Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 13

AGRICULTURAL

ECONOMICS

Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163

On the efficiency of composting organic wastes


Iddo Kana,∗ , Ofira Ayalonb , Roy Federmanb
a Department of Agricultural Economics and Management, The Robert H. Smith Faculty of Agriculture, Food and Environment,
The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, P.O.Box 12, Rehovot 76100, Israel
b Natural Resource and Environmental Research Center, University of Haifa, Mt. Carmel, Haifa 31905, Israel

Received 2 April 2009; received in revised form 17 September 2009; accepted 28 October 2009

Abstract
We develop a mathematical programming model for the analysis of a nationwide waste-management system based on composting of organic
wastes. The model integrates a wide range of engineering, environmental, and economic factors, including estimated production functions based
on agronomic experimental data, as well as demand functions for vegetative agricultural products. The model is applied to the case of Israel,
comprising 14 groups of municipalities as the source of organic municipal solid waste and wastewater-treatment sludge, 8 composting plants, and
13 agricultural regions; the latter constitute the source of livestock manure and are the consumers of compost to be potentially applied to 42 crops.
From a social point of view, 90% of the compost’s potential production was found to be warranted. This efficient solution, however, does not emerge
under the base-year-observed situation, largely because of the absence of source separation of organic municipal solid waste and the farmers’ lack
of awareness of compost’s advantages as a substitute for conventional fertilizers and as a soil-amending product. Consequently, most of the organic
wastes are disposed of by landfilling, resulting in a loss of $102 million per year in terms of net social benefits. While the consumers of agricultural
products are expected to benefit from a shift from the base-year situation to the efficient solution, most of their gain is expected to come at the
expense of the farming sector. Nevertheless, the appearance of the efficient solution does not depend on administrative compensation payments,
but on the removal of bottlenecks. Potential government intervention strategies to promote the change are analyzed.

JEL classification: Q28, Q53

Keywords: Agriculture; Economics; Waste management; Recycling; Positive mathematical programming

1. Introduction landfills in order to reduce methane emissions, a potent green-


house gas, from landfills, and stresses the importance of biolog-
Governmental intervention in waste-management systems is ical treatment of the organic municipal solid waste (OMSW).
rationalized by both the involvement of externalities (Ayalon However, the extent to which composting of OMSW is justifi-
et al., 2000, 2001) and the public-good nature of this service. able should be considered in view of economic considerations,
Frequently, the intervention takes the form of setting goals based while taking into account a wide range of environmental, tech-
on technological and environmental considerations. The Euro- nological, and economic factors. For instance, the demand for
pean national waste strategy, set up according to Article 5(2) of OMSW compost is affected by farmers’ perceptions of the con-
EU Council Directive 99/31/EC of 26 April 1999 (EU, 2007), is tribution of compost to agricultural production, which depends
an example of this approach. This Directive sets specific targets on the content of organic matter in the soils, climatic conditions,
for the reduction of biodegradable municipal waste going to compost quality, and the presence of compost produced from
alternative organic materials, such as livestock manure (LM)
and wastewater-treatment sludge (WTS). The supply depends
∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +972-8-9489233; fax: +972-8-9466267. on the compost’s production and transportation costs, as well as
E-mail address: kan@agri.huji.ac.il (I. Kan)
on the savings realized by avoiding landfilling of OMSW. All of
Data Appendix Available Online
these economic factors are highly sensitive to government in-
A data appendix to replicate main results is available in the online version of tervention, not only in the waste-management system, but also
this article. Please note: Wiley-Blackwell Inc. is not responsible for the content
or functionality of any supporting information supplied by the authors. Any
through provision of agricultural research and guidance.
queries (other than missing material) should be directed to the corresponding The primary objective of this study is to develop an economic
author for the article. model to evaluate the extent to which it is worthwhile, from


c 2010 International Association of Agricultural Economists DOI: 10.1111/j.1574-0862.2009.00432.x
152 I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163

a social point of view, to use composting as a solution for toxins is significantly reduced (Eunomia, 2002). However,
organic waste disposal, and to apply it to a case study—the given the investments associated with source separation, it is
case of Israel. The secondary objective is to utilize the model expected that municipalities will adopt this waste-collection
to assess the potential impact of some policy instruments by management provided that agreements ensure a steady con-
which government intervention can advance realization of the sumption of the separated materials in the long run. Since such
socially optimal solution. agreements frequently require the involvement of a few neigh-
There is a vast amount of scientific information on vari- boring agricultural enterprises and local authorities, the cen-
ous aspects of organic waste treatment and its agricultural tral government may initiate and stimulate the formation of
uses; for example, logistic processes (Chakrabarti and Sarkhel, such regional cooperations by creating appropriate economic
2003); air pollution (He et al., 2001); compost productivity, incentives (e.g., by providing guarantees with respect to prices
soil fertility, and water-holding capacity (Annabi et al., 2007; and consumption). Even so, the demand for compost by the
Avnimelech, 1997; Stewart et al., 2000); and socioeconomic agricultural sector depends on the farmers’ recognition of the
aspects (Hayashi et al., 2004; Janzen et al., 1999). Each of benefits of compost application. Afik Engineering and Lavee
these studies considers some of the elements associated with the (2000) found that farmers’ perception of compost productivity
aforementioned objectives. In this article, we present a compre- is highly dependent on both the quality of the compost and rec-
hensive nationwide-scale economic analysis of organic waste ommendations by the authorities (IMARD, 2008). Therefore,
recycling through composting, that (1) encompasses the main the government can play a major role in increasing the demand
types of competing sources for organic raw materials, (2) ex- for compost by both setting and enforcing clear standards for
plicitly incorporates the agricultural productivity of compost, high-quality compost, and by disseminating scientific informa-
(3) considers costs associated with alternative disposal meth- tion on compost’s advantages via the government’s agricultural
ods, (4) accounts for monetarily evaluated external impacts guidance services. For example, the demand for compost might
stemming from the relevant waste-disposal strategies, and (5) increase if farmers were informed that applying compost to cal-
takes into account the spatial nature of the problem, as well careous soils—such as those in Israel—significantly reduces
as (6) variations in prices of vegetative agricultural products the risk of heavy-metal pollution (Avnimelech, 1986).
under partial equilibrium conditions. The analytical framework Our analysis integrates, within an economic model, a wide
is based on the development of a spatial positive mathematical range of science-based information in order to calculate the
programming (PMP) (Howitt, 1995) partial equilibrium model, efficient1 level of compost production in the case of Israel, and
and its application to the case of Israel. the consequent social benefits in a situation in which all of the
There are two reasons why composting should be considered abovementioned compost production and consumption barriers
a promising waste-management strategy in Israel. The first is are removed. In addition, we examine whether government in-
associated with the supply of organic materials. Landfill space tervention in the form of compensation payments to some of
is becoming scarce (Hoshva Consultants, 2005), and therefore the involved agents is required to realize the efficient solution.
Israel’s Waste Master Plan sets specific targets for reducing the
fraction of landfilled waste to 50% by the year 2025 (IMEP,
2. The model
2008b). Composting constitutes an alternative disposal solu-
tion for OMSW, which comprises the highest fraction (40%)
The model is developed to take into account the spatial distri-
of the total MSW produced in Israel (IMEP, 2008a). Moreover,
bution of the sources of organic waste, the composting plants,
diverting organic waste from landfills reduces the emission of
and the agricultural regions in which compost may be applied.
greenhouse gases, groundwater pollution, and other environ-
Fourteen groups of the urban and rural settlements throughout
mental burdens (Ayalon et al., 2003). The second reason is
Israel are the sources of OMSW and WTS. Each settlement
related to the demand for compost: in this semiarid region,
group (SG) is characterized by the quantity of OMSW and
compost productivity is high due to low soil organic content.
WTS produced there, and a geographic location represented by
Nevertheless, to date, only 30% of compost’s potential pro-
the center of the group’s largest city. We consider 13 agricul-
duction (of 1.725 million tons per year from OMSW, LM, and
tural regions of demand for compost based on data reported
WTS) is realized. This apparently low rate is due to various
by the Israeli Central Bureau of Statistics (ICBS, 2004). Each
constraints associated with processing of the raw materials and
region is characterized by a point located at its geographic
use of compost by the agricultural sector. The production of
center,2 and by the different crops grown there, 42 crops alto-
compost from WTS is expected to remain negligible until the
gether. These agricultural regions also constitute sources of LM.
regulations prohibiting discharge into the Mediterranean Sea
under the Barcelona Declaration in 1995 (EU, 2008) come into
1 Efficiency refers to a situation in which potential improvements according
effect in 2012. The low production of OMSW compost is at-
tributed mainly to low agricultural demand, which is associated to the Kaldor–Hicks criterion are unachievable.
2 The distance between a composting plant and the center of an agricultural
with the product’s low quality resulting from the absence of region is assumed to represent the average distance from the plant to the various
source separation of MSW—if waste is separated at the source, agricultural plots throughout that region. The same assumption holds with
the risk of polluting agricultural output with heavy metals and respect to the largest city in a settlement group.
I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163 153

Compost is assumed to be produced at eight plants, some of where βiw , βis , and βkl (all in $ per ton ) are, respectively, the
which are currently operational, while the rest are located in landfilling costs of nonseparated MSW,4 WTS, and LM in the
official landfills.3 Since the process of collecting OMSW is respective regions in which they are created. While precom-
based on separation at the source, the model does not incor- posting treatment of WTS and LM is assumed similar to the
porate sorting plants. Moreover, source separation ensures the prelandfilling process, recycling of OMSW is associated with
production of high-quality compost with low levels of metal additional costs due to source separation of MSW
and salt contents (Hargreaves et al., 2008).
The model maximizes an objective function by allocating 
14 
8

the three sources of organic waste to the plants, allocating the CS = μ wij , (2)
i=1 j =1
compost produced there to the agricultural regions, determin-
ing the amount of compost applied to each crop grown in each where μ ($ per ton) is the additional collection cost per separated
region, and allocating the regional agricultural lands among OMSW unit.
the crops. The objective function encompasses the benefits and The annual amount of compost sent from plant j to region k
costs associated with the analyzed system. The benefits com- is denoted cjk (ton per year). The total compost production costs
prise the savings incurred by avoiding waste landfilling—the are given by
cheapest authorized waste-disposal alternative in Israel (EMC,
1996), and the contribution of compost to farming income 
8 
8 
13
through soil amendment and savings in fertilizers, while the C CP = ϕ1 δj + ϕ2 cj k , (3)
costs include the expenses related to agricultural production, j =1 j =1 k=1
compost-production processes, and transportation of compost
and organic wastes. The model accounts, wherever available, where ϕ1 ($ per year) and ϕ2 ($ per ton) are the fixed and
for monetary evaluations of environmental costs and benefits; variable costs, respectively, and δj is a categorical variable,
for example, avoided greenhouse gas emissions and leachates which has a value of 1 if plant j is operational, and 0 otherwise.
from landfills, and externalities associated with hauling and Transportation costs depend on both the shipped quantities and
compost production. Equilibrium in the markets for vegetative the traveled distances
agricultural products is assumed, where variations in output 
14 
8
  14 
8
 
prices in response to production changes are calculated by the CT = wij τ1w + τ2w dij + sij τ1s + τ2s dij
use of estimated inverse-demand functions. Using the PMP cal- i=1 j =1 i=1 j =1
ibration procedure (Howitt, 1995), the model is calibrated so 
13 
8
  8 
13
 
as to reconstruct the observed base-year situation, under which + lkj τ1l + τ2l dj k + cj k τ1c + τ2c dj k ,
farmers apply compost to specific crops according to the doses k=1 j =1 j =1 k=1
reported by Afik Engineering and Lavee (2000), and the supply (4)
of high-quality compost is limited by the observed availability
where τ1w , τ1s , τ1l , and τ1c (all in $ per ton) are the quantity-cost
of raw organic materials (Zadikov, 2005). Then, the optimiza-
coefficients, and τ2w , τ2s , τ2l , and τ2c (all in $ per ton per kilometer)
tion problem is modified and the model searches for a new
are the quantity-distance cost parameters of OMSW, WTS, LM,
optimum. As detailed in Section 5, we consider four modified
and compost, respectively; the parameters dij and dj k (km)
scenarios, relative to the base-year conditions, which combine
represent, respectively, the distance of SG i and agricultural
changes related to both farmers’ consideration of the compost’s
region k from composting plant j.
advantages and the removal of compost-production barriers.
Let gkm be the land (hectare) devoted to crop m in region
In addition, the sensitivity of the results to changes in various
k, and akm (ton per hectare per year) the respective amount of
factors and assumptions is analyzed.
applied compost. The costs associated with compost application
Let wij , sij , and lkj (all in ton per year) be, respectively, the
are
annual amount of OMSW transported from SG i, i = 1 , . . . , 14,
to composting plant j, j = 1 , . . . , 8; the amount of WTS carried 
13 
42
from SG i to plant j; and the quantity of LM shipped from CA = ψ gkm akm , (5)
agricultural region k, k = 1 , . . . , 13, to plant j. Recycling these k=1 m=1
organic residues saves the costs associated with their disposal
where ψ ($ per ton) is the per compost-unit application cost.
by landfilling
All other agricultural production costs not directly related to
compost application are represented by a cost function, which

14 
8 
14 
8 
13 
8
SL = βiw wij + βis sij + βkl lkj , (1) is nonlinear with respect to land allocation. In line with the
i=1 j =1 i=1 j =1 k=1 j =1
4 On a wet-weight basis, OMSW comprises 40% of MSW; thus, assuming
that once separated, both the organic and nonorganic components of the MSW
3 Establishment of facilities in new sites is considered impractical in light of are recycled, implies that composting 1 ton of separated OMSW saves the costs
past failures attributed to the NIMBY effect (Feinerman et al., 2004). of landfilling 2.5 tons of nonseparated MSW.
154 I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163

PMP approach, the role of this function is to indirectly reflect citrus fruits, celery, pepper, avocado, and potato affect prices in
the comprehensive impact of a wide range of unobserved fac- the destination countries (Kachel, 2004). Given the consider-
tors contemplated by farmers when allocating their constrained able quality differences between locally consumed and exported
land among crops; for example, the spatial variation in soil qual- products, the local and export markets are assumed to act sep-
L E
ity, input constraints, know-how limitations, crop rotations, risk arately. Let pm ($ per ton) and pm ($ per ton) be crop m’s local
aversion, traditional habits, etc. Economic studies that explicitly and export prices, respectively. These prices are assumed to
model the effects of such attributes on cropping patterns fre- vary according to the linear inverse-demand functions
quently rely on large farm-level samples (e.g., El-Nazer and Mc-
Carl, 1986). The PMP method of incorporating land-allocation
L
pm = χ1m
L
+ χ2m
L
rm Ym , and E
pm = χ1m
E
+ χ2m
E
(1 − rm )Ym ,
decisions into programming models is commonly applied when (9)
only a limited and regionally aggregated data set is available. 
Following Henseler et al. (2009), we employ the power cost where Ym = K k=1 gkm ykm is the nationwide total production
function of crop m, rm is the fraction of crop m’s output for local con-
L L E
sumption, which is assumed constant,6 and χ1m , χ2m , χ1m , and

13 
42 E
χ2m are parameters. Production in the two markets depends on
C AP = [ς1km gkm + ς2km (gkm )γ ], (6) market structure. With respect to the local markets, farmers are
k=1 m=1
unorganized and in general act as price takers. Kachel (2004)
where the parameters ς1km and ς2km are calibrated according and Dvir (2008) showed that, despite the existence of farmers’
to the PMP calibration procedure developed by Howitt (1995), exporting corporations, they do not take advantage of market
as described in Appendix I, and γ > 1 is the power parameter. powers. We therefore consider competition conditions in both
Since γ is unknown, we adopt the commonly used quadratic markets, and calculate the equilibrium by accounting for the
function (γ = 2) and analyze the sensitivity of the outcomes to consumers’ total willingness to pay for vegetative products
this assumption. 42 
Compost contributions include both savings on fertilizer ex-  1 L
TWTP = L
χ1m rm Ym + χ2m (rm Ym )2 + χ1m
E
(1 − rm )Ym
penses and yield increase attributed to soil amendment. Total 2
m=1
fertilizer savings are
1 E
+ χ ((1 − rm )Ym )2 . (10)

13 
42 2 2m
S =
F
gkm akm ρkm , (7)
k=1 m=1
Aggregating Eqs. (1) through (7) and (10) yields the objective
where ρkm ($ per ton) is the compost’s value of nutrients that function
replace fertilizers, the calculation of which is described in Ap-
pendix II. Compost’s contribution to production through soil = TWTP + S F + S L − C S − C CP − C T − C A − C AP ,
amendment is represented by quadratic production functions (11)
  2  where ($ per year) represents the net social benefits as-
ykm = ȳm 1 + v1m (akm − ām ) + v2m akm − ām2
, (8)
sociated with the waste-management system under consider-
where ykm (ton per hectare per year) is crop m’s production ation. Optimization is achieved by setting the variables akm ,
in region k, ȳm (ton per hectare per year) and ām (ton per gkm , cj k , wij , sij , and lkj so as to maximize , subject to
hectare per year) are the base-year observed yield and compost the following
 constraints: aggregated land use in every re-
application, respectively,5 and v1m and v2m are the production- gion, 42 m=1 gkm , should not exceed the total agricultural area
function parameters, estimated by a procedure that is described there, denoted Gk (ha); field-level compost application to ev-
in the next section. ery crop m, akm , is constrained by a specific maximum  value,
Our analysis is based on a partial equilibrium approach, Am (ton per hactare per year); regional compost use, 42 m=1
where agricultural production depends on the prices emerg- gkm akm , should not exceed the total amount  transported
ing under equilibrium in the local and world markets. Most of there from the eight composting plants, 8j =1 cj k ; compost
13
the local consumption of field crop products in Israel, such as supplied from every plant j, k=1 cj k , cannot exceed the
wheat, barley, chickpea, and cotton, is imported and therefore, amount
 producible from
14 the organic
13wastes arriving wat itss gate,
farmers producing these products for local consumption face α w 14 w
i=1 ij + α s
s
i=1 ij + α l
k=1 lkj , where α , α , and
world-market prices. On the other hand, due to high import α l are, respectively, the raw material-to-compost production
tariffs and transportation costs, there is almost no import of ratios of OMSW, WTS, and LM; the  quantities of OMSW,
vegetables and fruits, whose prices are determined in equilib- WTS, and LM sent to the factories, 8j =1 wij , 8j =1 sij , and
rium in the local markets (Hadas, 2001). In addition, exports of
6 There is no information on changes in the allocation between the two markets
5 Values are available only in terms of nationwide averages. in response to variations in Ym .
I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163 155

8
To neutralize variations in climate and soil quality, only field
j =1 lkj ,
are limited by their availability at their sources, Wi ,
Si , and Lk (all in ton per year), respectively; finally, every plant experiments7 conducted in areas with climate conditions and
j has a specific production capacity, Zj (ton per year), such that soil properties similar to those in Israel were considered. More-
 14 13 over, the production function should reflect the contribution
α w 14 i=1 wij + α
s
i=1 sij + α
l
k=1 lkj ≤ Zj . Altogether,
there are 629 constraints, plus nonnegativity bounds with re- of compost through soil amendment alone, separated from its
spect to all 1,524 variables of the programming problem. fertilization impact, which can be achieved by conventional fer-
tilizers. Therefore, priority was given to experiments that used
MSW as the compost’s raw material due to its low nutrition
3. Compost production functions content. Sources that reported on the yield responses to com-
post application subject to these limitations were found for corn
A key element in our analysis is the response of yields to (Avnimelech et al., 1990; Mor et al., 1990); wheat and clover
compost application due to improved soil properties. While the (Agassi et al., 2004); potato (Avnimelech et al., 1996; Fine et al.,
agronomic literature reports vast evidence of compost’s agro- 2003); broccoli (Jackson et al., 2004; Perez-Murcia et al., 2006);
nomic advantages, this information has never been concentrated strawberry (Arancon et al., 2004); olive, orange, and grapevine
and arranged into a format useful for economic analyses. Our (Aguilar et al., 1997); and sunflower and watermelon (Izencot
objective in this section is to assign a production function to and Zilberman, 2004). Allocation into groups was based on
each of the 42 crops under consideration that relies on the widest botanical families when possible, while all other crops were
up-to-date experimental scientific knowledge on compost pro- classified into “trees” and “nontrees.” Table 1 summarizes the
ductivity through soil amendment, and that, at the same time, estimated parameters for the various groups of crops.
can be calibrated to reflect yields obtained in large-scale farm-
ing operations. Moreover, due to the scarcity of experimentally
4. Data
based information, a method is needed to enable adjustment of
the production functions for a large number of crops based on
Table 2 reports the main cost parameters and compost-
experimental results associated with only a few crops. To this
production ratios, the sources of which are detailed in this
end, we develop the following procedure.
section.8 Our base year for the analysis is 2003, and all mone-
Suppose that there are field-experimental findings for a given
tary values are in July 2004 US dollars.
crop, m, such that a quadratic production function can be esti-
Nationwide base-year per-hectare average agricultural pro-
mated
duction, ȳm , as well as ym —the maximum observed yield
reduction below the average yield, ȳm (see Appendix I)—were
ym (am ) = θ0m + θ1m am + θ2m am
2
, (12) calculated using nationwide yields obtained from the ICBS
(2004) for the period 1992–2002. Base-year cropping areas,
where θ0m , θ1m , and θ2m are crop m’s specific parameters. ḡkm , and average prices, pm , were also from ICBS (2004).
Given ȳm and ām , one can calibrate θ0m based on the identity Compost application in the base year, ām , and maximum appli-
ȳm = ym (ām ) = θ0m + θ1m ām + θ2m ām
2
. By substituting this into cation, Am , were based on findings of a survey conducted by
Eq. (12) and rearranging, we get the ratio of yield change re- Afik Engineering and Lavee (2000), who studied actual com-
sulting from applying any quantity of compost, am , relative to post practices in Israel and farmers’ perspectives on compost
the base-year amount, ām application. They also provided monetary values of the fertil-
ization elements (nitrogen and phosphorus) available to each
ym (am ) − ȳm θ1m θ2m  2  crop m in 1 ton of compost produced from clean OMSW, WTS,
= (am − ām ) + am − ām
2
. (13) and LM, denoted ϑmw , ϑms , and ϑml (all in $ per ton), respectively
ȳm ȳm ȳm
(see Appendix II).
Data obtained from a survey of waste-transport contractors
Define θȳ1mm = v1m and θȳ2mm = v2m , multiply by ȳm and re-
were used to estimate parameters of transportation costs of
arrange to get the quadratic production function presented in
MSW (τ1w and τ2w ). Transportation costs of compost, WTS, and
Eq. (8).
LM (τ1s , τ1l , τ1c , τ2s , τ2l , and τ2c ) were adopted from Pluda (2002).
Although this estimation procedure can be applied only to
In all cases, we added the external cost of $0.008 per ton per
crops for which experimental data are available, it constitutes
kilometer (EMC, 1996) to the distance-dependent parameters—
a convenient framework for making inferences on compost-
these costs account for damages associated with noise, road
productivity responses of crops that are lacking such infor-
depreciation, traffic accidents, and air pollution. The unit cost of
mation. The deduction is based on the assumption that crops
landfilling raw materials, βiw , βkl , and βis ,was calculated for each
belonging to a specific botanical family exhibit the same ratio
source as the sum of the cost of transporting to, and dumping
parameters v1m and v2m . We therefore clustered the 42 crops
into 12 groups, such that there was at least one crop in each 7 Pot experiments were excluded in order to reflect large-scale agricultural
group for which field experiments had been reported in the performance.
agronomic literature. 8 The model and the entire data set are available from the authors upon request.
156 I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163

Table 1
Estimated production-function parameters for crop groups

Botanical Representative Location of Crops in Obs. v 1 ×100% v 2 ×100%


family crops experiment the group

Vitaceae Grape Spain Grape 15 19.11∗∗ −2.30∗∗


Compositae Sunflower Israel Sunflower, lettuce, 3 8.33na −0.86na
artichoke
Citrus Orange Spain Orange, lemon, 3 14.83na −2.52na
grapefruit, other citrus
Cruciferae Broccoli California & Cauliflower, cabbage, 5 9.78∗∗∗ −0.12∗∗∗
Mexico radish
Solanaceae Potato Israel Potato, pepper, tomato, 4 3.17∗∗∗ na
eggplant
Oleaceae Olive Spain Olive 9 15.23∗∗∗ na
Papilionaceae Clover Israel Alfalfa, ground nut, bean, 3 6.17na −0.19na
chickpea, pea
Gramineae Wheat Israel Wheat, barley 3 11.47na −0.42na
Gramineae Corn Israel Corn 5 3.03∗∗ −0.18∗
Cucurbitaceae Watermelon Israel Watermelon, melon, 2 2.44na na
marrow, cucumber
Trees Orange – Plum, avocado, almond, 3 14.83na −2.52na
apple, pear, peach,
banana
Non-trees Sunflower, broccoli, – Celery, carrot, cotton, 19 5.60∗∗ −0.04∗∗∗
potato, clover, wheat, onion, garlic,
corn, watermelon strawberry
∗ ,∗∗ ,∗∗∗ significant at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively; na = not available.

Table 2
Costs and compost-production-ratio parameters

Symbol Description Units Value

μ Added cost due to source separation of OMSW [$ per ton] 45.05


τ1w Fixed cost of transporting OMSW [$ per ton] 0.79
τ2w Distance variable cost of transporting OMSW [$ per ton per kilometer] 0.06
τ1l Fixed cost of transporting LM [$ per ton] 1.57
τ2l Distance variable cost of transporting LM [$ per ton per kilometer] 0.07
τ1s Fixed cost of transporting WTS [$ per ton] 7.86
τ2s Distance variable cost of transporting WTS [$ per ton per kilometer] 0.32
τ1c Fixed cost of transporting compost [$ per ton] 1.57
τ2c Distance variable cost of transporting compost [$ per ton per kilometer] 0.07
ϕ1 Fixed cost at plant for production of compost [$ per year] 79,420
ϕ2 Variable cost of producing compost from organic materials [$ per ton] 5.20
ψ Compost application costs in the field [$ per ton] 4.44
αw Production ratio by weight—compost/OMSW – 0.52a
αl Production ratio by weight—compost/LM – 0.52a
αs Production ratio by weight—compost/WTS – 1.80b
a Pluda (2002).
b Zadikov (2005).

at the specific landfill associated with the source in the base alternative techniques of anaerobic digestion and in-vessel com-
year. Costs at the landfills include gate price and external costs posting (Karagiannidis and Perkoulidis, 2009; Komilis and
of $1.77 per ton, as estimated by EMC (1996) with respect Ham, 2004). The variable cost, ϕ2 , includes external cost associ-
to damages associated with pollutants emitted to the air and ated with N2 O emissions, in terms of effective greenhouse gas,
leachates. The additional cost associated with source separation which is equal to the emission of 11 g per ton (Avnimelech et al.,
of MSW, μ,was calculated based on Broitman (2008) and Kahat 2005) multiplied by the damage of $11.2/kg N2 O (Eshet et al.,
et al. (1999). 2005); this amounts to $0.12 per ton of compost. Compost ap-
Calculations of ϕ1 and ϕ2 —the compost-production cost plication costs, ψ, and all other non-compost-related costs, ωm ,
parameters—were from Pluda (2002), based on the windrow- were taken from sample cost calculations reported by IMARD
composting method, which is known to be cheaper than the (2008). The SGs’ OMSW productions, Wi , were calculated
I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163 157

according to ICBS (2004) data on MSW production by cities. denoted Scenario 1, represents the case of no source separa-
LM production, Lk , was estimated by use of the annual pro- tion of MSW, limited production capacities of the composting
duction of milk, eggs, chickens, turkeys, heads of sheep for plants, and farmers’ compost applications based on the ob-
milk, and heads of calves for meat (ICBS, 2004); all of these served levels (Afik Engineering and Lavee, 2000); moreover,
production parameters were converted to amounts of manure us- there are no savings on conventional fertilizers. In Scenario 2,
ing conversion coefficients (Afik Engineering and Lavee, 2000; we calculate the efficient levels of compost production, as-
Pluda, 2002). Amounts of WTS, Si , were from Zadikov (2005). suming implementation of MSW source separation wherever
Base-year compost production from the three sources was cal- warranted, removal of production-capacity constraints in the
culated based on information from Afik Engineering and Lavee composting plants, and farmers being fully informed about
(2000) and Zadikov (2005). compost’s agronomic values and hence applying compost based
The coefficients of the linear assumed inverse-demand func- on profit-maximization behavior under competitive conditions.
tion were calculated using the demand elasticity with respect to The purpose of the additional three scenarios is to evaluate the
L
the local crop m’s consumption, ηm , and to the exported quan- impact of each of the factors differentiating the base year and
E
tity, ηm , as estimated, respectively, by Hadas (2001) and Kachel efficient scenarios. In Scenario 3, we consider MSW source
L E
(2004) for the 42 crops. Let Ȳm , p̄m , and p̄m be the observed separation and the removal of production barriers, but keep the
base-year crop m’s nationwide output, the output price in the base-year situation with respect to farmers’ perceptions of com-
local market, and the price of exported production, respectively. post. Farmers’ awareness of the fertilization value of compost
Hence, only is added in Scenario 4, while in Scenario 5, we add only
L E
p̄m p̄m their recognition of compost’s advantages as a soil-amending
L
χ2m = , χ E
= ,
L
rm Ȳm ηm 2m
(1 − rm )Ȳm ηmE product. In addition, we investigate the impact of an event in
which farmers get organized and act as a cartel in the vegetative-
L
χ1m = p̄m
L
− χ2m
L
rm Ȳm , products markets, denoted as the “cartel” scenario. This case is
similar to Scenario 2, except that the total willingness to pay
and function (Eq. 10) is replaced by the aggregated farming revenue
function
E
χ1m = p̄m
E
− χ2m
E
(1 − rm )Ȳm . 
42
 L
R= χ1m rm Ym + χ2m
L
(rm Ym )2 + χ1m
E
(1 − rm )Ym
The reasonableness of the model’s outputs can be assessed by m=1

comparing the computed compost prices to the observed ones. + χ2m
E
((1 − rm )Ym )2 , (15)
Under competitive conditions, if farmers do not undervalue the
compost’s advantages, the price paid by compost consumers in the objective function (Eq. 11).
in each agricultural region can be calculated according to the Fig. 1 shows the efficient (Scenario 2) amount of every or-
compost’s marginal contribution to the region’s net returns from ganic material to be shipped from every source to the com-
farming. In view of Eqs. (4), (5), (7), (8), and (9), the price of posting plants, and of the quantities of produced compost to
the compost sold to farmers in region k, at the gate of plant j is be transported from the plants to every agricultural region. The
figure exhibits the spatial implications of the problem. Sources
pjc k = min(gkm (pm ȳm (v1m + 2v2m akm ) + ρkm )) and destinations are ordered from north to south, with diagonal
m
  distances being the shortest. As expected, plants receive organic
− ψ − τ1c + τ2c dj k , m ∈ mk , (14) materials from sources nearby, and allocate the compost to the
agricultural regions in their surroundings.
where mk denotes the set of crops that get positive amounts Tables 3 and 4 present, respectively, compost-production
of compost in region k, and pm = χ1m L
rm + χ2m rm Ym +
L 2
and objective-function components under the various scenarios.
χ1m (1 − rm ) + χ2m (1 − rm ) Ym is crop m’s weighted average
E E 2
Table 5 reports the changes in the net benefits obtained under
output price. The gate prices computed under the base-year scenarios 2 through 5 and the cartel case, in comparison to Sce-
conditions vary from $−14 to $58 per ton, with a weighted nario 1, and the allocation of these changes in benefit among
average of $20 per ton; this average price lies within the range two activities and three sectors. The allocation to two activities
of observed gate prices for compost, which vary between $45 is based on the objective-function components associated with
and $15 per ton for high- and low-quality compost types, re- activities up to the composting plant’s gate, denoted “waste
spectively (Zadikov, 2005). management,” and activities from the plant’s gate onward, de-
noted “agriculture.” The allocation among sectors—waste man-
5. Efficiency and governmental policies agers (municipalities, LM suppliers, and compost producers),9
9 Due to the linear formulation of the waste-management costs, computation
We analyze five scenarios with respect to the organic materi- of benefits allocation among the waste-management agents requires additional
als recycling system through compost production and farmers’ assumptions. Given their mediation position, composting plants may reap most
perceptions of compost productivity. The base-year situation, of the benefits of this sector.
158 I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163

(a) (b)

200,000 350,000
180,000

Livestock Manure (ton/year)


300,000
160,000
OMSW (ton/year)

140,000 250,000
120,000
200,000
100,000
80,000 150,000
60,000 100,000
40,000 Dudaim
Dudaim 50,000
20,000 Tovlan
Tovlan
0 Sdot Micha 0 Sdot Micha
Kalansua Kalansua
Kiryat-Shemona

Galil
Zefat

Golan
Hasharon
Carmiel

Hasharon

Western Galil
Tiberius

Yizre'el Valley

t
t
Nazareth

Plan
Amnir Afula

Lower Galil
Plan
Amnir Afula
Haifa

Haifa
Hadera

Jordan Valley
Netanya

Comopst 2000 Comopst 2000

Hasharon
Tel-Aviv

Center
Rehovot

Ashkelon
Shazarim Shazarim
Jerusalem

Yehuda
Ashdod

Negev Arava
Ashkelon
Be'er-Sheva

Arad
Settle Agric
ments ultur
g roup al reg
ion

(c) (d)

70,000 350,000
60,000 300,000
Compost (ton/year)
Sludge (ton/year)

50,000 250,000
40,000 200,000
30,000 150,000
20,000 100,000
Dudaim
10,000 Dudaim 50,000 Tovlan
Tovlan
0 Sdot Micha 0 Sdot Micha
Kalansua Kalansua
Kiryat-Shemona

Galil
Zefat

Golan

Hasharon
Carmiel

Hasharon
Western Galil
Tiberius

Yizre'el Valley

t
t
Nazareth

Plan
Plan

Amnir Afula
Lower Galil

Amnir Afula
Haifa

Haifa
Hadera

Jordan Valley
Netanya

Comopst 2000 Comopst 2000


Hasharon
Tel-Aviv

Center
Rehovot

Ashkelon

Shazarim Shazarim
Jerusalem

Yehuda
Ashdod

Negev Arava
Ashkelon
Be'er-Sheva

Arad

Settle Agric
m ents g ultur
roup al reg
ion

Fig. 1. Allocation of (a) OMSW, (b) LM, and (c) WTS to composting plants, and (d) compost to agricultural regions, under the efficient solution (Scenario 2).

Table 3
Compost production

Potential Production rate of the potential (%)


(103 ton per year) Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4 Scenario 5 Cartel
Scenario Base year Efficiency Removal of Removal of Removal of Removal of
description composting composting composting composting
barriers barriers & barriers & barriers &
recognizing recognizing recognizing
fertilization soil amendment fertilization
value only only value & soil
amendment

OMSW 771 26 78 61 61 75 65
LM 755 40 100 100 100 100 100
WTS 200 8 100 15 92 100 100
Total 1,725 30 90 73 82 89 84
I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163 159

Table 4
Benefits and costs (106 $ per year)

Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4 Scenario 5 Cartel

Benefits
MSW landfill savings 19.9 69.3 59.1 59.1 68.0 61.3
LM landfill savings 9.5 25.9 25.9 25.9 25.9 25.9
WTS landfill savings 0.2 3.7 0.7 3.5 3.7 3.7
Fertilization savings 0.0 7.6 0.0 6.3 0.0 6.7
Total willingness to paya 2,156 2,315 2,264 2,272 2,315 1,835
Total benefits 2,185 2,421 2,349 2,367 2,412 1,932
Costs
MSW collection cost increase 17.2 51.4 40.5 40.5 49.9 42.8
OMSW transportation costs 1.2 2.8 2.2 2.2 2.7 2.5
LM transportation costs 1.5 4.3 4.3 4.3 4.3 4.3
WTS transportation costs 0.2 1.8 0.2 1.7 1.8 1.8
Compost production costs 3.2 8.6 7.1 7.9 8.5 8.1
Compost transportation costs 1.8 5.2 3.1 3.6 5.1 4.9
Compost application costs 2.3 6.9 5.6 6.3 6.8 6.5
Agricultural production costs 163 243 266 266 244 −43
Total costs 190 324 329 333 323 28
Net benefits 1,995 2,097 2,020 2,034 2,089 1,904
a The willingness-to-pay value is calculated based on the assumed agricultural products’ linear inverse-demand functions; hence, it should be considered useful only
as a measure for comparison among scenarios rather than as an evaluation of the true willingness-to-pay value.

Table 5
Changes in total net benefits under each scenario relative to the base-year scenario and allocation of the changes among activities and sectors; compost average gate
price; changes in the agricultural-production; and output-price indices

Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4 Scenario 5 Cartel

Net-benefits change (106


$ per year) 102 25 39 94 −91
Allocation among activities (106 $ per year)
Waste management 24 25 26 24 25
Agriculture 78 0 13 70 −116
Allocation among sectors (106 $ per year)
Waste-management agents 48 4 8 41 29
Farmers −95 −85 −81 −95 231
Consumers of agricultural products 148 106 111 148 −351
Compost average gate price ($ per ton) 22 −8 −5 17 10
Changes in Laspeyres indices (%)
Agricultural production 26 22 23 26 −7
Agricultural output price −9 −6 −7 −9 31

farmers, and consumers of vegetative agricultural products— to the additional costs associated with OMSW pretreatment
is calculated by the use of the computed compost gate prices through MSW source separation, which is irrelevant in the
(Eq. 14) and the prices of agricultural products (Eq. 9).10 Also cases of LM and WTS. In effect, source-separation costs in
presented in Table 5 are the calculated prices of compost at the combination with landfill savings play a major role in the justi-
composting plants’ gates and the changes in the agricultural- fication for recycling OMSW: implementing source separation
production and output-price Laspeyres indices. of MSW is found to be unwarranted in the cities of Kiryat-
Compost production under the efficient scenario (Scenario 2) Shemona, Zefat, Tiberius, Jerusalem, and Be’er-Sheva (see Fig.
amounts to 90% of the potential production; that is, triple that of 1)—the municipalities with the lowest landfilling costs (not
the base-year situation. Among the three organic-waste sources, shown). Obviously, forcing these municipalities to comply with
only OMSW’s potential is not fully realized; this is attributed the aforementioned 50% landfilling targets (IMEP, 2008b) is
unfavorable.
10 In scenarios 3 and 4, farmers’ ignorance of compost productivity is simu- Compared to the base-year situation, net benefits increase
lated by solving the optimization problem with the compost production function by $102 million per year under the efficient solution. Of
parameters v1m and v2m , m = 1 , . . . , 42, set to zero; then, the agricultural pro-
duction and the compost gate prices expected under the resultant allocation
this gain, $24 million is attributed to savings in the waste-
of land and compost among crops is calculated, substituting in the parameter management system, and the other $78 million to agricultural
values reported in Table 1. activities (Table 5). The main beneficiaries are the consumers of
160 I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163

agricultural products; their rise in surplus resulted from the in- achieved by adding fertilization savings to farmers’ considera-
crease in vegetative agricultural production and the associated tions; this increases net benefits by $8 million per year, which
price decrease, which amount, according to the Laspeyres pro- are attributed entirely to agricultural activities, but ultimately
duction and price indices, to 26% and −9%, respectively. On the are pocketed almost entirely by the waste-management agents
other hand, farmers’ aggregated surplus is diminished by $95 through the associated rise in composting-plant gate prices.
million per year. The reduction in agricultural output prices To summarize our five-scenario analysis, about two-thirds
entails only a slight change in the computed prices of com- of the $102 million in benefits increase is achieved through
post at the composting plants’ gates, to an average $22 per ton. the compost’s effect as a soil-amending material, whereas com-
However, due to the increase in compost production, the overall post’s fertilization value contributes only 1/12th to this increase.
expenses on compost purchases are enlarged by $24 million per The realization of these gains, however, depends on the es-
year and, in addition to waste-management savings, the waste tablishment of a waste-management system that enables pro-
managers’ gains amount to $48 million. duction of high-quality compost. Nevertheless, as indicated by
If the total net-benefit increase is larger than the (unknown) Scenario 3, even when the compost’s agricultural advantages
costs associated with stimulating the emergence of the effi- are ignored, such a reorganization of the waste-management
cient outcome, then government intervention is justifiable. The system is warranted, and can itself contribute about a quar-
impact of the intervention strategies under consideration—the ter of the potential net-benefit increase. Interestingly, the
removal of composting constraints and guiding farmers to rec- waste-management sector is expected to benefit from the
ognize compost’s agronomic advantages—is further analyzed waste-management reform under consideration only when it
by examination of Scenarios 3 through 5. is accompanied by a change in farmers’ perception of compost
Relative to the base year, the elimination of composting con- utilization. Note, however, that our analysis forecasts a consid-
straints without changing farmers’ attitudes toward compost ap- erable deterioration in farmers’ incomes if the efficient solution
plication, simulated in Scenario 3, yields a net-benefit increase is to be realized. This raises the following question: in addition
of $25 million per year, which is achieved through composting to the aforementioned steps required for realization of the effi-
100% of the LM, and approximately doubling the composting cient solution, should the government compensate farmers for
rates of OMSW and WTS. While this increase is entirely cred- their profit loss? The answer is no. Since farmers act in a com-
ited to savings in the waste-management activity, the earnings of petitive environment, they ignore the impact of increased ag-
the waste-management sector rise by only $4 million per year; gregated production on agricultural product prices. Moreover,
this is because the calculated gate prices of compost become the increase in the utilization of compost should be viewed as
negative (on average −$8 per ton), implying that farmers should only one element of a comprehensive and long-term process of
be compensated in order to encourage them to use compost, the adoption of improved agricultural technologies, which is partly
advantages of which are unappreciated. In Scenario 4, where in supported by public expenditures, and ultimately leads to a
addition to the elimination of composting constraints farmers worsening of agriculture’s terms of trade. For example, during
identify the substitution of compost for conventional fertilizers, the 1990s, the technological level of agriculture in Israel in-
the composting rate of WTS is increased to 92%, while that of creased by 52%, while the terms-of-trade index (outputs/inputs
OMSW is the same as in Scenario 3. This outcome is expected, price-index ratio) of vegetative agriculture decreased by 28%
since the fertilization value of OMSW is negligible. In compar- (Kislev and Vaxsin, 2003).
ison to Scenario 3, net benefits are increased by $14 million per The efficient solution may be sensitive to changes in various
year. While almost all of this change is attributed to agricultural factors and assumptions. The solution appears to be robust to
production and consumption activities, this amount is allocated variations in the assumed value of the agricultural production
approximately equally among the three sectors. Farmers’ ben- cost function’s power parameter γ (Eq. 6), which has no impact
efits from the fertilization savings increase the compost’s value on the composting rates, and entails only negligible changes in
of marginal production, which is translated by Eq. (14) to less the net benefits and allocations of compost among regions and
negative compost gate prices, and thereby to an enlargement in crops. On the other hand, simulating an event of cartelization
waste managers’ income. The fertilization savings also partly in the farming sector leads to a decline in OMSW composting
compensate farmers for the reduction in agricultural output rate to 65%. The most significant factor under the cartelization
prices, which in turn raises consumers’ surplus. When farmers scenario is the land allocation—compared to all other scenar-
consider only the compost’s productivity through soil amend- ios, land is allocated so as to decrease agricultural production,
ment (Scenario 5), the potential LM- and WTS-composting thereby increasing agricultural output prices and reducing agri-
rates are completely realized, and that of OMSW attains 75%. cultural production costs. These changes dramatically increase
Again, relative to Scenario 3, all of the net-benefits increase ($69 farmers’ surplus, to a large extent at the expense of the con-
million per year) is associated with agricultural activities; how- sumers of agricultural products. Thus, as the cartelization sce-
ever, the improvement in the situation for waste managers and nario may be viewed as an extreme extrapolation with respect
consumers of agricultural products comes partly at the expense to the observed conditions, the change it entails in the com-
of the farmers, whose income declines by $10 million per year. posting rate seems rather small. Next, an increase of 100% in
Moving from Scenario 5 to the efficient solution (Scenario 2) is transportation costs, say, due to a rise in oil prices, does not alter
I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163 161

the composting rates—this outcome is explained by the mutual matter in the soil, for example, Southern California, Australia,
impact on both the composting and landfilling waste-disposal Portugal, Spain, Southern France, Italy, and Greece (Zdruli
alternatives. A rise in oil prices may also increase the price of et al., 2004). On the other hand, our analysis abstracts in various
commercial fertilizers. Also here the effect is negligible: dou- aspects, which may constitute objectives for future research
bling the prices increases the total composting rate by only 3%. avenues. One development may be the discrimination among
Increases in landfill gate prices by 10%, 20%, and 80% increase productivity levels of different types of compost, in combination
OMSW composting rates to 93%, 97%, and 100%, respectively. with application to a variety of soils and types of irrigation
Finally, the additional cost of $45 per ton for OMSW source water. Another noteworthy extension would involve accounting
separation, as estimated by Broitman (2008), may be consid- for potential positive and negative impacts of compost on the
ered lower if the separated nonorganic materials (e.g., plastics quality of yields (Hargreaves et al., 2008; Zennaro et al., 2005),
and paper) are sold to the recycling industry. Adopting Broit- which may influence recommendations for compost application
man’s estimation of an up to 56% reduction in the additional and affect compost-production costs and prices of agricultural
collection cost, the OMSW composting rate rises to 100%. products.

6. Concluding remarks Acknowledgment

In this study, the efficiency of compost production in Israel The authors thank the reviewer and editor for helpful com-
and related governmental intervention strategies were analyzed ments, and the Israeli Ministry of Environmental Protection for
based on a mathematical programming model that integrates funding support.
a wide range of spatial, agronomical, environmental, and eco-
nomic factors. Our evaluation showed that governmental inter-
Appendix I
vention through both elimination of existing composting con-
straints and directing farmers to recognize compost’s agronomic
The PMP calibration procedure is based on viewing farm-
advantages could increase social welfare by $102 million per
ers as price takers, referring to each region k as a single
year. Under this scenario, composting about 90% of the organic
farm, and considering land allocation observed in the base
waste produced in Israel is economically warranted. This eval-
period as optimal from the farmers’ point of view. Define
uated optimal composting rate was found to be robust to shifts
gk = {gk1 , . . . , gk42 } as region k’s land allocation and let
in the cost of transportation and fertilizer prices, as well as to
π̄km = pm ȳm − ām (ψ − ρ̄km ) − ωm be the base-year per hectare
cartelization in the market for agricultural products; neverthe-
profit of crop m in region k, where ρ̄km ($ ton−1 ) is the base-year
less, the composting rate is sensitive to changes in costs related
compost’s fertilizer-equivalent value. In our application, we set
to landfilling and source separation of MSW.
ρ̄km = 0, since farmers tend to ignore the fertilization value
Long-run processes may alter the optimal management of
of compost (Afik Engineering and Lavee, 2000). The regional
organic wastes. Population growth is expected to increase the
farming profit is expressed as a linear-programming  problem,
amounts of OMSW and WTS, and therefore, ceteris paribus,
in which gk is set so as to maximize πk (gk ) = 42 m=1 gkm π̄km ,
reduce their composting rates. At the same time, however, pop- 42
ulation growth may have a counteractive effect through an in- subject to the regional land constraint, m=1 gkm ≤ Gk , and
crease in equilibrium food prices, followed by an upward shift an additional set of 42 auxiliary land-calibration constraints,
of the agricultural products’ inverse-demand functions, as well gkm ≤ ḡkm + ε, where ε is a perturbation element, the role
as a rise in landfilling costs due to the associated increase in land of which is to ensure the effectiveness of the regional land
scarcity. While our model may be used to evaluate the impact constraint. Letting m = 1 denote the crop with the lowest
of such changes, the changes themselves are hard to predict. base-year average per-hectare profit, the dual value of the
Hence, it is concluded that a reform of the waste-management regional land constraint, λ1k ($ ha−1 per year), is given by
system should be flexible enough to enable adjustment to dif- λ1k = p1 (ȳ1 − y1 ) − ā1 (ψ − ρ̄k1 ) − ω1 . Then, λ2km ($ ha−1
ferent circumstances. For instance, government enforcement per year)—the dual value of the auxiliary land-calibration con-
of the 50% landfilling targets set in Israel (IMEP, 2008b) is a straint with respect to crop m, gkm ≤ ḡkm + ε, m = 1, . . . , 42—
nonflexible approach that may lead to inefficiency. can be calculated according to λ2km = π̄km − λ1k . By substitut-
How applicable is this analysis to other cases throughout the ing ωm = ς1km + ς2km (ḡkm )γ −1 , we get ς2km = λ2kmγ −1 and
(γ −1)ḡkm
world? At the heart of the model stand the compost production ς1km = ωm − λ2km
γ −1
for every crop m, m = 1, . . . , 42.
functions, estimated based on data collected from the scientific
literature. This information can be used in similar analyses of
regions facing the same challenges, particularly in countries Appendix II
where landfilling is costly due to land scarcity, regions in which  14
high consumption of fresh fruits and vegetables leads to MSW Let cjw = α w 14 i=1 wij , cj = α
s s
i=1 sij and cj =
l
 13
with high organic content, and areas with low content of organic α l k=1 lij be the amount of compost produced in plant j from
162 I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163

OMSW, WTS, and LM, respectively, where α w , α s , and α l are, Avnimelech, Y., Cohen, A., Shkedi, D., 1990. The effect of municipal solid
respectively, the raw material-to-compost production ratios of waste compost on the fertility of clay soils. Soil Technol. 3, 275–284.
Ayalon, O., Avnimelech, Y., Shechter, M., 2000. Alternative MSW treatment
OMSW, WTS, and LM. It is assumed that the three sources are options to reduce global greenhouse gases emissions: The Israeli example.
homogeneously mixed; the fractions of OMSW, WTS, and LM Waste Manag. Res. 18, 538–544.
in the produced compost are denoted φjw , φjs , and φjl , respec- Ayalon, O., Avnimelech, Y., Shechter, M., 2001. Solid waste treatment as a high-
tively, where priority and low-cost alternative for greenhouse gas mitigation. Environ.
Manag. 27(5), 697–704.
cjw cjs Ayalon, O., Shechter, M., Avnimelech, Y., 2003. Assessing the ancillary
φjw = , φjs = , and socio-economic benefits of mitigating greenhouse gasses from municipal
cjw + cjs + cjl cjw + cjs + cjl solid waste management. In: Giupponi, C., Shechter, M. (Eds.). Climate
cjl Change and the Mediterranean: Socio-Economic Perspectives of Impacts,
φjl = w . Vulnerability and Adaptation. Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA, pp. 213–
cj + cjs + cjl
222.
Broitman, D., 2008. Waste separation at source in Israel: Costs assess-
Denote by φkw , φks , and φkl , respectively, the fraction of ment in local authorities. Master’s dissertation, Haifa University, Israel (in
OMSW, WTS, and LM in the compost which has arrived at Hebrew).
Chakrabarti, S., Sarkhel, P., 2003. Economics of solid waste management: A
region k, where
survey of existing literature. Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi.
Dvir, A., 2008. From government monopoly to oligopoly: The liberalization of

8 
8 
8
φjw cj k φjs cj k φjl cj k the avocado sector in Israel. Master’s dissertation, The Hebrew University
j =1 j =1 j =1 of Jerusalem, Israel (in Hebrew).
φkw = , φks = , and φkl = . El-Nazer, T., McCarl, B.A., 1986. The choice of crop rotation: A modeling

8 
8 
8
cj k cj k cj k approach and case study. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 68(1), 127–136.
j =1 j =1 j =1 Environmental Management and Consulting (EMC), 1996. Solid waste dis-
posal methods—external and direct costs evaluation. A Report to an Inter-
Ministerial Committee (in Hebrew).
Then,
Eshet, T., Ayalon, O., Shechter, M., 2005. A critical review of economic valua-
tion studies of externalities from incineration and landfilling. Waste Manag.
ρkm = ϑmw φkw + ϑms φks + ϑml φkl . Res. 23(6), 487–504.
EU, 2007. Available at http://europa.eu.int/comm/environment/index_en.htm,
accessed 22 June 2009.
EU, 2008. Available at http://www.eu-delegation.org.eg/en/eu_and_country/
4.pdf, accessed 22 June 2009.
References Eunomia, 2002. Economic analysis of option for managing biodegradable mu-
nicipal waste, final report and appendices. Available at http://europa.eu.int/
Afik Engineering and Lavee, A., 2000. The compost in Israel: A survey of comm/environment/waste/compost/econanalysis_finalreport.pdf, accessed
sources and uses and an economic analysis. A report to the Ministry of 12 February 2007.
Environmental Protection (in Hebrew). Feinerman, E., Finkelshtain, I., Kan, I., 2004. On a political solution to the
Agassi, M., Levy, G.J., Hadas, A., Benyamini, Y., Zhevelev, H., Fizik, E., NIMBY conflict. Am. Econ. Rev. 94(1), 369–381.
Gotessman, M., Sasson, N., 2004. Mulching with composted municipal Fine, P., Gips, A., Zilberman, A., Rosenberg, R., Davidov, S., Suriano, S.,
solid wastes in the Central Negev, Israel. 1. Effects on minimizing rainwater Baruzkin, A., Isicson, E., Bar, Z., Einshtain, A., Katlan, Y., 2003. Application
losses and on hazards to the environment. Soil Till. Res. 78, 103–113. of lime-stabilized sludge (ecosoil, N-viro) in autumn potato growing in the
Aguilar, F.J., González, P., Revilla, J., de León, J., Porcel, O., 1997. Agricultural North-West Negev. The Agricultural Research Administration, Report No.
use of municipal solid waste on tree and bush crops. J. Agric. Eng. Res. 67(1), 607/03 (in Hebrew).
73–79. Hadas, E., 2001. Economic aspects of agricultural trade among Israel, Gaza and
Annabi, M., Houot, S., Francou, C., Poitrenaud, M., LeBissonnais, Y., 2007. the West-Bank. Doctoral dissertation, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem,
Soil aggregate stability improvement with urban composts of different ma- Israel (in Hebrew).
turities. Soil Sci. Soc. Am. J. 71, 413–423. Hargreaves, J.C., Adl, M.S., Warman, P.R., 2008. A review of the use of com-
Arancon, N.Q., Edwards, C.A., Bierman, P., Welch, C., Metzger, J.D., 2004. posted municipal solid waste in agriculture. Agr. Ecosyst. Environ. 123,
Influences of vermicomposts on field strawberries: 1. Effects on growth and 1–14.
yields. Bioresour. Technol. 93(2), 145–153. Hayashi, T., Yamamoto, M., Masuda, K., 2004. Evaluation of the recycling of
Avnimelech, Y., 1986. Organic residues in modern agriculture. In: Chen, Y., biomass resources by using the waste account. Stud. Regional Sci. 34(3),
Avnimelech, Y. (Eds.), The Role of Organic Matter in Intensive Agriculture. 289–295.
Martinus Nijhoff, Dordrecht, The Netherlands, pp. 1–10. He, Y., Inamori, Y., Mizuochi, M., Kong, H., Iwami, N., Sun, T., 2001. Nitrous
Avnimelech, Y., 1997. Land application of composted municipal wastes. In: oxide emissions from aerated composting of organic waste. Environ. Sci.
Chremisinoff, P.N. (Ed.). Ecological Issues and Environmental Impact As- Technol. 35(11), 2347–2351.
sessment. Advances in Environmental Control Technology. Gulf Publishing, Henseler, M., Wirsig, A., Herrmann, S., Krimly, T., Dabbert, S., 2009. Modeling
Houston, TX, pp. 551–570. the impact of global change on regional agricultural land use through an
Avnimelech, Y., Ayalon, O., Ben Brit, T., Kochva, M., 2005. N2 O emissions activity-based non-linear programming approach. Agric. Syst. 100(1–3),
from compost piles. In: Mingelgrin, U. (Ed.). Sustainable Reduction, Treat- 31–42.
ment and Recovery of Waste in Israel. Final Report to the Ministry of Science Hoshva Consultants, 2005. Master plan for solid waste in Israel. A Report to the
(in Hebrew). Ministry of Environmental Protection. Available at http://www.sviva.gov.
Avnimelech, Y., Bruner, M., Ezrony, I., Sela, R., Kochba, M., 1996. Stability il/Enviroment/Static/Binaries/Articals/tochnit_psolet_1.pdf (in Hebrew),
index for municipal solid waste compost. Compost Sci. Util. 4(2), 13–20. accessed 24 March 2007.
I. Kan et al. / Agricultural Economics 41 (2010) 151–163 163

Howitt, R.E., 1995. Positive mathematical programming. Am. J. Agric. Econ. Karagiannidis, A., Perkoulidis, G., 2009. A multi-criteria ranking of different
77, 329–342. technologies for the anaerobic digestion for energy recovery of the organic
Israeli Central Bureau of Statistics (ICBS), 2004. Available at http://www. fraction of municipal solid wastes. Bioresour. Technol. 100(8), 2355–2360.
cbs.gov.il. (in Hebrew), accessed 18 July 2007. Kislev, Y., Vaxsin, Y., 2003. Statistical atlas of Israeli agriculture, 2003 up-
Israeli Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development (IMARD), 2008. date. The Hebrew University of Jerusalem. Available at http://departments.
Instructions for growers. The Agricultural Extension Service, various re- agri.huji.ac.il/economics/kislev-atlas2.pdf (in Hebrew), accessed 28 May
ports. Available at http://www.shaham.moag.gov.il/ (in Hebrew), accessed 2009.
17 August 2008. Komilis, D.P., Ham, R.K., 2004. Life-cycle inventory of municipal solid waste
Israeli Ministry of Environmental Protection (IMEP), 2008a. Available and yard waste windrow composting in the United States. J. Environ. Eng.
at http://www.sviva.gov.il/Enviroment/Static/Binaries/ModulKvatzim/f& 130(11), 1390–1400.
f2006_1.pdf, accessed 28 May 2009. Mor, Y., Gilboa, S., Kochva, M., Avnimelech, Y., Orly, H., 1990. Application
Israeli Ministry of Environmental Protection (IMEP), 2008b. Available at of compost to corn in the Jordan Valley. Hassadeh 70(7), 1052–1054 (in
http://www.sviva.gov.il, accessed 28 May 2009. Hebrew).
Izencot, A., Zilberman, A., 2004. Multi annual summary of impact of sludge Perez-Murcia, M.D., Moral, R., Moreno-Caselles, J., Perez-Espinosa, A., Pare-
compost and sewage sludge on yields and soil in field crops in three re- des, C., 2006. Use of composted sewage sludge in growth media for broccoli.
gions, 1999–2003. A Report to the Ministry of Environmental Protection Bioresour. Technol. 97(1), 123–130.
(in Hebrew). Pluda, D., 2002. The array of composting centers for livestock manure in
Jackson, L.E., Ramirez, I., Yokota, R., Fennimore, S.A., Koike, S.T., Hen- the Yizre’el Valley. A Report to the Ministry of Agriculture and Rural
derson, D.M., Chaney, W.E., Calderón, F.J., Klonsky, K., 2004. On-farm Development (in Hebrew).
assessment of organic matter and tillage management on vegetable yield, Stewart, B.A., Robinson, C.A., Parker, D.B., 2000. Examples and case studies
soil, weeds, pests, and economics in California. Agric., Ecosyst. Environ. of beneficial reuse of beef cattle by-products. In: Dick, W.A. (Ed.). Land
103(3), 443–463. Application of Agricultural, Industrial, and Municipal Byproducts. Soil Sci.
Janzen, R.A., McGill, W.B., Leonard, J.J., Jeffrey, S.R., 1999. Manure as a Society Amer., pp. 387–407.
resource—ecological and economic considerations in balance. Trans. ASAE Zadikov, I., 2005. The reform program for the dairy sector. A Report to
42(5), 1261–1274. the Ministry of Environmental Protection. Available at http://www.sviva.
Kachel, Y., 2004. The influence of industry structure on performance: The case gov.il/Enviroment/Static/Binaries/Articals/milk_reform_1.pdf (in Hebrew),
of the Israeli citrus industry. Doctoral dissertation, The Hebrew University accessed 10 October 2007.
of Jerusalem, Israel. Zdruli, P., Jones, R.J.A., Montanarella, L., 2004. Organic matter in the soils of
Kahat, D., Lavee, D., Halerman, J., Kahat O., 1999. Improvement of waste Southern Europe. European Soil Bureau Technical Report, EUR 21083 EN.
collection services in Israel. A Report to the Ministry of the Interior Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.
and the Ministry of Environmental Protection. Available at http://www. Zennaro, M., Cristofori, F., Formigoni, D., Frignani, F., Pavoni, B., 2005. Heavy
sviva.gov.il/Enviroment/Static/Binaries/index_pirsumim/p0327_1.pdf (in metal contamination in compost. A possible solution. Annali di Chimica 95,
Hebrew), accessed 10 October 2007. 247–256.

You might also like