Anderson 1990

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 23

World Development, Vol. 18, No. 8, pp. 1057-1079, 1990. 0305s750)</90s3.00+0.

00
Printed in Great Britain. c 1990 Pergamon Press plc

Investment and Economic Growth

DENNiS ANDERSON*
University College, London and St. Anthony’s College, Oxford

Summary. - The paper revisits the old question, how much does investment contribute to economic
growth? Building on recent work of Maurice Scott, it suggests that the analysis of growth. in
developing as in the industrial countries, would benefit from a capital accumulation approach. In
the following analysis, economic growth is related to three variables, all greatly influenced by the
quality of economic policies: the rate of investment, the social rate of return to investment, and the
investment-induced returns to labor.

1. INTRODUCTION The advantage of reworking the approach to


growth accounting in these ways is that the econ-
This paper considers once again the role of omist’s tools for analyzing the allocative efficiency
investment in economic growth and development. of economic policies can be brought to bear on the
Its aim is to derive an accounting relationship analysis of the effects of those policies on growth.
between the rate of economic growth and variables It leads to what Johnson (1964) once described
representing the rate, allocation and efficiency of as “a generalized capital accumulation approach”
investment. Efficiency is measured by the social net toward growth and development:
present value or social rate of return to investment.
The growth of income that defines economic devel-
The paper draws on earlier approaches to the opment is necessarily the result of the accumulation
analysis of growth in three ways. First, it shows of capital, or of “investment”; but “investment” in
that changes in output arising from technical pro- this context must be defined to include such diverse
gress turn out, in large measure, to be due to the activities as adding to material capital, increasing the
redeployment of labor brought about by invest- health, discipline, skill and education of the human
ment in human and material resources; that is, they population, moving labor into more productive occu-
can be attributed to investment. The paper draws pations and locations, and applying existing know-
ledge or discovering and applying processes. All such
on vintage theories of investment-embodied tech-
activities involve incurring costs, in the form of use
nical progress to show how these gains from
ofcurrent resources, and investment in them is worth-
redeployment can be linked to investment. Second, while if the rate of return over the cost exceeds the
turning to disembodied sources of technical pro- general rate of interest, or the capital value of the
gress, the paper shows that factors that appear
to change output in ways seemingly disconnected
from investment turn out to actually change it by
*This paper was originally prepared while I was on leave
changing the outputs of new investments and from the World Bank in 1986 at St. Anthony’s College.
(especially important) of investments in place. Oxford. I am grateful to Hans Fuchs and Tariq Husain
Again, the effect is to link output gains from tech- for encouraging me to write up my ideas on the subject.
nical progress to investment. to the Bank for giving me the leave. and to the Fellows
A corollary of these two extensions is that the and staff of St. Anthony’s for providing an exceedingly
“residual” factor in economic growth is much pleasant and stimulating environment in which to under-
smaller than growth accounting studies commonly take research. I wish to thank Maurice Scott for gen-
find. Indeed, in a third extension, using an idea erously sharing with me his ideas on the subject. Carl
of Maurice Scott,’ the residual is set to zero, by Liedholm, Peter Kilby and Paul Streeten for their com-
ments and encouragement, and Ralph Turvey for raising
definition of the accounting conventions used, on
some thought-provoking points on earlier drafts. I should
the grounds that the effects of technical progress also like to thank two anonymous referees whose com-
on output are captured in the returns to investment ments saved me from a potentially embarrassing mistake
and the investment-induced returns to labor. The and led to several other helpful revisions. The paper is
accounting conventions used are those relating to based on a World Bank Discussion Paper of a similar
the social rate of return to investment. title (Anderson, 1987). The usual disclaimers apply.

1057
1058 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

additional income they yield exceeds the cost of investment is determined by the point at which its
obtaining it. From the different perspective of plan- quasi rents become zero or negative on account of
ning, efficient development involves allocation of changes in relative prices. Its net present value is
investment resources according to priorities set by the the discounted value of its quasi rents, less the
relative rates-of return on alternative investments.
discounted value of actual investment expenditures
The paper benefits greatly from the work of (which may be incurred over several years for
Maurice Scott (1981, 1986, 1989). His recent book investments with long lead times). These defi-
on the subject is very important, and I hope will nitions and accounting procedures follow Scott
be influential. The following analysis departs from (1981, 1986), Salter (1960) and are also standard
his work in three respects; in each case, the aim is in social cost-benefit analysis.
constructive. First, it draws extensively on vintage Before deriving the relationship, it is necessary
theories of growth, of which Scott is critical (and to reconsider the effects of investment on the
which have long been dismissed, as well, as being redeployment of labor and thus on labor’s income.
“unimportant” by Denison [ 19641 and others). The These effects can be appreciable and tend to be
analysis shows that what was surely a major devel- underestimated by current methods of growth
opment in growth theory 30 years ago can benefit accounting. A reworking of the relationship so as
from Scott’s ideas, and moreover leads to inter- to reflect them better is the first task of this analysis.
esting results. Second, Scott uses the familiar
“quality adjustment” approach to estimate labor’s
contribution to growth, whereas below I raise (a) Inoestment and the redeployment of labor
questions (as have many others before me) about
its reliability. Third, to get the theory straight, Most growth accounting studies allow for the
Scott is more concerned with steady growth. My output and income gains from redeployment, but
aim is to relate the analysis to developing and only for broadly defined occupations, e.g., for the
industrial countries, whether or not growth is movement of workers from agriculture to industry,
steady, and whether or not the “stylized facts” of defined at the one-digit level. The practice is as
long-term growth apply. In this respect, my aim is follows.3 The labor force is grouped according to
to broaden the applicability of Scott’s own the occupations, educations and ages of its male
attempts to revive the investment approach to and female members. The contribution of the
growth. redeployment of labor to the growth of income is
Section 2 of the paper derives an aggregate then taken to be a weighted average of the rates of
accounting relationship, first for the case of purely change of the proportions of the labor force in
investment-embodied technical progress, and then each group, the weights being the average incomes
for embodied and (seemingly) disembodied sources of the labor force in each group divided by national
of technical progress together. Section 3 discusses income per worker. Then (i) if there is a net move-
how the relationship can be disaggregated and ment of workers from, say, agriculture to industry,
generalized in other ways. Section 4 uses the aggre- with wages being higher in industry, there is a
gate form to estimate the imputed returns to invest- rise in income attributable to the redeployment of
ment in various countries; the estimates serve to labor from agriculture to industry; (ii) if there is
illustrate the strength of the link between the alloc- an increase in the proportion of workers in the
ative efficiency of investment and growth. Section higher paid, better educated groups, there is a rise
5 reviews some points of departure between current in income attributable to redeployment associated
approaches to growth accounting and the with investment in education; (iii) if there is an
approach followed in this paper. Section 6 makes increase in their average age, such that a greater
some concluding remarks. proportion of workers are in the higher paid age
groups, there is a further rise attributable to the
increased experience of the labor force; and (iv) if
2. INVESTMENT, EFFICIENCY AND there is an increase in the proportion of women in
GROWTH: SOME AGGREGATE the labor force, the average contribution of the
RELATIONSHIPS quality of labor to the growth of income may
(according to such procedures) be estimated to fall,
To begin, a note on definitions and procedures: since women (within any particular education-age-
The following analysis uses the gross rather than occupation group) are paid less than men4
the net value of investment. Any provision to keep It is likely that a greater disaggregation of occu-
an investment in service up to the end of its econ- pational or industrial groupings would show the
omic lifetime is not regarded as depreciation but rate of redeployment of the labor force, and the
as maintenance, which in turn is considered part increased income derived from redeployment, to
of operating costs.2 The economic lifetime of an be significantly greater. For instance, in the course
INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH 1059

of economic growth both the size distribution It is unlikely, however, that a greater dis-
and the composition of manufacturing activities aggregation of industries or of occupations, say
change appreciably over time - from a con- to the four of five digit level, would provide a
centration of employment in small-scale, cottage satisfactory estimate of the rate of redeployment
industries and workshops in food processing, tex- that takes place as a consequence of investment in
tiles, wearing apparel and light engineering, toward a growing economy. Workers of a given age and
a greater concentration on heavy engineering.‘The education may be redeployed by material invest-
earnings differentials between these activities for ment without changing their industry or occu-
workers of a given age and education are often pation - or even their firm or place of employ-
large, e.g. over a two or three to one range as ment. In agriculture, for example, changes from
between large and small firms in a given industry.6 rainfed to irrigated crops, from traditional to high-
It follows that an application of the above method yield, seed-fertilizer varieties, from the use of bull-
of analysis would attribute some (if not a large ocks to the use of tractors, all bring about a
share) of the observed increases of labor incomes redeployment of agricultural labor. often without
in manufacturing to redeployment within manu- changing the crop variety. In factories, labor may
facturing. Similar remarks can be made about be redeployed and retrained at regular intervals in
changes in the scale and composition of activities order to introduce new machines and new mana-
within agriculture (the transition from manual till- gerial methods with higher outputs per worker to
age to the use of draft animals, or changes in mech- produce essentially the same product. It is not
anization, crop varieties, land tenure systems, difficult to think of examples in other industries,
investment in irrigation, and so forth),’ commerce each being associated with a change in the nature
(e.g., changes in the types and scales of retailing, of work, economic output and ultimately in labor’s
wholesaling and banking activities), transport and income.
construction. Furthermore, each generation of the Since greater disaggregation will not work, let
labor force is continually redeploying itself us consider an alternative approach toward esti-
through the introduction of new, higher tech- mating the effects of investment on labor’s income,
nology industries and products in the indu- drawing on vintage theories of growth. To begin,
strialized countries, or through diversification of a “pure,” aggregate vintage model will be taken,
the industrial base in the developing countries. after which attempts will be made to generalize it.
Insofar as the new industries are associated with
higher productivity and earnings levels for workers
in a given age and education group, a redeploy- (b) A relationship for the case of embodied
ment of the labor force toward them will again technical progress
account for some - if not a large share - of
the observed increases of both labor’s income and Figure I shows a plot of output per worker
value added. against the numbers of workers deployed on vari-

-------7-;y&of&

/’ introduced
I” Y

Growth of wages on
- Investments Introduced in v

--CF.-----
-,
-‘(number depioyed new vIntageI
L” number of workers
employed an Y

Figure I. Vintage model: Emplqvment, producrivity, wages and quasi rents for successive vimoges
of investments.
1060 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

ous vintages of investments. It is drawn for the as just described, and real wages and real output
case of steady growth, in which new vintages of per worker are rising? It is defined as the discount
investment with higher outputs per worker are con- rate which equates the (gross) expenditures on new
tinuously redeploying workers from old vintages. investments with the present worth of the quasi
It is not difficult to consider other cases such as rents over the economic lifetime of the investments.
dualistic growth shown in Figure 2.’ The steady Let the annual output (value added) of investments
growth case, however, suffices for the purpose of introduced in v be q,,. If we take exponential instead
the present analysis. The construct used here fol- of compound growth to simplify algebra, then
lows Solow (1970). qC = E,b,e&‘, where E, denotes the number of wor-
Output per worker on the latest vintage, v, is kers deployed on the investments introduced in v.
denoted by b,$“, where b is the rate of growth of The annual outputs of the investments, the growth
output per worker. On the oldest vintage still in of wages, and the (declining) quasi rents are shown
use, output per worker is b,eb’“-“‘, where n is the as dotted lines on Figure 1 and correspond to a
economic lifetime of the investments. When a new stylized form (shown in the lower half of Figure 3)
vintage is introduced it will have higher quasi rents. of the costs of and returns to investments fre-
If the labor force were fully employed, or if the quently encountered in project analysis. The net
labor requirements of the new vintages exceeded present value (NPV) of the outputs of these invest-
unemployment levels plus the number of new ments is thus given by:
entrants into the labor force, then labor would o+n Cf”
have to be redeployed from existing investments. NPV = qCe-Ir-u,dt_. W,,,e@-‘)dt - I,
As Solow explains, in any competitive economy, s 1
or in any planned economy maximizing output per (1)
worker, labor would be redeployed from the oldest
investments, which would be duly retired. Further, where I, is the present value of the expenditures
in a competitive economy, wages would be bid up on investments whose outputs first appear in v,
to the point where the quasi rents of the oldest referred to the period v; r is the discount rate and
(marginal) investments remaining in operation n is the average economic lifetime of the invest-
were zero (or close to zero). That is, the output per ments; as discussed above, n is defined by the time
worker on the oldest investments determines the when their quasi rents have declined to zero.
wage rate, which rises whenever those investments Denoting total economic output in v by Q”, and
are displaced by, and labor is redeployed on, new the annual rate of investment in v by i, we also
investments. have
Now consider the question: what is the rate of
Iv = iQ. (2)
return to investment in a period of steady growth,
in which workers are being continually redeployed (This expression is really an approximation

blue cdded
(net of I
rnaintemnce)
per worker

Quos~ rents on

Value added
per worker In
I I new vmtoges

I’E, number employed on


‘Lv (number of wakers employed in 14’ ,-,,,,. vlntqe

Figure 2. As in Figure 1, but wilh low rates of deployment of the labor force on new invesfmenfs
(large shares of Iabor force on old vintages).
INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH 1061

Actual vorlottbns
I

mantenonce and
intermedlate rtputs

Economtc lifetime
L

Styhzed form of above

I
I,,~---_-_---
Grossoutput

Value odded
--_--_-

- Trne

Ii _______._
\
Expenditure on molntenance
G’expendhures and Intemwdlote inputs

Figure 3. Variations over time of costs, gross output, intermediate inputs, value added, wage bill
and quasi rents of an investment.

because the effects of lead times on the value of I, the outputs of investment are assumed to be con-
are ignored for the moment.) stant after they are brought into service. From
Total economic output in v is given by the sum equation (4), the net change in output equals the
of outputs from all investments being utilized in v, output from new investments minus the outputs of
i.e., by investments about to be retired. Since qC = Elb,eb”,
q.-qU_, can be written as q,(l -(E,._,,/E,.)e-““). If
Qr = ’ q,dt (3) the labor force, L,, is growing at a rate of c per
s ,.-!I year, and the rate of redeployment, EJL,., is
while the rate of change of output is obtained by constant, then the expression for q0-q41,_. further
differentiating equation (3) to give simplifies to q,,( 1 -e-g”), where g = (b+c) is the
rate of economic growth. This simplification is
dQc
-=
dL3 s ’ &Jr
r_,z.dt+qp-q,.-n = qr-ql._n

Note that dq,/dc = 0 in the present case because


(4)
used below since it reduces notation
affecting the analysis in any basic way.
To complete the above relationships,
without

note that
investments are retired once their quasi rents have
1062 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

become zero, i.e., when and others, the effects of investment on growth
were usually estimated from the product ir. But the
W,,,,” = 4c (5) above result shows that they should be estimated
For this equality to hold, we are also including the from ir times I/( 1- 5’). Since S is typically in the
opportunity cost of entrepreneurial labor in the range 0.6 to 0.75, the total effects of investments
wage bill. on growth may be. in an economy redeploying its
The above five expressions are sufficient for a labor in productive ways. of the order of 2.5 to 4.0
relationship between the allocative efficiency of times the estimates of these early studies.’
investment and the rate of economic growth to be It is reassuring to find that the relationships on
derived. Taking g to be the exponential rate of which equations (6) and (7) are based appeared in
growth and w to be the growth rate of wages, a similar form in the growth literature nearly 30
noting that g = (l/Q,)(dQ,/dv), and using equa- years ago, in the growth model of Kaldor and
tions (2) (4) and (5) in equation (I), gives Mirrlees (196162) which evolved out of Kaldor’s
earlier work (Kaldor, 1957. 1961). As in the vintage
NPV = (1 -e-“‘)/r-(e-“‘“-e-‘“)/(r-W) models of Solow discussed above. technical pro-
-i(l --eAng)/g (6) gress is embodied in new investment; investments
are retired once their quasi rents have declined to
In the pure vintage model sketched in Figure 1, zero on account of the growth wages (as in equa-
the growth rate of wages, w, equals the growth tion 5 and Figure 3); the amount of labor available
rate of output per worker, b. However, the above for working on new investments is equal to the
expression is applicable to a slightly more general growth of the working population plus the labor
case where the two may be different, as they often released from obsolescent investments (as above)
are in practice. In developing countries, real wages and physically wasted equipment; wage growth is
frequently grow more slowly than output per linked (as above) to the rate of redeployment of
worker over long periods. It seems important to labor and the growth rate of productivity of new
allow for such possibilities. investments. New investments take place so long
To facilitate the interpretation of equation (6), as the present value of expected quasi rents equals
iedefine r to be the social rate of return and (by or exceeds the costs of investments (as in equation
definition of the latter) set the NPV = 0. Also, note 1). There is no residual account, since the effects
that the ratio of the second term to the first on the of technical progress appear in the returns to
right-hand side of equation (6) is the present value investment and the returns to labor. It is puzzling
of labor’s share in output; like the more familiar that the insights provided by vintage theory have
quantity, labor’s share in current output, it would been so long ignored in the growth accounting
seem to merit its own definition and notation in the literature. even though Abramovitz (1962) raised
analysis. Denoting it by S, equation (6) becomes: the issue with great clarity more than 25 years ago.
g = air/(l-S) (7)
where u = (1 - e-“‘)/( 1 - eeng). Since CJdepends (c) Disembodied and embodied technical
on r and g, and S on r, any solution for g in terms progress together
of i, r and S, or for r in terms g, i and S, has to be
obtained iteratively. It turns out (see Section 4) The analysis has so far concentrated on a stan-
that equation (6) is easier to work with in this dard case of embodied technical progress. Now
respect, e.g., by scanning a range of possible values consider the effects on the returns to investment
of r to find the value which makes NPV zero, as is and growth of factors not embodied in new invest-
the practice in project analysis. However, since CJ ment directly. Familiar examples are growth in
and S are fairly stable quantities, equation (7) is agriculture arising from improvements in hus-
easier to interpret. bandry, and growth in industry and commerce
Equation (7) indicates that investment’s con- arising from improvements in organization and
tribution to the growth of economic output is sig- reductions in managerial inefficiencies. Negative
nificantly higher than growth accounting studies examples might be the economic costs of bureau-
usually find, because of its influence on the growth cratic and political harassment of public and pri-
of wages. This is the reason for the (1 -s) term in vate enterprises, which affect not only the choice
the denominator. New investments not only gen- and rate of investment (and thus the rate of
erate annual returns of the order of the product embodied technical progress) but how well invest-
ir for the investors, but also raise real wages by ments in place work and are managed (and thus
redeploying labor from one kind of activity to the rate of disembodied technical progress). There
another - more productive - kind. Recalling the are also some cases in which increases in output
calculations of Cairncross (1961) Kuznets (1966) per worker, though seemingly disembodied from
INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH 1063

direct investment, require it in significant amounts (see equation 4) leads to the following expression
indirectly. Public investment in agricultural ex- for the rate of change of output:
tension services to improve husbandry and facili-
tate the dissemination of the results of scientific
research would be one example. lo One of the two
main effects of such indirect investments, however,
(-1
dQt
dt
= d. Qr +q,, -qt mm., (11)

is to raise the returns of investments already in But qL’P-ql-_n.l.can be written as q,,(l-(E,._,/


place (the other being to raise the returns to new EL,)e-@++ ), which again suggests the approxi-
investments) such that output per worker, b, exp mation qol.- q,.-n.r = q,,,( 1 -eeg”), assuming that
(6~) in the preceding notation, is no longer constant the rate of redeployment is approximately constant
after t’, but may rise (or fall, if managerial problems over time.
or bureaucratic harassment become worse). Out- Substituting equation (9) into equation (8) and
put per worker is not therefore fully defined by integrating, substituting for q,.t from equation
(embodied in) the investment at the time it takes (11) in the resulting expression, noting that
place. g = (l/Q,.)(dQ,./dt)and taking Z, = iQ, (we are con-
Such sources of growth increase the quasi rents tinuing to ignore lead times for the moment), leads
and thus the returns to both present and future to
investments. Changes in quasi rents might also g = air/(1-S)+d[l -ai/(l -s)] (12)
affect the deployment of labor on various vintages
of investments and thus real wages, as is apparent To compare this result with that of the “pure”
if a general upward shift of the curve of output per vintage case, denote the values of g, r and s in the
worker is considered in Figures 1 and 2. The effects latter case by the subscript 1, and in the present
might be quitecomplicated depending on the inci- case by the subscript 2. The difference in the rates
dence of the efficiency improvements on the vari- of growth in the two cases is d:
ous vintages of investments. But suppose outputs 92 =g,+d (13)
per worker increase at a rate of d per year on each
vintage of investment, with qt, being the output in where g, = air,/( 1 -S,), while g2 is given by equa-
year t of investments in the amount of IV com- tion (12) with the subscripts 2 attached to r and S.
missioned in year D (t > ~1). As before, let S be the It follows that, comparing equations (12) and (13),
present value of labor’s share in output. Then by d=r,-r,(l-S,)/(l-S,) (14)
definition of the rate of return,
2: r2-r,
,‘+?I

I, = (1 -s) -<l-V,& assuming Sz u S,.


qr, e (8)
Hence the contribution to growth of factors not
directly embodied in investment can be measured
Using the previous notation, the value of qc is by their effects on the returns to investment - in
now given by the present case, by the change in the returns to
investment. Substituting for rz from equation (14)
into equation (12) leads to:
The first term inside the exponent indicates that
g2 = air,/(l -S,)+aid/(l -SJ
new investment may capture the managerial and
other such efficiency improvements as well, while +d[l -ai/(l -S?)] (15)
the second term represents the effects of such The first term on the right-hand side of equation
improvements on the investment’s output after it (15) represents the rate of economic growth due to
has been commissioned. Since qv, represents the factors embodied in investments at the time they
output of investments commissioned in L‘in their are brought into service. The second term,
first year of service (2,) it simplifies notation to aid(1 -Sz), represents the effects on growth of
rewrite the last expression as managerial and other such sources of efficiency
improvement being captured by new investments.
(9) Note that it can be written approximately as
Total output in r, Q,, is then given by ai(r2 - r ,)/(1 - SJ, so that not only is there a gain
in terms of the returns to investment, measured by
Q, = 1 q,, dt’
J, = I -n
(10)
ai(r, - r ,), but a gain arising from the influences of
disembodied sources of economic growth on the
growth of labor’s income as well (as we would
The variable q,, has the same form as equation expect if we consider an upward shift of curves
(9) with obvious changes in notation. Substituting representing outputs per worker in Figures 1 and
equation (9) into equation (IO). and differentiating 2); hence the appearance of (1 - S2) in the denomi-
1064 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

nator of this term. The third term, d (the full managerial efficiency and other influences not
growth effect of disembodied factors) minus the initially embodied in investment. The only changes
second represents the effects on output of efficiency in prices considered were those of labor relative
improvements to investments in place. to other inputs and outputs together, while the
The effects of efficiency improvements not changes in labor costs were also assumed to take
directly embodied in investment may be quite a simple exponential form. The assumptions were
large, since they apply here to the entire capital depicted graphically in the lower half of Figure
stock. If such improvements were confined to a 3. They were obviously restrictive assumptions,
smaller share of the capita1 stock (as they often are which might be relaxed as follows:
in practice) the effects would be smaller. But the
underlying conclusion would remain the same.
(a) The value added each year by an investment
Improvements in managerial and other sources of
may change over economic cycles, or with
efficiency seemingly not embodied in investment
weather, political shocks, and other ran-
directly can nevertheless be viewed as influencing
dom factors.
growth by influencing the returns to existing and
(b) Value added may also change over time
new investments, and cannot accomplish much
with “learning-by-doing” and with the
without them. Their economic desirability can also
experience of the labor force working on
be assessed using a standard measure of economic
the new vintages of investments.
efficiency, the social rate of return to investment.
(c) Investments often have long lead times.
(d) Maintenance costs generally rise as the
investments age. leading to a decline in
(d) The rate of profit analogue and the capital
quasi rents even if labor costs remain
output ratio
unchanged.
(e) Finally, relative prices of outputs and
Consider the accounting identity Q = pK+ wL,
inputs may change with innovation,
where p is the rate of profit, K capital stock, wL.
changes in terms of trade, and scarcities in
the wage bill and Q value added. Then if wages
the supply of certain factor inputs.
ch>nge with investment:

@Q/Q) = p~+UlQ)kTw~)l=ld~ In general, and after smoothing out random and


The second term on the right-hand side represents cyclical factors, the outputs and costs of an invest-
the effects of investment on real wages; it becomes ment may look more like the form shown in the
gS if, drawing on the results of vintage theory, we upper half of Figure 3 than in the stylized form
argue that it is investment which maintains labor’s below it.
share in output at some level S*. The expression It is apparent that once one begins to allow for
then reduces to g = pi/( 1 - S*), the rate of profit such realities, explicit algebraic relations between
analogue of equation (7). The incremental capital/ the growth of output, investment, and the returns
output ratio also follows readily from the above to investment (including the returns of labor)
and is (1 - S)/ar if we are working in terms of the become more difficult to derive. But two points can
rate of return, and (1 - Q/p in terms of the rate of be fairly made. First, when we are considering
profit. Since neither the rate of profit, nor (recalling how the rate and efficiency of investment influence
Streeten, (1972)) the incremental capital/output growth, the principle of comparing the present
ratio provides a satisfactory basis for the analysis value of the change in output associated with
of investment decisions and their effects on output, investment with the present value of the investment
it is generally preferable to work with the rate of and labor costs of producing the change remains
return. applicable. The computational difficulties of esti-
mating the returns to investment and labor from
data on output, investment and wages are sig-
nificantly increased, but the basic accounting ident-
3. SOME GENERALIZATIONS AND A ity for the rate of return or NPV of investment
MORE DISAGGREGATED RELATIONSHIP remains a valid starting point for analysis. Second,
it is still useful to know how the averages of the
In the analysis in Section 2, the cost and revenue various quantities of interest (i, g. r and 5’) relate
streams associated with investment have a simple to each other in more complicated situations, and
form, with the yearly value added by an investment how they might be estimated.
being assumed constant over its economic lifetime In a separate paper, ’ ’ I have attempted to show
in the pure investment-embodied case, or changing that the aggregate relationships derived in Section
at a steady rate of d per year with changes in 2 may hold for the periods over which growth
INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH 1065

performance is usually studied (typically IO-20 taking place in u do not affect output until IJ to U+ 1
years). The approach is to divide the outputs years later (depending on when they were begun in
of investments of vintage tr into two parts, the period ~1-1 to v), where I is the lead time
qc,= &.+u,;,, where IV is their mean output over of the investments, while the output of activities
the period of interest and u,.,(? 2 v) is the deviation started up in L’originates from investments taking
of the actual output from the mean. The variable place over the period r-1 to c. Lead times raise the
u,, may be negative in the early years of an invest- discounted costs of investment (if the discounted
ment as output gradually builds to full capacity values are referred to period P), or alternatively
levels; negative in later years, as maintenance prob- lower the discounted benefits (if the discounted
lems increase and the investment is gradually values are referred to the time when investment
worked shorter hours until being taken out of ser- activities begin, r-I). Taking the former case, we
vice; positive or negative at other times on account can define the proportionate effects on costs by a
of business cycles, random factors, and so forth; term L,, where
rise or fall if there are any systematic improvements
or deteriorations in the efficiency with which the
investment is managed and operated; and rise or a,e-*‘-“dt, and a,dt = 1
fall with relative changes in factor and product
prices. By definition of 41, and u,,, the integral of
the latter over sufficiently long periods is small; the Here, a, represents the profile of investment expen-
approximation that its discounted value over such ditures, such as that depicted in Figure 3. In this
periods is small is also used (which helps to simplify case, and again taking an average value of L,.,
rate-of-return identities like equation (8)). An equation (17) becomes
expression similar to equation (7) then emerges,
with the variables g, i, 6, r and S being replaced Q = 6itF/(l-3) (17)
by their average values, namely
Third, turning to the calculation of 3, the main
difference between this variable and the more fam-
iliar quantity, labor’s share in current output
Equation (16) raises issues regarding the aver- (denoted by s*), is that the effects of discounting
aging process itself, the lead times of investments, are to give the present value of labor’s share in the
the calculation of 3, and disaggregation. (present value of) output a lower weight toward
First, using averages does not preclude analysis the end of an investment’s lifetime, when labor’s
of the numerous events which may influence an share in output is high (see Figure 3). Thus 3 is
investment’s output over its lifetime. The value of generally lower than s*, though not appreciably
&+u,, = qt, in general cannot exceed the capacity (because output is discounted as well as wages).
output of an investment, which means that the The procedures for calculating .!? from data on
larger is u, the smaller the average output 4., the wages (or on s*) follow straightforwardly from
smaller the average quasi rents, the smaller the discounted cash flow formulae (see Table 1). When
rates of return to investment and thus the smaller wages are constant, S equals S*.
the contribution of investment to the growth of Finally, turning to disaggregated forms of equa-
output. In other words, the transitory factors rep- tion (16), the rate-of-return accounting identity is
resented by u,, exert their influence on growth applicable to any investment. Denoting each
through their influences on quasi rents. This pro- investment activity by j, the disaggregated form of
cess affects the average returns to investment and equation (16) is readily shown to be
may also affect the rate of investment and labor’s
share in output. The division of a particular vintage g = ‘1 ff,L,l;,i//(1 - 3,) (18)
of investment’s contribution to output into tran-
sient and average terms is in any case only the
simplest of several ways of expressing qr,. where the I;, represents the average share of invest-
Lead times of investments are a second factor ment in activity j over the period 0 to T.” This
which the analysis has neglected thus far. Lead relationship does not rest on any particular
times vary greatly with the kind of investments, assumptions as to the number of investment activi-
from a few weeks or months for machinery and ties or sectors. The composition of such activities
equipment, to one to seven years or more for fac- or sectors within the group defined by j = I.. .J
tories, power plants, physical infrastructure, and can be thought of as changing over time. with old
irrigation works. Investments in such areas as agri- sectors beoming a zero subgroup of J once they
cultural extension and research may need lead are obsolete, and new sectors having been a zero
times of more than IO years. Thus investments subgroup before their appearance.
1066 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

4. IMPUTED AVERAGE RATES OF was to estimate a lower and an upper limit for r.
RETURN TO INVESTMENT FOR SOME The lower limit was obtained by setting w = b,
COUNTRIES the rate of growth of average output per worker,
shown in column (4). It is considered a lower limit
The following exercise uses the aggregate because real wages have probably grown more
relationships derived in Sections 2 and 3 to impute slowly than average output per worker in most of
the rates of return to investment from data on g, i the developing countries shown, on account of a
and S for some developing and industrial concentration of investment away from the tra-
countries. The aims are to determine whether ditional sector. The situations in these countries
approach gives estimates of r consistent with pro- tend to vary between those depicted in Figures I
ject experience and, second, to show how the three and 2, and are unlikely to fit Figure 1, in which
variables, i, S and r relate to the rate of economic b = n’. A high value for n’ (and thus for labor’s
growth in practice. The estimates of r are based on share in output) naturally lowers the value of r for
the NPV form of equation (17): ’ 3 given values of g and i; a low value for w raises the
value of r.
NPV = (1 -e-“‘)/r-(em”‘“-em’“)/(r-w) The upper limit for r corresponds to the case
-i(l -e-g”)/g(l +r)Li2 (19) where S = S*, labor’s share in current output, and
a value of S* based on output per worker in agri-
where L represents the average lead time of invest- culture less an allowance for operating surplus per
ment. The procedure is to scan a range of r and worker (in agriculture). Thus it is based on the
find the value which makes NPV zero. relation:
Estimated average rates of return to investment
NPV=O=
using this equation are presented for 19 countries
in Table I. The period considered is 196&8 1. The (1 --S*)(l -e-“‘)/r -i(l -e-““)/g(l +r)L*2 (20)
countries were chosen to give a broad sample in
Let us comment further on the estimates of S*.
ttrms of development, rates of growth and region.
For six of the countries listed, the operating surplus
There are five African, three Middle Eastern, five
of unincorporated enterprises (OSUE) is itemized
Asian, three Latin American and three indu-
in the national accounts, as are the wage labor
strialized countries in the sample; three of the coun-
bills of government and nongovernment activities.
tries are also major oil exporters (Saudi Arabia,
Hence, using the following definitions:
Mexico and Nigeria).
Two estimates of r are presented in the table, a W, = government wage bill as a proportion of
low estimate (in column lo), and a high estimate (national) value added;
(in column 11). Also shown (in column 12) is the W, = nongovernment wage bill also as a pro-
effect on r, for the developing countries, of includ- portion of value added;
ing current expenditures on health and education V, = value added by nongovernment activi-
in the rate of investment. Let us first consider the ties as a proportion of (national) value
reasons behind the low and high estimates of r. added; V, = I- WY;
Data on g, i, c (the labor force growth rate) and S,* = share of labor in V,; and
b = (g-c), the labor productivity growth rate, are OSUE = Operating surplus of unincorporated
shown in the first four columns. An attempt was enterprises as a proportion of (national)
also made to construct an index for the growth rate value added. Then:
of real wages (which include the imputed wages of
entrepreneurial labor). Published data relevant for s* = w,+s,*v,;
the estimate of this variable (and for labor’s share
S,,* V,, = W,+ S,,* OSUE, assuming labor’s share
in output) are surprisingly scarce or, when avail-
in output is the same in the unin-
able, are generally unreliable for developing coun-
corporated as in the incorporated
tries. The main difficulty in using these data is that
sector. Hence, on this assumption,
large proportions of the labor force are either self-
employed or family workers for whom it is difficult S* = W,,+ W,,/(l -OSUE/V,,).
to impute a wage rate, given the diversity of activi-
ties involved. Only India among the countries listed The calculations of S* using this procedure are
explicitly adjusts for this factor. Typically 3&50% shown in column (5) of Table 1; the background
of the labor force is self-employed or household data and worksheet are provided in Table 2.
workers in Latin American and Asian countries, For 13 of the countries listed no information is
and 70-90% in Africa, as compared to around published in the sources cited on OSUE, though
10% for the industrialized countries. data are available on W, and IV,. Hence an attempt
Given these uncertainties, the approach taken was made to proceed by rewriting the accounting
INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH 1067

identity for the nongovernment sector as follows: ments and the rates of redeployment of labor
would both be higher.
.s,*v, = w”+s,*(v”- w,/S”*) (21) The values of g shown in the table relate to the
Since W,, in equation (21) is the share of wage growth of GDP at factor cost, and of i to gross
labor in value added, it follows that (V, - W,/.S,*) investment. No adjustments to these figures were
represents value added by non-wage labor (as a made to allow for depreciation. When deriving
proportion of national value added). The problem the relationships discussed in Section 2 and 3, the
at hand, given that W, and V, are known, is to change in output was formulated as the derivative
determine what this quantity might be. S* would (with respect to L.)of the integral of the outputs of
then follow as before from the identity all investments in service in ~7,introduced over the
S* = W,+ .S,* V,,. Several ways of estimating the period r-n to r; a negative component of the
value added by non-wage labor were tried, of change in output thus appeared in the resulting
which the following expression gives a fairly con- expression, arising from the shift in the lower limit
servative estimate: Va(NSE/Na), where Va is the of the integral from r-n to v+dzl-n. This com-
value added in agriculture as a proportion of ponent represented the effects on output of the
national value added, NSE is the number of self- retirement of investments with zero quasi rents. In
employed and household workers in the economy, addition, the finite life of the investments leads to
and Na is the number of agricultural workers. This the appearance of the capita1 recovery factor in
estimate is conservative because NSE includes a expressions like equations (I 9) and (20). To deduct
significant fraction of nonagricultural workers official estimates of depreciation from both the
whose value added per worker, though higher than GDP and the investment series thus would be to
in agriculture, is costed at (VaiNa) in the analysis. double count costs. I4
That the proportion of household workers is Before turning to the results, a comment might
greater in agriculture (one-half to two-thirds of be added on investment in health and education.
NSE in agriculture) than in nonagricultural acti- The national accounts data cover physical invest-
vities (around a quarter, the rest being proprietors) ment only, including physical investment in health
also leads to a downward bias in the resulting and education services and in the training of the
estimate of S*. labor force. But in developing countries most
The calculations of S* using this procedure are recurrent expenditures on health, education, train-
shown in column (6) of Table 1, the background ing and agricultural extension have the effect of
data again being provided in Table 2. Comparing improving the quality (i.e. productivity) of the
the results in this column with those shown in labor force, as opposed maintaining the quality
column (5) for countries for which data on OSUE intact. At least for the developing countries, there-
were available. it can be seen that the cor- fore, such expenditures ought to be included in the
respondence is generally quite good. Also shown investment cost stream. This adjustment was made
in column (7) is an estimate of S* from the vintage in the results shown in column (I 2) of Table 1. The
model discussed in Section 2 assuming M’= 6. This general effect is to lower the returns by a factor of
estimate was made solely to begin the iterations to 1.1 to 1.3, depending on the size of such expen-
find r when using equation (2); it shows, however, ditures in relation to investment.
when comparing the results with those in column Turning to the results shown in columns (IO) and
(8) that the approximation S = S* is not a bad (I I), it is apparent that the captial accumulation
one in an economy where wages are growing in approach to growth followed in this paper does
step with output per worker, but will generally not lead to anomalously high rates of return to
overestimate the influence of investment on labor’s investment. For the three industrialized countries
income where M:< b, as we would expect. the estimated average rates of return vary between
The values of g, c, b and c used are those sum- 4.6% (United Kingdon) up to 7.6% (Japan). For
marized in the World Tables published by the the developing countries, the estimates vary from
World Bank. Assumptions were needed about the being negative (Ghana) to l2-16% for the high-
average economic lead times and lifetimes of growth countries.
investment. The values used were five years for the The results indicate that what is important for
sub-Saharan African countries listed, four years growth is neither a high rate of investment in and
for the other developing countries, and three years of itself, nor simply high social yields from invest-
for the industrialized countries. The values of n ment, but rather the product of the two, with g
used range from 15 years for the countries with being approximately equal to 3(ir). Savings and
high growth rates per worker, to 30 years for the investment are emphasized by the approach, but
slow-growth countries, the shorter lifetimes in the so are savings wisely invested - with the rewards,
high-growth cases being considered more likely on in terms of growth, being appreciable indeed. Fig-
the grounds that the rates of retirement of invest- ure 4 illustrates this point graphically by plotting
Table 1.Imputed averaqe rates of return to investment in selected countries, 1960-41

Effect on I F;
Labor Labor’s share in output S*% PV of Rate of return, r% (col. 1I)
force Labor -_.--. labor’s --- of including g
Growth Rate of growth productivity Using Using share in Rate of Using Using health and $
rate investment rate growth rate Accounts equation vintage output profit equation equation education 6
Country 9% i% C% b% data* (21) model? S%$ r*%§ (19) (20) expenditures11 2

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) z
4
Ghana 0.9 IO.5 2.0 -1.1 >lOOI -- > IOOf -1.7 _** -**
Cdte d’lvoire 7.1 22.2 4.0 3.1 64 67 69 68 9.g 9.1 9.3 8.2
Kenya 5.8 21.5 2.8 3.0 59 67 71 70 7.8 7.8 8.7 7.1
Nigeria 3.8 20.8 I.9 1.9 - 52 74 71 5.1 5.5 9.6 8.7
Sierra Leone 2.8 13.6 1.3 I.5 - 52 78 75 4.5 6.7 12.6 I I.0

Egypt 6.2 21.3 2.1 4.1 -- 57 71 58 10.8 12.4 12.7 Il.6


Turkey 5.7 20.9 1.8 3.9 - 57 66 60 9.7 II.6 12.5 10.2
Saudi Arabia 10.1 20.1 3.3 6.8 - 35 55 40 22.5 21.4 25.9 ma.

India 3.6 19.6 I.6 2.0 71 77 71 68 5.3 6.7 4.2 4.1


Sri Lanka 4.5 19.0 2.1 2.4 - 69 71 68 6.8 8.4 8.0 7.4

Korea (Republic of) 8.8 26.3 2.9 5.9 60 61 60 58 13.3 12.9 11.8 10.8
Philippines 5.7 24.4 3.4 - 58 68 67 7.5 7.8 10.4 8.7
Thailand 7.8 24.3 ::; 5.3 52 44 64 61 II.6 II.9 17.6 15.8
Brazil 6.6 22. I 3.2 3.4 53 67 65 9.7 10.3 14.0 13.5
Colombia 5.4 22.0 3.1 2.3 16 13 71 70 7.0 1.3 6.4 6.1
Mexico 7.0 23.2 3.1 3.9 45 63 61 11.0 11.5 15.9 14.5

Japan 7.5 34.7 1.6 5.9 74 68 61 61 8.4 7.6 5.2 -


United Kingdom 2.3 18.3 0.4 1.9 75 75 74 71 3.3 5.5 4.3
llnited States 3.6 19.0 1.6 2.0 71 70 76 74 4.6 5.8 6.9
___._._ ___~
Sources: values of 9. i and c are taken from World Bank (1983). Estimates of S* are derived from the data presented in Table 2.
The values of n and L were assumed to be as follows: L = five years for the African countries, four years for other developing countries, and three years for the
industrialized countries; n = 30 years for the slow-growth countries (where the rate of “turnover” of investment is low) with output per worker growth rates, b, of less
than 2% per year; 25 years for countries with h in the range 2 3%; 20 years for countries with b in the range 3-5%; and 15 years when b > 5% per year.
*Using the relation S* = W,,/(I -OSLJE/V,)+ W,, where W, is the share of nongovernment wages, W, of government wages and OSUE of the operating surplus of
unincorporated enterprises in value added. V, = (I - W,). Data on W,, I+‘, and OSUE are provided in Table 2.
tFor the pure vintage model that generates equations (6) and (7) in Section 2, the value of S* is given by:

S* = @/c)(e-“-e~v’)/(l -e-““). LZ
fThe ratio of the second term to the first in equation (19). evaluated at the equalizing discount rate (T, shown in column IO), assuming w = h.
Or* = (1 - S’)g/i. T
1li.e.. current expenditures on health and education, since investment expenditures on these items are already included in the figures for investment. Health and education
expenditures are also tabulated in the above source and vary from l-.5% of GDP. To obtain the estimates in column (12), column (I I) is multiplied by I/( I +current 2
health and education expenditures per unit of GDP). The exercise was not done for the industrialized countries.
TValues of S* and S > 100% are feasible for a period if capital stock and inventories are being consumed (as happened in Ghana in the 1970s). R
**No feasible value exists because the benefit and cost streams are both negative. The analysis thus works with the rate of profit instead, as a proxy, shown in column 0
(9).
B
i;
8
Table 2. Worksheets for estimates of labor’s share in current output in the 1960s and 1970s
E
Value added % Labor
Split of W between in force Fz
Wages as government and nongovernment agriculture in Labor force S* from Estimates of S* from accounts data Fz
% of GDP as % GDP Agriculture self-employed equation (21) s
country W W,% W”% Va% Na% NSE% S% * OSUE as % GDP s*t s
;;;
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
3
Ghana 84 8 76 53 58 73 >I00
Cote d’lvoire 43 II 32 35 81 89 67 35 62
Kenya 40 10 30 40 80 85 67 353 56
Nigeria 27 5 22 40 60 76 525
Sierra Leone 29 8 21 38 70 89 52

Egypt 47 1011 37 30 55 36 57
Turkey 31 10 21 32 45 70 57
Saudi Arabia 15 6 9 - 35ll

India** 77 - 77**
Sri Lanka 47 4 43 32 55 56 69

Korea, (Republic of) 39 5 34 28 45 60 61 36 58


Philippines 36 6 30 28 50 71 58
Thailand 28 4 24 35 78 85 44 48 50
Brazil (45)tt 8 (37) 14 40 45 (53)
Colombia 44 7 37 33 35 43 73 43 72
Mexico 40 8 32 12 40 38 45

Japan 60 5 55 7 22 36 68 18 72
United Kingdom 68 6 62 2 3 14 75 9 74
United States 69 13 53 3 4 IO 70 8 70

Sources: W, I+‘, and W, are obtained from the UN, Yearbooks of Ndonal Accounts Starisrics and are rough averages. The Operating Surplus of Unincorporated
Enterprises (OSUE) shown in column (8) was taken from the same source. Note that the values of W, W, and W, and OSUE are expressed as percentages of GDP at
factor cost. Va and Na are tabulated in World Bank (1983). Data on NSE are published by the ILO, (various years), but for some countries were only available for one
or two years in the period; estimates of NSE are approximate, and based on spotty data.
*I.e., S* = Wg+ W./(l -x). where x = (Va.NSE)/( V,Na).
tAs estimated from S* = W,+ W,/( I -OSUE/V,). 2
$For Kenya, OSUE is taken to be the sum of the output of the “semi-monetary” sector plus the marketed production of small farms and businesses. See Hazlewood 3
(1979), chapters 3, and 5 for data.
§For the non-oil economy, S* is about 70%. 3
/IA nominal figure, taken for this exercise (Egypt does not publish estimates of W,).
IAssuming S* is 60% for the non-oil sector of economy, which accounted for about 45% of value added, on average, over the period, and dividing the nongovernment 2
wage bill (W,) between the oil and non-oil sectors in the ratio (I-0.45) to (0.45). The value of S* is then W,+O.SSW,+O.6 x 0.45 = 35% (rounded).
**Indian statistics estimate labor’s share in current output directly, “including part of net operating surplus of unincorporated enterprises which cannot be separated
Z
from income on own account.
ttAgain, a nominal figure taken for this exercise, since W is not published in the sources cited. An analysis of wages in Brazil is to be found in PfetTermann and Webb #
(1979). 0
1072 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

II-

IO - 0 +

-9 -
+ 0

f”-
0 +
e + 0
o+ 0 +
;’ 0 +
E _
8” +o
08 o++”
‘ij5-
30
+ High value of R
&I-
+8e + 0 LOW VclLue of R
3-
0 +
+o
2-

I -

I I I I I
200 loo 300 500
Rate of Investment times the rate of return (ir )
Figure 4. Economic growth us investment times its yield.

the product i. r against g. The high and low esti- (1957), is to estimate a production function of the
mates of r discussed above are identified separately form Q = A exp &f) F(K,L), where A exp (&,r)
in the figure so as to show the effects of the uncer- represents the technical progress, or the “resi-
tainties (regarding the treatment of labor’s share) dual”) and A is a constant. From this,
on the results; the uncertainties are not small, but
also not such as to obscure the rule just stated. 9 = @7,+(J --)g,+g, (22)
Regrettably, the data on labor’s share are not good whereg,g, andg, are the rates ofgrowth of output.
enough for a third element to be investigated, capital and labor (in person hours), tl = pK/Q is
which is that high growth rates might also be ach- capital’s share in output, and (I --3~) = M,L/Q is
ieved with higher returns to labor than many devel- labor’s share in output. ” The other approach is to
oping countries have achieved in the past. This work with the “fundamental accounting identity”
subject has been examined extensively elsewhere (Jorgenson and Griliches, (1967) in which the total
however, ” and, broadly speaking, we might value of outputs equals the total value of inputs,
amend the opening statement of this paragraph or, at an aggregate level, Q = pK+ wL. If Q, K, \t
and conclude that what matters for growth is the (wage rates) and L are changing over time, then,
product of three variables: the rate of investment. from this identity,
the returns to investment, and the investment-
induced returns to labor. 9 = ag, f(J -~)g1_+(l-~)g. (23)
where g,, is the rate of growth of real wages.
Comparing equations (22) and (23). g,, =
5. RELATION TO CURRENT (1 -x)9,*; hence most of the attempts to explain
APPROACHES TO GROWTH or whittle down the residual since Solow’s article
ACCOUNTING have amounted to accounting for the growth
of real wages - associated, for instance. with
Growth accounting studies generally work with changes in the educational, age (experience), and
the rate of profit, p. rather than the rate of return. skill compositions of the labor force, and with the
To simplify algebra and to make comparisons, the redeployment of labor from low to higher wage
following analysis uses the rate of profit analogues sectors, as described in Section 2. The rate of
of the relationships derived earlier. growth of labor’s income is usually divided into
Assessments of the contribution of investment four parts: changes in the number of employed
to growth have been based on two essentially equi- people. in their hours of work. in their educational
valent approaches. ” The first, following Solow levels. and in their occupations or sectors of work.
INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH 1073

Letting N denote the number of workers, H their (I- r)gL* +gy*, where go* is a new residual, vari-
hours of work, and for simplicity taking H to be ously termed total factor productivity (TFP), out-
the same for all categories of worker. put growth due to advances in knowledge, or
technical progress (TP). It is apparent that, from
WL = NH~e,~s,,w,, (24) this definition of gL*. TFP or TP is the fifth term
J I
on the right-hand side of equation (25) multiplied
where e, is the proportion of the total labor force by (1 -c(); i.e., and substituting for NH/wL
(in worker hours) in education group i with from equation (24),
Ze, = I; wi/ denotes the wages of workers of edu-
cation i in occupation or sector i; and sii is the TFPorTP =
share of workers with education i in sectorj, with
Z/s,, = I. Differentiating, omitting second-order
terms, and dividing by wL,
1 d(wL) 1 dN 1 dH That is, TFP or TP is the sum of the wage growth
-.p = N.X + H’Z (quantityinputs) rates of labor within the various educational and
WL dt
occupational groups, weighted by the shares of
NH de, each group in value added.
+ wL c dr c sbwij (quality adjustments)
I Expressions (25) and (26) reveal three points of
I
departure between current approaches to growth
+ gx e, c we% (gains from redeployment) accounting and the capital accumulation approach
t I to growth: the treatment of technical progress; the
NH dw, (wage growth ostensibly analysis of economic efficiency; and the com-
+ wL, c e, Isof without quality change plementarities among physical investment, human
1 I or redeployment) (25) investment and the deployment of labor.
As regards the treatment of technical progress,
where wL/NHis the average wage per worker hour. terms like equation (26) have been left in labor’s
The first three terms on the right-hand side of account in the present analysis (as the expression
equation (25) follow Jorgenson and Griliches suggests they should be) when imputing the returns
(1967) and Grilliches (1970) except that I have also to investment from growth rates of output and
disaggregated by sector to identify redeployment wages. They have also been left in when suggesting
effects on labor’s income. The first four terms on how growth rates of output might be estimated
the right-hand side are similar to those in the dis- from assumptions about the rates of invest-
aggregated study of Nishimizu and Hulten (1978). ment, the returns to investment, the deployment of
Considering each term in turn, the first two rep- labor, and the rates of growth of wages. In other
resent changes in quantity inputs, and the third words, following Scott (1981, 1986), no “residual
the familiar quality adjustments for changes in the account” is kept open to represent the effects on
educational composition of the labor force. The growth of TP. The residual is zero, by definition
fourth represents the effects on labor’s income of of the accounting convention used (the social rate
shifts in the sectoral or occupational composition of return convention), and the effects of TP on
of (each education group of) the labor force. The output are reflected in the returns to labor and the
fifth represents wage growth over time of labor returns to investment.
within given educational and sectoral or occu- In adopting this convention, the intention is not
pational categories. As indicated, this term repre- to suggest that TP is unimportant or that its role
sents wage growth ostensibly without changes in in economic growth would be “catastrophically
the quality of labor, and also without redeploy- reduced” if the residual (as it is usually estimated)
ment, because these two effects are intended to be were small or zero, as Kennedy and Thirlwall
measured by the third and fourth terms; in prac- (1972) suggested it would be in reference to Jorg-
tice, however, both quality changes and redeploy- enson and Griliches (1967). Rather, technical pro-
ment may be appreciable within any i,jgroup even gress, in the generic sense, is give a greater role by
if, as discussed in Section 2, one is working at quite the capital accumulation approach: its con-
high levels of disaggregation, so that significant tribution can be seen as being closer to the early
quality changes and redeployment effects may be estimates of Abramovitz, Solow, Kuznets and
unintentionally included in the fifth term. others, in which it was estimated to account for
Growth accounting studies generally estimate around 90% of output growth as opposed to the
the first four terms on the right-hand side of 3650% figures later suggested by the growth
equation (25) to obtain an estimate of the rate of accounting procedures just discussed.
growth of the quality-and deployment - adjusted Consider again, for instance, the relation
labor force. Denote this by gL*. Then g = ag,+ g = uir/(l -S), and suppose that new techniques
1074 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

with higher outputs per worker were not intro- in the social as in the physical sciences, to compare
duced - neither through new investment nor outputs with inputs directly. This is the basic case
through improvements to investments in place. Let for comparing the value of output changes with
the value of g.in these circumstances be g,. Since the costs of achieving them using the economist’s
this would be a static economy with constant real measure of economic efficiency. the social rate of
wages and output levels, the present value of return or NPV of investment. Its use does not
labor’s share in output would equal labor’s share preclude the analysis of the various causal factors
in current output, so that S = (1 -a). Also, the to which Denison refers, such as the relative con-
lifetimes of the investments would be large, assum- tributions of physical and human capital to the
ing maintenance is uridertaken as required, and so growth of output - though such contributions
u = 1. Hence g, = air/(l-S) = ir+(l -a)g,. But need to be assessed in terms of their total rather
ir = ug,, so that g,, which under the preceding than their partial effects on output, as discussed
conditions falls to gL, can be written as g, = below.
ag,+(l -cZ)g,.‘* This means that without new Instead, use of NPV raises additional questions,
techniques and the redeployment of labor to utilize such as are expenditures on physical and human
them, the growth rate of output collapses to a rate investment, and the policies which bear on the
corresponding to the quantity inputs of labor and rate and composition of such expenditures, being
capital only. (The accounting identities derived in applied efficiently to the task’of rasing output? Is
this paper thus fit this special case of no TP.) Hence there too little investment in raising the quality
the difference between such an economy and an of labor given the technologies available and the
economy in which technical progress is taking amount of physical investment taking place? Con-
place is given by (recalling equation 22 above), versely, is there too little physical investment to
fruitfully employ increasingly educated and skilled
g, = g-Ugk--(l -a)gL = oir/(l -g-g,
workers capable, if they had the tools at their dis-
Hence the capital accumulation approach to posal, of raising the output of investment? In
growth (as I have attempted to interpret it in this addressing these and other such questions, it is
paper), measures the “fruits” of technical progress necessary to compare outputs with inputs, specifi-
( ga) in terms of their effects on the returns to labor cally, the present value of output changes with the
and to capital. ’ 9 present value of the investment and rising real
This result raises the issue, long noted by Deni- labor costs of achieving changes. The labor costs
son, that a small or zero contribution of TFP to would be estimated at prevailing real wage rates
growth can be correct “onZy, if.. . procedures have over the periods in question, and would include
the effect of reclassifying.. a contribution of out- allowances for real wage growth uithin well-
put per unit input to an input contribution.“” defined educational and occupational groups (the
In a much cited critique of Jorgenson and Gri- fifth term in equation (25) as well as for real wage
liches (1967), Denison concludes that growth arising from redeployment or changes in
the quality of labor (the third and fourth terms).
there is an advantage in matching growth sources Thus all five terms on the right-hand side of equa-
with the reasons that income changes, and I have tried tion (25) are relevant. Together they represent the
to adhere to this principle in my own work. rising opportunity costs of labor. It seems impor-
In particular, confusion and misinterpretation are tant for an economy, if it is to raise real wages as
avoided if the contribution of capital is identified well as real output, to assess its policies in terms of
with changes in income that result from investment,
their capacity to generate positive quasi rents in
and the contribution of advances in knowledge is
identified with changes in income that result from ad- the presence of rising real wages.
vances in technical and managerial knowledge. and If one must allow for the full costs of labor in
that can be altered by changing the state of know- the analysis of how economic policies affect
ledge. Confusion is hard to avoid if the consequences growth, and not just the quality - and occu-
of advances in knowledge are classified as contribu- pation ~ adjusted costs of labor (the first four
tions of capital.*’ terms on the right-hand side of equation (25) the
following question arises: is there any purpose in
These remarks indicate the second point of separating out the effects of education and
departure between the capital accumulation ap- redeployment on real wages from those within nar-
proach to growth and current approaches. which rowly defined educational and occupational
relates to the measurement and analysis of eco- groups?
nomic efficiency. It seems reasonable that, if the The position here is that the analysis of the con-
economist is seeking to determine how perceived tribution of education to growth should surely not
efficiencies or inefficiencies in economic policies end with the estimation of terms like the third and
affect the rate of economic growth. it is necessary, fourth on the right-hand side of equation (25). It
INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH I075

seems likely, as Bowman (1980) suggested, that of recruitment to the civil service and business man-
the approach significantly understates education’s agement..
contribution to growth in many ways. Blaug (1976) He notes the waste involved in “not planning for
has noted several ambiguities in the assumptions the required complementarities, and pushing edu-
and evidence underlying human capital theory. cation too far.. .r’24 In general, it is the joint
In addition, the returns to human investment so returns to human and material investment that are
estimated are necessarily based on the derived important for growth. In Sections 2 and 3. an
demands for various qualities of labor and assume attempt was made to allow for interdependence by
that the complementary physical investments are considering the joint returns to physical and human
in place; they are higher than the joint returns investment, and by considering the effects of these
to human and physical investment except in the (joint) investments on the returns to labor, as well
special case where they equal the marginal cost of as on the returns to investment itself.
capital. ** Then there are the problems of dis-
aggregation discussed in Section 2(a) and of the
human and material investment requirements of
raising labor productivity within even narrowly 6. CONCLUSIONS
defined sectors.
Regarding the complementarities between The above analysis sought to show how a coun-
physical and human investment, and also between try’s rate of economic growth can be expressed in
physical investment and the redeployment of terms of variables representing the size and quality
labor, it seems important to recognize that it is of its investment portfolio. The size of the portfolio
the total rather than the partial changes that are is determined by the rate and its quality by the
relevant for identifying changes in income that allocative efficiency of investment. The principal
result from investment. The redeployment of labor relationships derived were based on an accounting
from rural to urban areas, for example, requires identity for the social rate of return to investment.
appreciable human and physical investment in In this identity the present values of output
urban areas; investment is also needed in rural increases arising from economic investments were
areas where agricultural output per worker must compared with the present values of the costs of
be raised to meet the rising food demands of urban achieving them. The underlying aim was to arrive
areas, when the size of the agriculture labor force at a means for analyzing how the efficiency of
is in relative or absolute decline. The redeployment economic policies affects the rate of economic
of labor from small-scale to large-scale industries growth.
or from lower- to higher-technology industries as The analysis departs in several respects from the
industrialization proceeds similarly requires physi- methods followed in a number of growth account-
cal as well as human investment. As Nelson (1973) ing studies over the past 30 years, in which
remarked, in the absence of investment in new investment’s contribution to growth was estimated
technologies “educated workers would be doing to be small. Following the lead of Maurice Scott,
nothing different than uneducated workers and the analysis suggests instead that when efficiently
would not be more productive,” and it can be applied to the task of raising output, investment
misleading to suggest what education did or might accounts for most of a country’s growth. Con-
contribute to growth without reference to the versely, when inefficiently applied, it accounts for
physical investments (and the policies that bear on most of a country’s decline or stagnation. Much
them) required to employ the educated workers emphasis was placed on the product of the rate of
fruitfully. In several papers, Nelson has com- investment and the social rate of return. But these
mented on the way “growth accounting tables . . were not the only variables emphasized, since the
repress interdependence” between physical and rates and choices of investments have appreciable
human investment. *’ effects on the ways in which labor is deployed and
Streeten (1970) has similarly drawn our atten- redeployed in an economy. Most growth account-
tion to the dangers of neglecting the comp- ing studies significantly underestimate these effects
lementaries among education, material investment both in “positive” instances, when labor is re-
and economic policy. He comments that in devel- deployed productively, and in “negative” instances
oping countries: when it is not. Finally, the analysis did not follow
The isolation of “educational” expenditure (in
the common practice of placing the benefits of
growth accounting studies) may distract attention technical progress in a residual account, separate
from the urgent need. not only to select the right type from those accounts representing the returns to
of education, but also to combine it with the provision labor and the returns to investment; in practice,
of better seeds. drainage and fertilisers, with improve- and once the total effects of investment on output
ments in transport and birth control, with a reform are considered, the benefits must appear in one or
1076 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

the other of the latter two accounts. Again fol- political shocks, and even droughts may be exam-
lowing Scott’s lead, it was argued that a residual ined through their effects on the variables dis-
account is not needed and that its closure might cussed - on the rate and composition of invest-
greatly facilitate the analysis of the influence of ment, on the social returns to new investments
economic policy on growth. and to investments in place, on the deployment of
Reworking growth accounting relationships in labor, and on real wage rates. A full discussion
this way need not rest on assumptions about the of the applications of the analysis to developing
“stylized facts” of growth. Indeed, departures from countries was beyond the scope of the paper. But
them - such as increases or decreases in the rates one general conclusion is likely to emerge from
of investment, in the social returns to investment, further analysis. It is that wise policies toward
and in labor’s share in output - are highlighted by investment in a country’s physical and human
the approach. In this respect, the approach seems resources are likely to be thrice blest: they would
especially relevant to the circumstances of the raise the rate of investment, the social returns to
developing countries. Furthermore, it need not investment, and the investment-induced returns to
concern itself only with the long-run aspects of labor. It is the three together which represent the
development, since the cumulative effects of (for total effects of investment, and of the policies that
instance) business cycles, changes in terms of trade, bear on it.

NOTES

1. Scott (1981, 1986, and 1989). loss.. The lines of the relationship between absolute
increases in population, labor force and capital on the
2. Methods of estimating depreciation in national as one hand, and growth in per capita product on the other,
in private accounts generally bear no relation to what are numerous and far reaching.. in ways that make it
determines actual maintenance requirements, and may dificult, if not impossible, to establish the correct partial
lead to a double counting of costs (see Section 4). The effects of increases in inputs of man hours and capital on
costs of maintenance include: (a) the costs of establishing growth of per capita product.”
maintenance workshops, equipment and machines (rou- I noted in the introduction that Scott (1981, 1986)
tinely included in an industry’s investment expenditure was critical of vintage theory. His problem is with the
streams); (b) the costs of labor; (c) spare parts and assumption that exogenous technical proress affects
materials; and (d) the “down times” of the machines growth like “manna from heaven” and that: “later vin-
and factories being maintained (reflected in the observed tages of capital goods are better than earlier ones just
values of output). because they are later, so that their efficiency is purely a
matter of time and nothing to do with investment or the
3. A fuller discussion appears in Section 5. The fol- yield of investment itself. In vintage theory this is pre-
lowing paragraphs draw on Grilliches (1970). cisely what is assumed to happen, but it is wildly implaus-
ible. It implies, for example, that if no investment had
4. Schulz (1970) questioned this last view of women’s taken place anywhere in the world between 1881 and
contribution to the growth of economic output drawing 198 1 we would have been able to build jet aeroplanes and
attention to the “troublesome omission” of investment electric computers despite this century of stagnation.”
in females and by them in the upbringing of children. Actually, vintage theory assumes growth is possible onI>
i/new investments embodying higher outputs per worker
5. See Hoselitz (19S9, 1968), Staley and Morse (1965). are in fact taking place. Also, as I hope the above analysis
Banerji (1978) and Anderson (1982). On small-scale shows, the investments have to have positive yields. While
industries, see also Chuta and Liedholm (1985). it would be desirable to treat technical progress endogen-
ously (and Scott’s book takes us a long way in this direc-
6. See Shinohara (1968) on wage differentials between tion) it does not undermine the ideas of technical progress
large and small firms in Japan. being embodied in investment.

7. See Johnston and Kilby (1975).


IO. These expenditures are routinely treated as invrst-
ment in the analysis of agricultural projects. See Gittinger
8. See Anderson (1987) for a discussion of this case,
(1982) and Baum and Tolbert (1985).
and also the analysis of Stewart (1977).

9. Both Cairncross and Kuznets were careful to qual- Ii. Anderson (1987), Part 111.
ify their conclusions about the apparently small con-
tribution of investment to growth. Thus Kuznets (1966. 12. Anderson (1987), Part 111.
p. 85) notes that “the low proportions of growth in per
capita product allocated to increased output of man-
hours and capital do not mean that the absence of such an 13. The averaging symbols used in Section 3 have been
input would have resulted in only a small proportionate omitted to simplify notation.
INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH 1077

14. Another way of making the same point is to note 19. c.f. the growth model suggested by Eltis (1973. ch.
that the investment cost term in expressions like (6) and 6) in which he proposed putting g0 = a+ bi, where n and
(20) can bc written as: b are parameters. If b is rewritten as ar/( 1 -s) to allow
for the efficiency of investment, and also for the effects

c’ iQ.@‘dr/Q,F
of TP on labor’s income. and o = gL, a similar model
follows from the above analysis.

(neglecting the costs of lead-times), where Q0 is value 20. Denison (1969) p. 26. Both in earlier papers and
added at f = 0. The numerator of this expression equals since he has also dismissed the “embodied question” as
capital stock in seroice, so that capital stock no longer in being unimportant, and thus further delinked the gains
service is excluded. from technical progress from investment. See Denison
(1964) in reference to Solow (1957, 1963). As Kennedy
15. On agriculture, see Johnston and Kilby (1975) and and Thirlwall (1972, p. 138) observed, he considered the
Mellor (1976); on industry, Little, Scitovsky and Scott effects of new vintages of investments on output to work
(1970),Myint(l971,Chapter 14),Balassa(l971),Stewart only through the average age of capital stock and ignored
(1977) and Ranis (1973). The IL0 mission’s report on point that the average vintage of investment progresses
the Phillipines, led by Ranis, gives a wide-ranging review by about one year each year; if the newer vintages indeed
of the evidence for both agriculture and industry: IL0 reflect investments with higher outputs per worker, sig-
(1974). nificant growth may arise whether the average age of the
capital stock rises or falls. See also Abramovitz (1962).
Balogh and Streeten (1963). and Currie (1986).
16. The literature on the subject is huge, and one necess-
arily must start with the papers and books of those who 21. Denison (1969). p. 27.
have reviewed it; e.g., Nelson (1981) Binswanger and
Ruttan (1978), Kennedy and Thirlwall(1972), Hahn and 22. Letting subscripts f and h denote physical and
Matthews (1967). and the readings in Sen (1970) and human investment respectively, the cost of capital (mea-
Stiglitz and Uzawa (1969). For historical and cross-coun- sured as a rate of profit) be pc, the incremental output
try comparisons see Kuznets ‘(1966); for a review of less incremental labor cost be (Q - wL) and incremental
material and a study on Japan see Nishimizu and Jorg- investments be I, then the joint rate of profit p = (Q - wL)/
enson (1978) and Denison and Chung (1976); on US (I,+&,) whereas the derived rates of profit are
estimates, Denison (1962 and 1964); on US and Europe, P,= ~~Q--W--b~,ll4 and ph = KQ-W-JP~I/L In
Denison (1967). A review is also provided in Maurice general p,, and p, are both greater than p unless p,, and
Scott’s (1989) book on growth. The preceding list is p, = pc-. from which p = p< also. Thus rates of return or
unavoidably selective, since this paper is not a review; profit estimated from derived demand schedules can give
but the references cited in the papers of these authors misleadingly high impressions as to the rates of return to
together provide a comprehensive bibliography. particular factors; for estimating the optimum “balance”
of investments, the returns so-estimated give consistent
results, but for estimating their contributions to growth
17. Scale economies are not discussed below. it is their joint returns which are important.

18. The first term follows from ir = r(l/Q)(dK/dt), 23. See e.g. his review article (Nelson, 1981) and his
which can be rewritten as (rK/Q)(I/K)(dK/dr) = czgr. discussion of a paper by Kuznets (Nelson, 1984).
The second term can be obtained as follows: S = S*
under the present circumstances (as just shown) 24. Streeten (1970) provides a lucid critique of the
and S = wL/Q, with w(dL./dr) = S(dQ/dt) also. Hence interpretations (or misinterpretations) of the residual in
(w’L/Q)gr = (1 -a)gr = (l--a)g,. growth accounting. See also Balogh and Streeten (1963).

REFERENCES

Abramovitz, Moses, “Rapid growth potential and its countries: A discussion of issues,” World Developmen/,
realization: The experience of capitalistic economics in Vol. 10, No. 11 (1982). pp. 913-948.
the post-war period,” in Edward Malinvaud (Ed.), Balassa, Bela and Associates. The Srrucrure of Protection
Economic Growth and Resources: The Major Issues, in Deoeloping Countries (Baltimore. MD: Johns Hop-
Vol. I (London: MacMillan Press, 1979). pp. l-30. kins University Press. 1971).
Abramovitz. Moses, “Economic growth in the United Balogh, Thomas, and P. Streeten. “The coefficient of
States,” American Economic Review, Vol. 52 (September ignorance,” Bulletin qf the Oxford Institute of Econ-
1962). omits and Srutisrics (1963) pp. 307-342.
Abramovitz. Moses, “Resource and output trends in the Banerji, Ranader, “Small-scale production units in
United States since 1870,” American Economic Review, manufacturing: An international cross-section over-
Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 46 (1956). view.” ~‘elfw,ir/schu~frlhes Archb. (1978). pp. 62-82.
Anderson, Dennis, “Economic growth and the returns to Bauer. Peter T., Equ&ty, The Third World and Economic
investment,” World Bank Discussion Papers. No. I2 Delusion (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
(Washington. DC: The World Bank, 1987). 1981a).
Anderson. Dennis, “Small-scale industry in developing Bauer, Peter T. Realit! and Rheroric: Studies in the
1078 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Economics ofDer,eiopment ((Cambridge, MA: Harvard countries,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 1Y
University Press, 1981b). (1959).
Baum, Warren C., and Stokes M. Toibert, Investing in International Labor Office, Sharing in Development: A
Dmelopment -(New York: Oxford University Press, Prqqram of Employment, Equity and Growth .for the
1985). Phillipines (Geneva: ILO, 1974).
Binswanger, Hans, and Vernon Ruttan, induced Inno- International Labor Office. Yearbook of National
cation: Technology. institutions, and Development (Bal- Accounts Statisrics (Geneva: ILO. various years).
timore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1978). Johnston, Harry G. *‘Towards a generalized capital
Blaug, Mark, “The empirical study of human capital accumulation approach to economic development.” in
theory: A slightly jaundiced view,” Journal of Econ- a note entitled “Comments on Mr. John Vaisey’s
omic Literature, (I976), pp. 827-855. Paper” in OECD, The Residual Factor and Economic
Bowman, Mary J., “Education and economic growth: Growth (Paris: OECD, 1964).
An overview,” in Timothy King (Ed.), “Education and Johnston, Bruce F., and Peter Kilby. Agriculture and
income,” World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 402 Structural Transformation: Economic Strategies in Late
(Washington, DC: The World Bank, July 1980). Detsefooino Countries (London: Oxford University
Caimcross, A. K., Factors in Economic Development Press, i97j).
(London: Allen and Unwin, 1961). Jorgenson, Dale W., and Zvi Griliches, “The expla-
Chuta, Enyinna, and C. Liedholm, Emplqvment and nations of oroductivitv change,” Review of Economics
Growth in Small Scale Industry: Empirical Evidence and Statist& Vol. 34*( 1967):~~. 249-28i.
and Policy Assessment from Sierra Leone (New York: Kaldor, N., “Capital accumulation and economic
St. Martin’s Press, 1985). growth,” in F. A, Lutz and D. C. Hague (Eds.), The
Currie, Lauchlin, “Sources of growth,” World Deael- Theory of Capital (London: Macmillan, 1961), pp.
opment, Vol. 14, No. 4 (1986), pp. 541-547. 177-220.
Denison, Edward F., “Some major issues in productivity Kaldor, N., “A model of economic growth,” _&onomic
analysis: An examination of estimated by Jorgenson Journal, Vol. 67 (June 1957), pp. 591-624.
and Griliches,” Sumey of Current Business, Vol. 49, Kaldor, N., and J. A. Mirlees, “A new model ofeconomic
No. 5, Part II (May 1969). growth,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 29 (1961-
Denison, Edward F., Why Growth Rates Differ; Postwar 62), pp. 174-190.
Experience in Nine western Countries (Washington, Kennedy, C. and A. P. Thirlwall, “Technical progress: A
DC: The Brookines Institution. 1967). survev.“Economic Journal, (March 1972).
Denison, Edward -F., “The unimportance of the Kuznets, Simon, Population, Capital and Growth: Selec-
embodied question,” American Economic Review ted Essavs (New York: W. W. Norton and Co. 1973).
(1964), pp. 90-94. Kuznets, ‘&mbn, Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Struc-
Denison, Edward F., “The sources of economic growth ture, and Spread (New Haven, CT: Yale University
in the United States and the alternatives before us” Press, 1966).
(New York: Committee for Economic Development, Kuznets, Simon, “Capital formation and economic
1962). growth (and some implications for the past),” in Third
Denison, Edward F., and W. K. Chung, How Japan> International Conference qf Economic Hisror.v, Munich
Economy Grew So F&t?’ The Sources of Postwar 1985 (Paris: Mouton, 1968). Reprinted in Kuznets
Expansion (Washington, DC: The Brookings lnsti- (1973).
tution. 1976). Lewis, W. Arthur, The Theory of Economic Growth
El&, W. A., Growth and Distribution (London: Macmil- (London: Allen and Unwin Twelfth Impression, 1978)
lan, 1973). [originally published 19X].
Gittinger, J. Price, Economic Anai.vsis qf Agriculture Pro- Little. I. M. D., T. Scitovsky, and M. F. Scott, Indusrr?
jects (Baltimore. MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, and Trade in Some Developing Countries (Paris: OECD.
1982). 1970).
Grilliches, Zvi, “Notes on the role of education in pro- Mellor, John W., The New Economics sf Growth: A
duction functions and growth accounting.‘* in W. Lee Sfrate.q_v .for India and the Developing Worid (Ithaca.
Hansen (Ed.) Educatzon. Income. and Human Capital. NY: Cornell University Press, 1976).
NBER Studies in Income and Wealth. Vol. 35 (New Myint. H. Economic Theory and the Underdecrloped
York: Columbia University Press, 1970). Countries (New York: Oxford University Press. 1971).
Hahn, F. H., and R. C. 0. Matthews, “The theory of Nelson. Richard R., “Comments on a paper by John
economic growth,” in AEA and RES (Ed%). Surzq,,s W. Kendrick,“in Herbert Giersch (Ed.);!Toward.c an
of Economic Theory. Vol. II: Growth and Development Esnlanation of Economic Growth (Kiel: Institiit fiir
(New York: St. Martin’s Press. 1967). pp. I-124. W;ltwirtscha& 1984) [symposium held in 19801.
Harberger, Arnold, “Three basic postulates for applied Nelson, Richard R., “Research on productivity growth
welfare economics,” Journal of Economic Literature. and productivity differences: Dead ends and new
Vol. 9, No. 3 (1971). pp. 785-797. departures,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 19
Hazlewood, Arthur, T&e Eeonom_r 41’ Kenya: The Ketl- (September 1981). pp. 1029%1064.
yatta Era (London: Oxford University Press. 1979). Nelson, Richard R.. “Recent exercises in growth
Hoselitz, Bert F.. The Role of Small Industry in the accounting: New Understanding of dead end?” Amc,r-
Process of Economic Growth (Paris: Mouton Press, ican Economic Rez?ew, Vol. 63 (1973). pp. 462468.
1968). Nishimizu. Mieko, and Charles R. Hulten, “The sources
Hoselitz. Bert F., “Small industry in underdeveloped of Japanese economic growth: 1955-71,” Review of
INVESTMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH 1079

Economics and Starisrics, Vol. 60, No. 3 (August Sen, Amartya K., (Ed.), Grousrh Economics (New York:
1978). Penguin Modern Economic Readings, 1970).
Nishimizu, Mieko, and Dale W. Jorgenson, “U.S. and Shinohara, M., “A survey of the Japanese literature on
Japanese economic growth, 1952274: An international small industry,” in Bert F. Hoselitz, The Role ofSmall
comparison,” Economic Journal, Vol. 88 (December Industry in rhe Process of Economic Growth (Paris:
1978) pp. 707-726. Mouton, 1968).
Pfeffennann, Guy P., and Richard Webb, “The dis- Solow, Robert M.. Growth Theory: An E.rposition (New
tribution of income in Brazil,” World Bank Staff York: Oxford University Press, 1970).
Working Paper No. 356 (Washington, DC: The World Solow, Robert M., Capital Theory and the Rare ofReturn,
Bank, 1979). Professor Dr. R. F. De Vries Lecture (Amsterdam:
Ranis, G., “Industrial sector labor absorption,” Econ- North-Holland, 1963).
omic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 21 (April Solow, Robert M., “Technical change and the aggregate
1973). production function” Review of Economics and Star-
Robinson, Sherman, *‘Sources of growth in less &tics, Vol. 39 (August 1957) pp. 79-115.
developed countries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Stalev. Eueene. and Richard Morse. Modern Small-Scale
Vol. 85 (1972). pp. 391408. In&r?, for Developing Countries (New York:
Salter, W. E. G., Productivity and Technical Change, McGraw-Hill, 1965).
2nd edition (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Stewart, Frances, Technology and Underdevelopment
1966) [originally published 19601. (Boulder, CO: Westview. 1977).
Schultz, Theodore W., “The reckoning of education as Streeten, Paulp’A critique of the ‘capi&/output ratio’
human capital. ” in W. Lee%iansen (Ed.). Education, and its application to. development planning,‘7
Income and Human Capilal, NBER Studies in Income reprinted from Gunnar Myrdbl’s Asian Drama (1968)
and Wealth, No. 35 (New York: Columbia University as chapter 6 iti P. Streeten, The Frontiers of Devel-
Press, 1970). opment Studies (London: Macmillan, 1972).
Scott, Maurice, A New Theory of Economic Growth (New Streeten, Paul, “Economic development and education,”
York: Oxford University Press, 1989). in A. R. Desai (Ed.), Essays on Modernisation of Unde-
Scott, Maurice, “Explaining,economic growth,” Keynes veloped Societies (1971), Vol. 1, Ch. 21, pp. 324347.
Lecture in Economics, Read to the British Academy Stiglitz. Joseph E., and Hirofumi Uzawa (Eds.), Readings
(November 11, 1986). in the Modern Theory of Economic Growth (Cambridge,
Scott, Maurice, “The contribution of investment of MA: MIT Press, 1969).
growth,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. United Nations, Yearbook of National Accounts Slaristics
28, No. 3 (November 1981). (New York: United Nations, various years).
Sen, Amartya K., “Development: Which way now?” World Bank, World Tables, 3rd edition (Washington,
Economic Journal, Vol. 93 (December 1983), pp. 745- DC: The World Bank, 1983).
762.

You might also like