Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 71

Stopping High Inflation: An Analytical Overview

Author(s): Carlos A. Végh


Source: Staff Papers (International Monetary Fund), Vol. 39, No. 3 (Sep., 1992), pp. 626-695
Published by: Palgrave Macmillan Journals on behalf of the International Monetary Fund
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3867476
Accessed: 16-03-2016 13:14 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

International Monetary Fund and Palgrave Macmillan Journals are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and
extend access to Staff Papers (International Monetary Fund).

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
IMF Staff Papers

Vol. 39, No. 3 (September 1992)

© 1992 International Monetary Fund

Stopping High Inflation

An Analytical Overview

CARLOS A. VEGH*

The evidence on stopping high inflation is interpreted in terms of an

analytical framework. The evidence suggests that, by using the exchange

rate as the nominal anchor, hyperinflations have been stopped almost

overnight with relatively minor output costs. In contrast, exchange rate-

based stabilizations in chronic-inflation countries have typically resulted in

a sluggish adjustment of the inflation rate, sustained real appreciation of

the domestic currency, current account deficits, and an initial expansion

in economic activity followed by a contraction. These stylized facts are

shown to be consistent with the predictions of a staggered-prices, cash-in-

advance model. [JEL F41]

There is no subtler, no surer means of overturning the existing basis of

society than to debauch the currency. The process engages all the hidden

forces of economic law on the side of destruction and does it in a manner

which not one man in a million can diagnose.

-John Maynard Keynes (1920, p. 220)

FROM A HISTORICAL perspective, high inflation is a recent phenome-

non. Prior to World War I, episodes of high inflation were mainly

confined to the period of the assignats in France, the American War of

* Carlos A. V6gh is an Economist in the Research Department and holds a

Ph.D. from the University of Chicago. The author is grateful to Pierre-Richard

Agenor, Saul Lizondo, Peter Montiel, and, especially, Mohsin Khan, Carmen

Reinhart, and Ratna Sahay for helpful comments and suggestions. This paper has

greatly benefited from the author's joint work with Guillermo Calvo on inflation

stabilization.

626

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 627

Independence, and the Confederacy during the American Civil War (see

Capie (1986)). The historically rare occurrence of high inflation reflects

the prevalence of convertible currencies and commodity monies, which

put a natural lid on inflationary forces. In the aftermath of World War I,

however, hyperinflation burst onto the stage. Heavy disruptions and

reparation payments resulting from the war caused massive fiscal deficits

whose monetary financing led to hyperinflation in Austria, Germany,

Hungary, and Russia. Following World War II, hyperinflation erupted

once again in Hungary, Greece, and China. In 1985, Bolivia experienced

the first hyperinflation of the twentieth century not related to a foreign

war, civil war, or political revolution.

After World War II, when hyperinflation had already achieved notori-

ety, a much less dramatic, but equally ominous, phenomenon began to

emerge: chronic inflation. Some countries, particularly in Latin America,

began to endure high (relative to industrial countries) and persistent rates

of inflation, which in many instances have lasted up to the present day.

Argentina, for example, has suffered from chronic inflation since the late

1940s and has been unsuccessful in eliminating it, in spite of eight major

plans (two per decade) and countless other attempts. A similar story

could also be told for Brazil and Uruguay. There are, however, success

stories: Chile, Israel, and Mexico managed to reduce three-digit annual

inflation rates to about 20 percent during the 1980s. Although such levels

of inflation are still quite high by international standards, they are

viewed as a significant achievement, considering the resilience of chronic

inflation.

High inflation has proved to be fertile ground for researchers. Seminal

studies by Cagan (1956) and Sargent (1982) on hyperinflation, and Pazos

(1972) on chronic inflation have set the tone for much of the discussion.

A reading of the extensive literature suggests that theory and evidence

need to be further integrated to enhance our understanding of inflation

stabilization in high-inflation countries. With this in mind, this paper

interprets the main stylized facts associated with stopping hyperinflation

and chronic inflation in terms of a unified analytical framework.

The model used in this paper, based on Calvo and Vegh (1991a),

provides a simple and plausible explanation of the dynamics of stabiliza-

tion policy. The model relies on intertemporal substitution effects as the

key channel through which stabilization policies may have real effects,

along the lines of Calvo (1986). In addition, the presence of sticky prices

introduces dynamic considerations that are key to an understanding of

the outcome of inflation stabilization programs. Since programs designed

to stop high inflation have usually relied on the exchange rate as the

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
628 CARLOS A. VEGH

nominal anchor, the analysis will concentrate on exchange rate-based

stabilization.'

The discussion is organized around two analytical exercises, which are

used to interpret the evidence on stopping hyperinflation and chronic

inflation. The first exercise considers a reduction in the rate of devalua-

tion that is fully credible, in the sense that the public views the policy

change as permanent. Under these circumstances, inflation falls instan-

taneously without any output costs. Sticky prices do not prevent an

instantaneous adjustment because all price-setting behavior is assumed

to be forward looking. It is argued that the analytical exercise of a

permanent reduction in the rate of devaluation is, to a first approxima-

tion, relevant for interpreting the end of hyperinflation. The reasons are,

first, hyperinflationary processes appear to be characterized by the ab-

sence of backward-looking behavior; and, second, programs designed to

stop hyperinflation usually command high credibility given the unsustain-

able state of affairs. The evidence reviewed in the paper seems to bear

out the prediction that hyperinflation can be stopped abruptly and at

relatively small output costs, compared to those that would obtain in

low-inflation countries.

A second analytical exercise assumes that the reduction in the rate of

devaluation is not credible, in the sense that the public expects the higher

rate of devaluation to resume at some point in the future. The fall in the

nominal interest rate that results from the lower devaluation rate and

the assumption of perfect capital mobility is thus viewed as temporary.

Since the cash-in-advance constraint requires that money be used to

purchase goods, the opportunity cost of holding money is part of the

effective price of consumption. The temporary fall in the nominal interest

rate thus reduces the effective price of consumption in the present relative

to the future. Hence, demand for both traded and nontraded goods

increases and leads to an initial expansion in the nontraded goods sector

and a current account deficit. The slow convergence of inflation to the

rate of devaluation results in a sustained real appreciation of the domestic

currency, which ultimately reduces the demand for nontraded goods. As

a consequence, output falls and a recession sets in. The recession may

occur either before or when the program ends. The real effects caused

by a noncredible stabilization do not depend on whether the program is

eventually abandoned, as the public expected, or not.

It is argued that the analytical exercise of a noncredible reduction in

As discussed below, the 1985 Bolivian stabilization, characterized by a "dirty"

floating, is an exception to this rule. The exchange rate, however, stabilized

immediately and acted as a de facto nominal anchor.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 629

the rate of devaluation can be used to interpret inflation stabilization in

chronic-inflation countries, where a history of failed stabilizations, to-

gether with the ability of the economy to live with high inflation, makes

any attempt to stop inflation less than fully credible. The stylized facts

are generally consistent with the predictions of the model. In particular,

a boom-recession cycle has characterized both failed and successful sta-

bilizations, with the recession often setting in before the program ends

(see Kiguel and Liviatan (1992a)). Furthermore, the dynamic adjustment

predicted by the model, with U-shaped curves describing the behavior of

both inflation and the real exchange rate (defined as the relative price of

traded goods in terms of nontraded goods), is consistent with the stylized

facts. The inflation "inertia" exhibited by the model, in the sense that the

inflation rate remains above the devaluation rate, has been observed in

most programs.2

The paper proceeds as follows. Section I discusses the stylized facts

associated with stopping high inflation. Section II introduces the model

and analyzes the effects of a permanent reduction in the rate of devalu-

ation. Section III discusses the evidence on ending hyperinflation in light

of the model. Section IV examines a temporary reduction in the rate of

devaluation and matches the analytical results with the evidence on

stopping chronic inflation. Section V discusses the quantitative relevance

of the lack-of-credibility (or "temporariness") hypothesis and the role of

backward-looking behavior, and offers some concluding remarks.

I. Stylized Facts of High-Inflation Stabilization

This section first discusses the key differences between chronic in-

flation and hyperinflation, and then reviews the main stylized facts

associated with ending both hyperinflation and chronic inflation.

Hyperinflation Versus Chronic Inflation

For practical purposes, the term "hyperinflation" will be defined as in

Cagan's (1956) classic paper.3 At a conceptual level, it is useful to keep

in mind the distinction between "hyperinflation" and "chronic inflation,"

emphasized by Pazos (1972). Pazos (1972) argues that chronic inflation

2 It is worth emphasizing that, in the model, inflation "inertia" results from the

lack of credibility and not from backward-looking indexation.

3Cagan (1956, p. 25) defines hyperinflation "as beginning in the month the rise

in prices exceeds 50 percent and as ending in the month before the monthly rise

in prices drops below that amount and stays below for at least a year."

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
630 CARLOS A. VEGH

exhibits two key characteristics. First, it may last for long periods of time;

it is not measured in terms of months, as is the case of most hyperinfla-

tions, but in terms of years. Second, chronic inflation has an intermediate

intensity-higher than that of moderate inflation but much lower than

that of hyperinflation-which results from countries' learning how to live

with high and persistent inflation by creating various indexation mechan-

isms. Specifically, inflation does not have an inherent propensity to

accelerate, or if it does, soon reaches a new plateau. In hyperinfla-

tions, however, the rate of inflation oscillates freely, before accelerating

exponentially in the last six months or so.4

In order to illustrate the differences between chronic inflation and

hyperinflation, Table 1 shows annual inflation rates and money growth

rates during the last three decades for six Latin American countries

(Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Mexico, and Uruguay), Israel, and,

for comparison purposes, the United States. Beyond the general notion

of high and persistent inflation, there is no generally accepted definition

of chronic inflation. Moreover, any definition would probably not with-

stand the test of time, since the notion of what constitutes high inflation

changes over time.5

In spite of the lack of a clear definition of chronic inflation, some cases

are beyond dispute. Countries such as Argentina, Brazil,and Uruguay

would be classified as chronic-inflation countries under any sensible

definition. In all three countries, average annual inflation has been above

20 percent in all three decades (Table 1).6 Argentina has had triple-digit

inflation since 1975 (with the exception of 1986, when, as the result of

the Austral Plan, inflation fell to 90.1 percent). Uruguay's inflation has

been above 30 percent since 1972 (with the exception of 1982, when, as

4Pazos (1972, p. 19), commenting on the inflation rate during the German

hyperinflation, points out that "oscillations were so large and so erratic that the

chart [of the inflation rate] seems to register the movements of an object that has

been let loose in a frictionless environment and is reacting, without offering

resistance, to the external forces being applied to it."

5 In Argentina, for instance, inflation rates of close to 30 percent in the mid-

1960s were viewed as intolerable, prompting the 1967 stabilization plan, which

brought inflation down to 7.6 percent in 1969. By today's standards, such rates

would still provoke uneasiness but would certainly not be looked upon as unac-

ceptable. Changes in public perception about inflation are not merely confined

to developing countries. In the United States, for instance, inflation rates of

around 5 percent, which are viewed with complacence today, prompted the Nixon

administration to impose price controls in August 1971.

6 In particular, note that in these three countries, with one exception (Argen-

tina in 1969, as a result of the 1967 stabilization plan), inflation has never fallen

to single digits in the last three decades. In contrast, in the United States inflation

has been below 10 percent in all but four years since 1961.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION
631

a result of the 1978 stabilization program, inflation fell to 19 percent), and

above 50 percent since 1984.7 As one would expect-and as the averages

presented at the bottom of Table 1 clearly suggest-the proximate cause

of inflation was high money growth. Massive money printing, in turn,

resulted from the need to finance chronic budget deficits.

Chile, Israel, and Mexico provide cases in which, after reaching three-

digit figures, chronic inflation was successfully stopped. During the 1960s

and 1970s, inflation in Chile was not much different from that in Ar-

gentina, Brazil, and Uruguay. However, as a result of the stabilization

plan of 1978, inflation fell to 9.9 percent in 1982, and averaged 20.3

percent during 1981-90. In contrast, Israel and Mexico were low-inflation

countries during the 1960s, with Mexico experiencing the same inflation

rate as the United States. During the 1970s inflation unraveled and soon

reached three-digit figures. Both the Israeli stabilization plan of July 1985

and the Mexican program of December 1987 brought inflation down to

around 20 percent where it has remained ever since.

The inflationary processes in the six countries just reviewed (Ar-

gentina, Brazil, Chile, Israel, Mexico, and Uruguay) exhibit the main

characteristics of chronic inflation suggested by Pazos (1972). As already

noted, inflation has been high and persistent. Moreover, inflation does

not have an inherent propensity to accelerate, as best exemplified by the

case of Uruguay, where inflation has been remarkably stable in the last

30 years. When inflation does accelerate, it soon reaches a new plateau.

In Argentina, for instance, inflation accelerated in 1975 to triple-digit

figures and remained there for 11 years. In Israel, after 9 years of

double-digit figures, inflation jumped to triple-digit figures in 1980 and

remained there for 6 years, until the 1985 stabilization plan.

Bolivia provides an excellent example of the explosive nature of hyper-

inflation. In contrast to the other six countries, Bolivia is certainly not

a chronic-inflation country. Annual inflation averaged only 5.5 percent

during the 1960s, and was below 10 percent in all but four years during

1961-77. By the end of the 1970s, however, political instability led to high

inflation. In 1982 inflation jumped to 123.5 percent, as the debt crisis cut

short the inflow of foreign credit and forced the government to resort to

monetary financing. High inflation skyrocketed into hyperinflation,

reaching 62.7 percent a month in April 1984. Hyperinflation thus started

7 Long periods of chronic inflation may eventually lead to hyperinflation: the

monthly inflation rate reached 76.5 percent in Argentina in May 1989, and 51.5

percent in Brazil in December 1989. However, these hyperinflationary outbursts,

which represent an explosive stage of a long period of chronic inflation, have

different characteristics from the traditional hyperinflations studied below (see

Kiguel and Liviatan (1992b)).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Table 1. Inflation and Money Growth in Selected Countries

(In percent per year)

Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Israel Mexico Uruguay United States >

Infla- Infla- Infla- Infla- Infla- Infla- Infla- Infla-

tion M1 tion M1 tion M1 tion M1 tion M1 tion M1 tion M1 tion Ml c1

Year rate growth rate growth rate growth rate growth rate growth rate growth rate growth rate growth >

1961 13.4 -7.3 7.6 18.4 33.4 51.2 7.7 ... 6.8 11.1 1.6 6.8 22.7 22.1 1.1 3.4 <

1962 28.3 8.9 5.9 12.1 51.8 61.9 14.0 28.9 9.4 30.0 1.2 13.2 10.9 -3.1 .1 6 0

1963 23.9 28.6 -0.7 19.6 70.1 64.4 44.1 34.1 6.6 23.1 0.6 16.1 21.3 29.0 1.2 4.2 a

1964 22.2 39.9 10.2 20.7 91.9 84.6 46.0 51.1 5.2 13.8 2.3 17.6 42.4 42.0 1.3 4.5

1965 28.6 25.5 2.9 17.5 65.7 76.6 28.8 21.1 7.7 16.7 3.6 5.7 56.6 102.7 1.7 4.7

1966 31.9 35.0 7.0 22.3 41.3 15.8 23.1 89.8 7.9 14.3 4.2 12.2 73.5 39.4 3.0 2.4

1967 29.2 62.7 11.2 3.3 30.5 42.6 18.7 24.9 1.7 25.0 3.0 9.2 89.3 111.2 2.8 6.5

1968 16.2 24.9 5.5 8.0 22.0 42.5 26.3 38.0 2.1 10.0 2.3 14.2 125.3 53.7 4.2 7.3

1969 7.6 21.3 2.2 5.8 22.7 28.7 30.4 35.5 2.4 9.1 3.4 15.0 21.0 61.2 5.4 3.3

1970 13.6 6.5 3.8 12.6 22.4 26.7 32.5 65.5 6.1 8.3 5.2 10.7 16.3 14.4 5.9 5.4

1971 34.7 13.5 3.7 15.2 20.1 32.4 20.0 112.2 12.0 23.1 5.3 7.6 24.0 54.0 4.3 6.6

1972 58.4 65.0 6.5 25.2 16.6 28.3 74.8 154.3 12.9 248.0 5.0 17.9 76.5 46.8 3.3 9.3

1973 61.2 72.7 31.5 34.3 12.7 47.5 361.5 322.6 20.0 33.2 12.0 22.4 97.0 80.0 6.2 5.2

1974 23.5 57.9 62.8 43.4 27.6 34.5 504.7 266.0 39.7 17.5 23.8 20.7 77.2 64.2 11.0 4.3

1975 182.9 211.1 8.0 11.8 29.0 44.4 374.7 256.0 39.3 22.0 15.2 21.4 81.4 42.3 9.1 4.9

1976 444.0 275.0 4.5 36.5 42.0 36.7 211.8 256.0 31.4 26.9 15.8 29.1 50.6 65.5 5.7 6.7

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1977 176.0 115.2 8.1 20.9 43.7 38.1 91.9 86.7 34.6 38.8 29.0

1978 175.5 159.7 10.4 12.4 38.7 36.1 40.1 76.7 50.6 44.0 17.5

1979 159.5 137.8 19.7 16.7 52.7 74.9 33.4 61.7 78.3 31.6 18.2

1980 100.8 96.7 47.2 42.6 82.8 69.7 35.1 53.8 131.0 96.7 26.4

1981 104.5 70.1 32.1 19.7 105.6 82.6 19.7 -5.2 116.8 91.3 27.9

1982 164.8 247.5 123.5 228.8 97.8 68.5 9.9 12.1 120.4 109.2 58.9

1983 343.8 362.0 275.6 207.0 142.1 102.7 27.3 22.3 145.6 140.8 101.8

1984 626.7 501.6 1,281.4 1,798.3 197.0 204.1 19.9 15.4 373.8 352.3 65.5

1985 672.1 571.5 11,749.6 5,784.6 226.9 334.3 30.7 13.8 304.6 245.7 57.7

1986 90.1 84.8 276.3 86.1 145.2 330.1 19.5


44.8 48.1 112.8 86.2

1987 131.3 124.7 14.6 39.9 229.7 215.4 19.9 6.6 19.8 49.5 131.8

1Y98 J4J.U J33/.Y 16.U 35.3 682.3 570.3 14.7 68.2 16.3 11.3 114.2 67.8 62.2 64.3 4.0 5.8

1989 3,079.8 4,096.2 15.2 2.4 1,287.0 1,384.2 17.0 14.5 20.2 44.4 20.0 37.3 80.4 72.8 4.8 1.5 O

1990 2,314.0 1,070.5 17.1 39.5 2,937.8 2,335.7 26.0 17.2 17.2 30.6 26.7 63.1 112.5 101.2 5.4 3.6

1991 171.7 ... 21.4 45.1 440.8 328.2 21.8 51.5 19.0 13.7 22.7 122.5 102.0 99.3 4.2 8.2 z

Annual Averages

1961-70 21.2 23.2 5.5 13.9 43.5 48.0 28.9a 41.8" 5.6 3.7 2.7 12.0 44.0 43.4 2.8 4.3 S

1971-80 119.5 108.6 18.8 25.4 35.3 43.5 130.3 147.6 41.6 48.9 16.5 24.4 62.7 59.0 7.8 6.7 :

1981-90 437.6 400.4 222.7 204.2 337.1 339.8 20.3 19.5 91.2 99.6 65.1 58.4 60.6 55.9 4.7 7.2 Z

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except for 1988-91 Ml figures for Brazil, from Central Bank ;

of Brazil.

aAverages are for 1962-70. o

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CARLOS A. VEGH
634

less than two years after annual inflation reached three-digit levels. It

lasted 18 months and was stopped by the September 1985 stabilization.

From 1987-91 annual inflation averaged 16.9 percent.8

The explosive nature of the inflationary process in hyperinflation is also

clear from other historical episodes. In Germany, for instance, annual

inflation averaged only 1.8 percent between 1900 and 1913. In July 1914,

one month before the outbreak of World War I, note convertibility was

suspended to prevent further losses of gold reserves. During the war

(1914-18), annual inflation averaged 25.2 percent. In 1919 inflation

jumped to 226.4 percent and, after slowing down to 79.3 percent in 1920

and 142.4 percent in 1921, climbed to a monthly rate of 89 percent a

month in August 1922. The hyperinflation lasted 17 months and came to

an abrupt end in January 1924. Annual inflation averaged 3.8 percent

during 1925-29.9 10

Stopping Hyperinflation: Stylized Facts

Hyperinflations offer a fascinating laboratory for the study of mone-

tary phenomena.l Astronomical rates of inflation serve to isolate many

aspects of reality, which, under normal conditions, are likely to be ob-

scured by other considerations. For further reference, it is useful to list

the hyperinflations (and subsequent stabilizations) that will be referred

to in this paper.

* The post-World War I European hyperinflations: Austria (October

1921-August 1922), Germany (August 1922-November 1923), Hungary

(March 1923-February 1924), Poland (January 1923-January 1924), and

8 In all four successful stabilizations (Chile, Bolivia, Israel, and Mexico), annual

inflation has remained around 20 percent, still well above inflation in the United

States, which averaged 4.7 percent during the 1980s. The reasons why inflation

has failed to come down to international levels remain unclear.

9 Annual data from 1900 to 1913 (for a cost of living index) are from Mitchell

(1975). Annual data from 1914 onwards (for wholesale prices) are from Bresciani-

Turroni (1937).

10 As suggested above, Pazos (1972) associates high oscillations of the inflation

rate with hyperinflationary periods. In effect, the evidence suggests that there is

a positive correlation between the mean and the standard deviation of monthly

inflation, so that the standard deviation is highest during hyperinflations (see

Vegh (1991)).

T The world's record inflation, according to Cagan (1989), occurred in Hungary

after World War II, when prices rose by an average monthly rate of 19,800 percent

between August 1945 and July 1946, and 4.2 x 1016 percent in the peak month

of July.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION
635

Russia (December 1921-January 1924).12 The common theme in these

episodes is how hyperinflation was successfully brought under control by

the introduction of drastic fiscal reforms, giving central banks greater

independence and restoring (or virtually restoring) convertibility of the

domestic currency in terms of the dollar or gold, as emphasized by

Sargent (1982) in his paper on the hyperinflations in Austria, Germany,

Poland, and Hungary.

* The post-World War II European hyperinflations: Hungary (August

1945-July 1946) and Greece (November 1923-December 1945).13 The

Hungarian stabilization fits the pattern identified by Sargent (1982) of

drastic reforms that achieve immediate price stability. In contrast, the

Greek stabilization was a more diffuse process, since it took the govern-

ment over a year and three attempts to finally put the required measures

in place.

* The Taiwanese hyperinflation (1945-49).14 The interesting feature of

this episode, which has not achieved the fame of its European counter-

parts, is that, according to Makinen and Woodward (1989), stabilization

apparently took place not only without any fiscal adjustment, but, more

important, with no prospects of any future fiscal adjustment. It was only

in mid-1952 that massive aid from the United States helped in balancing

the budget.

* The Bolivian hyperinflation (April 1984-September 1985).15 The key

components of the stabilization program were a drastic fiscal correction,

unification of exchange rates, and a return to full convertibility-capital

controls had been in place since late 1982. Unlike other hyperinflations

referred to above, which were based on a fixed exchange rate, the

exchange rate system in Bolivia during the stabilization plan is best

characterized as a dirty float.16 However, when the exchange rate markets

12 Dates in parentheses indicate the hyperinflationary period. These episodes

have been studied by, among many others, Cagan (1959), Dornbusch and Fischer

(1986), Rostowski (1992), Sargent (1982), Wicker (1986), and Yeager (1981). See

also Vegh (1991) and the references therein.

13On Hungary, see Bomberger and Makinen (1983) and Siklos (1989); on

Greece, see Makinen (1984). The end of the Greek hyperinflation, December

1945, differs from Cagan's (1956) date of November 1944, because inflation fell

below 50 percent a month only until August 1945.

14 All references to Taiwan for the period 1945-52 are to Taiwan Province of

China. This hyperinflation was separate from the one taking place in mainland

of China, since Taiwan constituted a separate currency area.

15 See Sachs (1986) and Morales (1988). Table 4 in the Appendix contains the

main macroeconomic variables.

16 Private agents were allowed to buy and sell foreign exchange freely, but the

central bank would sell foreign exchange to the public in a daily auction and buy

foreign exchange at the average price fixed in the last auction. For each auction,

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CARLOS A. VEGH
636

were unified, the official exchange rate depreciated by 1,600 percent in

one day, thus eliminating the parallel market premium practically

overnight. The exchange rate stabilized immediately after this initial

adjustment, providing a de facto anchor to the system.

For the purposes here, two main stylized facts regarding hyperinflation

stabilization need to be emphasized:17 (1) inflation is stopped immedi-

ately; and (2) output costs are relatively small.

(1) Inflation stops abruptly. In most instances, price stability was

virtually achieved overnight following exchange rate stabilization.'8 To

illustrate this point, Table 2 shows monthly averages for the rates of

devaluation and inflation 12 months before and 12 months after the ex-

change rate was stabilized in eight hyperinflations (Austria, Poland, Ger-

many, Greece, Hungary after each World War, Bolivia, and Taiwan).19

The figures clearly show how anchoring the exchange rate can ensure a

swift return to price stability. The most dramatic examples are Hungary

1946 and Germany, where the monthly inflation rate in the 12 months

before stabilization averaged 19,800 percent and 455.1 percent, respec-

tively. After stabilization, the monthly average dropped to 1.3 percent

and 0.3 percent, respectively. In more moderate hyperinflations, such as

Hungary after World War I where monthly inflation averaged 33.3 per-

cent before stabilization, the same phenomenon of overnight price stabil-

ity took place. Even when price stability was not fully achieved, as in

Bolivia and Taiwan, the drop in inflation was substantial. Not sur-

prisingly, in Bolivia and Taiwan, the exchange rate did not stabilize

completely.20

In summary, the evidence clearly suggests that in hyperinflationary

situations, price stability can be the immediate result of using the ex-

change rate as the nominal anchor. As discussed in Section III, during

hyperinflation virtually all prices are indexed to the dollar or, which

the central bank would fix both a base price at which it would sell foreign

exchange and the amount that it would offer; bidders would not have access to

this information beforehand.

17The discussion focuses on those aspects that are the most relevant for the

discussion of the theoretical model in the next section.

'8 With the exception of Bolivia (see the above discussion), the exchange rate

was generally stabilized by fixing the value of the domestic currency in terms of

gold or a foreign currency.

19 For the Polish, Greek, and Taiwanese stabilizations, slightly different periods

had to be considered because of insufficient data.

20 In the Taiwanese stabilization, the black market rate stood 60 percent above

the official rate six months after stabilization (see Makinen and Woodward

(1989)).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 637

Table 2. Devaluation, Inflation, and Money Growth in Hyperinflations

(In percent a month)

Devaluation Inflation Money

Country Rate Rate Growth

Austria (October 1922)

October 1921-September 1922 32.6 46.0 35.7

October 1922-September 1923 -0.4 0.4 8.7

Poland (February 1924)

February 1923-January 1924 63.7 66.2 62.7

February 1924-November 1924 0.8 1.2 11.1

Greece (February 1946)

February 1945-January 1946 27.0 31.6

February 1946-December 1946 -0.8 13.4

Taiwan (June 1949)

30.7 23.7
January 1948-May 1949

6.7 11.4
June 1949-December 1950

Germany (January 1924)

409.8 455.1 419.7


January 1923-December 1923

0.3 12.0
-3.9
January 1924-December 1924

Hungary (April 1924)

28.0 33.3 28.1


April 1923-March 1924

0.0 0.2 8.5


April 1924-March 1925

Hungary (August 1946)

August 1945-July 1946 19,800.0 12,200.0

... 1.3 14.2


August 1946-July 1947

Bolivia (October 1985)

44.0 57.6 48.5


October 1984-September 1985

4.9 5.7 8.3


October 1985-September 1986

Sources: Austria, Germany, and Hungary 1924: Sargent (1982); Poland: Sar-

gent (1982) and Llach (1990); Greece: Makinen (1984); Hungary 1946: Cagan

(1956) and Bomberger and Makinen (1983); Taiwan: Makinen and Woodward

(1989); and Bolivia: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues), and

Morales (1988).

Note: The date in parentheses following the country name indicates the month

in which the exchange rate stabilized. Money refers to notes in circulation, except

in Bolivia and Taiwan where it indicates M1.

amounts to the same thing, quoted in dollars; hence, stabilizing the

exchange rate is tantamount to achieving price stability.21

(2) Output costs are relatively small. Although this second stylized fact

is certainly more controversial than the first one, a review of the evidence

21 Naturally, this assertion should not be taken to mean that stabilizing the

exchange rate is sufficient to ensure lasting price stability. If permanent fiscal

measures are not taken, inflation may resume shortly. In the Greek stabilization,

for instance, the successful stabilization of January 24, 1946 was preceded by two

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
638 CARLOS A. VEGH

suggests that hyperinflations have been stopped with small output costs

compared to those that would have resulted from stopping inflation in

low-inflation countries.22 There are two key difficulties in assessing the

output effects of stopping hyperinflation. First, available data are usually

sparse and unclear. Second, the real effects of stabilization per se are

difficult to disentangle from the real dislocations that characterize the

transition from hyperinflation to price stability. Moreover, in the Euro-

pean hyperinflations following the two World Wars, the effects of the war

itself and the burden of heavy reparations payments have also tended to

blur the picture.

Of the nine hyperinflations listed above (Tables 3a-3g present data for

seven episodes), economic activity appears to have increased following

stabilization in three cases-Germany, Greece, and Russia. In Germany

the per capita index of industrial production rose substantially in 1924-

the year following stabilization-from the depressed level of 1923 that

had resulted mainly from the French occupation of the Ruhr and the

policy of passive resistance. The rate of unemployment also decreased

substantially from its peak of 23.6 percent in the fourth quarter of 1923,

to 3.8 percent in the second quarter of 1925. In the summer of 1925,

a recession set in. Garber (1982) attributes this recession not to the

monetary stabilization per se, but rather to a reallocation of industry,

as the capital goods sector had been heavily subsidized during the hyper-

inflation.

In Greece the sparse available evidence seems to suggest that there

were no output costs. In fact, as Table 3b shows, national income in-

creased after the stabilization, and unemployment apparently de-

creased.23 In Russia, Rostowski (1992) reports that the economy con-

tinued to grow strongly after stabilization: industrial output increased by

about 30 percent in 1923-24, with higher growth concentrated after

stabilization (the reforms took place in February and March 1924), and

by about 45 percent in 1924-25.

In two cases-Taiwan and Bolivia-there appear to be no costs asso-

ciated with stabilization. In Taiwan, Makinen and Woodward (1989)

failed attempts to stabilize (in November 1944 and June 1945). Inflation fell

drastically immediately after the first two attempts (for two to four months), but

came back with a vengeance shortly thereafter (see Makinen (1984)). In Poland,

there were also two failed stabilizations before the successful January 1924 plan

(see Yeager (1981)).

22 Sargent (1982) has been the chief proponent of this idea. The most influential

dissenters are probably Garber (1982) and Wicker (1986).

23 It is not clear whether the figures on unemployed reported in Table 3b are

comparable; see Makinen (1984).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 639

Table 3a. Real Effects of Stopping Hyperinflations: Germany (January 1924)

Index of Per Capita

Unemployment Industrial Productiona

Year/Quarter Rate (1913 = 100)

1920:1 .

2 ...

3 ...

4 ... 61

1921:1 .

2 ...

3 ...

4 ... 77

1922:1 .

2 ...

3 ...

4 ... 86

1923:1 5.0

2 5.8

3 6.6

4 23.6 54

1924:1 22.7

2 9.8

3 11.8

4 7.9 77

1925:1 7.1

2 3.8

3 4.2

4 12.0 90

1926:1 22.0

2 18.3

3 16.5

4 15.0 86

1927:1 14.5

2 7.4

3 5.0

4 8.3 111

Source: Garber (1982).

Note: In Tables 3a-3g, the date in parentheses following the country name

indicates the month in which the exchange rate stabilized.

a Annual data.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
640 CARLOS A. VEGH

Table 3b. Real Effects of Stopping Hyperinflations: Greece (February 1946)

Real

Number of National Income

Year Unemployed (Percent change)

1945 ... 5.5

1946 197,000a 62.1

1947 122,000b 33.9

Source: Makinen (1984).

a Summer 1946.

bDecember 31, 1947.

Table 3c. Real Effects of Stopping Hyperinflations: Bolivia (October 1985)

Unemployment Real GDP

Year Rate (Percent change)

1980 5.8 0.6

1981 9.7 1.0

1982 10.9 -4.4

1983 13.0 -4.5

1984 15.5 -0.6

1985 18.0 -1.0

1986 20.0 -2.5

1987 20.5 2.6

1988 18.0 3.0

1989 25.0 2.8

Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues), and Ministry of

Labor.

report small, if any, costs after stabilization. The unemployment rate

increased only slightly even though Taiwan was forced to absorb nearly

a half million mainlanders early in the stabilization. National income kept

growing at positive rates, albeit less rapidly than during hyperinflation.24

In Bolivia the stabilization plan in and of itself does not seem to have had

much impact on the real sector. As shown in Table 3c, real gross domestic

product (GDP) had been falling and unemployment rising since the early

1980s, as a result of internal political chaos and the onset of the debt crisis.

There is no apparent reason why this negative trend should have ended

in 1985-86. Moreover, the Bolivian economy suffered severe external

shocks in late 1985 and 1986: the terms of trade deteriorated substantially

as international prices of tin and hydrocarbons collapsed; sales of natural

24Makinen and Woodward (1989) argue that growth before stabilization was

artificially high due to the large-scale reconstruction after World War II and the

use of the inflation tax to expand state enterprises and give subsidized loans.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION
641

Table 3d. Real Effects of Stopping Hyperinflations: Austria (October 1922)

Unemployment Real GNP

Year Rate (Percent change)

1921 ... 10.7

1922 ... 9.0

1923 ... -1.1

1924 5.6 11.7

1925 6.3 6.8

1926 7.0 1.6

1927 6.2 3.1

Source: Wicker (1986).

Table 3e. Real Effects of Stopping Hyperinflations: Hungary (August 1946)

Index of

Production
Unemployment

Year/Month
(1946:1 = 100)
Ratea

1946 January
100.0

February
103.0

March
104.7

April
111.2

May
134.8

June
115.1

July
128.7

August
136.5
5.0

September 136.5

October
154.2

November
157.2

December
141.5
5.0

1947 January
141.3

February

March
7.9

April
114.7

May
122.3

June
125.8

July
125.7

August 130.8
8.6

September 151.5

October
173.8

November
,..

December
...
11.5

Source: Siklos (1989).

aData not available on a regular monthly basis.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
642 CARLOS A. VEGH

Table 3f. Real Effects of Stopping Hyperinflations: Poland (February 1924)

Unemployment

Year Rate

1922 1.2

1923 1.0

1924 5.6

1925 12.7

1926 8.5

1927 6.7

Source: Wicker (1986).

Table 3g. Real Effects of Stopping Hyperinflations: Hungary (April 1924)

Unemployment

Year/Quarter Rate

1924:1 7.7

2 8.8

3 10.1

4 12.6

1925:1 14.5

2 13.3

3 9.5

4 10.8

1926:1 11.3

2 9.7

3 7.3

4 7.9

Source: Wicker (1986).

gas to Argentina fell significantly; and large disruptions resulted from a

campaign to curtail illegal drug trade. According to Sachs (1986), a

conservative estimate would put the export revenue loss at 10-15 percent

of gross national product (GNP) in one year. In 1987 real GDP began

to increase again, even if at a slow rate.

In two other cases-Austria and Hungary in 1946-there appears to

be conflicting evidence. In Austria the number of unemployed increased

following the stabilization of September 1922, peaking in February 1923,

although it had started to increase even before stabilization. According

to estimates provided by Wicker (1986), the unemployment rate peaked

in 1926 at 7 percent (Table 3d). Assuming unemployment to be 3 percent

in 1921, he concluded that the rise in unemployment of 4 percentage

points could be attributed to the stabilization. In contrast, the behavior

of real GNP tells a somewhat different story. After increasing by 9

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 643

percent in 1922 (the stabilization took place in September), real GNP fell

by 1.1 percent in 1923, but rose by 11.7 and 6.8 percent in 1924 and 1925,

respectively.25

In Hungary 1946 the unemployment rate began to increase in the first

quarter of 1947 (the stabilization took place in August 1946), and reached

11.5 percent in December 1947 (Table 3e).26 In contrast, national income

rose by 20 percent in the 12 months following stabilization. Industrial

production increased by 9.8 percent in the six months following stabiliza-

tion. After falling somewhat in the first quarter of 1947, it increased again

and, in October 1947, was 35 percent above the prestabilization level.

Reinforcing the evidence in favor of very small output costs, studies

reported in Siklos (1989) by the Hungarian Institute of Economic Re-

search concluded that in 1946-47, GDP was only 0.1 percent lower

relative to the business cycle peak of 1928-29 and 50 percent higher

relative to the business cycle trough year of 1932-33.

In the last two cases-Poland and Hungary in 1924-according to

estimates reported by Wicker (1986), the unemployment rate rose sub-

stantially, reaching a peak of 12.7 percent in Poland during 1925 (Table

3f) and 14.5 percent in the first quarter of 1925 in Hungary (Table 3g).

In Poland, however, even though the number of unemployed increased

after the January 1924 stabilization, the level reached in December

(159,060) was no worse than before the stabilization (the number of

unemployed peaked in January 1922 at 221,444).

In summary, of the nine episodes, available evidence suggests that

there were no output costs resulting from monetary stabilization per se

in five (Germany, Greece, Russia, Taiwan, and Bolivia); there is conflict-

ing evidence for two (Austria and Hungary in 1946), since both unem-

ployment and economic activity increased; and unemployment increased

in two (Poland and Hungary in 1924; output data are not avalable in

either case).

In sharp contrast, the real costs of disinflation in industrial countries

are estimated to be substantial.27 For instance, according to Gordon

25Layton and Rist (1925) suggested that the explanation for the conflicting

behavior of output and unemployment in Austria during the winter of 1924-25

lay in the incentives to achieve greater efficiency provided by price stability.

Specifically, firms could not pass on increases in costs in the form of higher prices

and thus had an incentive to shed labor to become more efficient. Layton and

Rist (1925, pp. 16-17) concluded that "reorganization in the factories is thus the

chief explanation of the apparent anomaly that unemployment has increased side

by side with a steady improvement in economic activity."

6Beginning in March 1947, Hungary began to move to a centrally planned

system (in October 1948, the first three-year plan was introduced). Hence, figures

for 1948 and beyond are not comparable.

27 As discussed below, inflation stabilization in chronic-inflation countries also

leads to sizable real effects.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CARLOS A. VEGH
644

(1982, p. 39), in the United States (in the period after 1922), there is

"abundant evidence that only 10 to 40 percent of nominal demand

changes are absorbed by the inflation rate in the first year after such

changes." This implies that a deceleration in nominal spending growth

from 10 percent to zero would result in a fall in inflation of only 1-4

percent and a corresponding drop in real output from 9 percent to

6 percent. Gordon (1982) argued that this basic message holds true for

other industrialized countries.

An alternative way of looking at the costs of disinflation is to estimate

the "sacrifice ratio," or cumulative percent output loss per percentage

point reduction in inflation. Estimates for the United States lie anywhere

from 3 to 18 (Sachs (1985)). The evidence, therefore, seems to warrant

the conclusion that hyperinflations have been stopped at relatively small

cost compared to low-inflation countries.28 As discussed in Section III,

the fact that in hyperinflations backward-looking contracts (so prevalent

in industrial and chronic-inflation countries) disappear is probably at the

heart of the difference in output costs.

Stopping Chronic Inflations: Stylized Facts

The ten episodes of stabilization in chronic inflation countries that

serve as background for the theoretical discussion can be divided as

follows.29

* Latin American heterodox programs of the 1960s. This group com-

prises stabilization plans in Argentina (March 1967), Brazil (March 1964),

and Uruguay (June 1968) (see Tables 5-7 in the Appendix).30 The com-

mon elements of these plans were, first, a fixed exchange rate (with

periodic devaluations in Brazil) as the main nominal anchor; and second,

the use of incomes policies in varying degrees. Whereas price controls

28 Of course, in making this comparison one would like to take into account the

fact that unlike inflationary periods in industrialized countries, output during

hyperinflations is likely to have been well below potential.

Tables 5 through 14 in the Appendix contain the main macroeconomic

indicators for each episode. Subject to data availability, the same variables are

reported in all episodes to facilitate comparisons.

Dates refer to month of implementation of the programs. On the Uruguayan

1968 stabilization plan, see Finch (1979) and Viana (1990). The Brazilian 1964

plan is discussed by Kafka (1967), Pazos (1972), and Foxley (1980). The Argentine

stabilization of 1967 is discussed by De Pablo (1974). Another heterodox program

of interest in Argentina is the Peronist stabilization of 1973-1975 (see Di Tella

(1989)).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION
645

were mainly voluntary in Argentina and Brazil, in Uruguay there was a

comprehensive freeze similar to that of the heterodox programs of the

mid-1980s. All three programs achieved an initial decline in inflation.

However, the reduction in inflation was sustained only in Brazil, lasting

well into the 1970s, and reaching 12.7 percent in 1973 (Table 1). In

Argentina and Uruguay, loss of fiscal discipline led to a resumption in

inflation.

* Southern cone stabilization programs of the late 1970s. This group

comprises stabilizations programs in Argentina (December 1978), Chile

(February 1978), and Uruguay (October 1978) (see Tables 8-10 in the

Appendix).3' 32 These programs shared two key characteristics in their

design. First, all were orthodox programs (that is, there were no price or

wage controls). Second, in all three cases the exchange rate policy con-

sisted in announcing a devaluation schedule (the "tablita," for "little

table") against the dollar, with a decreasing rate of devaluation. Chile

eventually fixed the exchange rate in June 1979. In spite of fiscal balance

in both Chile and Uruguay, the slow convergence of inflation and the

corresponding real appreciation of the domestic currency proved fatal.

All three programs ended in dramatic fashion with large exchange rate

and financial crises.

* Heterodox programs of the mid-1980s. This group comprises the

Austral Plan in Argentina (June 1985), the Cruzado Plan in Brazil

(February 1986), the Israeli plan (July 1985), and the Mexican plan

(December 1987).33 A key common element of the four plans was the use

of wage and price controls to counter the inertial component of inflation.

The Israeli and Mexican plans were successful in bringing down inflation

to about 20 percent. In Argentina and Brazil, however, inflation quickly

resumed and soon reached higher levels than before the programs.

The key stylized facts shared by most of these programs are (1) inflation

converges only slowly to the rate of devaluation; (2) there is a sustained

real appreciation of the domestic currency; (3) the current account and

31 The Chilean stabilization consisted of two stages. From July 1976 to January

1978, the exchange rate began to be explicitly used for stabilization. Beginning

in February 1978, a lasting preannounced schedule was introduced (see Corbo

(1985)).

32 These episodes are discussed, among many others, by Corbo (1985), Hanson

and de Melo (1985), Ramos (1986), Kiguel and Liviatan (1988), and Edwards and

Edwards (1991). Another orthodox stabilization program of interest is the Argen-

tine stabilization of 1959-62 (see Petrecolla (1989)).

33 Discussions of these programs can be found in, for instance, Dornbusch and

Simonsen (1987), Kiguel and Liviatan (1989), Bruno and others (1988), and

Bruno and others (1991).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
646
CARLOS A. VEGH

the trade balance deteriorate; and (4) real activity increases at the begin-

ning of the program and later contracts.34

(1) Slow convergence of inflation. To illustrate the slow convergence

of the inflation rate to the devaluation rate, Figure 1 shows four-quarter

changes (that is, changes over same quarter of previous year) of devalu-

ation and inflation for the ten programs just described.35'36 The evidence

clearly suggests that inflation takes a long time to converge, if at all, to

the rate of devaluation. This lack of convergence is particularly striking

in the Southern cone tablitas. These programs were based on the belief

that the inflation rate would quickly converge to the world inflation plus

the preset rate of devaluation. However, to the surprise of policymakers,

such convergence was remarkably slow. In fact, as Figure 1 shows,

inflation convergence was never achieved. To judge from the three het-

erodox programs of the 1960s, this slow adjustment was nothing new.

Given the nonconvergence of inflation in the tablitas, it is hardly

surprising that some analysts concluded (for instance, Dornbusch (1982))

that wage and price controls should be part of a stabilization package.

Fiscal adjustment was viewed as a necessary, but not sufficient, condition

for a successful stabilization attempt due to the inertial components of

inflation. As a result, all four major programs of the 1980s resorted to

price and wage controls. 37 As Figure 1 illustrates, convergence continued

to be a problem, although not as severe as before. Even in successful

programs such as Israel's and Mexico's, inflation has yet to converge to

the policy-determined devaluation rate.

(2) Sustained real appreciation of the domestic currency. Given the

slow convergence of inflation, it is hardly surprising that the real ex-

change rate, defined as the relative price of traded goods in terms of

nontraded goods, fell during most plans (see Figure 2).38 Sustained real

34 Only those stylized facts relevant for the analytical discussion of the next

sections are emphasized. See Kiguel and Livitan (1992a) for a more complete

discussion.

35 With the exception of the Southern cone tablitas and the Cruzado Plan, there

were initial maxidevaluations in all other programs, which explains initial spikes

in the four-quarter devaluation rate.

36 Vertical bars indicate the quarters in which the programs were implemented

and abandoned. When the programs were implemented late in a given quarter

(in particular, the Argentine tablita on December 20, 1978, and the Mexican Plan

on December 15, 1987), the beginning of the program was taken to be the

following quarter.

37The fiscal adjustment was all but absent, however, in Brazil and soon de-

teriorated in Argentina.

38 In Israel the depreciation of the dollar in international markets that began

in 1985 explains the initial behavior of the real exchange rate. To facilitate

comparisons across different episodes, the initial real exchange rate (that is, the

real exchange rate in the quarter before the plan was implemented) has been set

equal to 100. When only annual data were available, the real exchange rate was

set to 100 in the year in which the program was implemented.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION
647

Figure 1. Inflation and Devaluation

(Percentage change over same quarter of previous year, monthly rates)

12

5- Argentina 1967

Brazil 1964

10

4 - j Devaluation -

8
- Devaluation

3 -& nt^ 4,.

_ Ynflationa/i _ - -19 %N Inflation


4

I -%**.ON

U 2

-1
0

1966 67 68 69 70 71 72
1963 64 65 66 67 68 69 70

10
20

- Uruguay 1968 Argentine tablita


8

- 15

4
Inflation 10

,- % Inflation

_%. #- - 5

Devaluation
Devaluation

-2

1967 68 69 70 71 72 73
1978 79 80 81 82

8
10

Chilean tablita
Uruguayan tablita _

Devaluation J I

4
- Inflation 6

Inflation

2 4

198 7I

0
2

Devaluation

I I9 I IJ I I I i I

-2 0

1977 78 79 80 81 82 83
1978 79 80 81 82 83

30

16

Cruzado Plan
25 - Austral Plan
14

- Devaluation
12
20 I

10

15 _ Inflation

- Inflaion
8

10- \

5 - Devaluation \^

I . . . i ...... . I . . -

0 1984 85 86 8 8
2

1984 85 86 8, 88 1984
1984 85 86 85
87 . 86 87

10
20

Israeli plan
- - Mexican plan

8
15

- \-.

6
10

.\ Inflation
_ Inflation

4
5

2
0 -Devaluation _ - _ . -%

Devaluation

lifilll 1,,II11 . ..
-5 0

1 984 85 86 87 88 89 90 1987 88 89 90 91

Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CARLOS A. VEGH
648

Figure 2. Real Effective Exchange Rates

105
110

1967=100 Argentina 1967

100

95

90

85

80

75

70

IiII
65
60

1! )66 67 68 69 70 71 72 1963 64 65 66 67 68 69 70

160

140

120

100

80

60

40

1978 79 80 81 82

110
120

100

110

90

100

80

90

70

80

60

70
50

60 40

1978 79 80 81 82 83
1978 79 80 81 82 83

115

150

1985:4=100 Cruzado Plan


140 1985:1=100 Austral Plan

140 -

105

130 -

120 -

95

110 -

.85
100

90 -

IIIIIIIIIIIIII

75
80 1 1 1 1

1984 85 86 87 88 1984 85 86 87

115 120

110 110

100
105

90
100

80

95

70
90

85 60

1984 85 86 87 88 89 90 1987 88 89 90 91

Source: Tables 5-14.

Note: A decline in the index denotes an appreciation.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION
649

appreciation proved to be fatal for most programs, because it led to

unsustainable trade and current account deficits. Failed programs are

thus characterized by U-shaped curves for the real exchange rate. The

largest appreciations occurred in the tablitas. In both Argentina and

Uruguay, the real exchange rate (set to 100 in the quarter before the

program was implemented) had halved by the time the programs ended

(see Tables 8 and 10 in the Appendix).

(3) The current account and the trade balance deteriorate. As a result

of the real appreciation, the current account deteriorated, as shown in

Figure 3.39 In Chile the current account deficit reached 14.5 of GDP in

1981, and in the Uruguayan tablita, it reached 7 percent of GDP in 1980.

Current account deficits were financed by large capital inflows. This is

particularly evident in the Southern cone tablitas (see Tables 8-10). In

Chile, for instance, capital inflows reached a peak of US $4,800 million

(15 percent of GDP) in 1981. The trade balance also deteriorated sub-

stantially (see Tables 5-14). Large increases in imports of durable goods

played a key role in the deterioration of the trade balance (see the

evidence reported in Drazen (1990)).

(4) Real activity increases at the beginning of the program and later

contracts. The peculiar phenomenon of an initial expansion in an infla-

tion stabilization program-traditionally viewed as generating initial out-

put losses-was brought to the forefront by the Southern cone tablitas

of the late 1970s. As illustrated in Figure 4, real private consumption (real

GDP for Uruguay) increased sharply in the first stages of the tablita

programs.4 Later-and in the cases of Chile and Uruguay even before

the programs ended-a sharp contraction in consumption (and output)

occurred. With the heterodox programs of the mid-1980s, this issue came

alive once again. The case of Israel was particularly striking because the

same boom-recession cycle was observed in spite of the success of the

program.41 The same pattern characterized the heterodox programs of

the 1960s, with the exception of Brazil. Kiguel and Liviatan (1992a)

analyzed 12 stabilization plans (which include the 10 depicted in Fig-

39 Current account figures for Israel are somewhat misleading due to the pres-

ence of grants, which explains why Figure 3 reports trade balance figures for

Israel.

40 In Chile the boom in consumption had already begun during the first stage

of the stabilization program (July 1976-January 1978). Specifically, after falling

by 11.4 percent in 1975, consumption remained basically unchanged in 1976, and

increased 16.0 percent in 1977 (data from Central Bank of Chile). For Uruguay,

consumption figures, available only on an annual basis, show the same pattern

as real GDP (Table 10).

41 Note, however, that four years into the program, Mexico is still enjoying a

consumption boom.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CARLOS A. VEGH
650

Figure 3. Current Account

(In millions of U.S. dollars)

400
300

_ razil 1964
Argentina 1967
200 200

100
0

0
-200

-100

-400

-200

-600

-300

\ -800

-400

-1000

-500

1963 64 65 66 67 68 69 7(
1966 67 68 69 70 71 72

1000
100

Uruguay 1968 Ij. Agrgentine tablita


500

50
0

-500

-1000

-1500

-50

-2000

..I..I_...

. . . . . . . . . . . . IW 1
-100

1967 68 69 70 71 72 73 1978 79 80 81 82

n 0

-100
Chilean tablita Uruguayan tablita -

-1000 - -200

-300

-2000 -
-400

-500

-3000 -

-600

-4000 -
-700

IiII
-800

-5000 '

1977 78 79 80 81 82 83 1978 79 80 81 82 83

2000
500

Austral Plan Cruzado Plan _

1000

0
0

-1000

-500

-2000

-3000

-1000

-4000

II I I II I 11111
-5000
-1500

1984 85 86 87 88 1984 85 86 87

2000

_- "\ JMexican plan

1000

-1000

-2000

-3000

Zs_ n n rn r

-4000

I 1 1 1, - I I I , , , I , , , I I
-5000

85 86 87 88 89 90 1987 88 89 90 91

Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues).

Note: Data are quarterly, except for Argentina 1967, Brazil 1964, Uruguay

1968, Chilean tablita, and Uruguayan tablita, for which annual data were used.

For Israel, the figures correspond to the trade balance. A minus number indicates

a deficit.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 651

Figure 4. Real Private Consumption

(Percentage change over same quarter of previous year)

20
7

Brazil 1964 - 15
6-

4-
A\ / ~~~~ - 10
5

-5
I - Argentina 1967

0',II, , , , , i , -10

1963 64 65 66 67 68 69 70
1966 67 68 69 70 71 72

20
10

J- Argentine tablita
8 - ruguay 1968 -

- / \_ \ - 10

6-

0
_-~~~~ t / - 10

-2 -

I, ,, a, i,,, Iii i Ii iIi -20


-4 i i i

1967 68 69 70 71 72 73 1978 79 80 81 82

15
30

- Uruguayan tablita - 10

20 A Chilean tablita

10

- 10

-10 -

- 15

-20 1l l l l" lilll' i "lli" " ,,, ,,,,i,,,I,,,,, ,YI, ...l -20

1978 79 80 81 82 83
1977 78 79 80 81 82 83

20 20

15 - Austral Plan
- Cruzado Plan \ - 15

10
- 10

1984 85 86 87 88

-5

30

-Israeli plan

-10-

I I I I I I I I I I I I I -10

-15 I i i i I I i I ' ' I ' ' ' I ' '

1984 85 86 87
1984 85 86 87 88

10

30

20 - sraeli plan

-6

--4
10-

/2

-10-
_ Mexican plan - -2

I I I I I I I I i I I I I -4
-20 I -ll ,I

1987 88 89 90 91
1984 85 86 87 88 89 90

Source: Tables 5-14.

Note: Annual percentage changes for Argentina 1967, Brazil 1964, and

Uruguay 1968. For the Uruguayan tablita, figures correspond to real GDP.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
652 CARLOS A. VEGH

ure 4) and concluded that the boom-recession cycle in real output remains

even when considered relative to the trend.

II. The Model

This section presents an analytical framework, based on Calvo and

Vegh (1991a), which will prove useful in interpreting the evidence pre-

sented in the previous section. Since the model is described in detail

elsewhere, most formal derivations will be bypassed and emphasis will be

placed on the results and their intuition.

Consider a small open economy with predetermined exchange rates.

There are two (nonstorable) goods: a tradable good, c*, and a nontrad-

able (or home) good, c. The representative consumer maximizes

f [log (ct) + log (c*)] exp (- 3t) dt, (1)


*'~~o~~~~~~~~~~(1)

where B denotes the constant and positive subjective discount rate.

The consumer is required to use money to carry out purchases. The

cash-in-advance constraint is thus

t(ctlet + c*) = mt,, (2)

where a is a positive constant, and e, the real exchange rate, is defined

as the relative price of traded goods in terms of home goods; that is,

e = EP*IP, where E is the nominal exchange rate (in units of domestic

currency per unit of foreign currency), P* is the (constant) price of the

traded good in foreign currency, and P is the domestic price of the home

good.42 Real money balances in terms of traded goods are denoted by m;

that is, m = M/EP*, where M stands for nominal domestic money

balances.

The consumer holds an internationally traded bond, b, which bears a

constant real interest rate (in terms of traded goods) equal to r. Real

financial wealth, a, is thus a, = mt + b,. The lifetime constraint faced by

the consumer is

ao + ( tlet + y* + T) exp(-rt)dt =

(ct/et + c* + itmt) exp(-rt)dt, (3)

42 Equation (2) already incorporates the fact that, given a positive nominal in-

terest rate, the cash-in-advance constraint will hold with equality at an optimum.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 653

where ao denotes initial real financial wealth; y and y* stand for output

of home and traded goods, respectively; T denotes real transfers from the

government; and i stands for the domestic nominal interest rate. Equa-

tion (3) equates the consumer's lifetime expenditure to his or her lifetime

resources. The consumer's expenditure includes the "rental" cost of real

money balances, im.

The consumer's optimization problem consists in choosing optimal

paths of c c *, c, and m, to maximize his or her lifetime utility (equation (1))

subject to the cash-in-advance constraint (equation (2)), and the in-

tertemporal budget constraint (equation (3)), given his or her initial real

financial wealth, o, and the paths of y, y, * T, it, and et. The first-order

conditions are (in addition to equations (2) and (3))

1/c* = X (1 + ai), (4)

and

c, = e,c*, (5)

where X is the (time-invariant) Lagrange multiplier associated with con-

straint (3), which can be interpreted as the marginal utility of wealth.43

Equation (4) is the familiar condition whereby the consumer equates the

marginal utility of consumption of traded goods to the marginal utility of

wealth times the "price" of traded goods. In the present context, the

relevant price of the traded good-which will be referred to as the

effective price-consists of the market price (unity) plus the opportunity

cost of holding the a units of real money balances that are necessary to

purchase the good, ai. Equation (5) indicates that the consumer equates

the marginal rate of substitution between traded and home goods to the

relative price of traded goods in terms of home goods (that is, the real

exchange rate).

Perfect capital mobility implies that

it = r + et, (6)

so that the nominal interest falls, one-to-one, with the rate of devaluation.

Consider now the supply side of the economy. It will be assumed that

the economy is endowed with a constant flow endowment of the tradable

good, y*. The supply of the home good is demand determined and

follows the staggered-prices model of Calvo (1983).44 Calvo (1983)

43To ensure the existence of a steady state, it has been assumed that P = r.

44 For simplicity, it is assumed that only the price of the home good is sticky.

For an alternative specification, see Calvo and Vegh (1991b).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CARLOS A. VEGH
654

showed that the rate of change of the inflation rate is negatively related

to excess demand. Formally

r, = -OD,, (7)

where ,r(= PIP) is the rate of inflation of home goods; and D, a measure

of excess demand in the home goods market, is defined as Dt = y, - y,

where y can be interpreted as the full-employment level of output.

Equation (7) can be derived in a framework in which firms set prices in

a nonsynchronous manner, taking into account the expected future path

of excess demand and of the average price prevailing in the economy.

Since only a small number of firms may change their individual prices at

any point in time, the price level is a predetermined variable; but inflation

is free to jump, because it reflects changes in individual prices charged

by firms. When higher demand emerges, some firms increase their indi-

vidual prices, and thus, inflation rises. Over time, the proportion of firms

that have yet to respond to excess demand declines, so that inflation

falls over time. Hence, the change in inflation is a negative function of

aggregate demand, as equation (7) indicates.

Imposing equilibrium in the home goods market (that is, ct = yt) and

using equation (5) and the definition of excess aggregate demand, equa-

tion (7) can be rewritten as

Trt = 0(y - e,c*). (8)

Differentiating e = EP*/P with respect to time yields (recalling that P*

is assumed constant)

et = (e, - rt) e,. (9)

For given paths of c* and the policy variable E, equations (8) and (9)

form a dynamic system for nr and e.45

To close the model, aggregate resource constraints need to be consid-

ered. Assuming that the government transfers back to the public interest

income on net foreign assets and revenues from money creation, it can

be shown (see Calvo and Vegh (1991a)) that the economy's resource

constraint is

ko + y*/r = c* exp(-rt) dt, (10)

45 The determinant of the matrix associated with the linear approximation of

the system (8) and (9) is negative, which indicates the existence of saddle-path

stability.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 655

where ko denotes the economy's initial stock of foreign bonds. Equation

(10) states that the present value of tradable resources must equal the

present value of consumption of traded goods. Under the assumption

that domestic credit just compensates the consumer for the depreciation

of nominal money balances, the current account is given by

k, = y* + rk - c*, (11)

which indicates that the current account balance is the difference between

traded goods income and consumption of traded goods.

Permanent Reduction in Devaluation Rate

Consider now a permanent reduction in the rate of devaluation. Spe-

cifically, suppose that at time 0 (the present), policymakers announce that

the rate of devaluation will be reduced immediately from Eh to E'. More-

over, the announcement is fully credible; that is, the public expects the

rate of devaluation to remain at the lower level, e', forever.

At time 0, the nominal interest falls by the same amount as the rate

of devaluation, as indicated by equation (6). Since the policy is fully

credible, the nominal interest rate is expected to remain at the lower

level, r + El forever. This implies that the consumption of traded goods

does not change. The reason is that a constant nominal interest rate, no

matter what the level is, implies, by first-order condition (4), that con-

sumption of traded goods is constant over time. Even if the effective price

of consumption is reduced, the fact that it remains constant over time

implies that there are no incentives to engage in intertemporal consump-

tion substitution. Since tradable resources do not change, consumption

of traded goods must remain at the same level.

From the system (8) and (9), it follows that, given that c* is not affected

by permanent changes in the rate of devaluation, a fall in Tr that exactly

matches the fall in E immediately moves the system to a new steady state.

Naturally, the (average) inflation rate of the economy, which is a

weighted average of the inflation rate of home goods, rr, and that of

traded goods, e, also falls instantaneously to its new level, el. Therefore,

an exchange rate-based stabilization program that is fully credible reduces

the inflation rate instantaneously at no real costs.

It is worth emphasizing that, even though the price level is sticky and

individual prices are set in a staggered manner, no real effects result from

a reduction in the devaluation rate that is perceived as being permanent.

This shows, as emphasized by Calvo and Vegh (1991a), that price level

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CARLOS A. VEGH
656

rigidity does not, by itself, imply stickiness in the inflation rate. The

reason is that in this framework, firms act in a forward-looking manner.46

III. Stopping Hyperinflation

Despite its simplicity, the exercise just undertaken analyzing the effects

of a permanent reduction in the rate of devaluation provides a useful

conceptual framework for discussing the end of hyperinflations. The

reason, as this section argues, is that the model captures two distin-

guishing characteristics of hyperinflations: the absence of backward-

looking behavior, and the presence of a high degree of credibility. Hence,

it seems reasonable to identify, if only as a first approximation, the above

analytical exercise with experiences of stopping hyperinflation.

Absence of Backward-Looking Behavior

The disappearance of long-term nominal contracts in hyperinflation

episodes is a recurrent theme in the literature (see, for instance, Cagan

(1989)). Furthermore, a key characteristic of hyperinflations is that at

some point all prices become indexed to the nominal exchange rate.

Wage contracts, for instance, are renegotiated more frequently as infla-

tion accelerates. At first, wage readjustments are based on a cost of living

index. As the interval between readjustments becomes shorter, however,

the cost of living index must be replaced by another index that is available

on a weekly or even daily basis. The quotation of a foreign currency-

usually the U.S. dollar-provides such an index; the dollar quotation is

available on a continuous basis and is widely circulated.

The de facto indexation of all prices in the economy to the foreign

exchange implies that nominal contracts virtually cease to exist. Thus, all

backward-looking behavior is eradicated from the economy. Since one

of the key features of the model presented in Section II is the absence

of backward-looking behavior, the model can be taken to apply to

hyperinflation episodes.

46This need not be the case in other models of staggered contracts. For

instance, in Fischer's (1986) model, a permanent reduction in the rate of deval-

uation causes real effects, because the price established in the contract does not

remain fixed during the life of the contract.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 657

High Credibility

It has been argued (see, for instance, Kiguel and Liviatan (1988)) that

two characteristics of hyperinflationary processes make a stabilization

attempt more credible than attempts to stop chronic inflation.

First, the need for seigniorage (that is, revenues from money creation)

as the cause of high inflation comes across more clearly in hyperinflations

than in chronic inflations. Since the fiscal nature of the inflationary

process is more obvious, the public may become more easily convinced

that closing the budget deficit is enough to ensure price stability.In

contrast, in chronic-inflation countries, the relationship between infla-

tion and revenues from money creation is much less clear, which may

raise doubts in peoples' minds as to whether a fiscal reform-even if

successfully implemented-may be enough to halt inflation. Thus, given

that in hyperinflations the source of the inflationary process is easily

identified and widely agreed upon, the announcement of a stabilization

program that includes a fiscal reform should command a high degree of

credibility.

The second factor that may increase the credibility of a stabilization

program is that hyperinflation creates such a chaotic social and economic

environment that the public becomes convinced that the situation is

untenable. This sense of urgency in tackling the problem is likely to lend

more credibility to a stabilization program. In contrast, chronic-inflation

countries learn how to live with high inflation by adopting various index-

ation mechanisms. An example of this ability to adapt to chronic inflation

can be observed in the behavior of real revenues from taxation. In

hyperinflations, the Olivera-Tanzi effect drastically reduces real revenues

from taxation; this is not the case in chronic inflations (see Kiguel and

Liviatan (1988)).

There is also more direct evidence on the presence of high credibility

in hyperinflation stabilizations. As emphasized by Sargent (1982), the

real monetization of the economies in which hyperinflation was success-

fully stopped is dramatic.47 In the aftermath of stabilization, monthly

growth rates of notes in circulation above 10 percent alongside a basically

stable price level have been observed in many episodes (Germany, Hun-

47The cash-in-advance specification of the model implies that real money

demand does not increase as a result of the fall in the nominal interest rate. The

remonetization usually observed in actual episodes could be captured by intro-

ducing money as an argument in the utility function. In that case, a permanent

reduction in the rate of devaluation would increase real money balances, while

still leaving the consumption of either good unchanged.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
658 CARLOS A. VEGH

gary 1946, Greece, and Poland), as shown in Table 3. In Hungary 1946,

for instance, notes in circulation increased by a factor of 4.9 in the 12

months following stabilization.48 Such enormous increases in real money

balances can only be attributed to a drastic reduction in inflationary

expectations, as a result of the high credibility of the program.

Matching Theory with Evidence

It has been argued that backward-looking behavior all but disappears

during hyperinflations and that attempts to stop hyperinflations enjoy

high credibility. Therefore, the analytical experiment undertaken in Sec-

tion II, which assumes full credibility in the context of a model in which

there is no backward-looking behavior, may be considered a reasonable

first approximation to understanding hyperinflation stabilization.

The next step is to match theory with evidence. If full credibility is

assumed, the model predicts that stabilizing the nominal exchange rate

should lead to an immediate halt in inflation at no real cost. This predic-

tion is in accordance with the evidence provided in Section I: price sta-

bility has been achieved overnight with relatively small output costs. The

costs that did emerge are more attributable to real dislocations-some-

times policy induced, such as Germany's policy of subsidizing the capital

goods industry with the inflation tax-than to the monetary stabilization

itself.

Admittedly, the model is a highly stylized version of the real world and

ignores many important aspects, in particular supply-side and structural

considerations that have played an important role in past hyperinflations.

But its usefulness lies precisely in its simplicity, because it isolates what

is regarded as key aspects in actual episodes. Furthermore, by enriching

the formulation of the supply side, the same model could be used to tackle

real sector considerations.

IV. Stopping Chronic Inflation

This section will interpret the evidence presented in Section I on

stopping chronic inflation in terms of the analytical model developed in

48 In this respect, the Bolivian hyperinflation is more of an exception, in that

remonetization has been slow. By 1991, the ratio of M1 to GDP was 6.7 percent,

up from 2.6 percent in 1985 but still lower than prehyperinflationary levels

(7.4 percent in 1982). (Data from Morales (1988) and IMF, International Finan-

cial Statistics, (various issues).)

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 659

Section II.49 The key assumption behind the analytical exercise developed

in this section is that there is lack of credibility. Unlike programs designed

to stop hyperinflation, stabilization attempts in chronic-inflation coun-

tries are likely to suffer from lack of credibility. Chronic-inflation coun-

tries have learned to live with high inflation, and as a result, the incentives

to eradicate inflation are much lower than in hyperinflations. Further-

more, given past failures, policymakers will have a hard time convincing

a skeptical public that the current stabilization plan will be sustained over

time.

The spreads between domestic and devaluation-adjusted foreign inter-

est rates provide at least a crude measure of credibility. Large positive

spreads suggest lack of credibility, since they indicate that the public

expected a devaluation (under a fixed exchange rate) or a larger deval-

uation than the one preannounced (in a tablita program). Tables 8-14 in

the Appendix show the presence of large spreads throughout the pro-

grams, except, as one would expect, in the quarters preceding a non-

scheduled devaluation.o5 In the Argentine tablita (Table 8), for instance,

the spread reaches its maximum of 45.7 percent (in annual terms) in the

third quarter of 1980. In the following quarter the spread becomes

negative, reflecting the devaluation that finally ended the program. In

Mexico (Table 14), the spread has been positive since the beginning of

the program. It declined, however, during 1989 as the authorities

switched from a fixed exchange rate to a constant (in absolute terms)

daily devaluation.

Lack of credibility will be modeled as temporary policy. Suppose that

at time 0 policymakers announce a permanent reduction in the devalua-

tion rate, but the public believes that the stabilization will be abandoned

at some time T in the future. Under this scenario, the public acts as

though the reduction in the devaluation rate were temporary. Hence, the

effects of temporary policy may be reinterpreted as arising from noncred-

ible policy. Formally, then, consider a temporary reduction in the rate of

devaluation. Suppose that initially (that is, prior to time 0), the rate of

devaluation is eh. At time 0, the expected path becomes

t = et, for 0 t < T (12a)

t = Eh, for t T, (12b)

49As argued in Section I, backward-looking behavior is one of the main

characteristics of chronic inflation. For analytical simplicity, this feature is ignored

in the model (see the discussion in Section V).

5Spreads are computed using the LIBOR rate and the one-quarter-ahead

devaluation rate.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
660 CARLOS A. VEGH

where T > 0 and Eh > E. The rate of devaluation falls at time 0 but is

expected to increase back to its original level at time T.

The lower rate of devaluation during the period [0,T)-hereafter re-

ferred to as the "transition"-implies, by the assumption of perfect

capital mobility (equation (6)), that the path of the nominal interest rate

is given by i = r + E, forO 0 t < T, and it = r + eh, for t - T. Since the

nominal interest rate is time invariant (that is, its time derivative is zero),

the first-order condition (equation (4)) indicates that consumption of

traded goods is time invariant, even though its level may change. Because

the nominal interest rate is lower during the transition than it is after T,

equation (4) shows that consumption of traded goods is higher during the

transition than afterwards (recall that X does not change at T). The reason

is that the effective price of consumption is lower during the transition.

Since the resource constraint (equation (10)) must be satisfied for any

equilibrium path, consumption of traded goods during the transition will

be above initial permanent income of traded goods, while consumption

of traded goods after T will be below initial permanent income of traded

goods (see Figure 5, panel A).51 Otherwise, the resource constraint would

be violated.

The current account path, which follows from the consumption path

just described and equation (11), is illustrated in Figure 5, panel B. At

time 0, the current account jumps into deficit because of the sudden

increase in consumption of traded goods. During the transition (that is,

for 0 - t < T), the trade deficit remains constant but the current account

deteriorates because interest income on net foreign assets declines. At

time T, the current account jumps into balance. As discussed in Section

I, the current account has deteriorated substantially throughout the

different programs (see Figure 3). The current account deficit usually

reflects sizable trade deficits (see Tables 5-14 in the Appendix).

Figure 5, panel C, illustrates the time path of inflation of home goods.52

On impact, there are two effects on the inflation rate of home goods that

go in opposite direction. On the one hand, the lower rate of devaluation

exerts a dampening effect on inflation of home goods. On the other hand,

aggregate demand increases (see below), which tends to push inflation

up. In the absence of the aggregate demand effect, inflation of home

goods would fall, one-to-one, with the rate of devaluation (which is what

happens under full credibility). However, because of the aggregate

demand effect, the rate of inflation of home goods falls by less than the

rate of devaluation, and could even increase. Inflation falls over time at

5 Initial permanent income is given by y* + rko.

52For a formal derivation, see Calvo and Vegh (1991a).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 661

Figure 5. Temporary Reduction in Devaluation Rate

A. Consumption of traded goods B. Current account

c*
k

tI

0 T time

II

I ---- -----

II

II

II

I... t

II_

0 T time

C. Inflation rate D. Real exchange rate

nh

II

II

II II

II

II

I I tim II-

0 T time 0 T time

E. Consumption of home goods F. Domestic real interest rate

rdi

I
r

II II

II

II

II

II

I I -~~~ II

0 T tim
0 T time 0 T time

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
662 CARLOS A. VEGH

the beginning of the program but later begins to rise in anticipation of

the expected resumption of the higher devaluation rate.53 When time T

is reached, the authorities face the choice of abandoning the program

(thus validating the public's expectations) or sticking to the lower rate of

devaluation. If the authorities abandon the program, inflation continues

to increase toward its initial level, as in Figure 5, panel C. If the author-

ities stick to the stabilization plan, then inflation jumps downwards at

time T and converges from below to the lower devaluation rate.

The (average) inflation rate of the economy is a weighted average of

the inflation rate of traded goods, E, and the rate of inflation of home

goods, ir, with the weights depending on the weight of traded and home

goods in the utility function. Since the devaluation rate is constant, the

inflation rate exhibits the same qualitative behavior during the transition

as inflation of home goods. The model thus predicts that, due to lack of

credibility, the inflation rate exhibits inertia. The U-shaped time profile

of inflation predicted by the model is typical of that observed in failed

programs (which include all the programs depicted in Figure 1, except

Israel and Mexico).54 The behavior of inflation in successful plans, such

as Israel and Mexico, is consistent with the assumption that policymakers

stuck to the stabilization plan.

Panel D in Figure 5 illustrates the behavior of the real exchange rate.55

The real exchange rate falls during the transition (that is, there is a real

appreciation of the domestic currency), because the inflation rate of

home goods is always above the rate of devaluation. At time T, whether

or not the plan is abandoned, the real exchange rate begins to increase

(that is, there is a real depreciation).56 If the plan is not abandoned,

inflation falls below the devaluation rate to generate the real deprecia-

tion. This U-shaped time profile of the real exchange rate predicted by

53 This presumes that Tis large. If Tis small, wr always falls during the transition

(see Calvo and Vegh (1991a)).

54 It can also be shown that the less credible the program, the lower the initial

fall (or the larger the initial increase) in the inflation rate. Hence, as intuition

would suggest, the initial behavior of inflation is very much dependent on the

credibility of the program.

55 The steady-state real exchange rate increases because steady-state consump-

tion of traded goods decreases while steady-state consumption of home goods

remains constant at its full-employment level.

56 Calvo and Vegh (1991a) show that all real effects remain the same no matter

what the authorities do at time T (assuming, of course, that if the authorities stick

to the plan, the public now sees it as permanent). Formally, once-and-for-all

changes in the rate of devaluation are everywhere superneutral; that is, only

nominal variables are affected.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 663

the model is the one that has generally been observed in practice (see

Figure 2).

Consider now the time path of consumption of home goods illustrated

in Figure 5, panel E. On impact, as already noted, consumption of home

goods increases as follows from equation (5) and the increase in c*.

Intuitively, since the relative price of home goods in terms of traded

goods has not changed, there are no incentives to change consumption

of home goods relative to consumption of traded goods. During the

transition, consumption of home goods falls as the real exchange rate

decreases (that is, the relative price of home goods increases). If Tis large

enough, the economy enters into recession (that is, output falls below its

full-employment level) before the plan is expected to be discontinued.

For a small T, output will remain above its full-employment level during

all of the transition. At time T, consumption of home goods jumps

downwards, accompanying the fall in consumption of traded goods. After

T, the real exchange rate increases, and therefore consumption of home

goods rises.

The evidence depicted in Figure 4 for private consumption is consistent

with the predictions of the model, in that there is an early consumption

boom followed by a contraction. Moreover, in two of the longest pro-

grams (Uruguay, 17 quarters; and Chile, 18 quarters), consumption fell

before the end of the programs. In Uruguay, as Table 10 indicates, the

annual rate of change of consumption was negative in 1980 and the

four-quarter change in real GDP turned negative in the last quarter of

1981, one year before the end of the program. In Chile, the four-quarter

change in both private consumption and real GDP turned negative in the

fourth quarter of 1981, two quarters before the end of the program. If

one identifies the actual duration of the program with T, this fact is

consistent with the prediction that the higher is T, the more likely it is

that the contraction will take place before the program ends. Even if the

program is not abandoned at T, the behavior of real variables remains

the same, as argued above. Hence, the model is also capable of rational-

izing consumption patterns such as Israel's, where the recession took

place in spite of the success of the program.

Consider now the time path of the domestic real interest rate (that is,

rd = i - rT), which is illustrated in Figure 5, panel F. The inflation rate

of home goods falls by less on impact than the nominal interest rate does;

therefore, the domestic real interest rate falls on impact. During the

transition, the domestic real interest rate stays below its initial level. At

time T, the domestic real interest rate jumps upwards, owing to the

sudden increase in the nominal interest rate. The domestic real interest

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
664 CARLOS A. VEGH

rate falls afterwards toward its unchanged steady-state value, given that

inflation increases.

The predictions of the model with respect to the behavior of the real

interest rate seem to hold for the Southern cone programs but not for the

rest of the programs.57 The Uruguayan tablita (Table 10) is the best

example: the (ex post) real lending rate fell substantially when the pro-

gram was implemented and was negative during the first three quarters

of 1979. In 1980 it became positive and reached a peak of 48.2 percent

(in annual terms) in the fourth quarter of 1981, undoubtedly contributing

to the contraction in economic activity. In the Argentine tablita (Table

8), the real lending rate was also negative in the first two quarters of the

program (even if it increased with respect to the fourth quarter of 1978).

In the Chilean tablita (Table 9), the real lending rate fell from very high

levels, reaching 5.8 percent, six quarters into the program.

In the rest of the programs for which data are available (the four

heterodox programs of the mid-1980s), real interest rates increased (see

Tables 11-14 in the Appendix). A possible explanation for this phe-

nomenon lies in the use of additional nominal anchors. The Israeli 1985

plan, for instance, had an explicit target for bank credit, which was to be

achieved by a combination of higher reserve requirements and a higher

discount rate (see Barkai (1990)). The idea was to offset the expansionary

effects of a large increase in credit to the private sector. In fact, credit

to the private sector declined in real terms at the beginning of the

program, which may explain the initial (although brief) downturn in the

last two quarters of 1985. In contrast, in the Southern cone tablitas, real

credit grew strongly. Analytically, high interest rates can be rationalized

by modeling the use of additional monetary anchors (see Calvo and V6gh

(1991b)).

In summary, a noncredible, exchange rate-based stabilization yields

predictions that are generally consistent with the stylized facts. In partic-

ular, the model generates a boom-recession cycle and U-shaped curves

for both inflation and the real exchange rate, as has been observed in

most programs. The key missing ingredient in explaining high real inter-

est rates at the beginning of the program seems to be the presence of

additional nominal anchors.

57 Since ex ante real interest rates cannot be observed, the model's predictions

are compared with ex post real interest rates. However, the comparison should

be viewed as suggestive only, because, especially at the beginning of a stabiliza-

tion program, ex post real interest rates might differ substantially from ex ante

real interest rates.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION
665

V. Final Remarks

This last section discusses the quantitative importance of lack of cred-

ibility (or the "temporariness" hypothesis) in explaining the observed

consumption booms and the role of backward indexation, and then offers

some concluding remarks.58

Quantitative Relevance of the Temporariness Hypothesis

A crucial, and relatively unexplored, question is the quantitative rele-

vance of the temporariness hypothesis. Given that intertemporal elastic-

ities of substitution are generally low, it is not clear whether models that

rely on intertemporal substitution effects can explain the magnitude of

observed rises in consumption. Since what triggers all effects in the model

is the temporary (as perceived by the public) fall in the nominal interest

rate relevant for consumption decisions, a first question is whether nom-

inal deposit interest rates (that is, the interest rate relevant for consump-

tion decisions) have fallen in different programs. Figure 6 shows that in

the four heterodox programs of the mid-1980s (Austral, Cruzado, Israeli,

and Mexican), deposit rates did indeed fall dramatically.59 In the South-

ern cone tablitas, however, the fall was considerably less, particularly in

Uruguay where the deposit rate soon reached its initial level.

The empirical question is therefore: can the observed fall in nominal

interest rates account for a sizable fraction of the rise in private consump-

tion in a temporariness model? A first attempt to answer this question

can be found in Reinhart and V6gh (1992). Using estimates of the in-

tertemporal elasticities of their own and other available estimates, they

concluded, based on a very simple simulation exercise, that the tempo-

rariness hypothesis accounted for an important fraction (over 60 percent)

of the actual increase in consumption in the four heterodox programs of

58 Policy conclusions that would follow from this framework are discussed in an

earlier version of this paper (Vegh (1991)).

59 Considering the deposit rate in the quarter before the plan was implemented

and its minimum value during the duration of the plan, deposit rates (in annual

terms) fell from 671 percent to 44.3 percent in the Austral Plan; from 305 percent

to 22.6 percent in the Cruzado Plan; from 305.8 percent to 11.9 percent in the

Israeli plan; and from 106.1 percent to 15.1 percent in the Mexican plan (see

Tables 11-14). The behavior just described holds for lending rates or other

nominal rates (see Tables 11-14).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
666 CARLOS A. VEGH

Figure 6. Nominal Deposit Interest Rates

(In percent per year)

140

120

100

80

60

40

20

1978 79 80 81 82 1977 78 79 80 81 82 83

90
1500

80 - Uruguayan tablita 194Austral Plan

1000
70 -

60 -

50 -
500

40-

30 19 7 8 81 8 I 0

1978 79 80 81 82 83 1984 85 86 87 88

600 700

600
500- CruzadoPlan

500

400 -

400

300-

300

200 -

200

100 -

100

0 o i I, II , I
0

1984 85 86 87 1984 85 86 87 88 89 90

1987 88 89 90 91

Source: Tables 8-14.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 667

the 1980s.60 In contrast, it only accounts for less than 15 percent in the

tablitas. The key difference, as discussed above, is that in the four

heterodox programs, nominal interest rates dropped sharply, whereas in

the Southern cone tablitas, the fall was considerably less. An important

caveat is that durable goods, which are likely to play a crucial role in any

empirical application, are not modeled. Elasticities of substitution are

bound to be higher if a distinction is made between durable and non-

durable goods, as found by Fauvel and Sampson (1991) for Canada.61

Therefore, although further work is warranted, Reinhart and V6gh's

(1992) results suggest that some other factors (for instance, negative or

falling real interest rates) may have played an important role in the

tablitas.

Backward Indexation

In the model presented in Section II, inflation "stickiness" results from

lack of credibility. Alternatively, inflation inertia could result from back-

ward-looking behavior.62 In this spirit, Rodriguez's (1982) assumed adap-

tive expectations and showed how, due to an initial fall in real interest

rates, there would be a consumption boom. In a setting of rational

expectations, Calvo and V6gh (1992) incorporated backward-looking

contracts in a model similar to that of Section II and, in contrast to

Rodriguez (1992), concluded that a fully credible, exchange rate-based

stabilization will lead to a recession if the intertemporal elasticity of

substitution is smaller than the elasticity of substitution between traded

and home goods (which seems to be the relevant case in practice; see

Ostry and Reinhart (1992; this issue)). Intuitively, the real appreciation

of the domestic currency has both expansionary effects-since it reduces

the domestic real interest rate-and recessionary effects-since it in-

creases the relative price of home goods. Hence, backward-looking con-

tracts, per se, may not be capable of explaining the observed expansion.

If, in addition, there is lack of credibility, then the net effect on consump-

60Bufman and Leiderman (1992) also emphasized the important role, from a

quantitative point of view, that temporariness plays in explaining the consump-

tion boom in Israel.

61 Needless to say, data availability is a formidable challenge when it comes to

durable goods consumption in developing countries.

62Pazos (1972) and Dornbusch and Simonsen (1987) discussed the notion of

inflation inertia arising from backward indexation. Wage indexation based on

past inflation was particularly important in the Chilean tablita (see Corbo (1985)

and Edwards (1990)). Since inflation was decreasing, backward-looking indexa-

tion resulted in a substantial increase in real wages (see Table 10).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
668 CARLOS A. VEGH

tion will still depend on the configuration parameter, but an increase in

consumption becomes more likely since the temporariness effect is al-

ways expansionary. Hence, the key ingredient in explaining a consump-

tion boom appears to be lack of credibility and not backward indexation.

Conclusions

A unified theoretical framework has been used to interpret the main

stylized facts associated with stopping both hyperinflation and chronic

inflation. The model predicts that, in the absence of backward indexa-

tion, a credible stabilization program stops inflation in its tracks with no

real effects. This experiment was taken as a reasonable first approxima-

tion to a hyperinflationary situation. Although the evidence regarding

the output costs of stopping hyperinflation is spotty and subject to debate,

a good case can be made that hyperinflation has, in fact, been stopped

suddenly with no major costs. The contractionary forces that have

come into play seem to result from real distortions brought about by

hyperinflation rather than by monetary stabilization itself.

A noncredible reduction in the rate of devaluation has been used to

interpret stabilization in chronic-inflation countries. The model predicts

a slow convergence of the inflation rate, a boom-recession cycle in the

home goods sector, a current account deficit, and real appreciation of the

domestic currency. This is consistent with the key stylized facts observed

in these episodes. The model also predicts a fall in domestic real interest

rates on implementation of the program. This prediction is consistent

with the experience of the Southern cone tablitas, but not with that of

the major heterodox plans of the mid-1980s.

The model used in this paper, based on Calvo and Vegh (1991a),

appears to offer a reasonably good description of reality and should prove

useful as a benchmark for interpreting the outcome of stabilization pro-

grams in high-inflation countries. Naturally, many issues remain to be

further analyzed, but three seem to stand out.

First, the behavior of real interest rates in the aftermath of stabilization

programs deserves further attention, from an analytical point of view.

Contrary to common perceptions, lack of credibility does not necessarily

generate high real interest rates. As mentioned above, additional nomi-

nal anchors are likely to be a key ingredient. In this respect, the issue of

tight credit policy during stabilization policy, an issue raised by Barkai

(1990) for the case of Israel, seems crucial.

Second, the role of credibility needs to be endogenized. The model

analyzed in the paper takes the existence of credibility, or the lack

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 669

thereof, as exogenous to the model. As long as credibility has an exoge-

nous component-given, for instance, by past experiences-the essence

of the model should not change. Common sense suggests, however, that

credibility is gained or lost as a program unfolds, since the evolution of

the different variables (for instance, the real exchange rate) provides

valuable information regarding the sustainability of the program.63 Ca-

sual evidence suggests that credibility often follows an inverted U-shaped

pattern, rising at first and decreasing later. This credibility pattern has

been found in the Cruzado Plan (Agenor and Taylor (1992; this issue)).

Guidotti and Vegh (1992) developed a model of endogenous credibility

in which this pattern arises.

Finally, it would be important to model supply-side considerations that

may come into play in periods of high inflation, and study the interaction

between real factors and monetary stabilization. This is bound to be

particularly useful in understanding stabilization programs in Eastern

Europe and the former Soviet Union where high inflation and structural

changes are likely to coexist in the foreseeable future.

APPENDIX

Statistical Appendix

This Appendix contains tables with selected macroeconomic indicators for

eleven stabilization programs in high-inflation countries: Bolivia 1985 (Table 4);

Argentina 1967 (Table 5); Brazil 1964 (Table 6); Uruguay 1968 (Table 7); Argen-

tina 1978 (Table 8); Chile 1978 (Table 9); Uruguay 1978 (Table 10); Argentina

1985, Austral Plan, (Table 11); Brazil 1986, Cruzado Plan (Table 12); Israel 1985

(Table 13); and Mexico 1987 (Table 14).

Subject to data availability, the same variables are reported for each episode

to facilitate comparisons across different episodes. Four-quarter changes indicate

percentage change over same quarter of the previous year.

63Vegh (1991) differentiates between "ex ante" credibility (how the public

perceives the plan when it is implemented), and "ex post" credibility (credibility

that is gained as the program evolves).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
670 CARLOS A. VEGH

Table 4. Bolivian 1985 Stabilization

Inflation Interest Rates

Rate Nominal Nominal Real

Devaluation Rate Inflation (4Q deposit lending lending

Year/ Official Parallel Rate change) rate rate rate Spread

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

1984:1 0.0 496.0 682.5 426.8 45.0 62.0 -96.5 -99.5

2 27,050.0 196.3 4,518.3 957.0 108.3 120.7 -56.5 -95.2

3 3,772.1 29,110.8 407.0 999.6 140.0 150.0 -96.9 -75.4

4 771.0 308.7 7,860.6 1,854.3 140.0 150.0 -99.8 -99.7

1985:1 83,837.2 171,003.4 123,729.9 6,831.4 20.0 34.0 -96.9 -78.0

2 399.2 14,631.5 4,217.9 6,715.8 25.0 44.0 -99.6 -100.0

3 5,355,597.6 1,076.0 38,803.3 20,072.4 120.0 379.5 -21.2 -66.9

4 513.7 1,071.4 508.6 10.507.3 110.0 231.1 -44.7 22.1

1986:1 59.0 66.0 498.8 2,697.2 249.8 756.6 519.1 219.4

2 1.5 0.0 38.4 1,083.5 86.3 219.0 150.7 70.4

3 2.1 9.9 27.3 183.0 49.7 123.0 102.3 39.1

4 1.3 -3.7 10.3 84.6 40.0 89.5 62.4 12.6

1987:1 17.1 16.7 22.7 35.8 70.1 53.3 11.4

2 14.6 11.0 16.1 31.3 60.4 55.6 13.5

3 8.0 3.1 10.2 31.1 54.2 37.6 1.6

4 20.3 12.1 10.6 34.5 42.8 34.1 8.1

1988:1 15.3 6.4 8.1 28.8 41.4 5.0 1.5

2 16.6 34.7 13.5 28.1 40.4 5.3 17.2

3 1.7 33.3 21.0 27.4 38.5 23.3 4.7

4 12.2 12.3 21.0 26.7 38.9 28.5 3.9

1989:1 11.8 8.1 21.5 24.2 36.9 30.4 -3.1

2 16.7 4.9 14.2 22.9 36.7 17.1 -19.8

3 39.7 16.7 10.4 24.8 36.9 2.3 -1.4

4 16.2 33.8 15.4 22.7 38.6 23.3 -2.3

1990:1 15.6 12.5 16.5 20.6 40.0 31.5 3.0

2 8.0 6.4 16.9 28.0 43.7 20.5 1.6

3 16.1 19.2 17.6 22.8 42.0 6.7 -2.9

4 16.9 33.1 17.4 23.9 41.6 1.1 1.4

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 671

Capital Fiscal

Real Trade Account Bal-

Credit to Private Balance Balance ance

Private Con- Real Real Effective (In (In (In

M1 Sector sumption GDP Exchange millions millions percent

(4Q (4Q (Annual (Annual Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of

change) change) change) change) (1985 = 100) (1985:2 = 100) dollars) dollars) GDP)

(9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) (17)

253.2 122.7 213.1

426.1 374.9 252.1

777.7 627.4 164.5

1,788.6 978.9 -3.5 -0.6 125.1 106.5 312 49 -29.4

3,935.3 3,914.1 118.2

6,364.1 3,968.7 100.0

11,417.1 20,112.3 50.0

5,769.6 18,939.2 17.0 -1.0 100.0 345.1 161 -42 -10.1

1,848.5 5,160.9 350.7

747.2 2.790.9 328.0

160.0 336.7 319.2

86.1 152.0 -7.9 -2.5 76.9 316.8 -51 90 -3.4

94.2 159.2 323.6

60.7 116.1 340.3

61.0 70.7 343.1

39.9 48.4 4.5 2.6 81.0 356.2 -128 33 -7.7

27.5 21.3 373.8 -17 -14

28.9 23.3 366.8 10 25

21.1 32.3 344.0 -39 67

35.3 42.0 2.0 3.0 97.0 352.6 -2 -56 -6.5

35.9 44.7 360.9 -29 -110

26.1 42.8 357.5 4 -91

16.6 39.7 383.9 7 8

2.4 49.8 2.5 2.8 99.3 395.0 12 57 -5.1

3.6 52.2 425.0 -1 40

18.3 52.5 439.6 16 -65

34.4 57.9 455.4 24 104

39.5 43.7 1.6 2.6 109.8 457.9 16 3 -3.3

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except

columns (2) and (13), from Central Bank of Bolivia, and column (17), from

Central Bank of Bolivia, SAFCO, and Fund estimates.

Note: All rates of change and interest rates are expressed in percent per year.

Horizontal line indicates the beginning of the program. The spread between the

parallel and the official rate has been negligible since 1987. Columns (11), (12),

(13), (15), (16), and (17) report annual figures; column (7) is computed using the

one-quarter-ahead inflation rate; column (8) is defined as the ratio of (1 plus) the

deposit rate to (1 plus) the three-month LIBOR rate times (1 plus) the one-quar-

ter-ahead devaluation rate; column (16) includes errors and omissions (a positive

sign indicates a capital inflow); and column (17) refers to the balance of the

nonfinancial public sector (a minus sign denotes a deficit).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Table 5. Argentine 1967 Stabilization

Real Trade Capital Fiscal cv

Credit to Private Balance Account Balance >

Private Con- Real Real (In Balance (In <

Inflation M1 Sector sumption GDP Exchange millions (In millions percent trM

Devaluation Inflation Rate (4Q (Annual (Annual (Annual (Annual Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of C

Year/ Rate Rate change) change) change) change) change) (1967 = 100) (1967 = 100) dollars) dollars) GDP)

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

1966:1 0.0 29.2 37.7

2 39.3 22.6 35.4

3 27.2 16.0 27.6

4 67.1 48.4 28.5 35.0 36.0 0.3 0.6 100.6 85.1 600 -236 -4.6

1967:1 301.2 21.8 26.6

2 0.0 24.3 27.0

3 0.0 39.2 33.0

4 0.0 34.7 29.8 62.7 31.1 2.6 2.7 100.0 100.0 495 414 -1.9

1968:1 0.0 10.8 26.8

2 0.0 -1.4 19.6

3 0.0 3.4 11.1

4 0.0 27.4 9.5 24.9 46.5 4.0 4.3 96.9 85.7 333 86 -2.1

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1969:1 0.0 1.8 7.2

2 0.0 -0.9 7.4

3 0.0 6.7 8.2

4 0.0 23.8 7.5 21.3 27.0 6.4 8.6 101.5 82.2 217 8 -1.6

1970:1 0.0 6.0 8.5

2 70.6 11.7 11.8

3 0.0 14.4 13.8

4 0.0 51.6 19.7 6.5 19.4 4.1 5.4 105.3 101.4 274 239 -1.7

1971:1 0.0 42.8 29.0

2 46.4 23.7 32.3

3 66.8 43.7 40.1

4 0.0 38.5 36.9 13.5 70.1 4.4 3.6 108.8 101.8 698 -55 -4.3

1972:1 0.0 98.1 48.6

2 0.0 58.6 58.1

3 0.0 47.0 59.0 z

4 0.0 64.4 66.0 65.0 58.6 1.5 1.6 98.7 71.6 256 162 -5.2 C)

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except columns (6) and (8), from Fundacion Mediterranea; 2

column (7), from Di Tella and Dornbusch (1989); column (9), from Kiguel and Liviatan (1989); and column (12), from Di Tella Z

(1983).

Note: All rates of change and interest rates are expressed in percent per year. Horizontal lines indicate the beginning and end g

of the program. All columns except (1), (2), and (3) report annual figures; column (11) includes errors and omissions (a positive B

sign indicates a capital inflow); and column (12) refers to the nonfinancial public sector (a minus sign denotes a deficit).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Table 6. Brazilian 1964 Stabilization

Real Trade Capital Fiscal

Credit to Private Balance Account Balance Q

Private Con- Real Real (In Balance (In >

Inflation M1 Sector sumption GDP Exchange millions (In millions percent r

Devaluation Inflation Rate (4Q (4Q (4Q (Annual (Annual Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of 0

Year/ Rate Rate change) change) change) change) change) (1964 = 100) (1964 = 100) dollars) dollars) GDP)

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

1963:1 0.1 73.4 54.6 58.5 50.7 t,

2 190.0 85.5 66.6 57.6 53.3

3 0.0 78.7 72.3 56.4 49.2

4 0.0 92.4 82.4 64.1 55.0 7.2 3.2 103.9 84.5 112 127 -4.2

1964:1 2,273.6 128.5 95.4 79.1 66.2

2 -40.9 89.2 96.4 90.8 79.8

3 233.3 67.3 93.2 93.7 92.2

4 69.4 62.8 85.3 85.1 80.2 -2.5 3.1 100.0

1965:1 0.0 99.0 79.0 84.5 68.3

2 0.0 67.9 73.7 82.8 64.9

3 0.0 30.6 63.3 84.2 59.9

4 107.4 25.0 52.8 77.6 57.5 -6.3 4.2 95.2 91.2

1966:1 0.0 51.8 42.8 58.5 50.7

2 0.0 53.0 39.5 42.0 48.9

3 0.0 38.6 41.6 26.7 39.9

4 0.0 24.1 41.4 16.7 33.8 4.7 4.9 89.3 79.6

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1967:1 123.7 34.8 37.2 24.9 36.4

2 0.0 34.1 32.8 34.6 42.6

3 0.0 20.1 28.1 42.2 49.4

4 0.0 13.6 25.3 43.6 58.3 9.6 11.4 86.4 73.4 213 54 -1.7

1968:1 97.9 20.9 22.0 50.2 75.3

2 0.0 28.7 20.7 40.4 68.8

3 74.3 25.0 21.9 38.8 70.2

4 14.8 19.0 23.4 43.3 65.4 10.2 9.7 89.3 78.8 26 636 -1.2

1969:1 19.0 22.0 23.6 34.5 53.7

2 5.1 20.1 21.5 32.5 51.0

3 10.2 25.3 21.6 30.0 43.9

4 20.7 28.5 23.9 29.0 42.3 3.2 8.9 91.2 80.3 318 817 -0.6 c

1970:1 13.5 16.8 22.6 27.4 42.5

2 6.4 18.4 22.1 31.2 43.4

3 14.8 28.6 22.9 27.5 35.7

4 21.0 23.9 21.8 26.6 34.7 15.2 11.3 92.3 76.8 232 1,331 -0.4

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except columns (8) and (9), from Kiguel and Liviatan (1989); C

and column (12), from Lemgruber (1977).

Note: All rates of change are expressed in percent per year. Horizontal lines indicate the beginning and end of the program.

Columns (6) through (12) report annual figures; column (11) includes errors and omissions (a positive sign indicates a capital

inflow); and column (12) refers to the operational balance of the nonfinancial public sector (a minus sign denotes a deficit).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Table 7. Uruguayan 1968 Stabilization

Real Trade Capital Fiscal O

Credit to Private Balance Account Balance >

Private Con- Real Real (In Balance (In

Inflation M1 Sector sumption GDP Exchange millions (In millions percent

Devaluation Inflation (4Q (4Q (4Q (Annual (Annual Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of O

Year/ Rate Rate change) change) change) change) change) (1968 = 100) (1968 = 100) dollars) dollars) GDP) 2

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

1967:1 61.5 119.3 63.2 26.4 7.9 7.0

2 11.7 61.8 65.6 34.5 5.0 3.6

3 58.0 191.1 97.3 48.9 1.2 -2.6

4 1,565.6 130.9 121.0 111.8 61.5 -3.6 -4.1 112.1 97.4 5.7 -13 -3.0

1968:1 0.0 268.5 151.6 107.8 61.6 18.9

2 144.1 105.7 167.2 104.6 95.5 -3.4

3 0.0 46.8 125.2 89.2 83.0 9.6

4 0.0 5.3 85.0 54.3 57.1 -1.5 1.6 100.0 100.0 18.3 -31 -1.7

1969:1 0.0 16.6 38.7 70.5 52.2 19.4

2 0.0 19.6 21.2 61.6 22.4 12.5

3 0.0 10.9 12.9 79.2 17.7 -5.8

4 0.0 14.8 15.4 62.2 23.4 8.2 6.1 111.5 90.0 7.7 46 -2.5

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
1970:1 0.0 19.7 16.2 40.3 26.3 -3.6

2 0.0 18.1 15.8 39.4 42.8 35.1

3 0.0 11.5 16.0 19.6 56.8 -6.2

4 0.0 19.9 17.2 15.2 46.1 6.4 4.7 110.0 80.6 9.0 6 -1.3

1971:1 0.0 27.4 19.1 18.5 53.2 19.1

2 0.0 19.0 19.3 28.9 46.4 29.7

3 0.0 28.3 23.6 40.9 41.1 -12.1

4 379.8 60.6 33.0 54.9 48.1 1.0 -1.1 115.7 71.4 -21.2 26 -5.8

1972:1 233.5 90.1 46.9 60.8 74.1 -4.9

2 71.3 124.4 72.2 47.0 91.1 19.0

3 63.7 59.4 81.8 40.8 88.9 -2.0

4 63.8 130.6 99.0 47.2 104.6 -0.2 -3.5 95.9 99.4 8.5 -61 -2.6

1973:1 77.6 160.3 115.2 50.5 92.1 23.0 3

2 16.0 33.4 89.0 67.3 84.8 39.3 C

3 16.4 134.0 108.1 74.3 75.3 -10.9

4 11.9 38.0 83.0 80.0 63.8 3.6 3.3 94.3 104.2 4.0 -64 -1.4 Z

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except columns (6), (7), and (12), from Viana (1990); and columns =

(8) and (9), from Kiguel and Liviatan (1989). C

Note: All rates of change are expressed in percent per year. Horizontal lines indicate the beginning and end of the program.

Columns (6) through (9), (11) and (12) report annual figures; column (11) includes errors and omissions (a positive sign indicates z

a capital inflow); and column (12) reports figures for the nonfinancial public sector (a minus sign denotes a deficit).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
678 CARLOS A. VIGH

Table 8. Argentine 1978 Stabilization (Tablita Program)

Inflation Interest Rates


Inflation

Devalu- Rate Nominal Nominal Real M1

ation Inflation (4Q deposit lending lending (4Q

Year/ Rate Rate change) rate rate rate Spread change)

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

1978:1 112.0 196.3 171.4 152.7 260.6 26.5 64.5 131.4

2 43.0 185.1 188.9 123.6 159.3 14.6 42.0 165.0

3 45.8 126.3 178.6 116.2 144.1 -8.5 10.5 159.9

4 79.9 166.9 167.3 117.8 141.0 -20.8 11.0 159.7

1979:1 76.4 204.3 169.0 113.8 131.1 -3.0 14.7 131.4

2 67.9 138.4 157.3 113.7 128.9 -15.1 23.3 121.9

3 56.5 169.5 168.7 131.2 148.1 26.1 41.7 129.2

4 46.0 96.7 149.0 111.7 131.1 17.3 35.7 137.8

1980:1 35.9 97.1 123.4 85.3 117.9 10.0 25.6 141.2

2 26.8 98.2 113.3 75.0 93.2 11.5 31.1 121.4

3 18.2 73.2 91.0 82.2 104.6 9.1 45.7 115.0

4 12.8 87.6 88.7 75.1 92.6 12.2 -24.8 96.7

1981:1 99.5 71.6 82.3 120.7 170.1 17.6 -85.8 39.4

2 1,233.4 129.8 89.2 170.3 234.1 20.5 -15.3 42.4

3 171.2 177.2 112.8 210.0 275.5 66.9 7.8 48.6

4 142.7 125.0 122.7 127.8 164.3 0.9 -69.4 70.1

1982:1 550.4 161.8 147.5 127.8 157.7 50.4 -42.2 105.5

2 240.6 71.3 130.0 130.7 171.0 -36.2 -94.7 145.0

3 3,673.8 324.5 155.8 95.5 115.1 -51.4 -27.9 245.4

4 140.7 342.6 203.0 152.5 165.1 -39.5 -37.8 247.5

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 679

Capital

Real Trade Account Fiscal

Credit to Private Balance Balance Balance

Private Consump- Real Real Effective (In (In (In

Sector tion GDP Exchange millions millions percent

(4Q (4Q (4Q Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of

change) change) change) (1978 = 100) (1978:4 = 100) dollars) dollars) GDP)

(9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16)

253.3 -1.9 -2.0 128.8 549 913.7

203.7 -5.1 -5.5 118.0 1,011 128.5

172.2 -3.0 -5.4 108.7 1,010 -498.0

181.0 5.3 0.0 100.0 100.0 343 -606.1 -3.2

184.0 16.4 7.2 89.4 457 936.0

204.3 15.7 8.2 83.1 1,137 1,132.3

216.3 13.0 5.4 76.7 447 1,023.0

228.6 9.4 8.3 114.8 72.9 -259 1,394.4 -2.7

224.0 5.6 1.9 68.2 12 1,198.7

188.7 6.2 -2.0 63.3 -113 -877.1

153.3 7.8 2.6 60.4 -442 1,643.3

108.5 10.8 3.6 128.4 53.7 -830 -74.7 -3.6

107.3 9.4 -0.8 50.9 -324 -1,598.1

133.5 1.4 -1.8 66.9 515 827.0

142.1 -11.9 -11.5 71.9 751 348.9

166.0 -14.7 -12.0 114.8 77.8 -230 1,493.8 -8.1

154.6 -15.4 -7.5 95.2 824 619.5

132.4 -16.8 -10.5 108.8 1,131 -2,430.4

203.6 -6.1 -2.9 130.5 512 147.6

210.5 -1.0 1.3 102.5 148.7 297 -671.7 -7.2

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except column

(5), from Balifio (1991); columns (10) and (11), from Central Bank of Argentina;

column (12), from Ramos (1986); and column (13), from Fund staff estimates.

Note: All rates of change and interest rates are expressed in percent per year.

Horizontal lines indicate the beginning and end of the program. Column (6) is

computed using the one-quarter-ahead inflation rate; column (7) is defined as the

ratio of (1 plus) the deposit rate to (1 plus) the three-month LIBOR rate times

(1 plus) the one-quarter-ahead devaluation rate; columns (12) and (16) report

annual figures; column (15) includes errors and omissions (a positive sign indi-

cates a capital flow); and column (16) reports figures for the central government

(a minus sign denotes a deficit).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
680 CARLOS A. VEGH

Table 9. Chilean 1978 Stabilization (Tablita Program)

Inflation Interest Rates

Devalu- Rate Nominal Nominal Real Ml

ation Inflation (4Q deposit lending lending (4Q

Year/ Rate Rate change) rate rate rate Spread change)

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

1977:1 24.5 90.4 149.7 124.6 265.0 108.9 36.3 204.7

2 56.8 74.7 106.4 83.6 148.0 61.5 -9.7 201.0

3 92.4 53.5 78.6 70.8 107.5 38.4 -9.1 154.7

4 76.7 49.9 66.3 99.8 132.1 74.6 36.7 113.0

1978:1 36.5 33.0 52.1 70.9 101.3 49.4 25.6 101.3

2 26.7 34.7 42.5 55.6 79.8 34.7 25.2 92.4

3 15.1 33.4 37.6 55.5 73.9 36.8 30.8 79.1

4 9.2 27.2 32.0 70.0 89.6 51.2 27.8 83.8

1979:1 19.6 25.4 30.1 47.4 67.6 24.5 -8.9 48.9

2 45.7 34.6 30.1 44.1 60.5 5.8 30.1 56.9

3 0.0 51.8 34.4 42.7 59.6 13.1 27.7 56.6

4 0.0 41.1 37.9 46.1 60.8 24.2 27.2 60.3

1980:1 0.0 29.5 39.0 52.0 61.9 21.4 30.7 70.5

2 0.0 33.3 38.7 32.7 43.6 12.1 17.5 58.0

3 0.0 28.1 32.9 31.8 41.0 5.0 18.9 57.9

4 0.0 34.4 31.3 34.2 42.0 20.0 15.1 58.3

1981:1 0.0 18.4 28.4 45.0 52.3 36.4 24.1 52.6

2 0.0 11.7 22.8 40.9 50.7 37.8 19.7 35.3

3 0.0 9.3 18.0 38.8 51.0 41.5 17.1 21.8

4 0.0 6.7 11.4 38.5 54.1 49.7 21.0 15.6

1982:1 0.0 2.9 7.6 38.9 55.2 56.4 -40.4 2.6

2 101.4 -0.8 4.5 32.4 47.7 17.1 -74.1 -3.9

3 343.2 26.1 8.3 50.1 64.2 5.4 -5.4 -6.0

4 40.8 55.8 19.0 73.2 88.4 58.6 58.9 -14.0

1983:1 -0.5 18.7 23.3 33.1 50.3 19.9 -3.5 17.3

2 26.1 25.4 30.8 29.0 44.1 13.6 -6.3 18.0

3 25.9 26.8 30.9 25.0 39.2 10.0 -11.3 23.5

4 27.9 26.5 24.3 24.9 37.7 28.8 10.2 30.5

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION
681

Capital

Real Trade Account Fiscal

Credit to Private Balance Balance Balance

Private Consump- Real Real Effective (In (In (In

Sector tion GDP Exchange millions millions percent

(4Q (4Q (4Q Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of

change) change) change) (1978 = 100) (1978:1 = 100) dollars) dollars) GDP)

(9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16)

11.7 11.9 ... 152

19.8 9.6 ... 39

15.4 6.1 ... -135

178.0 3.6 7.8 101.8 ... 29 677 -1.1

9.8 3.6 100.0 141

14.7 6.4 102.1 -154

8.1 8.9 106.0 -103

145.0 13.0 7.3 100.0 107.0 -122 1,818 -0.2

14.6 10.4 105.4 129

4.8 8.2 102.4 6

5.1 8.8 104.4 1

87.0 9.3 6.4 108.3 98.4 -72 2,141 4.9

71.1 5.6 6.7 92.9 217

74.9 3.0 5.7 88.2 70

65.7 9.4 3.6 87.0 -243

76.8 13.3 7.7 118.1 83.0 -348 3,216 5.5

73.7 10.5 8.5 76.9 -242

75.9 7.7 8.9 71.7 -437

69.8 4.2 7.4 68.9 -556

39.4 -7.1 -2.8 128.8 71.4 -383 4,800 2.4

51.8 -13.7 -9.5 71.2 19

53.0 -16.0 -1.5 70.0 181

44.0 -16.1 -4.7 87.6 247

57.1 -16.7 -14.3 128.3 100.5 254 946 -2.3

41.4 -9.4 -7.7 103.8 364

26.4 -2.4 -2.8 96.0 448

24.4 -1.7 -11.8 94.7 337

13.0 2.4 6.1 114.7 97.6 228 -3,168 -2.6

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except

columns (10) and (11), from Arrau and De Gregorio (1991); column (12), from

Ramos; and column (16), from IMF, Government Finance Statistics (various

issues).

Note: All rates of change and interest rates are expressed in percent per year.

Horizontal lines indicate the beginning and end of the program; column (6) is

computed using the one-quarter-ahead inflation rate; column (7) is defined as the

ratio of (1 plus) the deposit rate to (1 plus) the three-month LIBOR rate times

(1 plus) the one-quarter-ahead devaluation rate; column (9) for 1977 through

1979 and columns (12), (15), and (16) report annual figures; column (15) includes

errors and omissions (a positive sign indicates a capital inflow); and column (16)

reports figures for the general goverment (a minus sign denotes a deficit).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
682 CARLOS A. VEGH

Table 10. Uruguayan 1978 Stabilization (Tablita Program)

Inflation Interest Rates

Devalu- Rate Nominal Nominal Real Ml

ation Inflation (4Q deposit lending lending (4Q

Year/ Rate Rate change) rate rate rate Spread change)

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

1978:1 0.0 23.7 48.1 49.1 76.7 15.9 -17.8 36.5

2 44.4 52.5 46.6 46.4 73.1 17.2 -20.5 62.3

3 49.3 47.6 41.9 50.7 74.9 17.1 -10.1 52.8

4 34.1 49.4 42.8 42.7 71.3 1.4 -5.2 85.1

1979:1 28.2 68.9 54.4 42.7 69.5 -2.2 -2.0 97.3

2 23.8 73.2 59.4 39.1 61.9 -14.8 2.6 103.5

3 17.2 90.0 69.8 41.2 62.5 -13.1 9.4 118.7

4 11.4 86.9 79.5 50.7 68.3 0.9 16.1 71.7

1980:1 9.5 66.7 79.0 48.6 67.1 17.8 9.9 57.0

2 16.9 41.8 70.2 52.4 68.3 6.9 1.1 23.6

3 24.2 57.4 62.4 48.6 65.4 22.9 -1.1 23.1

4 23.8 34.6 49.6 50.2 65.4 32.2 9.9 47.4

1981:1 17.4 25.1 39.2 45.9 63.6 26.2 14.9 37.8

2 11.8 29.7 36.2 43.2 57.4 12.0 8.7 44.6

3 18.5 40.4 32.3 45.9 58.5 26.6 13.2 25.0

4 15.0 25.2 29.9 47.5 59.6 48.2 9.7 8.3

1982:1 15.0 7.7 25.2 41.7 49.1 33.8 7.4 -2.5

2 17.5 11.4 20.5 44.8 54.6 26.0 -0.2 -5.0

3 26.6 22.7 16.5 54.0 66.0 39.7 -97.0 -5.3

4 4,098.1 18.8 15.0 60.8 76.1 -26.5 39.2 39.2

1983:1 -11.3 139.6 40.4 79.8 105.3 56.0 33.9 55.2

2 -5.4 31.6 46.4 73.7 101.9 48.4 -23.8 63.6

3 64.9 36.0 50.2 64.2 84.8 25.6 -36.0 69.2

4 95.0 47.2 58.5 67.1 84.8 18.4 -53.1 9.0

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 683

Capital

Real Trade Account Fiscal

Credit to Private Balance Balance Balance

Private Consump- Real Real Effective (In (In (In

Sector tion GDP Exchange millions millions percent

(4Q (4Q (4Q Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of

change) change) change) (1978 = 100) (1978:3 = 100) dollars) dollars) GDP)

(9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16)

73.9 1.5 95.9 26.7

80.9 10.6 93.4 16.4

79.5 6.9 100.0 -34.1

76.4 5.6 8.5 100.0 101.9 -30.0 265.3 -0.8

92.8 11.9 98.2 -15.3

105.8 5.5 92.4 -37.8

110.5 7.9 87.3 -103.9

120.2 13.6 4.3 96.9 78.0 -157.9 430.9 0.2

115.1 6.3 70.8 -198.5

93.6 1.3 69.3 -139.4

89.9 4.9 68.1 -79.8

79.7 -1.6 6.1 97.3 68.3 -13.9 827.3 0.2

67.2 4.9 64.4 -98.5

59.4 5.0 58.9 -57.4

52.4 1.8 54.5 -77.4

40.4 -2.7 -4.4 104.5 54.9 -45.2 495.3 -1.4

30.6 -7.5 62.2 -64.9

24.7 -9.0 53.7 -50.7

18.5 -17.9 51.8 20.1

90.9 -13.3 -8.5 104.2 63.3 85.8 -181.4 -9.0

76.6 -11.8 92.4 77.2

45.6 -7.6 89.4 105.0

47.7 3.2 88.1 29.0

10.5 -13.6 -2.6 82.7 90.5 93.6 -5.9 -3.9

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except

columns (4) and (5), from Perez-Capanero and Leone (1991); column (12), from

Ramos (1986); and column (16), from IMF, Government Finance Statistics (var-

ious issues).

Note: All rates of change and interest rates are expressed in percent per year.

Horizontal lines indicate the beginning and end of the program; column (6) is

computed using the one-quarter-ahead inflation rate; column (7) is defined as the

ratio of (1 plus) the deposit rate to (1 plus) the three-month LIBOR rate times

(1 plus) the one-quarter-ahead devaluation rate; columns (10), (12) (15), and (16)

report annual figures; column (15) includes errors and omissions (a positive sign

indicates a capital inflow); and column (16) reports figures for the general

goverment (a minus sign denotes a deficit).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
684 CARLOS A. VEGH

Table 11. Argentine 1985 Stabilization (Austral Plan)

Inflation Interest Rates

Rate Nominal Nominal Real

Devaluation Rate Inflation (4Q deposit lending lending

Year/ Official Parallel Rate change) rate rate rate Spread

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

1984:1 291.7 156.9 508.6 446.6 232.3 339.6 -41.4 -49.9

2 501.2 54.0 650.7 559.1 333.5 618.1 -22.6 -62.2

3 929.8 92.6 827.4 655.3 463.6 708.0 -11.2 -65.0

4 1,337.4 86.7 810.0 688.0 558.0 1,808.0 72.7 -55.8

1985:1 1,252.1 190.9 1004.4 814.6 671.0 1,267.5 -23.5 -76.2

2 2,875.7 148.9 1,687.8 1,036.2 1,315.0 3,141.0 804.0 1207.0

3 0.0 24.4 258.5 795.9 51.1 139.5 82.1 39.7

4 0.0 -11.8 31.6 452.4 44.3 93.2 37.6 33.4

1986:1 0.0 8.2 40.4 229.9 44.3 83.6 12.0 -12.7

2 53.1 -2.0 63.9 81.5 46.6 68.9 -20.7 -34.0

3 107.3 51.3 113.0 59.4 67.5 110.1 1.4 -17.7

4 91.5 39.1 107.2 78.5 86.6 167.6 25.1 -21.6

1987:1 124.1 27.7 113.9 98.3 78.0 135.7 24.7 -10.5

2 87.0 14.3 88.9 105.5 83.4 162.6 -16.8 -62.6

3 357.5 97.2 215.7 126.7 195.0 365.9 6.8 -33.4

4 313.2 43.8 336.1 173.1 239.1 306.6 45.2

1988:1 291.5 57.9 179.9 192.1 386.6 391.6 -15.3 -38.4

2 638.2 90.0 480.0 286.7 610.8 607.7 -32.9 84.8

3 258.0 56.8 954.8 422.8 497.1 520.1 93.6 252.6

4 56.2 13.4 220.2 383.9 236.5 201.8 4.4 57.5

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION
685

Capital Fiscal

Real Trade Account Bal-

Credit to Private Balance Balance ance

Private Con- Real Real Effective (In (In (In

M1 Sector sumption GDP Exchange millions millions percent

(4Q (4Q (4Q (4Q Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of

change) change) change) change) (1980 =100) (1985:1 =100) dollars) dollars) GDP)

(9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) (17)

502.9 366.7 3.7 1.9 109.3 1,379 -268 -11.0

545.5 429.8 5.8 4.2 97.7 1,462 -16 -9.3

550.0 497.2 8.9 1.1 91.7 886 -306 -6.9

501.6 554.1 5.5 2.7 129.1 98.8 255 598 -9.3

486.3 684.8 -1.1 -1.1 100.0 900 -103 -10.1

728.6 1030.6 -8.7 -4.6 109.8 1,712 111 -6.5

761.6 676.6 -13.2 -8.8 121.5 1,411 -264 -3.0

571.5 372.1 -2.6 -3.1 100.0 116.7 855 581 -2.0

372.9 177.4 0.1 0.7 116.4 649 -293 -4.7

153.8 46.4 10.9 6.2 111.6 888 918 -2.2

85.2 62.4 15.7 11.6 109.3 632 -84 -1.5

84.8 83.7 4.8 4.4 109.3 109.5 277 179 -8.7

95.6 110.6 6.9 3.5 116.0 343 595 -5.1

84.2 119.5 0.2 3.5 117.0 470 -494 -5.7

86.7 149.3 -0.5 1.3 116.2 123 -443 -8.1

124.7 196.0 -1.6 1.8 102.2 134.6 81 204 -5.9

121.1 239.2 -0.2 2.9 137.2 641 -95 -9.3

191.0 343.6 -4.4 -0.4 138.6 1,013 -176 -5.1

340.4 398.1 -11.6 -5.5 131.2 1,335 614 -3.5

337.9 355.7 -7.1 -6.7 97.3 121.1 1,253 -77 -6.1

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except

columns (2) and (17), from Heymann (1991); columns (11) and (12), from Central

Bank of Argentina; column (13), from Kiguel and Liviatan (1989); and column

(14), from Fund staff estimates.

Note: All rates of change and interest rates are expressed in percent per year.

Horizontal lines indicate the beginning and end of the program. Column (13)

reports annual figures; column (7) is computed using the one-quarter-ahead

inflation rate; column (8) is defined as the ratio of (1 plus) the deposit rate to (1

plus) the three-month LIBOR rate times (1 plus) the one-quarter-ahead devalu-

ation rate; column (16) includes errors and omissions (a positive sign indicates

a capital flow); and column (17) refers to the operational balance of the nonfinan-

cial public sector (a minus sign denotes a deficit).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
686 CARLOS A. VEGH

Table 12. Brazilian 1986 Stabilization (Cruzado Plan)

Inflation Interest Rates

Rate Nominal Nominal Real

Devaluation Rate Inflation (4Q deposit savings savings

Year/ Official Parallel Rate change) rate rate rate Spread

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

1984:1 238.8 55.0 195.3 187.6 219.7 ... ... 3.3

2 180.7 83.4 190.2 195.4 219.1 ... ... -13.3

3 230.0 318.4 216.9 193.6 302.2 ... ... 2.9

4 249.3 272.1 214.8 204.1 329.5 ... ... 2.3

1985:1 281.5 259.7 273.6 222.5 350.0 309.0 51.0 26.6

2 226.1 274.0 170.8 217.0 268.3 248.4 -2.7 16.1

3 193.2 380.1 258.0 226.8 258.3 176.9 -20.0 2.6

4 223.0 225.3 246.4 234.7 305.0 284.4 -26.0 23.6

1986:1 203.0 254.5 419.6 263.5 269.9 327.1 213.0 242.8

2 0.0 102.7 36.4 206.2 22.6 21.7 11.7 14.5

3 0.0 74.4 9.0 127.5 36.7 27.4 1.1 -4.1

4 34.2 101.3 26.1 76.7 108.7 78.8 -51.4 -59.7

1987:1 388.5 24.6 268.1 62.1 491.9 612.0 -26.0 -62.2

2 1,372.2 197.0 862.5 164.2 524.4 948.5 134.3 198.3

3 95.4 473.7 347.6 276.0 193.4 161.4 -27.8 -30.6

4 294.0 163.3 262.3 389.6 394.4 325.3 -44.0 -27.5

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 687

Capital Fiscal

Real Trade Account Bal-

Credit to Private Balance Balance ance

Private Con- Real Real Effective (In (In (In

M1 Sector sumption GDP Exchange millions millions percent

(4Q (4Q (4Q (4Q Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of

change) change) change) change) (1985= 100) (1985:4= 100) dollars) dollars) GDP)

(9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) (17)

109.0 131.7 -6.2 3.9 93.8 2,386 -1,472

119.5 156.2 -2.8 4.0 95.7 3,600 -1,065

148.7 175.0 2.5 5.7 94.8 3,623 -1,282

204.1 205.3 6.9 10.1 94.1 93.0 3,477 -1,780 -5.8

208.9 221.4 6.6 12.2 96.8 2,021 -196

243.5 241.6 2.3 3.6 106.3 3,484 -2,077

304.5 262.9 12.3 9.2 102.9 3,627 -3,053

335.1 262.4 14.4 10.9 100.0 100.0 3,334 -3,496 -13.0

641.0 345.4 10.9 4.2 104.2 96.1 2,460 -1,832

729.5 298.9 16.4 14.1 110.9 97.6 3,700 -3,286

491.9 262.0 11.1 12.3 112.9 93.1 2,484 -1,860

330.8 214.2 5.5 7.5 116.5 87.2 -340 -1,540 -14.5

146.3 150.1 10.2 11.0 103.2 87.2 585 -1,505

99.3 196.9 2.8 6.6 105.1 86.5 2,887 -3,299

146.1 204.9 -7.1 -2.2 97.2 89.5 4,380 -2,475

212.2 231.6 -3.1 -2.0 104.3 80.5 3,306 -3,805 -14.4

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except column

(2), from Centro de Estudios Economicos; columns (11) and (12), from Conjun-

tura Economica; column (13), from IBGE; column (14), from Fund staff esti-

mates; and column (17), from IMF, Government Finance Statistics (various is-

sues).

Note: All rates of change and interest rates are expressed in percent per year.

Horizontal lines indicate the beginning and the end of the program. Column (7)

is computed using the one-quarter-ahead inflation rate; column (8) is defined as

the ratio of (1 plus) the deposit rate to (1 plus) the three-month LIBOR rate times

(1 plus) the one-quarter-ahead devaluation rate; column (13) reports annual

figures for 1984 and 1985; column (16) includes errors and omissions (a positive

sign indicates a capital inflow); and column (17) reports annual figures for the

central government (a minus sign denotes a deficit).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
688 CARLOS A. VEGH

Table 13. Israeli 1985 Stabilization

Inflation Interest Rates


Inflation

Devalu- Rate Nominal Nominal Real Ml

ation Inflation (4Q deposit lending lending (4Q

Year/ Rate Rate change) rate rate rate Spread change)

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

1984:1 309.0 334.2 225.1 239.5 452.4 0.8 -45.6 128.0

2 466.1 447.8 296.0 357.8 710.7 54.0 -50.6 195.0

3 730.7 426.5 401.9 516.2 1,062.0 43.3 -14.2 264.6

4 541.5 710.9 464.5 639.9 1,067.1 315.8 106.1 351.2

1985:1 226.4 180.7 406.2 215.4 499.8 28.8 -38.1 405.8

2 367.5 365.8 386.1 305.8 715.3 71.5 95.7 354.1

3 91.6 375.4 373.8 150.9 612.2 406.4 123.3 385.0

4 3.9 40.7 205.8 43.0 186.3 172.2 32.4 244.8

1986:1 -0.2 5.2 139.2 21.6 78.9 38.4 12.7 248.3

2 0.1 29.2 73.6 14.5 51.7 34.8 9.2 190.8

3 -2.1 12.6 21.1 17.7 53.4 18.9 12.2 126.6

4 -1.2 29.0 18.5 20.5 57.0 28.1 -16.8 112.9

1987:1 36.5 22.5 23.2 28.4 67.8 42.2 20.0 51.2

2 0.6 18.0 20.4 21.7 65.8 51.7 13.4 64.3

3 0.1 9.3 19.5 13.3 57.5 34.0 26.4 56.7

4 -16.4 17.5 16.8 14.2 54.7 31.5 0.2 49.5

1988: 1 5.6 17.7 15.6 14.4 46.3 20.2 -8.8 52.6

2 17.2 21.8 16.5 12.0 42.3 32.7 -0.9 33.7

3 5.1 7.3 15.9 13.2 40.0 14.8 -5.5 27.9

4 10.6 22.0 17.0 18.6 38.0 5.6 -20.0 11.3

1989:1 36.0 30.7 20.1 17.7 39.5 17.1 -28.2 10.6

2 49.3 19.2 19.5 13.6 32.4 17.4 9.4 26.3

3 -5.5 12.8 21.0 11.9 27.7 7.0 6.9 33.4

4 -4.0 19.4 20.4 13.3 26.9 12.7 -2.0 44.3

1990:1 6.5 12.6 15.9 ... ... ... ... 32.4

2 17.9 21.1 16.4 14.4 27.2 6.9 9.8 25.9

3 -4.0 19.0 18.0 13.9 25.8 4.8 7.2 20.1

4 -1.7 20.0 18.2 13.9 25.3 12.0 -29.1 30.7

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 689

Capital

Real Trade Account Fiscal

Credit to Private Balance Balance Balance

Private Consump- Real Real Effective (In (In (In

Sector tion GDP Exchange millions millions percent

(4Q (4Q (4Q Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of

change) change) change) (1985:2 = 100) (1985:2 = 100) dollars) dollars) GDP)

(9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16)

230.0 -7.6 -0.1 96.1 98.7 -560 458

305.5 -4.0 0.3 105.9 96.7 -672 873

419.3 -0.4 4.7 110.8 97.5 -761 -256

468.6 -3.9 4.4 101.0 100.8 -473 -344 -13.0

426.0 3.7 2.8 105.9 99.1 -599 -229

407.6 0.5 8.0 100.0 100.0 -803 224

327.5 -11.5 5.2 85.3 103.9 -472 -299

173.4 3.2 -0.6 84.3 103.6 -448 -466 -2.8

118.0 4.2 4.7 97.1 105.8 -312 -349

63.8 9.9 0.5 102.0 104.1 -575 -141

32.2 23.2 4.4 102.0 105.2 -479 301

36.4 14.1 5.1 104.9 101.8 -459 -486 0.7

42.0 10.9 3.8 102.0 107.9 -857 665

40.9 9.6 7.8 112.7 108.1 -1,068 573

39.3 6.5 6.1 106.9 105.5 -895 436

36.2 9.3 5.8 113.7 105.8 -846 -196 -3.3

29.1 11.1 8.0 112.7 102.0 -631 -23

29.1 2.1 0.2 117.6 98.7 -860 589

26.7 1.9 1.0 115.7 95.6 -722 62

28.5 2.5 1.7 118.6 93.6 -800 -1,284 -8.1

26.9 -3.5 -1.7 110.8 96.3 -416 1,456

25.9 3.1 4.4 117.6 94.5 -632 -185

26.9 2.7 1.8 117.6 98.0 -321 -347

21.5 0.5 2.1 113.7 96.8 -338 -737 -3.9

22.3 2.0 5.5 111.8 97.2 -454 -371

20.1 2.0 3.5 116.7 98.0 -677 134

19.1 6.6 5.6 113.7 100.4 -671 -64

23.2 4.4 5.6 112.7 100.0 -1,014 241 -4.4

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except column

12), from Bank of Israel; column (13), from Fund staff estimates; and column

16), from IMF, Government Finance Statistics (various issues).

Note: All rates of change and interest rates are expressed in percent per year.

Horizontal line indicates the beginning of the program. Column (6) is computed

using the one-quarter-ahead inflation rate; column (7) is defined as the ratio of

(1 plus) the deposit rate to (1 plus) the three-month LIBOR rate times (1 plus)

the one-quarter-ahead devaluation rate; column (15) includes errors and omis-

sions (a positive sign indicates a capital inflow); and column (16) reports figures

for the central government (a minus sign denotes a deficit).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
690 CARLOS A. VEGH

Table 14. Mexican 1987 Stabilization

Inflation Interest Rates


Inflation

Devalu- Rate Nominal Nominal Real M1

ation Inflation (4Q deposit treasury bill treasury (4Q

Year/ Rate Rate change) rate rate bill rate Spread change)

Quarter (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

1987:1 121.0 139.1 109.4 94.3 103.8 -16.0 -12.6 77.9

2 108.9 142.7 124.3 94.3 98.8 -18.3 0.0 92.5

3 81.3 143.3 134.2 94.3 96.3 -27.2 -53.7 122.9

4 291.6 169.5 148.4 106.1 113.4 -42.7 68.1 118.8

1988:1 13.5 272.3 177.4 127.7 134.5 51.9 112.8 132.0

2 0.0 54.3 147.7 50.4 52.1 27.4 40.0 146.1

3 0.0 19.4 107.3 38.3 41.1 25.0 27.5 101.5

4 0.0 12.9 66.8 38.3 48.9 19.5 9.0 68.6

1989:1 16.3 24.6 26.9 38.3 49.2 27.4 8.3 39.8

2 16.3 17.2 18.4 38.3 52.9 34.5 8.9 17.6

3 15.6 13.7 17.0 32.9 38.7 16.0 6.2 25.2

4 14.9 19.6 18.7 35.8 39.2 -4.7 9.0 37.6

1990:1 14.7 46.0 23.5 40.4 44.4 16.8 14.7 38.0

2 13.0 23.6 25.2 34.7 38.0 11.0 12.2 49.4

3 10.7 24.3 28.0 26.3 30.2 3.5 8.4 42.7

4 7.8 25.8 29.6 23.5 26.5 -4.6 8.7 63.4

1991:1 4.9 32.7 26.5 20.8 22.9 6.7 7.6 70.1

2 5.1 15.3 24.3 17.2 19.5 7.3 5.0 63.6

3 5.1 11.4 21.0 15.1 17.6 -1.7 6.6 100.0

4 2.0 19.6 19.5 15.3 17.0 -5.2 7.9 122.5

Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues); except

columns (10), (11), (12), and (16), from Banco Central de Mexico; and column

(13), from Fund staff estimates.

Note: All rates of change and interest rates are expressed in percent per year.

Horizontal line indicates the beginning of the program. Column (6) is computed

using the one-quarter-ahead inflation rate; column (7) is defined as the ratio of

REFERENCES

Agenor, Pierre-Richard, and Mark P. Taylor, "Testing for Credibility Effects,"

Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund (September 1992), pp. 545-71.

Arrau, Patricio, and Jose De Gregorio, "Financial Innovation and Money De-

mand: Theory and Empirical Implementation," Policy Research and Exter-

nal Affairs Working Paper No. 585 (Washington: World Bank, 1991).

Balino, Tomas J.T., "The Argentine Banking Crisis of 1980," in Banking Crises:

Cases and Issues, ed. by V. Sundararajan and Tomas J.T. Baliiio (Washing-

ton: International Monetary Fund, 1991).

Barkai, Haim, "The Role of Monetary Policy in Israel's 1985 Stabilization Ef-

fort," IMF Working Paper 90/29 (Washington: International Monetary

Fund, April 1990).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 691

Capital

Real Trade Account Fiscal

Credit to Private Balance Balance Balance

Private Consump- Real Real Effective (In (In (In

Sector tion GDP Exchange millions millions percent

(4Q (4Q (4Q Real Wage Rate of U.S. of U.S. of

change) change) change) (1987:4 = 100) (1987:4 = 100) dollars) dollars) GDP)

(9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16)

78.4 -2.2 -0.6 113.0 2,315 430

92.5 -2.3 -0.3 111.2 2,445 2,632

118.0 0.8 4.7 102.7 1,903 -155

158.1 4.8 6.3 100.0 100.0 1,770 -2,756 1.8

127.8 2.1 3.1 96.5 1,537 -2,751

125.6 2.4 1.3 88.0 854 -1,300

87.8 1.8 0.8 81.4 -267 -2,777

82.9 4.5 1.0 98.1 80.7 -456 -1,881 -3.6

98.6 7.2 2.6 81.0 237 206

100.4 7.6 4.9 80.3 61 -573

109.9 7.0 4.1 79.6 -293 3,735

97.6 3.0 2.4 96.8 80.0 -650 379 -1.7

94.4 5.0 3.3 80.2 215 -1,121

84.0 4.4 2.6 78.6 -1,288 2,927

82.8 5.9 4.7 77.8 -1,021 3,861

73.5 8.0 5.9 105.5 77.2 -932 4,355 2.3

75.7 4.7 4.1 75.3 -1,635 2,158

73.0 3.5 5.6 71.6 -2,413 4,571

66.5 3.8 3.6 69.9 ...

62.1 4.7 3.0 115.5 68.6 .... 3.3

(1 plus) the deposit rate to (1 plus) the three-month LIBOR rate times (1 plus)

the one-quarter-ahead devaluation rate; columns (12) and (16) report annual

figures; column (15) includes errors and omissions (a positive sign indicates a

capital inflow); and column (16) reports figures for the operational balance of

the public sector (a minus sign denotes a deficit).

Bomberger, William A., and Gail E. Makinen, "The Hungarian Hyperinflation

and Stabilization of 1945-1946," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91

(October 1983), pp. 801-24.

Bresciani-Turroni, Costantino, The Economics of Inflation: A Study of Currency

Depreciation in Post-War Germany (London: G. Allen and Unwin, Ltd.,

1937).

Bruno, Michael, Guido Di Tella, Rudiger Dornbusch, and Stanley Fischer, eds.,

Inflation Stabilization: The Experience of Israel, Argentina, Brazil, Bolivia,

and Mexico (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1988).

Bruno, Michael, Stanley Fischer, Elhanan Helpman, and Nissan Liviatan, eds.,

Lessons of Economic Stabilization and Its Aftermath (Cambridge, Massachu-

setts: MIT Press, 1991).

Bufman, Gil, and Leonardo Leiderman, "Simulating an Optimizing Model of

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
692 CARLOS A. VEGH

Currency Substitution," Revista de Andlisis Ec6nomico, Vol. 7 (1992),

pp. 109-24.

Cagan, Phillip, "The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation," in Studies in the

Quantity Theory of Money, ed. by Milton Friedman (Chicago: University of

Chicago Press, 1956).

,"Hyperinflation," in Money, ed. by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and

Peter Newman (New York: The Macmillan Press Limited, 1989).

Calvo, Guillermo A., "Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework,"

Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12 (September 1983), pp. 383-98.

, "Temporary Stabilization: Predetermined Exchange Rates," Journal of

Political Economy, Vol. 94 (December 1986), pp. 1319-29.

, and Carlos A. Vegh, "Credibility and the Dynamics of Stabilization

Policy: A Basic Framework," IMF Working Paper 90/110 (Washington:

International Monetary Fund, 1990); forthcoming in the Proceedings of the

VI World Congress of the Econometric Society (Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press).

(1991a), "Exchange Rate-Based Stabilization Under Imperfect Credibil-

ity," IMF Working Paper 91/77 (Washington: International Monetary Fund,

August).

(1991b), "Exchange Rate-Based Stabilization: The Dynamics of Non-

credible Policy" (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

, "Stabilization Dynamics and Backward-Looking Contracts" (unpub-

lished; Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

Capie, Forrest, "Conditions in Which Very Rapid Inflation Has Appeared," The

National Bureau Method, International Capital Mobility and Other Essays,

ed. by Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer, Carnegie-Rochester Conference

Series on Public Policy, Vol. 24 (1986), pp. 115-69.

Corbo, Vittorio, "Reforms and Macroeconomic Adjustments in Chile During

1974-84," World Development, Vol. 13 (August 1985), pp. 893-916.

, Jaime de Melo, and James Tybout, "What Went Wrong with the Recent

Reforms in the Southern Cone," Economic Development and Cultural

Change, Vol. 34 (April 1986), pp. 607-40.

De Pablo, Juan Carlos, "Relative Prices, Income Distribution and Stabilization

Plans: The Argentine Experience, 1967-1970," Journal of Development

Economics, Vol. 1 (December 1974), pp. 167-89.

Di Tella, Guido, Argentina Under Peron, 1973-76 (New York: St. Martin's Press,

1983).

, "Argentina's Economy Under a Labour-Based Government, 1973-76,"

in The Political Economy of Argentina, 1964-83, ed. by Guido Di Tella and

Rudiger Dornbusch (London: McMillan Press, 1989).

, and Rudiger Dornbusch, eds., The Political Economy of Argentina,

1964-83 (London: McMillan Press, 1989).

Dornbusch, Rudiger, "Stabilization Policies in Developing Countries: What

Have We Learned?" World Development, Vol. 10 (September 1982), pp.

701-708.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
693
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION

,and Stanley Fischer, "Stopping Hyperinflations Past and Present,"

Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Band 122 (March 1986), pp. 1-47.

Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Mario Henrique Simonsen, "Inflation Stabilization

with Incomes Policy Support: A Review of the Experience in Argentina,

Brazil, and Israel" (New York: Group of Thirty, 1987).

Drazen, Allan, "Can Exchange Rate Freezes Induce Business Cycles?" (unpub-

lished; College Park, Maryland: University of Maryland, 1990).

Edwards, Sebastian, "Stabilization and Liberalization Policies in Eastern Eu-

rope: Lessons from Latin America" (unpublished; Los Angeles: University

of California, 1990).

, and Alejandra Cox Edwards, Monetarism and Liberalization: The

Chilean Experiment (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, reprint, 1991).

Fauvel, Yvon, and Lucie Samson, "Intertemporal Substitution and Durable

Goods: An Empirical Analysis," Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 24

(February 1991), pp. 192-205.

Finch, M.H.J., "Stabilization Policy in Uruguay since the 1950s," in Inflation and

Stabilization in Latin America, ed. by Rosemary Thorp and Laurence White-

head (New York: Holmes & Meier, 1979).

Fischer, Stanley, "Exchange Rate Versus Money Targets in Disinflation," Chap.

8 in Indexing, Inflation, and Economic Policy (Cambridge, Massachusetts:

MIT Press, 1986).

Foxley, Alejandro, "Stabilization Policies and Stagflation: The Cases of Brazil

and Chile," World Development, Vol. 8 (September 1980), pp. 887-912.

Garber, Peter M., "Transition from Inflation to Price Stability," Monetary

Regimes and Protectionism, ed. by Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer,

Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 16 (Spring

1982), pp. 887-912.

Guidotti, Pablo E., and Carlos A. V6gh, "Losing Credibility: The Stabilization

Blues" (unpublished; Washington: Internal Monetary Fund, 1991).

Gordon, Robert J., "Why Stopping Inflation May Be Costly: Evidence from

Fourteen Historical Episodes," in Inflation: Causes and Effects, ed. by

Robert E. Hall (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982).

Hanson, James, and Jaime de Melo, "External Shocks, Financial Reforms, and

Stabilization Attempts in Uruguay During 1974-83," World Development,

Vol. 13 (August 1985), pp. 917-39.

Heymann, Daniel, "From Sharp Disinflation to Hyperinflation, Twice: The

Argentine Experience," in Lessons of Economic Stabilization and Its After-

math, ed. by Michael Bruno, Stanley Fischer, Elhanan Helpman, and Nissan

Liviatan (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1991).

International Monetary Fund, Government Finance Statistics (Washington: Inter-

national Monetary Fund, various issues).

, International Financial Statistics (Washington: International Monetary

Fund, various issues).

Kafka, Alexandre, "The Brazilian Stabilization Program, 1964-66," Journal of

Political Economy, Vol. 75, (supplement, August 1967), pp. 596-634.

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
CARLOS A. VEGH
694

Keynes, John Maynard, The Economic Consequences of Peace (London:

MacMillan Press, 1920).

Kiguel, Miguel, and Nissan Liviatan, "Inflationary Rigidities and Orthodox

Stabilization Policies: Lessons from Latin America," The World Bank Eco-

nomic Review, Vol. 2 (September 1988), pp. 273-98.

,"The Old and the New in Heterodox Stabilization Programs: Lessons

from the 1960s and the 1980s," Policy Planning, and Research Department

Working Paper Series No. 323 (Washington: World Bank, 1989).

(1992a), "The Business Cycle Associated with Exchange Rate-Based

Stabilizations," The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 6 (May), pp. 279-

305.

(1992b), "Stopping Three Big Inflations" (unpublished; Washington:

World Bank).

Layton, W.T., and Charles Rist, The Economic Situation of Austria (Geneva:

League of Nations, 1925).

Lemgruber, Antonio C., "Inflation in Brazil," in Worldwide Inflation: Theory

and Recent Experience, ed. by Lawrence B. Krause and Walter S. Salant

(Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1977).

Llach, Juan J., "Las Hiperestabilizaciones sin Mitos" (unpublished; Buenos

Aires: Instituto Torcuato Di Tella, 1990).

Makinen, Gail E., "The Greek Stabilization of 1944-46," American Economic

Review, Vol. 74 (December 1984), pp. 1067-74.

, and G. Thomas Woodward, "The Taiwanese Hyperinflation and Stabi-

lization of 1945-52," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 21 (Febru-

ary 1989), pp. 90-105.

Mitchell, Brian R., European Historical Statistics: 1750-1970 (New York: Colum-

bia University Press, 1975).

Morales, Juan Antonio, "Inflation Stabilization in Bolivia," in Inflation Stabiliza-

tion: The Experience of Israel, Argentina, Brazil, Bolivia, and Mexico, ed.

by Michael Bruno, Guido Di Tella, Rudiger Dornbusch, and Stanley Fischer

(Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1988), pp. 307-46.

Ostry, Jonathan D., and Carmen M. Reinhart, "Private Saving and Terms of

Trade Shocks: Evidence from Developing Countries," Staff Papers, Inter-

national Monetary Fund, Vol. 39 (September 1992), pp. 495-517.

Pazos, Felipe, Chronic Inflation in Latin America (New York: Praeger Publishers,

1972).

Perez-Campanero, Juan, and Alfredo M. Leone, "Liberalization and Financial

Crisis in Uruguay (1974-87)," in Banking Crisis: Cases and Issues, ed. by V.

Sundararajan and Tomas J.T. Baliiio (Washington: International Monetary

Fund, 1991).

Petrecolla, Alberto, "Unbalanced Development, 1958-1962," in The Political

Economy of Argentina, 1946-83, ed. by Guido Di Tella and Rudiger Dorn-

busch (London: MacMillan Press, 1989).

Ramos, Joseph, Neoconservative Economics in the Southern Cone of Latin Amer-

ica, 1973-1983 (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1986).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
STOPPING HIGH INFLATION 695

Reinhart, Carmen M., and Carlos A. Vegh, "Nominal Interest Rates, Consump-

tion Booms, and Lack of Credibility: A Quantitative Examination" (unpub-

lished; Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

Rodriguez, Carlos Alfredo, "The Argentine Stabilization Plan of December

20th," World Development, Vol. 10 (September 1982), pp. 801-11.

Rostowski, Jacek, "The Benefits of Currency Substitution During High Inflation

and Stabilization," Revista de Analisis Econ6mico, Vol. 7 (1992), pp. 91-107.

Sachs, Jeffrey, "The Dollar and the Policy Mix: 1985," Brookings Papers on

Economic Activity: 1 (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1985), pp.

117-97.

, "The Bolivian Hyperinflation and Stabilization," NBER Working Paper

No. 2073 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Re-

search, 1986).

Sargent, Thomas J., "The Ends of Four Big Inflations," in Inflation: Causes and

Effects, ed. by Robert E. Hall (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982).

Siklos, Pierre L., "The End of the Hungarian Hyperinflation of 1945-46,"

Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 21 (May 1989), pp. 135-47.

Vegh, Carlos A., "Stopping High Inflation: An Analytical Overview," IMF

Working Paper 91/107 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, Novem-

ber 1991).

Viana, Luis, "Uruguay's Stabilization Plan of 1968" (unpublished; Uruguay:

CERES, 1990).

Wicker, Elmus, "Terminating Hyperinflation in the Dismembered Hapsburg

Monarchy," American Economic Review, Vol. 76 (June 1986), pp. 350-64.

Yeager, Leland B., and associates, Experiences with Stopping Inflation (Washing-

ton: American Enterprise Institute, 1981).

This content downloaded from 129.100.58.76 on Wed, 16 Mar 2016 13:14:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like