Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 7

EnergyPolic3'. Vol. 23, No. 10, pp. 871477.

1995
~]E UTTE RwO RTH Copyright © 1995 Elsevier Science Ltd
IN E M A N N
Printed in Great Britain. All rights reserved
0301-4215/95 $10.00 + 0.00
0301-4215(95)000126-3

The changing structure of the


international oil industry

Implications for OPEC

Kathleen L Abdalla
United Nations Economic and Social Commission/br Western Asia, PO Box 927124, Amman, Jordan

This paper examines the changes in international oil market structure observed in the 1980s
and early 1990s and assesses possible effects on oil market conditions in the future and implica-
tions for OPEC. it focuses on the trend toward a more vertical organization mainly resulting
from substantial purchases of downstream assets by state owned oil companies in major oil pro-
ducing countries. While the Gulf war prevented greater horizontal concentration ofoil reserves,
it merely interrupted the trend toward vertical concentration in the international oil industry.
The vertical integration of only some of the OPEC members will cause a further divergence of
goals within the organization resulting in a lower likelihood of OPEC regaining its former posi-
tion as an effective cartel. If the trend toward greater vertical concentration increases, future oil
prices will, in part, be affected by decisions made by vertically integrated firms.
Kevwords: Oil; OPEC; Organization

The Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries which came about by Libya's ability to exploit the weak
(OPEC) I has undergone many changes since its incep- position of the independent producer, was the first step
tion in 1960. it has evolved from a loosely organized in the break down of the vertical organization of the oil
group in the 1960s to a powerful cartel in the 1970s and industry. During OPEC's most successful years its con-
early 1980s to a group with varied objectives in the trol over the industry represented a significant degree of
1980s and 1990s. For the past ten years or so OPEC has horizontal concentration. Oil market conditions during
grappled with the problem of satisfying the different the 1980s and 1990s, however, led some OPEC mem-
goals of its members with varying degrees of success. bers to consider vertical organization as a means of en-
For some time OPEC has faced a situation of relatively hancing their market positions. This paper argues that
low oil prices and conflicting goals among the members those members with a vertically organized industry
have led to production over agreed upon levels by some structure will have different goals from other members
members with excess capacity. The past success of of OPEC and these differences will contribute to the
OPEC as a working cartel was in part due to the advent weakness of the cartel.
of independent oil companies which added a degree of Historically the oil industry provides classic textbook
competition to the industry and, most importantly, pro- examples of monopolistic, oligopolistic and competitive
vided an alternative outlet for emerging national oil com- market structures as well that of an effectively operating
panies (Schneider, 1983). The Tripoli agreement in 1971, cartel. The production level and ultimate price charged
for oil has depended, along with other factors, on the
IOPEC comprises Algeria, Gabon, Indonesia, lran, lraq, Kuwait, market structure prevailing at any given time. While
Libya, Nigeria, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates and
Venezuela. Ecuador withdrew its membership in 1992 and indications many analysts focus on reserves, production capacity
are that Gabon may withdraw soon. and expected demand when forecasting future oil market

Energy PolicT 1995 Volume 23 Number 10 871


The oil mdust O, and OPEC: K L Abdalla

trends, recent changes in the market structure of the in- secured large concessions in countries with proven or
dustry may also have an impact on production and prices potential oil reserves. The control over world supply and
well into the 21 st century. distribution by the Seven Sisters, as they came to be
Throughout the history of the oil industry, political known, became a classic case of a highly concentrated,
developments have influenced its structure. The Sherman oligopolistic market structure in a vertically organized
Anti-trust Law passed in 1890 was partially a result of industry. 2
public indignation of John D Rockefeller's control over The 1960s and early 1970s saw the dissolution of the
the US oil industry at the time. It was used to break up control of the Seven Sisters over the production of oil.
the integrated Standard Oil Company early in the 20th OPEC was founded in 1960 but, during the 1960s, con-
century. More recently, Iraq's invasion of Kuwait was, tinued to compete for market share. In the meantime
among other things, an attempt by Iraq to gain greater many countries nationalized their oil assets or found
control over world reserves and thus supply. A greater other means to take control over their reserves. The
horizontal concentration of the oil industry would have long-term concessions previously granted to the oil
resulted if lraq had been successful. The political and companies were significantly altered or rendered null
military intervention on the part of the international and void. This trend gave rise to the establishment of na-
community prevented further concentration of the in- tional or state-owned oil companies in the 1960s and
dustry as effectively as the US Justice Department did 1970s which were basically owned and controlled by the
almost a century earlier. countries themselves. The vertical organization of the oil
By 1990, there were other less visible trends which industry was broken and the major international oil com-
would ultimately affect market concentration. A change panies became purchasers of oil produced by the na-
in the ownership patterns in the refining and distribution tional oil companies in the producing countries. The
processes had been under way, as the entire downstream private oil companies, though, still owned downstream
side of the industry had been restructured. Companies operations, refineries and marketing facilities, in major
were consolidated and unprofitable concerns, especially oil consuming countries.
refineries, were closed throughout the 1980s. A more This significant change in oil industry structure, how-
cooperative atmosphere between oil producers and com- ever, did not result in a greater degree of competitive-
panies in major consuming countries was emerging as ness. OPEC began operating as an effective cartel in
companies began securing reserves all over the world. the early 1970s when its members successfully imple-
At the same time major oil producing countries were mented production quotas which resulted in higher
purchasing downstream facilities in oil importing coun- prices. OPEC virtually controlled prices throughout the
tries. A 'verticalization' of the industry was quietly 1970s and became a classic example of a working cartel.
occurring as upstream and downstream sectors of the Although vertical integration had been effectively weak-
industry became more integrated. ened, the oil industry remained highly concentrated. The
While political events in the Gulf may have inter- short-run demand and supply were both inelastic with
rupted this trend temporarily, indications are that the respect to price, allowing OPEC to maintain control over
restructuring of the oil industry is continuing. This prices using production quotas in the short run. OPEC
paper examines the trend toward a greater degree of con- met other conditions of a successful short-term cartel
centration in the industry during the 1980s and 1990s including concentration of production, few available
and suggests that the emerging market structure, not- substitutes and substantial cost differences among
ably the trend toward vertical concentration, may have producers (Eckbo, 1975).
a long-term impact on OPEC's production decisions and Necessary conditions for a longer lasting agreement
prices. were not satisfied and eventually the cartel functioned
less efficiently. The high prices affected consumption
Background of the structure of the oil and production patterns. Though it took some time for
a number of reasons, consumers eventually undertook
market
measures both to conserve oil and to substitute other en-
While the history of the international oil industry is well ergy products for oil where possible. In addition, the
known, it is relevant here to very briefly review trends high prices encouraged the development of high cost oil
post-World War 2 related to market structure develop- reserves in non-OPEC countries which had not been
ment. Immediately after the war, a number of Western
companies actively sought to develop reserves outside 2The Seven Sisters were Standard Oil Company of New Jersey (now
their own boundaries continuing a process which had Exxon), Royal Dutch Shell, Mobil, Texaco, Anglo-Iranian Oil Com-
pany (now British Petroleum), Standard Oil Company of California
begun before the war (Yergin, 1991 ; Sampson, 1975). Seven (now Chevron) and Gulf Oil Corporation (acquired by Chevron in
major firms, which had come to dominate the industry, 1984).

872 Energy Polio, 1995 Volume 23 Number 10


The oil indusoy and OPEC. K L Abdalla

economically fcasible as well as provided an inccntivc Table I Access to refinery facilities in other countries of selected
to engage in costly exploration activities. As a result, oil producing countries (thousand barrels/day)
demand was somewhat curbed and supply grcatly in- Country 1983 1987
creased in the long run. Significant oil reserves were Kuwait 0 133
Libya 105 105
discovered and developed in many areas of thc world in- Saudi Arabia 0 8~6
cluding Alaska, the North Sea, Egypt and Yemen. Con- United Arab Emirates 0 346
ditions for a longer lasting cartel, including a lack of or Venezuela 294 1355
a minimum level of government involvement, a formal Source: Williams ( 1988, p 15)
production or profit sharing agreement and a tight con-
trol of distribution channcls, were not met (Eckbo, 1975).
The sharp decline in oil prices in 1986 was a result curred in any formal sense, other measures were under-
of the slowdown in demand and the increase in world taken to promote price stability. Both longer term supply
supplies. Oil production by non-OPEC countries in- contracts and netback pricing had the potential of tying
creased from 27 million barrels/day (b/d) in 1973 to oil prices to product markets more directly, yet neither
41.5 million b/d in 1986. Prices, which had been rising strategy was successful in promoting stable oil prices
continuously from 1974 began falling in 1982. In 1986 in the short run. The introduction of the futures market
average prices fell sharply to US$13/barrel from the for oil, however, did lend some stability to oil prices by
previous year's average of almost US$28/barrel. Dur- allowing buyers and sellers to 'lock into' a price at any
ing the summer months of 1986 the price ofoil fell to given time and by providing information about expecta-
below $10/barrel. tions of future prices.
Lower oil prices caused some OPEC countries to
Effects o f lower prices on market structure reassess their investment strategies and purchase down-
stream facilities in major consuming countries (Martin,
d u r i n g the 1980s
1989). This trend had the same potential as a successful
Between 1986 and 1990, after the sharp fall in oil prices, consumer-producer dialogue by matching their interests
cooperation among OPEC members declined. Saudi in a structural way. While investments in refineries had
Arabia, which had acted as a swing producer to en- been made earlier in their home countries, during the
sure restricted supply and continued higher prices, aban- 1980s some OPEC countries began purchasing refin-
doned that role. It was difficult to satisfy all members eries abroad. This trend was part of a general worldwide
and occasionally quotas were arranged without consen- restructuring of the oil refining industry and was noticed
sus. OPEC members also began cheating on their quotas and regularly reported on in trade journals and news-
by producing at higher than agreed upon levels. A pris- letters. The long-term effects of this aspect of industry re-
oner's dilemma situation developed. As prices fell, there structuring were also noted and some viewed the trend
was more incentive for an individual country to produce as stabilizing (Constantino, 1990; Akacem, 1987; Fhadar,
more which, as every country realized this and acted 1987). Perhaps the most publicized acquisition was
alone, caused prices to fall again. Lower, rather than Kuwait's purchase of over 20% of the stock of British
higher, revenues were thus accrued) Petroleum. 5 Tables 1 and 2 show the access to refining
During this time calls for dialogues between pro- and marketing facilities by OPEC members in major oil
ducers and consumers were often made. Not only were consuming countries during the 1980s.
prices lower, they varied considerably from month to While it is difficult to quantify the extent of 'vertical-
month which caused uncertainties both in oil producing ization' of the industry resulting from these purchases,
countries and oil consuming countries. 4 Investment deci- a more direct access to consumers was being forged by
sions in the oil industry itself were difficult since the certain producers. The purchase arrangements varied
long-run rate of return was difficult to determine. Since from country to country were often complicated finan-
the price ofoil affects the cost of every good transported, cially and usually for partial ownership. Kuwait, for in-
fluctuating prices also caused uncertainty in major in- stance, preferred 100% ownership of facilities while
dustrial countries. Though such a dialogue never oc- other countries became partial owners with agreements
to supply crude oil. Certainly a return to the 1950s, where
3This was the situation in 1990 immediately prior to Iraq's invasion of a few firms controlled all aspects of oil production,
Kuwait. lraq was producing according to its quota which was approx-
imately equal to its production capacity. Iraq's complaint that oil prices refining and marketing was not imminent. Yet direct
were too low stemmed from its need for higher prices to maximize rev- access to consumers was seen as an advantage by some
enues after the costly Iran Iraq war. oil officials from oil producing countries (Sheikh
41n 1989, for example, oil prices (Arabian light, netback prices) ranged
from US$14.50/barrel to over US$20/barrel. Price variations were also Ahmed Zaki Yamai cited in Constantino, 1990; H E
considerable weekly and even on a daily basis. Hisham Nazer cited in Middle East Economic Survey,

Energy Policy 1995 Volume 23 Number lO 873


The oil indus#.'v and OPEC: K L Abdalla

Table 2 Acquisitions of major oil producing countries of downstream facilities in consuming countries
Country/year Acquisition
Kuwait/1983 Two refineries in Rotterdam and Denmark with capacities of 135 000 b/d and 750000 b/d respectively. Acquired
1575 service stations in Benelux countries and Scandinavia
Kuwait/1984 1500 service stations in Italy
Kuwait/1986 82 service stations in the UK
Kuwait/1987 35 service stations and the right to supply 430 dealer-owned outlets in the UK
Kuwait/1987 53 service stations in the UK
Kuwait/1987 389 service stations and other marketing and distribution facilities in Denmark
Kuwait/1987 47% share (controlling interest) in a refining and fertilizer company in Spain
Kuwait/1988 21.6% share in BP reduced to 9.9% in 1989
Libya/1986 Majority holding in an Tamoil ltlaiana SpA with a refinery of 100000 b/d and gasoline and fuel-oil marketing op-
erations
Libya/ 1990 Purchased Gatoil Suisse with over 300 petrol stations, a terminal and a refinery in Switzerland
Libya/1993 80% of a German company (HEM) with 400 petrol stations
Saudi Arabia/1988 50% share in three Texaco refineries with a total capacity of 615 000 b/d and I 1 450 petrol stations in the USA
Saudi Arabia/1991 35% share of a Ssangyong, a South Korean company company with over 250 000 b/d refinery capacity
Saudi Arabia/1993 Purchase of refinery and 860 petrol stations in the Philippines from Petron
UAE/1987 10% share in Total of France
UAE/1988 10% share of CEPSA of Spain
UAE/1994 20% share of an Austrian lima with petrol stations in Europe and two refineries
Venezuela/1983-88 Various purchases of refining and marketing facilities in the USA, Germany, Sweden, Belgium, England and the
Caribbean
Venezuela/1989 50% share in 153 000 b/d refinery in the USA
Venezuela/1990 Purchase of Citgo in the USA

Sources: Gulf International Bank ( 1989); Ghadar ( 1987 ); Petroleum Economist ( 1989); Petroleum Intelligence Weekly (various issues).

14 November 1988). This trend was coupled with an ef- ated that their rates of return were lower than could have
fort by international oil companies to secure a more di- been attained in other non-oil investments, indicating
rect access to oil supplies. that goals other than short-term profits were factors in
The purchase of downstream facilities during the such purchases (Wood-Collins and Ait-Laousine, 1988).
1980s was limited to those producing countries with Countries lacking the financial capability to pur-
large financial reserves. Kuwait, Saudi Arabia, the chase downstream facilities would have been in a much
United Arab Emirates and Venezuela were able to make weaker position in the event of an abundant world sup-
significant purchases in consuming countries as indi- ply or declining demand. At the very least, they would
cated in the tables. Since refining adds to the value of have been forced to accept lower prices. This group in-
crude oil it is seen as advantageous for state-owned com- cluded lran and Iraq, whose financial resources had been
panies to invest in downstream facilities. One study depleted during their eight-year war, as well as Algeria,
notes that in 1990 average refining and marketing mar- Indonesia and Nigeria. Perhaps the most interesting
gins were US$13.61/barrel (excluding taxes) and that, example in this group is lraq. The late 1980s found lraq
by investing in downstream facilities, oil producers had expanding production capacity by improving oil trans-
the potential to increase the return on each barrel of oil port facilities and consequently increasing output. Its
by as much as two thirds (Verleger, 1994, pp 170-173). output increased more or less continuously from the
Investing in downstream facilities also would allow end of the Iran-lraq war in 1988 until the United Na-
state-owned companies a greater degree of flexibility in tions sanctions were imposed in 1990. Output increased
marketing their oil and leave them in an especially from an average of slightly over 2 million b/d during
strong position during periods of ample supply or weak- 1987 to 3.4 million b/d in July 1990. During this time
ened demand. During these times they would have lraq worked, within OPEC as well as on a bilateral
secure outlets for their oil and be in a position to make basis with its neighbours, to encourage other oil pro-
less of a profit in the upstream sector since profits could ducers to limit production in an effort to increase Iraqi
be garnered in the downstream sector. This was some- oil revenues. However, other major oil producers also
what similar to the strategy of the fully integrated Seven increased their output causing prices to fall. Iraq found
Sisters during the 1950s, though they had much more its oil revenues much lower than expected due to falling
control over total supply. Such downstream investments prices.
were most probably undertaken as strategic moves with Iraq's problematic financial position was partly due
benefits beyond simple short-term profitability, such to the debt incurred during its prolonged conflict with
as the capture of market share and improvements to full Iran which was estimated at US$80 billion (Abdalla,
margins (Treat, 1991). At the same time, estimates indic- 1991). While Iraq faced difficulties in raising needed

874 Energ), Poficy 1995 Volume 23 Number I0


The oil indusoy and OPEC." K L Abdalla

revenues in the short run, it also found itself unable to public spending. Kuwait's expenses for the military in-
participate in long-run investments aimed at integrat- tervention, extinguishing oil fires and immediate recon-
ing its state-owned oil company with the purchase of struction amounted to US$23 billion. Kuwait borrowed
downstream assets. Virtually no purchases were made US$5.5 billion from external sources to help pay these
at a time when many other OPEC producers were un- expenses. Saudi Arabia's external debt reached US$18.5
dertaking such investments. If the trend towards a more billion in 1991 due to war-related expenses.
integrated oil industry were to continue, Iraq would find Despite these financial setbacks, both countries have
itself as part of the fringe producer group. Without direct remained interested in downstream investments. Saudi
access to marketing facilities it would be part of the Arabia, however, is in a better position to make pur-
group with less influence in the market. In other words, chases and acquired 35% of a Korean refining company
Iraq and other oil producers without downstream assets with 300 000 b/d capacity in 1992. Saudi Arabia also ex-
would be under greatcr pressure to accept lower prices pressed interest in other downstream operations and in
in times of ample supply or weakened demand. 1993 purchased a refinery and 860 petrol stations in the
Substantial purchases of downstream facilities by Philippines. Officials have identified vertical integration
some members of OPEC could eventually result in di- as a major aim and are considering a major purchase in
verging goals of member countries, OPEC had operated Japan. Kuwait, while under greater financial strain, still
successfully as a cartel when each member country had expresses interest in the downstream sector and officials
similar incentives and goals. Its problems during the consider selling oil on the futures market as a financing
1980s not only resulted from outside competition and option (statement by Kuwait Oil Minister Homoud A.
lower prices but a change in the objectives of some of al-Rqobah quoted in Petroleum Intelligence Weekly, 22
its members. Saudi Arabia, in particular, changed from June 1992, p 4). Kuwait has also indicated a readiness
maximizing price to maximizing output or market share to purchase partial shares rather than acquiring 100%
as its main objective. Once some of the OPEC members ownership as in the past and officials have indicated an
become vertically integrated their interests and goals interest in the Asian downstream market (according to
will no longer be the same and a further, perhaps more Nader Sultan, Deputy Chairman and Managing Director
damaging, split to the cartel could occur. of Kuwait Petroleum Company as quoted in Middle East
Economic Survey, 26 September 1994, pp A5-A7). In
Oil market structure in the 1990s fact, Kuwait hopes to add 400 000 b/d to its total refin-
ing capacity though joint ventures in Asia.
The 1990s began with the invasion of Kuwait and the Other notable downstream purchases by OPEC mem-
subsequent political and military intervention of the in- bers in the 1990s, so far, have been made by Libya,
ternational community. In terms of the market structure Venezuela and the United Arab Emirates, indicating that
o f the oil industry, the overall long-term effect was the trend toward a greater degree of vertical integration
minimal. However, as noted earlier, if Iraq had been in the oil industry is continuing. Libya has made sub-
successful there would have been greater horizontal stantial purchases in Germany, the Netherlands and
concentration since Iraq would have had control over Switzerland and is reportedly considering possibilities
Kuwait's reserves as well as its own. Its ownership of in Eastern Europe. It was able to distribute 213 000 b/d
the downstream facilities, though, was more in doubt through its own organizations in Europe in 1992. Libya's
from the beginning. Kuwait was able to supply its con- ownership of downstream assets has been, in part, cred-
sumers with purchases on the spot market and kept con- ited with its recent success in avoiding a politically mo-
trol over its downstream assets throughout the period tivated oil boycott by consuming countries. Venezuela
1990-9 I. The ultimate effect, after military intervention, has also made substantial downstream purchases
was no change in horizontal organization and a mere recently including the 1990 purchase of the American
slowdown of the process of vertical integration of the in- firm, Citgo. By 1991 Venezuela's overseas refining
ternational oil industry. capacity had reached 1.5 million b/d. In 1994 the United
The Gulf war interrupted the trend toward vertical in- Arab Emirates announced the purchase of 20% of an
tegration by draining the financial reserves of the two Austrian firm with petrol stations in Austria and neigh-
countries most able to afford expensive downstream bouring countries and two refineries for approximately
purchases and active in this endeavour, namely Saudi US$450 million. The United Arab Emirates will be able
Arabia and Kuwait. Substantial financial reserves to market 60 000 b/d of crude oil directly under the
garnered during the late 1970s and early 1980s were arrangement.
essentially used to pay for the military intervention. Other oil producing countries with state owned firms
Both countries have incurred budget deficits and have such as Norway and Mexico, have also invested in down-
borrowed on the international financial markets to cover stream facilities outside their home countries. Norway

Energy Policy 1995 Volume 23 Number tO 875


The oil indusoy and OPEC." K L Ahdalla

purchased 260 service stations in Ireland in 1992 and is and Madan, 1992; MacFadyen, 1993; Young, 1994). Most
considering downstream investments in Eastern Europe. models, though, have not explicitly considered the effects
Mexico's state owned firm recently purchased a 50% of recent changes in structure of the industry.
share in a US refining company with over 200 000 b/d Although an exact, quantitative measure of the grow-
capacity. ing concentration of the international oil industry is dif-
Along with state-owned oil companies purchas- ficult to establish, a definite trend toward the vertical
ing downstream facilities, the early 1990s witnessed a integration of the international oil industry has been
continuation of the trend of oil companies purchasing noted in the 1980s and early 1990s. This has resulted
upstream assets. This is another aspect of the process mainly from purchases of downstream refining and mar-
of vertical integration in the oil industry and includes keting assets in consuming areas by state owned oil
equity production arrangements in oil producing coun- companies, although a higher incidence of equity pro-
tries, Oil producing countries which had spurned oil duction agreements has provided oil companies with
company participation during the 1970s and 1980s are upstream assets as well. This change in the structure of
now more amenable to such arrangements. For instance the international oil industry may have an impact on
Ente Nazionale Idrocarburi (ENI) of Italy has equity pro- supply decisions, and thus prices, well into the 21st
duction arrangements in 11 countries including OPEC century.
members Libya and Nigeria as well as Egypt and It is difficult to predict the effects of such purchases
Norway. Such arrangements provided it with almost on competiveness in any given market; they are likely to
500 000 b/d of crude oil in 1990. Even Kuwait, which vary depending on the downstream market itself. Ver-
had insisted on full control over production, is discus- leger notes that downstream purchases by state owned
sing the possibility of equity production arrangements in oil companies may benefit consumers by increasing
border areas. competition, though this will be more likely if the pur-
One of the most interesting developments, though chase is in the nature of assets in a small or medium
subject to political approval, has been in the state owned sized concern rather than in the largest facility in an area
oil company of Venezuela, Petroleos de Venezuela. Along (Verleger, 1994). Purchase of the largest company in a
with purchasing downstream facilities in consuming downstream market may decrease the degree of competi-
areas, it has offered equity production arrangements to tion. Verleger's assessment of recent acquisitions, such
foreign firms and now has downstream capacity approx- as Aramco's (Saudi Arabia) purchase of Texaco's re-
imately equal to its upstream capacity, and thus is now fineries in the USA and Kuwait's purchase of refineries
essentially an integrated international finn. Libya is an- in northern Europe, resulted in either the prevention of a
other country which allows equity production arrange- decrease in the degree of competition or an increase in
ments and, as mentioned above, has considerable down- competition in the market area.
stream assets. At the level of the upstream producer, specifically
Though not as binding as legal ownership of assets, OPEC members, a greater degree of vertical integration
long-term contracts also forge ties between producers has the potential to further divide oil producers into
and consumers. The 1980s witnessed an attempt to rely splinter groups. During the early 1980s OPEC and non-
on long-term contracts and other innovative contractual OPEC producers undertook different measures in their
arrangements to a varying degree. The beginning of the efforts to maximize oil revenues. As prices fell in the lat-
1990s, however, saw the implementation of'frame' con- ter part of the decade, some countries within OPEC
tracts which commit the seller but not the buyer. The changed their strategies and the effectiveness of the
seller, however, has the right to set the price. This type cartel decreased substantially. The vertical integration,
of flexible, non-binding arrangement cannot be con- even on a partial basis, of some oil producing state
sidered a contributing factor to the trend of increasing owned firms has the potential to cause a further diver-
vertical integration in the international oil industry. gence of goals and strategies of oil producers as a
whole. The group fortunate enough to own downstream
Impact of vertical organization on prices assets in consuming countries will be better able to
and market conditions withstand temporary periods of lower prices and thus
be less likely to cooperate to limit supply. If this trend
The market structure of the oil industry has had an im- continues, the oil industry could be characterized by a
pact on prices and market conditions throughout the his- group of vertically integrated companies, including oil
tory of the industry. Economic models used to analyse companies in consuming countries and state owned oil
and forecast oil prices and market conditions are con- companies in producing countries, and a group of other
tinually updated and modified to account for changing oil producers. The integrated companies may have a
OPEC behaviour and oil market conditions (Hammoudeh substantial influence on oil market conditions while the

876 Energy Policy 1995 Volume 23 Number IO


The oil indusoy and OPEC." K L Abdalla

other producers will, in times of decreasing demand or companies and further divisions split within OPEC in
ample supply, be in a weaker position and be more likely the coming decade.
to accept lower prices sooner in order to facilitate the
sale ofoil. A two-tiered pricing system could develop. Acknowledgements
Conclusion The views expressed here are those of the author and do
not necessarily reflect those of the United Nations. The
Supply decisions and prices in the latter half of the author benefited from discussions with Mahmoud Saleh
1990s and into the 21 st century will be affected, not only and Mundhir Abdul Salam and from the comments of an
by the degree of cooperation among all oil producers, but anonymous referee.
also by the degree of cooperation within each group. If
the vertically integrated oil companies eventually co- References
ordinate their output decisions, even in an informal
manner, the market structure will tend to be closer to that Abdalla, N ( 1991 ) Impact q["the Gull' Crisis on Developing Countries
United Nations Development Programme, New York
of an oligopoly with a few major firms dominating the Akacem, M (I 987) 'The future of the organization of the petroleum ex-
industry and a secondary group of producers acting as porting countries' Journal o[Energy and Development 13 ( 1) 123-139
Constantino, C (1990) 'International oil market new directions' Nat-
price takers. In this case, those producers in the sec-
ural Resources Forum 12 (4) 280~285
ondary group will find their positions weaker at any Eckbo, P L (1976) The Future o[ World Oil Ballinger, Cambridge, MA
given time. This trend will be tempered by the depletion Ghadar, F (1987) "The impact of the new OPEC downstream operations
on oil industry structure' Natural Resources Forum I 1 (2) 179-188
of mature reserves throughout the world leading to a
Gulf International Bank (1989) Gull'Economie and Financial Report 4 (8)
more concentrated supply of reserves. However, given Hammoudeh, S and Madan, V (1992) 'The dynamic stability of OPEC's
the divergence in interests and goals between these two oil price mechanism' Energy Economics 14 ( 1) 65 7 I
MacFadyen, A J (1993) "OPEC and cheating: revisiting the kinked
groups, and along with other geopolitical and economic demand curve' Energy Policy 21 (8) 858 867
factors, OPEC will be unlikely to regain its status as an Martin, J (1989) 'From the erosion of crude oil prices to reorganiza-
effective cartel. Even if OPEC's overall market share in- tion of the oil industry' Natural Resoutz'es Forum 13 (2) 149-159
Middle East Economic Survey (various issues)
creases in the future, the different goals of the integrated
Oil and Gas Journal (various issues)
group and the non-integrated group suggests that pro- Petroleum Economist (1989) December, 384
ducers will be unlikely to cooperate as before. Petroleum Economist (various issues)
Petroleum Intelligence Weekly (various issuesl
Although beyond the scope of this paper, an analysis Sampson, A (1975) The Seven Sisters: The Great Oil Companies and
of demand is also needed for forecasting future oil prices the World They Shaped Viking Press, New York
and market conditions. World energy demand is ex- Schneider, S A (1983) The Oil Price Revolution Johns Hopkins Uni-
versity Press, Baltimore, MD
pected to continue to grow well into the 21 st century but Treat, J ( 1991 ) 'Vertical integration: a flashing yellow light' Petroleum
the oil industry will be faced with greater competition Intelligence Weekly 2 December, 6
from non-oil energy sources. Thus, while the trend Verleger, P K (1994) Ad/usting to Volatile Energy Prices Institute for
International Economics, Washington, DC
within the oil industry may be moving toward greater Williams, R (I 988) 'OPEC ventures downstream: industry threat or
concentration, the overall energy market will be more stability aid'?' Oil and Gas Journal 16 May, 15
competitive. However, the integrated oil companies will Wood-Collins, J and Ait-Laousine, N (1988) 'Downstream integra-
tion: myths and realities' Petroleum Intelligence Weekly 3 October,
be in a better position to cope with such competition Special Supplement
underscoring the potential for a divergence of interests Yergin, D (1991) The Prize." The Epic Quest.lbr Oil. Money and
between integrated companies and other state-owned Power Simon and Schuster, New York

Energy Policy 1995 Volume 23 Number 10 8"]7

You might also like