Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 17

Received: 10 February 2020 Revised: 5 November 2020 Accepted: 19 November 2020

DOI: 10.1002/csr.2098

RESEARCH ARTICLE

Giving too much and paying too little? The effect of corporate
social responsibility on corporate lobbying efficacy: Evidence
of tax aggressiveness

Woon Leong Lin

Faculty of Economics and Administration,


University of Malaya, kuala Lumpur, Malaysia Abstract
Though lobbying accounts for a significant proportion of corporate political expendi-
Correspondence
Lin Woon Leong, Faculty of Economics and ture, comprehensive research on its advantages is scarce. Further, research findings
Administration, University of Malaya, Kuala have been inconclusive in quantifying political lobbying expenditures' rate of return.
Lumpur, Malaysia.
Email: linwoonleong@gmail.com Using data from Fortune's America's Most Admired Companies (AMAC) with publicly
available financial statements for the period from 2008 to 2017, this study delved
into the tax benefits of lobbying using the dynamic panel system GMM and quantile
regression model. This study found strong evidence that corporate lobbying is associ-
ated with higher levels of tax aggressiveness. The results also show that firms that
spend more on lobbying in a given year pay lower effective tax rates. Additionally,
this study revealed that the reputational effects of corporate social responsibility lead
to the increased effectiveness of corporate lobbying expenditures. Thus, political lob-
bying affects tax enforcement, resulting in lower tax burdens for politically active
firms. These results are consistent with the conjecture that firms with high levels of
social responsibility and political lobbying are more tax aggressive. This study has
addressed the need to quantify the benefits of lobbying and corporate social respon-
sibility activities, especially in terms of lower tax payments and better financial
returns to shareholders while still meeting the needs of non-owner stakeholders.

KEYWORDS

corporate financial performance, corporate lobbying, dynamic panel quantile regression,


Fortune's America's Most admired company, system GMM

1 | I N T RO DU CT I O N empirical studies have shown that politically aligned firms are tax
aggressive as they enjoy low detection risk, high risk-taking tendency,
The last decade has seen the exponential growth of the lobbying less corporate pressure for transparency, lower political costs associ-
industry around the world. Popular press reports state that money ated with aggressive tax planning, and more information on future
does not just buy influence and political access but also affects buying changes in tax regulation and enforcement (Barrick & Brown, 2016;
outcomes (Richter, Samphantharak, & Timmons, 2009). Sorauf (1994) Chen, Dyreng, & Li, 2015; Faccio, 2016; Martinez, 2017). Neverthe-
observed that academic inquiry has rejected the argument that corpo- less, research on lobbying has neglected to investigate the issue of tax
rate campaign contributions yield organizational benefits. However, aggressiveness. Furthermore, there are limited systematic cross-
campaign contributions are not the only form of corporate political industry reports investigating whether individual organizations derive
money involved, as the amount of money spent for lobbying purposes any benefits from their lobbying activities. In this article, the
is substantially high (Kim & Zhang, 2016; Richter et al., 2009). Many researcher attempted to address this gap by determining (i) the effect

Corp Soc Responsib Environ Manag. 2020;1–17. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/csr © 2020 ERP Environment and John Wiley & Sons Ltd. 1
2 LIN

of corporate lobbying on tax aggressiveness and (ii) the effect of cor- about 85% of the period's special interest-related registered political
porate social responsibility (CSR) on lobbying efficacy. expenses. Though firms aim for different political benefits, all of them
Andreoni, Erard, and Feinstein (1988) adopted a policy viewpoint care about taxes, since lower taxes significantly increase net profits.
to state that the topic of corporate tax aggressiveness is not new but Therefore, firms consider tax issues as their topmost lobbying priority.
highly significant for all countries, given that it is related to the active Hired lobbyists believe that lobbying related to tax policies is the
avoidance of taxes. Tax aggressiveness was described by Bird and “World Series” of lobbying (The Hill, 2004). Brown, Drake, and
Davis-Nozemack (2018) as the various structures and transactions Wellman (2015) attributed cash effective tax rates (ETRs) to political
that potentially decrease tax responsibilities, contrary to the inten- access (i.e., number of candidates supported by political action com-
tions and policies of government legislations. Furthermore, Hanlon mittee [PAC] contributions) and influence (number of tax lobbying
and Heitzman (2010) regard tax avoidance as regular tax planning pol- reports filed) from the differential effects of lobbying and campaign
icies which include low-risk and legal strategies on one hand and tax- contributions. They further stated that campaign contributions signifi-
sheltering and tax-evading strategies on the other. Tax aggressiveness cantly influence policies via lobbying.
thus helps corporate organizations derive the benefits of corporate Second, numerous studies have determined the influence of lob-
citizenship without bearing any costs, since the latter are then trans- bying on tax aggressiveness, arguing that firms lobby to acquire or
ferred to different parties (Whait, Christ, Ortas, & Burritt, 2018). In maintain tax breaks, which further decreases tax rates. For instance,
fact, global corporate culture has assimilated the development of Richter et al. (2009) noted that firms that spend more on lobbying
aggressive managerial activities to decrease corporate taxes. In gen- activities in a specific year pay a lower ETR the following year. In their
eral, tax aggressiveness could offer several benefits, but may also report, Meade and Li (2015) found that firms that engage in aggres-
prove to be costly. sive lobbying rather than defensive lobbying show a negative relation-
In the US, tax avoidance is well known to federal lawmakers. A ship between future tax rates and tax lobbying expenses. Conversely,
report from the Institute of Taxation and Economic Policy (ITEP) dis- Drope and Hansen (2008) observed that firms that spend more on
covered that in 2018, 60 of America's biggest corporations circum- influencing general policies (especially tax-related policies) are not
vented federal income taxes for US$79 billion dollars of pre-tax likely to derive additional benefits from lower tax rates. Meanwhile,
income. Instead of paying US$16.4 billion in taxes at the 21% statu- according to Brown et al. (2015), campaign contributions increase the
tory corporate tax rate, these companies enjoyed a net corporate tax efficiency of lobbying in decreasing ETRs. Thus, the evidence suggests
rebate of US$4.3 billion. ITEP's report also indicated that the compa- mixed results on firms' ETR and lobbying activities.
nies that avoided income tax in 2018 were from multiple sectors in The third factor that motivated this study is the inconclusive
the US economy. Computer maker IBM made US$500 million and results presented by earlier studies due to the limitations of condi-
received a federal income tax rebate of US$342 million; retail giant tional mean regression models such as Ordinary Least Squares and
Amazon reported US$11 billion in income and claimed a federal Fixed Effects. This study determined that the effect of corporate lob-
income tax rebate of US$129 million; streaming service Netflix paid bying on tax aggressiveness requires further investigation. Thus, this
no federal income tax on US$856 million of income; beer maker study proposed a novel dynamic panel quantile regression model to
Molson Coors earned US$1.3 billion and received a federal income bridge the gap in the literature. Conditional mean regression models
tax rebate of US$22.9 million; and automobile maker General Motors provide estimates based on the average effect of the independent
reported a negative tax rate on US$4.3 billion of income. variable on the average firm. Alternatively, this study posit that the
This research was motivated by four factors. First, Figure 1 indi- estimation of dynamic panel models via quantile regression is pre-
cates that lobbying is a major business in the USA. In the 29-year ferred because of its two main advantages: (i) quantile results are
period between 1998 and 2018, registered lobbying expenses robust to outliers (Buchinsky, 1995) and (ii) quantile regression can
increased to US$3.46 billion from US$1.45 billion, accounting for describe the entire conditional distribution of the dependent variable
(see Koenker & Bassett, 1978; Koenker & Hallock, 2001).
Fourth, this study addressed the logical question, “What makes
4 16000
lobbying effective?” (Mathur & Singh, 2011). Hansen (2011)
3.5 14000
3 12000 suggested that the success of lobbyists is based on their ability to con-
2.5 10000 vey relevant information to their target audience. Their credibility
2 8000 plays a vital role in this transfer of information. When Wise (2007)
1.5 6000
interviewed various lobbyists, 22 of them stated that relationships are
1 4000
0.5 2000 important for effective lobbying. They further asserted that honesty,
0 0 ethics, and integrity are necessary to maintain positive relationships.
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018

Furthermore, lobbyists noted that sustained investments in access are


related to lower ETRs. Consequently, Lanis and Richardson (2012,
Total Lobbying Spending Total Lobbyists
2015) opined that corporate social responsibility (CSR) principles
F I G U R E 1 Aggregate lobbying Trends between 1998 and 2018 potentially affect tax aggressiveness. Indeed, researchers have
[Colour figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com] observed that CSR affects tax aggressiveness with regards to how
LIN 3

corporations account for and direct all their systems and processes to (Hadani, Bonardi, & Dahan, 2017). It has been actively practised and
benefit the overall society (Avi-Yonah, Clausing, & Durst, 2008; protected in the US under the Constitution's “freedom of speech”
Desai & Dharmapala, 2006). In this study, the researcher explored this law. Controlled by the Lobbying Disclosure Act of 1995, corporate
issue by considering CSR as a moderating factor that acts as a bound- lobbying is described as any information regarding the modification,
ary condition for the correlation between tax aggressiveness and cor- formulation, and adoption of legislation that is communicated by cli-
porate lobbying (Lanis & Richardson, 2012, 2015; Richardson, ents to members of the Congress, the President, congressional
Taylor, & Lanis, 2016). staffers, White House staff, and high-level employees of about
This study used a sample of 162 America's Most Admired Compa- 200 agencies (The Centre for Public Integrity). Corporate lobbying is
nies (AMAC) listed in the Fortune list between 2008 and 2017. This helpful as it provides the central government with important informa-
study examined how corporate lobbying (measured through total lob- tion from the different individuals and interest groups who are
bying expenses) relates to corporate tax aggressiveness (proxied by affected by existing and upcoming legislative activities (den Hond,
ETR). The results indicated a negative relationship between corporate Rehbein, de Bakker, & Lankveld, 2014; Lock & Seele, 2017). This
lobbying and firms' tax aggressiveness. Furthermore, CSR perfor- information helps governmental agencies make better and more
mance showed a negative moderating effect on the relationship informed decisions. However, interest groups can also use lobbying to
between corporate lobbying and tax aggressiveness. These results manipulate the policy formation process and its benefits in their favor
suggest that firms engaged in CSR activities also consider their tax (Chen, Dyreng, & Li, 2015). In fact, some groups who spend a lot of
evasion stance. This confirms the notion that CSR is a core activity money on lobbying include corporations involved in controversies,
used by corporations to support their tax positions. The quantile scandals, and lawsuits like WorldCom, Enron, Phillip Morris, and
regression estimates were similar to earlier studies which showed that Halliburton. Such corporations may engage in corporate lobbying for
the effect of corporate lobbying is stronger for firms with a higher various reasons like to manage firm perspectives, to influence the
ETR, implying that profitable Fortune AMACs have manipulated the competitive environment, to increase governmental sales, to avoid
tax system to avoid paying tax on billions of dollars in profits. taxes, and because they belong to regulated industries (Aggarwal,
This study contributes to the literature in three ways. First, it pre- Meschke, & Wang, 2012; Hillman, Keim, & Schuler, 2004).
sents empirical evidence that politically lobbied organizations have a
higher likelihood of engaging in tax aggressiveness. Second, it used a
comprehensive measurement of CSR activities to reveal CSR's moder- 2.2 | Corporate lobbying and tax aggressiveness
ating effect on the corporate lobbying–tax aggressiveness link. The
negative relationship between these factors is consistent with the fact The literature on the political economy shows that corporate lobbying
that politically lobbied corporations with high CSR performance are is a valuable resource to individual firms (e.g., Faccio, Masulis, &
more likely to participate in corporate tax aggressiveness. Third, previ- Mcconnell, 2006; Fisman, 2001; Goldman, Rocholl, & So, 2009; Kim &
ous studies generally used the traditional conditional mean regression Zhang, 2016). Some recent studies have highlighted the myriad ways
method, which estimates the linear relationship between the depen- in which corporate lobbying adds value, such as through better alloca-
dent and exogenous variables. This technique prevents analysis of a tion of governmental contracts, preferential access to bank finances,
case wherein the regression parameters are heterogeneously distrib- and government capital investments (Chen, Dyreng, & Li, 2015;
uted among the dependent variables. To overcome this limitation, this Claessens, Feijen, & Laeven, 2008; Duchin & Sosyura, 2012; Unsal,
study used a novel statistical method, that is, quantile regression Hassan, & Zirek, 2016). Other reports contradict these findings,
(Koenker & Bassett, 1978), which describes the effect of exogenous claiming that corporate political activity is ineffective or even harmful
variables and assesses the distribution of different variables across to financial and political outcomes (Aggarwal et al., 2012;
the quantiles of liquidity creation. This presented a clear picture of the Ansolabehere, de Figueiredo, & Snyder, 2003). Overall, extant
relationship between tax aggressiveness and corporate lobbying. research has described the effect of lobbying expenses in general
This paper is organized as follows: Section 2 reviews the related terms rather than on a particular aspect of tax legislation. Although
theories and hypotheses; Section 3 describes the research design; taxes are a prevalent issue addressed by lobbyists, few researchers
Section 4 reports and analyzes the empirical results; and Section 5 have investigated the outcomes of tax lobbying.
presents the study's conclusions. Alexander, Scholz, and Mazza (2009a) mentioned that it is diffi-
cult to determine the returns from lobbying expenses and to link lob-
bying expenses to specific legislative policies. Consequently, limited
2 | LITERATURE REVIEW AND relevant results have been established in earlier studies. To address
HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT these issues, this study investigated lobbying in terms of a specific
activity. The American Jobs Creation Act of 2004 was established to
2.1 | Corporate lobbying offer tax saving schemes to American organizations that repatriate
their incomes from foreign subsidiaries. It was noted that the corpora-
Many corporations engage in political activities to influence legislators tions that lobbied for this legislation received tax savings amounting
at different governmental levels; this is known as corporate lobbying to US$62.5 billion on US$208 billion of repatriated foreign income.
4 LIN

They had spent US$282.7 million for lobbying purposes, suggesting a their lobbying activities (den Hond et al., 2014). Many companies use
return of 22%. Richter et al. (2009) conducted one of the first studies non-marketing CSR strategies to signify to their shareholders that
on the relationship between lobbying expenses and corporations' they donate a portion of their profits to a specific social cause
ETRs. They found that an increase in lobbying expenditure signifi- (e.g., environmental protection, cancer research, etc.) (Wickert, 2016).
cantly decreases firms' ETR, supporting the notion that corporations Thus, the customer develops a positive feeling for CSR-practising
can successfully lobby for laws and regulations that help them firms, leading to a meaningful relationship between the customer and
decrease their tax costs. Similar results were revealed by Hill, Kubick, the corporation. Hence, customers exhibit loyalty towards the com-
Brandon Lockhart, and Wan (2013), who used book ETRs and differ- pany and ignore any negative information regarding the company and
ences in discretionary permanent book taxes to measure the avoid- its operations.
ance of tax payments, which represented firms' engagement in tax With regards to lobbying, socially responsible organizations are
lobbying. more favored by policymakers compared to those that are not. Thus,
Corporate lobbying can potentially decrease the political costs of policymakers recognize these corporations and are likely to allow their
being tax aggressive. Mills, Nutter, and Schwab (2013) stated that US lobbying positions. However, limited research exists on CSR and cor-
companies that depend more on government contracts pay more porate lobbying parameters. Regarding them as non-market strategies
taxes; as such, they suffer the cost of losing contract work when they used to increase firm value, Richter (2011) investigated whether CSR
are tax aggressive. However, Goldman, Rocholl, and So (2013) argued and lobbying complement or substitute one another. The study noted
that corporate lobbying can improve the value of US firms' procure- that firms at lower and higher ends of the CSR spectrum are more
ment contracts, such that connected firms worry less about losing likely to engage in lobbying activities than firms in the middle. Rich-
government contracts. Hence, politically connected firms can afford ter (2011) further observed a significant positive coefficient for the
more aggressive tax planning because their connections alleviate the interaction between lobbying and CSR, confirming a complementary
political cost concerns of being tax aggressive. Based on this discus- relationship. However, in the within-firms (using firm fixed effects), a
sion, this study proposed the following hypothesis: negative coefficient was noted between lobbying and CSR, whereby
their existing positive relationship was attributed to the unmeasured
Hypothesis 1. (H1): Political lobbying firms exhibit a higher degree of “good management” characteristics of the firms that engaged in
tax aggressiveness compared to non-lobbying firms. higher lobbying or CSR activities. This indicates that these companies
have to pay a price. Based on this relationship and the existence of
tax-related lobbying, this study investigated the effect of the interac-
2.3 | Corporate social responsibility tion between CSR and lobbying activities on beneficial outcomes
proxied by ETR. Earlier studies by Alexander, Scholz, and
CSR has various rationales, one of which is “any organization needs to Mazza (2009b), Farber, Johnson, and Petroni (2007), and Richter
consider the effect of its operations on the environment and society, et al. (2009) showed that higher lobbying increases tax benefits. Posit-
thereby maximizing benefits and minimizing issues” (UK Government, ing that this relationship may be improved by social responsibility, this
2004). It is defined as a constant commitment made by businesses to study proposed the following hypothesis.
behave ethically and to contribute to economic development while also
improving the life quality of workers, their families, the local commu- Hypothesis H2. (H2): CSR moderates the relationship between cor-
nity, and the general society (Holme & Watts, 2000). CSR is regarded as porate lobbying expenses by a firm and tax aggressiveness.
an important factor that is responsible for the survival and success of Highly sociable responsible firms were more effective at
any firm. Though corporations engage in CSR activities for many rea- engaging in lobbying activities for reducing their effective tax
sons, Watts and Zimmerman (1990) applied the agency theory to the rates than the less socially responsible firms.
field of accounting and stated that CSR is an illegitimate attempt by
managers to tax shareholders without their consent and evade account-
ability for their activities. This perspective could explain why scarcely 3 | DA T A A N D M E T H O D O L O G Y
any accounting studies have determined the effect of firms' CSR activi-
ties on corporate tax policies despite the agency theory being highly rel- 3.1 | Conditional mean regression—System GMM
evant in accounting research (Avi-Yonah et al., 2008; Desai &
Dharmapala, 2006). This study employed the System Generalized Method of Moments
(System GMM) panel estimator, initially described by Holtz-Eakin,
Newey, and Rosen (1988) and extended by other researchers
2.4 | The role of CSR in corporate lobbying and tax (Arellano & Bond, 1991; Blundell & Bond, 1998), for two reasons.
aggressiveness First, firm-related effects had to be controlled, which would have
been impossible using organization-specific dummies due to the
Socially-responsible firms also possess political capital, which dynamic structure of different formulated regressions. Second, this
increases their ability to contact and persuade policymakers through method controlled for simultaneity biases arising from the probable
LIN 5

endogenous nature of several explanatory variables. The two-step outcome variable. As corporate lobbying could affect tax aggressive-
system GMM (Windmeijer, 2005) was used to estimate the substitut- ness and its components differently based on its distribution, the
ability and complementarity effects of corporate lobbying and ETRs. above-mentioned conditional mean regression technique could
In addition, this technique determined the moderating effect of CSR obscure substantial parameter heterogeneity in the relationship
on the relationship between corporate lobbying and ETR. The System between corporate lobbying and tax aggressiveness. This study there-
GMM estimator was also utilized to determine the effect of corporate fore used the quantile regression technique to resolve this problem
lobbying on ETR as well as to develop specific dynamic dimensions (Koenker & Hallock, 2001). Panel quantile regressions present con-
from the dataset. Based on earlier models (Brown, 2016; Waisman, vincing values, especially with regards to misspecification errors aris-
Ye, & Zhu, 2015), this study formulated the empirical relationship ing from outliers and non-normality (Koenker & Hallock, 2001).
between firms' corporate lobbying and ETR as follows: Dynamic panel quantile regression is a technique that projects
conditional quantile functions for dependent variables. It assesses
ð ð
Tax Aggressiveness ðETRÞ = Corporate Lobbying + Control μi + εit parameters by decreasing the sum of all weighted absolute values of
residuals using weighted least squares regression. Some earlier studies
ð1Þ
(e.g.,Koenker & Bassett, 1978; Koenker & Hallock, 2001) have dis-
cussed the different quantile regression processes that can be used. In
Equation (1) was also written as: comparison to conditional mean regression, the quantile regression
technique can manifest the impact of various independent variables
ETRit = α + β1 ETRit−1 + β2 Lobbyit + β3 Controlit + μi + εit ð2Þ on the position, scale, and shape of the distribution of a dependent
variable. It also indicates the distribution's characteristics (Koenker &
where lobby indicates lobbying-related expenses; ETR stands for Bassett, 1978; Koenker & Hallock, 2001). In this analysis, this study
effective tax rate; εit is the disturbance or residual term; μi denotes ascertained the set of estimators and assigned one for each desirable
the unobserved firm-specific effect term; t represents the index's quantile τ (e.g., 0.10, 0.20, 0.30, 0.40, 0.50, 0.60, 0.70, 0.80, and 0.90).
years, and i signifies the index's firms. Next, this study typified the conditional distribution of all outcome
All the above variables are related to terms used in different cor- variables by displaying the effect of each input variable on the out-
porate political surveys, such as revenue, free cash ratios, total assets come at every quantile value (Koenker, 2004). This study achieved
(wherein a natural logarithmic method is applied to translate the ele- this using the panel quantile regression estimates in STATA 15.
ments), advertisement intensities, and corporate leverage. To test the The panel quantile regression technique proposed by Koenker and
hypothesis on the moderating effect of CSR between lobbying and Bassett (1978) guided our investigation of the impact of corporate lob-
ETR, this study extended Equation 2 by incorporating the interaction bying on the tax aggressiveness of AMACs. This method allowed us to
between CSR and Lobby. All model specifications used the interaction analyze the sensitivity of corporate lobbying results based on the inten-
term (Lobby*CSR) as follows: sity levels of tax aggressiveness. The major advantages of using the
quantile regression technique are: (i) it does not exhibit sensitivity
ETRit = α + β1 ETRt− 1 + β2 Lobbyit + β3 CSRit + β4 ðLobby*CSRÞit + β5 Controlit + μi + εit towards outliers (Coad & Rao, 2008); (ii) it fits data with skewed distri-
ð3Þ butions (Kottas & Krnjajic, 2009); and (iii) it captures non-monotonous
and non-even effects of independent variables on dependent variables
The consistency of the GMM estimators was evaluated with three (Behr, 2010). However, the greatest advantage of using the quantile
specification tests, that is, the Hansen test of over-identifying restrictions; regression method in this study is that it unearthed the variances in tax
the difference-in-Hansen test for multiple instruments; and the autocorre- aggressiveness intensity for different quantiles, thus comprehensively
lation test for disturbances (Arellano & Bond, 1991). In the Hansen test, a depicting variable interactions. It should also be noted that the panel
failed rejection of the null hypothesis indicates the instruments' validity quantile regression technique thoroughly delineates the macro aspects
and the accuracy of model specifications. In the difference-in-Hansen that could explain tax aggressiveness policies, thereby improving on
test, failure to reject the hypothesis reflects the presence of multiple simple conditional mean regression.
instruments or a flaw in the instruments. In the autocorrelation test, the Therefore, this study used quantile analysis via the Quantile
absence of the second autocorrelation must not be rejected (AR2). Regression Dynamic Panel Data Instrumental Variable (QRPIV) model,
which included individual fixed effects. This technique effectively
addressed the concerns of this study with regards to the different tax
3.2 | Dynamic panel quantile regression aggressiveness policies and the duration of corporate lobbying activi-
ties. The panel quantile regression technique determined heteroge-
The Ordinary Least Squares (OLS), Fixed Effect, and System GMM neous effects and unobserved cross-firm heterogeneity
techniques use the conditional mean regression approach, which is (Chernozhukov & Hansen, 2008) in addition to assessing the different
based on the assumption that the mean effect of corporate lobbying types of interactions and asymmetry in co-movement forms.
on tax aggressiveness is stable and is estimated by decreasing the The traditional dynamic model used for panel data with individual
mean square error to determine the conditional average of the fixed effects was:
6 LIN

ETRit = ηi + αETRit−1 X0it βτ + μit ð5Þ mandatory; hence, there were differences in the sample number per
year as the estimation technique in this study prioritized available
wherein i = 1……n are the different firms used in the sample; βτ is a k observations. Furthermore, to construct the database's dimensional
x 1 vector of the regression parameters related to the τth percentile; dynamics by adding the lagged values of the dependent variable, this
ETRit is the dependent variable; X'i is a vector of independent vari- study included corporations that had been on the list for at least
ables; and μit is the error term used in the model. Based on the previ- seven consecutive years. Firms that did not offer complete informa-
ous discussion of the study's hypotheses, this study proposed a tion were excluded from the study. This helped us understand the
quantile regression model in Equation (6) as follows: interaction effect of two different non-market strategies, that is, com-
plementing or substituting, on ETRs. Ultimately, the dataset used in
Qτ τ j ETRit− 1 , X0it = ηi ðτÞ + αðτÞyETRit −1 + X0 it βðτÞ ð6Þ this study comprised 162 firms in cross-section and 1129 firm-year
observations for the period between 2008 and 2017. To develop this
Here, Qτ (ETRitjXit) represents the τth quantile regression function model, three published data sources were combined, namely (i) public
of the ETR. After preliminary examination, this study presented the records related to the lobbying expenses of the firms; (ii) firms'
projections of quantile functions at the median for size distribution accounting statements; and (iii) a complete and accessible CSR
(50th percentile) and at interquartile regressions (10th and 90th per- database.
centile) after projecting nine quantile regression functions: 0.01, 0.20,
0.30, 0.40, 0.50, 0.60, 0.70, 0.80, and 0.90. In the equation, η is
believed to signify the cause of “unobserved heterogeneity”, which 3.4 | Measurement of variables
was not described for other covariates. Thus, it would have been diffi-
cult to approximate τ–dependent distributional firm effects. In view of 3.4.1 | Tax aggressiveness—Effective tax rates
this, this study limited the estimation of firm-specific effects to be
independent of τ for all the quantiles. This constraint was used to esti- This study adopted the ETR measure described by Gupta and
mate the model for different quantiles. Newberry (1997). Though a majority of accounting-related studies
Though Koenker (2004) described a quantile regression fixed have employed various measures of ETRs based on financial state-
effects model for panel data, such a model is biased with regards to ment data, Gupta and Newberry's (1997) measure remains the most
the presence of lagged dependents as regressors. Alternatively, some favored. Plesko (2003) stated that despite none of the ETR measures
researchers (e.g., Anderson & Hsiao, 1982; Arellano & Bond, 1991) based on financial statements being correlated to confidential IRS tax
have suggested linear regression using the Instrumental Variables payments, the Gupta-Newberry measurement performed better than
(IV) approach to generate stable estimators for dynamic panel data the other measures, especially in multivariate settings. Gupta and
models that are independent of initial conditions. These estimators Newberry (1997) used the Thomson Reuter DataStream to estimate
are lagged (or lagged differences of) regressors related to the regres- the ETR as follows:
sor but not correlated with error terms. As such, similar to the method
proposed by Chernozhukov and Hansen (2008), bias in the dynamic Effective Tax Rate
panel quantile regression was resolved using IVs. With this approach, Income Taxes Total− Deferred Taxes
=
PreTax Income− Equity in Earnings + Special Items + Interest Expense
lags (or differences of lags) for the exogenous variable (X) affect the
lagged term (y), but are independent of μit and can be used as instru-
ment (w) to estimate α and β using the QRPIV technique Since values for the factors of “Equity in Earnings”, “Deferred
(Galvao, 2011). Thus, the estimators were defined as follows: Taxes”, “Special Items”, and “Interest Expenses” were not mentioned
in the Thomson Reuter DataStream, this study estimated the ETR
     
ƞ^ðαj τ , β^ αj , τ , γ αj , τ Þ value after assuming the values of these factors as zero.
X
K X
N X
T  
0
= min υK ρτ × ðETRIT −ƞ1 −αðτK ÞETRit −1 − XIT β τk Þ− wit0 γ ðτk Þ
ƞ, β, γ
k=1 i=1 j=1

ð7Þ 3.4.2 | Corporate lobbying

wherein ρτ is a consequence function, νk is the weight that controls Since 1998, the Centre for Responsive Politics (CRP) has compiled all
the relative effect of the K quantiles {τi τk…}, and ηi is the fixed effect. registered lobbying expenses under public records. Similar to other
studies that have used CRP data (e.g., Ansolabehere et al., 2003; de
Figueiredo & Richter, 2014), this study collected records for lobbying
3.3 | Sample description expenses and PACs from the CRP's published data on the US Senate
website, as it presents organizational expenses for lobbying opera-
This study tested its predictions using a sample population of 162 pub- tions at three-month intervals since 1999. According to the 1995 Lob-
licly trading Fortune AMACs for the period between 2008 and 2017. bying Disclosure Act, every firm desiring to affect US governmental
In terms of sample selection, a balanced panel was not seen as strategies or Federal programs must be registered and file bi-annual
LIN 7

reports on their lobbying activities and expenses at least 30 days necessary to analyze a firm's CSR. Third, earlier studies
before the end of every six months. Notably, CRP data does not just (e.g., Fombrun & Shanley, 1990; Fryxell & Wang, 1994; Gatzert, 2015;
exclude firms' legal expenses but also bribes and other illegal methods Lin, Ho, Ng, & Lee, 2019; Lin, Law, Ho, & Sambasivan, 2019; McGuire,
used to garner political influence. It is also biased against any indica- Sundgren, & Schneeweis, 1988) have used multiple tools to evaluate
tion of a systematic relationship between firms' political activities and firms' CSR, which helped us relate their findings to a wider range of
their achievement of policy outcomes. literature.
This study noted the names of the firms mentioned in the CRP
data and assigned them unique ticker symbols. Since the CRP data
does not display any company identifiers, this study had to physically 3.4.4 | Control variables
match it with the DataStream data to verify the firms' names. Thereaf-
ter, this study merged the CRP and Thomson Reuter DataStream The main control factors used in this study considered the impact of
datasets as per the firms' tickers. In the merged dataset, this study corporate lobbying on the dependent parameter. At the organizational
combined two novel variables that were featured in the analysis, level, this study controlled for several factors that may influence cor-
whereby Lobbyit was defined as the natural logarithm of all lobbying porate productivity, such as firm sales revenue, fixed assets, corporate
expenses (USD) of Firm i for year t. Next, this study estimated the log influence, free cash flow, and advertising expenses. Firm size was
values of lobbying expenses to normalize the data. The major limita- measured using overall sales while fixed assets were reflected in the
tion of this method is that it made it impossible to determine the asset sum of balance sheets. Dang, Frank) Li, and Yang (2018) and
amount spent by firms on specific bills. To ensure that the CRP and Zimmerman (1983) stated that various proxies for firm size reflect the
financial statements were described for the same period, this study differing viewpoints on firm size and have shown dissimilar results
discarded any firm that showed a non-calendar financial year-end. with regards to corporate investments. For example, fixed assets are a
Thus, based on the investigation of all dependent parameters, the measure of the total assets of a firm, while total sales are related to
number of firms amounted to 1129. the product market and are not progressive. The selection of mea-
sures for firm size is thus an empirical and hypothetical issue. If this
study had aimed to control for firm size in the stock market, this study
3.4.3 | Corporate social responsibility would have used market capitalization. Conversely, to control for firm
size in the product market, this study would have used total sales.
This study used Fortune's annual corporate reputation index as CSR However, this study used total assets as this study referred to firm
index, which is based on research carried out among some 10,000 size as the total assets used by a firm to generate returns. This study
senior executives in the USA who are asked to rate the ten largest computed free cash flow (to equity) as net income accounting for
companies in their industry. The CSR index is characterized by the depreciation, net debt concerns, preferred payments, and capital
Fortune 1000 ranking of large corporations from 70 different indus- expenses as well as their effects on non-cash working assets. This
tries. This ranking has been carried out every Fall since 1982, and the study described corporate influence using the ratio of a firm's current
summarized results are announced every January in the magazine's assets to its current liabilities. Finally, advertising expenses and R&D
“America's Most Admired Companies”1 edition. The organizations expenditures were also included as controls, as they reflect tax
ranked by the magazine include the largest firms in 25 trade groups aggressiveness and corporate lobbying activities (Lev, Petrovits, &
and the “Top 10” companies in every group. More than 8000 external Radhakrishnan, 2010).
industry experts and administrators rate firms in their field based on
nine attributes, that is, proper use of assets, financial health, long-term
investment value, product and service quality, organizational quality, 4 | RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
innovation, global competitiveness, ability to attract, train, and retain
employees, and fulfillment of environmental and societal obligations. 4.1 | Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix
Based on firms' annual data, Fortune also scores the CSR of every firm
against its major competitors on a scale ranging from zero (poor) to Table 1 presents the summary of the descriptive statistics for the
10 (excellent). Therefore, this study acquired data on firms' CSR per- AMACs. The results indicated that corporate lobbying fluctuated
formance from Fortune magazine's reviews over the last 11 years. between 0.1310 and 12.4798 over the studied period. Furthermore,
This study selected this particular review for several reasons. First, it CSR varied from 5.210 to 9.800 with a median of 7.789, indicating
presents comparable data of numerous organizations across 32 coun- that in many cases, CSR scores were close to the average sample
tries over a long period of time. While firms have been added and value. Standard deviations of 1.8334 and 0.702 were noted for corpo-
deleted from the dataset due to performance changes and mergers, rate lobbying and CSR, respectively, showing that CSR values were
the overall number has remained relatively stable. Second, the quality clustered near the mean value while corporate lobbying values were
of the respondents consistently reflects the various organizations widespread. The mean effective tax value was 0.1278 with a standard
under review, as the respondents only rate the organizations they are deviation of 0.1452, suggesting widely distributed data. The mean
familiar with. They thus have direct access to the industry data firm size, which was measured using the logarithm of total assets, was
8 LIN

TABLE 1 Description summary


Variable Obs Mean Std. dev. Min Max
ETR 1129 0.1278 0.1452 0.4566 1.68013
Log lobbying 1119 8.3706 1.8334 0.1310 12.4798
CSR 1129 7.789 0.702 5.210 9.800
Free cash flow 1119 −0.0962 2.9798 −97.000 7.2941
R&D intensity 1129 0.1253 0.1152 −2.2000 0.5774
Advertising intensity 1129 0.1087 0.0962 0 0.5536
Log Total assets 1129 8.4112 1.8942 2.7801 13.0843
Leverage 1129 1.2382 4.6004 −0.6341 90.4000

Notes: All statistics are based on original data values.

TABLE 2 Correlation matrix

Log Free R&D Advertising Log Total


ETR lobby CSR cash flow intensity intensity assets Leverage
ETR 1
Log lobby −0.2171 1
(0.0000)
CSR −0.1151 0.0577 1
(0.0001) (0.0535)
Free cash flow 0.0370 0.1578 0.0022 1
(0.2158) (0.0000) (0.9410)
R&D intensity 0.0516 0.0582 0.0403 0.0325 1
(0.0833) (0.0516) (0.1757) (0.2772)
Advertising 0.7027 −0.3295 −0.0459 0.0494 0.0342 1
intensity (0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0984) (0.5984) (0.2511)
Log Total assets −0.3408 0.5942 0.0755 −0.4700 −0.0345 −0.4674 1
(0.0000) (0.0000) (0.0112) (0.1160) (0.2461) (0.0000)
Leverage 0.0257 0.0158 0.0147 0.0108 −0.0028 0.134 0.0048 1
(0.3891) (0.5967) (0.6222) (0.7170) (0.9240) (0.6522) (0.8707)

Notes: All statistics are based on original data values. The p-values are reported in parentheses.

8.4112, while the mean R&D intensity value was 0.1253. On average, 4.2 | Conditional mean regression model—
a sample firm reported a debt-to-asset ratio of 1.2382 and a free cash System GMM
flow ratio of −0.0962.
This study used the Pearson correlation matrix to quantify the To investigate the effect of lobbying on tax aggressiveness, this study
strength and direction of the linear correlations between the indepen- constructed two models to test Hypotheses 1 and 2. Table 3 presents
dent and dependent variables. The correlation matrix is presented in the linear panel regression results on the effect of corporate lobbying
Table 2. The results confirmed that corporate lobbying is negatively expenses on tax aggressiveness. The models for Specifications (1) to
related to the parameters of CSR at −0.0577 (5% significance level) (5) showed a linear correlation between tax aggressiveness (based on
and tax aggressiveness at −0.2171 (1% significance level). Further- the ETR) and corporate lobbying for the fixed effects and static
more, CSR showed a negative correlation with tax aggressiveness at pooled OLS estimates, as well as the dynamic fixed effects, dynamic
−0.1151 (1% significant level). The parameters in this study further pooled OLS, and System GMM estimates. First, the significant positive
reported variance inflation factor (VIF) values that ranged between coefficient of the lagged dependent variables implied that the ETR
0.141 and 1.781. The tolerance mean value was 0.951, which indi- relies on its previous values. Second, the results indicated that regard-
cated that all the variables showed a comparatively low Pearson coef- less of the estimation method used, there is no substantial difference
ficient (<0.8). The results revealed that the multicollinearity issue was between an organization's control variables (i.e., advertising and firm
non-existent in our data (Gujarati & Porte, 2008). size) and tax aggressiveness in the various models in Table 3. R&D
LIN 9

TABLE 3 The impact of corporate lobbying on tax aggressiveness (N = 163, T = 2008–2017): conditional mean regression models

Static panel Dynamic panel

Model 1 pooled OLS Model 2 fixed effect Model 3 pooled OLS Model 4 fixed effects Model 5 system GMM
Variables ETR ETR ETR ETR ETR

ETRt-1 0.862*** 0.0779*** 0.648***


(0.0114) (0.0156) (0.0358)
Log lobbying 0.0117*** −0.00290 0.000319 −0.000893 −0.0224***
(0.00441) (0.00304) (0.00182) (0.00325) (0.00658)
CSR −0.00132*** 0.0000253 0.0000153 0.0000267 0.000105
(0.000339) (0.000091205) (0.000141) (0.000100) (0.000122)
Free cash flow −0.00131 0.000126 −0.000107 0.0000375 −0.000751***
(0.00116) (0.000263) (0.000451) (0.000265) (0.000214)
R&D intensity 61.75 10.81 67.10 2.165 2.829
(107.5) (19.33) (44.43) (20.34) (16.53)
Advertising intensity 1.022*** 1.019*** 0.210*** 1.003*** 1.033***
(0.0371) (0.0169) (0.0189) (0.0204) (0.0173)
Log Total assets −0.0115** −0.00444 −0.00147 −0.00553* −0.00134
(0.00446) (0.00305) (0.00184) (0.00329) (0.00702)
Leverage 0.000520 0.000143 0.000284 0.0000462 0.000221**
(0.000667) (0.000147) (0.000280) (0.000149) (0.000110)
Constant 0.0845*** 0.0779*** −0.0236** 0.0617*** −0.249***
(0.0254) (0.0140) (0.0105) (0.0157) (0.0440)

Observations 1119 1119 957 957 957


R-squared 0.503 0.807 0.928 0.786
Number of firms 163 162 162
Number of instruments 23
AR1 −1.42(0.156)
AR2 −2.07(0.488)
Hansen test 18.96(0.124)
Hansen different test 14.26(0.095)

Notes: The standard errors are reported in parentheses, except for the Hansen test, AR1, AR2, and Difference-in-Hansen test. ***, ** and * indicate
significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Time dummies were included in the model specification, but the results were not reported to save
space. System GMM model was estimated using Blundell and Bond's (1998) dynamic panel system GMM estimations and Roodman's (2009) Stata
xtabond2 command.

intensity does not affect the ETR; however, free cash flow and lever- corporate lobbying, since fixed effects and OLS values could lead to
age affect the ETR in Model 5, that is, the System GMM model. biased results (Blundell & Bond, 1998).
Conversely, corporate lobbying values were dependent on the In this study, this study tested H1 using the dynamic System
model used. This study stated that disregarding unobservable hetero- GMM. The results indicated that corporate lobbying significantly
geneity (shown in the pooled OLS model in Table 3) and the dynamic affects the ETR, thereby supporting H1. The results also showed that
nature of corporate lobbying and ETR (shown in the fixed effects in a linear correlation, corporate lobbying negatively affects ETR quan-
model in Table 3) would generate biases. As shown in Table 3, the tifiers. Similarly, the lagged ETR coefficients were positive and signifi-
OLS values displayed a positive relationship between ETR and corpo- cant, confirming that there was dynamism in the model. Similar to
rate lobbying; however, the fixed effects (in the dynamic and static earlier studies (e.g., Chen, Dyreng, & Li, 2015; Faccio, 2016; Hoopes,
models in Table 3) and dynamic pooled OLS values did not show any Mescall, & Pittman, 2012; Kim, Li, & Zhang, 2011; Kim &
such correlation. Therefore, one needs to take dynamics into consid- Zhang, 2016; Richter et al., 2009; Wilson, 2009), this study achieved
eration before investigating the correlation between ETR and the expected conclusion of a negative relationship and a dynamic
10 LIN

T A B L E 4 The impact of the interaction between corporate social responsibility and corporate lobbying on tax aggressiveness (N = 163,
T = 2008–2017): conditional mean regression models

Static panel Dynamic panel

Model 1 pooled OLS Model 2 fixed effects Model 3 pooled OLS Model 4 fixed effects Model 5 system GMM
Variables ETR ETR ETR ETR ETR

ETRt-1 0.862*** 0.0779*** 0.685***


(0.0114) (0.0156) (0.0443)
Log lobbying 0.00440 −0.00402 0.00201 −0.000495 −0.123**
(0.0108) (0.00371) (0.00440) (0.00417) (0.0486)
CSR −0.00242 −0.000199 0.000271 0.0000989 −0.0242***
(0.00152) (0.000435) (0.000622) (0.000483) (0.00753)
Log lobbying*CSR 0.000129 0.0000263 −0.0000301 −0.000845*** −0.00274***
(0.000174) (0.0000498) (0.0000713) (0.0000553) (0.000909)
Free cash flow −0.00126 0.000115 −0.000118 0.0000391 −0.000988**
(0.00117) (0.000264) (0.000452) (0.000265) (0.000449)
R&D intensity −61.95 −10.94 67.11 2.240 −14.01
(107.6) (19.34) (44.45) (20.36) (37.95)
Advertising intensity 1.024*** 1.020*** 0.210*** 1.003*** 1.058***
(0.0373) (0.0169) (0.0190) (0.0205) (0.0435)
Log Total assets −0.0112** −0.00454 0.00143 −0.00554* 0.00826
(0.00448) (0.00306) (0.00184) (0.00330) (0.0142)
Leverage 0.000510 0.000144 0.000285 4.58e-05 0.000359***
(0.000667) (0.000147) (0.000280) (0.000149) (0.000124)
Constant 0.143* 0.0882*** −0.0374 0.0585** 0.946***
(0.0834) (0.0240) (0.0344) (0.0263) (0.332)

Observations 1119 1119 957 957 957


R-squared 0.503 0.807 0.928 0.786
Number of firms 163 162 162
Number of instruments 23
AR1 −2.29(0.022)
AR2 0.72(0.672)
Hansen test 21.17(0.148)
Hansen different test 17.47(0.094)

Notes: The standard errors are reported in parentheses, except for the Hansen test, AR1, AR2, and Difference-in-Hansen test. ***, ** and * indicate
significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Time dummies were included in the model specification, but the results were not reported to save
space. System GMM model was estimated using Blundell and Bond's (1998) dynamic panel system GMM estimations and Roodman's (2009) Stata
xtabond2 command.

model. These findings argue that politically lobbying organizations are 4.3 | Conditional mean regression model:
more tax aggressive as lobbying decreases detection risk, offers more Interaction model
information for future changes on tax enforcement and regulation,
lowers capital market pressure for transparency, decreases the politi- As shown in Table 4, the interaction between CSR and corporate lob-
cal costs of aggressive tax planning, and displays high risk-taking ten- bying and its consequent effect on the ETR is presented under Model
dencies. Therefore, our findings affirm that a firm can receive tax 5. To test H2, this study referred to Model 5 as it was a specified
benefits through the political process. model which depicts the effects of every variable. H2 predicted that
LIN 11

ETR-CSR-LOBBYING different ETR distributions. This study set the panel dynamic quantile
0
regression models as discussed in Section 3.2, the results of which are
-0.5
presented in Table 5. This study conducted Wald-type tests for the vec-
-1
tor β (τk) of equality of slope coefficients for all quantiles (Galvao, 2011).
-1.5
In a quantile regression, the null hypothesis that all parameters at the
ETR

-1.80
-2
-2.25 low quantile (τ = 0.1) are similar to those at the upper quantile (τ = 0.90)
-2.5 -2.56
-2.71 is commonly tested. Any disparity indicates the presence of asymmetric
-3 -3.11
-3.5
behavior related to the distributional location of the dependent variable,
-3.66
-4 that is, ETR. Our results rejected the null hypothesis and showed that
low med high
corporate lobbying activities at different quantiles have distinct effects
LOBBYING
on ETRs. Therefore, corporate lobbying has a heterogeneous influence
CSR high low
on ETRs. Also, the results reported that the regressor's effects on ETR
indicators vary for different quantiles (Figure 3).
F I G U R E 2 Effects of corporate lobbying on tax aggressiveness:
contingent on corporate social responsibility [Colour figure can be Initially, the effect of corporate lobbying on ETR (Table 5) was not
viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com] uniform for all the quantiles. In contrast with the System GMM
results, the quantile regression estimates were similar to earlier stud-
CSR would negatively moderate the relationship between corporate ies that reported the effect of corporate lobbying to be stronger for
lobbying and ETR. That is, when CSR increases, it is expected that the firms with a higher ETR. For example, in Table 5, corporate lobbying
negative correlation between corporate lobbying and ETR would be improved ETR only for high lower quantiles (wherein the coefficients
stronger. This study found support for H2 as the results confirmed for corporate lobbying had greater negative values); however, it
that CSR does indeed negatively moderate this relationship. Model showed no effect on the quantiles below 0.02. This can be attributed
5 reported a significant negative coefficient for the interaction to the low ETR firms being in the growth phase, whereby any invest-
between CSR and corporate lobbying (β = −0.00274, p < 0.01). Thus, ment in corporate lobbying expenses does not decrease the ETR as it
the effect of corporate lobbying on ETR is stronger if a firm presents does not affect tax policies. Thus, corporate lobbying does not signifi-
higher CSR engagement. cantly contribute to tax aggressiveness among low-income firms.
Based on these results, the technique proposed by Aiken, West, However, in the case of higher income firms that engage in aggressive
and Reno (1991) was used to display important interactive effects lobbying rather than defensive lobbying, a negative relationship was
(p ≤ 0.10) and show moderating effects. Based on this technique, a seen between the magnitude of tax lobbying expenses and future tax
standard deviation value higher or lower than the mean value would rates. This relationship between corporate lobbying and tax avoidance
represent higher or lower levels of moderating variables, respectively. is more likely to prevail among extremely high tax avoidance corpora-
When a significant interaction was seen between CSR and corporate tions because such avoidance transfers a significant amount of wealth
lobbying, a visual inspection (Marques & Mintzberg, 2015) was thus from the community to the corporation.
deemed necessary. Figure 2 portrays the effect of corporate lobbying
on the ETR at two different organizational CSR levels (i.e., high and
low). Upon investigating the moderating effect of CSR, this study 4.5 | Dynamic panel quantile regression:
noted that firms' corporate lobbying activities showed a greater effect Interaction model
on the ETR when they performed more CSR. On the other hand, this
relationship was weaker when firms exhibited less CSR. When firms' To determine the moderating role of CSR in the relationship between
CSR ratings increase, they earn a high return on their lobbying corporate lobbying and tax aggressiveness at different ETRs, this
expenses, which is reflected in their low ETRs. Thus, firms with better study added the interaction term of CSR to Equation (6). Table 6 pre-
CSR derive more benefits than firms with poor CSR. The fact that sents the quantile regression results with this addition. This study
firms with low CSR spend more money than CSR-neutral organiza- employed various dynamic quantile regression techniques for differ-
tions implies that the former are potentially involved in defensive lob- ent models and considered the differential effect of corporate lobby-
bying activities to retain existing tax benefits or to prevent the ing on ETRs. Table 6 shows that corporate lobbying has a significant
implementation of rules or laws that increase their ETRs. negative effect on ETRs for all quantiles. The results confirmed H2's
prediction that corporate lobbying and CSR are effective for firms' tax
avoidance. This study also noted an asymmetric ETR effect, wherein
4.4 | Dynamic panel quantile regression the absolute value of coefficients at lower quantiles were smaller than
the higher quantiles. Therefore, large firms with high CSR practise tax
This study extended our empirical investigation by solving Equation (6) aggressiveness by decreasing their taxes.
at nine quantiles, that is, 10th, 20th, 30th, 40th, 50th, 60th, 70th, 80th, To uncover the distinct impact of the interaction between CSR
and 90th quantiles, using a single list of explanatory variables. This and corporate lobbying on ETRs, this study also plotted ETR effects
allowed us to determine the effect of the explanatory variables at against the interaction effect of Lobbying*CSR (Figure 4). For every
12

TABLE 5 Results of the dynamic panel quantile model with effective tax rate as the tax aggressiveness measure

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (1)


VARIABLES τ = 0.10 τ = 0.20 τ = 0.30 τ = 0.40 τ = 0.50 τ = 0.60 τ = 0.70 τ = 0.80 τ = 0.90

ETRt-1 −0*** −0*** 0.0928*** 0.522*** 0.688*** 0.750*** 0.825*** 0.939*** 0.713***
(0) (0) (0.000310) (0.000496) (0.00143) (0.00128) (0.00215) (0.000335) (0.00338)
Log lobbying −0*** −0*** −0.0000776** −0.000145*** −0.000191*** −0.000190*** −0.000325*** −0.000458*** −0.000552***
(0) (0) (0.00000357) (0.0000139) (0.0000620) (0.0000378) (0.0000876) (0.0000170) (0.000156)
CSR −0*** −0*** −0.00000109 −0.000000971 0.00000663 0.0000414*** 0.0000376 −0.0000768 −0.0000786***
(0) (0) (0.00000230) (0.00000199) (0.00000449) (0.0000116) (0.00000762) (9.01e−07) (0.00000507)
Free cash flow 0*** -0*** −0.00000693** −0.00000922** −0.0000265** 0.0000105** −0.00000413 −0.0000152*** −0.0000761***
(0) (0) (0.00000311) (0.00000148) (0.0000130) (0.00000510) (0.000109) (0.00000316) (0.0000274)
R&D intensity 0*** −0*** −0.00164*** −0.00607*** −0.00745*** 0.000964* −0.00812 0.00320*** −0.00535***
(0) (0) (0.000173) (0.000186) (0.000716) (0.000576) (0.0246) (0.000140) (0.000695)
Advertising intensity 1 1 0.909*** 0.489*** 0.326*** 0.292*** 0.233*** 0.145*** 0.147***
(0) (0) (0.000634) (0.000389) (0.00291) (0.00101) (0.00609) (0.000270) (0.00259)
Log Total assets 0*** −0*** −0.0000342 −0.0000640** −0.000307* 0.000201*** −0.000443 −0.000257*** −0.00155***
(0) (0) (0.0000325) (0.0000269) (0.000163) (0.0000412) (0.00138) (0.0000189) (0.000108)
Leverage −0*** −0** −0.00000913*** −0.0000469*** −0.000102*** −0.0000691*** 0.000338 0.000548*** 0.000373***
(0) (0) (0.00000297) (0.00000863) (0.0000215) (0.0000218) (0.000300) (0.00000333) (0.0000102)

Observations 957 957 957 957 957 957 957 957 957
Number of groups 163 163 163 163 163 163 163 163 163

Notes: The values in parentheses denote the p-value. The table reports the results of the impact of corporate lobbying on ETR using the quantile regression approach. *,**, and *** indicate significance at the
10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
LIN
LIN 13

F I G U R E 3 Change in dynamic panel Tax Aggressiveness (ETR)


quantile regression coefficients for 0 0 0
corporate lobbying as quantiles vary from 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
-0.0000776
0 to 1 [Colour figure can be viewed at -0.0001
wileyonlinelibrary.com] -0.000145
-0.0002 -0.000191 -0.00019

-0.0003
-0.000325

-0.0004
-0.000458
-0.0005
-0.000552
-0.0006

F I G U R E 4 Change in dynamic panel Tax Aggressiveness (ETR)


quantile regression coefficients for 0 0 0
-0.0000137
interaction between corporate lobbying 1 2 3 4 -0.0000251
5 -0.0000299
6 -0.0000335
7 8 9
-0.00005
and CSR as quantiles vary from 0 to 1
[Colour figure can be viewed at -0.0001
wileyonlinelibrary.com] -0.000125
-0.00015

-0.0002

-0.00025

-0.0003
-0.0003196
-0.00035 -0.000347

-0.0004

dependent variable, this study determined nine quantile regressions and dynamic quantile regression techniques to panel data for a
for quantiles ranging between 0.1 and 0.9 at a 10% increment. In 10-year period. This study determined the relationship between cor-
Figure 4, the horizontal X-axis shows the quantile scale while the ver- porate lobbying expenses (based on AMAC data) and the tax charac-
tical Y-axis indicates the effect of the coefficients of interaction teristics of 162 companies (based on their ETR values). This study also
(Lobbying*CSR) on the ETR. It can be seen that the coefficients for examined the moderating role played by CSR in the relationship
Lobbying*CSR were significant and negative for all nine quantiles and between corporate lobbying and tax aggressiveness. The results
displayed a decreasing trend. These results indicated that corporate showed that corporations with a high lobbying expense in a single
lobbying has a greater effect on the ETR when firms exhibit higher year pay a low ETR. This relationship is strengthened when CSR is
CSR; this is true across all quantiles of the ETR. This is consistent with present. While the results did not show that all forms of lobbying
our proposition that higher tax-paying firms are involved in numerous activities derive tax benefits, the dynamic quantile regression model
profit-shifting activities as the relationship between Lobbying*CSR indicated that higher income organizations that receive more benefits
and ETR becomes more negative. Additionally, it is plausible that carry out lobbying. These results are consistent with the perspective
higher CSR firms lobby to derive additional benefits from their lobby- that tax lobbying is defensive and opportunistic. Firms with high CSR
ing expenses, which is reflected in their lower tax rate. The results spend money on lobbying to influence political decisions to lower
again provided support for H2, as large firms with high CSR are more ETRs. This study thus conclude that lobbying activities and CSR
effective at reducing their taxes. Our findings suggest that the com- investments help firms derive significant tax benefits.
peting perspectives of shareholders and stakeholders are similar to
those in the literature. Financial benefits from social responsibility
offer bottom-line profits to shareholders while also addressing the 5.1 | Theoretical implications
desires and needs of non-owner stakeholders.
This study contributes to the existing literature in multiple ways. First,
it unearthed a determinant of corporate tax aggressiveness by identi-
5 | C O N CL U S I O N S fying corporate lobbying as an important factor that influences tax
aggressiveness. Second, the results add to the literature on tax avoid-
In this study, the researcher investigated the effect of corporate lob- ance and corporate lobbying by establishing and explaining a mecha-
bying activities on tax aggressiveness by applying the System GMM nism used by firms to reduce their tax payments. Third, this study
14

TABLE 6 Results of the dynamic panel quantile model with effective tax rate as the tax aggressiveness measure (interaction between corporate lobbying and corporate social responsibility)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (1)


VARIABLES τ = 0.10 τ = 0.20 τ = 0.30 τ = 0.40 τ = 0.50 τ = 0.60 τ = 0.70 τ = 0.80 τ = 0.90

ETRt-1 −0*** −0*** 0.0931*** 0.538*** 0.691*** 0.741*** 0.831*** 0.941*** 0.719***
(0) (0) (0.0000321) (0.0195) (0.000189) (0.000140) (0.000923) (0.00133) (0.00455)
Log lobbying 0*** −0*** 0.000122*** 0.0144 0.00146*** 0.000912*** 0.000632*** 0.00114*** −0.000523
(0) (0) (0.0000130) (0.0266) (0.0000418) (0.0000351) (0.000127) (0.000224) (0.000377)
CSR 0*** −0*** 0.0000134*** 0.00185 0.000183*** 0.000111*** 0.000127*** 0.000182*** −0.0000447
(0) (0) (0.00000149) (0.00333) (0.00000644) (0.00000462) (0.00000283) (0.0000328) (0.0000781)
Log lobbying*CSR −0*** 0*** −0.0000137*** −0.000251*** −0.0000209*** −0.00000135*** −0.0000125*** −0.0000196*** 0.0000147***
(0) (0) (0.000000176) (0.0000452) (0.000000660) (0.000000518) (0.00000269) (0.00000357) (0.00000791)
Free cash flow −0*** 0*** −0.0000509*** −0.00000318 −0.0000359*** −0.0000295*** 0.00000838*** −0.0000354*** −0.0000708*
(0) (0) (0.000000835) (0.000157) (0.00000189) (0.00000223) (0.00000228) (0.00000620) (0.0000403)
R&D intensity −0*** 0*** −0.00135*** −0.00133 −0.00659*** −0.00239*** 0.000342 0.00272*** −0.00664***
(0) (0) (0.0000370) (0.0274) (0.000178) (0.0000525) (0.000230) (0.000189) (0.000820)
Advertising intensity 1 1 0.908*** 0.428*** 0.328*** 0.296*** 0.220*** 0.142*** 0.149***
(0) (0) (0.0000525) (0.121) (0.000224) (0.000182) (0.000675) (0.00208) (0.00441)
Log Total assets −0*** 0*** −0.0000150*** 0.000983 −0.000291*** −0.000240*** −0.000188*** −0.000602*** −0.000864***
(0) (0) (0.00000257) (0.00164) (0.0000144) (0.0000139) (0.0000252) (0.00000705) (0.000192)
Leverage −0*** −0*** −0.00000160 0.000111 −0.0000777*** 0.000204*** 0.000507*** 0.000549*** 0.000329***
(0) (0) (0.00000142) (0.000419) (0.00000483) (0.00000462) (0.00000451) (0.00000342) (0.0000231)

Observations 957 957 957 957 957 957 957 957 957
Number of groups 163 163 163 163 163 163 163 163 163

Notes: The values in parentheses denote the p-value. The table reports the results of the impact of the interaction effect between CSR and corporate lobbying on ETR using the quantile regression approach.
*,**, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
LIN
LIN 15

determined the moderating role played by CSR in the correlation not be reliably linked to specific lobbying-related issues. The data on
between ETR and corporate lobbying. The results showed that firms lobbying expenses reflects the amount paid for lobbying activities as a
with higher CSR display more corporate lobbying to avoid taxes, pos- whole, not for tax lobbying alone. This may have biased our results as
iting that taxes and CSR act as substitutes instead of complements. this study used tax rate as the dependent variable. Also, other political
Fourth, this study applied the quantile regression technique to over- activities (e.g., PAC, campaign contributions, industry group lobbying,
come the limitations of the conditional mean regression in reporting or unreported personal interactions) are not captured by the lobbying
the average effect of corporate lobbying on the ETR. As per Koenker variable. Another limitation of our study is the use of the tax rate to
and Bassett (1978), the quantile regression presents the effect of cor- measure the effect of lobbying, since the tax rate is influenced by
porate lobbying on different quantiles of the ETR distribution. This many factors besides lobbying and varies each year. Also, it is difficult
technique also determined if corporate lobbying has a homogeneous to ascertain when successful lobbying effects would be reflected in
effect on the overall ETR distribution. tax rates because of the variability and length of the policymaking
process. Hence, other researchers (e.g., Alexander et al., 2009a; Cao,
Fernando, Tripathy, & Upadhyay, 2018) investigated the different lob-
5.2 | Managerial implications bying activities surrounding a particular legislation item. Though the
use of the tax rate as a dependent variable improves generalization of
The results presented in this study carry valuable implications for cor- the results, it remains less impactful and economically less significant
porate stakeholders who regard corporate lobbying and CSR as neces- than other outcomes.
sary activities by public companies and tax policymakers in developing
tax reform legislation. Hillenbrand, Money, Brooks, and Tovstiga (2019) OR CID

argued that firms should understand the plurality of stakeholders and Woon Leong Lin https://orcid.org/0000-0002-6568-412X
reconcile mixed signals from different groups. The results of this study
imply that an influential section of stakeholders in US public organiza- ENDNOTE
1
tions do not consider tax payment a socially responsible activity. For details of the methodology, please visit: http://fortune.com/worlds-
most-admired-companies/list/.
Brooks, Godfrey, Hillenbrand, and Money (2016) stated that govern-
ment officials would trade corporate tax revenue for higher employ-
ment and other taxes from additional economic activities if the RE FE RE NCE S
governmental regime allows more foreign direct investment. If Aggarwal, R. K., Meschke, F., & Wang, T. (2012). Corporate political contri-
butions: Investment or agency? Business and Politics, 14(1), 1–43.
policymakers want to carry out social welfare, they need to understand
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.972670
the relevance of this trade-off when designing tax laws.
Aiken, L. S., West, S. G., & Reno, R. R. (1991). Multiple regression: Testing
and interpreting interactions, Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE.
Alexander, R., Scholz, S., & Mazza, S. (2009a). Measuring rates of return
5.3 | Policy implications for lobbying expenditures: An empirical analysis under the American
jobs creation act. Journal of Law and Politics, 25(785), 36. https://doi.
org/10.2139/ssrn.1375082
The findings of our study advocate caution in scrutinizing firms' lobby- Alexander, R., Scholz, S., & Mazza, S. (2009b). Measuring rates of return on lob-
ing and CSR activities, as politically lobbied corporations that appear bying expenditures: An empirical case study of tax breaks for multinational
socially responsible might pay lower taxes than less socially responsi- corporations. Journal of Law and Politics, 25, 401. Retrieved from. http://
ssrn.com/abstract=1375082http://ssrn.com/abstract=1375082
ble corporations, eventually decreasing government income and
Anderson, T. W., & Hsiao, C. (1982). Formulation and estimation of
thereby government expenditure on infrastructure, defence, educa- dynamic models using panel data. Journal of Econometrics, 18(1),
tion, and healthcare services (Sikka & Willmott, 2010). According to 47–82. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(82)90095-1
one school of thought, paying less taxes is justified when compen- Andreoni, J., Erard, B., & Feinstein, J. (1988). Tax compliance. JSTOR, 36(2),
818–860. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2565123
sated for through more CSR. This study is thus vital for policymakers
Ansolabehere, S., de Figueiredo, J. M., & Snyder, J. M. (2003). Why is there
and tax agencies to recognize the potential issues that encourage so little Money in U.S Politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1),
firms to indulge in tax aggressiveness strategies. Policymakers should 105–130. https://doi.org/10.1257/089533003321164976
change existing rules and regulations to mitigate the problem of cor- Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data:
Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The
porate tax avoidance and to accurately tax firm income. Firms, on
Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297968
their end, should publish accurate information on taxes in their CSR Avi-Yonah, R. S., Clausing, K. A., & Durst, M. C. (2008). Allocating business
disclosures to minimize reputational risk (Sikka & Willmott, 2010). profits for tax purposes: A proposal to adopt a formulary profit Split.
Florida Tax Review, 9(5), 497. Retrieved from. http://repository.law.
umich.edu/laweconarchive/art95Electroniccopyavailableat:http://
ssrn.com/abstract=1317327
5.4 | Limitations Barrick, J. A., Brown, J. L. & Alexander, R. M. (2016). Tax corporate political
activity: A literature review. SSRN Electronic Journal. Retrieved from
This study is not without its limitations. First, though a few filters https://ssrn.com/abstract=2841803 or https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.
were used to identify lobbying issues, the existing lobbying data could 2841803
16 LIN

Behr, A. (2010). Quantile regression for robust bank efficiency score esti- Fisman, R. (2001). Estimating the value of political connections. American
mation. European Journal of Operational Research, 200(2), 568–581. Economic Review, 91(4), 1095–1102. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.91.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2008.12.033 4.1095
Bird, R., & Davis-Nozemack, K. (2018). Tax avoidance as a sustainability Fombrun, C., & Shanley, M. (1990). What's in a name? Reputation building
problem. Journal of Business Ethics, 151(4), 1009–1025. https://doi. and corporate strategy. Academy of Management Journal, 33(2),
org/10.1007/s10551-016-3162-2 233–258. https://doi.org/10.2307/256324
Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions Fryxell, G. E., & Wang, J. (1994). The fortune corporate “reputation” index:
in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143. Reputation for what? Journal of Management, 20(1), 1–14. https://doi.
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8 org/10.1177/014920639402000101
Brooks, C., Godfrey, C., Hillenbrand, C., & Money, K. (2016). Do investors Galvao, A. F. (2011). Quantile regression for dynamic panel data with fixed
care about corporate taxes? Journal of Corporate Finance, 38, effects. Journal of Econometrics, 164(1), 142–157. https://doi.org/10.
218–248. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2016.01.013 1016/j.jeconom.2011.02.016
Brown, J. L., Drake, K., & Wellman, L. (2015). The benefits of a rela- Gatzert, N. (2015). The impact of corporate reputation and reputation
tional approach to corporate political activity: Evidence from politi- damaging events on financial performance: Empirical evidence from
cal contributions to tax policymakers. The Journal of the American the literature. European Management Journal, 33(6), 485–499. https://
Taxation Association, 37(1), 69–102. https://doi.org/10.2308/atax- doi.org/10.1016/j.emj.2015.10.001
50908 Goldman, E., Rocholl, J., & So, J. (2009). Do politically connected boards
Brown, R. S. (2016). Lobbying, political connectedness and financial perfor- affect firm value? Review of Financial Studies, 22(6), 2331–2360.
mance in the air transportation industry. Journal of Air Transport Man- https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhn088
agement, 54, 61–69. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jairtraman.2016. Goldman, E., Rocholl, J., & So, J. (2013). Politically connected boards of
03.009 directors and the allocation of procurement contracts. Review of
Buchinsky, M. (1995). Quantile regression, box-cox transformation model, Finance, 17(5), 1617–1648. https://doi.org/10.1093/rof/rfs039
and the U.S. wage structure, 1963–1987. Journal of Econometrics, 65 Gujarati, D., & Porte, D. (2008). Basic econometrics. New York: McGraw-
(1), 109–154. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01599-U Hill Education.
Cao, Z., Fernando, G. D., Tripathy, A., & Upadhyay, A. (2018). The econom- Gupta, S., & Newberry, K. (1997). Determinants of the variability in corpo-
ics of corporate lobbying. Journal of Corporate Finance, 49, 54–80. rate effective tax rates: Evidence from longitudinal data. Journal of
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2017.12.012 Accounting and Public Policy, 16(1), 1–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/
Chen, Z., Dyreng, S., & Li, B. (2015). Playing the corporate political contri- S0278-4254(96)00055-5
butions lottery: Evidence from tax avoidance. SSRN Electronic Journal. Hadani, M., Bonardi, J.-P., & Dahan, N. M. (2017). Corporate political activ-
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2403918 ity, public policy uncertainty, and firm outcomes: A meta-analysis. Stra-
Chernozhukov, V., & Hansen, C. (2008). Instrumental variable quantile tegic Organization, 15(3), 338–366. https://doi.org/10.1177/
regression: A robust inference approach. Journal of Econometrics, 142 1476127016651001
(1), 379–398. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2007.06.005 Hanlon, M., & Heitzman, S. (2010). A review of tax research. Journal of
Claessens, S., Feijen, E., & Laeven, L. (2008). Political connections and pref- Accounting and Economics, 50(2–3), 127–178. https://doi.org/10.
erential access to finance: The role of campaign contributions. Journal 1016/j.jacceco.2010.09.002
of Financial Economics, 88(3), 554–580. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. Hansen, T. B. (2011). Lobbying of the IASB: An empirical investigation.
jfineco.2006.11.003 Journal of International Accounting Research, 10(2), 57–75. https://doi.
Coad, A., & Rao, R. (2008). Innovation and firm growth in high-tech sec- org/10.2308/jiar-10078
tors: A quantile regression approach. Research Policy, 37(4), 633–648. Hill, M. D., Kubick, T. R., Brandon Lockhart, G., & Wan, H. (2013). The
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2008.01.003 effectiveness and valuation of political tax minimization. Journal of
Dang, C., (Frank) Li, Z., & Yang, C. (2018). Measuring firm size in empirical Banking & Finance, 37(8), 2836–2849. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
corporate finance. Journal of Banking & Finance, 86, 159–176. https:// jbankfin.2013.04.002
doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2017.09.006 Hillenbrand, C., Money, K. G., Brooks, C., & Tovstiga, N. (2019). Corporate
Desai, M. A., & Dharmapala, D. (2006). Corporate tax avoidance and high- tax: What do stakeholders expect? Journal of Business Ethics, 158(2),
powered incentives. Journal of Financial Economics, 79(1), 145–179. 403–426. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-017-3700-6
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.02.002 Hillman, A. J., Keim, G. D., & Schuler, D. (2004). Corporate political activity:
Drope, J. M., & Hansen, W. L. (2008). Futility and free-riding: Corporate A review and research agenda. Journal of Management, 30(6),
political participation and taxation rates in the United States. Business 837–857. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jm.2004.06.003
and Politics, 10(3), 1–23. https://doi.org/10.2202/1469-3569.1238 Holme, R., & Watts, P. (2000). Corporate social responsibility: Making good
Duchin, R., & Sosyura, D. (2012). The politics of government investment. business sense, Conches-Geneva, Switzerland: World Business Council
Journal of Financial Economics, 106(1), 24–48. https://doi.org/10. for Sustainable Development.
1016/j.jfineco.2012.04.009 Holtz-Eakin, D., Newey, W., & Rosen, H. S. (1988). Estimating vector
Faccio, M. (2016). Discussion of “corporate political connections and tax autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica, 56(6), 1371–1395.
aggressiveness.”. Contemporary Accounting Research, 33(1), 115–120. https://doi.org/10.2307/1913103
https://doi.org/10.1111/1911-3846.12214 den Hond, F., Rehbein, K. A., de Bakker, F. G. A., & Lankveld, H. K. (2014).
Faccio, M., Masulis, R. W., & Mcconnell, J. J. (2006). Political connections Playing on two chessboards: Reputation effects between corporate
and corporate bailouts. Journal of Finance, 61(6), 2597–2635. https:// social responsibility (CSR) and corporate political activity (CPA). Journal
doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.01000.x of Management Studies, 51(5), 790–813. https://doi.org/10.1111/
Farber, D. B., Johnson, M. F., & Petroni, K. R. (2007). Congressional inter- joms.12063
vention in the standard-setting process: An analysis of the stock Hoopes, J. L., Mescall, D., & Pittman, J. A. (2012). Do IRS audits deter cor-
option accounting reform act of 2004. Accounting Horizons, 21(1), porate tax avoidance? Accounting Review, 87(5), 1603–1639. https://
1–22. https://doi.org/10.2308/acch.2007.21.1.1 doi.org/10.2308/accr-50187
de Figueiredo, J. M., & Richter, B. K. (2014). Advancing the empirical Kim, C. F., & Zhang, L. (2016). Corporate political connections and tax
research on lobbying. Annual Review of Political Science, 17(1), aggressiveness. Contemporary Accounting Research, 33(1), 78–114.
163–185. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-polisci-100711-135308 https://doi.org/10.1111/1911-3846.12150
LIN 17

Kim, J.-B., Li, Y., & Zhang, L. (2011). Corporate tax avoidance and stock Richardson, G., Taylor, G., & Lanis, R. (2016). Women on the board of
price crash risk: Firm-level analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 100 directors and corporate tax aggressiveness in Australia an empirical
(3), 639–662. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.07.007 analysis. Accounting Research Journal, 29(3), 313–331. https://doi.org/
Koenker, R. (2004). Quantile regression for longitudinal data. Journal of 10.1108/ARJ-09-2014-0079
Multivariate Analysis, 91(1), 74–89. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmva. Richter, B. K. (2011) ‘Good’ and ‘Evil’: The Relationship Between Corpo-
2004.05.006 rate Social Responsibility and Corporate Political Activity. SSRN Elec-
Koenker, R., & Bassett, G. (1978). Regression quantiles. Econometrica, 46 tronic Journal, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1750368.
(1), 33. https://doi.org/10.2307/1913643 Richter, B. K., Samphantharak, K., & Timmons, J. F. (2009). Lobbying and
Koenker, R., & Hallock, K. (2001). Quantile regression. Nature Methods, 15 taxes. American Journal of Political Science, 53(4), 893–909. https://doi.
(4), 143–156. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41592-019-0406-y org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2009.00407.x
Kottas, A., & KrnjajiC,  M. (2009). Bayesian semiparametric modelling in Sikka, P., & Willmott, H. (2010). The dark side of transfer pricing: Its role in
quantile regression. Scandinavian Journal of Statistics, 36(2), 297–319. tax avoidance and wealth retentiveness. Critical Perspectives on Account-
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9469.2008.00626.x ing, 21(4), 342–356. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cpa.2010.02.004
Lanis, R., & Richardson, G. (2012). Corporate social responsibility and tax Sorauf, F. J. (1994). Inside campaign finance: Myths and realities. Yale Uni-
aggressiveness: An empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting and Public Pol- versity Press.
icy, 31(1), 86–108. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jaccpubpol.2011.10.006 The Hill (2004). Business & Lobby: ‘Most Precious resource is … time',
Lanis, R., & Richardson, G. (2015). Is corporate social responsibility perfor- Retrieved on 16 May 2019. https://thehill.com/business-a-lobbying/
mance associated with tax avoidance? Journal of Business Ethics, 127 2808-most-precious-resource–is-time.
(2), 439–457. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-014-2052-8 Unsal, O., Hassan, M. K., & Zirek, D. (2016). Corporate lobbying, CEO
Lev, B., Petrovits, C., & Radhakrishnan, S. (2010). Is doing good good for political ideology and firm performance. Journal of Corporate Finance,
you? How corporate charitable contributions enhance revenue 38, 126–149. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2016.04.001
growth. Strategic Management Journal, 31(2), 182–200. https://doi. Waisman, M., Ye, P., & Zhu, Y. (2015). The effect of political uncertainty
org/10.1002/smj.810/full on the cost of corporate debt. Journal of Financial Stability, 16,
Lin, W. L., Ho, J. A., Ng, S. I., & Lee, C. (2019). Does corporate social 106–117. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2015.01.002
responsibility lead to improved firm performance? The hidden role of Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1990). Positive accounting theory: A ten
financial slack. Social Responsibility Journal, 16(7), 957–982. https:// year perspective. The Accounting Review, 65(1), 131–156.
doi.org/10.1108/SRJ-10-2018-0259. Whait, R. B., Christ, K. L., Ortas, E., & Burritt, R. L. (2018). What do we
Lin, W. L., Law, S. H., Ho, J. A., & Sambasivan, M. (2019). The causality know about tax aggressiveness and corporate social responsibility? An
direction of the corporate social responsibility—Corporate financial integrative review. Journal of Cleaner Production, 204, 542–552.
performance Nexus: Application of panel vector autoregression https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.08.334
approach. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 48, Wickert, C. (2016). “Political” corporate social responsibility in small- and
401–418. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2019.03.004 medium-sized enterprises: A conceptual framework. Business and Soci-
Lock, I., & Seele, P. (2017). Politicized CSR: How corporate political activity ety, 55(6), 792–824. https://doi.org/10.1177/0007650314537021
(mis-)uses political CSR. Journal of Public Affairs, 18(3), e1667. https:// Wilson, R. J. (2009). An examination of corporate tax shelter participants.
doi.org/10.1002/pa.1667 Accounting Review, 84(3), 969–999. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr.
Marques, J., & Mintzberg, H. (2015). Why corporate social responsibility 2009.84.3.969
Isn't a piece of cake. MIT Sloan Management Review, 56(4), 8–11. Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear
Retrieved from. http://mitsmr.com/1R4U9RC efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1),
Martinez, A. L. (2017). Tax aggressiveness: A literature survey. Journal of 25–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005
Education and Research in Accounting (REPeC), 11, 106–124. https:// Wise, K. (2007). Lobbying and relationship management: The K street con-
doi.org/10.17524/repec.v11i0.1724 nection. Journal of Public Relations Research, 19(4), 357–376. https://
Mathur, I., & Singh, M. (2011). Corporate political strategies. Accounting & doi.org/10.1080/10627260701402457
Finance, 51(1), 252–277. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-629X.2010. Zimmerman, J. L. (1983). Taxes and firm size. Journal of Accounting and
00386.x Economics, 5, 119–149. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(83)
McGuire, J. B., Sundgren, A., & Schneeweis, T. (1988). Corporate social 90008-3
responsibility and firm financial performance. Academy of Management
Journal, 31(4), 854–872.
Meade, J., & Li, S. (2015). The clientele effect of corporate tax lobbying.
The Journal of the American Taxation Association, 37(2), 23–48.
Mills, L. F., Nutter, S. E., & Schwab, C. M. (2013). The effect of political How to cite this article: Lin WL. Giving too much and paying
sensitivity and bargaining power on taxes: Evidence from federal con- too little? The effect of corporate social responsibility on
tractors. Accounting Review, 88(3), 977–1005. https://doi.org/10. corporate lobbying efficacy: Evidence of tax aggressiveness.
2308/accr-50368
Corp Soc Responsib Environ Manag. 2020;1–17. https://doi.
Plesko, G. A. (2003). An evaluation of alternative measures of corporate
tax rates. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 35(2), 201–226. org/10.1002/csr.2098
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-4101(03)00019-3

You might also like