that focus on prominent groups
alone. In this extension of my work, in collaboration with Enze Han, I relaxed
the assumption with regard to relatively symmetrical host state–external patron
dyad and demonstrated that my argument can help us explain the variation in
nation-bulding policies as well as patterns of non-core group mobilization
(see Table 8.1).

Estonian Nation-Building in the Post–Cold War Era


Now we can turn to the post–Cold War era and focus on the policies toward the
“Russian-speakers” in Estonia35 with an eye on the role of two important post–
World War II developments: the emergence of strong regional integration proj-
ects, such as the EU, and the spread of international norms regarding human
rights.
Right after Independence, when Russian troops and KGB officers were still in
Estonia, the Russian-speaking population was perceived as a potential fifth
column and was thus targeted with exclusionary measures. By the mid-1990s,
with the withdrawal of the Russian troops as well as a shift in the Russian
Diaspora policy, a gradual turn to accommodation began. But it was only after
Estonia’s EU accession that more clear policies of accommodation for the
Russian-speakers emerged. Again, the cleavage between the Estonians and the
Russian-speakers is not a recent phenomenon; however, the activation of this
cleavage and the consequent nation-building policies pursued – and their tim-
ing – were conditional to a great extent on the interstate relations between
Estonia and Russia and between Estonia and the EU, which pressured Estonia
to accommodate the Russian-speakers.36 Consistent with my argument, the
Russian foreign policy toward its diaspora had a significant impact on the
nation-building policies pursued by the Estonian state. Let’s take a closer look.

35
For a historical overview of Estonian language and culture, see Raun 1991; Roos 1994; and David
Smith 2001 and 2005. For a comprehensive historical account of the Estonian party system and
cleavage structure since 1917, see Arter 1996 and Pettai and Kreuzer 1999. For a comparative
study of elections in Estonia during the transition period (1989–1993), see Raitviir 1996. For an
epitomized version of the process of transition with a focus on the internal competition among
Estonian elites, see Pettai and Hallik 2002, Steen and Ruus 2002. Ishiyama and Breuning (1998)
put the case of Estonia in a comparative perspective with other cases of ethnopolitical conflict in
Western and Eastern Europe. Finally, for very insightful comparative accounts on the question of
citizenship policies in the post-soviet Republics, see Brubaker 1992; Barrington 1995; and Smith
and Wilson 1997.
36
Also conditional, by extension, on the interstate relations between Russia and the EU.
Application of the Theory Beyond the Balkans 181

table 8.2. Ethnic Composition of Estonia, 1920–1989

Year Estonians (%) Russians (%)

1920 87.7 8.2


1934 87.8 8.2
1959 74.6 20.1
1979 64.7 27.9
1989 61.5 30.3

Source: Kirch et al. 1993: 174.

During the 1980s, glasnost and Perestroika changed the opportunity struc-
ture for mobilization in the Soviet Republics.37 Ethnic Estonians organized in
both moderate (Popular Front) and more extreme forms (Estonian Citizens
Committees). A nationalistic language law was introduced in 1989, and the
legal restorationist logic propagated by the Estonian Citizens Committees
together with their “grassroots campaign to register citizens of the pre-war
republics and their descendants,”38 were signals of exclusionary intentions
toward the Russian-speakers.39 Most of the latter had migrated to the Baltic
republics during the Soviet Era, as part of the central economic planning of the
Soviet Union. In this process of migratory flows, Russians were the most numer-
ous ethnic group to migrate in the region. Between 1979 and 1989, the Baltic
republics were the destination of 246,000 immigrants. Since the beginning of the
twentieth century, the share of the titular population in the total population
dropped from 87 percent to 61.5 percent in Estonia (see Table 8.2).
My theory predicts exclusionary policies in the first half of the 1990s. The
logic here is that the Estonian ruling elites in their efforts to restore the
Estonian State were really suspicious of a sizeable non-core group backed by
an enemy power – the Russian Federation (see Table 8.3).40 Indeed until the
withdrawal of the Russian military forces in 1994 the security of Estonia’s

37
Suny 1993.
38
Pettai and Hallik 2002: 510.
39
I use the term “Russian-speakers” for lack of a better term. Students of political science studying
the Baltics or Estonia in particular tend to take ethnic categories as given. Usually they base their
assumption on census data and surveys. However, the former imposes the criteria on the
respondents (Goskomstat SSSR 1991) and the later presupposes the existence and salience of
certain cleavages as early as the sampling stage (Rose and Maley 1994). This primordial under-
standing of the “Russian-speakers” is not restricted in journalistic or academic accounts (Baltic
Review, Ishiyama and Breuning 1998: 79), but also in the legal framework that has been
established in Estonia after independence. For more information on the Russian-speaking pop-
ulations, Russophones, the new diasporas, the Russians Beyond Russia, see Barrington 1995;
Berg 1999; Brubaker 1996; Mandelbaum 2000; Melvin 1995.
40
It is clear that the cleavage dimension that was politicized in Estonia around the period of
Restoration (1988–1992) was “ethnicity,” in the sense that Estonians were distinguished from
all the immigrants that moved in the country after the Soviet annexation. Four identity categories
182 Empirical Evidence

table 8.3. Russians Living in Estonia, 1989

Total Russians Living in Russians Fluent in


Total Number of Russians Urban Settlements Titular Language
Population Russians (%)% (%) (%)

Estonia 1,566,000 475,000 30.3 92 14.9

Source: Kolstø 2000: 201–222.

independence was not guaranteed in the eyes of its ruling elite. Thus the
Estonian ruling political elites at the time were revisionist and faced an
enemy-backed non-core group.
Indeed, under these conditions, exclusionary policies ensued. After the
August 1991 coup several highly exclusionary provisions were introduced in
relation to the naturalization process. It was at this point that the ethnic
Estonians managed to effectively exclude the Russian-speaking community
from the state. The Russian-speakers went from being a majority in the USSR,
enjoying privileges in housing and employment, to being a disenfranchised
minority in a restored Estonian State. Citizenship in Estonia was restricted to
those who or whose parents were citizens of the republic in 1940 (before the
annexation of Estonia to the USSR), and examinations in Estonian language
were necessary for naturalization. In 1991 (the year of independence), approx-
imately 450,000 non-Estonians,41 some of whom had lived their entire lives in
Estonia, were automatically disenfranchised.42 Moreover, injustices were
recorded during the process of pre–World War II property restitution.
After the Russian troops left Estonia, Estonian authorities took over all Union
enterprises and the property of the Estonian Communist Party (together with the
archives), and most of the political organizations that used to mobilize Russian-
speakers in favor of the Soviet Union (and had supported the August putsch)
were outlawed and new Russian organizations were created. At the same time
most Russian-speakers were excluded from the first parliamentary and presi-
dential elections. As Khrychikov and Miall put it:

On 21 June 1993, the Estonian government passed the Law on Aliens.. . . In the context of
radical anti-Russian and anti-Soviet rhetoric, in which prominent politicians and leading
parties did not hesitate to voice the desirability of expatriation of non-Estonians, the new
requirements were interpreted as a first step towards legalized expulsion.. . . At the same

were arrayed around the latter cleavage dimension: Estonian Citizens (including 75,000 ethnic
Russians in 1992), Citizens of the Russian Federation (with resident permits in Estonia), Stateless
persons (Undetermined Citizenship, mostly ethnic Russians), Citizens of other States (Ukraine,
Byelorussia, etc.).
41
A vast majority of this group was reported as ethnically Russian in the 1989 census (see Table 8.3),
followed by Ukrainian and Byelarussians. That accounts for the characterization of Russian-
speakers that has prevailed in the literature.
42
Berg 2001:14.
Application of the Theory Beyond the Balkans 183

time . . . President Boris Yeltsin warned that Estonia had forgotten about “geopolitical
and demographic realities” and pointed out that “Russia will take steps to defend its
national interests in Estonia.”43

Estonian elites had good reason to worry about the intentions of the powerful
backer of the Russian-speakers. In his first legislative act on the issue44 Yeltsin
referred to the same population in very inclusive terms, as “compatriots.”45
Thus, even people belonging to ethnic groups or nationalities that did not speak
Russian were considered to be subject to the Russian state policy. The Russian
Federation in the early 1990s cultivated the idea among the “compatriots
abroad” that they should expect support, within the framework of international
law, in the realization of their civil, political, social, and cultural rights.46
At this point the Russian-speaking community was clearly backed by the
Russian Federation and the exclusionary Estonian programmatic positions
with respect to Russian-speakers can actually be construed as a reaction to the
threat the latter posed for their national existence. This security logic under-
lying the decisionmaking process of the Estonian elites is consistent with my
argument.

Change in Russian Foreign Policy, End of Exclusionary Policies (1996–2000)


The terminology used in the 1994 presidential decree changed later on – toward
the end of 1996 – in the proposal of a new federal law on state policy for the
protection and support of the “diaspora of Russia” and the “compatriots of
Russia,” under discussion in the Duma, the lower house of the Federal Assembly
of Russia. Many high officials thought that the inclusiveness of the definition
was actually undermining the implementation of state policy.47
Gradually, the Russian Federation resorted to policies that aimed at keeping
the Russian-speaking populations in their respective regions abroad and using
them as an asset in economic matters, while at the same time avoiding an
enormous wave of refugees. Consequently, the official position wanted
Russians to adapt to the local culture “while retaining their specific cultural
identity.” According to Aalto this arrangement lasted until the late 1990s.48
The Russian government began to increasingly perceive the Baltic states as
“transit corridors for Russian export goods – mainly oil and other raw materi-
als – on their way to European markets”; while at the same time Russian think-
tanks “started changing their view.”49 Russian foreign policy makers decided to

43
2002: 195. For similar points, see Aalto 2003: 574; King and Melvin 1999/2000: 120.
44
Presidential decree No. 1681 of 11 August 1994, “On the basic directions of state policy of the
Russian Federation in relation to the compatriots living abroad.”
45
Presidential decree No. 1681 of 11 August 1994, Article 1, points 1 and 2.
46
For more on this, see Shevel 2011.
47
For more aggressive formulations of this thesis by Russian politicians, institutes, and political and
nongovernmental organizations, see Kolstø 2000.
48
2003: 576.
49
Ibid.
184 Empirical Evidence

stop getting involved in the affairs of the Russian-speakers in the Baltic States for
economic and geopolitical reasons.
At the same time, Estonia’s early invitation to join the EU in 1997 as well as
pressure from OSCE and the EU to improve its minority policies made any
Russian complaint for violations of the rights of the Russian-speakers less
credible. President Putin’s statement in 2001 that Estonia’s membership in
NATO was inevitable completed the new geopolitical arrangement.
The combination of international backing by the West (EU, the United States,
and NATO) coupled with the shift in Russian foreign policy that was already in
progress paved the way for a new approach by the Estonian state. It could now
afford to moderate its exclusionary policies and resort to assimilationist ones. In
the context of the EU, however, these policies had to be called “integrationist.”
The naturalization of Russian-speakers progressed faster and integrationist
rather than exclusionary arguments emerged. Consistent with my argument,
the Estonian government although hard pressed by the OSCE and the EU did not
consider policies of accommodation, such as cultural and linguistic rights, at any
point in the 1990s. Thus in the late 1990s and early twenty-first century:
[O]nly 113,764 had received citizenship by naturalization. The Language Law made
many jobs less accessible for people without a sufficient command of Estonian. In
February 1998, it was toughened to require fluency of everyone working in the service
industry or with customers. Members of the Riigikogu (the Estonian parliament) and
local councilors were also required to be fluent, a measure that clearly restricted the
representation of non-Estonians in state structures. University education was switched to
Estonian, resulting in a significant decline in the number of Russian-speakers entering
higher education. In 1998, Estonia also adopted a new education policy, which envisaged
the closure of Russian upper-secondary schools in 2007.50

International Pressure, “Shy Turn” to Accommodation (2001–2008)


Recent government documents proclaim that Estonia is striving to become a
multicultural society or, rather, that it has come to terms with its multicultural
character. The Estonian government has accepted the responsibility to align the
language legislation with international standards and the European Agreement.
It has committed to implement concrete measures for the integration of non-
citizens and include language training and necessary financial support.51 This
change in policy is not unrelated to subsiding threat perceptions.
Moreover, reluctant to jeopardize their relationship with the EU or NATO,
Estonians try to avoid provocations. Similarly, Herd and Löfgren report that
accession to the EU and the increased sense of security that this process generated
have both served to diminish the security concerns with respect to their Russian-
speaking communities.52 According to the Estonian Ministry of Defense,
“Between the years 2000 and 2003, the percentage of Estonians believing in

50
Khrychikov and Miall 2002: 198.
51
Berg and Van Meurs 2002: 259.
52
2001: 291–292.
Application of the Theory Beyond the Balkans 185

the probability of being attacked from another state steadily decreased from 33
to 15.”53
To be sure, the improvement of Russo-Baltic relations is an important but not
the only reason behind this shift toward accommodation. The Council of
Europe, EU, and the OSCE have all put pressure on Estonia and have been a
significant driving force behind the shift of Estonian nation-building policies
toward more accommodation.54 This pressure, part and parcel of the process of
EU integration, is important for the implementation of the relevant domestic
policy changes.

conclusion
All in all, my argument explains critical shifts in nation-building policies beyond
the interwar Balkans, provides a novel interpretive perspective on a variety of
cases, and accounts for complex empirical patterns that existing theories do not.
Further probing of the argument is necessary, but finding adequate evidence to
conclusively test my theory in each case is challenging. Material on cases beyond
the interwar Balkans presented in this chapter is consistent with my argument
that a host state’s foreign policy goals interact with the interstate relations
between the external power supporting a non-core group and the host state to
decide the nation-building policies pursued by the latter toward the non-core
group in question.
In the process, a number of conclusions were drawn. From the Balkan cases
some lessons stand out. First, I qualified a prominent view about the frequency
of scapegoating showing that it is rather a special case of false accusation of a
non-core group by a host state. Second, I confirmed the importance of one of
my scope conditions for the applicability of my argument, namely the ruling
elites must be motivated by a homogenizing imperative. Third, my argument
applies more generally in the modern Balkans; changes in the international
system impact patterns of alliances and thus the planning of nation-building
policies as well. From the cases outside the Balkans three insights arise: the role
of the relative capacity of the external power versus the host state, the need to
find the functional equivalent terms in each case to capture the concept of
assimilation, and the importance of regional integration and international
human rights norms in the post–World War II era, but especially the post–
Cold War era.
Many research questions emerge. For instance, more empirical work is
required on instances of scapegoating. This state policy is a special case of
false accusation of a non-core group by a host state; however, we have very little

53
Noreen and Sjöstedt 2004: 733.
54
One concrete sign of accommodation of the Russian-speaking community – besides the declara-
tions on intent in the programs of national integration submitted to Brussels – is Estonia’s decision
to change the electoral law and allow candidates to run in national elections irrespectively of their
level of proficiency in the Estonian language.
186 Empirical Evidence

systematic work on the conditions under which scapegoating occurs. Scholars


may also want to study the role that the relative capacity of the external power
versus the host state plays in the politics of nation-building policies. Finally,
work on the impact of regional integration and/or international human rights
norms on nation-building policies is long overdue. Pursuing these themes fur-
ther, however, would require another book.
9

Conclusion

I introduced my argument referring to the shift of Ottoman policies toward the


Armenians at the turn of the nineteenth century. Within a couple of decades,
Ottoman perceptions of Armenians changed dramatically from viewing them as
the most loyal millet to perceiving them as a threat to the country’s territorial
integrity. Policies of accommodation that lasted for centuries were followed by
mass killings and deportations. What accounts for this puzzling shift of Ottoman
perceptions and policies toward Armenians? Why, how, and when does one
become a co-ethnic, a minority, or a refugee?
The most prominent explanations for the variation in nation-building policies
focus on domestic factors. Often the ethnic politics that result from the salience
of different attributes between the core and the non-core group (race, religion,
language) are considered the cause of such policy choices.1 Other scholars
suggest that what matters are political ideologies of the ruling elites2 or the
regime type of the host state where the non-core group resides.3 For others the
history of past interactions between the core and the non-core groups4 or
demographic and terrain variables5 can explain state policies toward non-core
groups. All these explanations capture important aspects of the dynamics of
nation-building. But they cannot account for the variation in nation-building
policies across space and over time without taking into account the international
security environment. The dynamic that I have highlighted in both my theory
and empirical chapters has gone largely unnoticed.
Explanations that emphasize structural international factors to account for
the occurrence of various nation-building policies are important to understand-
ing long-term processes but unfit to account for quick shifts in nation-building
policies. For instance, if a non-core group has a national homeland, we should

1
Geertz 1963; Gurr 1993; Horowitz 1985; Kaufman 2001.
2
Browning and Matthäus 2004.
3
Brass 1991; Gagnon 1994/1995; Snyder 2000.
4
Petersen 2001 and 2002.
5
Fearon and Laitin 2003; Toft 2003.

187
188 Empirical Evidence

expect that the group is more likely to mobilize, be emboldened, and ultimately
rebel against the host state, thus bringing exclusionary policies upon it.6 As I
have made clear, however, international alliance patterns often trump such
dynamics and, importantly, national homelands do not always act as agitators
of co-ethnics abroad.
Mann’s systemic argument highlights the “dark side of democracy” suggest-
ing – among other things – that the international diffusion of the ideal of popular
rule converts demos into ethnos, which in turn generates “organic nationalism,”
and it ultimately encourages ethnic cleansing.7 Such systemic arguments are
useful to account for shifting aggregate patterns between historical periods or
regions but, again, cannot account for the differences in nation-building policies
pursued toward non-core groups that do not fit equally the ethnos in each case.
Finally, it is unclear what accounts for variation in nation-building policies in
authoritarian regimes that are not supposed to be subject to the same dynamics.
Overall, prominent domestic and international explanations either involve
processes that change slowly (e.g., modernization) or focus on attributes that can
hardly change (e.g., race, ethnicity). But nation-building policies can – and do –
shift at a faster pace. I have presented an argument that moves at a pace similar to
that of these policies.
Forging a bridge between the comparative politics and international relations
literature on this topic, I have argued that a state’s choice of nation-building
policies toward non-core groups is driven by both its foreign policy goals and its
interstate relations. The foreign policy goals of a host state may be revisionist or
status quo. Revisionist states are unhappy with the international status quo and
their foreign policy goals are focused on overturning it. Status quo states are
content with the existing state of affairs and want to preserve it. Interstate
relations with the external powers supporting non-core groups can take the
form of rivalry or alliance; these in turn are influenced by – but are independent
from – international alliance blocs.
A host state’s foreign policy goals as well as its perception of non-core groups
drive nation-building choices. The presence of external support for a non-core
group and the interstate relations between the external power and the host state
determine whether the group will be perceived as threatening or not. A non-core
group supported by an enemy external power and residing in a revisionist host
state is more likely to be excluded than targeted with assimilation or granted
minority rights; if a similar group were to reside in a status quo state it would be
most likely to be targeted with assimilationist policies. Non-core groups sup-
ported by allied states are more likely to be accommodated than assimilated or
excluded.
The evidence makes clear that the attributes of non-core groups are secondary
in the process I am describing. To be sure, ethnicity matters, but only when
activated in the international arena. Similarly, the existence of a homeland is also

6
Brubaker 1996; Jenne 2007; Van Houten 1998.
7
Mann 2005.
Conclusion 189

endogenous to interstate relations with the host state, since in my framework an


external power chooses when to act as a “homeland” based on these relations.
Nor do I argue that cultural distance arguments are trivial. While it is true that
I draw attention to and force into the discussion international factors previously
ignored, I do so without seeking to discount or trivialize cultural distance argu-
ments. In fact, religion comes up as statistically significant in my statistical
analysis. Moreover, in the empirical chapters, I control for cultural distance to
isolate the effect of international factors, not to render it obsolete.
Furthermore, cultural distance arguments may very well be important for the
success or failure of certain policies, but not as relevant in the decisionmaking
process of core group elites when they plan their nation-building policies. When
the core group elites face a culturally similar non-core group that is supported by
an enemy power, the cultural similarity will not prevent them from deporting or
exterminating the group. For example, in the 1920s the Turkish-speaking
Christian Orthodox population was included in the Greco-Turkish population
exchange together with the Greek-speaking population of Asia Minor. Loyalty
matters more than cultural markers in the age of nationalism.
Here is the appropriate point to clarify one more thing. The focus of my work
is not non-core groups that have suffered status reversals but non-core groups
perceived by the core group elites as being supported by an external power. It
may be true that groups that have experienced status reversal are more likely to
rebel than other types of groups;8 such findings do not contradict my theory. In
fact, such findings might be endogenous to my argument since groups that have
experienced status reversal might also be more likely to be supported by external
powers because of their propensity to rebel and their organizational cohesion.
In Chapters 3–7, I focused on the politics of nation-building in the states that
emerged from the gradual decline of the Ottoman Empire in Europe. These cases
provided an optimal context in which to study nation-building policies due to the
protracted intermingling of peoples, common experiences of past rule, similar
modernization trajectories, and a great deal of external involvement, as well as
variation in the timing of their state-building experiences. In Chapter 8, I moved out
of the southeast corner of Europe, relaxed some of my assumptions from Chapter 2,
and illustrated the generalizability but also some of the limitations of my argument.
More such tests are necessary to calibrate the theory for today’s rapidly changing
international system.

three conceptual moves


This book makes three critical conceptual moves: first, from “minority” to “non-
core group”; second, from “homeland” to “external power”; and third, from the
dichotomous conceptualization of nation-building policies as “inclusion/exclu-
sion” or “violent/non-violent” to “assimilation, accommodation, and exclusion.”

8
Horowitz 1985; Petersen 2001 and 2002.
190 Empirical Evidence

The first move addresses a long-standing problem in nationalism and ethnic


politics studies. Calling a “non-core group” a “minority” often implies either a
legal status, recognition from the host state, or the existence of a claim by the non-
core group. Thus, referring to “non-core groups” as “minorities” carries a wide
range of assumptions that are often flawed. In my framework, a minority is a non-
core group that has been targeted with accommodationist policies or one aspiring
recognition. The term “non-core group” is more adequate since it includes aggre-
gations of people who are conscious of their difference from the dominant national
type without necessarily being mobilized around this difference. It does not imply
anything about group size, and allows us to view even stereotypical members of
the demographic core group as targets of assimilationist policies by the ruling
political elites and not necessarily assume their national loyalty. In the initial stages
of nation-building even people who fit the criteria of inclusion in the core group
are often not conscious of their national identity and in that sense they have to be
assimilated through conscription, schooling, and other nationwide policies. The
term “minority” obscures these important points.
The second conceptual move facilitates the study of third parties involved in
the mobilization process of a “non-core group” without being an “external kin”
or “homeland.” In my framework the “external power” could be a neighboring
state, a great power, a diaspora group, a non-governmental organization, or a
combination of these that interferes with the political fate of a non-core group in
the host state. The term “homeland” is restrictive and cannot capture the full
range of external actors involved.
The third move refers to the conceptualization of nation-building policies.
The dichotomies of inclusion versus exclusion or violent versus non-violent
policies are common ways of categorizing policies. I hold that they do not
capture the full range of the observed variation. A nuanced and robust theory
of nation-building must focus equally on violent and non-violent policies pur-
sued by governments engaged in nation-building policies. In order to better
capture the options available to nation-builders, I conceptualize nation-building
policies by constructing a categorical variable that takes the following values:
accommodation, assimilation, and exclusion. I also allow for mixed policies not
just as an unintended consequence but as part of a strategy.
Existing conceptualizations put emphasis on explaining the occurrence of the
most violent state policies such as genocide, mass killing, or ethnic cleansing. As
a result, theories end up over-aggregating the different “peaceful” outcomes
under the residual category of “non-violent” or “inclusionary,” however, there
is an important difference between assimilation and accommodation.
Disaggregating policies is key if we want to test mechanisms, address observa-
tional equivalence problems, and unearth the logic of nation-building.

methodological contributions
While collecting archival material and secondary sources to test the various
explanations against my own argument, I identified a wide range of caveats in
Conclusion 191

the study of nation-building. Scholars who study state-planned nation-building


policies face both technical and conceptual problems. To begin with, as dis-
cussed in the Appendix to Chapter 4 there is the politics of “counting people.”
This issue refers to the difficulties and politics involved in three interrelated
choices: identifying a group as an “ethnic group” or a “minority,” deciding on
an estimate of its population, and studying it as a relatively unitary and homo-
geneous entity. The most common methodological problems resulting are selec-
tion bias and overaggregated actors.
Similarly, in Chapter 5 I identified more caveats in the study of nation-
building policies. First, we discussed how the time horizon chosen in each
study affects the results we get. Second, that governments often pursue mixed
policies toward certain non-core groups. Third, we found that sometimes a
government will pursue a transitional nation-building policy before it pursues
its terminal one. Fourth, it was revealed that external powers’ foreign policy
priorities and the degree to which alliances are asymmetrical significantly impact
the decisionmaking process of host states with respect to nation-building.
Another caveat in the study of nation-building policies involves a “revealed
preferences problem” in the social sciences, namely the practice of inferring an
actor’s intentions by taking statements at face value or just observing the out-
comes on the ground. In Chapter 6 I discussed the importance of disentangling
the relationship between intentions, policies, implementation, and outcomes in
order to understand the process of nation-building.
In the nation-building process, intentions, policy choices, and policy out-
comes are definitely linked, yet intentions are not always translated into policy
choices, nor do those choices always produce the desired outcome. Moreover,
policy choices are sometimes a function of capabilities and not of intentions.
Other times, intentions are veiled because of the possibility of external interven-
tion by an international organization or a hegemonic power. Moreover, private
interests and biases of state officials, especially at lower levels of the adminis-
tration, interfere in the planning and implementation of state policies. As a
result, many theories are developed and tested on “events” that were unintended
consequences or forced outcomes rather than accurate reflections of the admin-
istration’s intentions. The outcome often is deceptive empirical support for or
incorrect falsification of theories.
An archival approach can help us address the revealed-preferences problem.
Studying the decisionmaking process that led to nation-building policies helps
differentiate between the intentions of the administration toward a particular
non-core group and the actual policy that it eventually adopts. One might argue
that this is not necessary because what actually matters in politics is the policy
that is implemented. However, if we want to understand why state officials
choose particular nation-building policies and not others, studying only the
observed outcomes will not suffice.
For example, two different non-core groups might be granted the same
minority rights, but with a different reasoning behind each case. In practical
terms, the reasoning matters because it most likely will inform the policy
192 Empirical Evidence

implementation. In theoretical terms, understanding elites’ reasons can help


distinguish between rival explanations. For instance, a hypothesis might predict
the granting of minority rights to a non-core group, but for completely different
reasons than the ones that were behind the actual decision. In this case, although
the hypothesis makes the “right” prediction, it does not accurately capture the
logic behind the policy.
To drive this point home, let us return to an example from Chapter 6, the
granting of minority rights to “Romanians.” A Romanian minority was recog-
nized by the Greek administration because Romania was an allied power at the
time and Greece needed its support in the diplomatic arena to secure its terri-
torial gains from the Balkan wars; this reasoning is consistent with my argument.
The Romanian minority was never thought of as something permanent and it
was treated from the beginning as an instrumental concession to be countered on
the ground. This case was different from the strategic nature of the initial
accommodation of the Muslims in Western Greek Macedonia.
In addition to the important difference between intentions and actual policy
choices, a distinction must be made between these policy choices and policy
implementation. The importance of this distinction is captured in the case of the
“Bulgarian-leaning” Slavs in Western Greek Macedonia. As described previ-
ously, Mazarakis recommended the deportation of the entire population,
describing this as a more “radical” measure for nationalizing the territory.
However, Eliakis dismissed this idea not because he deemed it immoral or
unfeasible, but rather because the Greek government had to act as “a civilized
liberal polity in the eyes of the international community.” A more practical
concern of his had to do with the ability of the Greek administration to repopu-
late these lands. A mass deportation of all the Bulgarian-speakers would have led
to a severe depopulation of Macedonia and resulted in economic loss for the
state. Instead, the governor ended up proposing the “hard and rough way of
proselytizing, through good and expensive administration.” Eliakis’s position
again points to the distinction between intentions and policy choices. A few years
later, however, Eliakis admitted that the policy of assimilation had been ineffi-
cient because it was poorly implemented. From this example we see how the
initial suggestion of deporting a non-core group was transformed into a policy
recommendation of targeting the group with assimilationist policies, and how
later, the leader responsible for the policy decision admitted its relative failure
due to poor implementation.
Both the challenges of the “revealed preferences problem” and the conflation
of intentions, policies, implementation, and outcomes hinder the study of state-
planned nation-building policies. Chapter 6 stands as a critique to studies in
comparative politics and international relations that fail to address these prob-
lems but mostly as an invitation for more work in this line.
Another related difficulty I have identified emerges from the principal-agent
problems that exist in any administrative system. I discussed these problems in
Chapter 7. In their effort to characterize various state policies toward non-core
groups scholars often rely on reports by journalists, secondary sources,
Conclusion 193

eyewitnesses, and archives. Often these reports are biased and even archival
documents can be forged. But even if they are not, another problem complicates
efforts to characterize a state policy: principal-agent problems. The events
reported (e.g., massacres, arson, rape, looting) might have taken place, but
they might not have been ordered by the central administration. It is difficult
to know whether a central policy actually is implemented locally or whether the
local elites pursue their own independent policies. The archival material I use in
this book provides ample examples of principal-agent problems. In many cases
the central administration of the state had both different intentions and policy
preferences than its local officials – not to mention its core group members. The
result of this incongruence ranged from private discrimination to systematic
violation of human rights by local authorities and even the use of violence.
Moreover, while archival material allows us to trace the logic behind the
choice of nation-building policies across groups and over time at the elites’ level;
it does not allow us to assess the effectiveness of the various policies or even the
extent and quality of their implementation. The actual implementation of such
policies is always mediated by various administrative levels from the mayor to
individual police officers – and sometimes even individual citizens.
In Chapter 7, we discussed an illustration of this in the Kingdom of Serbia
where British consuls referred to excessive use of violence by the Serbian army.
The consul pondered over the locus of agency of these actions. The degree of
control of the Serbian administrative apparatus in the newly annexed territories
as well as the quality of policy implementation of state policies is still an under-
studied topic. It remains unclear what percentage of the actions observed on the
ground in Kosovo were dictated by Belgrade and what was part of a micro-level
story of opportunism on the part of uncoordinated individuals. Trotsky writes
about paramilitaries that killed and looted, but whose connection to the official
Serbian forces it was not possible to ascertain.9 According to Stefanović, “the
very existence of the paramilitaries was out of question without the consent,
encouragement, supply, and toleration of the authorities.”10 With respect to
administrators, we do know that they were often selected on the basis of patron-
age and were not trained at all.
We find similar concerns in a report to the Hellenic Ministry of Foreign
Affairs by the Governor-General of Epirus, A. Kalevras, where he writes: “The
officer of the police had his own national policy. The local military authorities
also had their own national policy, and so did the educational and re-
settlement civil servants.”11 Similarly, Repoulis, Minister of the Interior during
World War I, was attributing the difficulties the Greek administration faced in
assimilating the local population in Macedonia to the fact that the state
representatives were not following state policy and laws but rather acted in a
capricious manner.

9
Trotsky 1980: 99, 120.
10
2005: 475.
11
Quoted in Divani 1995: 247.
194 Empirical Evidence

Eliakis was also always concerned about the principal-agent problem. His
conviction was that things would have been different if the representatives of the
administration in the new lands had been different. Prime Minister Venizelos
also did not conceal his frustration with this phenomenon. As the Serbian
Minister of Interior reported to the Serbian Ministry of Foreign Affairs:

Venizelos is disappointed by the actions of the Greek authorities. . .. Addressing the


Prefect St. Gregoriou, he told him, “You are forgetting that in Greece there is only one
policy, the one that requires the preservation of friendly relations with the Serbs, without
propagandas, chauvinisms, and provocations. However, you are following a wholly
different policy and you will be punished for that.”12

Also in Turkey we know that certain local officials did go beyond the scope of
their orders in the persecution of Armenians and Greeks, illegally confiscating
properties and arbitrarily discriminating against particular individuals.
This list of cases and relevant stories is far from exhaustive, but still makes the
point that the principal-agent problem affects the study of nation-building
policies in a number of ways. To begin with, focusing on local events may give
us a misleading picture of the overall policy of a state administration. For
example, if we find evidence of systematic police abuse toward the members of
a specific non-core group in a locality we are studying, we might be tempted to
infer that this was a policy choice coming from the central administration.
However, such an inference is often unwarranted. Thus if we want to under-
stand the logic of state-planned nation-building policies we have to make an
effort to distinguish central policy from unauthorized actions by local author-
ities.13 Certainly, such a distinction might be unnecessary if we are trying to
understand the success or failure of certain policies, but it is crucial if we want to
discern the logic of central policy planning.
The above challenges impede the study of state-planned nation-building
policies. Not addressing them in our research can lead to deceptive empirical
support for theories or just wrongheaded theories. This book demonstrates the
centrality of archival research and careful process tracing in the effort to over-
come these important caveats in the study of nation-building and serves as a call
for more interdisciplinary work in the social sciences.
Beyond the discussion of the methodological problems, important questions
remain unanswered and require further research. A set of questions revolves
around the form that different nation-building policies take. What accounts for
the variation in the actual means that a government follows in order to assimilate,
accommodate, or exclude a non-core group? Why is one group targeted with
violent assimilationist policies while another with non-violent ones? Why are some
groups targeted with deportation while others with mass killing? Another set of
questions has to do with the nature of the modern state itself in the future. Is the

12
Quoted in Hassiotis 2004: 353.
13
There are cases of centrally planned tolerance of unauthorized behavior. The motivations for this
vary widely.
Conclusion 195

nation-state model going to survive the parallel pressures coming from regional
integration and globalization? What type of state may replace the nation-state?
In our effort to answer these and other research questions, focusing on the
meso-level is key. Bridging the macro-level with the micro-level, that is, under-
standing the structure of the international system in which nation-building takes
place at the local level, is crucial. Studies that focus on specific regions or specific
ethnic groups would benefit from a more explicit treatment of the international
dimensions of the process they are analyzing. The international context affects
the preference ordering of host states, external powers that contemplate inter-
ference, and non-core group elites alike. Scholars studying the politics of nation-
building should also focus more on the perceptions of state officials as well as the
influential international players (Great Powers, international organizations,
nongovernmental organizations), and try to identify the new cleavage dimen-
sions that are about to be politicized.
At the same time, studies that emphasize the importance of systemic effects
but neglect the micro-level processes at work are also problematic. Such studies
often fail to identify the right level of analysis for data collection and hypotheses
testing. Moreover, they suffer from a “revealed preferences problem” because
they frequently make inferences about the actor’s motivations based exclusively
on public statements or observed behavior. Archival material coupled with
historical contextualization is one way to mitigate this problem. A balanced
study of nation-building should bridge the micro-level empirical work with the
systemic effects of the structure of the international system by providing a
theoretical argument at the meso-level, linking the macro- and the micro-levels.

policy implications
What we learn by examining a number of empirical examples is that external
involvement in favor of specific unassimilated ethnic groups in other countries
significantly impacts – all too often for the worse – the nation-building policies
national governments adopt toward these groups. There are thousands of ethnic
groups living in roughly 195 countries today,14 mostly concentrated in post-
imperial and post-colonial territories. Understanding the logic of nation-
building is therefore crucial to navigating the challenges ethnic diversity poses
to the international system. Such an understanding could help decisionmakers in
the international community devise incentives to prevent ethnic cleansing,
encourage accommodation, or foster national integration.
In particular, three policy implications flow from my analysis. To prevent
exclusionary policies we should (1) uphold the principle of state sovereignty and
(2) encourage governments that venture to assist non-core groups in enemy host
states to be particularly judicious. Finally, if our goal is to increase the probability
of accommodation, we should (3) increase interstate alliances through regional
integration initiatives and international institutions such as the EU and ASEAN.

14
Doyle 1998.
196 Empirical Evidence

1. Self-Determination as a Universal Norm: a Pandora’s Box


To prevent exclusionary policies, we should uphold the principle of state sover-
eignty. The United Nations should only allow the creation of new states in cases
where there will not be any non-core groups in the newly independent states or,
alternatively, no external power would have an interest in interfering in their
internal affairs.
The principle of state sovereignty has guided the international system for
more than three hundred years. Since the Peace of Westphalia, modern states
have agreed not to interfere with the internal matters of their neighbors, partic-
ularly those that concern their religious and more recently ethnic non-core
groups. Once a state’s borders are in place, international law guarantees their
integrity. The unintended consequences of ethnic partitions have typically
brought more violence, more interstate conflict, and more self-determination
movements. Moreover, major global players such as the United States and
Russia are often supporting self-determination movements without much evi-
dence that they have thought through the consequences (intended and unin-
tended ones). In short: the most judicious plan of action is to work with the
borders we have, not the borders we want.15
Another reason for discouraging self-determination movements is the well-
documented phenomenon of “horizontal escalation” of ethnic conflict.16 We
know that events in one state can – and often do – affect the politics in
neighboring states. This can happen directly (e.g., through refugee flows) or
indirectly (e.g., by “inspiring” a new movement in the neighboring state). There
are plenty of such examples in Africa (e.g., Congo, Rwanda, Burundi, Sudan,
Chad), in the Balkans (e.g., Albanians from Kosovo moving to former Yugoslav
Republic of Macedonia), and in the Middle East (e.g., Kurds from Turkey
moving to Iraq). Gleditsch suggests “the international community can alter the
prospects for conflict by regulating access to transnational support, mobiliza-
tion, and the availability of arms.”17 He is right, but such efforts presuppose a
consensus over the principles that should guide the international system. Judging
from the recent deadlock in the UN Security Council over the situation in Syria,
this is in short supply.18
As long as hegemonic blocs of the international community continue to
reward overly assertive self-determination movements with new states and
partition settlements, the leaders of such movements will continue to pursue
maximalist goals – and in response, host states will be more likely to pursue
exclusionary policies.

15
Meaney and Mylonas 2008.
16
Lake and Rothchild 1998.
17
2007: 305.
18
For more on the conflict in Syria, see http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-middle-east-17258397.
Conclusion 197

2. Minimize External Involvement


The causes of interethnic conflict are often to be found outside the place in which
they are taking place. External involvement by interested powers politicizes
differences that had not been as salient before and often triggers exclusionary
policies by the host state; an example of this process occurring was the 2008
Georgian War.19 The best safeguard against exclusionary policies is to preclude
the eventuality of a non-core group being perceived as externally supported,
especially by an enemy. As long as there are external powers that have an interest
in destabilizing or partitioning other states, however, assimilationist and exclu-
sionary policies will persist. Foreign policy decisionmakers ought to be partic-
ularly judicious in supporting indigenous movements in other states – China and
Iran are two pertinent examples – since their governments might pursue exclu-
sionary policies against enemy-backed non-core groups.
Thus, the decision whether it is a good idea for an external power to support a
non-core group or not – in the special case where the host state is an enemy –
depends on the relative capabilities between the external power and the host
state and the degree of commitment of the former. For instance, if the external
power is significantly stronger than the host state and is willing to dedicate all the
necessary resources to support a specific non-core group, then external backing
may work to the benefit of the non-core group and maybe even force the host
state to change its policies. The auxiliary assumption here is that the external
power will act quickly enough to avoid any desperate measures used by the host
state against the non-core group.20
Critics might ask, “What should we do when groups are forcefully repressed by
their host state?” From a moral standpoint, the world community has an obliga-
tion to protect them.21 But it is far from clear that – uncritically or self-interestedly –
supporting self-determination movements and partitioning existing states is the
best policy for protecting the human rights of non-core group members. History
shows that government elites are more likely to consider ethnic cleansing as a
solution whenever an enemy-backed movement for a new state emerges.
In a recent study, Kuperman and Crawford found that non-core groups often
turn to violent means of claim-making in anticipation of external support.22
Bearing in mind that there are thousands of ethnic groups that are concentrated
in post-imperial and post-colonial territories, the explosive potential consequen-
ces of failing to address these problems are apparent.
There is an important and ongoing debate over humanitarian military inter-
vention and its unintended consequences for nation-building policies.
Intervention in favor of discriminated-against minorities and oppressed peoples
is widely seen today – probably more so than ever before – as a coverup for other,

19
For more on this, see Meaney and Mylonas 2008.
20
Downes 2006.
21
Bellamy 2009; Hoffmann and Hollkaemper 2012.
22
2006; Bob 2005.
198 Empirical Evidence

more cynical political goals and interests. Regardless of the external powers’
actual motivations (ethnic kinship, human rights, or pure geopolitical interest) in
supporting non-core groups against host states, the intervening power is likely to
trigger exclusionary policies and repression, particularly in a world order where
assimilationist policies have been greatly delegitimized.
Moreover, an international system that favors aggressive humanitarian inter-
vention is more likely, all things being equal, to experience rebellions and self-
determination movements, since the opportunity structure for non-core groups
is more favorable. Even when an intervention is genuinely attempting to address
a local conflict and is not part of geopolitical competition, perverse incentives
may easily be generated. If the goal is to prevent ethnic cleansing, then third
parties should stop “offering rhetorical and military support for armed seces-
sionists and revolutionaries in the name of fighting oppression and defending
human rights, whether in Rwanda, Bosnia, Kosovo, East Timor, Iraq or else-
where unless they are prepared to act quickly and decisively.”23 The future of
nation-building policies will correlate closely with the changing international
norms of humanitarian intervention.24
It is conceivable that a broad shift away from exclusionary policies would
occur if there were no longer any non-core groups mobilized by enemy powers.
However, external powers interested in destabilizing certain states persist, and
with them so do assimilationist and exclusionary policies. This is not to say that
the international efforts to check such practices have no impact on the process.
However, the classic drivers of international politics appear to still define the
politics of ethnicity today, and there is little reason to think this reality will
vanish anytime soon.

3. Regional Alliances and Nation-Building Policies


If we envision a multicultural world where ethnic and racial hierarchies will no
longer exist and a new model of citizenship will emerge,25 we should increase
interstate alliances through regional integration initiatives and international
institutions. There are three presuppositions behind this statement: that states
participating in regional integration schemas such as the European Union are
less likely to be revisionist, more likely to be in an alliance with their neighboring
states, and consequently more likely to accommodate their non-core groups.
Overall, I hold that countries in regions that have established stable security
configurations are more likely to move toward multicultural arrangements.
For example, the current prevalence of accommodation in Europe is the
product of EU integration, which began since the Treaty of Rome was signed
in 1957. ASEAN has also had a more limited but similar impact in Southeast

23
Kuperman 2001: viii.
24
Finnemore 2004.
25
Joppke 2005; Kymlicka 2012.
Conclusion 199

Asia. The norm of nonintervention enforced by ASEAN has contributed to the


proliferation of accommodationist policies and the prevention of exclusionary
ones. Similarly, the deepening of regional alliances through a “Eurasian Union”
proposed by Vladimir Putin is likely to lead to less exclusionary policies and the
accommodation of Russians in the near abroad as well as allied-supported non-
core groups within the Russian Federation.26

Looking Ahead: The Structure of the International System


The future of nation-building policies will ultimately depend on the future of the
international system, and vice versa. While everyone agrees that the bipolar
system that existed during the Cold War belongs to the past, there is less of a
consensus as to what has taken its place since the dissolution of the Soviet Union.
The United States has been recognized by scholars and journalists alike as the
only superpower for all of the 1990s and into the twenty-first century, providing
analysts with evidence for a “unipolar moment.” However, experts have been
increasingly arguing that we live in a “multipolar” or a “nonpolar” world.27
Whether multipolar or nonpolar, the international system is definitely not
unipolar as it was in the 1990s or bipolar as it was during the Cold War. The
United States, China, Russia, the United Kingdom, France, Germany, India, and
Japan are the most important poles of the international system. The picture
becomes a great deal more complicated once we consider regional powers as
well, such as Brazil, Iran, and South Africa. China’s change of stance with
respect to interference in other countries’ affairs, the resurgence of Russia’s
hegemonic intentions, and U.S. unwillingness to give up its global hegemonic
role are hard to reconcile. Without strong and functional international institu-
tions, the rise of competing hegemonic powers may lead to an international
system and nation-building policies that approximate those of the interwar
period.

26
Putin, Vladimir. “A new integration project for Eurasia: The future in the making,” Izvestia, 4
October 2011. Available at: http://premier.gov.ru/eng/events/news/16622/.
27
Haass 2008: 44–56.
Methodological Appendix

a. the politics of “counting people”


The most daunting problem of studying nation-building is that of deciding
which groups should be included in the analysis. The necessary historical
research has not progressed enough in this highly politicized field to allow for
a clear picture of the situation on the ground in the Balkan states during the
period of interest.
The politics surrounding statistics on “national minorities” or “ethnic
groups” is an extremely problematic aspect in the study of nation-building.
First, whoever is doing the counting often predetermines the results. Second,
even if we assume that existing statistics on ethnic composition are accurate, we
can never be sure that the categories used in a census were the most salient ones
for the people on the ground. For example, depending on which dimension the
state census committee chooses to highlight – religious affiliation, mother
tongue, regional identity, racial categories, or ethnic origin – it can produce a
very different “ethnic structure.”
An aggregate approach to issues related to nation-building is precarious and
cannot serve as the final word. Using census data to explain nation-building
policies is, to an extent, confusing the outcome for the cause. Census data on
“ethnicity” are part and parcel of nation-building policies and so are maps and
atlases.1 The obvious case is that of groups that are not represented in census
categories and are thus muted.
Take the Ottoman Empire, for example, which granted official status only
to religious communities (millets). The Ottoman censuses record Muslims,
Orthodox Christians, Gregorian Christians, Jews, and, later, Catholics and
Protestants. Ottoman statistics provide no information about language, cultural
difference, or national consciousness. In the Balkan Peninsula in particular, this
meant that Muslim Albanian-speakers, Turkish-speakers, Ladino-speakers
(Donmehs – Jewish converts to Islam), and other Muslim groups were all under
the broad “Muslim” category. Similarly, all Christian Orthodox people – Slavic-
speakers with various national affiliations, Albanian-speakers, Greek-speakers,

1
Black 2002; Wilkinson 1951; Wood 1992.

201
202 Methodological Appendix

Vlach-speakers, Sarakatsans, and so forth – were considered members of the


Rum millet, represented by the Greek-dominated Patriarchate in Istanbul.
The transition from empire to nation-state in the Balkans occurred in the
nineteenth and twentieth centuries, and with it a transition in the relevant
recorded categories occurred. The same inhabitants of these territories were
now aggregated with respect to language or a notion of national consciousness
that was, at least initially, vague. This was the face of modernity in the region.
Modern states in Western Europe, such as Germany and Great Britain, recorded
language use and national origin in their censuses, and the Balkan states fol-
lowed suit in order to be on equal footing and to try to prove their historical
rights on disputed territories. In the hands of the ruling political elites of the
Balkan states, the census was part of a broader war for the hearts and minds of
the newly incorporated rural populations.
Scholars of nationalism and ethnic conflict have relied on various indices
such as the Ethnolinguistic Fractionalization Index,2 the Politically Relevant
Ethnic Groups,3 Fearon’s,4 Alesina et al.’s,5 and so forth to capture ethnic
diversity. Most studies rely either on census categories or on material pro-
duced by the elites of “oppressed” groups. Both sources are inadequate if our
research question has to do with state-planned nation-building policies. For
example, when we use census data, we are likely to get deflated population
estimates of certain non-core groups and no estimates for the ones that are
targeted with assimilationist policies. Similarly, if we try to discern the ethnic
makeup of a country or a region using material produced by the elites of non-
core groups we often encounter propaganda that inflates their numbers. In
this latter case, however, what is more disconcerting is that we are not
capturing any of the non-core groups whose elites have been successfully
co-opted, or any non-core groups with no elites. Selection bias is therefore
almost unavoidable.
Another caveat in the study of nation-building policies is that all of these
data collection projects I cited above ignore small groupings of people; this
occurs in multiple ways. First, most of the times the cutoff point for inclusion
in a study of ethnic politics or conflict is 1 percent of a country’s population.
This means that groups that are relatively small are rarely if ever included in
existing models. If a scholar is genuinely interested in including small groups
(or even potential groups) he or she is quickly discouraged by the lack of data.6
But even if we assume that someone has all the censuses of the world for the

2
Atlas Narodov Mira 1964.
3
Posner 2004.
4
Fearon 2003.
5
Alesina et al. 2003.
6
I should note that the Ethnic power relations data set is an attempt to solve this problem (Cederman
et al. 2010) and the Minorities at Risk project is also working on improving its dataset in this
direction (Birnir et al. 2011).
Methodological Appendix 203

past hundred years down to the individual questionnaire and an army of


research assistants to help with coding, even then the biases would persist
since the categories used are the ones strategically selected by political elites
and not disinterested academics.
The seriousness of this problem depends on the research question of interest.
A straightforward way in which ignoring small groups is problematic is to think
of the possibility that a country has 30 groups smaller than 1 percent, which
cumulatively total 15 to 20 percent of the total population, as compared with a
country that has two such groups. The seriousness of such neglect becomes even
more apparent when we consider the possibility that this very fragmentation is
an outcome of state policy, as the divide and rule pattern discussed in Chapter 5
suggests, rather than a mere fact of the ethnic landscape.
Finally, comparability across countries is further hindered by the fact that
statistical bureaus collect data on identity categories that are arrayed around
different cleavage dimensions in each country. And, as we know from the
empirical record, once the decision concerning the cleavage dimension and the
relevant identity categories has been taken, a particular incentive structure is
created for individuals on the ground. The result is usually overreporting in
favor of the core group.
How can we overcome this situation where available statistics are capturing
host states’ nation-building policies instead of realities on the ground? One way
to avoid this bias is to shun data from conflict-ridden territories until a fair
amount of time has passed. Biased estimates and census manipulation are much
more likely in contested areas. Focusing on such cases only exacerbates the
problem. Detached historical research can put things into perspective. For
example, Yugoslavia and Austria both claimed Carinthia for the first half of
the twentieth century. According to the Austrian census of 1951, there were only
7,000 Slovenes in the Klagenfurt area of Carinthia, while the Yugoslavs claimed
that there were more than 35,000. What accounts for this discrepancy? The
Austrian census grouped people by “language used daily” into nine identity
categories: “German, Slovene, Windish (a Slovenian dialect), and six combina-
tions of the three.”7 Scholars had no way to tell how many “Slovenes” were
living there. Moreover, the population inhabiting Carinthia could be grouped in
various different ways depending on the census question. Data from contested
territories are unreliable; scholars studying such areas should be upfront about
the various sources of bias.
Another solution involves looking at census data that were produced prior to
significant political changes in a region. In the case of Southeastern Europe, I
overcame several problems with the help of the Ottoman censuses from the
nineteenth century, as well as confidential diplomatic reports prior to World
War I.

7
Kostanick 1974: 27.
204 Methodological Appendix

The ideal solution when studying state-planned nation-building policies,


however, is to move our attention to state policymakers and take their percep-
tions seriously. The ruling political elites, who are central to the planning of
nation-building policies, know that they cannot ignore non-core groups. These
governmental officials, ministers, and governors write reports and confidential
documents concerning groups of people that rarely come up in censuses or
newspapers. They are treasures for both building and testing hypotheses. In the
empirical chapters of this book, I relied primarily on such sources.
To construct the dataset for the post–World War I Balkans, I initially looked
at available censuses (here we find the groups that the state recognized as
“minorities”); then I moved on to secondary sources (here we find some excellent
books but also a lot of the propaganda); and then to consular reports, and other
materials such as memoranda, petitions, and telegrams from the region (here we
get a complex but also more comprehensive picture). Once I put together a list of
non-core groups, I then coded the nation-building policies pursued toward them
by their respective host states.
A list of the secondary sources I used is available in this appendix. I also
conducted a coding reliability test consulting academics, human rights activists,
and journalists from the region – the names of those who answered full question-
naires are included in my acknowledgments. This final step was especially crucial
for the coding of my dependent variable because it forced me to engage alternative
interpretations of these historical events. All final judgments remain my own.

b. codebook

Variable
Name Description Coding Rule

Policy Nation-building policy When the ruling political elites


accommodate the non-core group, I
assign the value “0”; when they
pursue assimilationist policies I
assign the value “1”; finally, when
they adopt exclusionary measures, I
assign the value “2.”
Prediction Theory prediction When my theory predicts accom-
modation of the non-core group, I
assign the value “0”; when it pre-
dicts assimilationist policies I assign
the value “1”; finally, when it pre-
dicts exclusionary measures, I assign
the value “2.”
Methodological Appendix 205

Variable
Name Description Coding Rule

External Non-core group has external sup- Coded as “1” if the non-core group
port (Configuration I) was supported by any external
power, “0” if it was not.
Extally Non-core group supported by an Coded as “1” if the non-core group
ally (Configuration II) was mobilized by an ally, “0”
otherwise.
Extenemy Non-core group supported by an Coded as “1” if the non-core group
enemy was mobilized by an enemy power,
“0” otherwise.
Revisionist Host state – revisionist Coded as “1” if the host state was
revisionist, “0” if it was status quo.
ConfigIII Enemy-supported group in revi- Coded as “1” if the non-core group
sionist host state (Configuration is supported by an enemy and lives in
III) a revisionist host state, “0”
otherwise.
ConfigIV Enemy supported non-core group Coded as “1” if the non-core group
in status quo host state is supported by an enemy and lives in
(Configuration IV) a status quo, “0” otherwise.
Contiguous Host state and external power are Coded as “1” if a non-core group is
contiguous states and have each supported by an external power that
others’ co-ethnics has co-ethnics of the host state
within its territory, “0” otherwise.
Status Status reversal Coded as “1” if the non-core group
enjoyed a higher status in the polity
than the core group in the recent
past, “0” otherwise.
Homeland Non-core group has a homeland Coded as “1” if the non-core group
had an external homeland, “0”
otherwise.
Reputation Host state cracks down harshly in Coded as “0” if there was less than
order to prevent future uprisings one secessionist non-core group in the
host state, “1” if there were more.
Pop1918 Percentage of the non-core group in Percentage of the non-core group in
the host state the country in 1918.
Groupsize1 Non-core group size larger Coded “1” if the non-core group
than 1% was larger than 1% of the total
population of the host state, “0”
otherwise.
Groupsize5 Non-core group size larger Coded “1” if the non-core group
than 5% was larger than 5% of the total
population of the host state, “0”
otherwise.

(continued )
206 Methodological Appendix

(continued )

Variable
Name Description Coding Rule

Core Percentage of the core group in thePercentage of the core group in the
host state host state circa 1918.
Non-core Percentage of non-core groups in Total percentage of non-core groups
the host state in the host state circa 1918.
Concentrated Most of the non-core group is Coded as “1” if the non-core group
territorially concentrated was territorially concentrated, “0”
otherwise.
Language Language Coded as “1” if the non-core group
had a different language from the
core group, “0” otherwise.
Worldrel World religion Coded as “1” if the non-core group
had a different world religion from
the core group, “0” otherwise.
Religion Different religion Coded as “1” if the non-core group
had a different religious denomina-
tion from the core group, “0”
otherwise.
Urban Non-core group primarily urban Coded as “1” if the non-core group
was primarily urban, “0” otherwise.
Rural Non-core group primarily rural Coded as “1” if the non-core group
was primarily rural, “0” otherwise.
Nomadic Non-core group primarily nomadic Coded as “1” if the non-core group
was primarily nomadic, “0”
otherwise.

Some of the variables included in the codebook are discussed in the cross tabs
but are excluded from the regression analysis because they are not statistically
significant and/or due to degrees of freedom constraints.

c. non-core groups in post–world war i balkans


circa 1919–1923

table a.1. Non-Core Groups with a Population Smaller Than 1% of the Total
Population of the Host State

Country Non-Core Group Prediction Policy

Albania Montenegrins/Serbs 2 1
Albania Turks 1 1
Bulgaria Armenians 0 0
Methodological Appendix 207

Country Non-Core Group Prediction Policy

Bulgaria Gagauz 1 1
Bulgaria Germans 0 0
Bulgaria Russians 0 0
Bulgaria Sarakatsans/Karakatsans 2 2
Bulgaria Tatars 0 0
Bulgaria Uniates 1 1
Greece Chams/Albanian Muslims 0 0
Greece Gypsies 1 1
Greece Meglen Vlachs 0 0
Greece Pomaks 1 0
Greece “Romanian leaning” Vlachs 0 0
Greece Romaniote Jews 1 1
Romania Armenians 0 0
Romania Czech and Slovak 0 0
Romania Gagauz 0 0
Romania Greeks 0 0
Romania Serbs 0 0
Romania Tatars 1 1
Romania Vlachs 1 1
KSCS Bulgarians (in the border areas) 1 1
KSCS Czechs 0 0
KSCS Greeks 0 2
KSCS Gypsies 0 0
KSCS Italians 1 1
KSCS Jews 1 0
KSCS Slavophone Muslims (South Serbia) 1 1
KSCS Slovaks 0 0
KSCS Vlachs 1 1
Turkey Albanians 1 1
Turkey Alevis (Tahtajis) 1 1
Turkey Arabs, Christian Orthodox 1 1
Turkey Assyro-Chaldean 2 2
Turkey Bosnian Muslims 1 1
208 Methodological Appendix

table a.2. Non-Core Groups with a Population Larger Than 1% and Less Than
5% of the Total Population of the Host State

Country Non-Core Group Prediction Policy

Albania Gypsies 1 1
Albania Slav Macedonians 0 0
Albania Vlachs 0 0
Bulgaria Greeks 2 2
Bulgaria Gypsies 1 0
Bulgaria Jews 1 0
Bulgaria Pomaks 1 1
Bulgaria Romanians 2 2
Bulgaria Slav Macedonians 1 1
Bulgaria Vlachs 2 2
Greece Albanians (Christian) 1 1
Greece Armenians 0 0
Greece Catholics 0 0
Greece Jews (Sephardim) 1 0
Greece Sarakatsans 1 1
Greece Slav Macedonians (Exarchate) 1 2
Greece Slav Macedonians (Patriarchate) 1 1
Greece Vlachs 1 1
Romania Bulgarians 1 1
Romania Germans 1 0
Romania Roma/Gypsies 0 0
Romania Russians 0 0
Romania Ruthenes/ Ukrainians 1 1
Romania Turks 1 1
KSCS Albanians 1 1
KSCS Germans 1 0
KSCS Hungarians/Magyars 1 0
KSCS Montenegrins 1 1
KSCS Romanians/Vlachs/Cincars 0 0
KSCS Turks 1 1
Turkey Arabs (Muslim) 1 1
Turkey Bulgarians 0 0
Turkey Circassians 1 1
Turkey Jews 1 0
Turkey Laz 1 1
Turkey Yuruks 1 1
Methodological Appendix 209

table a.3. Non-Core Groups with a Population Larger Than 5% of the Total
Population of the Host State

Country Non-Core Group Prediction Policy

Albania Greeks 2 0
Bulgaria Turks 2 2
Greece Turks 1 0
Romania Jews 1 0
Romania Hungarians/Magyars/Szeklers/Csangos 1 0
Romania Romanian Uniates 0 0
KSCS Slav Macedonians 1 1
KSCS Bosnian Muslims 1 1
KSCS Slovenes 1 0
KSCS Croats 1 1
Turkey Armenians 2 2
Turkey Kurds 1 1
Turkey Greeks 2 2

d. works used for coding


General Southeastern Europe
Adanır, Fikret, and Suraiya Faroqhi. 2002. The Ottomans and the Balkans: A Discussion
of Historiography. Leiden and Boston: Brill.
Banac, Ivo. 1995. “Nationalism in Southeastern Europe,” in Charles A. Kupchan (ed.),
Nationalism and Nationalities in the New Europe. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University
Press,107–121, 207–208.
Benbassa, Esther, and Aron Rodrigue. 1995. The Jews of the Balkans: The Judeo-Spanish
Community, 15th to 20th Centuries. Jewish Communities of the Modern World.
Oxford and Cambridge, Mass.: Blackwell.
Bianchini, Stefano, and Marco Doggo (eds.). 1998. The Balkans: National Identities in a
Historical Perspective. Ravenna: Longo Editore.
Biondich, Mark. 2011. The Balkans: Revolution, War, and Political Violence since 1878.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bowman, Isaiah. 1926 [1921]. The New World: Problems in Political Geography. New
York: World Book.
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. 1993. The Other Balkan Wars.
Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.
Carr, E. H. 1945 [1939]. The “Twenty Years” Crisis, 1919–1939. New York: Harper &
Row, Publishers.
Castellan, Georges. 1992. History of the Balkans: From Mohammed the Conqueror to
Stalin. Columbia: New York: Columbia University Press.
Dafnis, Grigorios. 1955. I Ellas Metaxy dyo Polemon, 1923–1940 [Greece between Two
Wars, 1923–1940]. 2 vols. Athens: Ikaros.
210 Methodological Appendix

Dérens, Jean-Arnault. 2003. “Winners and Losers among the Minority Groups in Former
Yugoslavia. Forgotten Peoples of the Balkans,” trans. Barry Smerin. Le Monde diplo-
matique. Available at http://mondediplo.com/2003/08/04Derens.
Destani, B. (ed.). 2003. Ethnic Minorities in the Balkan States: 1860–1971. Slough, U.K.:
Archive Editions.
Dogo, Marco, and Guido Franzinetti (eds.). 2002. Disrupting and Reshaping: Early
Stages of Nation-Building in the Balkans. Ravenna: Longo Editore.
Durham, M. E. 1905. The Burden of the Balkans. London: Nelson.
Elazar, Daniel J., Harriet Pass Friedenreich, Baruch Hazzan, and Adina Weiss Liberles.
1984. The Balkan Jewish Communities: Yugoslavia, Bulgaria, Greece and Turkey. The
Center for Jewish Community Studies/Jerusalem Center for Public Affairs. Lanham,
Md.: University Press of America.
Gewehr, Wesley M. 1931. The Rise of Nationalism in the Balkans, 1800–1930. New
York: Henry Holt.
Gianaris, Nikolas V. 1996. Geopolitical and Economic Changes in the Balkan Countries.
Westport, Conn.: Praeger.
Hupchick, Dennis P., and Harold E. Cox. 2001. The Palgrave Concise Historical Atlas of
the Balkans. New York and Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Ilchev, Ivan. 1995. Rodinata mi prava ili ne! Vunshnopoliticheskata propaganda na
balkanskite strain (1821–1923) [My Motherland, Right or Wrong! The Foreign
Political Propaganda of the Balkan States (1821–1923)]. Sofia: Universitetsko izd-vo
“Sv. Kliment Okhridski.”
Jankovic´, Branimir M. 1988. The Balkans in International Relations, trans. Margot
Milosavljević and Boško Milosavljević. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Janowsky, Oscar Isaiah. 1945. Nationalities and National Minorities (With Special
Reference to East-Central Europe). New York: Macmillan.
Jelavich, Barbara. 1964. A Century of Russian Foreign Policy, 1814–1914. Philadelphia
and New York: J. B. Lippincott.
Jelavich, Barbara. 1983. History of the Balkans: Eighteenth and Nineteenth Centuries.
Vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Jelavich, Barbara. 1988 [1983]. History of the Balkans: Twentieth Century. Vol. 2.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Jelavich, Barbara. 1991. Russia’s Balkan Entanglements, 1806–1914. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Jelavich, Charles, and Barbara Jelavich. 1977. The Establishment of the Balkan National
States, 1804–1920. Seattle and London: University of Washington Press.
Karpat, Kemal. 1973. An Inquiry into the Social Foundations of Nationalism in the
Ottoman State: From Social Estates to Classes, from Millets to Nations. Research
Monograph No. 39, Center of International Studies, Princeton University.
Karpat, Kemal H. 2002. Studies on Ottoman Social and Political History: Selected
Articles and Essays. Leiden, the Netherlands, and Boston, Mass.: Brill.
Ladas, Spethen P. 1932. The Exchange of Minorities: Bulgaria, Greece and Turkey. New
York: Macmillan.
Lampe, John R. 2006. Balkans into Southeastern Europe: A Century of War and
Transition. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Lampe, John R., and Marvin R. Jackson. 1982. Balkan Economic History, 1550–1950:
From Imperial Borderlands to Developing Nations. Bloomington: Indiana University
Press.
Methodological Appendix 211

Macartney, C. A., and A. W. Palmer. 1962. Independent Eastern Europe: A History. New
York: St. Martin’s Press.
Magocsi, Paul Robert. 2002. Historical Atlas of Central Europe. Seattle: University of
Washington Press.
McCarthy, Justin. 1995. Death and Exile: The Ethnic Cleansing of Ottoman Muslims
1821–1922. Princeton, N.J.: Darwin Press.
McGrowan, Bruce. 1981. Economic Life in Ottoman Empire: Taxation, Trade and the
Struggle for Land, 1600–1800. Cambridge and Paris: Cambridge University Press and
Editions de la Maison des Sciences de l’Homme.
Ortakovski, Vladimir. 2000. Minorities in the Balkans. Ardsley, N.Y.: Transnational
Publishers.
Palairet, Michael. 1997. The Balkan Economies c. 1800–1914: Evolution without
Development. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Pavlowitch, Stevan K. 1999. A History of the Balkans, 1804–1945. New York: Longman.
Pavlowitch, Stevan K. 2000. “Europe and the Balkans in a Historical Perspective, 1804–
1945,” Journal of Southern Europe and the Balkans, 2(2): 141–148.
Pearson, Raymond. 1983. National Minorities in Eastern Europe, 1848–1945. London
and Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Poulton, Hugh. 1993. The Balkans: Minorities and States in Conflict. London: Minority
Rights Publications.
Rossos, Andrew. 1981. Russia and the Balkans: Inter-Balkan Rivalries and Russian
Foreign Policy 1908–1914. Toronto; Buffalo, N.Y.; and London: University of
Toronto Press.
Rothschild, Joseph. 1974. East Central Europe between the Two World Wars. Seattle
and London: University of Washington Press.
Roudometof, Vicrtor. 2001. Nationalism, Globalization, and Orthodoxy: The Social
Origins of Ethnic Conflict in the Balkans. Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press.
Seton-Watson, Hugh. 1962 [1945]. Eastern Europe between the Wars, 1918–1941.
Hamden, Conn.: Archon Books.
Seton-Watson, Hugh. 1975. The “Sick Heart” of Modern Europe: The Problem of the
Danubian Lands. Seattle and London: University of Washington Press.
Seton-Watson, R. W. 1966 [1917]. The Rise of Nationality in the Balkans. New York:
Howard Fertig.
Shaw, Stanford J. 1974 [1963]. “The Ottoman View of the Balkans,” in Charles Jelavich
and Barbara Jelavich (eds.), The Balkans in Transition: Essays on the Development of
Balkan Life and Politics since the Eighteenth Century. Hamden, Conn.: Archon Books,
56–80.
Skran, Claudena M. 1995. Refugees in Inter-war Europe: The Emergence of a Regime.
Oxford, New York: Clarendon Press.
Stavrianos, L. S. 2000 [1958]. The Balkans since 1453. London: C. Hurst.
Stokes, Gale. 1984. Nationalism in the Balkans: An Annotated Bibliography. New York:
Garland.
Sugar, Peter F., and Ivo J. Lederer. Nationalism in Eastern Europe. Seattle and London:
University of Washington Press.
Tounta-Fergadi, Areti. 1994. Meionotites sta Valkania. Valkanikes Diaskepseis 1930–
1934 [Minorities in the Balkans. Balkan Summits 1930–1934]. Thessaloniki:
Paratiritis.
Tudjman, Franjo. 1981. Nationalism in Contemporary Europe. New York: Columbia
University Press.
212 Methodological Appendix

Várdy, Steven Béla, T. H. Tooley, and Agnes Huszar Várdy. 2003. Ethnic Cleansing in
Twentieth-Century Europe. New York: Columbia University Press.
Winnifrith, T. J. 1987. The Vlachs: The History of a Balkan People. London: Duckworth.

Albania
Austin, Robert. 1996. “Fan Noli, Albania and the Soviet Union,” East European
Quarterly, 30(2): 153–169.
Barnes, J. S. 1918. “The Future of the Albanian State,” The Geographical Journal,
52(1, July): 12–27.
Clayer, Nathalie. 2007. Aux origines du nationalisme Albanais: La naissance d’une
nation majoritairement musulmane en Europe. Paris: Karthala.
Clayer, Nathalie. 2008. “Behind the Veil. The Reform of Islam in Inter-War Albania or
the Search for A ‘Modern’ and ‘European’ Islam,” in Nathalie Clayer and Eric Germain
(eds.), Islam in Inter-war Europe. New York: Columbia University Press, 128–155.
Destani, Beytullah (ed.). 1999. Albania and Kosovo. Political and Ethnic Boundaries
1867–1946. Slough, U.K.: Archive Editions.
Elsie, Robert. 1997. Kosovo: In the Heart of the Powder Keg. Boulder, Colo.: East
European Monographs.
Fischer, Bernd Jürgen. 1984. King Zog and the Struggle for Stability in Albania. East
European Monographs, no. 159. New York: Columbia University Press.
Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920. Albania. No. 17. London:
H. M. Stationery Office.
Marmullaku, Ramadan. 1975. Albania and the Albanians, trans. Margot Milosavljević
and Boško Milosavljević. London: C. Hurst.
Pearson, Owen. 2004. Albania and King Zog: Independence, Republic and Monarchy
1908–1939. New York: I. B. Tauris Publishers.
Schwandner-Sievers, Stephanie, and Bernd Jurgen Fischer (eds.). 2002. Albanian
Identities: Myth and History. Bloomington and Indianapolis: Indiana University Press.
Skendi, Stavro. 1967. The Albanian National Awakening 1878–1912. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Tsitselikis, Konstantinos, and Dimitris Christopoulos (eds.). 2005. He Helliniki
Meionotita tis Alvanias [The Greek Minority in Albania]. Athens: KEMO Editions.
Vickers, Miranda. 1995. The Albanians. A Modern History. London and New York:
I. B. Tauris.
Zickel, Raymond, and Walter R. Iwaskiw (eds.). 1994. Albania: A Country Study.
Washington, D.C.: GPO for the Library of Congress.

Bulgaria
Bell, John D. 1977. Peasants in Power: Alexander Stamboliski and the Bulgarian
Agrarian National Union, 1899–1923. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Black, Cyril E. 1943. The Establishment of Constitutional Government in Bulgaria.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Crampton, R. J. 1993. A Short History of Modern Bulgaria. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Daskalov, Roumen. 2004. The Making of a Nation in the Balkans: Historiography of the
Bulgarian Revival. Budapest: CEU Press.
Methodological Appendix 213

Dimitrov, Vesselin. 2000. “In Search of a Homogeneous Nation: The Assimilation of


Bulgaria’s Turkish Minority, 1984–1985,” Journal on Ethnopolitics and Minority
Issues in Europe, 1(4): 1–21.
Dragostinova, Theodora. 2011. Between Two Motherlands: Nationality and Emigration
among the Greeks of Bulgaria, 1900–1949. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Eminov, Ali. 1989. “There Are No Turks in Bulgaria.” International Journal of Turkish
Studies, 4: 203–202.
Eminov, Ali. 1997. Turkish and Other Muslim Minorities in Bulgaria. Institute of Muslim
Minority Affairs, Book Series No. 6. London: C. Hurst.
Eminov, Ali. 2000. “Turks and Tatars in Bulgaria and the Balkans,” Nationalities Papers,
28(1): 129–164.
Georgeoff, John. 1981. “Ethnic Minorities in the People’s Republic of Bulgaria,” in
George Ed Klein and Milan Reban (eds.), The Politics of Ethnicity in Eastern
Europe. New York: Columbia University Press.
Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920. Bulgaria. No. 22. London:
H. M. Stationery Office.
Karagiannis, Evangelos. An Introduction to the Pomak Issue in Bulgaria. Free University
Berlin. Available at: http://www2.nbu.bg/iafr/inandout2.htm.
Kostanick, Huey Louis. 1957. Turkish Resettlement of Bulgarian Turks, 1950–1953.
Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Krasteva, Anna (ed.). 1998. Communities and Identities in Bulgaria. Ravenna: Longo
Editor.
McCarthy, Justin. 1995. Death and Exile: The Ethnic Cleansing of Ottoman Muslims
1821–1922. Princeton, N.J.: Darwin Press.
Meininger, Thomas A. 1970. Ignatiev and the Establishment of the Bulgarian Exarchate,
1864–1872. Madison: State Historical Society of Wisconsin.
Monroe, Will S. 1914. Bulgaria and Her People. Boston: Page.
Neuberger, Mary. 1997. “Shifting Balkan Borders: Muslim Minorities and the Mapping of
National Identity in Modern Bulgaria.” Ph.D. dissertation, University of Washington.
Neuberger, Mary. 2004. The Orient Within: Muslim Minorities and the Negotiation of
Nationhood in Modern Bulgaria. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Perry, Duncan M. 1993. Stefan Stambolov and the Emergence of Modern Bulgaria,
1870–1895. Durham, N.C., and London: Duke University Press.
Radkova, Roumyana. 1980. “The National Awareness of the Bulgarians during the 18th
and Early 19th Centuries.” Bulgarskata Nazia Prez Vuzrazhdaneto. Sofia: Bulgarian
Academy of the Sciences.
Tonev, Velko. 1980. “Nation-forming Processes in Northeastern Bulgaria and Dobroudja.”
Bulgarskata Nazia Prez Vezrazhdaneto. Sofia: Bulgarian Academy of the Sciences.

Greece
Aarbakke, Vemund. 2003. Ethnic Rivalry and Quest for Macedonia, 1870–1913.
Boulder, Colo.: East European Monographs.
Alexandris, Alexis. 1988. “To Istoriko Plaisio ton Ellinotourkikon Sheseon, 1923–1955”
[The Historical Framework of Greek-Turkish Relations, 1923–1954], in Oi
Ellinotourkikes Sheseis, 1923–1987 [Greek-Turkish Relation, 1923–1987]. Athens:
Gnosi, 31–172.
214 Methodological Appendix

Anthogalidou, Theopoula. 1987. O Rolos tis Ekpaideusis stin Anaparagogi kai Exelixi
mias Paradosiakis Koinonias [The Role of Education in the Reproduction and
Evolution of a Traditional Society]. Athens: Themelio.
Bowman, Steven. 2002. “Jews,” in Richard Clogg (ed.), Minorities in Greece: Aspects of a
Plural Society. London: C. Hurst, 64–80.
Carabott, Philip. 1997. “The Politics of Integration and Assimilation vis-à-vis the Slavo-
Macedonian Minority of Inter-war Greece: From Parliamentary Inertia to Metaxist
Repression,” in Peter Mackridge and Eleni Yannakakis (eds.), Ourselves and Others:
The Development of a Greek Macedonian Cultural Identity since 1912. Oxford and
New York: Berg, 59–78.
Carabott, Philip. 2005. “Aspects of the Hellenization of Greek Macedonia, ca. 1912–ca.
1959,” ΚΑΜΠΟΣ: Cambridge Papers in Modern Greek, No. 13: 21–61.
Christides, Christopher J. 1949. The Macedonian Camouflage, In the Light of Facts and
Figures. Athens: Hellenic Publishing.
Clogg, Richard. 1981. Balkan Society in the Age of Greek Independence. Totowa, N.J.:
Barnes & Noble Books.
Clogg, Richard (ed.). 2002. Minorities in Greece: Aspects of a Plural Society. London:
C. Hurst.
Constantinople (Ecumenical patriarchate). 1993 [1906]. Episema engrapha peri tes en
Makedonia odyneras katastaseos [Official Documents on the Painful Situation in
Macedonia]. Thessaloniki: Kyriakides.
Constantopoulou, Photini (ed.). 1999. The Foundation of the Modern Greek State. Major
Treaties and Conventions (1830–1947). Ministry of Foreign Affairs of Greece, Service
of Historical Archives. Athens: Kastaniotis.
Dakin, Douglass. 1966. The Greek Struggle in Macedonia 1897–1913. Thessaloniki:
Institute for Balkan Studies.
Dakin, Douglass. 1972. The Unification of Greece, 1770–1923. New York: St. Martin’s
Press.
Danforth, Loring. 1995. The Macedonian Conflict: Ethnic Nationalism in a Transnational
World. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Divani, Lena. 1995. Hellada kai Meionotetes: to systema Diethnous Prostasias ton
Ethnon [Greece and Minorities: The League of Nation’s International Protection
System]. Athens: Nefeli.
Divani, Lena. 2000. He Edafike Oloklerose tes Elladas [The Territorial Integration of
Greece]. Athens: Kastaniotis.
Eliakis, Ioannis. 1928. O Venizelos [Venizelos], 2nd ed. Athens: George Kallergis.
Eliakis, Ioannis. 1932. O Venizelos os Dimosiografos [Venizelos as a Journalist]. Athens:
Dimitrakou.
Finlay, George. 1861. History of the Greek Revolution. Vols. 1 and 2. Edinburgh and
London: W. Blackwood and Sons.
Glavinas, Ioannis. 2010. O Mousoulmanos ypikoos stis antilipseis ton foreon tis ellinikis
dioikisis tin periodo 1912–1922 [The Muslim Citizen in the Views of the Hellenic
Administration during the Period 1912–1923]. Paper presented at the 4th Conference
of the European Society of Modern Greek Studies, University of Granada, Spain
(10–12 September 2010).
Gounaris, Basil G. 1996. “Social Cleavages and National ‘Awakening’ in Ottoman
Macedonia,” East European Quarterly, 29(4): 409–425.
Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920a. Greece. No. 18. London:
H. M. Stationery Office.
Methodological Appendix 215

Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920b. Macedonia. No. 21. London:
H. M. Stationery Office.
Heraclides, Alexis. 2001. He Ellada ke o Ex Anatolon Kindinos [Greece and the Eastern
Threat]. Athens: Polis.
Human Rights Watch/Helsinki Report. 1994. Denying Ethnic Identity: The Macedonians
of Greece.
Jong, F. de. 1980. Names, Religious Denomination and Ethnicity of Settlements in
Western Thrace: A Supplement to the “Ortsnamenkonkordanz de Balkanhalbinsel.”
Leiden: E. J. Brill.
Karakasidou, Anastasia. 1997. Fields of Wheat, Hills of Blood: Passages to Nationhood
in Greek Macedonia, 1870–1990. Chicago, Ill., and London: University of Chicago
Press.
Kontogiorgi, Elisabeth. 2006. Population Exchange in Greek Macedonia: The Rural
Settlement of Refugees 1922–1930. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Livanios, Dimitris. 1999. “‘Conquering the Souls’: Nationalism and Greek Guerrilla
Warfare in Ottoman Macedonia, 1904–1908,” Byzantine and Modern Greek Studies,
23: 195–221.
Mackridge, Peter, and Eleni Yannakakis (eds.). 1997. Ourselves and Others: The
Development of a Greek Macedonian Cultural Identity since 1912. Oxford and New
York: Berg.
Margaritis, George. 2005. Anepithimiti Sympatriotes [Unwanted Compatriots]. Athens:
Vivliorama.
Mavrogordatos, George Th. 1983. Stillborn Republic: Social Coalitions and Party
Strategies in Greece, 1922–1936. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Mazower, Mark. 2004. Salonica, City of Ghosts. London: HarperCollins.
Michailidis, Iakovos. 1996. “Minority Rights and Educational Problems in Greek
Interwar Macedonia: The Case of the Primer ‘Abecedar,’” Journal of Modern Greek
Studies 14(2): 329–343.
Michailidis, Iakovos. 1998. “The War on Statistics: Traditional Recipes for the
Preparation of the Macedonian Salad,” East European Quarterly 32(1): 9–21.
Nakratzas, George. 1999. The Close Racial Kinship between the Greeks, Bulgarians and
Turks: Macedonia–Thrace. Thessaloniki: Batavia Publications.
Pallis, Alexander A. 1925. “Racial Migrations in the Balkans during the Years 1912–
1924,” Geographical Journal, 66(4): 315–331.
Sotiriou, Stephanos. 2000. To Alvaniko Ethniko Zetema [The Albanian National Issue].
Athens: Pelasgos.
Stefanou, Stefanos (ed.). 1965. Eleutheriou Venizelou Politikai Ypothikai [The Political
Legacy of Eleftherios Venizelos]. Vol. A. Athens: Rodi.
Stefanou, Stefanos (ed.). 1969. Eleutheriou Venizelou Politikai Ypothikai [The Political
Legacy of Eleftherios Venizelos]. Vol. B. Athens: Rodi.
Tounta-Fergadi, Areti. 1986a. Ellino-Voulgarikes Meionotetes: Protokollo Polite-Kalfof
1924–1925 [Greek-Bulgarian Minorities: The Politis-Kalfof Protocol 1924–1925].
Thessaloniki: Institute for Balkan Studies.
Tounta-Fergadi, Areti. 1986b. Themata Ellinikis Diplomatikis Istorias [Themes in Greek
Diplomatic History]. Athens: Paratiritis.
Veremis, Th., and G. Goulimi (eds.). 1989. Eleftherios Venizelos: Koinotita, Economia,
Politiki stin Epochi tou [Eleftherios Venizelos: Commuity, Economy and Politics in His
Era]. Athens: Gnosi.
216 Methodological Appendix

Vouri, Sophia. 1992. Ekpaideuse kai Ethnikismos sta Valkania. He Periptose tis
Voreiodytikes Makedonias 1870–1904 [Education and Nationalism in the Balkans.
The Case of North-Western Macedonia 1870–1904]. Athens: Paraskinio.

Romania
Fischer-Galati, Stephen. 1969. “Romanian Nationalism,” in Peter Sugar and Ivo Lederer
(eds.), Nationalism in Eastern Europe. Seattle and London: University of Washington
Press, pp. 373–395.
Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920. Rumania. No. 23. London:
H. M. Stationery Office.
Illyes, Elemer. 1982. National Minorities in Romania: Change in Transylvania. Boulder,
Colo.: East European Monographs.
Iordachi, Constantin. 2002. Citizenship, Nation- and State-Building: The Integration of
Northern Dobrogea into Romania, 1878–1913. The Carl Beck Papers in Russian and
East European Studies, No. 1607.
Livezeanu, Irina. 2000 [1995]. Cultural Politics in Greater Romania: Regionalism,
Nation-Building, and Ethnic Struggle, 1918–1930. Ithaca, N.Y., and London:
Cornell University Press.
Rothschild, Joseph. 1974. “Romania,” in East Central Europe between the Two World
Wars. Seattle and London: University of Washington Press.

Ottoman Empire/Turkey
Akcam, Taner. 2006. A Shameful Act: The Armenian Genocide and the Question of
Turkish Responsibility, trans. Paul Bessemer. New York: Henry Holt.
Alexandris, Alexis. 1983. The Greek Minority of Istanbul and Greek-Turkish Relations,
1918–1974. Athens: Center for Asia Minor Studies.
Cagaptay, Soner. 2003. “Crafting the Turkish Nation: Kemalism and Turkish
Nationalism in the 1930s.” Ph.D. dissertation, Yale University.
Cagaptay, Soner. 2006. Islam, Secularism, and Nationalism in Modern Turkey: Who Is a
Turk? London and New York: Routledge.
Dominian, Lèon. 1917. The Frontiers of Language and Nationality in Europe. New
York: Henry Holt.
Gingeras, Ryan. 2009. Sorrowful Shores: Violence, Ethnicity, and the End of the
Ottoman Empire, 1912–1923. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920a. Turkey in Asia. No. 58. London:
H.M. Stationery Office.
Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920b. Turkey in Europe. No. 16.
London: H.M. Stationery Office.
Kasaba, Reşat (ed.) 2008. Cambridge History of Turkey, vol. 4: Turkey in the Modern
World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Levene, Mark. 1998. “Creating a Modern ‘Zone of Genocide’: The Impact of Nation-
and State-Formation on Eastern Anatolia, 1878–1923,” Holocaust and Genocide
Studies, 12(3): 393–413.
Lewis, Bernard. 1961. The Emergence of Modern Turkey. London: Oxford University
Press.
McCarthy, Justin. 1983. Muslim and Minorities: The Population of Ottoman Anatolia
and the End of the Empire. New York and London: New York University Press.
Methodological Appendix 217

McCarthy, Justin. 1995. Death and Exile: The Ethnic Cleansing of Ottoman Muslims,
1821–1922. Princeton, N.J.: Darwin Press.
McCarthy, Justin. 2001. The Ottoman Peoples and the End of Empire. New York:
Arnold and Oxford University Press.
Poulton, Hugh. 1997. Top Hat, Grey Wolf and Crescent: Turkish Nationalism and the
Turkish Republic. London: C. Hurst.
Romano, David. 2006. The Kurdish Nationalist Movement: Opportunity, Mobilization
and Identity. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Sonyel, Salahi R. 2001. The Assyrians of Turkey: Victims of Major Power Policy.
Ankara: Turkish Historical Society Printing House.

The Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and Slovenes/The Kingdom of Yugoslavia


Banac, Ivo. 1984. The National Question in Yugoslavia: Origins, History, Politics.
Ithaca, N.Y., and London: Cornell University Press.
Banac, Ivo. 1993. “Insignia of Identity: Heraldry and the Growth of National Ideologies
among the South Slavs,” Ethnic Studies, 10: 215–237.
Banac, Ivo. 1995. “Zarathustra in Red Croatia: Millan Šufflay and His Theory of
Nationhood,” in Ivo Banac and Katherine Verdery (eds.), National Character and
National Ideology in Interwar Eastern Europe. (Russian and East European
Publications, No. 13). New Haven, Conn.: Yale Center for International and Area
Studies.
Biondich, Mark. 2007. “Vladko Maček and the Croat Political Right, 1928–1941,”
Contemporary European History, 16(2): 203–213.
Curtis, Glenn E. (ed.). 1992. Yugoslavia: A Country Study. Federal Research Division,
Library of Congress.
Destani, Beytullah (ed.). 1999. Albania and Kosovo: Political and Ethnic Boundaries
1867–1946. Archive Editions.
Destani, B. (ed.). 2003. Ethnic Minorities in the Balkan States: 1860–1971. Slough, U.K.:
Archive Editions Limited.
Djilas, Aleksa. 1991. The Contested Country: Yugoslav Unity and Communist
Revolution, 1919–1953. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Djokić, Dejan (ed.). 2003. Yugoslavis Histories of a Failed Idea, 1918–1992. London:
C. Hurst.
Djokić, Dejan. 2007. Elusive Compromise: A History of Interwar Yugoslavia. London:
C. Hurst.
Dragnich, Alex N. 1983. The First Yugoslavia: Search for a Viable Political System.
Stanford, Calif.: Hoover Institution Press.
Edwards, Lovett F. (ed.). 1969. The Memoirs of Prota Matija Nenadović. London:
Oxford University Press.
Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920a. Macedonia. No. 21. London:
H. M. Stationery Office.
Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920b. Montenegro. No. 19. London:
H. M. Stationery Office.
Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920c. Serbia. No. 20. London:
H. M. Stationery Office.
Grimm, Gerhard. 1984. “Ethnographic Maps of the Kosova Region from 1730–1913,”
in Arshi Pipa and Sami Repishti (eds.), Studies on Kosova. Boulder, Colo.: East
European Monographs.
218 Methodological Appendix

Irvine, Jill A. 1993. The Croat Question: Partisan Politics in the Formation of the
Yugoslav Socialist State. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
Lampe, John R. 2000. Yugoslavia as History: Twice There Was a Country. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Malcolm, Noel. 1998. Kosovo: A Short History. New York: HarperPerennial.
Miller, Nicholas John. 1991. “Between Great Serbianism and Yugoslavis Serbian Politics
in Croatia, 1903–1914.” Ph.D. dissertation, Indiana University.
Mittleman, Earl Niel. 1954. “The Nationality Problem in Yugoslavia: A Survey of
Developments, 1921–1953.” Ph.D. dissertation, University of Michigan.
Pasic, Najdan. 1973. “Varieties of Nation-Building in the Balkans among the Southern
Slavs,” In S. N. Eisenstadt and Stein Rokkan (eds.), Building States and Nations:
Analyses by Region. Vol. 2. Beverly Hills, Calif., and London: Sage Publications,
117–141.
Petranović, Branco. 2002. The Yugoslav Experience of Serbian National Integration.
New York: Columbia University Press.
Ramet, Sabrina P. 2006. The Three Yugoslavias: State-Building and Legitimation, 1918–
2005. Bloomington and Indianapolis: Indiana University Press.
Sardamov, Ivelin. 1998. “Mandate of History: War, Ethnic Conflict and Nationalism in
the South Slav Balkans.” Ph.D. dissertation, University of Notre Dame.
Singleton, Fred. 1985. A Short History of the Yugoslav Peoples. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Stathi, Sasa K. 1983. Yugoslavia kai Tito 1919–1953 [Yugoslavia and Tito 1919–1953].
Athens: Hestia.
Vasiliadis, Nikolaos. 2004. I Elliniki parousia sti Notia Servia apo tous Valkanikous
polemous eos to Mesopolemo [The Hellenic Presence in South Serbia from the Balkan
Wars to the Interwar Period]. Thessaloniki: Anatropi.
Vickers, Miranda. 1998. Between Serb and Albanian: A History of Kosovo. London:
C. Hurst.
References

Archives

AEV Archive of Eleftherios Venizelos. Benaki Musuem, Athens


A.P.K. Archeion Pavlou Kalliga [Pavlos Kalligas Papers],
The Museum of the Macedonian Struggle, Thessaloniki
AYE Archive of the Hellenic Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Athens
BNA British National Archives
DDI Documenti Diplomatici Italiani
GAK/Florinas General State Archives of Florina
GAK/Kozanis General State Archives of Kozani
GAK/Makedonias General State Archives of Macedonia, Thessaloniki
G.L. Gennadius Library
ELIA The Hellenic Literary and Historical Archive

Newspapers
Efimeris ton Valkanion
Eleftheron Vima
Iho tis Makedonias
New York Times

Works Cited
Aalto, Pami. 2003. “Revisiting the Security/Identity Puzzle in Russo-Estonian Relations,”
Journal of Peace Research, 40(5): 573–591.
Aarbakke, Vemund. 2000. “The Muslim Minority of Greek Thrace.” Ph.D. dissertation,
University of Bergen.
Aarbakke, Vemund. 2003. Ethnic Rivalry and Quest for Macedonia, 1870–1913.
Boulder, Colo.: East European Monographs.
Aarbakke, Vemund. 2012. “Urban Space and Bulgarian-Greek Antagonism in Thrace,
1870–1912,” presented at the The Balkans: From Academic Field to International
Politics Workshop, a joint workshop by Ecole Française d’Athènes and British
School of Athens, (Athens, 17–19 April). Available at: http://www.bsa.ac.uk/doc_
store/IT/IT2012_50.pdf.

219
220 References

Ai Agoreuseis tou Ellinikou Koinovouliou, 1909–1956 [The Greek Parliament Speeches].


1957. Vol. 3. Athens: Ethnikos Kirix.
Akcam, Taner. 2006. A Shameful Act: The Armenian Genocide and the Question of
Turkish Responsibility, trans. Paul Bessemer. New York: Henry Holt.
Akhund, Nadine. 2009. “Muslim Representation in the Three Ottoman Vilayets of
Macedonia: Administration and Military Power (1878–1908),” Journal of Muslim
Minority Affairs, 29 (December): 443–54.
Akturk, Sener. 2007. “Continuity and Change in the Regimes of Ethnicity in Austria,
Germany, USSR/Russia, and Turkey: Varieties of Ethnic Regimes and Hypotheses for
Change,” Nationalities Papers, 35(1, March): 23–49.
Akturk, Sener. 2011. “Regimes of Ethnicity: Comparative Analysis of Germany, the Soviet
Union/Post-Soviet Russia, and Turkey,” World Politics, 61(1, January): 115–164.
Alba, Richard, and Victor Nee. 1997. “Rethinking Assimilation Theory for a New Era of
Migration,” International Migration Review, 31(4): 826–874.
Alba, Richard, and Victor Nee. 2003. Remaking the American Mainstream: Assimilation
and Contemporary Immigration. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Alesina, Alberto, and Enrico Spolaore. 2003. The Size of Nations. Cambridge, Mass.:
MIT University Press.
Alesina, Alberto, Arnaud Devleeschauwer, William Easterly, Sergio Kurlat, and
Romain Wacziarg. 2003. “Fractionalization.” Journal of Economic Growth, 8 June:
155–194.
Alter, Peter. 1994. Nationalism. London: Edward Arnold.
Alvanos, Raymondos. 2005. “Koinonikes sygkrouseis kai politikes symperifores stin
periohi tis Kastorias, 1922–1949” [Social Conflicts and Political Behaviors in the
Area of Kastoria, 1922–1949]. Ph.D. dissertation, Aristotle University of Thessaloniki.
Ambrosio, Thomas. 2001. Irredentis Ethnic Conflict and International Politics. Wesport,
Conn., and London: Praeger.
Anagnostou, Dia. 2005. “Nationalist Legacies and European Trajectories in the Balkans:
Post-Communist Liberalization and Turkish Minority Politics in Bulgaria,” Southeast
Europe and Black Sea Studies, 5(1): 87–109.
Anagnostou, Dia. 2007. “Development, Discrimination and Reverse Discrimination: The
Effects of EU Integration and Regional Change on the Muslims of Southeast Europe,”
in Aziz Al-Ahmet and Effie Fokas (eds.), Islam in Europe: Diversity, Identity, and
Influence. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Anderson, Benedict. 1983. Imagined Communities: Reflections on the Origins and
Spread of Nationalism. New York: Verso.
Anderson, Charles W., Fred R. von der Mehden, and Crawford Young. 1967. Issues of
Political Development. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
Andrić, Ivo. 1997. “Draft on Albania (1939),” in Robert Elsie (ed.), Kosovo: In the Heart
of the Powder Keg. Boulder, Colo.: East European Monographs, 435–448.
Armitage, Andrew. 1995. Comparing the Policy of Aboriginal Assimilation: Australia,
Canada, and New Zealand. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.
Armstrong, Hamilton Fish. 1928. “Italy, Jugoslavia and Lilliputia,” Foreign Affairs, 6(2):
191–202.
Armstrong, John A. 1982. Nations before Nationalism. Chapel Hill: University of North
Carolina Press.
Aron, Raymond. 1966. “Social Class, Political Class, Ruling Class,” in Reinhard Bendix
and Seymour M. Lipset (eds.), Class, Status and Power. New York: Free Press, 201–210.
References 221

Arter, David. 1996. Parties and Democracy in the Post-Soviet Republics: The Case of
Estonia. Aldershot, UK: Darmouth Publishing.
Atlas Narodov Mira. 1964. Moscow: Miklukho-Maklai Ethnological Institute at the
Department of Geodesy and Cartography of the State Geological Committee of the
Soviet Union.
Austin, Robert. 1996. “Fan Noli, Albania and the Soviet Union,” East European
Quarterly, 30(2): 153–169.
Austin, Robert. 2004. “Greater Albania: The Albanian State and the Question of Kosovo,
1912–2001,” in John R. Lampe and Mark Mazower, Ideologies and National
Identities: The Case of Twentieth-Century Southeastern Europe. Budapest: Central
European University Press, 235–253.
Azcárate, P. de. 1945. League of Nations and National Minorities: An Experiment, trans.
Eileen E. Brooke. Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.
Babuna, Aydin. 2000. “The Albanians of Kosovo and Macedonia: Ethnic Identity
Superseding Religion,” Nationalities Papers, 28(1): 67–92.
“Bahrain Hints at Iranian Role over Country’s Shia Uprising,” 2011. Guardian, 21
March. Available at: http://www.guardian.co.uk/world/2011/mar/21/bahrain-iran-
role-uprising-shia.
Banac, Ivo. 1984. The National Question in Yugoslavia: Origins, History, Politics.
Ithaca, N.Y., and London: Cornell University Press.
Banac, Ivo. 1995. “Nationalism in Southeastern Europe,” in Charles A. Kupchan (ed.),
Nationalism and Nationalities in the New Europe. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University
Press, 107–121, 207–208.
Banac, Ivo. 2006. “The Politics of National Homogeneity,” in Brad K. Blitz (ed.), War
and Change in the Balkans. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 30–43.
Barker, Elisabeth. 1950. Macedonia: Its Place in Balkan Power Politics. London and New
York: Royal Institute of International Affairs/Oxford University Press.
Barnet, Richard J. 1968. Intervention and Revolution: America’s Confrontation with
Insurgent Movements around the World. New York: New American Library/World
Publishing.
Barnett, Michael N. 2011. Empire of Humanity: A History of Humanitarianism. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Barrington, Lowell. 1995. “The Domestic and International Consequences of Citizenship
in the Soviet Successor States,” Europe-Asia Studies, 47(5): 731–763.
Barros, James. 1970. The League of Nations and the Great Powers: The Greek-Bulgarian
Incident, 1925. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Barth, Frederik. 1998 [1969]. Ethnic Groups and Boundaries. Prospect Heights, Ill.:
Waveland Press.
Bartov, Omer. 1996. Murder in Our Midst: The Holocaust, Industrial Killing, and
Representation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bataković, Dušan. 1991. Kosovo i Metohija u srpsko-arbanaškim odnosima [Kosovo and
Metohija in Serb-Albanian Relations]. Priština: Jedinstvo.
Bataković, Dušan. “Kosovo and Metohija: A Historical Survey.” Available at: http://
www.kosovo.net/histkim.html.
Beljo, Ante (ed.). 1992. Greater Serbia: From Ideology to Aggression. Zagreb: Croatian
Information Centre.
Bellamy, Alex J. 2009. Responsibility to Protect: The Global Effort to End Mass
Atrocities. Cambridge: Polity Press.
222 References

Bendix, Reinhard. 1969. Nation-Building and Citizenship: Studies of Our Changing


Social Order. Garden City, N.Y.: Anchor Books.
Benhabib, Seyla. 2004. The Rights of Others. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Berg, Eiki. 1999. Estonia’s Northeastern Periphery in Politics: Socio-Economic and
Ethnic Dimensions. Tartu: Dissertationes Geographicae Universitatis Tartuensis.
Berg, Eiki. 2001. “Ethnic Mobilization in Flux: Revisiting Peripheriality and Minority
Discontent in Estonia,” Space & Polity, 5(1): 5–26.
Berg, Eiki, and Wim Van Meurs. 2002. “Borders and Orders in Europe: Limits of Nation-
and State-Building in Estonia, Macedonia and Moldova,” Journal of Communist
Studies and Transition Politics, 18(4): 51–74.
Bieber, Florian. 2000. “Muslim Identity in the Balkans before the Establishment of
Nation States,” Nationalities Papers, 28(1): 13–28.
Biondich, Mark. 2007. “Vladko Maček and the Croat Political Right, 1928–1941,”
Contemporary European History, 16(2): 203–213.
Birch, Anthony. 1978. “Minority Nationalist Movements and Theories of Political
Integration,” World Politics, 30(3): 325–344.
Birnir, Jóhanna, Jonathan Wilkenfeld, James Fearon, David Laitin, Ted Robert Gurr,
Dawn Brancati, Stephen Saideman, and Amy Pate. 2011. “A-MAR (All-Minorities at
Risk): Addressing the Selection Bias Issue.” Unpublished manuscript.
Bisaku, Gjon, Shtjefën Kurti, and Luigj Gashi. 1997. “The Situation of the Albanian
Minority in Yugoslavia. Memorandum presented to the League of Nations (1930),” in
Robert Elsie (ed.), Kosovo: In the Heart of the Powder Keg. Boulder, Colo.: East
European Monographs, 361–399.
Biskupski, Mieczyslaw B. 2000. The History of Poland. Westport, Conn.: Greenwood
Press.
Black, Jeremy. 2002. Maps and Politics. Chicago, Ill.: University of Chicago Press.
Bob, Clifford. 2005. The Marketing of Rebellion: Insurgents, Media, and International
Activism. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bodlore-Penlaez, Mikael. 2010. Atlas des nations sans état en Europe: peuples minori-
taires en quête de reconnaissance. Fouenant: Yoran Embanner.
Bogdanović, Dimitrije. 1986. Knjiga o Kosovu (Book on Kosovo). Belgrade. Available at:
http://www.kosovo.net/sk/rastkokosovo/istorija/knjiga_o_kosovu/index.html.
Brailsford, Henry Noel. 1906. Macedonia: Its Races and Their Future. London:
Metheun.
Brass, Paul. 1991. Ethnicity and Nationalis Theory and Comparison. New Delhi and
Newbury Park, Calif.: Sage.
Brass, Paul. 1997. Theft of an Idol. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Braude, Benjamin, and Bernard Lewis. 2000. Christians and Jews in the Ottoman
Empire: The Functioning of a Plural Society. New York: Holmes & Meir.
Braudel, Fernand. 1980. On History, Chicago, Ill.: University of Chicago Press.
Brown, DeNeen L. 2008. “Canadian Government Apologizes for Abuse of Indigenous
People,” Washington Post, 12 June: A01.
Brown, Michael E. (ed.). 1996. The International Dimensions of Internal Conflict.
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Brown, Michael E. (ed.). 1997. Nationalism and Ethnic Conflict. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT
Press.
Browning, Christopher R., and Jürgen Matthäus 2004. The Origins of the Final Solution:
The Evolution of Nazi Jewish Policy, September 1939–March 1942. London: William
Heinemann.
References 223

Brubaker, Rogers. 1992. Citizenship and Nationhood in France and Germany. Cambridge,
Mass., and London: Harvard University Press.
Brubaker, Rogers. 1993. “National Minorities, Nationalizing States, and External
Homelands in the New Europe. Notes toward a Relational Analysis,” Reihe
Politikwissenschaft No. 11. Institut für Höhere Studien.
Brubaker, Rogers. 1996. Nationalism Reframed: Nationhood and the National Question
in the New Europe. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Brubaker, Rogers. 1998. “Migrations of Ethnic Unmixing in the ‘New Europe,’”
International Migration Review 32(4, Winter): 1047–1065.
Buchanan, Allen, and Margaret Moore (eds.). 2003. States, Nations, and Borders: The
Ethics of Making Boundaries. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bulutgil, Zeynep. 2009. “Territorial Conflict and Ethnic Cleansing.” Ph.D. dissertation,
University of Chicago.
Burgwyn, H. James. 1997. Italian Foreign Policy in the Interwar Period, 1918–1940.
Westport, Conn.: Praeger.
Byman, Daniel. 2007. Understanding Proto-Insurgencies. National Security Research
Division, RAND Corporation.
Byman, Daniel, and Stephen Van Evera. 1998. “Why They Fight: Hypotheses on the
Causes of Contemporary Deadly Conflict,” Security Studies, 7(3): 1–50.
Byman, Daniel, Peter Chalk, Bruce Hoffman, William Rosenau, and David Brannan.
2001. Trends in Outside Support for Insurgent Movements. National Security
Research Division, RAND Corporation.
Caldwell, Christopher. 2009. Reflections on the Revolution in Europe: Immigration,
Islam, and the West. New York: Doubleday.
Camilleri, Joseph. 1990. “Rethinking Sovereignty in a Shrinking, Fragmented World,” in
Robert B. J. Walker and Saul H. Mendlovitz (eds.), Contending Sovereignties. Boulder,
Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 13–44.
Carabott, Philip. 1997. “The Politics of Integration and Assimilation vis-à-vis the Slavo-
Macedonian Minority of Inter-war Greece: From Parliamentary Inertia to Metaxist
Repression,” in Peter and Eleni Yannakakis (eds.), Ourselves and Others: The
Development of a Greek Macedonian Cultural Identity since 1912. Mackridge,
Oxford, and New York: Berg, 59–78.
Carment, David, Patrick James, and Zeynep Taydas. 2006. Who Intervenes? Ethnic
Conflict and Interstate Crisis. Columbus: Ohio State University Press.
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. 1914. Report of the International
Commission to Inquire into the Causes and Conduct of the Balkan Wars.
Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.
Cederman, Lars-Erik, Andreas Wimmer, and B. Min. 2010. “Why Do Ethnic Groups
Rebel? New Data and Analysis,” World Politics 62(1): 87–119.
Chandra, Kanchan (ed.). 2001. “Symposium: Cumulative Findings in the Study of Ethnic
Politics,” APSA-CP 12.
Chomsky, Noam. 1985. Turning the Tide: U.S. Intervention in Central America and the
Struggle for Peace. Boston: South End Press.
Chomsky, Noam. 1993/1994. “Humanitarian Intervention,” Boston Review, 18: 3–6.
Clark, Bruce. 2006. Twice a Stranger: The Mass Expulsions That Forged Modern Greece
and Turkey. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Clayer, Nathalie. 2008. “Behind the Veil: The Reform of Islam in Inter-War Albania or
the Search for A ‘Modern’ and ‘European’ Islam,” in Nathalie Clayer and Eric Germain
(eds.), Islam in Inter-war Europe. New York: Columbia University Press, 128–155.
224 References

Clogg, Richard (ed.). 2002. Minorities in Greece: Aspects of a Plural Society. London:
C. Hurst.
Comstock, John Lee. 1828. Greek Revolution: Compiled from Official Documents of the
Greek Government. New York: William W. Reed.
Connor, Walker. 1972. “Nation-Building or Nation-Destroying?” World Politics, 24(3):
319–355.
Connor, Walker. 1973. “The Politics of Ethnonationalism,” Journal of International
Affairs 27(1): 1–21.
Coufoudakis, Van. 1976. “United Nations Peacekeeping and Peacemaking and the
Cyprus Question,” Western Political Quarterly, 29(3): 457–473.
Čubrilović, Vaso. 1997. “The Expulsion of the Albanians: Memorandum presented in
Belgrade on 7 March 1937,” in Robert Elsie (ed.), Kosovo: In the Heart of the Powder
Keg. Boulder, Colo.: East European Monographs, 400–424.
Curtis, Glenn E. (ed.). 1992. Yugoslavia: A Country Study. Federal Research Division,
Library of Congress.
Dakin, Douglass. 1966. The Greek Struggle in Macedonia 1897–1913. Thessaloniki:
Institute for Balkan Studies.
Dalai Lama. 1987. Five Point Peace Plan. Address to the U.S. Congressional Human
Rights Caucus. Available at: http://www.dalailama.com/messages/tibet/five-point-
peace-plan.
Danforth, Loring. 1995. The Macedonian Conflict: Ethnic Nationalism in a Transnational
World. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Darden, Keith. forthcoming. Resisting Occupation: Mass Literacy and the Creation of
Durable National Loyalties. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Darden, Keith, and Harris Mylonas. 2012. “The Promethean Dilemma: Third-Party
State-Building in Occupied Territories,” Ethnopolitics, 1 (March): 85–93.
David, Steven R. 1991. Choosing Sides: Alignment and Realignment in the Third World.
Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Davidson, Jason W. 2002. “The Roots of Revisionism: Fascist Italy, 1922–39,” Security
Studies, 11(4): 125–159.
Davis, David R., and Will H. Moore, 1997. “Ethnicity Matters: Transnational Ethnic
Alliances and Foreign Policy Behavior,” International Studies Quarterly, 41(1): 171–184.
Dérens, Jean-Arnault. 2008. Le piège du Kosovo. Paris: Non Lieu.
Deutsch, Karl. 1965. Nationalism and Social Communication. Cambridge, Mass.:
Technology Press.
Deutsch, Karl W., and William J. Foltz (eds.). 1963. Nation-Building. New York: Atherton
Press.
Dillon, Michael. 2004. Xinjiang: China’s Muslim Far Northwest. London and New
York: RoutledgeCurzon.
Divani, Lena. 1995. Hellada kai Meionotetes: to systema Diethnous Prostasias ton
Ethnon [Greece and Minorities: The League of Nation’s International Protection
System]. Athens: Nefeli.
Djilas, Aleksa. 1991. The Contested Country: Yugoslav Unity and Communist
Revolution, 1919–1953. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Djokić, Dejan. 2003. “(Dis)Integrating Yugoslavia: King Alexander and Interwar
Yugoslavism,” in Dejan Djokić (ed.), Yugoslavism: Histories of a Failed Idea, 1918–
1992. London: C. Hurst, 136–156.
Djokić, Dejan. 2010. Nikola Pašić and Ante Trubić: The Kingdom of Serbs, Croats and
Slovenes. London: Haus Publishing.
References 225

Dobbins, James, John G. McGinn, Keith Crane, Seth G. Jones, Rollie Lal,
Andrew Rathmell, Rachel M. Swanger, and Anga R. Timilsina. 2003. America’s
Role in Nation-Building: From Germany to Iraq. Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND
Corporation.
Dobbins, James, Seth G. Jones, Keith Crane, Andrew Rathmell, Brett Steele,
Richard Teltschik, and Anga Timilsina. 2005. The UN’s Role in Nation-Building:
From the Congo to Iraq. Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation.
Dobbins, James, Seth G. Jones, Keith Crane, and Beth Cole DeGrasse. 2007. The
Beginner’s Guide to Nation-Building. Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation.
Donohoe, J. Patrick. 2004. “Preparing Leaders for Nationbuilding,” Military Review, 84
(May/June): 24–26.
Doremus, Paul, William W. Keller, and Louis W. Pauly. 1998. The Myth of the Global
Corporation. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Doyle, Rodger. 1998. “By the Numbers: Ethnic Groups in the World,” Scientific
American Magazine, September.
Downes, Alexander B. 2006. “Desperate Times, Desperate Measures: The Causes of
Civilian Victimization in War,” International Security, 30(4): 152–195.
Downes, Alexander B. 2008. Targeting Civilians in War. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University
Press.
Dragnich, Alex N. 1974. Serbia, Nikola Pašić, and Yugoslavia. New Brunswick, N.J.:
Rutgers University Press.
Dragnich, Alex N. 1983. The First Yugoslavia. Search for a Viable Political System.
Stanford, Calif.: Hoover Institution Press.
Driault, Édouard. 1921. La question d’orient: depuis ses origines jusqu’a la Paix de Sèvres
(1920). Paris: Alcan.
Dündar, Fuat. 2010. Crime of Numbers: The Role of Statistics in the Armenian Question
(1878–1918). New Brunswick, N.J., and London: Transaction Publishers.
Durham, M. Edith. 2001. Albania and the Albanians: Selected Articles and Letters, 1903–
1944, ed. Bejtullah Destani. London: Center for Albanian Studies and I. B. Tauris.
Dwyer, Arienne M. 2005. The Xinjiang Conflict: Uyghur Identity, Language Policy, and
Political Discourse. Washington, D.C.: East-West Center Washington.
Eberhardt, Piotr. 2003. Ethnic Groups and Population Changes in Twentieth-Century
Central-Eastern Europe: History, Data, and Analysis. Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe.
Edwards, Lovett F. (ed.). 1969. The Memoirs of Prota Matija Nenadović. Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
Eisenstadt, S. N., and Stein Rokkan (eds.). 1973. Building States and Nations: Analyses
by Region. Vol. 2. Beverly Hills, Calif., and London: Sage Publications.
Elbadawi, Ibrahim, and Nicholas Sambanis. 2000. “External Interventions and the
Duration of Civil Wars,” Policy Research Working Paper 2433, Washington, D.C.:
The World Bank Development Research Group, Public Economics.
Eliakis, Ioannis. 1940. He Hestoria Exinta Hronon me eikones kai documenta [The
History of Sixty Years with Pictures and Documents]. Hania, Greece: “Efedrikou
Agonos.”
Elsie, Robert. 1997. Kosovo: In the Heart of the Powder Keg. Boulder, Colo.: East
European Monographs.
Emerson, Rupert. 1960. From Empire to Nation. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press.
Eminov, Ali. 1997. Turkish and Other Muslim Minorities in Bulgaria. New York:
Routeledge.
226 References

Evans, James. 2008. Great Britain and the Creation of Yugoslavia: Negotiating Balkan
Nationality and Identity. London: Tauris Academic Studies.
Evrigenis, Ioannis D. 2008. Fear of Enemies and Collective Action. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Fearon, James D. 1998. “Commitment Problems and the Spread of Ethnic Conflict,” in
David Lake and Donald Rothchild (eds.), The International Spread of Ethnic Conflict:
Fear, Diffusion, and Escalation. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 114–126.
Fearon, James D. 2003. “Ethnic Structure and Cultural Diversity by Country,” Journal of
Economic Growth, 8 (June): 195–222.
Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. 2003. “Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War,”
American Political Science Review, 97(1, February): 75–90.
Fearon, James D., and David D. Laitin. 2011. “Sons of the Soil, Migrants, and Civil
War,” World Development, 39(2): 199–211.
Fein, Helen. 1993. “Accounting for Genocide after 1945: Theories and Some Findings,”
International Journal on Minority and Group Rights, 1(2): 79–106.
Fichte, Johann Gottlieb. 1968 [1806]. Thirteenth Address, Addresses to the German
Nation, ed. George A. Kelly. New York: Harper Torchbooks.
Findley, Carter Vaughn. 2010. Turkey, Islam, Nationalism, and Modernity: A History,
1789–2007. New Haven, Conn., and London: Yale University Press.
Finnemore, Martha. 2004. The Purpose of Intervention: Changing Beliefs about the Use
of Force. Ithaca, N.Y., and London: Cornell University Press.
Finney, Patrick B. 1995. “‘An Evil for All Concerned’: Great Britain and Minority
Protection after 1919,” Journal of Contemporary History, 30(3): 533–551.
Fischer, Bernd J. 2007. “King Zog, Albania’s Interwar Dictator,” in Bernd J. Fischer (ed.),
Balkan Strongmen: Dictators and Authoritarian Rulers of Southeast Europe. West
Lafayette, Ind.: Purdue University Press, 19–49.
Fleming, Katherine E. 2008. Greece: A Jewish History. Princeton, N.J., and Oxford:
Princeton University Press.
Fravel, M. Taylor. 2008. Strong Borders, Secure Nation: Cooperation and Conflict in
China’s Territorial Disputes. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Freundlich, Leo. 1997. “Albania’s Golgotha: Indictment of the Exterminators of the
Albanian People (1913),” in Robert Elsie (ed.), Kosovo: In the Heart of the Powder
Keg. Boulder, Colo.: East European Monographs, 332–360.
Friedman, Isaiah. 1973. The Question of Palestine, 1914–1918: British-Jewish-Arab
Relations. New York: Schocken Books.
Friedman, Thomas L. 2000. The Lexus and the Olive Tree. New York: Farrar, Straus &
Giroux.
Friedman, Thomas L. 2007. The World Is Flat, 3.0: A Brief History of the Twenty-first
Century. New York: Picador/Farrar, Straus & Giroux.
Friedman, Victor A. 1999. Linguistic Emblems and Emblematic Languages: On
Language as Flag in the Balkans (Kenneth E. Naylor Memorial Lecture Series in
South Slavic Linguistics, No. 1). Department of Slavic and East European Languages
and Literatures, Ohio State University.
Friedman, Victor A. 2001. “Languages and Ethnicity in Balkan Politics: Macedonian,
Bulgarian, and Albanian” (Meeting Report No. 215). East European Studies (EES)
News, Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. Washington, D.C.:
Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. January–February.
Fukuyama, Francis. 2004. “State of the Union: Nation-Building 101,” Atlantic Monthly,
January/February.
References 227

Fukuyama, Francis (ed.). 2006. Nation-Building: Beyond Afghanistan and Iraq.


Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Gaddis, John Lewis. 1997. We Now Know: Rethinking the Cold War. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Gagnon, V. P. Jr. 1994/1995. “Ethnic Nationalism and International Conflict: The Case
of Serbia,” International Security, 19(3, Winter): 132–168.
Gagnon, V. P. Jr. 2004. The Myth of Ethnic War: Serbia and Croatia in the 1990s. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Ganster, Paul, and David E. Lorey (eds.). 2005. Borders and Border Politics in a
Globalizing World. Lanham, Md.: SR Books.
Garašanin, Ilija. 1998 [1844]. Načertanije. Beograd: Studio 104.
Gartzke, Erik A., and Kristian Skrede Gleditsch. 2006. “Identity and Conflict: Ties That
Bind and Differences That Divide,” European Journal of International Relations,
12(1): 53–87.
Geertz, Clifford. 1963. “The Integrative Revolution: Primordial Sentiments and Politics
in the New States,” in Clifford Geertz (ed.), Old Societies and New States: The Quest
for Modernity in Asia and Africa. New York: Free Press of Glencoe.
Gelber, N. M., D. Florentin, Adolf Friedmann, and G. F. Török. 1955. “An Attempt to
Internationalize Salonika, 1912–1913,” Jewish Social Studies, 17(2): 105–120.
Gellner, Ernest. 1983. Nations and Nationalism. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
General Staff of the Army. 1940. O Ellinikos Stratos kata tous Valkanikous Polemous
tou 1912–1913 [The Greek Army during the Balkan Wars of 1912–1913]. Vol. A.
Athens: Army History Directorate.
General Staff of the Army. 1958. O Ellinikos Stratos kata ton Proton Pagosmion
Polemon, 1914–1918 [The Greek Army during World War I, 1914–1918]. Vol. 1.
Athens: Army History Directorate.
Gerolymatos, Andre. 2002. The Balkan Wars: Conquest, Revolution, and Retribution
from the Ottoman Era to the Twentieth Century. New York: Basic Books.
Gerring, John. 2007. Case Study Research: Principles and Practices. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Giannoulopoulos, Ioannis. 1999. I eugenis mas tyflosis. Exoteriki Politiki kai “Ethnika
Themata” apo tin Itta tou 1897 eos ti Mikrasiatiki Katastrofi [Our Noble Blindness.
Foreign Policy and “National Issues” from the 1897 Defeat to the Asia Minor
Catastrophe]. Athens: Vivliorama.
Giuliano, Elise. 2011. Constructing Grievance: Ethnic Nationalism in Russia’s Republics.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Glavinas, Ioannis. 2008. “Oi mousoulmanikoi plitismoi stin Ellada (1912–1923): anti-
lipseis kai praktikes tis ellinikis dioikisis, sheseis me hristianous gigeneis kai prosfyges”
[The Muslim Population in Greece (1912–1923): Views and Practices of the Hellenic
Administration, Relations with Indigenous Christians and Refugees]. Ph.D. disserta-
tion, Aristotle University of Thessaloniki.
Glazer, Nathan, and Daniel Patrick Moynihan. 1970. Beyond the Melting Pot. Cambridge,
Mass.: MIT Press.
Glazier, Jack. 1998. Dispersing the Ghetto: The Relocation of Jewish Immigrants across
America. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede. 2007. “Transnational Dimensions of Civil War,” Journal of
Peace Research, 44(3): 293–309.
Glenny, Misha. 2001 [1999]. The Balkans: Nationalism, War, and the Great Powers,
1804–1999. New York: Penguin Books.
228 References

Göçek, Fatma Müge. 1993. “Ethnic Segmentation, Western Education, and Political
Outcomes: Nineteenth-Century Ottoman Society,” Poetics Today, 14(3): 507–538.
Goertz, Gary, and Paul F. Diehl. 1997. “Linking Risky Dyads: An Evaluation of the
Relations between Enduring Rivalries,” in Gerald Schneider and Patricia A. Weitsman
(eds.), Enforcing Cooperation: Risky States and Intergovernmental Management of
Conflict. London: Macmillan, 132–160.
Goldstein, Melvyn C. 1989. A History of Modern Tibet, 1913–1951: The Demise of the
Lamaist State. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Goldstein, Melvyn C. 2006. “The United States, Tibet, and the Cold War,” Journal of
Cold War Studies, 8(3): 145–164.
Goldstein, Melvyn C., Dawei Sherap, and William R. Siebenschuh. 2004. A Tibetan
Revolutionary: The Political Life and Times of Bapa Phuntso Wangye. Berkeley, Los
Angeles, and London: University of California Press.
Gordon, Milton. 1964. Assimilation in American Life: The Role of Race, Religion and
National Origins. New York: Oxford University Press.
Gounaris, Basil G. 1996. “Social Cleavages and National ‘Awakening’ in Ottoman
Macedonia,” East European Quarterly, 29(4): 409–425.
Gounaris, Basil G. 2005. “Preachers of God and Martyrs of the Nation: The Politics
of Murder in Ottoman Macedonia in the Early Twentieth Century,” Balkanologie,
9(1–2): 31–43
Great Britain. Foreign Office. Historical Section. 1920. Albania. No. 17. London:
H. M. Stationery Office.
Greenfeld, Liah. 1993. Nationalism: Five Roads to Modernity. Cambridge, Mass.:
Harvard University Press.
Grigoryan, Arman. 2010. “Third-Party Intervention and the Escalation of State-Minority
Conflicts,” International Studies Quarterly, 54(4, December): 1143–1174.
Grimm, Gerhard. 1984. “Ethnographic Maps of the Kosova Region from 1730–1913,”
in Arshi Pipa and Sami Repishti (eds.), Studies on Kosova. Boulder, Colo.: East
European Monographs.
Grunfeld, Tom A. 1987. The Making of Modern Tibet. London: Zed Books.
Guibernau, Montserrat. 1999. Nations without States: Political Communities in a Global
Age. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Gullather, Nick. 2006. Secret History: The CIA’s Classified Account of Its Operations in
Guatemala, 1952–1954. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
Gurr, Ted. 1993. Minorities at Risk: A Global View of Ethnopolitical Conflicts.
Washington, D.C.: United States Institute of Peace.
Haass, Richard. 2008. “The Age of Nonpolarity: What Will Follow U.S. Dominance,”
Foreign Affairs, 87(3): 44–56.
Hadri, Ali. 1995. “The Albanian League of Prizren 1878–1881,” Kosova, 5: 7–9.
Hajdarpašić, Edin. 2008. “Out of the Ruins of the Ottoman Empire: Reflections on the
Ottoman Legacy in South-eastern Europe,” Middle Eastern Studies, 44(5):
715–734.
Hale, Henry E. 2008. The Foundations of Ethnic Politics: Separatism of States and
Nations in Eurasia and the World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Han, Enze, and Harris Mylonas. 2011. “Interstate Relations, Perceptions, and Power
Balance: Explaining China’s Nation-Building Policies, 1949–1965,” paper pre-
sented at the 2011 ISA Annual Convention, Montreal, Canada (16–19 March
2011).
References 229

Hanioğlu, M. Şükrü. 2001. Preparation for a Revolution: The Young Turks, 1902–1908.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Harff, Barbara. 1987. “The Etiology of Genocides,” in Isidor Walliman and Michael
N. Dobkowski (eds.), Genocide and the Modern Age: Etiology and Case Studies of
Mass Death. New York: Greenwood Press, 41–59.
Harff, Barbara. 2003. “No Lessons Learned from the Holocaust? Assessing Risks of
Genocide and Political Mass Murder since 1955,” American Political Science Review,
97(1): 57–73.
Harth, Erica. 2001. Last Witnesses: Reflections on the Wartime Internment of Japanese
Americans. New York: Palgrave.
Hartmuth, Maximilian. 2008. “De/constructing a ‘Legacy in Stone’: Of Interpretative
and Historiographical Problems Concerning the Ottoman Cultural Heritage in the
Balkans,” Middle Eastern Studies, 44(5): 695–713.
Hassiotis, Loukianos. 2004. Hellinoservikes Sheseis 1913–1918 [Greek-Serbian
Relations 1913–1918]. Thessaloniki: Vanias.
Hassiotis, Loukianos. 2005. “Forcible Relocation from Greek Macedonia during the
First World War.” Available at: http://www.macedonian-heritage.gr/Contributions/
20030110_HassiotisL.html.
Hausman, Jerry, and Daniel McFadden. 1984. “Specification Tests for the Multinomial
Logit Model,” Econometrica, 52(5): 1219–1240.
Heaton-Armstrong, Captain Duncan. 2005. The Six Month Kingdom: Albania 1914, ed.
Gervase Belfield, and Bejtullah Destani. London: I. B. Tauris in association with the
Centre for Albanian Studies.
Hechter, Michael. 1975. Internal Colonialism: The Celtic Fringe in British National
Development, 1536–1966. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Hechter, Michael. 1987. Principles of Group Solidarity. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Hechter, Michael. 2000. Containing Nationalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Helmreich, Ernst Christian. 1938. The Diplomacy of the Balkan Wars: 1912–1913.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Heraclides, Alexis. 1990. “Secessionist Minorities and External Involvement,”
International Organization, 44(3): 341–378.
Heraclides, Alexis. 1991. The Self-Determination of Minorities in International Politics.
London: Frank Cass.
Herder, Johann Gottfried. 2004. Another Philosophy of History and Selected Political
Writings, trans. and ed. Ioannis Evrigenis and Daniel Pellerin. Indianapolis, Ind.:
Hackett Publishing.
Hersh, Seymour. 2008. “Preparing the Battlefield: The Bush Administration Steps Up Its
Secret Moves against Iran,” The New Yorker, 7 July.
Hippler, Jochen. 2005. Nation-Building: A Key Concept for Peaceful Conflict Transformation?
London: Pluto Press.
Hirschon, Renee. 2003. Crossing the Aegean: An Appraisal of the 1923 Compulsory
Population Exchange between Greece and Turkey. New York: Berghahn Books.
Hobsbawm, Eric. 1990. Industry and Empire: From 1750 to the Present Day. London:
Penguin.
Hobsbawm, Eric. 1991. Nations and Nationalism since 1780: Programme, Myth,
Reality. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Hoffmann, Julia, and André Hollkaemper (eds.). 2012. Responsibility to Protect: From
Principle to Practice. Amsterdam: University of Amsterdam Press.
230 References

Hollingshead, August B. 1952. “Trends in Social Stratification: A Case Study,” American


Sociological Review, 17(6): 679–686.
Horowitz, Donald. 1985. Ethnic Groups in Conflict. Berkeley: University of California
Press.
Horvat, Branko. 1988. Kosovsko Pitanje. Zagreb: Globus.
Hovannisian, Richard G. (ed.). 1986. The Armenian Genocide in Perspective. New
Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Publishers.
Howard, Marc Morje. 2009. The Politics of Citizenship in Europe. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press..
Hroch, Miroslav. 2000 [1985]. Social Preconditions of National Revival in Europe: A
Comparative Analysis of the Social Composition of Patriotic Groups among the
Smaller European Nations. New York: Columbia University Press.
Huntington, Samuel. 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, Conn.:
Yale University Press.
Ilicak, H. Sükrü. 2011. “Ottoman Perceptions of and Reactions to the Greek War of
Independence.” Ph.D. dissertation, Harvard University.
Institute of History. 1993. The Truth on Kosova. Tirana: Academy of Sciences of the
Republic Albania.
Isaacs, Harold. 1975. Idols of the Tribe. New York: Harper & Row.
Ishiyama, John T., and Marijke Breuning. 1998. Ethnopolitics in the New Europe.
Boulder, Colo., and London: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Jagodić, Miloš. 2009. Srpsko-albanski odnosi u Kosovskom vilajetu 1878–1912 [Serbo-
Albanian Rellations in the Kosovo Vilajet/Area]. Belgrade: Zavod za udžbenike.
Jagodić, Miloš. 2010. Uredjenje oslobodjenih oblasti Srbije 1912–1914 [The
Arrangement of the Liberated Areas of Serbia]. Belgrade: Istorijski institut SANU.
Janjetović, Zoran. 2005. Deca careva, pastorcad kraljeva: nacionalne manjine u Kraljevini
Jugoslaviji 1918–1941 [The Children of the Emperors, the Stepchildren of the Kings:
Minorities in the Kingdom of SCS 1918–1941]. Belgrade: Istorijski institut SANU.
Janković, Branimir M. 1988. The Balkans in International Relations, trans. Margot and
Boško Milosavljević. Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Janowsky, Oscar Isaiah. 1966 [1933]. The Jews and Minority Rights (1898–1919). New
York: AMS Press.
Jelavich, Barbara. 1991. Russia’s Balkan Entanglements, 1806–1914. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Jelavich, Charles, and Barbara Jelavich. 1965. The Balkans. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.:
Prentice-Hall.
Jelavich, Charles, and Barbara Jelavich. 1977. The Establishment of the Balkan National
States, 1804–1920. Seattle and London: University of Washington Press.
Jenne, Erin. 2004. “A Bargaining Theory of Minority Demands: Explaining the Dog That
Didn’t Bite in 1990s Yugoslavia,” International Studies Quarterly 48(4): 729–754.
Jenne, Erin. 2007. Ethnic Bargaining: The Paradox of Minority Empowerment. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Jenne, Erin, and Harris Mylonas. 2011. “Fighting the ‘Enemy Within’: State Responses
toward Externally Leveraged Minorities,” paper presented at the 2011 annual meeting
of the American Political Science Association, Seattle, Washington (1–4 September
2011). Previous versions of this paper were presented at the 2010 Annual Meeting of
the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C. (2–5 September 2010)
and the GW Comparative Politics Workshop, Washington, D.C. (10 September 2010).
References 231

Joppke, Christian. 2005. Selecting by Origin: Ethnic Migration in the Liberal State.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Kamalov, Ablet. 2009. “Uyghurs in the Central Asian Republics: Past and Present,” in
Colin Mackerras and Michael Clarke (eds.), China, Xinjiang and Central Asia: History,
Transition and Crossborder Interaction into the 21st Century. London and New York:
Routledge.
Kaplan, Robert. 1993. Balkan Ghosts: A Journey through History. New York: St.
Martin’s Press.
Karadžić, Vuk. 1972 [1860]. Etnografski spisi [Ethnographic Handwritings]. Belgrade:
Prosveta.
Karakasidou, Anastasia. 1997. Fields of Wheat, Hills of Blood: Passages to Nationhood in
Greek Macedonia, 1870–1990. Chicago, Ill., and London: University of Chicago Press.
Karavas, Spyros. 2010. “Makarioi oi katehontes tin gin.” Gaioktitikoi Shediasmoi pros
Apallotriosi Syneidiseon sti Makedonia, 1880–1909 [“Blessed are they who shall possess
the Earth.” Land-Ownership Plans for Expropriating Consciences in Macedonia,
1880–1909]. Athens: Vivliorama.
Karavidas, Konstantinos. 1931. Agrotika: Ereuna epi tis Oikonomikis kai Koinonikis
Morfologias en Elladi kai en tais Geitonikais Slavikais Horais [Agrarian Studies: An
Inquiry into the Economic and Social Morphology in Greece and in the Neighboring
Slavic Countries]. Athens: Ethnikon Typographeion.
Kasaba, Reşat (ed.) 2008. Cambridge History of Turkey: Turkey in the Modern World.
Vol. 4. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Katsikas, Stefanos. 2009. “Millets in Nation-States: The Case of Greek and Bulgarian
Muslims, 1912–1923,” Nationalities Papers, 37(2): 177–201.
Kaufman, Stuart J. 2001. Modern Hatreds: The Symbolic Politics of Ethnic War. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Kaufmann, E., and O. Haklai. 2008. “Dominant Ethnicity: From Minority to Majority,”
Nations and Nationalism, 14(4): 743–767.
Kedourie, Elie. 1993. Nationalism. Oxford and Cambridge, Mass.: Wiley-Blackwell.
Kennan, George Frost. 1993. The Other Balkan Wars. Washington, D.C.: Carnegie
Endowment for International Peace.
Khazanov, Anatoly M., and André Wink (eds.). 2001. Nomads in the Sedentary World.
London: Curzon Press.
Khrychikov, Sergey, and Hugh Miall. 2002. “Conflict Prevention in Estonia: The Role of
the Electoral System,” Security Dialogue, 33(2): 193–208.
King, Charles. 2008. “The Five-Day War: Managing Moscow after the Georgia Crisis,”
Foreign Affairs, 87: 62–11.
King, Charles, and Neil J. Melvin. 1999/2000. “Diaspora Politics: Ethnic Linkages,
Foreign Policy, and Security in Eurasia.” International Security, 24(3): 108–138.
King, Gary, Michael Tomz, and Jason Wittenberg. 2000. “Making the Most of Statistical
Analyses: Improving Interpretation and Presentation,” American Journal of Political
Science, 44(2): 347–361.
Kirch, Aksel, Marika Kirch, and Tarmo Tuisk. 1993. “Russians in the Baltic States: To Be
or Not to Be?” Journal of Baltic Studies, 24(2): 174
Kitromilides, Paschalis M. 1994. Enlightenment, Nationalism, Orthodoxy: Studies in the
Culture and Political Thought of South-Eastern Europe. Aldershot and Brookfield, Vt.:
Variorum.
Kliot, N. 1989. “Accommodation and Adjustment to Ethnic Demands: The Mediterranean
Framework,” Journal of Ethnic Studies, 17(2): 45–70.
232 References

Knaus, John Kenneth. 1999. Orphans of the Cold War: America and the Tibetan Struggle
for Survival. New York: Public Affairs.
Kocher, Matthew Adam. 2004. “Human Ecology and Civil War.” Ph.D. dissertation,
University of Chicago.
Kofos, Evangelos. 1964. Nationalism and Communism in Macedonia. Thessaloniki:
Institute for Balkan Studies.
Kohn, Hans. 1945. The Idea of Nationalism: A Study in Its Origins and Background.
New York: Macmillan.
Kola, Paulin. 2003. The Myth of Greater Albania. New York: New York University
Press.
Koliopoulos, John S. 1987. Brigands with a Cause: Brigandage and Irredentism in
Modern. Greece 1821–1912. New York: Oxford University Press.
Koliopoulos, John S. 2003. I “peran” Ellas kai oi “alloi” Ellines: To Synhrono Elliniko
Ethnos kai oi Eteroglossoi Synoikoi Hristianoi (1800–1912) [The Greece of “Beyond”
and the “Other” Greeks]. Thessaloniki: Vanias.
Kolstø, Pål. 2000. “Interstate Integration in the Post-Soviet Space. The Role of the
Russian Diasporas,” in Renata Dwan and Oleksandr Pavliuk (eds). Building Security
in the New States of Eurasia: Subregional Cooperation in the Former Soviet space.
Armonk, N.Y.: M.E.Sharpe.
Kondylis, Panayotis. 1985. Introduction, Translation, Notes, in Marx – Engels: I Ellada,
I Tourkia kai to Anatoliko Zitima [Marx – Engels: Greece, Turkey and the Eastern
Question]. Athens: Gnosis.
Kontis, Vasilis. 1994. Evesthites Isorropies. Ellada kai Alvania ston 20o Aiona [Sensitive
Balances. Greece and Albania in the 20th Century]. Thessaloniki: Paratiritis.
Kontogiorgi, Elisabeth. 2006. Population Exchange in Greek Macedonia: The Rural
Settlement of Refugees 1922–1930. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Koppa, Marilena. 1997. Oi Meionotites sta Meta-Kommounistika Valkania: Politikes
toy Kentrou kai Meionotikes Apantiseis [Minorities in Post-Communist Balkans:
Center’s Policies and Minority Responses]. Athens: “Nea Synora” – A. A. Livani.
Koppa, Marilena. 2002. I Sigrotisi ton Kraton sta Valkania, 19os aionas [The
Establishment of States in the Balkans, 19th Century]. Athens: “Nea Synora” – A. A.
Livani.
Kostanick, Huey Louis. 1948. “Macedonia: A Study in Political Geography.” Ph.D.
dissertation, Clark University.
Kostanick, Huey Louis. 1974 [1963]. “The Geopolitics of the Balkans,” in Charles Jelavich
and Barbara Jelavich (eds.), The Balkans in Transition: Essays on the Development of
Balkan Life and Politics since the Eighteenth Century. Hamden, Conn.: Archon
Books, 1–55.
Kostopoulos, Tasos. 2009. To “Makedoniko” tis Thrakis [The “Macedonian Question”
of Thrace]. Athens: Vivliorama.
Kovrig, Bennett. 2000. “Partitioned Nation: Hungarian Minorities in Central Europe,”
in Michael Mandelbaum (ed.), The New European Diasporas: National Minorities and
Conflict in Eastern Europe. New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press, 19–80.
Krstić-Brano, Branislav. 2004. Kosovo: Facing the Court of History. Amherst, N.Y.:
Humanity Books.
Kuperman, Alan. 2001. The Limits of Humanitarian Intervention: Genocide in Rwanda.
Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Kuperman, Alan. 2008. “The Moral Hazard of Humanitarian Intervention: Lessons from
the Balkans,” International Studies Quarterly, 52(1, March): 49–80.
References 233

Kuperman, Alan, and Timothy Crawford (eds.). 2006. Gambling on Humanitarian


Intervention: Moral Hazard, Rebellion, and Internal War. New York: Routledge.
Kymlicka, Will. 1995. Multicultural Citizenship: A Liberal Theory of Minority Rights.
Oxford and New York: Clarendon Press.
Kymlicka, Will. 2012. Multiculturalism: Success, Failure, and the Future. Washington, D.C.:
Migration Policy Institute.
Ladas, Stephen P. 1932. The Exchange of Minorities: Bulgaria, Greece and Turkey. New
York: Macmillan.
Laitin, David. 1986. Hegemony and Culture: Politics and Religious Change among the
Yoruba. Chicago, Ill., and London: University of Chicago Press.
Laitin, David. 1995. “Marginality: A Microperspective,” Rationality and Society, 7(1):
31–57.
Laitin, David. 1998. Identity in Formation: The Russian-Speaking Populations in the
Near Abroad. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Laitin, David. 2001. “Secessionist Rebellion in the former Soviet Union.” Comparative
Political Studies, 34(8): 839–861.
Lake, David A., and Donald Rothchild. 1998. The International Spread of Ethnic
Conflict: Fear, Diffusion, and Escalation. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press.
Lampe, John R. 2000. Yugoslavia as History: Twice There Was a Country. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Leon, George B. 1974. Greece and the Great Powers, 1914–1917. Thessaloniki: Institute
for Balkan Studies.
Levene, Mark. 1993. “Nationalism and Its Alternatives in the International Arena:
The Jewish Question at Paris, 1919,” Journal of Contemporary History, 28: 511–531.
Livanios, Dimitris. 1999. “‘Conquering the Souls’: Nationalism and Greek Guerrilla
Warfare in Ottoman Macedonia, 1904–1908,” Byzantine and Modern Greek Studies,
23: 195–221.
Livanios, Dimitris. 2008. The Macedonian Question: Britain and the Southern Balkans:
1939–1949. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.
Llewellyn-Smith, Michael. 1998. Ionian Vision: Greece in Asia Minor, 1919–1922.
London: Hurst.
Lobell, Steven E., Norin M. Ripsman, and Jeffrey W. Taliaferro (eds.). 2009.
Neoclassical Realism, the State, and Foreign Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Longworth, Philip. 2007. “Albania and King Zog: Independence, Republic and Monarchy
1908–1939,” Slavonic and East European Review, 85(1): 160–164.
MacFarquhar, Roderick. 1997. The Origins of the Cultural Revolution. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Mackie, John L. 1988. The Cement of the Universe: A Study in Causation. Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
MacMillan, Margaret. 2002. Paris 1919: Six Months That Changed the World. Toronto:
Random House.
Magocsi, Paul Robert. 2002. Historical Atlas of Central Europe. Seattle: University of
Washington Press.
Malcolm, Noel. 1998. Kosovo: A Short History. New York: HarperPerennial.
Mandelbaum, Michael (ed.). 2000. The New European Diasporas: National Minorities
and Conflict in Eastern Europe. New York: Council on Foreign Relations Press.
Mango, Andrew. 1999. Atatürk. London: John Murray.
234 References

Mann, Michael. 2005. The Dark Side of Democracy: Explaining Ethnic Cleansing.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mantouvalou, Katerina, and Harris Mylonas. 2010. “Islam at the EU Border: Explaining
the Policies of Greece and Bulgaria toward Muslims in the Past Three Decades,”
presentation at the Constantine Karamanlis Chair in Hellenic and Southeastern
European Studies, Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy, Cambridge, Mass.
(22 April 2010). The paper was also presented at the 21st Symposium of the Modern
Greek Studies Association, Vancouver, Canada (15–17 October 2009).
Marmullaku, Ramadan. 1975. Albania and the Albanians. London: Archon Books.
Martin, Terry. 2001. Affirmative Action Empire: Nations and Nationalism in the Soviet
Union, 1923–1939. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Marx, Anthony W. 1999. Making Race and Nation: A Comparison of the United States,
South Africa, and Brazil. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mavrogordatos, George Th. 1982. Meletes kai Keimena gia tin Periodo 1909–1940
[Studies and Documents on the Period 1909–1940]. Athens: Sakkoulas.
Mavrogordatos, George Th. 1983. Stillborn Republic: Social Coalitions and Party
Strategies in Greece, 1922–1936. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Mavrogordatos, George Th. 2003. “Oi Ethnikes Meionotites” [The National Minorities],
in Chatziiosif, Christos (ed.), Historia tis Elladas tou 20ou aiwna [History of Greece of
the 20th Century]. Vol. B2. Athens: Vivliorama, 9–35.
Mazower, Mark. 1997. “Minorities and the League of Nations in Interwar Europe,”
Daedalus, 126(2, Human Diversity, Spring): 47–63.
Mazower, Mark. 2001. The Balkans: From the End of Byzantium to the Present Day.
London: Phoenix Press.
Mazower, Mark. 2004. Salonica, City of Ghosts. New York: HarperCollins.
Mazower, Mark. 2009. No Enchanted Palace: The End of Empire and the Ideological
Origins of the United Nations. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
McCarthy, Justin. 1995. Death and Exile: The Ethnic Cleansing of Ottoman Muslims,
1821–1922. Princeton, N.J.: Darwin Press.
McGarry, John, and Brendan O’Leary. 1994. “The Political Regulation of National and
Ethnic Conflict.” Parliamentary Affairs, 47(1): 94–115.
McGranahan, Carole. 2010. Arrested Histories: Tibet, the CIA, and Memories of a
Forgotten War. Durham, N.C., and London: Duke University Press.
McMillen, Donald H. 1979. Chinese Communist Power and Policy in Xinjiang,
1949–1977. Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
Meaney, Thomas, and Harris Mylonas. 2008. “The Pandora’s Box of Sovereignty,” Los
Angeles Times, 13 August.
Mearsheimer, John. 2001. The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. New York: W.
W. Norton.
Meininger, Thomas A. 1970. Ignatiev and the Establishment of the Bulgarian Exarchate,
1864–1872: A Study in Personal Diplomacy. New York: Arno Press.
Melson, Robert. 1986. “Provocation or Nationalis A Critical Inquiry into the Armenian
Genocide of 1915,” in Richard G. Hovannisian (ed.), The Armenian Genocide in
Perspective. New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Publishers.
Melvin, Neil. 1995. Russians beyond Russia: The Politics of National Identity. London:
Royal Institute of International Affairs.
Michailidis, Iakovos. 1998. “The War on Statistics: Traditional Recipes for the Pre-
paration of the Macedonian Salad,” East European Quarterly, 32(1): 9–21.
References 235

Michailidis, Iakovos. 2003. Metakiniseis slavofonon plithysmon. O polemos ton


statistikon [Slavophone Population Novement. The War of Statistics]. Athens:
Kritiki.
Michailidis, Iakovos. 2005. “National Identity versus Minority Language: The Greek
and Bulgarian Experience in the 20th Century,” in Ann Katherine Isaacs (ed.),
Language and Identities in Historical Perspective. Pisa: Pisa University Press.
Mijatovich, Chedomille. 1917. The Memoirs of a Balkan Diplomatist. London: Cassell.
Mikesel, Marvin W., and Alexander B. Murphy. 1991. “A Framework for Comparative
Study of Minority-Group Aspirations,” Annals of the Association of American
Geographers, 81(4): 581–604.
Miller, Benjamin. 2007. States, Nations, and the Great Powers: The Sources of Regional
War and Peace. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Miller, William. 1927. “Albania and Her Protectress,” Foreign Affairs, 5(3, April):
438–445.
Millward, James A. 2007. Eurasian Crossroads: A History of Xinjiang. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Minahan, James. 2002. Encyclopedia of the Stateless Nations: Ethnic and National
Groups Around the World. Vols. 1–4. Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press.
Molho, Rena. The Jerusalem of the Balkans: Salonica 1856–1919. The Jewish Museum
of Thessaloniki. Available at: http://www.jmth.gr/web/thejews/pages/pages/history/
pages/his.htm.
Mylonas, Harris. 2006. “Peripheries, State Capacity, and Great Power Politics: Accounting
for Secession from the Ottoman Empire”, paper presented at the 11th Annual World
Convention of the Association for the Study of Nationalities, Columbia University
(22–25 March).
Mylonas, Harris. 2008. “Assimilation and Its Alternatives: The Making of Co-Nationals,
Refugees, and Minorities.” Ph.D. Dissertation, Yale University.
Mylonas, Harris. 2010. “Assimilation and Its Alternatives: Caveats in the Study of Nation-
Building Policies,” in Adria Lawrence and Erica Chenoweth (eds.), Rethinking Violence:
States and Non-state Actors in Conflict. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Mylonas, Harris. 2011. “Balkan Nation-Building Policies: Ottoman Legacy or
Replication?” paper presented at the PONARS Eurasia Bishkek workshop (Kyrgyzstan,
11–16 June 2011).
Mylonas, Harris. 2012. “Ottoman, Nationalist, and Communist Legacies in the
Balkans,” in Stoica Lascu (ed.), Balkans: Contributions to History, Culture and
Civilization. Constanţa, Romania: Ovidius University Press.
Mylonas, Harris, and Nadav Shelef. 2012. “Which Land Is Our Land? Explaining
Variation in Border Claims,” paper presented at the 17th Annual ASN World
Convention, Harriman Institute, Columbia University (April).
Naimark, N. 2001. Fires of Hatred: Ethnic Cleansing in Twentieth Century Europe.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Nikolić, Lazar. 2003. “Ethnic Prejudices and Discrimination: The Case of Kosovo,” in
Florian Bieber and Zidas Daskalovski (eds.), Understanding the War in Kosovo.
Portland, Ore.: Frank Cass, 53–76.
Njegoš, Petar Petrović. 1930 [1847]. The Mountain Wreath: An Historical Happening
Towards the Close of the 17th Century, trans. James W. Wiles. London: Allen &
Unwin.
Noreen, Erik, and Roxanna Sjöstedt. 2004. “Estonian Identity Formations and Threat
Framing in the Post–Cold War Era Source,” Journal of Peace Research, 41(6): 733–750.
236 References

Pallis, Alexander A. 1925. “Racial Migrations in the Balkans during the Years
1912–1924,” Geographical Journal, 66(4, October): 315–331.
Panaiotov, Ivan. 1946. Greeks and Bulgarians: A Historical Outline. Sofia: Hristo
G. Danov Publishers.
Pavlowitch, Stevan K. 1999. A History of the Balkans, 1804–1945. London and New
York: Longman.
Pavlowitch, Stevan K. 2000. “Europe and the Balkans in a Historical Perspective,
1804–1945,” Journal of Southern Europe and the Balkans, 2(2): 141–148.
Pearson, Owen. 2004. Albania and King Zog: Independence, Republic and Monarchy,
1908–1939. Vol. 1. London and New York: Centre for Albanian Studies in Association
with I. B. Tauris.
Pentzopoulos, Dimitri. 1962. The Balkan Exchange of Minorities and Its Impact upon
Greece. Paris: Mouton.
Perry, Duncan M. 1988. The Politics of Terror: The Macedonian Revolutionary
Movements, 1893–1903. Durham, N.C., and London: Duke University Press.
Petersen, Roger. 2001. Resistance and Rebellion: Lessons from Eastern Europe.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Petersen, Roger. 2002. Understanding Ethnic Violence: Fear, Hatred, and Resentment in
Twentieth-Century Eastern Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Petranović, Branco. 2002. The Yugoslav Experience of Serbian National Integration.
New York: Columbia University Press.
Pettai, Vello, and Klara Hallik. 2002. “Understanding Processes of Ethnic Control:
Segmentation, Dependency and Cooptation in Post-Communist Estonia,” Nations
and Nationalism 8(4): 505–529.
Pettai, Vello, and Marcus Kreuzer. 1999. “Party Politics in the Baltic States: Social Bases
and Institutional Context,” East European Politics and Society, 13(1): 148–189.
Philliou, Christine. 2008. “The Paradox of Perceptions: Interpreting the Ottoman Past
through the National Present,” Middle Eastern Studies, 44(5): 661–675.
Popović, Janjićije. 1987. Život Srba na Kosovu, 1812–1912 [Life of the Serbs in Kosovo,
1812–1912]. Belgrade: Književne novine.
Posen, Barry. 1993a. “Nationalism, the Mass Army and Military Power,” International
Security, 18(2): 80–124.
Posen, Barry. 1993b. “The Security Dilemma and Ethnic Conflict,” Survival, 35(1, Spring):
27–47.
Posner, Daniel N. 2003. “The Colonial Origins of Ethnic Cleavages: The Case of
Linguistic Divisions in Zambia,” Comparative Politics, 35(2): 127–146.
Posner, Daniel. 2004. “Measuring Ethnic Fractionalization in Africa,” American Journal
of Political Science, 48(4): 849–863.
Poulton, Hugh. 2003. “Macedonians and Albanians as Yugoslavs,” in Dejan Djokić
(ed.), Yugoslavism: Histories of a Failed Idea, 1918–1992. London: Hurst, 115–135.
Poulton, Hugh, and Miranda Vickers. 1997. “The Kosovo Albanians: Ethnic
Confrontation with the Slav State,” in Hugh Poulton and Suha Taji-Farouki (eds.),
Muslim Identity and the Balkan State. New York: New York University Press.
Protić, Milan St. 2007. “Serbian Radicalism 1881–1903: Political Thought and
Practice,” Balcanica, 38: 173–189.
Psomiades, Harry J. 1968. Eastern Question: The Last Phase, a Study in Greek-Turkish
Diplomacy. Thessaloniki: Institute for Balkan Studies.
Putin, Vladimir. 2011. “A New Integration Project for Eurasia: The Future in the Making,”
Izvestia, 4 October. Available at: http://premier.gov.ru/eng/events/news/16622/.
References 237

Quataert, Donald. 2005 [2000]. The Ottoman Empire, 1700–1922. Cambridge:


Cambridge University Press.
Rae, Heather. 2002. State Identities and the Homogenisation of Peoples. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Raitviir, Tiina. 1996. Eesti üleminekuperioodi valimiste (1989–1993) võrdlev uurimine
[Elections in Estonia during the Transition Period: A Comparative Study 1989–1993].
Tallinn: Rahvusvaliste ja Sotsiaaluuringute Instituut (Institute of International and
Social Studies).
Ramet, Sabrina P. 2006. The Three Yugoslavias: State-Building and Legitimation,
1918–2005. Bloomington and Indianapolis: Indiana University Press.
Rathbun, Brian. 2008. “A Rose by Any Other Name: Neoclassical Realism as the Logical
and Necessary Extension of Structural Realism,” Security Studies, 17(2): 80–124.
Raun, Toivo. 1991. “The Re-establishment of Estonian Independence,” Journal of Baltic
Studies, 22(3): 251–258.
Ray, Paramesh. 1973. “Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives,” Econometrica, 41(5):
987–991.
Regan, Patrick M. 2000. Civil War and Foreign Powers. Ann Arbor: University of
Michigan Press.
Regan, Patrick M. 2002. “Third-Party Interventions and the Duration of Intrastate
Conflicts,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(1): 55–73.
Renan, Ernest. 1996. “What Is a Nation?” in Geoff Eley and Ronald Grigor Suny (eds.),
Becoming National: A Reader. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press,
41–55.
Reynolds, Michael A. 2011. Shattering Empires: The Clash and Collapse of the Ottoman
and Russian Empires 1908–1918. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Roberts, Sean R. 1998. “The Uighurs of the Kazakhstan Borderlands: Migration and the
Nation,” Nationalities Papers 26(3): 511–530.
Robinson, Greg. 2009. A Tragedy of Democracy: Japanese Confinement in North
America. New York: Columbia University Press.
Roeder, Philip G. 1991. “Soviet Federalism and Ethnic Mobilization,” World Politics 43:
196–232.
Roeder, Philip G. 2007. Where Nation–States Come From: Institutional Change in the
Age of Nationalism. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Ron, James. 2003. Frontiers and Ghettos: State Violence in Serbia and Israel. Berkeley:
University of California Press.
Roos, Aarand. 1994. Words for Understanding Ethnic Estonians. Tallinn: Kommunaalprojekt
Ltd.
Rose, Gideon. 1998. “Neoclassical Realism and Theories of Foreign Policy,” World
Politics, 51(1): 144–172.
Rose, Richard, and William Maley. 1994. “Conflict or Compromise in the Baltic States?”
RFE/RL Research Report 3 (28).
Rosenau, James N. 1964. International Aspects of Civil Strife. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Rotzokos, Nikos. 2007. Ethnafipnisi kai ethnogenesi. Orlofika kai elliniki istoriografia
[National Awakening and Nation-Building: The Orlov Revolt and Greek
Historiography]. Athens: Vivliorama.
Roudometof, Victor. 1996. “Nationalism and Statecraft in Southeastern Europe
(1750–1923).” Ph.D. dissertation, University of Pittsburgh.
238 References

Roudometof, Victor. 2001. Nationalism, Globalization, and Orthodoxy: The Social


Origins of Ethnic Conflict in the Balkans. Westport, Conn., and London:
Greenwood Press.
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques. 1985 [1772]. The Government of Poland, trans. Willmoore Kendall.
Indianapolis, Ind.: Hackett.
Sabatos, Charles. 2008. “Slovak Perceptions of the Ottoman Legacy in Eastern Europe,”
Middle Eastern Studies, 44(5): 735–749.
Saideman, Stephen M. 1997. “Explaining the International Relations of Secessionist
Conflicts: Vulnerability vs. Ethnic Ties,” International Organization, 51(4): 721–753.
Saideman, Stephen M. 2002. “Discrimination in International Relations: Analyzing
External Support for Ethnic Groups,” Journal of Peace Research, 39(1): 27–50.
Saideman, Stephen M., and William Ayres. 2000. “Determining the Causes of Irredentism:
Logit Analyses of Minorities at Risk Data from the 1980s and 1990s,” Journal of Politics,
62(4): 1126–1144.
Saideman, Stephen M., and William Ayres. 2008. For Kin and Country: Xenophobia,
Nationalism, and War. New York: Columbia University Press.
Sajti, Enikô A. 2006. “The Former ‘Southlands’ in Serbia: 1918–1947,” Hungarian
Quarterly, 181: 111–124.
Salehyan, Idean. 2009. Rebels without Borders: Transnational Insurgencies in World
Politics. Ithaca, N.Y., and London: Cornell University Press.
Salehyan, Idean, and Kristian Gleditsch. 2006. “Refugees and the Spread of Civil War,”
International Organization, 60(2, April): 335–366.
Sambanis, Nicholas. 2001. “Do Ethnic and Non-ethnic Civil Wars Have the Same
Causes? A Theoretical and Empirical Inquiry (Part 1),” Journal of Conflict
Resolution, 45(3): 259–282.
Sambanis, Nicholas, and Branko Milanovic. 2009. “Explaining the Demand for
Sovereignty.” Unpublished manuscript.
Sanders, Ronald. 1984. The High Walls of Jerusalem: A History of the Balfour Declaration
and the Birth of the British Mandate for Palestine. New York: Holt, Rinehart and
Winston.
Sassen, Saskia. 1996. Losing Control? Sovereignty in an Age of Globalization. New
York: Columbia University Press.
Sassen, Saskia. 1998. Globalization and Its Discontents: Essays on the New Mobility of
People and Money. New York: New Press.
Sassen, Saskia. 2002. Global Networks, Linked Cities. New York: Routledge.
Schaeffer, R. K. 2003. Understanding Globalization: The Social Consequences of
Political, Economic, and Environmental Change. New York: Rowman and
Littlefield.
Schecter, Jerrold L. 1963. “Khrushchev’s Image Inside China,” China Quarterly, 14
(April/June): 212–217.
Schweller, Randall. 2004. “Unanswered Threats: A Neoclassical Realist Theory of
Underbalancing,” International Security, 29(2): 159–201.
Schweller, Randall. 2006. Unanswered Threats: Political Constraints on the Balance of
Power. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Sereni, Angelo Piero. 1941. “The Legal Status of Albania,” American Political Science
Review, 35(2, April): 311–317.
Seton-Watson, Hugh. 1962 [1945]. Eastern Europe between the Wars, 1918–1941.
Hamden, Conn.: Archon Books.
References 239

Shakya, Tsering. 1999. The Dragon in the Land of Snows: A History of Modern Tibet
since 1947. London: Pimlico.
Shaw, Stanford J. 1974 [1963]. “The Ottoman View of the Balkans,” in Charles Jelavich
and Barbara Jelavich (eds.), The Balkans in Transition: Essays on the Development of
Balkan Life and Politics since the Eighteenth Century. Hamden, Conn.: Archon Books,
56–80.
Shevel, Oxana. 2011. Migration, Refugee Policy, and State Building in Postcommunist
Europe. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Skendi, Stavro. 1967. The Albanian National Awakening 1878–1912. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Smith, Anthony. 1986. “State-Making and Nation-Building,” in John Hall (ed.), States in
History. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 228–263.
Smith, Anthony D. 1991. National Identity. London: Penguin.
Smith, David J. 2001. Estonia: Independence and European Integration. London and
New York: Routledge.
Smith, David J. (ed.). 2005. The Baltic States and Their Region: New Europe or Old?
Amsterdam and New York: Rodopi B.V.
Smith, Graham, and Andrew Wilson. 1997. “Rethinking Russia’s Post-Soviet Diaspora:
The Potential for Political Mobilization in Eastern Ukraine and North-east Estonia,”
Europe-Asia Studies, 49(5): 845–864.
Smith, Rogers M. 2001. “Citizenship and the Politics of People-Building,” Citizenship
Studies, 5(1): 73–96.
Smith, Rogers M. 2003. Stories of Peoplehood: The Politics and Morals of Political
Membership. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Snyder, Glenn. 1991. “Alliances, Balance, and Stability,” International Organization, 45
(1): 121–142.
Snyder, Jack L. 1991. Myths of Empire. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Snyder, Jack L. 2000. From Voting to Violence: Democratization and Nationalist
Conflict. New York: Norton.
Snyder, Jack, and Barbara Walter. 1999. Civil Wars, Insecurity, and Intervention. New
York: Columbia University Press.
Snyder, Timothy. 2003. The Reconstruction of Nations: Poland, Ukraine, Lithuania,
Belarus, 1569–1999. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Snyder, Timothy. 2008. The Red Prince: The Secret Lives of a Habsburg Archduke. New
York: Basic Books/Random House.
Snyder, Timothy. 2010. Bloodlands: Europe between Hitler and Stalin. New York: Basic
Books/Random House.
Sørensen, Jens Stilhoff. 2009. State Collapse and Reconstruction in the Periphery:
Political Economy, Ethnicity and Development in Yugoslavia, Serbia and Kosovo.
Oxford: Berghahn Books.
Sowards, Steven W. 1996. Twenty-five Lectures on Modern Balkan History: The Balkans
in the Age of Nationalism. Available at: http://www.lib.msu.edu/sowards/balkan.
Spruyt, Hendrik. 1994. The Sovereign State and Its Competitors. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Stavrianos, L. S. 1957. “Antecedents to the Balkan Revolutions of the Nineteenth
Century,” The Journal of Modern History, 29(4): 335–348.
Steed, H. Wickham. 1927. “Italy, Yugoslavia and Albania,” Journal of the Royal
Institute of International Affairs, 6(3): 170–178.
240 References

Steen, Anton, and Jüri Ruus. 2002. “Change of Regime – Continuity of Elites? The Case
of Estonia,” East European Politics and Societies, 16(1): 223–248.
Stefanidis, Yannis, Vlasis Vlasidis, and Evangelos Kofos (eds.). 2010. Macedonian
Identities through Time: Interdisciplinary Approaches. Thessaloniki: Epikentro.
Stefanović, Ðord̄e. 2005. “Seeing the Albanians through Serbian Eyes: The Inventors of
the Tradition of Intolerance and Their Critics, 1804–1939,” European History
Quarterly, 35(3): 465–492.
Stein, Leonard. 1961. Balfour Declaration. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Stephenson, Carolyn. 2005. “Nation Building,” in Guy Burgess and Heidi Burgess (eds.),
Beyond Intractability. Conflict Research Consortium, University of Colorado.
Available at: http://www.beyondintractability.org/essay/nation_building/.
Stern, Laurence. 1975. “Bitter Lessons: How We Failed in Cyprus,” Foreign Policy, 19:
34–78.
Strange, Susan. 2000. “The Declining Authority of States,” in David Held and
Anthony McGrew (eds.), The Global Transformation Reader: An Introduction to the
Global Debate. Cambridge: Polity Press, 148–155.
Straus, Scott. 2006. The Order of Genocide: Race, Power, and War in Rwanda. Ithaca,
N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Sugar, Peter. 1977. Southeastern Europe under Ottoman Rule, 1354–1804. Seattle and
London: University of Washington Press.
Suny, Ronald Grigor. 1993. The Revenge of the Past: Nationalism, Revolution, and the
Collapse of the Soviet Union. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
Suny, Ronald Grigor, and Terry Martin. 2001. A State of Nations: Empire and Nation-
Making in the Age of Lenin and Stalin. New York: Oxford University Press.
Suny, Ronald Grigor, Fatma Muge Gocek, and Norman M. Naimark (eds.). 2011.
A Question of Genocide: Armenians and Turks at the End of the Ottoman Empire.
Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.
Swire, Joseph. 1971. Albania: The Rise of a Kingdom. London: Allen & Urwin.
Taras, Ray, and Rajat Ganguly. 2002. Understanding Ethnic Conflict: The International
Dimension, 2nd ed. New York: Longman.
Thyne, Clayton L. 2009. How International Relations Affect Civil Conflict: Cheap
Signals, Costly Consequences. Lanham, Md.: Rowman & Littlefield.
Tilly, Charles (ed.). 1975. The Formation of National States in Western Europe.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Tilly, Charles. 1992. Coercion, Capital and European States. Cambridge, Mass., and
Oxford: Blackwell Press.
Tilly, Charles. 1994. “States and Nationalism in Europe 1492–1992,” Theory and
Society, 23: 131–146.
Todorov, Nikolai. 1983. The Balkan City, 1400–1900. Seattle and London: University of
Washington Press.
Todorova, Maria. 1997. Imagining the Balkans. New York: Oxford University Press.
Todorović, Desanka. 1979. Jugoslavija i balkanske drzave 1918–1923 [Yugoslavia and
the Balkan States 1918–1923]. Belgrade: Institut za savremenu istoriju.
Toft, Monica Duffy. 2003. The Geography of Ethnic Violence. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Tomasevich, Jozo. 1955. Peasants, Politics, and Economic Change in Yugoslavia.
Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
Tomz, Michael, Jason Wittenberg, and Gary King. 2003. CLARIFY: Software for
Interpreting and Presenting Statistical Results. Version 2.1. Stanford University,
References 241

University of Wisconsin, and Harvard University. Available at: http://gking.har


vard.edu.
Treisman, Daniel. 1997. “Russia’s ‘Ethnic Revival’: The Separatist Activism of Regional
Leaders in a Postcommunist Order,” World Politics, 49(2): 212–249.
Troch, Pieter. 2010. “Yugoslavism between the World Wars: Indecisive Nation
Building,” Nationalities Papers, 38(2, March): 227–244.
Trotsky, Leon. 1980. The Balkan Wars, 1912–1913, trans. Brian Pearce, ed.
George Weissman and Duncan Williams. New York: Monad Press.
Troumbeta, Sevasti. 2001. Kataskevazontas Tautotites gia tous Mousoulmanous tis
Thrakis [Constructing Identities for the Muslims of Thrace]. Athens: Kritiki.
Tsitselikis, Konstantinos. 2007. “The Pending Modernisation of Islam in Greece: From
Millet to Minority Status,” Südosteuropa, 55(4): 354–372.
Tsitselikis, Konstantinos. 2012. Old and New Islam in Greece: From Historical
Minorities to Immigrant Newcomers. Leiden, the Netherlands, and Boston: Martinus
Nijhoff Publishers.
Tucker, Spencer, Laura Matysek Wood, and Justin D. Murphy (eds.). 1999. The
European Powers in the First World War: An Encyclopedia. New York: Taylor &
Francis.
Ülker, Erol. 2005. “Contextualising ‘Turkification’: Nation-Building in the Late
Ottoman Empire, 1908–18,” Nations and Nationalism, 11(4): 613–636.
Üngör, Ugur Ümit. 2011. The Making of Modern Turkey Nation and State in Eastern
Anatolia, 1913–1950. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Valentino, Benjamin. 2004. Final Solutions: Mass Killing and Genocide in the Twentieth
Century. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Van den Berghe, Pierre L. 1981. The Ethnic Phenomenon. New York: Elsevier.
Van Evera, Stephen. 1994. “Hypotheses on Nationalism and War,” International
Security, 18(4): 5–39.
van Houten, Pieter. 1998. “The Role of a Minority’s Reference State in Ethnic Relations,”
Archives Européennes de Sociologie, 39(Spring): 110–146.
Vasiliadis, Nikolaos. 2004. I Elliniki parousia sti Notia Servia apo tous Valkanikous
polemous eos to Mesopolemo [The Hellenic Presence in South Serbia from the Balkan
Wars to the Interwar Period]. Thessaloniki: Anatropi.
Vasquez, John, and Marie T. Henehan. 2001. “Territorial Disputes and the Probability of
War, 1816–1992,” Journal of Peace Research, 38(2): 123–138.
Venizelos, Eleutherios. 1919. Greece before the Peace Congress of 1919: A Memorandum
Dealing with the Rights of Greece. New York: Oxford University Press.
Verli, Marenglen. 1995. “Slavic Colonial Policy in the Albanian Territories between the
Two World Wars (1918–1941),” Kosova, 5: 15–18.
Verli, Marenglen. 1999. “Garašanin’s Načertanije: Ideological Basis of Greater Serbia’s
Program,” Kosova, 7: 49–55.
Vickers, Miranda. 1998. Between Serb and Albanian: A History of Kosovo. London:
C. Hurst.
Villari, Luigi. 1956. Italian Foreign Policy under Mussolini. New York: Devin-Adair.
Vlasidis, Vlasis. 1998. “Consequences of the Demographic and Social Re-arrangements
to the Vlach-speaking Element of Greek Macedonia (1923–1926),” Revue des
Etudes Sud-Est Europeennes, Danube-Balkans-Mer Noire Tome, 36(1–4): 155–171.
Vouri, Sophia. 1992. Ekpaideuse kai Ethnikismos sta Valkania. He Periptose tis
Voreiodytikes Makedonias 1870–1904 [Education and Nationalism in the Balkans.
The Case of North-Western Macedonia 1870–1904]. Athens: Paraskinio.
242 References

Vouri, Sophia. 1994. Piges gia tin Istoria tes Makedonias. Politike kai ekpaideuse 1875–
1907 [Sources for the History of Macedonia. Politics and Education 1875–1907].
Athens: Paraskinio.
Vouri, Sophia. 2005. Oikotrofeia kai ypotrofies ste Makedonia (1903–1913). Tekmiria
Istorias [Boarding Schools and Scholarships in Macedonia (1903–1913). Historial
Evidence]. Athens: Gutenberg.
Walt, Stephen. 1985. “Alliance Formation and the Balance of World Power,”
International Security, 9(4): 3–43.
Walt, Stephen. 1987. The Origins of Alliances. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Walt, Stephen. 1988. “Testing Theories of Alliance Formation: The Case of Southwest
Asia,” International Organization, 42(2): 275–316.
Walt, Stephen. 1997. “Why Alliances Endure or Collapse,” Survival, 39(1): 156–179.
Walter, Barbara. 2009. Reputation and Civil War: Why Separatist Conflicts Are So
Violent. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Waltz, Kenneth. 1979. Theory of International Politics. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Wang, Lixiong. 2002. “Reflections of Tibet,” New Left Review, 14 (March/April):
79–111.
Weber, Eugen. 1976. Peasants into Frenchmen: The Modernization of Rural France,
1870–1914. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
Weber, Katja. 1997. “Hierarchy amidst Anarchy: A Transaction Costs Approach to
International Security Cooperation,” International Studies Quarterly, 41: 321–340.
Weber, Max. 1978. Economy and Society. Vol. 1. Trans. and ed. Guenther Roth and
Claus Wittich. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Weinberg, Gerhard L. 1995. Germany, Hitler, and World War II. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Weiner, Myron. 1971. “The Macedonian Syndrome: An Historical Model of
International Relations and Political Development,” World Politics, 23(4): 665–683.
Weiner, Myron. 1996. “Bad Neighbors, Bad Neighborhoods: An Inquiry into the Causes
of Refugee Flows,” International Security, 17(1): 5–42.
Weiner, Tim. 2007. Legacy of Ashes: The History of the CIA. New York: Anchor
Books.
Wheeler, Geoffrey. 1963. “Sinkiang and the Soviet Union,” China Quarterly, 16:
56–61.
Wilkinson, Henry R. 1951. Maps and Politics: A Review of Ethnographic Cartography of
Macedonia. Liverpool: Liverpool University Press.
Wilson, Thomas M., and Hastings Donnan. 1998. Border Identities: Nation and State at
International Frontiers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wimmer, Andreas. 2002. Nationalist Exclusion and Ethnic Conflict: Shadows of
Modernity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wimmer, Andreas. 2012. Waves of War: Nationalism, State Formation, and Ethnic
Exclusion in the Modern World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wolf, Lucien. 1919. Notes on the Diplomatic History of the Jewish Question: With Texts
of Protocols, Treaty Stipulations and Other Public Acts and Official Documents.
London: Ballantyne.
Wolfers, Arnold. 1962. Discord and Collaboration: Essays on International Politics.
Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Wood, Denis (with John Fels). 1992. The Power of Maps. New York: Guilford Press.
Woodwell, Douglas. 2004. “Unwelcome Neighbors: Shared Ethnicity and International
Conflict during the Cold War,” International Studies Quarterly, 48: 197–223.
References 243

Yıldırım, Onur. 2006. Diplomacy and Displacement: Reconsidering the Turco-Greek


Exchange of Populations, 1922–1934. New York: Routledge.
_
Yilmaz, Şuhnaz, and Ipek K. Yosmaoğlu. 2008. “Fighting the Spectres of the Past:
Dilemmas of Ottoman Legacy in the Balkans and the Middle East,” Middle Eastern
Studies, 44(5): 677–693.
_
Yosmaoğlu-Turner, Ipek. 2005. “The Priest’s Robe and the Rebel’s Rifle: Communal
Conflict and the Construction of National Identity in Ottoman Macedonia,
1878–1908.” Ph.D. dissertation, Princeton University.
Young, Crawford (ed.). 1993. The Rising Tide of Cultural Pluralism. Madison:
University of Wisconsin Press.
Zavalani, T. 1969. “Albanian Nationalism,” in Peter F. Sugar and Ivo J. Lederer (eds.),
Nationalism in Eastern Europe. Seattle and London: University of Washington Press,
55–92.
Zickel, Raymond, and Walter R. Iwaskiw (eds.). 1994. Albania: A Country Study.
Washington, D.C.: GPO for the Library of Congress.
Žižek, Slavoj. 2008. Violence: Six Sideways Reflections. London: Profile Books.
Zürcher, Eric J. 2004. Turkey: A Modern History, 3rd ed. London: I. B. Tauris.
Author Index

Aalto, Pami, 183 Longworth, Philip, 161


Anderson, Benedict, 48
Mann, Michael, 4,
Banac, Ivo, 153 20, 188
Bell, Wendell, 18 Mazower, Mark, 55, 119
Brubaker, Rogers, 20, 80 McCarthy, Justin, 150
Byman, Daniel, 32, 34–35, 47 McGarry, John, 21
Miall, Hugh, 182
Connor, Walker, 18 Moynihan, Daniel, 18
Cvijić, Jovan, 148
O’Leary, Brendan, 21
Dérens, Jean-Arnault, 162
Durham, Mary Edith, 150 Pavlowitch, Stevan, 59
Protić, Milan St., 68
Fischer, Bernd Jürgen, 69
Ramet, Sabrina P., 165
Geertz, Clifford, 18
Gellner, Ernest, 48 Saideman, Steven, 32
Glazer, Nathan, 18 Sajti, Enikô A., 104
Göçek, Fatma Müge, 55 Seton-Watson, Hugh,
111
Hale, Henry, 32 Snyder, Jack, 4
Han, Enze, 180 Stavrianos, L. S., 54
Hechter, Michael, 26 Stefanović, Ðord̄e, 145
Heraclides, Alexis, 33 Straus, Scott, 20
Hersh, Seymour, 31
Horowitz, Donald, 19 Treisman, Daniel, 20
Trotsky, Leon, 51, 193
Janković, Branimir, 59
Jenne, Erin, 34 Van Houten, Pieter, 20
Verli, Marenglen, 162
Kedourie, Elie, 48
Khrychikov, Sergey, 182 Walter, Barbara, 20
Kohn, Hans, 48 Wang, Lixiong, 177
Kontis, Vasilis, 100, 104 Weiner, Myron, 20
Kuperman, Alan, 197 Wimmer, Andreas, 10

245
Historical Name Index

Aleksandar, King of Yugoslavia, 68, 159, Grey, Sir Edward, 151


160, 162, 165–167
attempted murder, 165 Herbert, Aubrey, 150
civil liberties, 160 Hitler, Adolf, 9, 25, 162
Alexander I, Tsar, 172
Andrić, Ivo, 164 _
Inönü, _
Mustafa Ismet, 67
Atatürk, Mustafa Kemal, 67 Ipsilantis, Alexandros, 172
Averescu, Alexandru, 68
Kadriu, Hoxha, 155
Balfour, Arthur James, 107 Kalevras, Achilleas, 100, 193
Boris, King of Bulgaria, 67 Karadjordjević dynasty, 68, 154
Brătianu, Ion I.C., 68
Bush, George W., 31 Macchio, Karl, 107
Maćek, Vladko, 168
Catherine II, Czarina of Russia, 31 Mao, Zedong, 175–178
Constantine, King, 115, 117–118 Marghiloman, Alexandru, 68
Crackanthorpe, Dayrell, 151, 152 Milošević, Slobodan, 26, 174
Čubrilović, Vaso, 163 Mussolini, Benito, 159, 162
Mustafa III, Sultan of the Ottoman
Dalai Lama, 176–178 Empire, 31, 59
Davidović, Ljubimir (Prime Minister),
165–166 Noli, Bishop Fan, 101, 104, 158
Deng, Xiaoping, 177
Orlov, Grigory, 31
Eliakis, Ioannis
opinion of Muslims, 122–129 Pallis, Alexandros, 114
reaction toward internal and external Pašić, Nikola, 68, 148–149,
enemies, 129–138 165–166
Peckham, Walter, 153
Ferdinand, King of Bulgaria, 67–68 Politis, Nikolaos, 114
Ferdinand, King of Romania, 68 Prishtina, Hasan, 151, 153, 157
Friedemann, Adolf, 107 Putin, Vladimir, 184, 199

246
Historical Name Index 247

Radić, Stjepan, 165–166, 168 Vamvakas, Harisios, 114


Repoulis, Emmanuel, 114, 193 Venizelos, Eleftherios, 68, 92, 100–101,
109–110, 113–118, 121, 125–128,
Sarrail, General Maurice, 118 134–135, 194
Spaho, Mehmed, 165
Stamboliiski, Aleksander, 67 William, Prince of Wied, 69
Stergiadis, Aristeidis, 114 Wilson, Woodrow, 69
Stojadinovic, Milan, 164 Wolf, Lucien, 108
Strang, William, 156
Yeltsin, Boris, 183
Trumbić, Ante, 165

Uzunović, Nikola, 166 Zog, King (also Ahmet Zogolli), 69,


157–161, 169
Vaida-Voevod, Aleksandar, 68 relations with Italy, 159–163
Subject Index

Abkhazia, 10 Anschluss, 162


Aboriginals, 28 Anti-Venizelist(s) 114
Accommodation, 1–4, 6, 17–19, 21–48, coalition, 117, 125–126
71–90, 92, 94, 97–99, 103–106, government, 115, 117
110–111, 123–124, 128, 130, 136, in Greek Macedonia, 115
139–140, 144, 155, 158, 166, Muslims, 125
174–180, 184–185, 187, 189–190, party 117, 125
192, 195, 198–199 political elites, 126
cost of, 23 rule, 68
of non-core groups supported by allies, vote, 125
10–11, 39 Apartheid, 22
Ottoman form of, 57, 171–172 Armenia, 8
in the Soviet Union, 31 Armenians, 1–2, 9, 121, 187, 194
as a transitional policy, 106 ASEAN (see Association of Southeast
Adriatic, 61, 143, 147, 154 Asian Nations)
Aegean Sea, 61, 64 Asia Minor, 33, 66, 68, 100, 110, 125,
African Union (AU), 10 127, 129, 132, 140, 189
Agreement of Moudania, 140 Assimilation, 2–7, 11–12, 17–27, 31,
Albania, 66, 104 36, 37–41, 44, 54, 57, 77–112,
Central, 69, 129 128, 130–133, 136–140, 144,
Southern, 92, 98, 100–101, 110 147–148, 153–154, 156, 159–160,
vassal state of Italy, 70 164, 169–173, 175, 178, 184–185,
Albanians, 64, 69, 94, 105, 127–128, 188, 190, 192, 194, 197–198,
138–139, 143–164 166–174 202, 204
Alliances through accommodation, 25, 37,
asymmetric, 30, 110–112, 105–110, 128, 137, 140, 175
179, 191 core group as target of, 27, 190
balancing, 25, 46, 47, 101 cost of, 23
bandwagoning, 46 as “cultural genocide,” 171
international alliance structure, 6, 30, escalates into conflict, 45
40, 47, 73, 188 through internal colonization, 37, 44,
symmetric, 30, 97, 110, 178, 180 84, 102, 153, 160
Anasselitsa (eparchy), 119, 127 linguistic, 59–60, 76–77, 139

248
Subject Index 249

nation-wide, 22 British support, 106


non-core groups without a homeland, Bulgaria, 1, 40–42, 54–56, 59–61, 63–67,
74, 80 69, 91, 94, 102, 111, 115, 117,
non-core groups not supported 135–136
by allies, 82 Bulgarian Exarchate, 55, 59, 130–131
non-core groups supported by allies, Burundi, 196
45–48, 82
rate of, 98 Caste, 7
in revisionist states, 73, 83 Caucasus, 66
in status quo states, 73, 84 CCP (see Chinese Communist Party)
subnational, 12, 97, 111–112 Cemiyet, 156, 158
targeting nomadic groups with, 79 Central Intelligence Agency (CIA), 43,
Assimilationist policies (see Assimilation) 175, 177
Association of Southeast Asian Nations Central Powers, 47, 67, 69, 91, 115,
(ASEAN), 10, 195, 198, 199 132, 140
AU (see African Union) Chad, 196
Australia, 28 China, 8, 13, 174–179, 197, 199
Austria, 91, 153–155, 162, 203 Chinese Communist Party (CCP),
Austria-Hungary, 9, 42, 47, 61, 63–64, 68, 176–177
69, 91, 107, 147–148, 154 (see also Christians
under World War I) Catholic, 94, 165, 201, 208
Autocephalous Christian Orthodox Orthodox, 9, 24, 55, 57, 59–60, 94,
Church of Albania, 105 121, 130, 137, 144, 168, 189, 201
Autocephalous Orthodox Church of slavic-speaking, 129–130
Greece, 105 Uniate, 207, 209
Azerbaijan, 8 CIA (see Central Intelligence Agency)
Co-ethnic(s), 11, 43, 73, 84–85
Bahrain, 31 avoiding assimilation, 95
Balfour Declaration, 109 becoming, 187
Balkan entente, 67, 91, 155, 162, 164 credible commitment to, 4, 20
Balkan peninsula, 53–56, 60–61, homelands as agitators of, 188
136, 201 in nearby states, 41
Balkan wars, 7, 10, 12, 41, 57, 63–66, non-core group presented as, 33
71–76, 91–94, 112–114, 116, potential, 137
121, 126–127, 129–130, 141, 148, protection of, 9
153, 192 redeeming, 114, 168
Baltic migration, 181 reprisals toward the, 57
Belgium, 8 retaliation on, 84
Berlin Conference of 1878, 60, 61 supporting, 32, 47, 87
Bessarabia, 68 “unredeemed,” 44, 56, 143
Beys, 125 Communism, 39
BFO (see British Foreign Office) Co-nationals, 22, 38
Big Four, 162 Congo, 196
Black Sea, 66 Constitutive myth, 27, 56
Bosnia, 9, 54, 55, 61, 63, 163, 174, 198 Core group, 3, 7, 11, 18–24, 26–27, 33,
Bosnia-Herzegovina, 166 36, 38, 41, 44, 48, 70–72, 76–78,
British Foreign Office (BFO), 91, 108 89, 92–94, 96, 129, 134, 138, 140,
British intervention, 101 169–170, 173–174, 189–190, 193,
British mediation, 100 203
250 Subject Index

Corfu Declaration (1917), 165 Epirus, 61, 64, 100–101, 110, 114, 193
Council of Europe, 185 Eritrea, 8
Crete, 54, 55, 63 Estonia, 13, 96, 174, 180–185
Cyprus, 8, 9 Ethnic cleansing, 4, 10, 18, 20, 42, 149,
Cyrenaica (Ottoman province), 63 174, 188, 190, 195, 197–198
Czechoslovakia, 25 Ethnicity, 7, 18, 32, 47–48, 168, 188,
198, 201
Devşirme system, 172 External involvement
“Divide and rule,” 12, 97, 102, 111, causation, 4, 5, 31–32
112, 203 clandestine, 5, 21, 32, 34, 45, 170
Dobrudja, 66 covert, 5, 21, 29, 31, 32, 34, 47, 73,
Dodecanese, 63, 100 140, 170
Donmeh, 55, 201 military intervention, 9–10, 73, 197
Duma, 183 mobilization, 47
non-core group allegiance, 28, 35, 170
East Timor, 8, 198 overt, 5, 21, 29, 32, 34, 45, 47, 73, 140
Eastern Crisis, 145 External support (see External
Eastern Question, 57–59, 61, 64 involvement)
Eastern Rumelia, 61 Eurasian Union, 199
Ecumenical Patriarchate of Istanbul, 105, European Union (EU), 10, 180, 198
130, 131, 202 Exclusion (see Exclusionary policies)
Edessa, 62, 134 Exclusionary policies, 1, 3, 9–11, 18,
Elites, 6, 72 (see also Ruling elite) 20–23, 25, 31, 36, 41–46, 57, 71,
Albanian, 69, 97, 169 73, 77, 80, 82, 85–86, 95, 97, 127,
assimilation of, 60 133, 140, 3-4, 145, 155, 164, 170,
Balkan, 59, 112 172, 174, 176, 183–184, 188,
core-group, 140, 173, 189 196–199
Estonian, 181, 183 EU (see European Union)
German Nationalist, 25
Greek, 121, 134 Fanariots, 172
Jewish, 108 Firman, 59–60
local, 154, 178, 193 Florina Prefecture, 113, 118
motivated by a homogenizing Foreign policy goals
imperative, 171 limited aims revisionist, 42
non-core group, 20, 22, 42, 44–45, 143, revisionist, 6, 36, 41–42, 48, 56, 70–71,
195, 202 73, 145, 154, 188
of “oppressed” groups, 202 status quo, 138, 143, 188 (see also
revisionist, 42, 97 Status quo)
Romanian, 103 France, 8, 47, 58, 109, 117, 147, 155,
Serbian, 68, 111, 143–145, 163, 162, 199
164, 168 Fustanela, 136
in states with a civic understanding of
nationhood, 4 Genocide
in states with an ethnic understanding of cultural, 171
nationhood, 4 Rwandan, 20
Uyghur, 176 Georgia, 8, 10, 31
Enlightenment, 48 Germany, 8, 24–25, 42, 47, 91,
Entente, 68–69, 108–109, 115, 117–118, 162, 199
125, 127, 131, 155, 162 Glasnost, 181
Subject Index 251

Globalization, 8, 195 Iran, 10, 31, 197, 199


Governing elites, 17, 72 (see also Ruling Iraq, 10, 26, 198
elites) Irredentism, 43
Great Britain, 42, 61, 91, 117, 155, 202 Albanian, 163
Great Powers, 1, 9, 13, 29, 33, 39, Greek, 61
42, 58–61, 69, 94, 138–139, 155, Serbian, 154
180, 195 variant of revisionism, 41
Greece (see also under World War I) Islam, 127, 144, 165, 201
Greek Ottoman War of 1897, 61 Israel, 8, 39
Greek War of Independence, 171–172 Italy, Lebensraum, 161 (see also under
Hellenism, 121, 126, 136 World War I)
Megali idea, 64
State of Siege Law, 127 Jews
Grevena (eparchy), 119, 134–135 assimilation, 97–99, 106
Gypsies, 111, 164 cultural organizations, 108–109
pogroms, 22, 108
Han, 175, 178 schools, 108
Hellenovlachoi, 136
Homeland, 4–5, 12, 20–21, 26, 37, Kaçaks/Kaçak movement, 151, 153–155,
48–49, 71–76, 80, 86, 106, 111, 158
115, 129, 133, 137, 140, 158, Italian support, 153–154
187–190 Albanian support, 153–154,
Host state 158–160
exclusion, 22–24, 179 suppressed, 169
perceived threats, 40 Kailaria, 119, 125, 136
Hungarians, 103–104 Kashmir, 10
Hutu, 20 Kastoria, 119, 134
Kazakhs, 177
Ideology, 47, 133 KGB, 180
nationalist, 7, 148 Khampas, 175
political, 92, 94 Kingdom of Serbia, 9, 143–144, 147, 153,
revisionist, 56 166, 193
Imam, 126 revisionist, 144
Immunization, 38 Kingdom of Serbs, Croats, and Slovenes
IMRO (see Internal Macedonian (KSCS), 12, 94, 103–104, 110, 143,
Revolutionary Organization) 153, 168
Inclusion, 7, 21, 27, 189–190, 202 Croatian autonomy, 160
India, 8, 10, 30, 61, 180, 199 interwar political parties, 66
Internal Macedonian Revolutionary law on the Protection of Public Order
Organization (IMRO), 67–68, 102 and the State, 167
International community Serb hegemony, 165
effect on nation-building choices, 132, Kingdom of Yugoslavia, 144, 159–161, 166
195–196 Banovinas, 161
Internment, of Japanese Americans, 8 Koniareoi, 121, 123, 124, 127–130, 162,
Interstate relations, alliances, 5, 6, 9, 12, 163, 164
29, 39–40, 48, 89, 101, 104, 112, Koran, 127
138–141, 148, 177–180, 188 (see also Koritsa, 134
specific alliances) Kosanica, 142, 145
Ioannina, 101 Kosova (vilayet), 59, 61, 146, 147, 150
252 Subject Index

Kosovo, 13, 64, 70, 100, 142–149, Magyars, 104


152–160, 162–164, 166–169, 174, Mali, 8
193, 196, 198 Maronites, 39
administrative split of, 154 Mass killing, 1–2, 20, 22, 187, 190, 194
annexation of, 153, 169 Member of Parliament (MP), 150
colonization effort in, 156, 162 Metohija, 142, 145
Committee for the National Defense Military intervention (see External
of, 155 involvement)
immigration of Serbs and Montenegrins, Millet system, 1, 9, 54, 57, 59, 60, 71, 129,
156–157 171, 172, 187, 201–202
interethnic relations in, 145 Minority (see also Non-core group), 27
Kaçak movement in, 154–155, 158 definition, 27
occupation by Bulgaria and interstate relations, 89, 104, 110–112
Austria-Hungary, 153 politics, 31, 189–191
occupation by Serbian forces, 145, 153 Mixed policies, 12, 72, 97, 102, 190
political exiles from, 155 Moldavia, 56
refugees from, 66 Monastir (vilayet), 33, 59, 110, 134, 152
secessionist movement in, 155 Moskopol, 134
Koumanoval, 150–151 Movement(s)
Koutsovlach, 134 Homegrown, 29, 35, 39–41, 46
Kozani Prefecture, 113, 117–119, 122 national, 35, 39, 59, 67, 143, 145, 148
Kurdistan, 10, 26 non-violent, 35
Kurds, 26, 196, 209 secessionist, 25, 31, 33, 39, 56–57, 74,
84–85, 95, 143, 155–158, 198
Lausanne Conference, 140 Mufti, 125
League of Nations, 92, 95, 101, 104–105, Mukhtars, 125
107, 108, 159, 162 Muslims, 55, 57, 61, 71, 80, 97, 99, 106,
Lebanon, 39 111–112, 115, 117, 119, 122,
125–129, 139, 148, 163–166
Macedonia, 57, 61, 91, 113–114, 117,
126–127, 130–134, 192–193 Napoleonic Wars, 30–33
Bulgaria’s claims in, 91 Nationalism, 7, 17, 20, 33, 38, 48, 55, 148,
central, 122 153, 188–189, 202
eastern, 64 age of, 7, 38, 55
former Yugoslav Republic, 174, 196 theories, 7, 17–20, 33–38, 48, 55
Front, 122 Nation-building (see also Nation-building
geographic, 33, 55, 59, 61, 64, 66, 115 policies)
Greek, 12–13, 66, 97, 102, 106, the Balkans, 53–67, 170–186
115, 117, 119, 120–122, 130, 132, causation, 9–13
137, 192 homeland group size, 3, 19–21, 48–49,
northwestern, 64 71–74, 84–87, 190
Romanian propaganda, 135 ideology, 7, 47, 92
southern, 61, 64 international alliances, 73–74, 91, 110,
Vardar, 168 112, 187–189
western, 12, 113–114, 117–119, international dynamics, 4, 21, 36–37, 199
122–125, 130–132, 138–139 state-planned, 3, 10, 98–100, 191–194,
Macedonian Struggle (1903–1908), 12, 202–204
75, 133, 137 Nation-building policies
Magyarization, 111 differences in language, 11
Subject Index 253

differences in religion, 9, 11, 71–73, 78 October Revolution, 47


to establish order, 35 Organization for Security and
logic behind, 3, 21, 194–198 Co-operation in Europe (OSCE),
methods of elite’s choosing, 23–24, 184–185
189–193, 204 Orthodox Christian, 9, 24, 55–60, 144,
national loyalty, 27, 41, 45, 168, 190 168, 201
size of group, 17, 24, 79–81, 86–89, 94 OSCE (see Organization for Security and
terminal vs. transitional policies, 105–110 Co-operation in Europe)
Nation-state, 2, 8, 18, 41, 55–57, 194–195 Ottoman Empire
National consciousness, 24, 33, 56–57, legacy in the Balkans, 1, 54–57, 82, 86
121, 127, 201–202 Orthodox patriarchy, 130, 171
fluid, 119–121 Ottomanism, 172
Greek, 133, 136 policies toward Armenians, 187–189
National Defense Revolutionary Russian support of Greeks of, 171–173
Government, 117, 135 war with Russia, 31, 57–61
National minority, 20, 27, 106–109, 134
National movement(s), 35–39, 67 Pakistan, 10
143–148 (see also Movement(s)) Palestinians, 39
National Slate Party, 117 Paris Peace Conference, Minorities
National type, 7, 24–27, 74, 119, 190 Treaty, 107
Nationalizing state, 20, 24, 74 Peloponnese, 31
NATO (see North Atlantic Treaty People’s Republic of China (PRC)
Organization) minority policy, 176–178
Nepal, 30, 180 nation-building, 174–177
“New ethnicists,” 18 non-core groups, 176–177
New Zealand, 28 Perestroika, 181
NGOs (see Non-governmental Pindus mountain range, 134–135
organizations) Poland, 31, 107
Non-core group Policy-makers, 183–184
demands, 28–29 Pomaks, 111–112
disloyal, 39–41, 43 Population exchange, 21–22, 84, 99–102,
ethnic kin, 37, 46, 66, 74, 140 106, 133, 136
external support, 29–35 PRC (see People’s Republic of China)
homeland, 4–5, 48–49, 73–80,134, Privilege, corporate, 11, 54, 119
187–190 Prizren League, 147
institutions, 22–23, 26
loyal, 22, 26, 40, 72–73 Radnitschke Novine, 151
nomadic, 26–28, 79, 86 Realist, 32–33
organization, 27–28 Realpolitik, 32–33
rural, 27–28, 56–57, 73, 79, 86 Refugees, 22, 41, 66, 68, 83, 141, 145,
urban, 75–79 150, 183
size, 74, 86–88, 190 “Revealed preferences problem,”
Non-governmental organizations (NGOs), 191–195
28, 190 Revisionist state(s), 6, 11, 41, 42, 48, 73,
Non-violent policies, 23, 75, 76, 83, 87, 89, 95, 99, 122, 141, 153,
189–190, 194 188, 198
North Atlantic Treaty Organization Romania, and World War I politics, 56,
(NATO), 8, 112, 184 68, 103–104, 135–139
Novi Pazar, 61, 163–164 Ruling elites (see Ruling political elites)
254 Subject Index

Ruling political elites, 7 ethnic Serbian consciousness in


with an ethnic understanding of Southeastern Serbia, 156, 174
nationhood, 4 Irredentism, 43, 154–158
foreign policy goals, 6, 41–42, 56 Serb-Albanian relations, 144–145, 156,
homogenizing imperative, 5, 24, 171, 158–162, 169
174, 185 Serbian army, 145, 147, 153, 193
nation-building choices, 18–23, 24, 27, Serbian elite’s attitude toward,
36, 38, 72–73, 78, 102, 167, 170, 144–145, 151
190, 202–204 Serbian elite’s foreign policy goals, 163,
reaction when threatened, 23, 184–185, 168–169
197 Serbian Orthodox Church, 167
revisionist, 182 Servia (eparchy), 119, 150–152
Russia(n), 46–47, 58, 61, 66, 108, Shar Mountains, 163
147–148, 158, 183, 196 (see also Sino-Soviet relations, 176
under World War I) Skenitai, 137
accommodation of, 199 Slav(s)
backing/support, 9, 55, 59, 91, 172 Bulgarian-leaning, 99, 102, 129–133,
conspiracy, 172 138–139, 151, 154, 173, 192
Diaspora policy, 180 Greek-leaning, 130, 133–134
Federation, 31, 181, 183, 199 Islamized, 144
foreign policy, 180, 183–184 Macedonian, 68, 97, 102, 154
hegemonic intentions, 199 majority territories, 64
Imperial, 9, 31, 39, 63 in South Serbia, 163
military forces, 181 -speaking Macedonians, 60
October Revolution, 47 -speaking Muslims, 168
Protectorate, 60 -speaking peasants, 55, 59
Sino-Soviet relations, 176 in Western Greek Macedonia, 192
Soviet, 20 Slavophone, 57
speakers, 174, 180–184 Slovakia, 8, 25
think-tanks, 183 Slovenes, 12, 66, 68, 94, 103–104, 110,
troops, 158, 180, 182 142–143, 153, 160, 165–167, 203
upper-secondary schools, 184 Smyrna, 118
Russo-Georgian War, 31 South Africa, 22, 199
Russo-Turkish Wars, 31, 57–61 South Ossetia, 8, 10, 31
Rwanda, 20, 196, 198 Spahis, Moroccan, 126
Sporazum Agreement, 168
Sarakatsans, 137–138, 202 State sovereignty, 10, 108, 195–196
Scapegoating, 171–173, 185–186 State capacity
Second Constituent Assembly absolute, 25
of Cretans, 121 relative, 25, 30
Security threat, 4, 8, 23, 26, Status quo, 36–38, 42–44, 48, 71, 83–84,
36–39, 145 95, 104, 188
Selanik (vilayet), 59 Sudan, 8, 196
Self-determination Sudeten Germans, 25
horizontal escalation, 196 Switzerland, 8, 164
human rights, 175, 185, 198 Syria, 10, 196
September 11, terrorist attacks of, 8
Serbia Tanzimat reform, 1, 58
Cemiyet organization (Serbia), 156 Tatars, 111
Subject Index 255

Thessaloniki, 61, 64, 107, 109, 113, 115, newspapers, 125


117–118, 135 party, 125
Thessaly, 61 political elites, 126
Thrace, 61, 66, 100, 110 Veroia, 134
Western, 64, 112 Vlachs
Eastern, 64, 114, 118, 140 Greek-leaning, 134, 136–137
Tibet, 10, 30, 43, 175–180 Italian-leaning, 135
Time horizon, 12, 42, 45, 97–101, 191 Muslim, 40, 55–57, 121, 202
Toplica, 142, 145 Romanian-leaning, 119, 134–138
Transylvania, 68, 103 Vojvodina, 104, 154, 166
Treaty of Bucharest (1913), 64, 74, 134–135
Treaty of London, 69 Wallachia, 56, 172
Treaty of Neuilly, 67, 99, 102, 132–133 Westphalian system, 48
Treaty of Rome, 198 World War I
Treaty of San Stefano, 61–62 Austria-Hungary, 9, 42, 47, 61, 63–64,
Treaty of Sevres, 118 68–69, 103, 153–154
Treaty of Trianon, 103 Greece, 97–100, 102, 113–115,
Tripolitania (Ottoman province), 63 128–129
Turkey, 10, 43, 56, 66, 92, 97–99, 141, Italy, 61, 69, 100, 135, 154–155,
162–164, 169, 194 159, 164
Turkification, 111 Russia, 9, 47, 55, 61, 63, 91, 147
Turkish National Movement, 67 World War II, 2, 8–9, 92, 164, 168–169,
173–174, 180–182, 184–185
Union of Soviet Socialist Republics, 8,
30–31, 33, 112, 176, 181–182 Xinjiang Uyghur Autonomous Region,
United Kingdom, 8, 30, 199 175–178
United Nations (UN), 10, 196
United States of America, 25, 30–31, Young Turk(s), 148
33, 46–47, 100, 174, 177–178 184, Revolution of 1908, 63
196, 199 Yugoslav Muslim Organization, 165
Üsküb (Skopje), 150–152 Yugoslav Parliament, 158
Uyghurs, 10, 175–176, 178–180 Yugoslavia, 110
National Question, 154, 163
Valaades, 127–128 northern borders of, 104
Venizelist(s), 115
coup, 68, 115 Zionism, 107
forces in Thessaloniki, 117 Zionist Action Committee, 107

You might also like