This Content Downloaded From 187.250.41.241 On Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 19

Mobilization and Participation: Social-Psychological Expansisons of Resource Mobilization

Theory
Author(s): Bert Klandermans
Source: American Sociological Review , Oct., 1984, Vol. 49, No. 5 (Oct., 1984), pp. 583-600
Published by: American Sociological Association

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2095417

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

American Sociological Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to American Sociological Review

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION:
SOCIAL-PSYCHOLOGICAL EXPANSIONS OF RESOURCE
MOBILIZATION THEORY*

BERT KLANDERMANS
Free University, Amsterdam

Resource mobilization theorists have nearly abandoned social-psychological


analysis of social movements. In this paper a fresh case is made for social
psychology. New insights in psychology are combined with resource mobilization
theory in an attempt to overcome the weaknesses of traditional social-psychological
approaches to social movements. Expectancy-value theory is applied to movement
participation and mobilization. It is assumed that the willingness to participate in a
social movement is a function of the perceived costs and benefits of participation.
Collective and selective incentives are discussed. Expectations about the behavior of
others are introduced as an important expansion of expectancy-value theory to make
this framework applicable to movement participation. The theory is applied to
mobilization campaigns of the labor movement, and empirically tested in a
longitudinal study of a campaign during the 1979 collective negotiations in the
Netherlands. Outcomes support the theory. Theoretical and practical implications
are discussed.

Resource mobilization theory was a reaction to pants in such divergent movements as fascism
traditional social-psychological theories of in Germany (Oberschall, 1973), the student
social movements (Zurcher and Snow, 1981). movement (Kenniston, 1968), the civil rights
Those theories focused on what attracted movement (Morris, 1981), the union movement
people to participation in social movements. (Moore, 1975), political protest movements
Amongst the explanations were: personality (Marsh, 1977; Barnes and Kaase, 1979), the
traits (cf. Kenniston, 1968; Kerpelman, 1969); environmental, antiabortion, and antinuclear
marginality and alienation (cf. LeBon [1903] movements (Leahy and Mazur, 1978), and the
1968; Freud, 1922; Hoffer, 1951; Kornhauser, unemployed movement (Klandermans, 1979).
1959); and grievances and ideology (cf. Davies, The importance of grievances and ideology as
1962; Toch, 1966; Geschwender, 1968; Gurr, determinants of participation in a social
1970; Rothman, 1974; Landsberger, 1976). movement has been ambiguous (Gerlach and
These explanations tended to be based on the Hine, 1970; McCarthy and Zald, 1976; Walsh,
assumption that participation in a social 1978; Leahy and Mazur, 1978; Tilly, 1979).
movement, like other forms of collective be- In contrast to traditional social-psycho-
havior, is an unconventional, irrational type of logical interpretations, resource mobili-
behavior (Schwartz, 1976).1 Thanks to re- zation theory emphasizes the importance of
source mobilization theorists themselves, structural factors, such as the availability of
these approaches became increasingly ques- resources to a collectivity and the position of
tionable. Attempts to show that movement individuals in social networks, and stresses the
participants have characteristic personality rationality of participation in social movements
traits were not very successful (Heberl6, 1968; (Oberschall, 1973; Gamson, 1975; Marx and
Roberts and Kloss, 1974; Klandermans, Wood, 1975; McCarthy and Zald, 1976; Zald
1983b). Marginality and alienation, for exam- and McCarthy, 1979; Snow et al., 1980; Gam-
ple, were not the typical background of partici- son et al., 1982). Participation in a social
movement is seen not as the consequence of
predisposing psychological traits or states, but
*Direct all correspondence to: Bert Klandermans, as the result of rational decision processes
Department of Social Psychology, Free University,
whereby people weigh the costs and benefits of
Amsterdam, The Netherlands.
participation.
I wish to thank two anonymous reviewers who
provided many insightful comments on an earlier
Currently, resource mobilization theory is
version of this paper. the dominant approach in the field. Paradoxi-
cally, a demand for new social-psychological
I Schwartz contrasts the social-psychological "ir-
rational" approach with the structural "rational" ap- theories of mobilization and participation has
proach. I hope to show here that such a charac- developed (Gamson et al., 1982; Jenkins, 1983;
terization of social psychology is unjust. Walsh and Warland, 1983). Resource mobili-

American Sociological Review, 1984, Vol. 49 (October:583-600) 583


This content downloaded from
187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
584 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

zation theory went too far in nearly abandoning A general criticism of resource mobilization
the social-psychological analyses of social theory has been that it underestimates the
movements. In this paper a fresh case is made significance of grievances and ideology as de-
for a social-psychological analysis of mobiliza- terminants of participation in a social move-
tion and participation in a social movement. By ment (Carden, 1978; Fireman and Gamson,
combining new insights in psychology with re- 1979; Useem, 1980; Isaac et al., 1980). This
source mobilization theory, the weaknesses of shortcoming results from confusing the indi-
earlier social-psychological approaches in the vidual and societal levels of analysis (see also
field can be overcome. Geschwender, 1968). The fact that grievances
and ideology cannot explain the rise of social
movements does not mean that they. do not
SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY AND RESOURCE
play a role in the decisions of individuals to
MOBILIZATION THEORY
participate in a social movement. One of the
Social psychology can expand resource aspirations of this social-psychological expan-
mobilization theory in an important way by sion of resource mobilization theory is to find a
revealing processes of social-movement par- more satisfying theoretical solution for the
ticipation on the individual level. To resource problem of grievances and ideology as deter-
mobilization theorists, participation results minants of participation in a social movement.
from "weighing" costs against benefits. How-
ever, little attention is given to weighing these
PERSUASION AND ACTIVATION: A
at the individual level. Nor is much attention
SOCIAL-PSYCHOLOGICAL THEORY OF
given to the interaction between individuals
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION
that generates mobilization.2
Identifying the interaction between individu- Participation in a social movement fluctuates.
als as the appropriate level of analysis has sig- Alternatingly, a movement has its rank and file
nificant theoretical consequences. It takes into in action and then it falls back on its cadre.
account the psychological truism that people Mobilization plays an important part in these
behave in a perceived reality. Individual deci- fluctuations. The remainder of this article will
sions to participate in a social movement are focus on participation in a social movement
based on perceived costs and benefits of par- and on the way it changes as a result of mobili-
ticipation. That perceived reality is capable of zation attempts.
being influenced, and both social-movement
leaders and adversaries try to do so. Persua-
The Willingness to Participate
sion is an important element in every mobiliza-
tion campaign. The efficacy of a mobilization A person will participate in a social movement
campaign in persuading the individual is a key if s/he knows the opportunities to participate, if
determinant of participation. s/he is capable of using one or more of these
Movement participation denotes activities opportunities, and if s/he is willing to do so.
This paper elaborates the third condition by
ranging from signing a petition to sabotage, and
applying expectancy-value theory to move-
from part-time or one-time to full-time activity.
The perceived costs and benefits for different ment participation. In general this theory "at-
activities can vary greatly (see also Tolbert, tempts to relate action to the perceived attrac-
1981). Moreover, there can be substantial dif- tiveness or aversiveness of expected con-
ferences in perceived costs and benefits be- sequences" (Feather, 1982:1).3 The key ele-
tween individuals, across regions, and during
the life cycle of the movement. This has im-
3 Expectancy-value models in psychology com-
portant implications for mobilization cam-
prise such concepts as attitude, motivation, choice
paigns. By timing, and by their choice of strat- and decision. The motivation for a certain behavior
egy and arena, social-movement organizations is a function of the expectation that it will yield
can profoundly influence the costs and benefits certain outcomes and the values of those outcomes
of participation. (Rotter, 1954, 1972; Mitchell, 1974; Campbell and
Pritchard, 1977). The value of an outcome of behav-
2 A number of students of social movements ior is a function of the instrumentality of the primary
whose approaches are cognate with resource mobili- outcome for other, secondary outcomes and the
zation theory do pay attention to processes at the value they have. Expectancy-value theory is a
individual level (Schwartz, 1976; Mitchell, 1979; rational-choice theory. It is one of the subjective
Oberschall, 1980; Tolbert, 1981; Gamson et al., 1982). utility theories in psychology. As such, it is easily
Their analyses bear resemblances to the one pre- compatible with resource mobilization theory. How-
sented here. They have in common, however, their ever, I do not want to suggest that social psychology
lack of a systematic, psychologically based theoreti- has nothing more to offer that is useful to the study of
cal framework. Moreover, they are not theoretical: social movements (see Gamson et al., 1982; Pinard,
they provide no empirical data at the individual level. 1983; Ferree and Miller, 1984).

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 585

ments of the theory are expected outcomes Fleishman (1980) stressed the importance of
(expectations) and the value of these out- feelings of responsibility and solidarity in this
comes. Theoretically, values and expectations connection. Schwartz (1976) and Oberschall
combine in a multiplicative way. Even if the (1980) added the probability of success as very
value of an outcome is very high it will not important. In their analysis the probability of
motivate individuals as long as they do not success is related to the number of partici-
believe that the outcome can be produced by pants. Oberschall (1980) pointed out that the
their efforts. Usually different outcomes (ma- important question for the individual is what
terial and nonmaterial) are distinguished. For his/her participation will contribute to the
each outcome a value-expectancy product can probability of success. From a hypothesized
be calculated. Motivation is defined as the sum relationship between the number of partici-
of these different value-expectancy products.4 pants and the probability of success, the indi-
A rational-choice framework does not imply vidual contribution as a function of the number
that feelings, emotions or sentiments are unim- of participants can be derived. Oliver et al.
portant in relation to movement participation. (1983) made clear that there is a variety of such
Nor does it argue that potential participants are production functions.
consciously multiplying and adding values and These arguments do not touch the funda-
expectations. The usefulness of the framework mental issue, namely, that persons have to de-
is that it provides a device for the systematic cide to participate at a point when they do not
analysis of the variety of beliefs, expectations know whether others will participate. There is
and attitudes that are related to participation in a social-psychological solution to this problem.
a social movement (see Schwartz [1976] and Although people do not know what others will
Oberschall [1980] for defenses of the rational do, they have expectations. Based on their ex-
view of human action). pectations about the behavior of others, people
However, before this general theoretical assess the probability of success and their own
framework can be applied to movement par- contribution to it. The expectation that partici-
ticipation, it has to be modified in an important pation helps to produce the collective good can
way. The goals of social movements are "col- therefore be categorized as follows:
lective goods." Obtaining a collective good is a. expectations about the number of partici-
not directly contingent on the decision of an pants;
individual to participate (Olson, 1977). Ra- b. expectations about one's own contribu-
tional individuals will not participate in the tion to the probability of success;
production of a collective good unless selective c. expectations about the probability of suc-
incentives motivate them to do so. Though Ol- cess if many people participate.
son's argument has been criticized (Schwartz, These expectations combine in a multiplicative
1976; Mitchell, 1979; Fireman and Gamson, way with the value of the collective good to
1979; Oliver, 1980), it clarified the distinction produce the expected collective benefits of par-
between collective benefits and selective ben- ticipation.
efits. If one finds it untenable that only the Applying expectancy theory yields the hy-
latter motivates movement participation, one pothesis that the value of a collective good is a
must acknowledge that the relationship be- function of its instrumentality6 for social
tween participation and collective benefits is changes which the movement hopes to achieve
different from the relationship between partici- and of the value of changes. To form an opin-
pation and selective benefits. ion about this instrumentality, an individual
Collective benefits and participation. Both must have knowledge about the collective good
Gamson (1975) and Schwartz (1976) argue that and its implications.
people participate in activities to produce a Participation and selective costs and bene-
collective goal precisely because they are
aware that the good would never be produced 5On the basis of the expectations distinguished,
if everyone sat back and waited for someone we can define the free-rider problem more closely. A
else to do something. Oberschall (1980) re- free rider is someone who believes that his/her own
marked that this was especially true for people contribution to the probability of success will be very
who are strongly in favor of the collective small, but who believes that the number of partici-
pants and the probability of success are large enough
good. Fireman and Gamson (1979) and
to expect that the collective good will be produced.
See Klandermans (1983a) for a reconsideration of
4 There is considerable discussion in the literature the free-rider dilemma along this line. Oliver et al.
concerning the mathematical part of the theory (see, (1983) propose a similar limitation of the free-rider
e.g., Kuhl, 1982). Leaving aside the theoretical problem.
argument, in practice most researchers use multiple 6 In expectancy-value theory expectation is used
regression analysis to combine the different vari- for behavior-outcome relations and instrumentality
ables. for outcome-outcome relations.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
586 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

fits. Selective costs and benefits are by defini- negative, the other motives can be so strong
tion contingent on participation. Expectations that a person is willing to participate. If the
about, and values of, these incentives directly collective motive is strong, the social motives
influence the willingness to participate. In the and/or reward motives can be negative without
literature there are different classifications of making a person unwilling to participate. Of
selective costs and benefits (cf. Freeman, 1979; course there are also situations in which the
Tolbert, 1981). An important distinction is that collective motive does not outweigh negative
between expected reactions of significant social and/or reward motives, either because
others7 and expected material costs and bene- the collective motive is too weak, or because
fits like money, time, injury, entertainment.8 the social and reward motives are too negative.
Motives. The willingness to participate in a Figure 1 summarizes the theory on the willing-
social movement can be defined as a function ness to participate.
of the perceived attractiveness or aversiveness
of the expected consequences of participation.
Mobilization
This signifies that willingness to participate is a
function of: Mobilization attempts by a movement organi-
(a) the expectation that participation will zation have the aim of winning participants,
help to produce the collective good and the that is, persuading people to support the
value of the collective good-the collective movement organization by material and non-
motive; (b) the expected selective costs and material means. Mobilization attempts always
benefits and the value of these costs and bene-contain two components. These are called con-
fits. As distinguished in the reactions of signifi- sensus mobilization and action mobilization.
cant others, these comprise the social motive. Consensus mobilization is a process through
As they relate to nonsocial costs and benefits, which a social movement tries to obtain sup-
they comprise the reward motive. port for its viewpoints.9 It involves (a) a col-
Expectations or instrumentalities and values lective good, (b) a movement strategy, (c)
combine in a multiplicative way and the three confrontation with the opponent, (d) results
motives in an additive way. The value of a achieved. Neither collective goods nor types of
collective good will be zero if it is not believed action are fixed quantities. They change, and
to be instrumental for valued societal changes, this requires renewed consensus mobilization.
or if the changes it is said to be instrumentalConsensus
for mobilization does not take place in
are not valued. The value of a collective good' a vacuum. Collective goods and actions are
will be negative if it is believed to hinder valued often controversial. Opponents, counter-
societal changes, or if changes are valued movements, rival organizations counter the
negatively. arguments of a social movement. A social
If the value of the collective good is zero, movement
the will have to go into these
collective motive will be zero. If this value arguments.
is In short, a "paper war" is waged
negative the motive will be negative, unlesspromote the or to discourage the mobilization of
expectation component is zero. consensus. The degree of success with which
The collective motive will also be zero if the consensus is mobilized around the collective
expectation that participation will help to pro- goods can be measured by the extent to which
duce the collective good is zero: persons will these goods are known and valued. Whether
not be motivated by the collective good if theypeople value a collective good depends on the
do not feel that their participation contributes extent to which consensus mobilization suc-
to the probability of success, or do not believe ceeded in making them believe that this good is
that enough other people will participate, or doinstrumental for valued social changes.
not feel there is any chance of success even if Action mobilization is the process by which
many people participate. an organization in a social movement calls up
Since the different motives combine in an people to participate. Consensus mobilization
additive way, they can compensate one an- does not necessarily go together with action
other. If the collective motive is weak, zero mobilization,
or but action mobilization cannot do
without consensus mobilization. Action
mobilization involves motivating people to
7To avoid circularity, it is important to point out participate. Ideally, social movement organi-
who in a person's environment will be significant. zations will take a variety of approaches, ap-
Although it is difficult to give exhaustive enumera- pealing both to collective and to social and
tions, certainly friends, colleagues and family mem-
bers are among them.
8 These costs and benefits can vary greatly de- 9 Consensus mobilization bears resemblances to
pending on the situation and the kind of participa- the spread of generalized beliefs (Smelser, 1971).
tion. However, often the main costs and benefits of a Consensus mobilization, however, is a purposeful
particular form of participation can be specified. effort of a social-movement organization.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 587

Attitude theory
Motivation theory

value of social
change advocated
I l value of collective
x 0 good

familiarity instrumentality of x
with collec- 0. collective good for I I
tive good social change advo- expectation that
cated participation will
help to achieve the
collective good*

- pa rticipation contributes to probabi-i value of reaction

lity of success i of significant


- expected number of participants i others
- expected success. if many people
participate
+ willingness
x +- + to parti-
cipate

expected reaction
of significant
others to partici-
pation and to
non-partici pation

value of costs
and benefits

expected costs and


benefits of parti-
cipation and non-
partici pation

a X means a multiplicative relationship.


+ means an additive relationship.

Figure 1. A Theory of the Willingness to Participatea

reward motives (Gamson, 1975; Carden, 1978; of free-rider behavior. Since free riders take a
Snow et al., 1980). They have every reason to positive stand on the collective good but do not
do so. Participation because of collective mo- believe that its production depends on their
tives means that both the collective good and participation, it is not of much use to appeal to
the type of participation are attractive. But it collective motives. What remains is to try to
will seldom be the case that each and every mobilize them using social and/or reward mo-
member of a collectivity is won over to the tives. Here, again, the chance that a social
collective good and the form of participation in movement decides to do this will be greater if a
the time available. Particularly if nearly higher degree of participation is required. '0
unanimous participation is demanded, there is
always a certain percentage who, lacking com- "I Not all types of action are equally vulnerable to
plete consensus, will have to be mobilized nonparticipation (cf. Fireman and Gamson, 1979;
using social and/or reward motives. Another Klandermans, 1983a; Oliver et al., 1983). This will
factor to be contended with is the occurrence differ for different types of action.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
588 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

A mobilizing organization will try to make ployment. The campaign started in August
the benefits of participation and the costs of 1978 when the chairman of the IB FNV
nonparticipation as high as possible, and the launched the 35-hour work week as the chief
costs of participation and the benefits of non- demand in the 1979 negotiations. The campaign
participation as low as possible. Apart from included numerous publications in the press
influencing the three motives directly, a and appearances on radio and television, issues
movement also has indirect means of control- of the union's magazine, posters, bulletins, and
ling the costs and benefits of participation. pamphlets, work by union officials and by
Two important ones are (a) the choice of the members. The union, however, quickly went
type of action and (b) the choice of the scene. on the defensive. Not just their opponent, but
A movement can choose among several types public opinion and even many "friendly"
of action, from moderate to militant. With its economists or politicians turned against it. In
choice of the type of action, a movement can an effort to break this massive resistance, the
determine to a large extent the costs and bene- union twice changed its goals: first, by replac-
fits of participation. A movement can fight ing the 35-hour week with a 39-hour week, later
where it is strongest, that is, in sectors of soci- by dropping the shorter work week and de-
ety with strong movement networks where it manding extra days off.
can organize many people. Resource mobiliza- Collective bargaining is a series of events.
tion literature has shown that people are more Our study was devoted to some of them. One
easily mobilized in such sectors (cf. Ragin et did have a great deal of influence: the failure of
al., 1982). The premise here is that this is prob- a 6-week strike against the West German steel
ably because a more favorable cost-benefit industry in which the 35-hour work week was
ratio can be created in such sectors. at stake. This failure made the union keenly
Psychologically speaking, there will be an aware of its small chances of success, even if
element of projection in estimates of the number militant action were taken. Thus no action was
of participants in a movement. A person who taken in the Netherlands that year. Ultimately,
does not wish to participate will make a lower however, an agreement was reached giving a
estimate of the number of participants than a few extra days off. Although the members
person who does wish to take part. "I In a col- were not markedly dissatisfied with this result,
lectivity this has all the look of a self-fulfilling many regretted the meager results. Few be-
prophecy: if many people think that few people lieved it would have a favorable effect on em-
will participate, many people will have doubts ployment.
about the efficacy of their own participation.
Thus a downward spiral ensues which is fatal
Research Design
to the willingness to participate. Mobilization
efforts attempt to reinforce the view that Mobilization campaigns often last several
"many people will participate." If this is -not months. In this case the campaign started in
successful, the prophecy fulfills itself. August 1978, and the negotiations were not
completed until June 1979. In such a situation,
longitudinal research is to be preferred. From
METHOD
the end of November 1978 through July 1979
The theory of mobilization and participation we interviewed a group of union members
has been applied in research on mobilization about once a month. We chose the timing so
campaigns of the union movement, the that the interviews fell shortly before or-after
women's movement and the peace movement. an important event. Although a total of seven
This paper presents data from a study of the waves were held, for methodological reasons a
effects of a mobilization campaign by the In- design was developed which ensured that no
dustrial Workers' Union of the Dutch Union respondent would be interviewed more than
Federation, the largest union of industrial three times. Seven groups of members were
workers in the Netherlands. selected, and they were interviewed according
to the schedule in Figure 2. When the similarity
of the seven groups was controlled on a
The Campaign
number of variables, the differences found
In 1979, the Industrial Workers' Union (IB were so few that the groups can be used for
FNV) tried to mobilize its members for a comparison with no difficulty.'2 In addition,
shorter work week. It was argued that
shortening the work week would reduce unem-
12 To check whether the differences found affected
the outcomes, analyses of covariance were carried
I See Granberg and Holmberg (1983) for an in- out on all effect variables, with the variables which
teresting elaboration of a similar assumption regard- had shown significant differences as covariates. Not
ing voting behavior. once did they lead to different conclusions.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 589

group I 1st 2nd 3rd


interview interview interview

group II 1st 2nd 3rd


interview interview interview

group III 1st 2nd 3rd


interview interview interview

group IV 1st 2nd 3rd


interview interview interview

group V 1st 2nd 3rd


interview interview interview

group VI 1st 2nd


interview interview

group VII 1st


interview

Nov. 20-29 Jan. 29- Feb. 19- Apr. 3-18 May 18- June 11-
|an. 4-18 Fe15. 9 Mar-. 2 June 1 July 11

Figure 2. Design

this design13 has many advantages. We can get The Interviews


a picture of the course of the campaign by
The interviews were held at the participants'
comparing the outcomes of the successive
homes and were carried out by the Netherlands
interviews. We can also study the effect of a
Institute of Opinion Polls. Each questionnaire
single event by comparing the outcomes of the
consisted of one part that was the same each
interviews before and after that event while
time and another that changed. The initial
controlling for repeated measurement.
interview included a general list of personal
data.
Respondents
The Questionnaire
Members of the IB FNV were interviewed at
three plants belonging to the AKZO concern: The variables from the theory of willingness to
Enka in Emmen; Enka in Ede; and AKZO take action were operationalized as follows. (I)
Pharma in Oss. A sample of 746 persons was The familiarity with the collective good was
taken from the membership lists of the union. measured by the following questions: Are the
The data set includes 490 complete series of unions demanding shorter working hours? (yes,
interviews (66%), well distributed over plants no, don't know). In what way do they want to
and interview waves. The first interview had shorten working hours? (open question). (II)
the highest nonresponse rate. This interview The instrumentality of the collective good for
was completed with 565 members (76%). the social change advocated: We asked the re-
Slightly less than half the dropouts refused to spondents if they felt that a "shorter working
take part in this interview. The others were not week would make a contribution to reducing
at home, were no longer members, no longer unemployment" (definitely, I think so, I don't
worked for the company, were sick, or had think so, definitely not). (III) The value of the
moved. The refusals (1/8 of the original sample) social change advocated: From the responses
may have damaged the representativeness. to various questions we were able to infer that
Small percentages again fell off at the second the interviewees almost without exception at-
(4%) and third interviews (6%). Half of the tached much value to reducing unemployment.
dropouts at the third interview were members Theoretically, this means that the value of the
who had already left for vacation. social change advocated equals 1 for each re-
spondent.
The question on the motives to participate in
union action always distinguished between two
II The design is one of the variants of the separate
types of action: militant action, such as a
sample-pretest-posttest design (Campbell and Stan-
ley, 1963): strike; and moderate action, such as holding
meetings on work time, a slowdown, a short
R 0, x 02 work stoppage, etc.
R x 02 Collective motives. (IV) The value of the

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
590 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

collective good: Union members were asked Willingness to take action. (IX) We mea-
how they stood on a shorter work week. They sured the willingness to take part in action by
could reply on a 5-point scale from very posi- asking, "If it comes to action for the negotia-
tive to very negative. tions, will you take part in moderate/militant
(V) The expectation that participation helps action?" (definitely, I think so, I don't think so,
to achieve the collective good: (a) The expec- definitely not).14
tation about one's own contribution to the
probability of success was operationalized in RESULTS
the following two statements: "It really doesn't
The Theory of the Willingness to Participate
make much difference whether or not I take
part in action." "It is important that I take part Tables I and 2 summarize the overall evalua-
in action, because in doing this I support the tion of the theory. Table 1 concentrates on the
union" (agree entirely, agree, disagree, dis- attitude towards the collective goal and Table 2
agree entirely). (b) The expectation about the on the willingness to participate.
number of participants was established as fol- Table 1 presents the correlations between
lows: "In your estimate, how many people at beliefs about the instrumentality of shorter
your plant will participate in moderate/militant working time for unemployment reduction and
action in connection with the negotiations?" the attitude toward shorter working time in five
(very few, not so many, quite a few, very successive interviews. The data show a signifi-
many). (c) The expectation about success if cant relationship between these two variables
many people participate was measured by the at all five points in time. It could be that people
question: "Imagine that very many people take- believe that shorter working hours reduce un-
part in moderate/militant-action. Do you think employment as a rationalization for their desire
that this will induce the employers to take into to have a shorter work week. That is, it may be
account the union standpoint in the negotia- that the attitudes produce the beliefs about in-
tions?" (definitely, I think so, I don't think so, strumentality rather than the reverse. The sec-
definitely not). ond part of Table 1 examines this issue. This
Social motives. (VI) Three categories of part of the table presents the correlations of the
people seemed significant: members of one's changes in the variables.15 The argument that
family, colleagues, and direct superiors. A instrumentality produces attitudes is confirmed
variable indicative of social motivation to par- if changes in one are correlated with changes in
ticipate was calculated. Basic data were (a) the the other, for it is unlikely that other possible
value a person attaches to reactions of family determinants of the attitude (for instance, the
members, colleagues, and direct superiors, and need for more leisure time) change in the same
(b) the expected reactions of these persons to way. As Table I shows, changes in the vari-
participation and to nonparticipation. The so- ables are significantly correlated.
cial motivation score is the sum of the products Table 2 is derived from six hierarchical re-
of values and expectations. If persons expect gression analyses with stepwise inclusion
favorable reactions if they participate and un- (three for moderate and three for militant ac-
favorable ones if they do not, then the score is tion).16 Following a procedure suggested by
positive. If they expect unfavorable reactions if
they participate and favorable ones if they do
not, then the score is negative. 14 To overcome the drawback that an important
Reward motives. Two types of costs seemed variable would only be measured by one question,
important: (a) financial sacrifices, and (b) other questions were asked at other points in the
worsening of a person's position in the com- interviews about the attitude toward action. The an-
swers to these questions correlated reasonably well
pany. (VII) For the financial sacrifices, we
with those to the direct question on the willingness to
asked: "Suppose that it would cost money if
take part in action (mean r = .50 for moderate action,
you took part in any action in connection with
and .67 for militant action), and they did not show
the negotiations. Do you feel this is not too any differences in their relationships to other vari-
detractive, detractive, or very detractive?" By ablest
this formulation we set the expectancy compo- 15 Residual scores were computed by substracting
nent at 1 and restricted ourselves to the value from the score on time 2 the score on time 1 multi-
component. (VIII) For the position in the com- plied by the correlation between the two scores.
pany, we assumed that no one would be indif- 16 Originally, expectancy-value theory prescribed
simple addition of the separate motives. This un-
ferent about his/her position in the company
realistically assumes that different motives are
worsening. We set the value of a worsened
mutually independent and have the same weight. A
position at -1 and restricted ourselves to this more realistic approach is to account for intercorre-
expectation by asking whether a person's posi- lations and different weights by using regression
tion in the company would worsen by par- analysis rather than simple summation (cf. Mitchell,
ticipating in moderate/militant action. 1974).

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 591

Table 1. The Attitudes Towards Shorter Working Time and the Instrumentality of Shorter Working Time for
Reducing Unemployment: Pearson Correlations of Single and Change Scores

Instrumentality

Nov. Jan. Early Feb. End of Feb. April

a) Single Scores
Attitude Towards
-shorter working hours .47*** .37** .44*** .38*** .48***
-shorter working week .35** .34** .33** .38*** .21*

Early Feb.! End of Feb.


Nov./Jan. Jan./Early Feb. End of Feb. April

b) Change Scores
Attitude Towards
-shorter working hours .35** .29* .39*** .44***
-shorter working week .19* .36** .25* .11
* p<.05.
** p<.o1.
p<.OO1.

Finn and Mattson (1978), in each regression types of action (4 and 10 percent in the last step
analysis the variables connected with one of and 20 and 31 percent in the first step). Militant
the three motives are included in the last step. actions are more controversial than moderate
The data show that the contribution of each of actions. Thus, reactions of significant others
the three motives in this last step is significant; will be more pronounced and have more influ-
each helps to account for the variance in the ence. Theoretically significant is the large
willingness to participate in action. Together contribution of the collective motives even
the motives account for 43 percent of the vari- when the other motives are accounted for. This
ance in the willingness to participate in militant is in opposition to Olson's (1977) argument that
action and 38 percent of the variance for mod- persons are not motivated to participate in
erate action. collective behavior by the collective good but
The contribution of reward motives is rela- only by selective incentives. For a better
tively small, possibly because these costs only theoretical understanding it is useful to break
really count when it actually comes to action, down the collective motive again. Most of the
and then especially if the action goes on a long members had a positive attitude toward shorter
time. Alternatively, it may be that the kinds of working time (see next paragraph); hence it
costs asked about (financial sacrifices, wors- follows that whether a person will be motivated
ening of the position in the company) are all in to participate by the collective good depends
the game for many people; only by becoming upon the expectancy component. The expec-
too high might they dissuade these people from tancy component is made up of three elements:
participation. There is a wide difference in the the expectation that participation contributes
contribution of the social motives for the two to the probability of success; -the expected
number of participants; and the expected suc-
cess if many people participate. The correla-
Table 2. Regression of Motives on the Willingness
tions between these elements were low, which
to Participate in Moderate and Militant
underlines the fact that each plays his/her own
Action: R2 Changes When a Motive is In-
role in the decision to participate. This is made
troduced in the Last Stepa
clear by the /3 coefficients in Table 3. The
Moderate Militant prominence of two elements (a2 and b) de-
Action Action serves some comment. Feelings of solidarity
A R2 A R2 and responsibility are reflected in the willing-
ness to support the union. Its weight validates
Collective Motives 13%*** 7%***
Social Motives 4%*** 10%*** Fireman and Gamson's (1979) argument that
Reward Motives 0.8%* 1%** group solidarity is an important determinant of
participation. The significance of expectations
a This table reflects the results of six stepwise
about the number of participants confirms the
regression analyses; the percentage in the table
applies to the motive on the left when it is introduced argument that the expected number of partici-
in the last step. pants is a self-fulfilling prophecy. Contrary to
* p<.05. Olson's logic, the willingness to participate in
** p<.Ol. collective action appears to be strengthened by
*** p<.oo1. the belief that many others will participate.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
592 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Table 3. Regressions of the Four Components of the Expectation that Participation Helps to Achieve the
Collective Good on the Willingness to Participate

Moderate Action Militant Action

B /3 B la
al. My participation doesn't matter .066 ** .052 .08*
(.027)a 11(.029)
a2. I participate because I want to support the union .296 39*** .282 35***
(.035) * (.038)
b. Number of participants .236 .28*** .29 .33***
(.039) (.040)
c. Expected success if many people participate .654 11** .075 12**
(.027) (.029)

R2 .57 .56

a Standard errors.
* .15<p<.10.
** p<.05.
*** p<.001.

The remainder of this discussion concerns knowledge is never more than a condition for
the results over the course of the campaign. the spread of a positive attitude toward a col-
Table- 4 gives a brief chronology of major lective good. The key concept here is the in-
events in the campaign in relation to the seven strumentality of the collective good for social
interview waves. changes felt to be worth fighting for or for the
preservation of a desirable situation. Cam-
paigns for the mobilization of consensus strive
Consensus Mobilization
to make such instrumentality plausible, often
Knowledge. Adequate diffusion of knowledge in the face of counterarguments by the oppo-
of the collective good is the cornerstone of nent. The 1979 campaign for a shorter work
every mobilization campaign. Collective week failed in this respect. The central ques-
goods., however, are not invariable quantities. tion was whether a shorter work week would
They can change, influenced by circum- have a positive effect on employment opportu-
stances, interaction with the opponent, etc. nity.
For a social movement, two dangers can arise: As Figure 4 shows, after an initial increase
(a) the collective good as it is defined initially there is a dramatic decrease in the extent to
does not become widely enough known; (b) which union members believed that a shorter
changes in the definition of the collective good work week would reduce unemployment.
do not become widely enough known. As can
be seen from Table 4, there were two policy
changes in the 1979 negotiations.
Figure 3 clearly shows that both policy
changes led to difficulties about the knowledge
of the goals. After a quite adequate initial level
(70-80Wo knew what the goals were), with the 90 change
1st policy

first policy change the number of people aware 80 4

of the changed goals was cut in half. A month 2nd policy


70 change
and a half later this number was once again 60

rising, but it did not reach the level of early


50
February. At the end of May the second policy
40
change took place, and again the number of
correct answers was cut in half. 30

In general, the union "elite" (the members 20

with a higher education and/or level of partici- 10

pation in the union) was better informed of the


goals of action after policy changes. Members end of mid- early end of mid- end of
outside these categories were less well in- Nov. Jan Febr. Febr. April May

Note Responses to first interview


formed and more vulnerable when it came to
dissemination of knowledge about changes in Figure 3. Percentages of Union Members Who
policy. Could Correctly Formulate the Demands
Beliefs and attitudes. Dissemination of for a Shorter Work Week

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 593

Table 4. Major Events in the Campaign

August 1978 The chair of the IB FNV proposes the 35-hour work week; mobilization
campaign starts; discussion on shorter work week begins

November 20-29, 1978 1 st interview

November 27, 1978 Government and employer organizations refuse to negotiate a nation-wide
agreement on a shorter work week.
December 1978 Steel strike in West Germany for a 35-hour work week.

January 4-18, 1979 2nd interview

End of January 1979 Steel strike in West Germany lost.

January 29-February 9 3rd interview

Beginning of February 1979 First policy change: 35 hours becomes 39 hours.

February 19-March 2 4th interview

March/April Negotiations with AKZO make no progress.

April 3-18 5th interview

April 17 Negotiations with AKZO break down.


April 24 Second policy change: 39 hours becomes a few days off.
May 15 Negotiations with AKZO start again.

May 18-26 6th interview

May 23 Agreement with AKZO


June 5-18 Membership meetings: membership agrees with contract.

June 11-July 11 7th interview

From the end of February onwards a majority instrumentality of the collective good for
no longer believed this. As expected, the de- valued social changes. Very often, as in the
velopments in the attitude toward a shorter case of reducing unemployment, the social
work week show the same picture, although change itself is above all discussion. The real
without becoming negative. These results problem is to make people believe that the
make clear the importance of beliefs about the collective good will advance this change.

Action Mobilization
definitely
instrumental
2.00 A mobilizing organization will try to make the
.40 benefits of participation and the costs of non-
\30 participation as high as possible, and the costs
.20 . \ of participation and the benefits of non-
.10 participation as low as possible. There are
0?- various ways of doing this: (a) choosing the
-.10
type of action; (b) choosing the scene, and (c)
-.20
influencing the motives to participate. This
-.30 \
must be viewed in the context of maneuvers by
-.40
the opponent and/or external events which
-2.00 A
may influence the costs and benefits of partici-
definitely end of mid- early end of mid-
not instru- Nov. Jan.' Febr. Febr. April
pation. The degree of success achieved in an
mental
action-mobilization campaign can be read from
Note Responses to first interviews.
Significant trend: F-lineair = 7.29, p <.01, df = 1.
the willingness to take action.
Difference jan. - april: p<.01 Figure 5 presents the developments in the
willingness to participate in moderate and mil-
Figure 4. Mean Perceived Instrumentality of Shorter
itant action. The figures for Ede and Oss did
Working Hours for Reducing Unemploy- not differ significantly, so they are presented
ment together. In the establishments in Ede and Oss

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
594 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Moderate action Militant action

Willing to Willing to
participate participate

1.00 1.00

.40 .40

.30 .30

.20 - .20 -

0?0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
0~~~~~~~~~~~

- .20 -~~0~ .20 ?

--~~~
.10~~ 03
- 0 01
.10 ?~~?
0~~~~~~~~~~~

_O.,5 , -- ,-- - 00
0-~~ - -O 0- -0
- .30 - . 30--

- .40- - .40

Notwilling to late mid- early late mid- Notwilling to late mid- early late mid-
rarticipate Nov. Jan. Febr. Febr. April participate Nov. Jan. Febr. Febr. April

Ermen - -- Ec O-SS Dnen - F- Ede / Oss

Notes Ede and Oss, no significant differences between groups; no significant trend.
Emren, moderate action: linear trend; F-unique = 5.711, df = , p< .05; F-step = 5.554. df 1,
p < .05. Militant action: no significant trend; difference Nov. - April: p = .12.

Figure 5. Mean Willingness to Take Action

there was a weak willingness to participate in number of participants could vary from very
moderate action, and no willingness to partici- few to very many. Because members estimated
pate in militant action throughout the entire the efficacy of an action based on the number
period. In Emmen, willingness to participate in ot participants, the percentage that expected
both types of action was comparatively high at very many colleagues to participate was of
first, but it gradually melted away. Initially, interest.
Emmen had the most potential participants, Figure 6 concentrates on the outcomes for
but by April the opposite was true. one of the three establishments (Emmen) be-
From these results we can conclude that the cause of dramatic changes there. In the other
union did not succeed in mobilizing its mem- two the percentages were low throughout the
bers. In two of the three establishments there campaign.
was a willingness to participate in moderate As Figure 6 shows, the percentages of union
action, it is true, but it very soon became clear members who expected very many participants
that moderate action would not be of any help, decline rapidly, indicating that the campaign
and the initial willingness to participate in mil- was losing its momentum. After an initial in-
itant action in the third establishment disap- crease (up to 58 percent in the case of moderate
peared. action and 39 percent in the case of militant
Changes in the costs and beliefits of partici- action), starting in January there was a sharp
pation. Theoretically, the willingness to take decline which reached 4.5 percent in April, or
action is a function of collective, social and the level at Ede and Oss at the time.'7
reward motives. We have already shown that
the collective good lost in value. Over the same
period the expectation that participation would '' If, instead of the percentage that expect very
help to achieve the collective good lost its many participants, we use changes in the mean esti-
force, not because members no longer believed mate of the number of participants, we find the same
pattern, except that the mean runs somewhat less
that their participation would contribute to the
steeply. For moderate action, we found a significant
probability of success, but because they grew
quadratic trend (F-unique = 7.074, df = 1, p = .01;
more and more pessimistic about the number F-step = 6. 181, df = 1, p = .01). For militant action
of participants and the probability of success we foUnd a marginally significant linear trend (F-
even if many people were to participate. tunique - 3.33, df = 1, p = .08( F=step = 3.075, df =
Niuminber (f particip(lats. Estimates of the
I, p .0)X.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION

employers went down to 25 percent, and for


moderate action to 10 percent.
60
Due to failing consensus mobilization, action
mobilization which lost its momentum, and
50 . external events that made success unlikely, the
collective motive to participate vanished. It
40 /
was weak in two of the three establishments
from the outset, and it disappeared in the third.
30 /
Since the reward motives had been negative for
20 many people from the beginnning, 18 only social
motives might have compensated for this loss
10
in motivation. In Emmen, however, the social
motives diminished as well, although not in
the same dramatic way as the collective mo-
end of mid- early eind of mid-
tives. In Ede and Oss the social motives for
Nov. Jan. Febr. Febr. April
participation in militant action were negative,
- militant action ----- moderate action so they strengthened the aversion to militant
Figure 6. Percentages of Union Members in Emmen action. In the case of moderate action, how-
Who Expect that Very Many Colleagues ever, the social motives were positive and did
will Participate in Action, by Type of compensate for the absence of collective mo-
Action tives. This explains why we found a weak
willingness to participate in moderate action
there.
Probability of success. Perhaps more than Type of action. Different costs and benefits
the other determinants of the willingness to are associated with participation in different
participate, the probability of success is influ- types of action. Table 5 summarizes evidence
enced by external events. The 1979 negotia- on the interaction of motives and moderate or
tions provide a good example. militant action in relation to willingness to par-
In 1979, at the start of the negotiations in the ticipate. Persons who only wish to take part in
Netherlands, a strike broke out in West Ger- moderate action are compared with persons
many in which a shorter work week was also at who are also willing to take part in militant
stake. The strike lasted six weeks. Both sides actions. '9 The first group is of interest because
played hard. Ultimately the West German they perceive such differences in the costs and
unions lost the strike, and early in February benefits that they are not willing to participate
they concluded an agreement which made no
reference to a shorter work week. This out- militant action is
40%1 definitely
come also affected the negotiations in the effective
0

Netherlands, and this was expressed most - - nmerate action is


30% - definitely
clearly in the expected success of actions effective

there. Figure 7 shows the changes in those 20%

expectations. Since we found no significant


differences between the establishments, the re- 10% - - _ -

sults are here combined.


Even before the disappointing end to the
West German steel strike, the adamant attitude late mid- early late mid-
Nov. Jan. Febr. Febr. April

of the Dutch employers had already made it


clear that little could be gained by moderate Note derate action linear trerd, F-unque = 7.313, df = 1,
p 4.01; F-step = 7.71, df = 1, p < .01.
action. The number of union members who felt Militant action F-unique = 6.21, df = 1, p .05;
F-step = 6.17, df = 1, p < .05.
moderate action would be effective showed an
immediate and rapid decrease. Members re- Figure 7. The Effectiveness of Trade Union Action
mained optimistic longer about the effective- in Attaining the Goal of a Shorter Work
ness of militant action. But this optimism also Week

suffered a setback when, around mid-January


and early February, the metal unions in West
"I For instance, on the average, 50% feared wors-
Germany lost their strike. Of the union mem-
ening of their position in the company in the case of
bers questioned in early February, 60 percent
participation in militant action, and 32% in the case
felt this would make the negotiations in the of moderate action.
Netherlands a good deal more difficult. Figure '9 Seventy-three persons were not willing to par-
7 reflects this gloomy outlook; the percentage ticipate in any kind of action. They are omitted from
of union members who were confident that this table because they are not relevant for this dis-
militant action would change the minds of the cussion.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
596 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Table 5. Mean Costs and Benefits of Participation in Moderate or Militant Action by Willingness to Take
Action

Wishes to Participate in
Wishes to Participate in Both Moderate and
Moderate Action Only Militant Action
(n = 79) (n = 200)
Collective Motives
a. How many colleagues will partici-
pate in moderate action? 2.41 2.82
same for militant action 1.69 2.54
b. Is moderate action effective? 0.51 0.25
same for militant action 0.51 0.85
Social Motives
c. moderate action 0.26 0.56
militant action -0.68 0.44
Reward Motives
d. Will position in company grow
worse as a result of participation
in moderate action? -0.33 -0.25
same for militant action -0.66 -0.40

in militant action. The first column of Table 5 collective motive is stronger for militant action
reveals these differences, especially in the so- because such action is perceived to be more
cial and reward motives. In the perception of efficacious. If one has to accept costs anyhow,
these persons, for militant action the costs of the more efficacious type of action is to be
participation are considerably higher than for preferred even if the costs are higher.
moderate action. Such differences could be Different plants. There were large dif-
balanced by collective motives. A look at ferences among the three plants in the strength
Table 5, however, makes it clear that this is not of the union (Table 6). Of the three establish-
the case. There are no differences in perceived ments, the union was strongest in Emmen. In
efficacy, and regarding the number of col- accordance with resource mobilization lit-
leagues, these persons are more pessimistic erature, at the start of the negotiations the
about militant action. In their perception, willingness to take action was the highest in
moderate action has a higher probability of Emmen; Table 6 shows why. To summarize
success because they expect more people to be the evidence: the stronger the position of the
willing to participate. So why should they take union, the greater is the chance that colleagues
the higher costs of militant action? will motivate people to participate; the less
A comparison of this group with the group they fear for worsening their position in the
that supported militant action shows important company, the more favorable can be the ex-
differences in social and collective motives. pected number of participants. The result is
Whereas the social motives of the "moderate" that the members are more easily mobilized. A
group are negative, those of the "militant" union can capitalize on this state of affairs by
group are positive. Optimism about the effi- fighting a conflict where it is strongest, that is,
cacy of militant action and the number of par- in plants that are highly unionized and have a
ticipants results in strong collective motives strong union network. This does not imply,
among the "militant" group as compared to the however, that the union can be assured of
"moderate" group. willingness to take action in such plants. This
It is of interest to note that the differences only refers to the potential which may be
between the two groups on the reward motives mobilized. A campaign that does not go well,
are not very large. In both groups many per- counterpropaganda, and setbacks can also
crush willingness to take action in such plants.
sons expect a worsening of their position in the
company. Nevertheless, all these people are The negotiations of 1979 were a vivid example
willing to participate because other motives of this.
compensate for the costs.
The evidence in Table 5 warrants a final re-
DISCUSSION
mark. The differences in perceived costs and
benefits of each type of action for the "mili- The theory formulated in this paper aims a
tant" group suggest that for this group militantbreak with both the traditional social-
action is more attractive. The social and re- psychological approaches to social movements
ward motives differ only slightly, whereas theand the neglect of social-psychological

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 597

Table 6. The Strength of the Trade Union, the Expected Reactions of Colleagues, the Fear for a Worsened
Position, and the Expected Number of Participants in the Three Plants

Trade Expects Positive Fears for a Expects


Level of Union Reactions of Worsened Very Many
Organization Network Colleaguesa Positiona Participantsb

Enka-Emmen 65% + 60% 32% 39%


Enka-Ede 30% - 23% 59% 5%
AKZO-Pharma-Oss 15% + 25% 59% 5%

a Expectancies of participation in militant action. Mean percentages from the series of interviews.
b Expectancies of participation in militant action. Highest percentage.

analyses by resource mobilization theory. not participate in a social movement unless


Contrary to the traditional social-psychological selective incentives motivate them to do so.
approach, participation in a social movement is Resource mobilization theory does not really
assumed to be rational. The emphasis is not on solve that problem. Concepts like ideological
personality characteristics or psychological incentives (Gamson, 1975; Carden, 1978),
states, but on the psychological process of feelings of solidarity (Gamson and Fireman,
weighing costs and benefits. One of the objec- 1979) or responsibility (Fleishman, 1980), the
tions to the traditional approach is that it de- perceived indispensability of an individual's
fines participation as tension release, and thus contribution (Tolbert, 1981), differences be-
it does not matter in which movement a person tween action forms in vulnerability to free rid-
participates. In the theory presented in this ing (Gamson and Fireman, 1979; Oliver, 1980),
article it does. Participation is seen as a ra- different production functions (Oberschall,
tional choice in the situation as the person per- 1980; Oliver et al., 1983), or thresholds
ceives it, and as a way to obtain desired out- (Granovetter, 1978) do not really touch the
comes. In the eyes of the participant, partici- heart of the matter, which is- that persons have
pation is a means of reaching valued goals. to decide at a point when they do not know
These goals and their relation to factors such whether others will participate.20 This article
as relative deprivation and frustration have argues that the problem can be solved on a
been the subject of much discussion in social- social-psychological level. Since people have
movement literature. Resource mobilization expectations about others' behavior, they can
has ruled this discussion out of order without formulate their "own" production functions.
solving the problem. The theory developed in As the evidence presented demonstrates, this
this article attempts to reconcile the social psy- production function heavily influences the
chological and resource mobilization ap- willingness to participate. On a collective level,
proaches in this respect. Feelings of relative the expectation that others will participate
deprivation or frustration do not necessarily works as a self-fulfilling prophecy. Counter to
evoke agreement with the goals of a movement Olson's argument, a collective good can moti-
which pretends to remedy these feelings: goals vate persons to participate in a social move-
have to be perceived as instrumental to the ment if they expect that others will also par-
elimination of these feelings. The research re- ticipate.
sults support the validity of this argument. 'Moreover, if the expectancy component is a
Theoretical emphasis must therefore shift from little larger than zero, a collective motive to
relative deprivation to the perceived instru- participate can exist if the collective good is
mentality of the collective good for the elimi- valued highly (cf. Oberschall, 1980). If a person
nation of relative deprivation. Such percep- comes from a supportive social background
tions do not originate spontaneously. Consen- (positive social motive) then there can be quite
sus mobilization is needed for this. Campaigns a few nonsocial costs of participation (negative
are needed which explain the situation and reward motive) before the balance turns to the
make clear why the collective good will bring negative. Oliver et al.'s (1983) theoretical no-
relief (cf. Schwartz, 1976). Agreement with the
goals of the movement does not necessarily
lead to participation: a person may doubt 20 Pinard (1983) arrived at the same conclusion.
whether participation will help to achieve the Using an expectancy-value framework, Pinard tried
to solve the problem primarily by expanding the
goals, social and/or reward motives may be too
value component with moral obligation as a separate
negative.
force. He mentioned expectancy of success as a
Theories that stress the rationality of partici-
factor but did not elaborate it in detail. In contrast to
pation in a social movement have to solve the Pinard, the solution here is sought in the expectancy
problem of the dilemma of collective behavior. component by introducing "expectations about
As Olson (1977) stated it, rational persons will others' behavior" as a separate factor.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
598 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

tions about the different production functions (Oberschall, 1973) are important in this re-
that characterize the relationship between in- spect. Influencing reward motives demands
dividual contribution, the number of partici- manipulation of rewards and punishments, for
pants and the production of the collective good instance, by creating organizations that can
are not invalidated by this argument. In par- help victims, decrease risks or collect money in
ticular, their hypotheses concerning the dif- support of activists (cf. Morris, 1981).
ferential mobilizability of people depending on
the part of a function that is relevant for them
still stand. We must keep in mind, however, REFERENCES
that individuals construct their own functions
based on their expectations; although these Barnes, Samuel H. and Max Kaase
1979 Political Action. Mass Participation in Five
expectations need not be real, they are real in
Western Democracies. London: Sage.
their consequences.
Campbell, Donald and Julian C. Stanley
The evidence presented makes it clear that 1966 Experimental and Quasi-Experimental De-
such expectations, in combination with selec- signs for Research. Chicago: Rand Mc-
tive costs and benefits, are of great importance Nally.
for the choice a person makes among alterna- Campbell, John P. and Robert D. Pritchard
tive forms of action. For instance, in the eyes 1977 "Motivation theory in industrial and orga-
of some respondents the goal could be reached nizational psychology." Pp. 63-131 in Mar-
by moderate action. Why should they take the vin D. Dunnette (ed.), Handbook of Indus-
trial and Organizational Psychology.
higher risks of militant action? For those who
Chicago: Rand McNally.
did not believe moderate action to be effective,
Carden, Maren L.
it did not make much sense to accept the costs 1978 "The proliferation of a social movement,
of such action. They preferred to participate in ideology and individual incentives in the
militant action, even though the perceived contemporary feminist movement." Pp.
costs were higher. 179- 96 in Louis Kriesberg (ed.), Research
People's expectations are based on past ex- in Social Movements, Conflict and Change,
periences. In a mobilization campaign a Volume 1. Greenwich, CT: JAI.
Davies, James
movement organization tries to influence these
1962 "Towards a theory of revolution." Ameri-
expectations. Resource mobilization theory
can Sociological Review 27:5-19.
has used the mobilization concept in a rather Feather, N.
unspecific way. By making the distinction be- 1982 Expectations and Actions: Expectancy-
tween consensus and action mobilization we Value Models in Psychology. Hillsdale, NJ:
separated the processes of convincing and ac- Erlbaum.
tivating. The research results on the spread of Ferree, Myra M. and Frederick D. Miller
knowledge and the beliefs about the instru- Forth- "Mobilization and meaning: toward an inte-
mentality of shorter working time showed the com- gration of social psychological and resource
ing perspectives on social movements."
importance of consensus mobilization as a sep-
Sociological Inquiry.
arate process. Schwartz (1976) made a similar
Finn, J. D. and I. Mattson
distinction between "ignorance reduction" and 1978 Multivariate Analysis in Educational Re-
"organizational disciplinization." The im- search. Chicago: International Education
portance of such distinctions is that they Service.
specify convincing and activating as two dif- Fireman, Bruce and William A. Gamson
ferent processes with different determinants. 1979 "Utilitarian logic in the resource mobiliza-
In yet another way, research on mobilization tion perspective." Pp. 8-45 in Mayer N.
Zald and John D. McCarthy (eds.), The
would do well, to specify mobilization efforts.
Dynamics of Social Movements. Cam-
Attempts to influence different motives require
bridge, MA: Winthrop.
different efforts. Influencing the collective
Fleishman, John A.
motive demands consensus mobilization for 1980 "Collective action as helping behavior: ef-
the collective good, but also attempts to influ- fects of responsibility diffusion on contri-
ence the expectations about the behavior of butions to a public good." Journal of Per-
others, the probability of success, and the indi- sonality and Social Psychology 38:629-37.
vidual contribution to the probability of suc- Freeman, Jo
cess. For instance, by means of tryouts it can 1979 "Resource mobilization and strategy: a
model for analyzing social movement orga-
be proved that others will participate. This is a
nization actions." Pp. 167-89 in Mayer
delicate affair, because one can make persons
N. Zald and John D. McCarthy (eds.), The
believe that enough people will participate and Dynamics of Social Movements. Cam-
that their participation is not necessary. Inten- bridge, MA: Winthrop.
sifying social motives requires influencing a Freud, Sigmund
person' s social environment. Social networks 1922 Group Psychology and the Analysis of Ego.
(Snow et al., 1980) and mobilization en bloc London: Hogarth.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 599

Gamson, William A. extensions, critique." Pp. 125-63 in Nor-


1975 The strategy of Social Protest. Homewood, man T. Feather (ed.), Expectations and
IL: Dorsey. Actions. Hillsdale: Erlbaum.
Gamson, William A., Bruce Fireman and Steve Landsberger, Henri A.
Rytina 1976 "Labor movements, social movements and
1982 Encounters with Unjust Authorities. social mobility." Pp. 839-77 in Robert
Homewood, IL: Dorsey. Dubin (ed.), Handbook of Work Organiza-
Gerlach, Luther P. and Virginia H. Hine tion and Society. Chicago: Rand McNally.
1970 People, Power, Change: Movements of So- Leahy, Peter and Allen Mazur
cial Transformation. Indianapolis: 1978 "A comparison of movements opposed to
Bobbs-Merrill nuclear power, fluoridation and abortion."
Geschwender, James A. Pp. 143-54 in Louis Kriesberg (ed.), Re-
1968 "Explorations in the theory of social search in Social Movements, Conflicts and
movements and revolutions." Social Forces Change, Volume 1. Greenwich, CT: JAI.
47:127-35. LeBon, Gustave
Granberg, Donald and Sbren Holmberg [1903] "The mind of the crowds." Pp. 6-11 in
1983 "Modeling the relationships among prefer- 1968 Louis E. Genevie (ed.), Collective Behav-
ence, expectations and voting behavior." ior and Social Movements. Itasca, IL:
Department of Political Science, University Peacock.
of Gdteborg. Marsh, Alan
Granovetter, Mark 1977 Protest and Political Consciousness.
1978 "Threshold models of collective behavior." London/Beverly Hills: Sage.
American Journal of Sociology 83:1420-43. Marx, Gary T. and James L. Wood
Gurr, Ted Robert 1975 "Strands of theory and research in collec-
1970 Why Men Rebel. Princeton, NJ: Princeton tive behavior." Annual Review of Sociol-
University Press. ogy 1:363-429.
Heberle, Rudolf McCarthy, John D. and Mayer N. Zald
1968 "Social movements I: types and functions 1976 "Resource mobilization and social move-
of social movements." Pp. 438-44 in D.L. ments: a partial theory." American Journal
Sills (ed.), International Encyclopedia of of Sociology 82:1212-93.
the Social Sciences. New York: Macmillan. Mitchel, Robert C.
Hoffer, Eric 1979 "National environmental lobbies and the
1951 The True Believer. New York: Harper. apparent illogic of collective action." Pp.
Isaac, Larry, Elizabeth Mutran and Sheldon Stryker 87-121 in Clifford S. Russell (ed.), Collec-
1980 "Political protest orientations among black tive Decision Making Applications from
and white adults." American Sociological Public Choice Theory. Baltimore: The Johns
Review 45:191-213. Hopkins University Press.
Jenkins, J. Craig Mitchell, Terence R.
1983 "Resource mobilization theory and the 1974 "Expectancy models of job satisfaction,
study of social movements." Annual Re- occupational preference and effort: a
view of Sociology 9:527-53. theoretical, methodological and empirical
Kenniston, Kenneth appraisal." Psychological Bulletin
1968 Young Radicals: Notes on Committed 81:1053-77.
Youth. New York: Harvest. Moore, Robert S.
Kerpelman, Louis C. 1975 "Religion as a source of variation in
1969 "Student political activism and ideology: working-class images of society." Pp.
comparative characteristics of activists and 35-55 in Martin Bulmer (ed.), Working-
non-activists." Journal of Counseling Psy- Class Images of Society. London: Rout-
chology 16:8-13. ledge and Kegan Paul.
Klandermans, P.G. Bert Morris, Aldon
1979 "Werklozen en de werklozenbeweging." 1981. "Black Southern student sit-in move-
Mens en Maatschappij 54:5-33. ments: an analysis of internal organiza-
1983a "The expected number of participants, the tion." American Sociological Review
effectiveness of collective action, and the 46:744-67.
willingness to participate: the free riders
dilemma reconsidered." Paper presented at
Oberschall, Anthony
1973 Social Conflict and Social Movements. En-
the 1983 American Sociological Association
Annual Meeting, Detroit. glewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
1980 "Loosely structured collective conflict: a
1983b "Rotter's I.E.-scale and socio-political
theory and an application." Pp. 45-68 in
action-taking: the balance of 20 years of
Louis Kriesberg (ed.), Research in Social
research." European Journal of Social Psy-
Movements, Conflict and Change, Volume
chology 13:399-415.
3. Greenwich, CT: JAI,
Kornhauser, William
1959 The politics of mass society. Glencoe, IL: Oliver, Pamela
Free Press. 1980 "Rewards and punishments as selective in-
Kuhl, Julius centives for collective action: theoretical
1982 "Expectancy-value approach within the investigations." American Journal of
theory of social motivation: elaborations, Sociology 85:1356-75.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
600 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Oliver, Pamela, Gerald Marwell and Ruy Teixeira microstructurat approach to differential re-
1983 "Group heterogeneity, interdependence cruitment." American Sociological Review
and the production of collective goods: a 45:787-801.
theory of the critical mass, I." Madison, Tilly, Charles
WI: Department of Sociology, University 1979 "Repertoires of contention in America and
of Wisconsin. Britain, 1750-1830." Pp. 126-156 in Mayer
Olson, Mancur Zald and John McCarthy (eds.), The
1977 The Logic of Collective Action. Public Dynamics of Social Movements. Cam-
Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cam- bridge, MA: Winthrop.
bridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Toch, Hans
Pinard, Maurice 1966 The Social Psychology of Social Move-
1983 "From deprivation to mobilization." Paper ments. London: Methuen.
presented at the Annual Meetings of the
Tolbert, Pamela
American Sociological Association, De-
1981 "Determinants of social movement partici-
troit.
pation." Paper presented at the Annual
Ragin, Charles C., Shelley Coverman and Mark
Meetings of the American Sociological As-
Hayward
sociation, Toronto.
1982 "Major labor disputes in Britain 1902-
1938." American Sociological Review Useem, Bert
47:238-53. 1980 "Solidarity model, breakdown model and
Roberts Ron E. and Robert Marsh Kloss the Boston anti-busing movement." Ameri-
1974 Social Movements Between the Balcony can Sociological Review 45:357-69.
and the Barricade. Saint Louis: C. V. Walsh, Edward J.
Mosby. 1978 "Mobilization theory vis a vis a mobilization
Rothman, Jack process: the case of the United Farm
1974 Planning and Organizing for Social Change. Workers movement." Pp. 155-77 in Louis
New York: Columbia University Press. Krnesberg (ed.), Research in Social Move-
Rotter, Julian B. ments, Conflicts and Change, Volume 1.
1954 Social Learning and Clinical Psychology. Greenwich, CT: JAI.
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Walsh, Edward J. and Rex H. Warland
1972 "Beliefs, social attitudes and behavior: a
1983 "Social movement involvement in the wake
social learning analysis." Pp. 335-51 in Ju-
of a nuclear accident: activists and free rid-
lian B. Rotter, June E. Chance, and E.
ers in the Three Mile Island area." American
Jerry Phares (eds.), Applications of a Social
Sociological Review 48:764-81.
Learning Theory of Personality. New York:
Zald, Mayer and John D. McCarthy
Holt, Rinehart & Winston.
1979 The Dynamics of Social Movements: Re-
Schwartz, Michael
1976 Radical Protest and Social Structure. New source Mobilization, Social Control and
Tactics. Cambridge, MA: Winthrop.
York: Academy Press.
Smelser, Neil J. Zurcher, Louis A., Jr., and David A. Snow
1971 Theory of Collective Behavior. New York: 1981 "Collective behavior: social movements."
Free Press. Pp. 447-82 in Morris Rosenberg and Ralph
Snow-, David A., Louis A. Zurcher, Jr., and Sheldon H. Turner (eds.), Social Psychology,
Ekland-Olson Sociological Perspectives. New York:
1980 "Social networks and social movements: a Basic.

This content downloaded from


187.250.41.241 on Fri, 20 Oct 2023 19:53:28 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like