Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 8

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/256642689

A Panel Data Analysis of Sectoral Allocation of FDI in India: Where Does


Construction (including Infrastructure Activities) Stand?

Article · June 2013

CITATIONS READS

0 212

3 authors:

Seshanwita Das Tapas Das


Amity University JSS Academy of Technical Education
15 PUBLICATIONS 4 CITATIONS 16 PUBLICATIONS 4 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Makarand Upadhyaya
University of Bahrain
70 PUBLICATIONS 395 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Pester power effect of advertising View project

Research Project View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Tapas Das on 26 May 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


International Journal of Management and Social Sciences Research (IJMSSR) ISSN: 2319-4421 83
Volume 2, No. 6, June 2013

A Panel Data Analysis of Sectoral Allocation of FDI in India:


Where Does Construction (including Infrastructure Activities)
Stand?

Seshanwita Das, Assistant Professor, Galgotia‟s Institute of Management & Technology, Greater Noida, Uttarpradesh,
India
Tapas Das, Assistant Professor, Department of Management Studies, JSS Academy of Technical Education, Noida,
Uttarpradesh, India
Dr. Rajiv Upadhyaya, Professor, Department of Economic Administration & Financial Management, University of
Rajasthan, Jaipur, Rajasthan, India

ABSTRACT manufacturing and services sectors. UNCTAD World


Investment Report (2001, pp 138), for instance, argues
Although it may seem natural to argue that foreign direct that in the primary sector, often the scope for linkages
investment (FDI) can convey great advantages to host between foreign affiliates and local suppliers is limited.
countries, it is generally seen that the benefits of FDI vary The manufacturing sector has a broad variation of linkage-
greatly across sectors. Allocation of FDI into different intensive activities. In the tertiary sector, the scope for
sectors, enjoying differential knowledge spillovers or dividing production into discrete stages and sub-
technology spillovers, is an important aspect to be contracting out large parts to independent domestic firms
considered due to its variable impact on the overall is also limited.
growth of the economy. This study empirically examines
the allocation of FDI into select sectors during 2004-2010 The capacity for FDI to serve as a channel of
in the post-reforms era. With the help of log-lin panel technological spillover might differ by sectors. For
regression model, we have seen that allocation of FDI instance, secondary sector could rely more upon imports
into different sectors over the years has experienced than FDI as an avenue of technological transfer, as the
heterogeneity effect. That is to say, growth rate of FDI importance of FDI as a channel of technological transfer
into different sectors over the years has been different and might not be so important in the secondary sector
this heterogeneity is the cause of such fixed factors across compared to the tertiary sector due to the fact that services
all sectors as, low level of development in the economy are less trade-able than manufactured goods. Moreover,
encompassing all the sectors, bureaucratic delays and knowledge is created by R&D, which itself is classified
widespread corruption and such random variables, which under the tertiary sector. Nevertheless, according to
vary over cross-section but are fixed over time as UNCTAD (2005), the largest R&D expenditure is
government policy regarding FDI across different sectors. concentrated in the IT hardware, Automotive,
Pharmaceuticals and Biotech industries, which are mostly
Keywords: in the manufacturing sector. Crowding-out effect of
Sectoral allocation of FDI, Panel Data Analysis, FDI in domestic suppliers as a result of competition from the
infrastructure entry of MNCs could also vary by sector. By and large,
higher tendency has been observed in tertiary sector
1. Introduction: UNCTAD (2004). Now the question is if sectoral
Inward FDI is conjectured to bring about increases in allocation of FDI matters for growth, then the shift of FDI
productivity levels. More importantly, it acts as a conduit from the primary and manufacturing sectors towards the
for the transfer of technology, leading to technological tertiary sector could have important growth effects.
spillovers or knowledge spillovers and also increases
economic growth in host countries by increasing the level Relatively few scholars (for instance Wheeler and Mody,
of investment. Blomstrom and Kokko (1997) have 1992; Loree & Guisinger, 1995; Richaud et al, 1999;
identified a number of ways through which technological Asiedu, 2002; Sekkat, 2004) have acknowledged the
diffusion can occur, such as, licensing, joint ventures and crucial role of infrastructure in stimulating FDI by arguing
goods-trade. But, needless to say, FDI has always that good infrastructure is a necessary pre-requisite for
remained a dominating channel for spreading technology. foreign investors to operate successfully. Poor
infrastructure or unavailability of public inputs increase
Though it seems natural to argue that FDI can augur gains costs for firms. A freeway is faster than a washed out dirt
to host countries, such gains might differ across primary, road, email is faster than the post-office and obviously

i-Xplore International Research Journal Consortium www.irjcjournals.org


International Journal of Management and Social Sciences Research (IJMSSR) ISSN: 2319-4421 84
Volume 2, No. 6, June 2013

time is money. Public input is non-excludable and non- demand for inputs leads to a positive externality to other
congestible and it will lower the costs of doing business producers owing to an increase in variety. Greater
for multinational and indigenous firms alike. varieties of inputs, however, seem to be more relevant to
the manufacturing than to the agricultural sector.
Multinationals are in fact profit-seeking entities that seek Likewise, Markusen and Venables (1999) analyze the
to minimize the costs of doing business. If locating in a effect of foreign firms on the development of domestic
developing economy to take advantage of lower labor firms in the industrial sector. In their model, foreign
costs means, on the other hand, losing patent protection to companies compete with domestic producers while
imitators, higher transport costs due to inadequate creating additional demand for domestically produced
transportation or missed supply shipments due to intermediate goods through linkages with local suppliers.
communication and transport problems, then they will This can lead to domestic firms entering into the
refrain from doing business there. Infrastructure and intermediate goods sector, which can result in lower costs
public inputs, or the lack thereof, contribute to firms cost that, reflected in lower final prices that increase demand,
structures and should be included in a model that explains can benefit domestic firms producing final goods.
the multinational‟s as well as the host government‟s
decisions for investment. Infrastructure should thus Most of the micro studies on FDI spillovers, as Lipsey
improve the investment climate for FDI by subsidizing the (2002) points out, tend to use manufacturing data and
cost of total investment by foreign investors and thus have regressed local firm productivity on within sector
raising the rate of return. Availability of crucial FDI. Although such studies find no horizontal technology
infrastructure, such as roads, highways, ports, transfer, the empirical work at the intra-industry level
communication networks and electricity should increase might not be suitable for capturing wider spillover effects
productivity and thereby attract higher levels of FDI. As on the host economy, such as those created by backward
Wei and al. (2000) said that a location with good and forward linkages with domestic firms. One of the
infrastructure is more attractive than the others. main reasons to examine productivity spillovers from
foreign-owned to domestically owned firms, as Lipsey
2. LITERATURE REVIEW: (2002) mentions, is to understand the contribution of
inward FDI to host country economic growth. If foreign
Theoretical work of Findlay (1978) and Wang & firms at the expense of lower productivity in domestic
Bloomstrom (1992) that models the importance of FDI as firms achieve higher productivity, there might be no
a conduit for transferring technology relates to the foreign implications for aggregate output or growth. However,
investment inflows to manufacturing or service sectors there might be growth effects without spillovers just from
rather than to the primary sector. In addition, FDI‟s the operation of foreign firms, which can be analyzed in
potential to create linkages to domestic firms might also terms of the impact of FDI on a country‟s output or
vary across sectors, as Albert Hirschman (1958) described growth. Moreover, because multinationals seek to
in his seminal book on economic development. Hirschman minimize technology leakages to competitors while
(1958) emphasized that not all sectors have the same improving the productivity of suppliers by transferring
potential to absorb foreign technology or to create knowledge, were FDI to generate spillovers they would
linkages with the rest of the economy. He noted, for more likely be vertical than horizontal.
example, that linkages are weak in agriculture and mining.
He warned that in the absence of linkages, foreign Park Jongsoo (2004) conducted a study on “Korean
investments could have limited effect in spurring growth Perspective on FDI in India: Hyundai Motors‟ Industrial
in an economy. The grudge against what has become Cluster” indicates that industrial clusters are playing an
known as the „enclave‟ type of development, he wrote, “is important role in economic activity. The key to promoting
due to this ability of primary products from mines, wells, FDI inflows into India may lie in industries and products
and plantations to slip out of a country without leaving that are technology–intensive and have economies of scale
much of a trace in the rest of the economy.” About the and significant domestic content. Sharma EAS (2005) in
consequences in potential linkages effects differences in his paper “Need for Caution in Retail FDI” examines the
manufacturing and agriculture, Hirschman (1958) wrote, constraints faced by traditional retailers in the supply
“the absence of direct linkage effects of primary chain and give an emphasis on establishment of a package
production lends these views (enclaves) a plausibility that of safety-nets as Thailand has done. India should also
they do not have in the case of foreign investment in draw lessons from restrictions placed on the expansion of
manufacturing.” organized retailing, in terms of sourcing, capital
requirement, zoning etc, in other Asian countries. The
More recently, the theoretical work on linkages, by article comments on the retail FDI report that as
Rodiguez-Clare (1996), shows that multinationals‟ commissioned by the Department of Consumer Affairs
intensive use of intermediate goods enhances production and suggests the need for a more comprehensive study.
efficiency in host economies. In this framework, increased

i-Xplore International Research Journal Consortium www.irjcjournals.org


International Journal of Management and Social Sciences Research (IJMSSR) ISSN: 2319-4421 85
Volume 2, No. 6, June 2013

Gonzalez J.G (1988) in his study “Effect of Foreign Direct by sectors. But, relatively few scholars like Wheeler and
Investment in the presence of sector specific Mody (1992), Loree & Guisinger (1995), Richaud et al.
unemployment” extends the work done by Srinivasan (1999), Asiedu (2002) and Sekkat (2004) have
(1983) “International factor movements, commodity trade acknowledged the important role of infrastructure in
and commercial policy in a specific factor model”, by stimulating FDI by arguing that availability of crucial
making an analysis of the welfare effects of foreign infrastructure, such as roads, highways, ports,
investment. The study shows that if there are no communication networks and electricity increases
distortions, foreign investment enhances the social uplift productivity and thereby attracts higher levels of FDI.
of the people. The study strongly favours import This sheer fact of positive of impact of roads, bridges &
substitution policies since such a strategy provides greater highways development on economic growth motivated us
job opportunities to the people and consequently improves to evince special interest to look into the sectoral
their standards of living. But the study finds that welfare allocation of FDI in construction (including
effects of foreign Investment do not explain the pattern of infrastructure), which invariably encompasses FDI in
trade in the economy. Thus, both Srinivasan (1983) and roads & bridges development during our study period
Gonzalez (1998) concluded that foreign direct investment 2004-2010.
and distortions of the labour market results in social uplift
of the people. 4. OBJECTIVE:
Sharma Rajesh Kumar (2006) in his article “FDI in To see, in terms of growth rate, the relative growth of
Higher Education: Official Vision Needs Corrections”, construction (including infrastructure activities) in
raises four issues which need critical attention: the sectoral allocation of FDI into select sectors of the
objectives of higher education, its contextual relevance, economy over the period 2004-2010.
the prevailing financial situation and the viability of
alternatives to FDI. The conclusion of the article is that
higher education needs long-term objectives and a broad 5. METHODOLOGY:
vision in tune with the projected future of the country and
the world. Higher education will require an investment of We have collected sectoral FDI data for select nine sectors
Rs. 20,000 to 25,000 crore over the next five or more from the factsheet of foreign direct investment (FDI),
years to expand capacity and improve access. For such a August 1991-Feb 2011, DIPP (Department of Industrial
huge amount, the paper argues, we can look to FDI. Policy & Promotion)
(dipp.nic.in/english/publication/fdi_statistics/fdi_statitistic
s.aspx). We have taken data for seven years (2004-2010),
3. MOTIVATION: as data for construction (including infrastructure) before
Empirical researches suggest that capacity for FDI to that period is not available.
serve as a channel of technological spillover might differ

Sectoral Allocation of FDI (Rs. Crore)


Sectors 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Services Sector (Financial & Non-
financial) 1,986 2,399 21,047 22,054 28,516 20,776 14,958
Computer Software & Hardware 2,441 6,172 11,786 5,476 7,329 4,351 3,490
Telecommunication 570 2,776 2,155 4,846 11,727 12,338 6,398
Housing & Real Estate 20 171 2,121 7,186 12,621 13,586 5,070
Construction(including Infrastructure
Activities) 696 667 4,424 6,119 8,729 13,516 4,839
Automobile Industry 559 630 1,254 2,204 5,212 5,754 5,962
Power 241 386 713 2,003 4,382 6,908 5,639
Metallurgical Industries 836 6,540 7,866 3,856 4,157 1,935 4,783
Chemicals (Other than fertilizers) 909 1,731 930 868 3,427 1,707 1,746
Source: Factsheet on Foreign Direct Investment (FDI), August 1991-Feb 2011, DIPP

Here the data is of panel nature, where if log of FDI is pooled regression of log of FDI on year, which is
regressed on year/time period will give growth rate of FDI equivalent to estimation with neither fixed nor random
over the period (2004-2010). In order to see the allocation effects, as given in the following equation. The Eviews 6
of FDI into different sectors over the period, first we run a output is also shown below;

i-Xplore International Research Journal Consortium www.irjcjournals.org


International Journal of Management and Social Sciences Research (IJMSSR) ISSN: 2319-4421 86
Volume 2, No. 6, June 2013

LFDIit = ß1+ ß2*YEARi+ uit


𝐿𝐹𝐷𝐼 it = -768.8856 + 0.387100*YEARi
t = (-5.646245)*** (5.705170)***
SE = (136.1765) (0.067851)
(F-Statistics = 32.54897) *** (R2 = 0.347935),

Here we see that both, the intercept and the regressor, are could be an inappropriate assumption. Instead, we can
statistically significant at below 5% (***). Since FDI is in estimate a model with cross-section fixed, which is also
logarithmic form (i.e., the model being a log-lin panel known as Least Square Dummy Variable Model (LSDV),
regression model), so the slope estimate of 0.387100 which will allow us to capture the latent sector-specific
corresponds to an approximately 38.71% growth-rate in heterogeneity, as given in the following equation. The
FDI over the years. But this pooled regression assumes Eviews 6 output with effects specification cross-section
that the intercepts are the same for each sector, which fixed (dummy variables) is also shown below;

LFDIit = ß1i+ ß2*YEARi+ uit


𝐿𝐹𝐷𝐼 it = -768.8856 + 0.387100*YEARi
t = (-6.522545)*** (6.590615)***
SE = (117.8812) (0.058735)
(F-Statistics = 7.982221***) (R2 = 0.347935),

Here also we see that allocation or growth rate of FDI into significant. We can also see the sector-specific
different sectors over the years is positive and statistically heterogeneity from the table below;

Cross-section Specific Heterogeneity


Sectors Effect
Services Sector-Financial & Non-financial 1.282600
Computer Software & Hardware 0.539875
Telecommunication 0.260380
Housing & Real Estate -0.571298
Construction ( including infrastructure activities) 0.152224
Automobile Industry -0.379072
Power -0.670193
Metallurgical Industries 0.135460
Chemicals (other than fertilizers) -0.749976

Actual Differential Intercept Values of Nine Sectors


Sectors Intercepts
Services Sector-Financial & Non-financial -770.1682
Computer Software & Hardware -769.4255
Telecommunication -769.1460
Housing & Real Estate -768.3143
Construction ( including infrastructure activities) -769.0378
Automobile Industry -768.5065
Power -768.2154
Metallurgical Industries -769.0210
Chemicals (other than fertilizers) -769.6355

Form the above tables, we see that heterogeneity in terms Automobile Industry, Power and Chemicals (other than
of allocation of FDI across different sectors over the years fertilizers).
has been captured and this contribution has been obtained
to be the highest in case of Services Sector-Financial & Next we go in for random effects (cross-section) model,
Non-financial, followed by Computer Software & which is sometimes also known as error component
Hardware, Telecommunication, Construction Activities model. Under random effects model, the intercept for each
and Metallurgical Industries whereas the same has been cross-sectional unit are assumed to arise from a common
obtained to be negative in case of Housing & Real Estate, intercept, which is same for all cross-sectional units and

i-Xplore International Research Journal Consortium www.irjcjournals.org


International Journal of Management and Social Sciences Research (IJMSSR) ISSN: 2319-4421 87
Volume 2, No. 6, June 2013

over time, plus a random variable that varies over cross- cross-section random and idiosyncratic random is shown
section but is constant over time, as given in the following below;
equation. The Eviews 6 output with effects specification

LFDIit = ß1+ ß2*YEARi+ 𝜀𝑖 + uit


Or, 𝐿𝐹𝐷𝐼𝑖𝑡 = ß1+ ß2*YEARi+ Wit
LFDIit = ß1+ ß2*YEARi+ 𝑊𝑖𝑡
t = (-6.522536)*** (6.590615)***
SE = (117.8814) (0.058735)
(F-Statistics = 43.43621***) (Weighted R2 = 0.415911), (Un-weighted R2 = 0.347935)

Simultaneously, it is also worth determining that whether fixed effects are necessary or not, as shown in Eviews 6 output
below;

Redundant Fixed Effects Tests


Effects Test Statistic d.f.
Cross-section F 3.550472*** (8,53)
Cross-section Chi-square 27.035176*** 8

Redundant fixed effects test has been employed to see meaning thereby that a pooled sample could not be
whether fixed effects are necessary or not, each in both χ2 employed. Next we see whether fixed effect model is
and F-test versions, restricting cross-section fixed effects preferred over random effect model or not, using
to zero. From the above output, we see that cross-section Hausman test, as shown below in Eviews 6 output;
fixed effects restrictions are not supported by data,

Correlated Random Effects - Hausman Test


Test Summary Chi-Sq. Statistic Chi-Sq. d.f
Cross-section random 0.000000*** (1)

Cross-section random effects test comparisons


Variable Fixed Random Var(Diff.) Prob.
LFDI 0.387100 0.387100 -0.000000 NA

From the above output, we see that Hausman test is not development in the economy encompassing all the sectors,
significant. Therefore, it can be concluded that though bureaucratic delays and widespread corruption, which
random effect model is preferred over fixed effect model could not attract considerable amount of FDI, resulting in
but there is no significant difference between them, which an initial negative growth rate. The other is the random
is shown in the cross-section random effects test variable, which is constant over time but varies over
comparisons of the Correlated Random Effects - Hausman cross-section, which is invariably government policy
Test. This means that heterogeneity in terms of allocation regarding FDI across different sectors. Now, we can
or growth-rate of FDI into different sectors over the years compare three models, such as, Pooled OLS Model, Fixed
could be arising from two legs. One is the common Effect (LSDV) model and Random Effect Model (Error
intercept, which is constant over cross-section and over Component Model) in a tabular form, as given below;
time periods. This invariably emerges out of low level of

Dependent Variable: LFDI


Coefficient (t-ratio) [Standard Error]
Independent Variable OLS FEM REM
YEAR 0.387100 0.387100 0.387100
(5.705170)*** (6.590615)*** (6.590615)***
[0.067851] [0.058735] [0.058735]
Observations 63
R2 0.347935 0.575457 0.415911
***Significant at 1%

i-Xplore International Research Journal Consortium www.irjcjournals.org


International Journal of Management and Social Sciences Research (IJMSSR) ISSN: 2319-4421 88
Volume 2, No. 6, June 2013

6. CONCLUSION: of the Literature. Working Paper No. 76, The


European Institute of Japanese Studies.
Form the above results, we see that during the study
period 2004-2010, the growth-rate of FDI has found to be [6] Borensztein, J., J. De Gregorio and J-W. Lee
positive and statistically significant. But allocation of FDI, (1998). How does foreign direct investment affect
during these years, into different sectors has experienced economic growth?. Journal of International
heterogeneity, which arises from two legs. One is the Economics, Vol. 45, pp.115-135.
common intercept, which is negative and constant over
cross-section and over time periods. This invariably [7] Dunning, J. D. (1981). Explaining the international
emerges out of extant low level of development in the direct investment position of countries toward a
economy encompassing all the sectors, bureaucratic dynamic or development approach.
delays and widespread corruption, which could not attract Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, vol. 117, pp. 30-64.
considerable amount of FDI, resulting in an initial
negative growth rate. The other leg is the random variable, [8] Goodspeed T, Martinez-Vazquez J and Zhang L
which varies over cross-section but constant over time, (2006). Are Government Policies More Important
which is invariably government policy regarding FDI Than Taxation in Attracting FDI. ISP Working
across different sectors. Moreover, the contribution to this Paper Number 06-14, International Studies
heterogeneity in sectoral allocation of FDI has been Program working paper series.
obtained to be the highest in case of Services Sector-
Financial & Non-financial, followed by Computer [9] Haughwout, AF., (2001). Infrastructure and Social
Software & Hardware, Telecommunication, Construction Welfare in Metropolitian America. Economic
Activities (including Infrastructure) and Metallurgical Policy Review, Vol. 7, No.3
Industries whereas the same has been obtained to be
negative in case of Housing & Real Estate, Automobile [10] Holtz-Eakin, D. and Schwartz, A. E., (1995).
Industry, Power and Chemicals (other than fertilizers). Spatial productivity spillovers from public
Thus, we see that though construction activities (including infrastructure: Evidence from state highways.
infrastructure) had a positive contribution in the NBER Working Paper Series, No 5004, NBER.
heterogeneity in sectoral allocation of FDI, but is poorly
placed in the cross-section specific heterogeneity table, [11] Kokko, A. (1994). "Technology, market
which should have been other way round for attracting characteristics and spillovers." Journal of
more FDI and subsequent economic growth. Development Economics vol. 43 pp. 279-93.

[12] Loree D. W. and S. E. Guisinger (1995). Policy and


REFERENCES: non-policy determinants of U.S. equity foreign
direct investment. Journal of International Business
[1] Asiedu, E. (2002). On the Determinants of Foreign Studies, Vol. 26 (2), pp. 281-299.
Direct Investment to Developing Countries: Is
Africa Different?. World Development, Vol. 30(1), [13] Limao N, and A, J, Venables (2001). Infrastructure,
pp. 107-118. geographical disadvantage, transport costs and
trade. World Development Economic Review, Vol.
[2] Alfaro, L. (2003). Foreign Direct Investment and 15, pp.451-479
Growth: Does the Sector Matter? Harvard Business
School. Boston. [14] Mencinger, J. (2003). "Does Foreign Direct
Investment Always Enhance Economic Growth?"
[3] Billington, Nicholas, (1999). The location of Kyklos 56(4): 491-508.
foreign direct investment: an empirical analysis.
Applied Economics, Vol. 31, pp. 65-76. [15] Morrison, C J. and A E Schwartz., (1996). State
Infrastructure and Productive Performance‟.
[4] Blomstrom, M. and A. Kokko (1997). "The Impact American Economic Review, Vol 86, Issue 5.
of Foreign Invest- ment on Host Countries: A
Review of the Empirical Evidence." World Bank [16] Richaud, C., K. Sekkat and A. Varoudakis (1999).
Policy Research Working Paper(No. 1745). Infrastructure and Growth Spillovers: A Case for a
Regional Infrastructure Policy in Africa. Mimeo,
[5] Blomstrom, M., S. Globerman, et al. (1999). The University of Brussels.
Determinants of Host Country Spillovers from
Foreign Direct Investment: Review and Syn- thesis [17] Schneider, F. and Frey, B. (1985). Economic and
Political Determinants of Foreign Direct

i-Xplore International Research Journal Consortium www.irjcjournals.org


International Journal of Management and Social Sciences Research (IJMSSR) ISSN: 2319-4421 89
Volume 2, No. 6, June 2013

Investment. World Development, Vol. 13(2), pp.


161-175.

[18] Sekkat K and Veganzones-Varoudakis, M. (2004).


Trade and foreign exchange liberalisation,
investment climate and FDI in the MENA
countries. Working Papers DULBEA, Université
libre de Bruxelles, Department of Applied
Economics (DULBEA)

[19] Tsai, P. (1994). Determinants of Foreign Direct


Investment and Its Impact on Economic Growth.
Journal of Economic Development, Vol 19, pp.
137-163.

[20] Wei, S. (2000). How Taxing is Corruption on


International Investors?. Review of Economics and
Statistics, Vol. 82 (1), pp. 1-11.

[21] Wheeler, D. and A. Mody (1992), International


investment location decisions: The case of U.S.
firms. Journal of International Economics, Vol.33,
pp. 57-76.

[22] UNCTAD World Investment Report (2001, pp


138).

i-Xplore International Research Journal Consortium www.irjcjournals.org

View publication stats

You might also like