Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 16

African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and

Development

ISSN: 2042-1338 (Print) 2042-1346 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rajs20

Natural resource endowment and firm-level


innovation in Africa: Evidence from cross-country
analysis

Abdi Yuya Ahmad, Babikigalaga Denis Akouwerabou & Yehualashet Demeke


Lakew

To cite this article: Abdi Yuya Ahmad, Babikigalaga Denis Akouwerabou & Yehualashet Demeke
Lakew (2019): Natural resource endowment and firm-level innovation in Africa: Evidence from
cross-country analysis, African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development, DOI:
10.1080/20421338.2018.1550926

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/20421338.2018.1550926

Published online: 17 Jan 2019.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 3

View Crossmark data

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rajs20
African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development, 2018
https://doi.org/10.1080/20421338.2018.1550926
© 2018 African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development

Natural resource endowment and firm-level innovation in Africa: Evidence from cross-country
analysis
Abdi Yuya Ahmad1*, Babikigalaga Denis Akouwerabou2 and Yehualashet Demeke Lakew3
1
Department of Economics, Adama Science and Technology University, Adama, Ethiopia
2
Department of Economics, University Ouaga II, Ouagadougou, Burkina Faso
3
Department of Management, Arsi University, Asela, Ethiopia
*Corresponding author email: yuyabdi@gmail.com

This paper investigates the impact of a country’s natural resource endowment on the innovation propensity of firms in
Africa. It was expected that firms in resource-rich countries have less incentive to innovate than firms in resource-poor
countries due to the destructive effects of large resource rents on supportive institutions and political order. The data
used for the empirical analysis were obtained from the World Bank’s enterprise surveys global development indicators
and the African Economic Outlook reports. The hierarchical nature of the analysis called for a multilevel mixed effect
modelling strategy. Results suggest that firms in resource-rich countries are not necessarily less innovative than firms in
resource-poor countries. High natural resource endowment appeared to reduce firm-level innovation only if associated
with poor institutional and technological capabilities. The innovativeness of firms in resource-rich sub-Saharan Africa
countries was found to be lower than that of firms in North African countries. The negative effect of poor institutional
quality appeared to be dampened among firms with better innovation capabilities. The findings imply that building
effective institutional environments and enhancing firm-level innovative efforts would help mitigate the ‘resource curse’
which, in turn, is dictated by the resulting types of political settlements in resource-rich African countries.

Keywords: firms, innovation, Africa, country, natural resource, institution

Introduction linked to innovation systems (Lundvall 2011). These


The largest proportion of differences between developed relationships also imply the possibility of explaining the
and least developed countries (LDCs) has been attributed ‘resource curse’ phenomenon from micro-perspectives
to total factor productivity (TFP) which mainly depends rather than pursuing macroeconomic approaches applying
on innovation and technological capabilities (Rodrik, Sub- growth regressions. Given the theoretical framework that
ramanian, and Trebbi 2004). The innovativeness of a puts firms at the centre of learning and innovation (Lund-
country, in turn, depends on various factors relating to vall 2011) and the fact that innovation plays key roles in
its institutional and social capabilities (Freeman 2011; economic growth, generating micro-level explanations
Lundvall 2011). Plenty of literature associates the poor for the ‘resource curse’ thesis, would produce important
growth performance of Africa’s economy with natural policy inputs for Africa.
resource endowment, conflict, locational disadvantages Inspired by the above ground, this study proposed to
in terms of access to the global market and advanced tech- examine the links between natural resource endowment
nologies (Pinkovskiy and Sala-i-Martin 2010), colonial and the innovation propensities of firms in a non-
legacies, ethnic divisions, initial conditions, and economic resource sector. Apart from filling the underlying gap
policies (Fosu 2008). Particularly, the fact that Africa’s in the literature, the research also aimed to lay the
export has been the least diversified of all developing ground for similar subsequent studies. Three related
countries and its excessive dependence on primary com- questions were set to be answered in this paper. 1) Are
modities (Asche, Neuerburg, and Menegatti 2012) have firms2 in resource-rich countries less innovative than
remained among the major concerns for both researchers those in resource-poor countries? What transmission
and policymakers. McMillan and Rodrik (2011) indicated mechanisms exist if there is any effect running from
that African countries whose export revenue largely resource endowment (macro-level) to innovation
depends on natural resources are less likely to succeed (micro-level)? 2) How important is institutional environ-
in spurring productivity enhancing structural change. For ment in determining the incentives for and hence out-
instance, Nigeria and Zambia have experienced negative comes of firm-level innovative efforts? 3) Are there
growth while Ghana, Ethiopia and Malawi have registered country-wise variations in the outcomes of firms’
relatively better growth (McMillan and Rodrik 2011). efforts to introduce new or significantly modified pro-
The empirical regularity that resource abundance ducts or processes? Seeking answers to these questions,
could affect economic growth through its effect on the study aimed at suggesting measures that would help
social and institutional capabilities (UNDP 2006) and tackle the likelihood of ‘resource curse’ in Africa which
the fact that innovation capacities had a pivotal role in is among the continent’s top priority agendas in view of
the growth dynamics of successful developing countries the increasing trend of new resource discoveries and the
(OECD 2012) suggest the potential linkages between growth potentials underlying natural resources.
natural resource endowment and innovation. Resource1 Unlike earlier studies, this paper gives new evidence
intensity can influence the likelihood of firms to innovate and a theoretical framework that can help explain the
via its effect on national framework conditions (UN 2016) ‘resource curse’ and its ramifications at the micro-level.

African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development is co-published by NISC Pty (Ltd) and Informa Limited (trading as Taylor & Francis Group)
2 Ahmad, Akouwerabou and Lakew

The expectation that firm-level innovation is lower in all Two opposing arguments exist regarding the links
resource-rich African economies has not been supported between natural resource endowment and economic
by the finding. The effects appeared to be different growth. The first constitutes a view that countries with
between countries in the sub-Sahara Africa (SSA) and high natural resources enjoy better growth opportunities
those in North Africa (MENA). Resource endowment than resource-poor countries. This has evolved from the
appeared to inhibit innovation in SSA countries and in experiences of industrialized economies including the
cases where there are poor political conditions. USA and Norway. Secondly, the experiences and
However, innovation is not hampered by poor political success of newly industrializing Asian economies led to
situations among firms with better innovative efforts. emergence of a ‘resource curse’ phenomenon in which
The findings suggest that getting the political machine economies with many natural resources are believed to
right and using resource revenues for building innovation perform more poorly than countries with fewer natural
capabilities are crucial if Africa is to overcome the resources (Sachs and Warner 1997, 2001; UNDP 2006).
‘resource curse’ and achieve the required types of struc- Different theoretical bases have been used to explain the
tural change. phenomenon among which the structuralist’s view, the
The remaining part of the paper begins with the next ‘Dutch Disease’ thesis and institutional economics are
section that presents a brief literature review and the the most common. Structural economists argue that
hypotheses formulated based on the major research ques- resource abundance slows growth owing to lower terms
tions. The section thereafter presents some stylized facts of exchange between primary and manufactured goods,
on descriptive insights about the manifestation of the volatility of commodity prices, and the weak linkages
‘resource curse’ phenomenon followed by the underpin- between natural-resource and other economic sectors. Pro-
ning analytical framework of the study. The section that ponents of the ‘Dutch Disease’ thesis argue that high
then follows discusses the data and the methodology uti- inflow of foreign currencies following resource booms
lized to test the hypotheses. The penultimate section con- and high returns to labour and other factors in the extrac-
stitutes discussions on the results of the econometric tive sector hinder industrialization in relation to manufac-
analyses. The final section gives conclusions on the tured goods’ decreased competitiveness fuelled by
main findings and recommendations. exchange rate appreciations and misallocation of pro-
ductive resources. Institutional economists associate the
‘resource curse’ phenomena with the growth-inhibiting
Literature review and hypotheses effect of high transaction costs due to increased incidences
There is a broad consensus that improvement in the quality of rent seeking in resource-rich countries (Robinson,
of labour, capital accumulation and technical change Torvik, and Verdier 2006). Besides, resource rents would
explains differences in economic growth and develop- inhibit growth through rendering different enabling insti-
ment. The deeper question has been about why some tutions ineffective (Bulte, Damania, and Deacon 2005;
countries perform better than others in terms of skills Isham et al. 2005) and directing entrepreneurial efforts
development, stocks of capital and innovation. One of towards less productive activities (Mehlum, Moene, and
the answers to this question concentrates on geography Torvik 2006).
(including natural resources and ecological factors) and Nevertheless, in their extensive review of the litera-
trade (Sachs and Warner 2001). Some countries have geo- ture Torres, Afonso, and Soares (2013) found that
graphical advantages in terms of their natural resource whether natural resources can be a ‘curse’ or a ‘blessing’
stocks and proximity to international trade or technologi- depends on various factors and the effects are more of
cally frontier countries. Countries with good stock of min- indirect than direct. Given the strong theoretical and
erals and fuel and/or those with better geographical empirical bases on the crucial role of innovation for
proximity are expected to have higher growth potential aggregate productivity and the strong roles of insti-
than those that do not. tutional arrangements in innovation systems, explaining
Some economists argue that differences between the ‘resource curse’ thesis along this line would be
countries in improving the quality of their labour and sti- more plausible. Well-functioning institutions are impera-
mulating capital accumulation and innovation relates to tive for entrepreneurial ability and innovation (Tebaldi
the functioning of their institutional set-ups. Institutions and Elmslie 2013), accumulation of physical and
are considered as the most important (in fact, the only human capital (Rodrik, Subramanian, and Trebbi
really important) root factor of development (Rodrik, 2004), and adoption and creation of better technologies
Subramanian, and Trebbi 2004). The question again is (Loayza, Oviedo, and Serven 2005), and determine the
why have some countries’ institutions proven to be outcomes of firms’ productivity enhancing inputs such
more effective than others’? One of the arguments as R&D (Goedhuys and Srholec 2015) all of which are
given in the ‘resource curse’ literature is that resource- crucial for innovation. Sachs and Warner (2001) argued
rich countries face distinct challenges in terms of that entrepreneurship and innovative activities are low
unemployment and weak production linkages among in resource-rich countries as high returns in the resource
economic sectors (WEF 2017); have lower levels of sectors divert factors away from non-resource sectors.
overall development, higher incidences of child malnu- This implies that firms in resource-rich countries are
trition, lower educational outcomes, and shorter life less likely to innovate than firms in resource-poor
expectancy (Page 2005); and poor governance (Collier countries. The following hypothesis (1a) was set to
and O’Connell 2008). verify this relationship:
African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development 3

. Hypothesis 1a: The higher a country’s natural resource own innovative efforts would also depend on country-
endowment, the lower is the innovation propensity of specific conditions. Countries differ in terms of conditions
firms in the country such political system, levels of development, stocks of
social and human capital, comparative advantages, levels
However, the above theoretical and empirical bases
of infrastructure, and openness to trade. These conditions
suggest that hypothesis (1a) can hold water only con-
dictate each country’s policy formulation and implemen-
ditionally. The assumption is that natural resource inten-
tation capabilities, industrial capabilities as well as firm-
sity may jeopardize innovation through affecting other
level incentives for doing business, entrepreneurship and
mediating factors. Natural resource wealth appeared to
innovation. Therefore, similar innovation inputs and
be a ‘curse’ when associated with low-quality institutions
efforts by firms in different countries would not produce
(Brunnschweiler 2008). Similarly, Daniele (2011) found
similar outcomes. Accordingly, hypotheses 2a and 2b
that the effect of natural resources on a country’s human
were set to be tested:
and economic development depends on the country’s
specific conditions in terms of the political and insti- . Hypothesis 2a: Poor institutional quality associates with
tutional features. lower firm-level innovation propensity due to lower
Barma et al. (2012) also noted that the quality of a incentives or efforts to innovative
country’s institutions is central in the resource paradox . Hypothesis 2b: The outcomes of firms’ innovative
and institutional quality in turn depends on levels of econ- efforts3 vary with country specific conditions
omic development. They referred to the simple empirical
Some stylized facts that would help justify the hypoth-
fact, often ascribed as a major dimension of the resource
eses and the analytical framework of the study are pre-
curse, that resource dependent countries possess poorer
sented in the following section.
institutional quality than they should, given their income
levels. Holding gross domestic product (GDP) constant,
Stylized facts and the analytical framework of the
resource-dependent countries perform less well in govern-
study
ance indicators demonstrating the institutional dimension
Some stylized facts on the manifestation of resource
of the ‘resource curse’ (Barma et al. 2012). Robinson,
curse
Torvik, and Verdier (2006) and Mehlum, Moene, and
In view of the limited empirical evidence regarding the
Torvik (2006) argue that countries with accountability
links between natural resource abundance and innovation
and state-competence promoting institutions will benefit
capability at micro- and macroeconomic levels, this
from resource abundance while those without such attri-
section presents some stylized facts pertaining to the
butes would face a ‘resource curse’. Specific to Africa,
implications of the ‘resource curse’ phenomena in
controlling corruption and high regulatory quality were
Africa. This was done by categorizing countries into
found to stimulate innovation (Oluwatobi et al. 2015).
resource-rich and resource-poor based on AfDB et al.
Therefore, conditions linked to institutional qualities con-
(2016). The focus was to illustrate the differences
stitute the transmission channel through which revenues
between these categories in terms of their manufacturing
from extractive sectors would affect innovations in the
and innovation capabilities. Given the pivotal role of tech-
manufacturing and service sectors. This suggests the
nological progress for long-term sustained development
need to modify hypothesis (1a) by (1b):
and the perception that the rate of technological change
. Hypothesis 1b: The higher the institutional quality of a may be more dynamic in manufacture or services sectors
country the lower is the probability that natural resource than in resource-dependent activities, African policy-
endowment reduces the innovation propensity of firms in makers aspire to diversify their economies and decrease
the country their natural resource dependencies (WEF 2017). Empiri-
cal evidence from Africa indicates the dominance of a
Furthermore, the transmission mechanism would
counterproductive impact of natural resource endowment
follow other channels than those that would be captured
on manufacturing and service sectors. Thus, looking at
by a single institutional indicator, embedded in broader
manufacturing capabilities would shed some light on the
characteristics such as initial conditions and geography.
impact of resource intensity on the development of other
For instance, countries in the MENA region have
non-resource sectors. The patterns of national innovation
medium to high human development indices (HDI)
capabilities of resource-rich and non-resource rich
while most countries in SSA have low HDI (AfDB et al.
countries would also indicate the potential channels
2016), not to mention other idiosyncrasies, country-wise.
through which resource endowment would affect firm-
Accordingly, it could be the case that the impacts of
level innovation performances. The selected indicators
resource intensity on firm-level innovation may be differ-
are shown below graphically (Figures 1–4).
ent between countries in the SSA and those in MENA.
Figure 1 displays differences in the manufacturing per-
Given this, the following was hypothesized:
formances measured in terms of manufacturing value
. Hypothesis 1c: The effects of natural resource intensity added (MVA) as a per cent of gross domestic product
on firm-level innovation are different for countries in (GDP) and the share of manufacturing export in total mer-
the SSA and those in the MENA region chandize export (MEX). Panel (a) shows that the average
MVA of resource-poor countries was above that of
Apart from the potential variations on the effects of resource-rich countries over the 2000–2016 period.
natural resource on innovation, the effectiveness of firms However, the gap decreased due to the declining trend
4 Ahmad, Akouwerabou and Lakew

Figure 1: Resource endowment and manufacturing performance.


Source: Global Development Indicators database.

of MVA of resource-poor countries from about 16% in Neuerburg, and Menegatti (2012) countries in the North-
2002 to below 12% after 2012. The MVA of resource- ern African region (henceforth MENA) have shown
rich countries was between 8% and 10% over the same better performances in their manufacturing and export
period. diversification than those in the sub-Saharan Africa
Similar to the MVA, the average MEX of resource- (SSA) regions with the exception of South Africa. On
poor countries [Figure 1(b)] was above the MEX of this account, Figure 2 was prepared to depict if the same
resource-rich countries. The average MEX of resource- differences would prevail between the two regions in
poor countries was above 25% while that of resource- terms of average MVA and MEX as well as the trends
rich countries remained below 25%. Between 2000 and of average percentage shares of natural resource revenues
2006, MEX exhibited a declining trend in both country (NRR) in the GDPs of the two regions.
groups. After 2007, however, there appeared to be asym- Comparing panel (a) and panel (b) reveals that the
metric movement whereby the MEX of resource-poor average MEX of countries in the MENA region ranged
countries was increasing while that of resource-rich between 32% and 50% while that of the SSA was far
countries was declining until 2009. MEX’s convergence lower (20–25%). The average MVA of countries in the
over the 2015–2016 period may be attributed to improve- MENA region also exceeded (15%) that of countries in
ment in the strategies of one or more countries in the the SSA (10%). The other interesting aspect of Figure 2
resource-rich countries which can only be traced through is the observed differences in the potential relationships
examining each country’s specific performance. between natural resource and manufacturing performances
Figure 2 uncovers the importance of disaggregating between the two regions. The figure shows that with the
African countries into more homogeneous groups so exception of years before 2003 and after 2011, the
that averages make better sense. According to Asche, average NRR of countries in the MENA region was

Figure 2 : Resource endowment and manufacturing performance by region.


Source: Computed from Global development Indicators database.
African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development 5

Figure 3: Number of Scientific and technical journal articles (in hundreds).


Source: WEF (2017).

above 15% of their GDP while that of countries in the SSA The two panels of the figure (3.4) together suggest a
fell below 15% except over the 2007–2008 and 2011– direct relationship between institutional quality and inno-
2012 periods. After 2008, the NRR of MENA countries vation in line with the theoretical and empirical evidences.
declined at a higher rate than the decline observed in Being resource rich may not necessarily discourage the
SSA. This may be linked to the political turmoil countries innovation propensities of firms in a given country. It is
in the region experienced. more likely to have a negative effect on firm-level inno-
Regarding the relationship between manufacturing vation if accompanied by lower institutional quality.
performance and natural resource, average MEX seems Therefore, if a resource-rich country manages to build an
to be correlated negatively with average NRR in both effective institutional environment, there would be favour-
MENA and SSA as their respective graphs tended to able condition for innovation in the country. Given this,
move in opposite direction. However, the gap between the analytical framework underpinning the possible
the two indicators was wider in case of the MENA micro manifestation of the ‘resource-curse’, as drawn
countries. Coupled with this, their higher export diversifi- from the literature and stylized facts, is given below.
cation depicts the underlying advancement in terms of
their relative technological and innovation capabilities.
As one of the alternative measures of national technologi- Analytical framework
cal capability, it may be useful to see the trends of the Figure 5 depicts the analytical framework of the study
number of scientific and technical journals (NSTJ) by driven from two strands of literature. The first class is lit-
the two African regions as depicted in Figure 3. eratures on the political economy of natural resource and
The left panel (a) of Figure 3 shows the total NSTJ while the second relates to the innovation system and
by a few countries in the MENA region was, almost, innovation capability literatures. Whether natural resource
equal to but growing faster than that of all countries in can be a ‘curse’ to a given country depends on its impact
the SSA. The comparison is clearer when the average on the country’s growth enabling conditions. It can be a
NSTJ is used as indicated in panel (b). It is apparent ‘blessing’, rather, if the country makes proper use of
that the average NSTJ of a country in the MENA resource revenues in creating growth-enabling conditions
reached over 4000 per annum in 2016 from its 2003 through building infrastructure, effective institutions and
status of about 1000. On the other hand, the average technological capabilities which in turn strongly depend
NSTJ of a country in SSA stalled with the highest on what Khan (2010) calls ‘political settlement’.
being about 500 per annum. This would decrease even This implies that the economic impact of high resource
further if South Africa were excluded from the group. intensity may be good or bad depending on its effect on the
This fact suggests MENA countries have greater resulting type of political settlement. According to Bates
human and institutional capabilities which are important (2008) mineral and petroleum production can affect politi-
for innovation. cal order in two different ways. The first is through affect-
Nevertheless, high resource endowment appears to be ing income distribution either between the centre and the
associated with low quality institution and low innovation periphery or between resource-rich and resource-poor
in the African context.4 Figure 4(a) depicts that the quality regions. The second channel relates to the impact of
of institutions in resource-rich countries is lower than that resource rents in shaping the behaviour of political elites
of the resource-poor groups. Similarly, Figure 4(b) indi- in a political system. Similarly, Nigeria’s oil resource has
cates that resource-poor countries have better innovation become a ‘curse’ as it turned the county’s political order
capability than their resource-rich counterparts. and institutions a convenient apparatus that better served
6 Ahmad, Akouwerabou and Lakew

Figure 4: Institutional quality and Innovation by resource endowment.


Source: Computed from Global competitiveness database.

politicians’ personal ends than the national interest (Olar- (Duruigbo 2014); and different growth inhibiting syn-
inmoye 2008). dromes (Fosu 2008). Focusing on the roles of history
With the exception of Botswana, Africa’s resource- and political interaction within and outside a country (Aye-
rich countries, in general, have experienced the worst lazuno 2014) would be important as problems emanating
economic situations (Collier and O’Connell 2008). They from historical or colonial legacies, social structures and
have been exposed to increased incidences of conflict ethnic diversities have contributed to the malaise of
and rent-seeking behaviours, clientelism in fiscal policies Africa’s politics and economy (Page 2005). Thus, the
and political institutions (Page 2005); poverty, environ- economic implication of Africa’s natural resource endow-
mental degradation, human rights abuses, authoritarianism ment is more tenable if analyzed from political economy

Figure 5. The analytical framework.


Source: Authors’ articulation based on Khan (2010).
African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development 7

perspective and hence the underpinning analytical frame- Surveys (ES) conducted in 30 different African countries
work is depicted in Figure 5. (Table 1) over 2011–2017 periods. The country-year com-
The top left box of Figure 5 shows that all other geo- bination that generated the total sample was for the simple
graphical location and historical legacies would affect reason that only countries with data over this period were
different national capabilities and political settlement. included, since the ES data collected before 2011 lacked
Political settlement is pivotal the effectiveness of national uniformity and the required innovation variables for the
policies as it determines how different actors at macro-, study. Enterprise surveys since 2011 have been conducted
meso- and micro-levels are coordinated (Khan 2010). At using more standardized questionnaires. The question-
the macro-level, the type of political settlement of a given naires also included an innovation module constituting
country dictates important conditions such as the quality questions about product innovation, process innovation,
of institutions, macroeconomic stability, infrastructure, organizational innovation, whether a firm has spent on
social and technological capabilities, and the policy Research and Development (R&D), and so on. The ES
making capacity. These conditions can also determine data also constitute important variables such as different
firm-level and sectoral performances through their effects firm characteristics, performance measures, markets, sec-
on firm-level and sectoral characteristics respectively. toral characteristics, and general business environment.
Actors at meso-level refer to sectoral characteristics such The data were collected by interviewing managers of
as sector-level policy, institutions, comparative advantage, enterprises operating in manufacturing, trade and other
technology, industrial structure, and learning opportunity service sectors including construction. The country-year
which are not immune from the prevailing type of political sample size (Table A1) ranges from 150 to 2897 with
settlement. These sectoral behaviours can constrain and Egypt contributing the largest followed by Nigeria. Ethio-
limit performance of firms through affecting learning capa- pia and Tanzania’s data, respectively, constitute 1492 and
bilities and various operational conducts (Malerba 2002). 1237 observations pooled from two different years.
At micro-level, political settlement determines not Countries were grouped into resource-rich and resource-
only the type of firms to be selected for reaping the poor based on African Economic Outlook’s (AfDB et al.
benefits of policy rents, it also affects the ex-post charac- 2016) definition which relied on each country’s 2010 per
teristics of the firms including their innovative behaviour. capita USD value of natural resource production.
According to Khan (2010) a ‘Capitalist’ political settle-
ment supports value adding firms which are characterized
by dynamic learning and innovation capabilities while The empirical model: Multi-level mixed effect logistic
‘clientlist’ type of political settlement often rewards rent- regression
seeking firms rather than value-adding capitalists In estimating a model that predicts the likelihood that a
through compromising the effectiveness of formal insti- firm will innovate as a function of firm-level and
tutions. The latter characterizes widespread failure of country level variables, one would use ordinary logistic
developing countries to catch up with advanced countries regression with or without country dummies and multile-
owing to the failure of their institutions to induce pro- vel mixed-effect logistic model. Using ordinary logit
ductivity growth in learning industries as the institutions including country dummies with other explanatory vari-
are unable to manage rents and create conditions for ables is preferred to the one without country dummy as
rapid learning (Khan and Blankenburg 2009). it fails to capture country fixed effects. However, using
Generally, the potential impacts of a country’s natural multilevel modelling is far better than the two as it
resource endowment on the innovation of firms would allows fitting firm-level regression while controlling any
transmit through affecting the country’s political settle- country specific systematic unexplained variation in a
ment. The resulting type of political settlement in turn dic- single statistical equation (Gelman 2006). Multilevel
tates different national and institutional capabilities which model disentangles the unexplained variance in a
are pivotal to the nature and interactions of actors in inno- regression attributed to differences among groups from
vation systems as well as the risk taking, learning, and inno- that of differences among individuals within a group.
vation behaviours of business entities (Oyelaran-Oyeyinka Besides, it allows measuring the relative sizes and
and Sampath 2007). Therefore, modelling the manifes- effects of country level variables on individual character-
tation of a ‘resource curse’ phenomenon at micro-level istics and outcomes by adding interaction terms (Goldstein
entails accounting for different national, sectoral, and 2011). Multilevel modelling is applied on hierarchically
firm-level characteristics. However, full-fledged empirical clustered data at two or more levels.
translation of the analytical framework is difficult due to This paper applied a two-level model with firms and
lack of appropriate theory, data and complexity of inter- countries taking the first and the second levels respect-
actions. Given these constraints, this research can be the ively. In line with the analytical framework, a country’s
first of its kind in Africa to examine the microeconomic natural resource endowment would affect innovation at
implication of the ‘resource curse’ paradox. The data and the firm-level through its effect on political settlement
methodology used in the study are presented below. which in turn dictates institutions and other capabilities
determining innovation. Therefore, the total effects of
Data and methodology firm-level, sectoral, and national characteristics constitute
The data both fixed and random components which would vary
The micro data utilized in this study constitute 18,928 with countries depending on their respective institutional
observations drawn from the World Bank’s Enterprise and national technological capabilities. Up on assuming
8 Ahmad, Akouwerabou and Lakew

Table 1: Definitions of variables.

Innov: dummy for innovation, assuming value ‘1’ if a firm performs new or significantly improved product/process or service during
three years before the survey and ‘0’ otherwise
lnage: the natural logarithm of number of years since a firm started operation
exptopm: measures experiences of top managers computed as the natural logarithm of the total number of years a manager has spent in a
specific sector
frmsize: represents firm size computed as the natural logarithm of the total number of permanent full-time employees of a firm
private: dummy for private ownership of a firm, taking value ‘1’ if a private owner’s share in a firm’s total paid-up capital exceeds 50%
and ‘0’ otherwise
foreign: dummy for foreign ownership of a firm, assuming value ‘1’ if a foreign owner’s share in a firm’s total paid-up capital is non-zero
and ‘0’ otherwise
training: dummy for training, assuming value ‘1’ if a firm offered formal training to its permanent full-time employees during years
before the survey reference
buscity: dummy for main business city, taking value ‘1’ if a firm is located in a country’s main business city and ‘0’ otherwise
RDS: dummy for R&D expenditure, assuming value ‘1’ if a firm has R&D spending over the last there years before survey. It is used as a
measure of innovation capability on the ground that firms with positive R&D spending also have the materials and expertise required for
innovation
export: Dummy for exporters taking value ‘1’ if a firm sells its product in foreign market(s) and ‘0’ otherwise
sector: stands for three separate dummies for manufacturing, trade and other service sectors
polhar: political hardening (a composite index representing institutional quality of a country computed based on observed events) taken
from African Economic Outlook (2016). Values range between 1 and 7 with the highest showing poor institutional quality
resd: dummy for resource-rich countries taking value ‘1’ if a country’s minerals, metals and oil production accounted more than 30% of
the country’s GDP in 2010 [following AfDB et al. (2016)]
SSA: dummy for SSA, taking value ‘1’ if a country is located in SSA and ‘0’ otherwise (or MENA)

random intercepts, the following was estimated: the relationships. The major objective was to see if there is
any connection between a country’s natural resource
Innovij = h0 + h1 frmsizeij + h2 lnageij + h3 trainingij endowment and the probabilities of firms in the country’s
non-resource sectors. Before presenting the regression
+ h4 exptopmij + h5 Foreignij + h6 buscityij results, it would be useful to give a descriptive view of
+ h7 RDSij + h8 sector + h9 exportij the proportion of firms that undertook product and
+ h10 privatedij + h11 resd + h12 SSA process innovations (Appendix Table A2) in each
country. Among the 30 countries in the sample, Kenya,
+ h13 polhar + uj + eij
Namibia, Uganda, Rwanda, Zimbabwe, Sudan, Maurita-
(1) nia, Malawi, Zambia, Tanzania and Ghana respectively
are the top 10 countries with over 50% of firms reported
where j = 1, … ,30 represent countries, i = 1, … , nj firms to have introduced new product or service. Rwandese
in country j, and uj is the random intercept, and e firms have the highest process innovation (0.71) whereas
denotes error term. firms in Lesotho have the least process innovation
If one or more covariates are assumed to vary across (0.06). Over 50% of the firms in Rwanda, Uganda,
upper level clusters, a model with both random intercepts Kenya, Namibia, Zimbabwe, Tanzania, Mauritania,
and slopes would be estimated. In this study, random vari- CAR, Ghana, and Malawi have undertaken process inno-
ation was assumed in terms of firm-level innovative capa- vation. Lesotho has the fewest innovative firms in terms of
bilities only and the resulting model was specified as: both product and process.
The main regression results are presented in Table 2
Innovij = h0 + h1 frmsizeij + h2 lnageij + h3 trainingij under seven columns (M1-M7). M1, M2, M3, and M6
+ h4 exptopmij + h5 Foreignij + h6 buscityij display results obtained from different specifications of
+ h7 RDSij + h8 sector + h9 exportij + h10 privatedij product innovation equation while M4, M5 and M7 con-
stitute estimates of process innovation. Estimates in M1-
+ h11 resd + h12 SSA+ h13 polhar +RDSij uj + eij
M5 show results of random intercept specification while
(2) M6 and M7 were obtained from random intercept and
slope specification (equation 2) with unstructured var-
Relevant interaction effects were also included in both iances that allow correlation between variances of the
equations to test the extended hypotheses corresponding random intercepts and slopes. The likelihood ratio tests
to the possible differential impacts of resource endowment beneath the columns suggest using multilevel mixed
by regions and country specific institutional environments. effect logit estimations is better than applying ordinary
Definitions of the major variables are given in Table 1. logit. Besides, the fact that the standard deviations of the
random intercepts and coefficients became more than
Results and discussion twice of their respective standard errors confirm the appro-
The above stylized facts suggested the potential relation- priateness of the model specifications.
ship between a country’s natural resources, institutions, Results show some differences in the effects of firm-
and innovation. This section presents results of the econo- level controls on product and process innovation. Age
metric analyses corresponding to the micro implications of and private ownership of firms have positive significant,
Table 2: Results of multi-level mixed effect logit.

M1 M2 M3 M4 M5 M6 M7
lnage 1.049**[0.025] 1.051**[0.025] 1.053**[0.025] 0.994[0.025] 0.995[0.025] 1.050**[0.025] 0.995[0.025]
frmsize 1.107***[0.018] 1.106***[0.018] 1.104***[0.018] 1.080***[0.018] 1.078***[0.018] 1.103***[0.018] 1.080***[0.018]
training 1.873***[0.079] 1.875***[0.079] 1.874***[0.079] 1.885***[0.081] 1.884***[0.081] 1.878***[0.079] 1.888***[0.081]
exptopm 1.008[0.007] 1.008[0.007] 1.008[0.006] 1.036***[0.008] 1.035***[0.008] 1.009[0.006] 1.036***[0.008]
export 1.054[0.049] 1.056[0.049] 1.041[0.048] 1.087*[0.052] 1.067[0.051] 1.045[0.048] 1.069[0.051]
privated 1.108*[0.066] 1.111*[0.066] 1.106**[0.065] 0.944[0.058] 0.941[0.058] 1.104*[0.065] 0.942[0.058]
RDS 3.423***[0.166] 3.421***[0.166] 2.657***[0.171] 3.915***[0.191] 2.855***[0.185] 2.552***[0.302] 2.902***[0.302]
foreign 1.220**[0.096] 1.217**[0.096] 1.218**[0.096] 0.978[0.082] 0.983[0.082] 1.215**[0.095] 0.981[0.083]
buscity 1.077**[0.040] 1.074*[0.040] 1.081**[0.041] 1.097**[0.043] 1.105**[0.044] 1.084**[0.041] 1.110***[0.044]
resd 1.500**[0.267] 3.697***[1.332] 4.342***[2.337] 1.053[0.187] 1.324[0.807] 5.312***[3.176] 1.275[0.793]
polhar 0.914**[0.040] 0.965[0.041] 0.960[0.047] 0.926*[0.040] 0.918[0.050] 0.966[0.047] 0.915[0.053]

African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development 9


SSA 1.600*[0.405] 2.721***[0.789] 2.858***[0.885] 2.003***[0.501] 2.206**[0.770] 2.947***[0.901] 2.168**[0.812]
resdxSSA 0.308***[0.130] 0.287***[0.131] 0.832[0.430] 0.274***[0.122] 0.854[0.438]
polharxRDS 1.102***[0.019] 1.129***[0.019] 1.116***[0.039] 1.122***[0.034]
resdxpolhar 0.951[0.111] 0.957[0.126] 0.881[0.139] 0.962[0.143]
Retail Service 0.873***[0.033] 0.872***[0.033] 0.876***[0.033] 0.637***[0.025] 0.640***[0.025] 0.878***[0.033] 0.641***[0.025]
other service 0.759***[0.060] 0.765***[0.060] 0.762***[0.060] 0.699***[0.060] 0.695***[0.060] 0.763***[0.060] 0.694***[0.060]
_cons 0.240***[0.078] 0.145***[0.050] 0.147***[0.052] 0.521**[0.171] 0.508*[0.202] 0.145***[0.051] 0.503*[0.207]
Random-effects Parameters Estimates
sd(_cons) 0.419[0.066] 0.354[0.061] 0.355[0.061] 0.411[0.068] 0.404[0.067] 0.342[0.060] 0.408[0.070]
sd(RDS) 0.363[0.079] 0.29[0.070]
corr(RDS_cons) 0.136[0.492] −0.207[0.350]
No. of obs 16843 16843 16843 16812 16812 16843 16812
No. of groups 30 30 30 30 30 30 30
Wald chi2 1316*** 1334*** 1368*** 1619*** 1678*** 693*** 973***
LR test vs. logi. 256*** 124*** 128*** 204*** 199*** 152*** 213***
NB: year dummies included in all models; and *,**,*** indicate significances at 10%, 5%, 1% respectively. Values in parentheses are standard errors.
10 Ahmad, Akouwerabou and Lakew

albeit marginally, effects on product innovation while caused changes in the political order. Alternatively, it
tending to have negative effects, though insignificant, on could mean that there are other important measures of
process innovation. RDS, training, and firm size appear institution which are strongly linked to the likelihood of
to have positive and strongly significant effects. The mag- ‘resource curse’.
nitude of the effect is the highest in RDS followed by train- The other important interaction effect was the one
ing. The innovation propensities of firms with R&D between SSA and resd (resd×SSA) with the aim of
spending exceeded those of firms without R&D by testing the third sub-hypothesis (hypothesis 1c). The
about 2.6–4-fold. Providing formal training to permanent interaction was assumed to capture broader factors
employees was also proved to raise innovation propensity embedded in regional differences in relation to the poten-
by about twofold. Firms located in a country’s main tial effects of natural resource on firm-level innovation.
business city (buscity) appeared to be more innovative The estimation results are presented in columns M2
than those in other locations. The probability of product and M3 of Table 2. As can be seen from the results,
innovation is significantly higher among foreign firms the odds ratios corresponding to the interaction term
than domestic firms. Neither export participation turned out to be significantly small fractions (0.308
(export) nor top managers’ experiences (exptopm) have and 0.287) at less than 1% level of significance. This
a significant effect on product innovation while the later suggests that the innovation propensity of firms in a
appears to have a significant effect on process innovation. resource-abundant SSA country is significantly lower
As expected, service firms have significantly lower inno- than that of a resource-rich MENA country. It implies
vation than manufacturing in terms of both product and that resource-rich SSA countries are more prone to the
process. ‘resource curse’ than those in MENA region as lower
Turning to the main variables of interest, M1 and M4 firm-level innovation in the former can be associated
display results estimated for product and process inno- with lower prospects to sustainable growth. This is in
vations, respectively, with the aim of testing hypothesis line with the stylized facts presented in the third section
1a up on controlling for the confounding effects of politi- of this paper which indicate relatively higher technological
cal conditions and regional differences while excluding and manufacturing capabilities in MENA countries than in
interaction terms. The results failed to support the hypoth- SSA countries. However, due to the inherent nature of the
esized negative relationship between resource endowment quantitative approach applied in this paper, the detailed
and innovation as the odds ratio (1.5) of resource dummy transmission mechanism that links regional affiliation of
(resd) appeared to be strongly significant (5% level). This a country and national technological capability to firm-
means that the innovation propensity of firms in resource- level innovation remains to be a ‘black box’.
rich countries exceeded that of their resource-poor com- Nevertheless, the analytical framework (Figure 5)
parators by about 50%. However, the same did not seem suggests that the effects of any factor at the national
to hold in the case of process innovation. Of the two and sector levels on innovation translate through chan-
country-level potential confounders, poor political situ- ging firm-level innovation capabilities or efforts. One
ation (high polhar) was found to significantly reduce the way to check this channel is to see if a country’s political
likelihoods of both product and process innovations. situation determines the effects of firm-level capabilities
Firms in SSA countries appeared to have significantly on innovation. Accordingly, hypothesis 2a was tested by
higher probabilities to innovate than firms in the MENA interacting polhar (proxy for institution) with RDS
region. The respective probabilities in the former countries (proxy for innovation capability). Pertaining to this, the
were found to be 1.6 and 2.0 times higher than the later in estimated odds ratios appeared to be significantly
terms of product and process innovations. higher than 1 (1.102 in M3 and 1.129 in M5) confirming
Evidence from the ‘resource curse’ literature suggests the hypothesis. This corresponds to a positive and sig-
that high natural resource ownership does not necessarily nificant interaction between polhar and RDS suggesting
lead to poor economic outcomes. Likewise, the effects of that the negative effect of poor political situation on
natural resources can affect firm-level innovation though innovation is dampened in firms with higher innovative
indirectly through various institutions and actors in inno- capabilities. Given this, it was expected that the effect
vation systems which ultimately determine innovation would vary by country giving rise to a random slope
capabilities at both sector and firm-levels. On account of model (equation 2) which also constitutes one way of
this, the relationships between natural resource and firm- testing hypothesis 2b.
level innovation were expected to vary across countries The random slope models were estimated with and
depending on their respective capabilities and institutions. without interaction terms but only results with interactions
This called for estimating models with interaction are reported in Table 2 (M6 and M7). The likelihood ration
terms. Accordingly, random intercept models with inter- (LR) tests on the assumption that random intercept models
actions were estimated and the results are reported in are nested in their respective random intercept and random
Table 2, columns M3 and M5. The interaction between slope counterparts strongly supported hypothesis 2b. Cor-
political hardening (proxy for institutional quality) and responding to models without interaction terms, compar-
resource endowment (resd×polhar) was included to test ing M1 and M4 against their respective random slope
hypothesis (1b). The results showed that high political counterparts (not reported) produced LR test statistics of
hardening turned the effect of natural resource on inno- 23.45 and 14.45 respectively. Similarly, the LR tests on
vation from positive to negative, although apparently stat- the assumptions that M3 is nested in M6 and M5 is
istically insignificant. Other unknown reasons might have nested in M7 respectively generated the LR test statistics
African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development 11

of 48.81 and 56.75. All the test statistics were found to be Robustness check
significant at less than 1% level suggesting the superiority Use of different measures of resource endowment would
of random slope model and hence random variations in the generate different results. For instance, Daniele (2011)
effects of innovative efforts by country. found different results in the relationship between
Using the random slope estimation results, schematic natural resource and human development up on using
views of country-wise variations in the effects of innovative commodity export and sub-soil asset measures of
capability (in odds ratios) on product and process inno- natural resources. Specifically, the impact of metals
vations are presented respectively in the left and right and ore exports had negative effect on human develop-
panels of Figure 6. Countries in the uppermost parts of ment. On the other hand, the impact of sub-soil assets
the two panels are those with the highest outcomes while measure on human development appeared to be positive.
those at the bottom are those in which innovative efforts To deal with such variation, IMF’s resource wise-
have the least effect. Differences in the total effects are country grouping (cited in AfDB et al. 2016) was used
due to differences in the country specific random com- which, unlike the grouping based on countries’ sub-
ponents since the fixed effects are equal for all countries. soil assets estimates, brought Egypt and Ghana under
Given the effects are described in terms of odds ratios, the resource-rich group.
values below one (1) in all cases indicate the dominance Given the statistical superiority of the random slope
of negative random effects over the positive fixed effects. specifications, estimations for the robustness check were
The total effects of R&D on product innovation range also made accordingly and the results are presented in
between 0.25 (CAR) and 2.5 (Sudan). This means that Appendix Table A3. The overall estimates show simi-
R&D spending in CAR decreases the innovation propen- larities with the results in Table 2. Comparing results in
sities of firms rather than increasing it. In contrast, R&D column 2 and 3 of Table A3 against M6 and M7 in
spending by Sudanese firms increases the innovation pro- Table 2, almost all the estimates appear to be the same.
pensities of firms by about 2.5-fold. Similarly, conditions However, it is worth mentioning two important changes
in other countries such as South Sudan, Tunisia, Zambia, in the new estimates. First, unlike the corresponding esti-
Morocco, Lesotho, Swaziland and Djibouti also do not mate in M6, the negative interaction between institution
seem to reward innovation. Apart from these, the remain- and resource endowment (R_rich×polhar) in the second
ing countries have positive reward for innovation efforts column of Table A3 became statistically significant. This
but with different levels as can be seen from the figure. indicates that the negative effect of a poor political (insti-
Similar country-wise variations also exist in the effects tutional) situation on product innovation is stronger in
of firms’ innovative efforts on process innovation. The resource-rich than in resource-poor countries. This gives
right-hand panel of Figure 5.1 shows that firms in better support to hypothesis 1b. The second difference
Nigeria harvest the highest benefit out of their innovative relates to the effects of the variable generated by interact-
efforts while those in Swaziland benefit the least. With the ing dummies for resource-rich and SSA (R_rich×SSA) on
exception of the bottom seven, R&D spending increases process innovation. The odds ratio corresponding to the
firms’ innovation in the rest of the countries though to interaction has increased (1.097) from its earlier value
different extents. (0.854) which has yet remained insignificant.

Figure 6. The total effects of R&D on firm-level innovations by country.


12 Ahmad, Akouwerabou and Lakew

Conclusion and Recommendation the above capabilities which in turn create incentives for
This paper gives an alternative explanation to the ‘resource firms to undertake innovations. Besides, facilitating con-
curse’ thesis in African context from a microeconomic ditions that would stimulate firms’ innovative efforts
perspective. A distinct analytical framework and method- would be among the important measures to be taken at
ology were applied to accommodate possible interactions the micro-level. The resulting increment in firm-level
at the micro-, meso- and macro-levels. The main objective innovation will definitely lead to both sectoral and aggre-
was to examine if the innovativeness of firms operating in gate productivity. Therefore, there is high potential for
non-resource sectors of Africa’s resource-rich economies resource-rich African countries to jump-start growth-
is hampered as a manifestation of ‘resource curse’. enhancing structural change if they can make effective
Given the possible hierarchal linkages, a multi-level mod- use of revenues obtained from natural resources.
elling strategy was applied to better capture the effects of
variables at different levels. The analysis was based on the Disclosure statement
World Bank’s enterprise surveys data collected from 30 No potential conflict of interest was reported by the
different African countries. Macro-level variables corre- authors.
sponding to these countries were extracted mainly from
Global Competitiveness Indicators database and African
Economic Outlook (AfDB et al. 2016).
Notes
The country-level descriptive analysis depicts that
1. Throughout this paper, resource refers to the stock of min-
resource-rich countries are less competitive than erals and fuel (also called hard commodities) a country is
resource-poor countries in terms of manufacturing value- endowed with.
added and export, innovation and technological capabili- 2. Throughout this paper, firms in the non-resource sectors or
ties. Similarly, countries in the MENA region have just firms are referred to as enterprises engaged in manufac-
better capabilities than their SSA counterparts in these turing and service activities only.
3. Innovative efforts or capabilities are represented by R&D
respects. The micro data, however, shows that the pro- spending of firms as this helps identify, acquire and adapt
portions of firms in the MENA countries are relatively new technologies (Lall 2003).
lower than that of SSA countries. The econometric 4. Composite measures of institution and innovation were
results indicate that firm’s age, training and R&D are the taken from WEF (2017) with the scores ranging from 1 to
most important firm-level characteristics in determining 7 with the high values representing better performances.
the likelihoods of both product and process innovation.
The hypothesized negative effect of a country’s high References
resource endowment on firm-level innovation was AfDB, OECD and UNDP. 2016. African Economic Outlook
unfounded. High political hardening appeared to have 2016: Sustainable Cities and Structural Transformation.
Paris: OECD Publications.
strong negative effect on innovation. Besides, there Asche, H., P. Neuerburg, and M. Menegatti. 2012. “Economic
seems to be weak evidence supporting the expectation Diversification Strategies: A Key Driver in Africa’s New
that resource abundance reduces innovation in countries Industrial Revolution.” Working paper 02/2012. Vienna:
with poor political orders. However, the effect of political UNIDO.
hardening was found to be lower among firms with better Ayelazuno, Jasper. 2014. “Oil Wealth and the Well-being of the
Subaltern Classes in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Critical Analysis
innovative capabilities. of the Resource Curse in Ghana.” Resources Policy 40:
The most interesting fining is with regards to the 66–73.
differential impacts of resource intensity on the innovation Barma, N. H., K. Kaiser, T. M. Le, and L. Vinuela. 2012. Rents to
of firms in non-resource sectors of countries in SSA and Riches? The Political Economy of Natural Resource–led
MENA. Firms in a resource-rich MENA country are Development. Washington DC: World Bank.
Bates, R. B. 2008. “Political Conflict and State Failure.” In The
more likely to undertake product innovation than firms Political Economy of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960–
in a resource-rich SSA country. In addition to this, the 2000, edited by J. Ndulu, A. O’Connell, H. Bates, P.
effects of firms’ innovative efforts on innovation (both Collier, and C. Soludo, Vol. 1, 249–290. Cambridge:
product and process) were found to vary widely with Cambridge University Press.
countries. However, the paper could not explain why the Brunnschweiler, C. N. 2008. “Cursing the Blessings? Natural
Resource Abundance, Institutions, and Economic Growth.”
outcomes of innovative efforts are high in some countries World Development 36 (3): 399–419.
while they appeared to be low in some others. This calls Bulte, E. H., R. Damania, and R. T. Deacon. 2005. “Resource
for country specific in-depth researches as the way Intensity, Institutions, and Development.” World
forward. Nevertheless, apart from filling the knowledge Development 33 (7): 1029–1044.
gaps, this study made a theoretical contribution that Collier, P., and A. O’Connell. 2008. “Opportunities and
Choices.” In The Political Economy of Economic Growth
would help explain the ‘resource curse’ thesis from micro- in Africa, 1960–2000, edited by J. Ndulu, A. O’Connell,
economic perspective. H. Bates, P. Collier, and C. Soludo, vol. 1, 76–135.
Based on this, resource-rich African countries would Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
be able to overcome the likelihood of facing the Daniele, V.2011. “Natural Resources and the ‘Quality’ of
‘resource-curse’ through protecting and building political Economic Development.” The Journal of Development
Studies 47 (4): 545–573.
systems that would help develop effective institutional Duruigbo, E. 2014. “The World Bank, Multinational Oil
and technological capabilities. The key to achieve this is Corporations and the Resource Curse in Africa.” University
through making effective use of resource rents in building of Pennsylvania Journal of International Law 26 (1): 1–67.
African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development 13

Fosu, A. K. 2008. “Anti-growth Syndromes in Africa: A Olarinmoye, Omobolaji Ololade. 2008. “Politics Does Matter:
Synthesis of the Case Studies.” In The Political Economy The Nigerian State and Oil (Resource) Curse.” Africa
of Economic Growth in Africa, 1960–2000, edited by J. Development 33 (3): 21–34.
Ndulu, A. O’Connell, H. Bates, P. Collier, and C. Soludo, Oluwatobi, S., Efobi, U., Olurinola, I., and P. Alege. 2015.
vol. 1, 136–168. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. “Innovation in Africa: Why Institutions Matter.” South
Freeman, Christopher. 2011. “Technology, Inequality and African Journal of Economics 83 (3): 390–410. doi:10.
Economic Growth.” Innovation and Development 1 (1): 11–24. 1111/saje.12071
Gelman, A. 2006. “Multilevel (Hierarchical) Modelling: What It Oyelaran-Oyeyinka, B. and P. G. Sampath. 2007. “Innovation in
Can and Cannot Do.” Technometrics 48 (3): 432–435. African Development: Case Studies of Uganda, Tanzania
doi:10.1198/004017005000000661 and Kenya.” A World Bank Study.
Goedhuys, M. and M. Srholec. 2015. “Technological Page, J. 2005. “Strategies for Pro-Poor Growth: Pro-Poor, Pro-
Capabilities, Institutions and Firm Productivity: A Growth or Both?” Paper drawn from a speech delivered at
Multilevel Study.” The European Journal of Development the DPRU, University of Cape Town, TIPS and Cornell
Research 27: 122–139. University Conference, held in October 2004 in Cape
Goldstein, H. 2011. Multilevel Statistical Models. London: Town, RSA.
Arnold. Pinkovskiy, M., and X. Sala-i-Martin. 2010. “African Poverty Is
Isham, J., M. Woodcock, L. Pritchett, and G. Busby. 2005. “The Falling Much Faster Than You Think!” NBER Working
Varieties of Resource Experience: Natural Resource Export Paper No. 15775.
Structures and the Political Economy of Economic Robinson, J. A., R. Torvik, and T. Verdier. 2006. “Political
Growth.” The World Bank Economic Review 19 (2): 141–174. Foundations of the Resource Curse.” Journal of
Khan, M. H. 2010. “Political Settlements and the Governance of Development Economics 79 (2): 447–468.
Growth-Enhancing Institutions.” Research Paper Series on Rodrik, D., F. Subramanian, and F. Trebbi. 2004. “Institutions
Governance for Growth. London: School of Oriental and Rule: The Primacy of Institutions Over Geography and
African Studies, University of London. Available at: http:// Integration in Economic Development.” Journal of
eprints.soas.ac.uk/9968. Economic Growth 9: 131–165.
Khan, M. H., and S. Blankenburg. 2009. “The Political Economy Sachs, J. D., and A. M. Warner. 1997. “Sources of Slow Growth
of Industrial Policy in Asia and Latin America.” In Industrial in African Economies.” Journal of African Economies 6 (3):
Policy and Development, edited by Giovanni Dosi, Mario 335–376.
Cimoli and Joseph Stiglitz, 336–377. Oxford: Oxford Sachs, J. D., and A. M. Warner. 2001. “Natural Resources and
University Press. Economic Development: The Curse of Natural Resources.”
Lall, S. 2003. “Industrial Success and Failure in a Globalizing European Economic Review 45: 827–838.
World.” QEH Working Paper Series – QEHWPS102. Tebaldi, E., and B. Elmslie. 2013. “Does Institutional Quality
Loayza, N. V., A. M. Oviedo, and L. Serven. 2005. “The Impact Impact Innovation? Evidence from Cross-Country Patent
of Regulation on Growth and Informality – Cross-country Grant Data.” Applied Economics 45 (7): 887–900.
Evidence.” Policy Research Working Paper Series 3623. Torres, N., Ó. Afonso, and I. Soares. 2013. “A Survey of
The World Bank. Literature on the resource curse: Critical Analysis of the
Lundvall, B-Å. 2011. “Notes on Innovation Systems and Main Explanations, Empirical Tests and Resource
Economic Development.” Innovation and Development 1 Proxies.” CEF.UP Working Paper 2013-02.
(1): 25–38. UN (United Nations). 2016. Science, Technology and
Malerba, F. 2002. “Sectoral Systems of Innovation and Innovation for Sustainable Development in Asia and the
Production.” Research Policy 31: 247–264. Pacific: Policy Approaches for Least Developed
McMillan, M., and D. Rodrik. 2011. “Globalization, Structural Countries. Bangkok: United Nations.
Change, and Productivity Growth.” Paper prepared for a UNDP (United Nations Development Program). 2006. Meeting
joint ILO-WTO volume. the Challenge of the ‘Resource Curse’ International
Mehlum, H., K. Moene, and R. Torvik. 2006. “Institutions and Experiences in Managing the Risks and Realizing the
the Resource Curse.” The Economic Journal 116: 1–20. Opportunities of Non-Renewable Natural Resource
OECD (Organization for Economic Co-operation and Revenues. London: Overseas Development Institute.
Development). 2012. “Innovation for Development.” A WEF (World Economic Forum). 2017. The Africa
Booklet on the Discussion of the Issues and an Overview Competitiveness Report 2017: Addressing Africa’s
of Work of the OECD Directorate for Science, Technology Demographic Dividend. Geneva: World Economic
and Industry, May 2012. Forum.
14 Ahmad, Akouwerabou and Lakew

Appendixes

Table A1: Number of firms/observations by country and year.

Country Year No. of firms Country Year No. of firms


Nigeria 2014 2676 Tanzania 2013 & 2015 1237
Namibia 2014 580 Uganda 2013 762
S. Sudan 2014 738 Zambia 2013 720
Sudan 2014 662 Morocco 2013 407
Ghana 2013 720 Mali 2016 185
Ethiopia 2011 & 2015 1492 Senegal 2014 601
Burundi 2014 157 Lesotho 2016 150
Cameroon 2016 361 Togo 2016 150
DRC 2013 529 Egypt 2014 2897
Guinea 2016 150 Kenya 2013 781
Malawi 2014 523 Benin 2016 150
Mauritania 2014 150 CAR 2011 150
Niger 2017 151 Zimbabwe 2011 600
Rwanda 2011 241 Djibouti 2013 266
Swaziland 2016 150 Tunisia 2014 592
Total No. of firms 18,928

Table A2: Proportion of innovative firms by country.

Product innovation Process innovation


Kenya 0.68 Burundi 0.46 Rwanda 0.71 DRC 0.33
Uganda 0.64 DRC 0.42 Kenya 0.60 Mali 0.33
Namibia 0.64 Cameroon 0.41 Uganda 0.60 Sudan 0.33
Rwanda 0.61 Ethiopia 0.40 Namibia 0.59 Djibouti 0.30
Zimbabwe 0.59 Togo 0.37 Zimbabwe 0.56 Morocco 0.30
Sudan 0.55 Mali 0.36 Tanzania 0.53 Tunisia 0.25
Mauritania 0.55 Djibouti 0.35 Mauritania 0.52 South Sudan 0.24
Malawi 0.54 Niger 0.34 Ghana 0.51 Niger 0.18
Zambia 0.53 Morocco 0.31 CAR 0.51 Egypt 0.16
Tanzania 0.52 Guinea 0.31 Malawi 0.51 Togo 0.15
Ghana 0.51 Swaziland 0.28 Nigeria 0.50 Cameroon 0.15
Nigeria 0.50 Tunisia 0.27 Zambia 0.48 Benin 0.14
South Sudan 0.49 Benin 0.26 Burundi 0.41 Guinea 0.14
CAR 0.48 Egypt 0.20 Senegal 0.40 Swaziland 0.07
Senegal 0.48 Lesotho 0.05 Ethiopia 0.34 Lesotho 0.06
African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development 15

Table A3: Results of multilevel mixed effect logit to check robustness.

Product innovation Process innovation


OR [Std. Err.] OR [Std. Err.] OR [Std. Err.]
lnage 1.049** [0.025] 1.050** [0.025] 0.995[0.025]
frmsize 1.104***[0.018] 1.103***[0.018] 1.080***[0.018]
training 1.876***[0.079] 1.877***[0.079] 1.887***[0.081]
exptopm 1.009 [0.007] 1.009 [0.006] 1.036***[0.008]
export 1.046 [0.048] 1.045 [0.048] 1.07[0.051]
privated 1.102 [0.065] 1.102 [0.065] 0.943[0.058]
RDS 3.231***[0.335] 2.559***[0.300] 2.903***[0.301]
foreign 1.218** [0.096] 1.214** [0.095] 0.984[0.083]
buscity 1.084** [0.041] 1.083** [0.041] 1.110***[0.044]
R_rich 1.406* [0.258] 5.257***[2.602] 1.185[0.646]
polhar 0.907* [0.049] 0.973 [0.061] 0.917[0.064]
SSA 1.613* [0.413] 2.819***[0.848] 1.892*[0.642]
polharxRDS – 1.116***[0.039] 1.122***[0.034]
R_richxpolhar – 0.857* [0.068] 0.971[0.085]
R_richxSSA – 0.282***[0.127] 1.097[0.545]
Retail Service 0.879***[0.034] 0.879***[0.033] 0.641***[0.025]
other service 0.758***[0.060] 0.762***[0.060] 0.692***[0.060]
2013 1.088 [0.173] 1.157 [0.182] 0.472***[0.081]
2014 1.161 [0.282] 1.074 [0.237] 0.544**[0.129]
2015 0.919 [0.117] 1.007 [0.130] 0.615***[0.084]
2016 0.324***[0.086] 0.335***[0.082] 0.054***[0.015]
2017 0.478 [0.245] 0.454* [0.206] 0.071***[0.037]
_cons 0.261***[0.087] 0.147***[0.054] 0.538[0.221]
Random-effects Parameters Country: Unstructured
Estimate[Std. Err.] Estimate[Std. Err.] Estimate [Std. Err.]

sd(RDS) 0.455[0.083] 0.364[0.079] 0.29[0.069]


sd(_cons) 0.427[0.068] 0.356[0.061] 0.408[0.067]
corr(RDS,_cons) −0.123[0.331] 0.063[0.341] −0.241[0.294]
No. of obs. 16843 16843 16812
No. of groups 30 30 30
Wald test 598*** 688*** 977***
LR test vs. logistic reg: 337*** 179*** 215***
*, **, *** indicate significances at 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. Values in parentheses are standard.

You might also like