Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/363233195

Vote-buying, anti-corruption campaigns, and identity in African elections

Article in World Development · December 2022


DOI: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2022.106064

CITATIONS READS

4 419

3 authors:

Kristen Kao Ellen Lust


University of Gothenburg University of Gothenburg
34 PUBLICATIONS 132 CITATIONS 127 PUBLICATIONS 2,941 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Lise Rakner
University of Bergen
94 PUBLICATIONS 1,364 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Ellen Lust on 11 September 2022.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


World Development 160 (2022) 106064

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

World Development
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev

Vote-buying, anti-corruption campaigns, and identity in African


elections
Kristen Kao a,⇑, Ellen Lust b, Lise Rakner c
a
Department of Political Science, University of Gothenburg, Sweden
b
Governance and Local Development Institute, Department of Political Science, University of Gothenburg, Sweden
c
Department of Government, University of Bergen, Senior Research Fellow Chr. Michelsen Institute, Norway

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: The literature on democracies in the developing world paints a picture of rampant vote buying. A growing
Accepted 1 August 2022 research field has shed light on how politicians decide whom to target, how individuals view vote buying,
and the consequences of such practices. Yet, most research compares support for candidates offering
handouts to those who do not. It fails to explore how offering handouts compares to other campaign
Keywords: strategies – promising future targeted goods or community goods, explicitly eschewing vote buying cam-
Vote-buying paign tactics, or garnering support based on ethnic or local social ties. In this study, we employ a conjoint
Elections
experiment fielded in Malawi (n = 1,166) to examine the relative power of vote buying versus other cam-
Clientelism
Identity politics
paign tactics. Our experimental results reveal that respondents view candidates who promise community
Localism service provision or criticize vote buying more positively than those who offer handouts. We also find
Africa that the magnitude of the effects for community service provision and anti-vote buying campaigns are
greater than that of platforms associated with coethnicity and local social ties. These findings are both
substantively and theoretically important. Policymakers and practitioners engaged in voter education
efforts may counter vote buying by informing candidates of the potential electoral benefits to champi-
oning anti-vote buying platforms and providing community services. Likewise, scholars can better under-
stand elections, representation and democracy by further exploring how different types of voters respond
to various campaign appeals in Africa.
Ó 2022 Published by Elsevier Ltd.

1. Introduction cies and their partners on the ground have implemented voter edu-
cation campaigns to raise awareness of the negative consequences of
Studies of elections in the Global South paint a picture in which vote buying (EC-UNDP, 2018; ACE, n.d.). Moreover, some politicians
campaign handouts are both rampant and successful in winning have sought to undermine the effectiveness of opponents’ vote buy-
voters’ support. Vote buying and clientelism, or the exchange of ing strategies. For instance, in the 2011 Zambian election, the oppo-
material goods or targeted services for votes,1 is thought to affect sition Popular Front (PF) party used the campaign slogan ‘donchi
voter turn-out (Vicente, 2014), the fairness of elections (Stokes, kubeba’ (Bemba for ‘don’t tell’), encouraging its supporters to accept
2007; Bratton, 2008), and the legitimacy of election outcomes the gifts handed out by the then-incumbent Movement for Multi-
(Kramon, 2018), and thus to undermine democracy (Gonzalez Party Democracy (MMD) without disclosing that they intended to
et al., 2014; Stokes, 2005, 2007). Consequently, Western donor agen- vote for the PF (Cheeseman & Lamer, 2015).2 Similarly, in 2014,
the Malawi Congress Party (MCP) campaigned on the basis of ending
handouts – perhaps spurred by the party’s own financial constraints
⇑ Corresponding author at: Department of Political Science, University of (Dulani & Dionne, 2014).
Gothenburg, Box 711, SE 405 30, Gothenburg, Sweden. Empirical research on vote buying has added new insights into
E-mail addresses: kristen.kao@gu.se (K. Kao), ellen.lust@gu.se (E. Lust), lise. when, how, and from whom candidates attempt to purchase votes
rakner@uib.no (L. Rakner).
1
As Nichter (2008) notes, ‘‘vote buying” is used in varied ways in the literature. In
2
this study, we do not demonstrate the contingency of handouts for votes required for ‘Don’t kubeba’ was used as a reaction to the ruling MMD’s clientelistic campaign
clientelistic exchanges, but rather see the handouts we discuss to fit the form of ‘‘non- strategies. Clearly outmatched by financial and material resources at the ruling
binding vote buying’” discussed by other authors. Thus, following others (Kramon MMD’s disposal, the PF used the don’t kubeba catchphrase to urge the electorate to
2016, Diaz-Cayeros et al., 2009), we use the term ‘‘vote buying” to highlight how our willingly receive any form of clientelist rewards from the MMD but vote for their
discussion lends insight into that scholarship. preferred candidate.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2022.106064
0305-750X/Ó 2022 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
K. Kao, E. Lust and L. Rakner World Development 160 (2022) 106064

(Weitz-Shapiro, 2012; Stokes et al., 2013; Cox & McCubbins, 1986; scholarship, emphasizing the need to explore the effects of anti-
Grossman & Helpman, 1996; Corstange, 2018; Justesen & Manzetti, vote buying campaigns at the candidate level on elections in the
2017). The picture of why voters accept hand-outs is also becoming Global South.
clearer (Gonzalez Ocantos et al., 2014; Erlich, 2020: Schaffer,
2007); however, there are only limited efforts aimed at under-
standing voter opposition to the practice (Weitz-Shapiro, 2012). 2. Mobilizing support: the roles of anti-vote-buying campaigns,
Scholars have examined the impact of anti-vote buying campaigns material handouts, and identity appeals
led by civil society, but they have primarily considered the impact
on voter turnout and support for incumbent parties (Blattman The literature on democracies in the developing world paints a
et al., 2019). To our knowledge, scholars have not examined how picture of rampant vote buying and ethnic voting (Bratton, 2008;
politicians running on anti-vote buying appeals compare, in the Conroy-Krutz, 2013; Nugent, 2007; Posner, 2005; Mares & Young,
voter’s calculus, with other candidates and competing platforms 2016). Voters are expected to prefer direct, tangible benefits in
and strategies. Furthermore, particularly in Africa, scholars gener- elections over campaign promises of public goods or national pol-
ally assume that campaigns are not issue-based (Wantchekon, icy (Keefer & Vlaicu, 2017; Khemani, 2015) and to distrust candi-
2003; Kramon, 2018), even though valence issues around anti- dates outside their own identity groups to deliver such goods
corruption, democracy, and good governance feature in most Afri- (Stokes, 2007; Kitschelt, 2000; Chandra 2007; Jensen & Justesen,
can election campaigns (Bleck & van de Walle, 2013, 2018). Impor- 2014). Yet, recent studies draw such assumptions into question.
tant questions therefore remain regarding how voters react to Studies find that political performance and issue-based campaigns
politicians who explicitly campaign on anti-vote buying messages may be more important than identity (Gadjanova, 2017, Lindberg
or other appeals. & Morrison, 2008; Weghorst & Lindberg, 2013; Bleck & van de
In this article, we employ a single profile, conjoint experiment Walle, 2011; Carlson, 2015) and that at least some voters eschew
(Hainmueller et al., 2014) to address these questions. In the real vote buying (Weitz-Shapiro, 2012). Such findings suggest that
world, candidates present bundles of appeals – they declare that politicians may gain support through offering anti-vote buying
they will combat corruption and deliver roads, provide access to appeals or community services.
water, and fortify health clinics with staff and supplies; they claim Given the considerable time, money, and effort that develop-
to represent key localities and interests; they emphasize their eth- ment practitioners invest into combatting vote buying, another
nic or social ties; and at times they pass out bags of sugar and rice. strand of literature evaluates the impact of pro-democracy pro-
These bundled campaign appeals impede our ability to compare gramming on voters’ activities. Some of this research finds that
the impact of offering material benefits to that of anti-vote- anti-vote buying appeals reduce voter turnout (Vicente, 2014)
buying messages or other appeals. The conjoint experiment allows and decrease vote shares for incumbent candidates (Blattman
us to isolate the relative importance of different appeals in deter- et al., 2019; Vicente, 2014). For instance, employing a field exper-
mining voter choice, and to do so in the absence of direct ques- iment in the Philippines, Hicken et al. (2018) find that information
tions, thereby reducing the social desirability bias associated appeals in which voters promise not to take money from candi-
with vote buying. Focusing the respondent’s attention on a single dates can reduce vote-selling, while the promise to take vote buy-
profile limits sensitivity bias that showing multiple candidates ing payments but vote according to one’s preferences can have a
(and their vote buying appeals) may trigger. Finally, the experi- smaller effect, and even possibly increase vote-selling. There is also
ment allows us to vary other important candidate characteristics evidence that such programs lower support for parties believed to
that might factor into how voters respond to clientelistic appeals, engage in vote buying (Hicken et al., 2018; Schechter & Vasudevan,
including ethnicity and local social ties. 2021; Vasudevan, 2019; Vicente, 2014). More generally,
Our experimental results show that candidates who criticize Murugesan’s (2020) review of experimental studies on vote buying
vote buying or promise community services are likely to do better and clientelism posits that the impact of anti-vote buying cam-
at the ballot box than those who offer targeted handouts. More- paigns may depend on the framing and approaches that they
over, we find that the magnitude of the effects for anti-vote buying utilize.
campaigns and community service provision are greater than those There is also evidence that non-government-driven, anti-vote
associated with coethnicity and local social ties. Electing a candi- buying campaigns influence voters’ perceptions. Erlich (2020) finds
date who spent his whole life in the village is significant, while that providing Kenyan voters with information about the detri-
coethnicity with the candidate was not found to be statistically sig- mental effect of vote selling (public service predation) or telling
nificant in our study. These findings are both substantively and them that their community members will look down on them if
theoretically important. Practitioners engaged in voter education they engage in the practice (social sanctioning) may shape vote-
efforts can encourage candidates to gain support by running selling attitudes in emerging democracies. Similarly, Hicken
against vote buying and for community services, and scholars et al.’s (2018) field experiment found that the voter education pro-
can benefit by turning attention to how voters evaluate various ject in the Philippines diminished the reported perception that
campaign strategies. votes were cast according to money received. These studies are
The article proceeds as follows. It first examines the literature important, but they do not explore how individuals respond to
on vote buying and clientelism in the Global South. We find that politicians that incorporate such appeals into their campaigns,
scholars recognize but do not compare the range of campaign nor, for that matter, how candidates’ other characteristics influ-
strategies employed, and that they rarely examine whether candi- ence voter responses to anti-vote buying efforts.
dates who embrace messaging aimed at rooting-out vote buying Moreover, voters react to politicians on the basis of their ethnic
can succeed. Next, the article outlines Malawi’s political context, identity or local social ties. Coethnicity and other shared identities
focusing on how it affected design choices in the experiment. Then appear to help solve commitment problems associated with vote
we present the experiment and our findings. In particular, the anal- buying during elections. Coethnicity may shape the moral obliga-
yses show that voters support candidates who campaign on anti- tion between patrons and clients (Ekeh, 1975), be linked to favor-
vote buying appeals and who promise community goods, and that itism in service provision (Posner, 2005; Carlson, 2015; Kramon,
these appeals appear more important to voter choice than ethnic- 2016; Lust-Okar, 2006; Kao, Forthcoming), and weaken obstacles
ity and social ties. Finally, the conclusion considers the implica- to collective action (Habyarimana et al., 2009). Kasara (2007) pro-
tions of our findings for future electoral programming and vides evidence that coethnics may not benefit as uniformly as
2
K. Kao, E. Lust and L. Rakner World Development 160 (2022) 106064

expected; she finds that executives tax coethnic farmers at higher backs and flaws, Malawi has maintained a durable democratic sys-
rates than non-coethnics. Nevertheless, there is reason to believe tem since the return to multiparty rule after 1993; three peaceful
coethnicity both mobilizes support and shapes how voters’ per- transfers of power after incumbent losses and continued judicial
ceive candidates’ appeals. According to Posner (2007), ‘‘voters seek independence indicate resilient democratic norms. Malawian elec-
access to state resources by allocating their electoral support to tions are also highly competitive (Dionne & Dulani, 2013; Patel &
members of their own ethnic groups, who they assume will be Wahman, 2015; Johnson, 2020).
more likely than non-coethnics to redistribute those resources to Parliamentarians focus primarily on providing constituent benefits
them.” Or, as Chandra put it, ‘‘the only credible promises are those over programmatic policymaking. Legislative capacities are limited,
made by coethnics” (Chandra, 2007, p.62). It is perhaps then not and parliamentary oversight of the executive is weak (Patel &
surprising that Kramon (2018) found that targeted handouts of Tostensen, 2007; Dionne & Dulani, 2013). The parliament does
money during campaign rallies increased support for a coethnic not control its own budget, determine its calendar, or dictate the
candidate in comparison to non-coethnics.3 duration of its sessions. At the same time, parliamentarians enjoy
Local social ties may have a similar impact. Politicians, like significant financing power, owing to legislation in 2006 which
sports teams, often expect and receive hometown support. gave MPs access to Constituency Development Funds. These dis-
Research on elections has uncovered a local electoral advantage cretionary funds totaled about 18 million Malawi MWK (approxi-
in Canada (Blais et al., 2003), Finland (Raunio, 2005), Ireland mately 32,000 USD) per constituency in 2015/16 (Chiweza, 2016,
(Marsh, 2007), Italy (Katz & Bardi, 1980), Japan (Horiuchi et al., p.107), in a country where the per-capita GDP was about 349
2017), and the UK (Evans et al., 2017). A similar advantage appears USD (World Bank, 2021). Parliamentarians show a preference for
in the Global South. Candidates generally receive disproportionate disbursing pork-barrel funding to their own districts or offering
vote shares in their home village (Blaydes, 2010), and would-be particularistic benefits to individual constituents over determining
candidates often anticipate that their home village will turn out broader-based legislation (Rakner & Svåsand, 2013; Ejdemyr, et al.,
to support them even if they have lived away for many years. 2018).
Hodler and Raschky (2014) find that voters benefit when co- The electoral system reinforces this tendency. Malawi employs
locals win. Analyzing night-light data from 126 countries over a single-member district electoral system which promotes the per-
17 years, they provide evidence that leaders’ home regions benefit sonal vote, in which voters cast ballots based on the personal rep-
disproportionately, and particularly in weakly institutionalized utation and responsiveness of individual candidates (Carey &
countries with poorly educated populations, as found in Malawi. Shugart, 1995). Independents are prevalent, and thus, political par-
This may be the result of a higher capacity for monitoring and ties are important but not the sole vehicles of campaigns. Finally,
sanctioning unresponsive officials, or reflect that voters hold other Malawi’s political landscape is fragmented. In the 2014 parliamen-
voters accountable, punishing them if they do not support their tary elections, there was a relatively high number of candidates per
own. In either case, it is not surprising that candidates often have seat (approximately 1 per 4000 registered voters) and high vari-
a hometown advantage, or that politicians often employ vote bro- ance in votes that candidates won (from 34 to over 24,000 bal-
kers with strong ties in the community (Auyero, 2000; Stokes, lots).5 This suggests there are low barriers to entry in politics,
2005; Szwarcberg, 2012). meaning that voters can conceive of an individual from their village
In short, the literature suggests that campaign appeals and can- running in the elections.
didates’ identities impact the likelihood that voters express sup- Candidates can employ handouts, credibly promise community ser-
port for candidates. However, it lends few insights into how vices, and campaign against corruption to gain support. Money plays
voters compare various appeals, the extent to which candidates an important role in Malawian politics, both during and after elec-
can gain from taking anti-vote buying positions, and how identity tions. Until 2018, Malawi did not have legislation regulating cam-
may interact with appeals to impact voter support. We explore if paign finance, and to our knowledge there were no voter education
voters’ support for a given candidate depends on his or her cam- programs prior to the 2014 tripartite elections that explicitly
paigning on selective handouts, community services, or anti-vote addressed vote buying.6 Moreover, the practice of vote buying
buying platforms. We also anticipate that voters are more likely (the distribution of private benefits in exchange for electoral sup-
to support candidates who share their ethnicity or with whom they port) is common (Birch, 2011; Ballington & Kahane, 2014; Mpesi &
have strong local ties. Muriaas, 2012; Hamer & Seekings, 2017).7 Reports on the 2014 elec-
tion campaign, the most recent elections prior to our study, found all
main parties provided material hand-outs (e.g., t-shirts, caps, food-
3. The Malawian political context
stuffs, or money) to attend events (Patel & Wahman, 2015). Eighteen
focus groups conducted with 147 Malawians found that candidates
Malawi provides a meaningful context in which to explore how
offered them gifts such as salt, money, sugar, and clothes as part
politicians’ campaign appeals and identities influence voter sup-
of their campaigns, thus informing the items we used as selective
port. The country has a democratic system of government with
incentives in the experiment. (See Online Appendix C for more infor-
high political engagement4 and frequent power alternation, but
mation on these focus groups.) One focus group participant from a
one in which vote buying is widespread, and ethnic identities and
local ties are salient. Malawi’s electoral context, much like other Afri-
can settings, allows us to run a credible survey experiment which 5
Authors’ calculations from data available in Malawi Electoral Commission (2018).
pits vote buying against other campaign appeals and considers the 6
International donors withheld USD 150 million in November 2013 when the
ways in which ethnicity and local ties influence reported political Cashgate corruption scandal unfolded, leaving organizations which normally imple-
support. ment voter education without the financial means to carry out such programs
Malawi’s democratic system offers electoral choices. Citizens are (Mbowela and Mwalubunju, 2015: 127).
7
free to cast their vote, and elections are competitive. Despite set- According to the Malawi Electoral Support Network (MESN) Observer report of
the 2014 elections: ‘‘In the campaign rallies before the 2014 elections it was observed
that most of the main parties provided audiences with material hand-outs such as
3
Of course, there are other reasons to vote for coethnics as well. Individuals may campaign t-shirts, caps and sometimes financial incentives to attend the events. The
feel that they have shared interests with coethnics, or that their status is reflected in People’s Party visibly had more resources than other parties, as they gave hand-outs
the status of their ethnic group (Chandra, 2007). such as bags of maize, motorbikes and bicycles, blankets and shoes in many districts”
4
Since 2014, turnout in Malawi for presidential and parliamentary elections has (quoted in Patel, 2015, p. 111). The EU electoral observation team made similar
been between 63 and 74% (IFES, n.d.). observations (EU EOM, 2014: 20).

3
K. Kao, E. Lust and L. Rakner World Development 160 (2022) 106064

village in the Dedza district explained, ‘‘During campaign periods it Voters value candidates with local ties. Finally, local ties are impor-
is our time to eat from politicians.” (Nyengo yakampeni nmdi nthawi tant in Malawi. Our survey finds that 69% of Malawians feel some-
yoti nafenso tiwadyere.) Another said, ‘‘When they bring the things, what or very obligated to help co-locals.12 Regarding elections, 59%
we receive and eat.” (Munthu uja akabwera nazo timangolandira agree or agree strongly that MPs respond more quickly to their vil-
nkudya.)8 In response to a direct question in our survey, 66% of lage members, and 79% of Malawians reported that they feel it is
Malawians in our sample confirm that candidates pass out goods important or very important to elect someone from their village. It
and promise targeted services during elections. is not unrealistic for citizens to consider candidates running from
Candidates can also win support by offering community ser- their village or a village nearby. As noted previously, there are a rel-
vices. We find evidence in the survey for the salience of community atively high number of candidates per population, with a large num-
goods in citizens’ ideals of governance; where we ask respondents ber of parties and candidates often running as independents; as a
directly which of the following activities they would like current result, voters often encounter candidates who hail from their village
MPs to prioritize – a) soliciting funds to finance projects in their or ward.
constituency (for example, funds for hospitals or schools), b) pass-
ing national laws, or c) providing individual services to citizens of 4. Experimental design
your constituency (helping them to obtain licenses, find jobs, edu-
cate children, etc.) – the majority (59% of the respondents) prefer We employ a rating-based, single vignette experimental design
that MPs focus on financing community projects. This is compared in which the respondent rates their likelihood of voting for a single
to 27% of the sample who prefer MPs to provide individual services candidate on a four-point scale.13 We have good reasons for selecting
and only 9% who want them to spend their time passing national this design. First, we were concerned that seeing differing vote buying
laws.9 Consequently, candidates can garner support by promising offers might invite social desirability bias in our responses as people
community goods, which they can fund, at least in part, through are unlikely to admit they prefer material handouts at election time.
Constituency Development Funds. These funds allow candidates to A single profile reduces this concern by better hiding this treatment
credibly campaign to improve health clinics, schools, and other local among the other profile attributes. One might be concerned that we
services. sacrificed external validity with our choice of this design. Yet, recent
Finally, candidates may attempt to gain support by campaign- work on elections in Africa shows that voters are rarely faced with a
ing against vote buying, whether immediate or future handouts. two-candidate run-off within their districts; Duvergerian logic often
Currently, civil society organizations and international donors does not hold in low-information contexts where ethnic identities
appear to implement most anti-vote buying campaigns as part of play an outsized role in party affiliation (Moser & Scheiner, 2012;
the voter education programs.10 Yet, as described in the introduc- Ferree et al., 2019; Kao, Forthcoming). Moreover, studies employing
tion, Malawian candidates have also employed anti-vote buying both a forced-choice model and a single-profile rating to test for
messaging in attempts to win support. Such messages appear to be robustness of results have found few differences in outcomes between
less prevalent than vote buying or promises of community services, the two designs (e.g., Hainmueller & Hopkins, 2015). Finally, a rating of
but they still exist. likelihood allows the respondent to add nuance to their response,
Thus, Malawi allows us to focus our study on comparing compared to a blunt ‘‘yes” or ‘‘no” outcome.
appeals regarding vote buying with promises of immediate selec- The experiment was embedded within a national face-to-face
tive incentives (e.g., cash, sugar), future selective incentives (e.g., survey of 8,100 Malawians carried out using tablet computers in
fertilizer subsidies, assistance with services), and community March of 2016; the experiment was seen by a random subsample
goods (e.g., schools, clinics). Such appeals reflect the reality of of 1,166 of the survey respondents. The survey was conducted in
Malawi’s political system and voters’ expectations. 269 villages, with probability proportional to size (PPS) sampling
Ethnicity is salient. Malawi is home to eleven major ethnic designed to be representative at the local and national levels.
groups, which are viewed as the basis of political support. Despite (More details on the survey are provided in Online Appendix C.)
party fractionalization (Rakner et al., 2007), Malawian voters have Our experimental setup involves randomly altering candidate
tended to remain loyal to parties associated with their ethno- characteristics. To ensure that the profiles were realistic, we devel-
regional affiliations (Posner, 2004; Ferree & Horowitz, 2010). Suc- oped the experimental arms based on a review of the literature,
cessive election cycles demonstrate an ethno-regional voting pat- reports on African elections, our fieldwork in Malawi in 2016,
tern in Malawian elections (Dionne & Horowitz, 2011). Moreover, and close consultation with our local partners. We use a fully-
in the survey we find that 74% of Malawians reported that they feel randomized conjoint analysis to non-parametrically identify the
it is important or very important to elect someone from their eth- average marginal component effect (AMCE) of each of the attribute
nic group. About 76% of Malawians in our sample feel very or levels on the probability of choosing a profile (Hainmueller et al.,
somewhat obligated to help out coethnics, compared to just 54% 2014). We also designed the experiment such that our attributes
who feel obligated to help others with whom they have no connec- would be independent of one another and cover a wide range of
tions. Additionally, 90% of Malawians think it is very important to realistic possibilities, in accordance with the methodological liter-
uphold the reputation of their ethnic group,11 and 56% agree or ature on conjoint analysis (Green & Srinivasan, 1978).
agree strongly that MPs respond more quickly to their coethnics The independently randomized assignment of profile character-
compared to others; just 41% believe that MPs respond more quickly istics in conjoint analysis allows us to test the effects of numerous
to those who voted for them. candidate characteristics at once, while maintaining a low number
of respondents.14 Candidate characteristics varied in a number of
8
Focus group discussions, Gunzuzi village, Malawi, September 12, 2017.
9 12
These figures come from a randomly selected sub-sample of 1,463 respondents Specifically, 37% are very obligated, 32% somewhat obligated, and 30% not
within the larger survey. They include 2% of respondents who wanted something else obligated to help a co-local, while 45% are very obligated, 31% somewhat obligated,
and 2% who said they did not know. and 23% not obligated to help a coethnic.
10 13
Malawi is heavily aid dependent with foreign aid contributing close to 40% of the See Hainmueller et al. (2014) for further explanation of this method.
14
government budget from 1994 until today (Chasukwa and Banik, 2019: 107). Due to Conjoint analysis still requires large sample variants on all characteristics, a
its aid-dependency, major aid trends have had a strong impact on domestic policy and requirement that our design is admittedly thin on (see Appendix Table A3 displaying
programs in Malawi (Page, 2019). the distribution of appeals). For this reason, we are not strongly confident in our
11
The respondent’s ethnic group in this question was input from an earlier question power to detect differences for heterogeneous effects. We limit these sorts of analyses
in the survey. below.

4
K. Kao, E. Lust and L. Rakner World Development 160 (2022) 106064

ways including campaign offers of immediate targeted goods, future Table 1


targeted goods, future public goods, or criticisms of candidates who Randomized Features of Hypothetical Parliamentary Candidates.

engage in these practices; strong (weak) local ties to the community; Characteristic Choices
and (non–)coethnicity with the respondent (see Table 1). The exact Platform  Pro-Immediate Goods – bags of sugar,
wording of these candidate features is provided in Table 1. salt, and K500 bills.
The experiment led respondents through a series of steps. The  Pro-Future Goods – promise of fertilizer
experiment began with an introductory prompt. This read: ‘‘I am subsidies/financial aid for funerals, and
help with personal problems
about to read you the descriptions of a candidate for parliament.  Pro-Community Goods – promise of more
Then I will ask you how likely you would be to vote for this parlia- schools, improved healthcare, digging of
mentary candidate.” Examples of full experimental prompts are boreholes
presented in Table 2, where items in parentheses are randomized  Anti-Immediate Goods: Criticism of can-
didates who offer immediate targeted
components. (Note, this table represents only some examples as
goods
the experiment yields 24 different profiles.) The interviewer read  Anti-Future Goods: Criticism of candi-
the description and then asked the respondent: ‘‘How likely is it dates who offer future targeted goods
that you would vote for this parliamentary candidate: very likely,  Anti-Community Goods: Criticism of can-
somewhat likely, not likely, not at all likely. Or would you like didates who offer future club goods
Ethnicity  Coethnic
me to read the description of the candidate again?” When the
 Non-coethnic
respondent indicated that he or she was ready to answer, the inter- Strong/weak local ties to  Born in (the village/ward) and has lived in
viewer recorded the answer. the community to the area for a long time
Immediate and Future Incentives, Community-Oriented Goods, and village  Has recently moved to back to (the vil-
lage/ward) after many successful years
anti-Vote-Buying Messaging. We test the effect of different candi-
living abroad
date platforms on respondents’ expressed likelihood to vote for
the candidate. We test two types of vote buying appeals often wit-
nessed at public rallies: 1) the immediate distribution of kilo bags
and has lived in the area for a long time versus a candidate who
of sugar, half-kilo bags of salt, and K500 bills to citizens in
was originally from the village but has only recently moved back
exchange for votes; and 2) the promise of future goods, including
after many successful years living abroad. In asking this question,
fertilizer subsidies, financial aid for funerals, and help with other
we brought in the name of the village or neighborhood from an
personal problems once elected in exchange for their votes.15 A
earlier survey item.
platform of community-oriented goods provision promises con-
It is important to note that this treatment focuses on local social
stituents the passing of legislation to improve healthcare, building
ties. In both cases, the candidates hail from the village and are cur-
more schools, and digging more boreholes once elected in exchange
rently living there. That is, both candidates are local in terms of
for their votes. The anti-vote buying appeals criticize each of these
place. Where they differ, and what we test, is the extent to which
platforms.16 We kept negative campaigns of all three offers in order
they have developed strong local ties. The candidate who grew up
to maintain balance and to test a fully factorialized model.
and remained in the village signals more dense and stronger com-
Coethnicity. In order to examine whether coethnicity drives
munity ties than the one who has recently moved back into the vil-
voter preferences, we include the candidate’s ethnic background
lage. Conversely, there is some evidence that those who have left
in the description. For coethnics, this background is brought in
the village may be associated with greater wealth, as many Malaw-
from an earlier question to the respondent about his or her ethnic-
ians who leave the country to work in South Africa or elsewhere
ity. We were able to include the nine largest ethnic groups, which
return wealthier. We inevitably have varied both the candidate’s
together make up 97% of the population of Malawi, in the random-
years in residence in the village and wealth at the same time, but
ization.17 If the respondent is a member of one the nine largest
if anything, this should bias respondents toward voting for the can-
Malawian ethnic groups -- by which we mean the respondent asso-
didate who is more capable of offering them goods; that is, they
ciated him or herself with either the Lomwe, the Yao, the Ngoni, the
should be biased toward the candidate who lived successfully
Tumbuka, the Mang’anja, the Sena, the Tonga, the Nkonde, or the
abroad. Thus, this item provides a ‘hard’ test of the importance of
Chewa -- then he or she had a 50% chance of seeing a coethnic. Any-
local ties. Nearly 48% of the sample saw a candidate who was born
one who is not a member of one of these nine largest ethnic groups
in their village versus one who recently returned to the village.
was equally likely to see each of the possible ethnicity conditions, all
of which were non-coethnics. About 47% of the respondents received
a coethnic candidate with the respondent’s ethnicity piped into the
5. Results
description of the candidate.
Local Ties. As described above, an understudied feature of candi-
We employ the four-point Likert scale to rate responses to can-
dates that may be important in determining voter behavior is
didates. The respondents displayed strong convictions in the
whether the candidate shares strong local ties to the same commu-
experiment. More than 75% of the sample chose one of the extreme
nity as the respondent. To test if local ties play an important role in
categories of either not at all likely or very likely to vote for the
determining vote choice in Malawian parliamentary elections, we
presented candidate.18 For ease of interpretation, we rescaled this
offered respondents the choice of a candidate who is a local resi-
four-point outcome (from not at all likely to very likely) to range
dent who was born in the respondent’s village or neighborhood
between 0 and 1.19
We follow Hainmueller et al. (2014) who show that Ordinary
15
The items and platforms chosen were informed by pre-survey focus group Least Squares (OLS) regression analysis is a consistent estimator
discussions (see Online Appendix C), and are also found in reports of the 2014 of the Average Marginal Component Effect (AMCE) of different can-
elections (see Malawi Electoral Support Network, 2014. See also Patel (2015).
16
The platforms of public goods provisions are informed by focus group respon-
dents and qualitative interviews with Malawian MPs who in conversations explained
what voters expected of their MP in terms of community development (see Rakner
18
and Svåsand, 2013). The full distribution of results across appeals is available in Online Appendix A.
17 19
See Berge et al. (2014, Table 1) for a complete listing of the ethnic groups and See the Online Appendix for the original scale and to verify that results are robust
their percentages of the population. to the use of this scale as well as alternative ordinal analyses.

5
K. Kao, E. Lust and L. Rakner World Development 160 (2022) 106064

Table 2
Examples of Full Experimental Prompts.

Example Candidate 1: A man (of respondent’s ethnicity) who (was born in this village and has lived in the area for a long time) is running as a candidate for the
parliamentary elections. At public rallies, he (hands out kilo bags of sugar, half-kilo bags of salt, and K500 bills to citizens) in exchange for votes).
Example Candidate 2: A man (of a non-coethnic ethnicity) who (has recently moved to back to after many successful years living abroad) is running as a candidate for
the parliamentary elections. At public rallies, he (criticizes candidates who offer citizens fertilizer subsidies, financial aid for funerals, and help with other personal
problems once elected) in exchange for their votes.
Example Candidate 3: A man (of a non-coethnic ethnicity) who (was born in and who has lived in the area for a long time) is running as a candidate for the
parliamentary elections. At public rallies, he (emphasizes to citizens that he will pass legislation to improve schools, improve healthcare, and dig more boreholes
once elected) in exchange for their votes.

didate attributes on the probability of a respondent voting for the have an advantage specifically when promising goods and if the
candidate.20 One level of each attribute is omitted to serve as the ref- poor will prefer handouts more than the wealthy.
erence category. Fig. 1 presents the impact of campaign appeals, To understand if the appeals employed in the experiment have
strong local ties and coethnicity.21 differential causal effects depending on whether or not the candi-
date is a coethnic, we run interactions between our experimental
arms to generate average component interaction effects (ACIEs).
Coethnic candidates offering community goods are the most popu-
6. Findings
lar appeal of all possible combinations. This is the only conditional
effect that is significant (p < 0.05).22 The estimated marginal effects
Promising Community Goods and anti-Vote-Buying Campaigns
of a coethnic on the likelihood of voting for the candidate is 12 per-
Outperform Immediate Vote-Buying Offers. Voters in our sample pre-
centage points (pp) compared to a non-coethnic offering community
ferred candidates who campaigned on promises of community
goods. (See Online Appendix Table B9 for full results of interactions
goods (statistically significantly at p < 0.000) more than those
between experimental arms.) Our study provides evidence that
who offered immediate targeted handouts (i.e., cash, bags of sugar
coethnics have an advantage over non-coethnics when it comes to
and salt). The outcome is rescaled to range between 0 and 1 for
promises of community goods, confirming previous literature with
ease of interpretation. Respondents were more likely to prefer pro-
these expectations (e.g., Carlson, 2015).
mises of community goods by 0.28 points compared to the baseline
To test for possible heterogeneous effects by wealth, we interact
of immediate targeted goods. Promises of future goods increase the
our experimental appeals arm with a measure of respondent
likelihood of voting for a candidate by 0.18 points (p < 0.01). Yet,
wealth. In the survey, we ask respondents for a measure of their
importantly, our findings show that candidates can also garner
household’s ability to pay bills and save money.23 We do not find
support by criticizing those who engage in direct vote buying; neg-
any significant differences between the effects of our candidate
ative campaigning against politicians handing out immediate
appeals conditional upon wealth groups.24
goods is a strategy that increases likelihood of supporting a candi-
date by 0.11 points (p < 0.05). There is also a marginally significant
effect of negative campaigning surrounding future targeted goods
provision by 0.10 points (p < 0.10) (see Fig. 1 and Online Appendix 7. Discussion and alternative explanations
Table A1).
Strong Local Ties Gain Support, Coethnicity Does Not. Our sample Our most significant finding is that anti-vote buying campaigns
demonstrates a statistically significant effect of strong local ties on are viable platforms for politicians to garner electoral support com-
voters’ likelihood of supporting a candidate, in contrast to a non- pared to candidates who offer handouts.25 This stands in direct con-
significant effect for coethnicity. Voters prefer long-time local can- trast to beliefs expressed in interviews with some candidates during
didates over those who have returned to the village after many our preliminary fieldwork, who argued that voters will not take
successful years abroad. Compared to the baseline of a candidate them seriously if they campaign empty-handed. This may lead to
who was born in this village (with village name input from an ear- questions about why voters view strategies as they do and why
lier question), we find that voters are about 0.07 points (p < 0.01) vote-buying persists, as well as concerns that alternative explana-
more likely to prefer candidates who are long-time locals. We do tions may drive the results.
not find a significant effect of coethnicity on voter preferences One may wonder why voters in our sample distinguish so
among our sample of Malawians. (For the full results, see strongly between immediate targeted handouts and other types
Table A1 in the Appendix.). of campaigning strategies. We cannot provide a definitive answer
Exploring Effects of Appeals by Coethnicity and Wealth. There are
22
two large literatures on voting in Africa which suggest that appeals Lack of significance should not be interpreted to mean that other interactions lack
meaningful effects; our inability to detect other significant effects could be the result
may matter differentially for (non)coethnics and for the (wealthy)
of lack of power due to a small sample size. (See Appendix Table A3 displaying the
poor. As noted above, in part because individuals are perceived to distribution of appeals). For this reason, we are not strongly confident in our power to
value the success of their own group over others, coethnicity gen- detect differences for ACIEs and heterogeneous effects. As a result, we limit these
erates expectations of favoritism (Posner, 2005; Ferree, 2006; analyses in this paper.
23
Carlson, 2015; Kramon, 2016). Studying vote buying in Kenya, For question wording and distributions of this variable, see Table B2 in the
Appendix.
Kramon (2016) substantiates earlier findings in other contexts 24
In earlier analyses of this experiment, we found that when we subsample our
(e.g., Stokes, 2005) and a broad theoretical literature underscoring results by wealth indicators, the poor rejected handouts to a significant degree and
that vote buying is more popular among the poor compared to the wealthy did not. Interacting the experimental arm with the respondent wealth
wealthier classes (e.g. Kitschelt, 2000; Scott, 1969). In this section category, which provides better estimates of the effects taking into account the
we explore these two hypotheses, examining whether coethnics differential sample sizes, we find that differences between wealth respondent wealth
categories are not statistically significant.
25
Campaigning against immediate targeted handouts is our third most popular
20
We found no substantive differences in the estimated marginal effects analysis appeal according to an estimated marginal means analysis. Voters preferred
from an ordinal logit model. candidates who offer community goods significantly more than this appeal, and
21
We do not run an analysis of the Complier Average Causal Effect (CACE) because they preferred offers of future targeted goods more on average though not to a level
we assume that we have all compliers or never compliers in this survey experiment. where we can detect statistical significance at traditional levels.

6
K. Kao, E. Lust and L. Rakner World Development 160 (2022) 106064

Fig. 1. Effects of Candidate Appeals. Note: Point estimates (circles) from OLS of candidate appeals regressed on likelihood of vote with 95% confidence intervals (horizontal
lines). Immediate goods (bags of money, sugar, and salt), recent returnee, and non-coethnic are the baseline comparison categories at 0 (vertical dashed line). Results are
clustered by Traditional Authority administrative district.

here, but we can infer a deeper understanding of voter attitudes Our results also bring into question how one can reconcile
towards vote buying by drawing upon twelve focus group discus- widespread vote buying with its apparent ineffectiveness. Why
sions which included Malawian women, men, and youth. These do candidates still engage in vote buying if it is disliked by voters?
focus group discussions were conducted shortly after the imple- It may be that the belief that campaign handouts are critical is so
mentation of our survey, with a total of 99 participants.26 (See prevalent that, even if incorrect, it is candidates who are well-
Online Appendix C for more information.) resourced and can give campaign handouts that run. It may also
Both male and female members of focus groups expressed the be that the distribution of goods and services is effective if it is part
opinion that candidates who try to sway them by offers of money of long-term clientelistic relationships, or coupled with more
or goods are not honest politicians and therefore do not deserve acceptable, community-based goods. In such cases, promises of
one’s vote.27 Youth in Dedza claimed that giving out money or items community welfare may diminish some of the negative associa-
to voters is a sign of dishonesty. Some qualified their negative atti- tions with immediate handouts, allowing voters to benefit from
tudes towards material campaign offers, suggesting that at least handouts while justifying their vote choice on the basis of con-
these strategies help community members during campaign cycles. comitant appeals to community welfare. Finally, candidates may
That said, according to them, material handouts are not a sign that employ vote buying because it is a successful strategy when it is
the candidate will actually deliver after elections. Voters were will- part of a communal activity, mediated by locally known brokers
ing to accept offers of cash, sugar and other handouts at election who deliver votes based on their personal networks. We cannot
time, but they questioned the candidates’ motives, seeing them as rule out this explanation, but it nonetheless suggests that vote
more interested in winning elections than in the community’s buying does not work in the way that many theorists believe it
welfare. does.
Moreover, few focus group discussants report feeling obligated Some may also be concerned that social desirability bias drives
to vote for a candidate who gave them money or gifts, despite their our results. Are Malawians reluctant to report support for candi-
willingness to accept handouts from politicians during the cam- dates who offer targeted goods because this is seen as socially
paign period. It is not unusual for voters to accept handouts from undesirable? The research design alleviates this problem to some
multiple candidates, even though they can vote for only one. Our extent, as conjoint experiments avoid direct questions regarding
survey results reflect these findings: 88% of respondents report one’s willingness to vote for a candidate offering targeted goods
that accepting money, food, or gifts from a candidate does not obli- (Horiuchi et al., 2018), and thus diminish the problems of social
gate one to vote for the candidate; likewise, 87% of our sample do desirability bias. Moreover, we do not use the phrase ‘vote buying’
not feel obligated to vote for a candidate who promises future tar- in the experiment; rather, we describe various appeals and actions
geted services and benefits. commonly witnessed in Malawi’s political campaigns. By showing
respondents a set of candidate characteristics rather than asking
them to directly evaluate each characteristic separately, the exper-
26
The discussions centered around the following main themes: 1) Local/National imental design mitigates issues of sensitivity bias (Hainmueller &
Elections, 2) vote buying, 3) Local Origin vs Local Residence vs Ethnicity, 4) Hopkins, 2015).
Ethnicization (Importance of Ethnic Group, Obligation to help: Ethnicity vs Religion,
Alternatively, readers may be worried that Malawian voters
Importance of working with co ethnics, 5) diverse people working together, Roles in
Ensuring quality education and health services), 6) Mixed Ethnicity. A total of 12 FGD ‘‘impute” offers of vote buying, even to those offering other
sessions - three in each of the four sample sites - were held. The highest participation appeals. This is based on the assumption that vote buying is a min-
rate was ten respondents, while the minimum group had seven. Overall, a total of 34 imum offer, and thus candidates who make other appeals would be
men, 33 women, and 32 youth in the FGDs.
27
seen as offering handouts as well. We have little reason to believe
Focus group, Malivenji village, Mzuzu, September 11, 2017; focus group, Kabinda,
Dedza, Malawi, September 12, 2017.
this is the case. Vote buying definitely exists in Malawian elections,

7
K. Kao, E. Lust and L. Rakner World Development 160 (2022) 106064

as noted above, but it is not ubiquitous. There are candidates who just handouts: only about one-third of our respondents stated that
abstain from offering handouts of cash and food. Only 24% of the immediate goods were the most that one could expect from the
survey sample reported that they had personally received gifts, elections.28 In our focus groups they often expressed distrust in can-
food, or money from a candidate; similarly, the Varieties of Democ- didates who campaign on the basis of immediate handouts.
racy data suggests that vote buying in the 2014 elections was Importantly, not only do voters punish candidates for immedi-
somewhat low with experts placing it at 0.98 on a scale ranging ate handouts, but they support those who campaign against vote
from 0 to 4 (Coppedge et al., 2021). We are unable to address this buying. To date, civil society organizations and international
concern fully but based on our survey results and focus groups it donors run most anti-vote buying programs; arguably, more candi-
does not appear that all candidates offer targeted handouts. More- dates engage in vote buying than campaign against it. However,
over, it is worth reiterating that our findings suggest not only that our results suggest that candidates can gain voter support when
offers of immediate targeted handouts are less effective in garner- they have anti-vote buying messages in their campaigns. This
ing support than other appeals, but also that negative campaigning opens avenues for candidates to engage in anti-vote buying
against such vote buying is significantly more appealing than offer- campaigns.
ing immediate targeted goods. These results have significant policy implications. The voters’
Another concern regards the relationship between local ties and reactions to candidates campaigning on anti-vote buying cam-
coethnicity. Many may anticipate that villages are homogeneous; paigns opens avenues for including candidates in electoral pro-
thus a preference for a long-time local resident is the same as a gramming. Policymakers and development practitioners may
preference for coethnics. First, it is important to recall that both have an opportunity to engage politicians in voter education
the long-time and returning local residents are from the village, efforts. They may also provide information that encourage the
and thus where villages are homogeneous, would be expected to entry of new candidates who may have refrained from running
hail from the same ethnic group. What varies is the extent of their due to lack of resources for vote buying efforts. By campaigning
social ties with the community. Moreover, our survey data demon- on anti-vote buying appeals and focusing on community goods,
strates that villages in Malawi are empirically less homogeneous candidates could simultaneously win voters and help to strengthen
than one may expect as ethnolinguistic fractionalization calculated a social norm against this behavior. In doing so, both the voter
at the village-level remains high. (See Table B6 in the Online bases of career politicians and democracy itself can be fortified.
Appendix.) The study also raises a number of additional questions and
Finally, one may be concerned that we gauge expressed willing- paths for research. Given the findings on vote buying, we join
ness to support a candidate, rather than actual voting at the ballot Hicken and Nathan (2020) in calling for more research focused
box. We accept this concern but note that there is evidence from on understanding the conditions under which vote buying is effec-
other contexts that survey experiments may indeed mirror real tive and why it occurs. About 48% of our sample saw offers of gifts,
world behavior. Hainmueller et al. (2015), for instance, find a high food and money or services and 46% saw offers of fertilizer subsi-
correspondence between acceptance of migrants in Switzerland on dies, financial aid to pay funeral fees, and/or other help with per-
a conjoint survey and real-world acceptance rates. Similarly, sur- sonal problems as ‘‘corrupting the democratic process.” Given the
vey evidence tends to find high correspondence between stated findings on the advantages of local ties as well as coethnicity when
intention to vote in pre-election surveys and electoral outcomes. candidates promise community goods, we second the call for
Actual behavior would be an ideal measure, but as discussed pre- scholars to move beyond ethno-regional vote buying as we seek
viously, this is not feasible given the difficulties in unbundling var- to understand elections, particularly in Africa (Bleck & Van de
ious components of campaign strategies and randomizing appeals. Walle, 2013, 2018; Weghorst & Lindberg, 2013). More work needs
to be done to disentangle the impact of ethnicity and localism on
candidate viability, paying particular attention to how different
8. Conclusions and future research voters may respond differently to candidate appeals.

Vote buying receives a great deal of scholarly attention and may CRediT authorship contribution statement
even be empirically widespread, but it does not appear to be as
effective in garnering voters’ support as often assumed. In Malawi, Kristen Kao: Conceptualization, Methodology, Software, Vali-
campaign handouts may be expected, and perhaps they worked to dation, Formal analysis, Data curation, Investigation, Visualization,
gain votes in the past (Dionne & Dulani, 2013). However, our study Supervision, Project administration, Writing - original draft, Writ-
suggests that candidates gain more support from promising com- ing - review & editing. Ellen Lust: Methodology, Writing – original
munity goods, future services, or even campaigning against the draft, Writing – review & editing, Investigation, Resources, Supervi-
practice of vote buying than they do from promising immediate sion, Project administration, Funding acquisition. Lise Rakner:
handouts. The strength of a candidate’s local social ties are also Investigation, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing,
important to voters. Finally, promises of community goods are par- Funding acquisition.
ticularly popular when issued by a coethnic candidate.
There is evidence that voters enjoy electoral handouts but they Declaration of Competing Interest
do not support candidates on the basis of what they receive. Voters
appear to have learned that they can take advantage of handouts The authors declare that they have no known competing finan-
from multiple candidates while still voting their preference in elec- cial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared
tions. Our findings are in line with what Blattman et al. (2019, p. 5) to influence the work reported in this paper.
find in Uganda, where voters facing multiple vote buying offers
‘‘eat widely, but vote wisely.” As noted above, voters do not feel Acknowledgement
obligated to support candidates who give them gifts or targeted
service provision, and most believe there is more to elections than The authors would like to thank the Swedish Research Council
(Grants No. E0003801 and No. 2016-01687), FORMAS (Grant No.
28
About 31% and 33% of respondents believe immediate and future targeted goods 2016-00228) in collaboration with the Governance and Local
are the only thing one can get out of the elections, respectively, with just 4% of the Development Program and the Norwegian Research Council (Grant
sample declining to answer the question.

8
K. Kao, E. Lust and L. Rakner World Development 160 (2022) 106064

No. 233803) funding this research. We would also like to acknowl- Dionne, K. Y., & Horowitz, J. (2011). The Distributional Logic of Government
Transfers in Malawi. APSA 2011 Annual Meeting Paper.
edge Boniface Dulani at the Institute for Public Opinion Research
Dulani, B. & Dionne, K. Y. (2014, May 31). Opinion: Incumbency and handouts don’t
and his team for managing the fielding of the survey, Sebastian guarantee winning an African election. Retrieved from Aljazeera America http://
Nickel for data cleaning, as well as Benjamin Akinyemi, Jennifer america.aljazeera.com/opinions/2014/5/malawi-
Bergman, and Mina Ghassaban Kjellen for editing assistance. For electionsjoycebandapetermutharikaafrica.html
EC-UNDP. (2018, November 1-30). Electoral assistance projects update. European
comments that helped to shape this article we are grateful to Mon- Commission & United Nations Development Program – Joint task force on electoral
ika Bauhr, Sarah Brierley, Ruth Carlitz, Alexander Coppock, Karen assistance. Retrieved from https://www.ec-undp-electoralassistance.org/
Ferree, Matthew Gichohi, Jefferson Gray, Marcia Grimes, Adam en/monthly-reports/.
Ejdemyr, S., Kramon, E., & Robinson, A. L. (2018). Segregation, ethnic favoritism, and
Harris, Elisabeth Ivarsflaten, Kyle Marquardt, Juraj Medzihorsky, the strategic targeting of local public goods. Comparative Political Studies, 51(9),
Anne Meng, George Ofosu, Luis Schiumerini, Jonah Schulhofer- 1111–1143.
Wohl, and Brigitte Seim. Ekeh, P. P. (1975). Colonialism and the two publics in Africa: A theoretical
statement. Comparative studies in society and history, 17(1), 91–112.
Erlich, A. (2020). Can information campaigns impact preferences toward vote
selling? Theory and evidence from Kenya. International Political Science Review,
Appendix A. Supplementary data 41(3), 419–435.
EU EOM (European Union Election Observation Mission). (2014, May 21). Final
report 2014 Malawi Tripartite Elections: Presidential, Parliamentary and Local
Supplementary data to this article can be found online at
Council. Retrieved from https://www.eods.eu/library/EUEOM%20FR%
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2022.106064. 20MALAWI%2020-05-2014_en.pdf.
Evans, J., Arzheimer, K., Campbell, R., & Cowley, P. (2017). Candidate localness and
voter choice in the 2015 General Election in England. Political Geography, 59,
References 61–71.
Ferree, K. (2006). Explaining South Africa’s racial census. The Journal of Politics, 68
(4), 803–815.
ACE (n.d.). Comparative data - voter education. The electoral knowledge network.
Ferree, K., & Horowitz, J. (2010). Ties that bind? The rise and decline of ethno-
Retrieved January 14, 2022, from https://aceproject.org/epic-en/.
regional partisanship in Malawi, 1994–2009. Democratization, 17(3), 534–563.
Auyero, J. (2000). The logic of clientelism in Argentina: An ethnographic account.
Ferree, K., Gibson, C., & Hoffman, B. (2019). Why the salience of social divisions
Latin American research review, 55–81.
matters in party systems: Testing the interactive hypothesis in South Africa.
Ballington, J., & Kahane, M. (2014). Women in politics: Financing for gender
Party Politics, 25(2), 208–220.
equality. In E. Falguera, S. Jones, & M. Ohman (Eds.), Funding of political parties
Gadjanova, E. (2017). Electoral clientelism as status affirmation in Africa: Evidence
and election campaigns: A handbook on political finance (pp. 301–342).
from Ghana. The Journal of Modern African Studies, 55(4), 593–621.
International IDEA: Stockholm.
Gonzalez, O. E., Jonge, C. K., & Nickerson, D. W. (2014). The conditionality of vote
Berge, E., Kambewa, D., Munthali, A., & Wiig, H. (2014). Lineage and land reforms in
buying norms: Experimental evidence from Latin America. American Journal of
Malawi: Do matrilineal and patrilineal landholding systems represent a
Political Science, 58(1), 197–211.
problem for land reforms in Malawi? Land Use Policy, 41, 61–69.
Green, P. E., & Srinivasan, V. (1978). Conjoint analysis in consumer research: Issues
Birch, S. (2011). Electoral malpractice. Oxford University Press on Demand.
and outlook. Journal of Consumer Research, 5(2), 103–123.
Blais, A., Gidengil, E., Dobrzynska, A., & Nevitte, N. (2003). Does the local candidate
Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1996). Electoral Competition and Special Interest
matter? Candidate effects in the Canadian election of 2000. Canadian Journal of
Politics. The Review of Economic Studies, 63, 265–286.
Political Science, 36(3), 657–664.
Habyarimana, J., Humphreys, M., Posner, D. N., & Weinstein, J. M. (2009).
Blattman, C., Larreguy, H., Marx, B., & Reid, O. R. (2019). Eat widely, vote wisely?
Coethnicity: Diversity and the dilemmas of collective action. New York, USA:
Lessons from a campaign against vote buying in Uganda (Working Paper No.
Russell Sage Foundation.
26293). National Bureau of Economic Research.
Hainmueller, J., Hopkins, D. J., & Yamamoto, T. (2014). Causal inference in conjoint
Blaydes, L. (2010). Elections and distributive politics in Mubarak’s Egypt. New York,
analysis: Understanding multidimensional choices via stated preference
USA: Cambridge University Press.
experiments. Political Analysis, 22(1), 1–30.
Bleck, J., & Van de Walle, N. (2011). Parties and issues in Francophone West Africa:
Hainmueller, J., Hangartner, D., & Yamamoto, T. (2015). Validating vignette and
Towards a theory of non-mobilization. Democratization, 18(5), 1125–1145.
conjoint survey experiments against real-world behavior. Proceedings of the
Bleck, J., & Van de Walle, N. (2013). Valence issues in African elections: Navigating
National Academy of Sciences, 112(8), 2395–2400.
uncertainty and the weight of the past. Comparative Political Studies, 46(11),
Hainmueller, J., & Hopkins, D. J. (2015). The hidden American immigration
1394–1421.
consensus: A conjoint analysis of attitudes toward immigrants. American
Bleck, J., & Van de Walle, N. (2018). Electoral politics in Africa since 1990: Continuity in
Journal of Political Science, 59(3), 529–548.
change. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.
Hamer, S., & Seekings, J. (2017). Social protection, electoral competition, and
Bratton, M. (2008). Vote buying and violence in Nigerian election campaigns.
political branding in Malawi (Working Paper No. 2017/99). WIDER.
Electoral studies, 27(4), 621–632.
Hicken, A., & Nathan, N. L. (2020). Clientelism’s red herrings: Dead ends and new
Carey, J. M., & Shugart, M. S. (1995). Incentives to cultivate a personal vote: A rank
directions in the study of nonprogrammatic politics. Annual Review of Political
ordering of electoral formulas. Electoral Studies, 14(4), 417–439.
Science, 23, 277–294.
Carlson, E. (2015). Ethnic voting and accountability in Africa: A choice experiment
Hicken, A., Leider, S., Ravanilla, N., & Yang, D. (2018). Temptation in vote-selling:
in Uganda. World Politics, 67(2), 353–385.
Evidence from a field experiment in the Philippines. Journal of Development
Chandra, K. (2007). Why ethnic parties succeed: Patronage and ethnic head counts in
Economics, 131, 1–14.
India. New York, USA: Cambridge University Press.
Hodler, R., & Raschky, P. A. (2014). Regional favoritism. The Quarterly Journal of
Chasukwa, M., & Banik, D. (2019). Bypassing government: Aid effectiveness and
Economics, 129(2), 995–1033.
Malawi’s local development fund. Politics and Governance, 7(2), 103–116.
Horiuchi, Y., Smith, D.M. & Yamamoto, T. (2017). Identifying Voter Preferences for
Cheeseman, N., & Larmer, M. (2015). Ethnopopulism in Africa: Opposition
Politicians’ Personal Attributes: A Conjoint Experiment in Japan (Research Paper
mobilization in diverse and unequal societies. Democratization, 22(1), 22–50.
No. 2016-32). MIT Political Science Department.
Chiweza, A. L. (2016). The political economy of fiscal decentralisation: Implications
Horiuchi, Y., Markovich, Z., & Yamamoto, T. (2018). Does conjoint analysis mitigate
on local governance and public service delivery. In D. Danik & B. Chinsinga
social desirability bias? Political Analysis, 1–15.
(Eds.), Political transition and inclusive development in Malawi (pp. 95–111).
IFES. (n.d.). Republic of Malawi. International foundation for electoral systems (IFES)
Oxon: United Kingdom: Routledge.
election guide. Retrieved January 17, 2022, from https://www.electionguide.
Conroy-Krutz, J. (2013). Information and ethnic politics in Africa. British Journal of
org/countries/id/130/.
Political Science, 43(2), 345–373.
Jensen, P. S., & Justesen, M. K. (2014). Poverty and vote buying: Survey-based
Coppedge, M., Gerring, J., Knutsen, C.H., Lindberg, S.I., Teorell, J., Altman, D., . . .
evidence from Africa. Electoral Studies, 33, 220–232.
Ziblatt, D. (2021). V-Dem Codebook, 11(1). Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem)
Johnson, J. (2020). Malawi: Taking stock in turbulent times. Journal of Southern
Project.
African Studies, 46(2), 195–207. https://doi.org/10.1080/
Corstange, D. (2018). Clientelism in competitive and uncompetitive elections.
03057070.2020.1735146.
Comparative Political Studies, 51(1), 76–104.
Justesen, M. K., & Manzetti, L. (2017). Poverty, partisanship and vote buying.
Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (1986). Electoral politics as a redistributive game.
Retrieved from https://ssrn.com/abstract=2902515.
The Journal of Politics, 48(2), 370–389.
Kao, Kristen (Forthcoming). Electoral Institutions and Identity-Based Clientelism in
Diaz-Cayeros, A., Estevez, F., & Magaloni, B. (2009). Buying off the poor: Effects of
Jordan. Political Research Quarterly. In press.
targeted benefits in the 2006 presidential race. In J. I. Dominguez, C. H. Lawson,
Kasara, K. (2007). Tax me if you can: Ethnic geography, democracy, and the taxation
& A. Moreno (Eds.), Consolidating Mexico’s Democracy: The 2006 Presidential
of agriculture in Africa. American Political Science Review, 101(1), 159–172.
Campaign in Comparative Perspective (pp. 23–38). Maryland, USA: Johns Hopkins
Katz, R. S., & Bardi, L. (1980). Preference voting and turnover in Italian
University Press.
parliamentary elections. American Journal of Political Science, 97–114.
Dionne, K. Y., & Dulani, B. (2013). Constitutional provisions and executive
Keefer, P., & Vlaicu, R. (2017). Vote Buying and Campaign Promises. Journal of
succession: Malawi’s 2012 transition in comparative perspective. African
Comparative Economics, 45(4), 773–792.
Affairs, 112(446), 111–137.

9
K. Kao, E. Lust and L. Rakner World Development 160 (2022) 106064

Khemani, S. (2015). Buying votes versus supplying public services: Political Maturing? (pp. 104-116). Lilongwe, Malawi: National Initiative for Civic
incentives to under-invest in pro-poor policies. Journal of Development Education (NICE).
Economics, 117, 84–93. Posner, D. N. (2004). The political salience of cultural difference: Why Chewas and
Kitschelt, H. (2000). Linkages between citizens and politicians in democratic Tumbukas are allies in Zambia and adversaries in Malawi. American Political
polities. Comparative Political Studies, 33(6–7), 845–879. Science Review, 98(4), 529–545.
Kramon, E. (2016). Where is vote buying effective? Evidence from a list experiment Posner, D. N. (2005). Institutions and ethnic politics in Africa. New York, USA:
in Kenya. Electoral Studies, 44, 397–408. Cambridge University Press.
Kramon, E. (2018). Money for votes: The causes and consequences of electoral Posner, D. N. (2007). Regime change and ethnic cleavages in Africa. Comparative
clientelism in Africa. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press. Political Studies, 40(11), 1302–1327.
Lindberg, S. I., & Morrison, M. K. (2008). Are African voters really ethnic or Rakner, L., Svåsand, L., & Khembo, N. S. (2007). Fissions and fusions, foes and
clientelistic? Survey evidence from Ghana. Political Science Quarterly, 123(1), friends: Party system restructuring in Malawi in the 2004 general elections.
95–122. Comparative Political Studies, 40(9), 1112–1137.
Lust-Okar, E. (2006). Elections under authoritarianism: Preliminary lessons from Rakner, L., & Svåsand, L. (2013). Competition and Participation, but No Democracy:
Jordan. Democratization, 13(3), 456–471. The Politics of Elections in Africa´ s Feckless Regimes. Statsvetenskaplig tidskrift,
Malawi Electoral Commission. (2014, May 21). 2014 tripartite elections. Elections 115(4).
results: Parliamentary elections results. Retrieved January 14, 2022 from https:// Raunio, Tapio (2005). Finland: One Hundred Years of Quietude. The Politics of
mec.org.mw/2014-tripartite-elections/. Electoral Systems, 471–493.
Malawi Electoral Support Network. (2014, February). Long Term Observation Report. Schaffer, F. C. (Ed.). (2007). Elections for sale: the causes and consequences of vote
Retrieved from https://www.ndi.org/sites/default/files/MESN-LTO-Report- buying. Colorado, USA: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
February-Final.pdf. Schechter, L., & Vasudevan, S. (2021). Persuading Voters to Punish Corrupt Vote
Mares, I., & Young, L. (2016). Buying, expropriating, and stealing votes. Annual Buyers: Experimental Evidence from a Large-Scale Radio Campaign in India.
Review of Political Science, 19, 267–288. Retrieved from https://ssrn.com/abstract=3929558.
Marsh, M. (2007). Candidates or parties? Objects of electoral choice in Ireland. Party Scott, J. C. C. (1969). Corruption, Machine Politics, and Political Change. American
Politics, 13(4), 500–527. Political Science Review, 63(4), 1142–1158.
Mbowela, N., & Mwalubunju, O. (2015). A scrutiny of voter participation and civic Stokes, S. (2005). Perverse accountability: A formal model of machine politics with
and voter education. In N. Patel & M. Wahman (Eds.), The Malawi 2014 Tripartite evidence from Argentina. American Political Science Review, 99(3), 315–325.
Elections: Is Democracy Maturing? (pp 117–134). Lilongwe, Malawi: National Stokes, S. C., Dunning, T., Nazareno, M., & Brusco, V. (2013). Brokers, voters, and
Initiative for Civic Education (NICE). clientelism: The puzzle of distributive politics. New York, USA: Cambridge
Moser, R. G., & Scheiner, E. (2012). Electoral Systems and Political Context: How the University Press.
Effects of Rules Vary Across New and Established Democracies. New York, USA: Stokes, S. C. (2007). Political clientelism. In C. Boix, & Stokes S.C. (Eds). The Oxford
Cambridge University Press. handbook of political science. doi: 10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199566020.003.0025.
Mpesi, A. M., & Muriaas, R. L. (2012). Food security as a political issue: The 2009 Szwarcberg, M. (2012). Uncertainty, political clientelism, and voter turnout in Latin
elections in Malawi. Journal of contemporary African studies, 30(3), 377–393. America: Why parties conduct rallies in Argentina. Comparative Politics, 45(1),
Murugesan, A. (2020, September 28). Electoral Clientelism and Vote Buying. Retrieved 88–106.
from Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics. doi: 10.1093/acrefore/ Vasudevan, S. (2019). Diminishing the Effectiveness of Vote Buying: Experimental
9780190228637.013.1334. Evidence from a Persuasive Radio Campaign in India (Working Paper). Poverty
Nichter, S. (2008). Vote buying or turnout buying? Machine politics and the secret Action Lab. Retrieved from https://www.povertyactionlab.org/sites/
ballot. American political science review, 102(1), 19–31. default/files/research-paper/Diminishing-the-Effect-of-Vote-Buying_Jan2019.
Nugent, P. (2007). Banknotes and symbolic capital. In M. Basedau, G. Erdmann, & A. pdf.
Mehler (Eds.), Votes, Money and Violence: Political parties and elections in Sub- Vicente, P. C. (2014). Is vote buying effective? Evidence from a field experiment in
Saharan Africa (pp. 253–275). South Africa: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet, Kwazulu- West Africa. The Economic Journal, 124(574), 356–387.
Natal Press. Wantchekon, L. (2003). Clientelism and voting behavior: Evidence from a field
Page, S. (2019). The Development Aid Situation in Malawi. In Development, Sexual experiment in Benin. World politics, 55(3), 399–422.
Cultural Practices and HIV/AIDS in Africa (pp. 43-60). Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. Weghorst, K. R., & Lindberg, S. I. (2013). What drives the swing voter in Africa?
Patel, N., & Tostensen, A. (2007). The Legislature. In N. Patel & L. Svåsand (Eds.), American Journal of Political Science, 57(3), 717–734.
Government and Politics in Malawi (pp. 79–108). Kachare Series. Weitz-Shapiro, R. (2012). What wins votes: Why some politicians opt out of
Patel, N., & Wahman, M. (2015). The Malawi 2014 Tripartite Elections: Is Democracy clientelism. American Journal of Political Science, 56(3), 568–583.
Maturing? Lilongwe, Malawi: National Institute of Civic Education (NICE). World Bank. (2021). GDP per capita (Current US$) – Malawi [Data file]. Retrieved
Patel, N. (2015). Management of the elections: Challenges and outcomes. In N. Patel from https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.CD?locations=MW.
& M. Wahman (Eds.), The Malawi 2014 Tripartite Elections: Is Democracy

10

View publication stats

You might also like