Behavioral Finance Versus Standard Finance-Annotated

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/247880912

Behavioral Finance versus Standard Finance

Article in AIMR Conference Proceedings · December 1995


DOI: 10.2469/cp.v1995.n7.4

CITATIONS READS

55 6,491

1 author:

Meir Statman
Santa Clara University
165 PUBLICATIONS 12,369 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

My book "Finance for Normal People: How investors and markets behave" to be published by Oxford University Press early next year. View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Meir Statman on 10 October 2016.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Behavioral Finance versus Standard Finance
Meir Statman
Professor, Department ofFinance
Leavey School ofBusiness
Santa Clara University

Behavioral finance is built on the framework of standard finance but supplies a replace-
ment for standard finance as a descriptive theory. Behavioral finance reflects a different
model of human behavior and is constructed of different components-prospect theory,
cognitive errors, problems of self-control, and the pain of regret. These components help
make sense of the world of finance-including investor preferences, the design of modem
financial products, and financial regulations-by making sense of normal investor
behavior.

Finance practitioners and academics are, or should that the rationality-based market equilibrium mod-
be, interested in the following questions: els in finance in general and of dividends in particu-
• Why do investors like dividends? lar are alive and well-or at least in no worse shape
than other comparable models in economics at their
• Why do investors hate to realize losses?
level of aggregation. The framework is not so
• Why do investors prefer stocks of "good" weighed down with anomalies that a complete re-
companies? construction (on behavioral!cognitive or other lines)
• How are expected returns determined? is either needed or likely to occur in the near future.
• What kinds of securities do investors like? (p.5466)
• What are the forces that shape financial regu- I argue that, today, ten years after Miller spoke,
lations? standard finance is indeed so weighted down with
The range of questions is wide. It includes investor anomalies that it makes much sense to continue the
behavior; the interaction of investors in markets, reconstruction of financial theory on behaviorallines.
which determines security prices; and the interaction Standard finance is constructed with a few com-
of citizens in public policy arenas, which determines mon components that have many uses. So is behav-
financial regulations. ioral finance. But the components of standard finance
Standard finance-the body of knowledge that and behavioral finance, reflecting different models of
is built on such pillars as the arbitrage principles of human behavior, are different. This presentation pro-
Merton Miller and Franco Modigliani, the portfolio vides examples of the construction of behavioral fi-
construction principles of Harry Markowitz, the nance as a framework that builds on standard finance
capital asset pricing theory of John Lintner and and replaces it.
William Sharpe, and the option-pricing theory of Proponents of standard finance often concede
Fischer Black, Myron Scholes, and Robert Mer- that their financial theory does poorly as a descrip-
ton-is so compelling because it uses only a few tive, or positive, theory of the behavior of individu-
basic components to build a unified theory, a the- als. They retreat to a second line of defense: that
ory that should provide answers to all the ques- standard finance does well as a descriptive theory of
tions of finance. the equilibrium that results from the interaction of
Few theories, however, are fully consistent with individuals in markets. For example, Miller (1986)
all the available empirical evidence, and standard wrote that, for individual investors,
finance is no exception. For example, Miller (1986)
stocks are usually more than just the abstract "bun-
readily acknowledges that the observed preference dIes of returns" of our economic models. Behind each
for cash dividends is one of the "soft spots in the holding may be a story of family business, family
current body of theory" (p. 5451). Miller goes on to quarrels, legacies received, divorce settlements, and
argue, however: a host of other considerations almost totally irrele-

14
vant to our theories of portfolio selection. That we nore covariances and assess the risk of an asset in
abstract from all these stories in building our models isolation from the overall portfolio. By that rule, the
is not because the stories are uninteresting but be- options position is more risky, but by the rules of
cause they may be too interesting and thereby dis- Markowitz, the cash position is the more risky one.
tract us from the pervasive market forces that should
People in standard finance are rational. People in
be our principal concern. (p. 5467)
behavioral finance are normal. When offered a choice
Even the second line of defense, however, does not between a $10 bill and a $20 bill, both rational and
hold. Evidence is mounting that the capital asset normal people choose the $20 bill. Rational people,
pricing model (CAPM), the market equilibrium the- however, are never confused by frames that make
ory by which risk and expected returns are deter- that $10 bill look like a $100 bill, whereas as Amos
mined in standard finance, is not a good description Tversky shows, normal people are often confused by
of reality. Moreover, contrary to Miller's view, I think frames. 1
that financial decisions by individuals and institu- The effect of frames on choice is one part of
tions are the proper domain of finance, not merely Kahneman and Tversky's (1979) prospect theory,
stories that "distract us from the pervasive market and prospect theory is one of the components of
forces that should be our principal concern." Indeed, behavioral finance. Susceptibility to cognitive errors
a good theory of the financial behavior of individuals is a second component of behavioral finance (see
is crucial for a good theory of the equilibrium that Kahneman, Slovic, and Tversky 1982). For example,
results from the interactions of individuals in the standard investors are never fooled by the "law of
marketplace. To understand the differences between small numbers." They know that five years of return
the components from which standard finance and data on a mutual fund provide little information
behavioral finance are constructed, consider the ar- about the investment skills of the fund's manager.
bitrage principle. Standard investors also know that, as they assess the
People in standard finance are not confused by ability of the manager of a particular fund-say, the
frames. The pricing of a call option in the Black- Magellan Fund-they should take into consideration
Scholes model is a good example. The price of a call the evidence on the ability of the average fund man-
option is determined by substance: the knowledge ager to beat the market. Behavioral investors tend to
that the cash flows of an option can be replicated by a conclude that a five-year record of a fund is plenty of
particular dynamic combination of a bond and the evidence about the skills of its manager and that the
underlying stock. The fact that in one case the cash performance of the average fund manager is irrele-
flows are framed in terms of options and in the second vant in the assessment of the skill of a particular fund
case flows are framed in terms of bonds and stocks manager.
does not matter to standard finance investors. If the Standard-finance people are immune to prob-
option cash flows exceed the cash flows of the stocks lems of self-control. They stick to their diet plans and
and bonds, "standard investors" engage in arbitrage, find it easy to turn down tempting desserts. They also
make arbitrage profits, and move prices to equilib- stick to their savings plans and never engage in im-
rium levels where arbitrage is no longer profitable. pulse buying. Behavioral investors are subject to
Whereas standard investors are never affected temptation and, as Thaler and Shefrin (1981) noted,
by frames, "behavioral investors" are often affected they look for ways to improve their self-control.
by frames. Moreover, behavioral investors are af- Standard-finance investors are also immune to
fected by frames in a normal, predictable way. Con- the pain of regret (see Kahneman and Tversky 1982).
sider the following question: Which investment Standard-finance people feel no greater disappoint-
position is more risky? mentwhen they miss their plane by a minute as when
1. a $1,000 long position in U.s. T-bills or they miss it by an hour. Behavioral investors know
2. a $1,000 short position in naked call options the joy of pride and the pain of regret as they kick
on the S&P 500 Index. themselves harder when they miss the plane by only
Most people choose the options position as the more a minute.
risky one. Someone whose overall portfolio is posi- The following sections describe how the compo-
tively correlated with the S&P 500 and who has cho- nents of prospect theory, cognitive errors, self-control,
sen the options position as the more risky position is and regret can help make sense of the world of finance
probably a behavioral investor-one who has been and answer the questions posed at the beginning of
fooled by the frame. The options position is nega- this presentation. I begin with dividends, the issue
tively correlated with this investor's portfolio; thus, discussed by Miller (1986).
it provides a hedge and lowers overall portfolio risk.
In contrast, the T-bill position has only a zero corre-
lation with the portfolio and reduces its risk by less
than the options position. Normal behavior is to ig- lSee Professor Tversky's presentation, pp. 2-5.

15
Investor Preferences for Cash Dividends savings, but behavioral investors have to combat the
desire for dessert even when they know that vegeta-
During the energy crisis of the early 1970s, Con bles are better for their long-term welfare. Rules are
Edison, the power company in New York City, de- a good tool for self-control. "No dessert before vege-
cided to eliminate its dividend. At Con Edison's 1974 tables" is one such rule. "Consume from dividends
annual meeting, shareholders revolted; some cried, but don't dip into capital" is another. Recall that the
some had to be restrained from doing physical harm person who spoke for the woman at the Con Edison
to the company's chairman. Here is a typical share- meeting did not even consider the possibility of dip-
holder reaction, quoted from the transcript of the ping into capital to create homemade dividends.
1974 meeting: Indeed, following standard finance theory can
A lady came over to me a minute ago, and she said get people into deep trouble. One person in the
to me, "Please say a word for the senior citizens." audience at the Con Edison meeting asked why
And she had tears in her eyes. And I really know stock dividends were not paid in place of cash divi-
what she means by that. She simply means that now dends "so at least the blow to stockholders by the
she will get only one check a month, and that will be omission of dividends would have been much less."
her Social Security, and she's not going to make it The chairman, in an explanation that would have
because you have denied her that dividend. made Miller and Modigliani proud, explained that
Standard-finance shareholders of Con Edison stock dividends are no more than pieces of paper
would have been upset by the energy crisis and its and that shareholders can create homemade divi-
impact on the value of Con Edison's stock, but they dends by selling a few shares. The chairman missed
would not have been angry about the decision to the point entirely. Naming the pieces of paper"divi-
eliminate the dividend. The Con Edison shareholders dends" moves them from the capital mental account
must have been behavioral investors. to a dividend mental account and allows consump-
Standard investors follow the arbitrage princi- tion without violating the rule of "don't dip into
ple of Miller and Modigliani and know that in a capital."
world without taxes and transaction costs, they In short, contrary to the precepts of standard
should be indifferent between a dollar in dividends finance, investors make important distinctions be-
and a dollar in capital. Standard investors are indif- tween dividends and capital. The distinctions are
ferent between dividends and capital because they rooted in the way they frame money in mental ac-
do not rely on company decisions to create divi- counts and the rules by which they use these frames
dends. They can create "homemade dividends" by to control savings and consumption. One cannot
selling shares. Moreover, in a world where divi- solve the dividend puzzle while ignoring the pat-
dends are taxed more heavily than capital gains, terns of normal investor behavior.
investors are actually better off when companies
refrain from paying dividends. So, why do investors
like dividends? This is the puzzle to standard fi- Selling Winners Too Early, Riding Losers Too
nance about which Black (1976) wrote. Hersh She- Long
frin and I have used the components of behavioral
finance to explain why investors like dividends Underlying the arbitrage principle of Miller and
(Shefrin and Statman 1984). Modigliani is the mechanism of arbitrage. An investor
A central element of prospect theory is that people who sells a share at $100 in one market and simulta-
segment their money into mental accounts. A dividend neously buys a share of the same company in another
dollar is identical to a capital dividend in standard market for $95 engages in arbitrage, with a risk-free
finance, but a dollar dividend is different from a capital gain of $5. Of course, standard-finance investors
dollar in prospect theory because the two dollars be- never leave arbitrage opportunities unexploited.
long to separate mental accounts and mental account- The tax law, especially as it stood before the 1986
ing is done account by account. The decline in the price changes, provided investors with the"timing" arbi-
per share of Con Edison is a loss in the capital mental trage opportunity described by Constantinides
account, and the elimination of the dividend is a loss in (1983,1984). The opportunity arises from differences
the dividend mental account. Paying the dividend in the tax rates on long-term and short-term gains
would have provided a "silver lining" lessening the and losses. Here is how it works: Imagine that you
pain even if the dividend payment had resulted in a have $10,000 and you have decided to invest it in a
further decline in the price of the stock. no-load mutual fund, Fund A. You also identify Mu-
Segregating monies into mental accounts is espe- tual Fund B, whose returns are perfectly correlated
cially beneficial for people who have difficulty with with the returns on Fund A. Imagine also that the
self-control. As noted earlier, standard finance inves- "short term" is classified by the Internal Revenue
tors have no self-control difficulties in either diets or Service as one year, so gain and loss realizations after

16
one year are classified by the IRS as "long term." Why Investors Prefer Stocks of Good
You hold Fund A for a month, and as it happens,
Companies
the stock market declines and your shares are now
worth $9,000, a paper loss of $1,000. Now the arbi- Everyone has heard that beta is dead. Some say it is
trage game at the expense of the IRS begins. You coming back; others say it is dead for good. The life
realize the $1,000 paper loss by selling your shares in or death of beta is so important because beta is the
Fund A and using the $9,000 in proceeds to buy center of the CAPM and the CAPM is the standard-
shares of Fund B. The $1,000 loss, as a short-term loss, finance way of understanding risk, expected returns,
can be offset against your regular income taxed at, and the relationship between the two.
say, 30 percent. Your "rebate" from the IRS is 30 The current state of the CAPM illustrates the
percent of $1,000, or $300. Now, imagine that you danger in the tendency of standard finance to down-
hold the $9,000 in Fund B for a year and a day, and play an understanding of human behavior and con-
the value of the shares appreciates from $9,000 to centrate instead on the resulting equilibrium in
$10,000. You realize your $1,000 paper gain as a financial markets. The assumptions about human
long-term gain. You pay, say, 20 percent, or $200, as behavior that underlie the CAPM are not simplified
a long-term tax to the IRS and buy $10,000 in shares versions of observed behavior. Rather, they contra-
of Fund A. dict observed behavior. For example, investors in the
Compare your situation to the situation of an world of the CAPM are assumed to agree on the
investor who held Fund A for the entire period. That expected returns of all assets. Of course, nobody
investor begins with $10,000 and ends with $10,000- believes that this assumption comes even close to a
no gains, no losses. You, however, have $10,100 be- description of human behavior.
cause your initial $300 tax rebate is $100 higher than Assumptions about individual behavior might
the later $200 tax payment. This kind of arbitrage is not matter when a theory works, but the CAPM does
easy. It involves only the exploitation of a quirk in the not work. Now that Fama and French (1992) have
tax law. And, of course, standard-finance investors brought the sorry state of the CAPM to the headlines,
have no difficulty recognizing or exploiting arbitrage standard finance offers no fallback theory for ex-
opportunities. pected returns and risk. Instead, the result is data
Behavioral investors have a problem with the mining in the form of size and book-to-market effects.
arbitrage prescription; it requires the realization of a Shefrin and I have also observed the choices of
$1,000 "paper loss" as they sell Fund A and buy Fund investors, rather than stock prices, and offered in-
B. Behavioral investors hate to realize losses. Behav- sights into the process by which investors form ex-
ioral investors think of money within mental ac- pectations about stock returns (Shefrin and Statman
counts and distinguish paper losses from "realized 1995b). An analysis of investor expectations might
losses." A stock with a paper loss might rise in price, well be the best route to understanding the equilib-
so the chance exists that the mental account contain- rium levels of expected returns because, as everyone
ing the stock will break even, but a realized loss agrees, realized-return data, upon which virtually all
means kissing the hope of breaking even goodbye. current analyses are based, are very noisy. In com-
Behavioral investors are reluctant to realize losses, parison, the noise level in expectational data is low.
despite the tax advantages of doing so, because of the For example, Fortune magazine collects data on
pain of regret that comes with kissing hope goodbye. expectations through surveys it conducts of a group
Gross (1982) described the reluctance of inves- of respondents who are commonly regarded as so-
tors to realize losses this way: phisticated investors-executives, members of
Many clients, however, will not sell anything at a boards of directors, and financial analysts. Thou-
loss. They do not want to give up the hope of making sands of respondents are asked each year to rank
money on a particular investment, or perhaps they companies on eight attributes, including quality of
want to get even before they get out. The"geteveni- management, quality of products and services, and
tis" disease has probably wrought more destruction value as a long-term investment. The top three com-
on investment portfolios than anything else. (p. 150) panies, as judged by the average quality score in the
Shefrin and I have analyzed transactions in mutual survey published in the February 1993 issue of For-
funds and stocks and found evidence against the tune, are Merck & Company, Rubbermaid, and Wal-
standard finance hypothesis that people engage in the Mart. The bottom three companies are Wang
tax arbitrage that Constantinides described (Shefrin Laboratories, Continental Airlines, and Glenfed.
and Statman 1985). Ignoring arbitrage opportunities Consider the relationship between the rating of
and leaving $100 (or much more) in the pocket of the a given company on quality of management and on
IRS may not be rational, but it is hard for behavioral value as a long-term investment. Quality of manage-
investors to bring themselves to realize losses. ment is an attribute of the company. In contrast, value

17
as a long-term investment is an attribute of the stock tial properties to its parent population and (2) reflects
of the company. If respondents to the Fortune survey the salient features by which it is generated. In other
believe in market efficiency, they will conclude that words, an event A is judged more probable than an
the price of a stock fully reflects the quality of the event B when A appears more representative than B.
company. In efficient markets, the wonderful growth Kahneman and Tversky (1972) have supported the
opportunities of good companies are fully reflected hypothesis that subjects judge the probability of an
in the prices of their stocks, and therefore, the stocks event by its representativeness with a series of ex-
offer no special value as a long-term investment. periments.
Similarly, the lousy growth opportunities of bad Consider this experiment (Kahneman and Tver-
companies are fully reflected in the prices of their sky 1982). Subjects were presented with a brief per-
stocks. Neither stocks of good companies nor stocks sonality sketch of Linda: Linda is 31 years old, single,
of bad companies are bargains in an efficient market. outspoken, and very bright. She majored in philoso-
If so, we should find a zero correlation between the phy. As a student, she was deeply concerned with
Fortune ratings on quality of management and the issues of discrimination and social justice and also
Fortune ratings on value as a long-term investment. participated in antinuclear demonstrations.
Now consider, in contrast, what might be expected Subjects were then asked which event is more
if the Fortune respondents are standard-finance inves- probable:
tors who properly incorporate the knowledge reflected • Linda is a bank teller (T).
in findings on size and ratio of book value to market • Linda is a bank teller and is active in the
value (BV/MV) by Fama and French (1992) and others. feminist movement (T & F).
Shefrin and I have found that, in general, companies The description of Linda was constructed to be
that Fortune respondents rate highly by quality of man- similar to or representative of the profile of an active
agement have high market values of equity (large size) feminist and unrepresentative of that of a bank teller.
and low BV/MVs. These characteristics, of course, ap- Now, the rules of probability state that the com-
ply to companies whose stocks provide low returns, pound event T & F cannot be more probable than the
according to Fama and French. If respondents to the simple event T. Yet, 87 percent of all subjects judged
Fortune survey are aware of the Fama and French the probability of the compound event that Linda is
results, explicitly or implicitly, they should produce a a bank teller and is active in the feminist movement
negative correlation between the rating of a company as higher than the probability of the simple event that
on quality of management and the rating of the stock Linda is a bank teller.
of the company on value as a long-term investment. The outcome of this experiment is consistent
In fact, Shefrin and I found neither the zero correlation with the hypothesis that subjects judge the prob-
between quality of management and value as a long- ability of an event by its similarity or repre-
term investment, which would be expected if the sentativeness. Specifically, because a feminist
Fortune respondents believe stock prices are efficient, attitude seems more representative of Linda than the
nor the negative correlation expected if the Fortune bank teller occupation, subjects concluded that Linda
respondents follow Fama and French. Instead, we is more probably a bank teller and feminist than a
found a strong positive correlation. A regression of bank teller.
value as a long-term investment on quality of man- In interviews following the experiment, Kahne-
agement produces not only a positive coefficient man and Tversky asked 36 subjects to explain their
with a rare significant t-statistic, 43.95, but also an choices. More than two-thirds of subjects who se-
adjusted R2 of 0.86. In other words, people as sophis- lected the compound event gave some version of a
ticated as the Fortune respondents think that good similarity or typicality argument as their reason but
stocks are the stocks of good companies although the agreed, after some reflection, that the response was
evidence indicates that the opposite is true. wrong because everyone who is both a bank teller
Why do people think that stocks of companies and a feminist must also be a bank teller. Only two
such as Merck, Rubbermaid, and Wal-Mart offer of the subjects maintained that the probability order
higher values as long-term investments than stocks need not agree with class inclusion, and only one
of companies such as Wang, Continental Airlines, claimed that he had misinterpreted the question.
and Glenfed? Michael Solt and I have argued that In relation to good companies and good stocks,
investors tend to believe that good stocks are stocks Solt and I argue that investors overestimate the prob-
of good companies because they fall prey to the ability that the stock of a good company is a good
representativeness heuristic (Solt and Statman 1989). stock because they rely on the representativeness
A person who follows the representativeness heuristic. They overestimate the probability that a
heuristic evaluates the probability of an uncertain good stock is stock of a good company because a
event by the degree to which it (1) is similar in essen- good stock is similar to a good company.

18
The Fortune respondents rate stocks as if they like The Design and Marketing of Financial Products
stocks of companies with high-quality management,
with high market values of equity, and with low In teaching students the basics of options, I draw
BV/MVs. Do they care about beta? No. Regression profit diagrams, as shown in Figure 1, of the four
basic positions: buying a call, selling a call, buying a
results show that there is no statistically significant
put, and selling a put. I ask the students, "Which
relationship between value as a long-term invest-
positions do you like?" They like the idea of buying
ment and beta. calls and puts, but they hate the idea of selling (na-
Typical Fortune respondents are behavioral in- ked) calls and puts. They explain that buying a call is
vestors, investors who believe that good stocks are attractive because the position has a floor on losses
stocks of good companies. Standard investors know but unlimited potential for gains. "The maximum
what Fama and French know, that good stocks are that I can lose is the premium," they say. Selling a
stocks of bad companies. Behavioral investors load (naked) call involves a ceiling on gains but unlimited
up on stocks of good companies. Standard investors potential for losses.
tilt their portfolios toward stocks of bad companies, Next, I show them a profit diagram of a covered-
but being fully rational, they are mindful of the nega- call option (shown in Figure 2), a position that com-
tive effect that concentration has on portfolio diver- bines buying a share of stock for, say, $21 and selling
sification. Thus, standard investors moderate the tilt a call option on the stock with an exercise price of $25
toward stocks of bad companies, and the force that for $1. My students like the idea of covered calls, but
they exert on stock prices may not, therefore, be they are surprised to realize that the shape of the
profit diagram of the covered-call position that they
sufficient to counter fully the effect of behavioral
like is identical to the shape of the selling a (naked)
investors. In short, the picture of equilibrium that
put position that they hate. My students are hardly
Shefrin and I see consists of many behavioral inves- unique; the attraction of covered calls has been a
tors who hold portfolios tilted toward the stocks of puzzle to standard finance for years. But Shefrin and
good companies, a few standard investors who hold I have attempted to explain that attraction (Shefrin
portfolios tilted toward stocks of bad companies, and and Statman 1993a).
an expected-returns equilibrium where stocks of bad Covered calls are promoted by investment advi-
companies-low market values of equity and high sors as positions that contain free lunches. Here is an
BV/MVs-have high returns. example from the Research Institute of America's

Figure 1. profit Diagram for Call and Put Options


Buy a Call Buy a Put

Maximum Maximum
Loss Loss

Sell a Call Sell a Put


Maximum Maximum
Gain Gain

Note: The solid horizontal line in each diagram is the stock price at option expiration date. The tick marks
on this line indicate the point at which the strike price equals the stock price at expiration.
Source: Meir Statman.

19
Figure 2. profit Diagram for a Covered-Call dividends due you as the owner of the stock.
The third source of profit would be in the in-
crease in price of the shares, from what you
paid, to the agreed selling price.
By agreeing to sell at a higher price than you
bought, all you are giving up is the unknown, un-
knowable profit possibility above the agreed price.
In return, for relinquishing some of the profit poten-
Stock Price tial, you collect a handsome amount of cash that you
at Option
Expiration Date
can immediately spend or reinvest, as you choose. (p.
166)
Note the way Gross frames the cash flows into
three "sources of profit" rather than integrating the
Source: Meir Statman. three into an overall net cash flow. Of course, stand-
ard investors have no difficulty in integrating the
Personal Money Guide: cash flows, and they understand that covered calls
provide no free lunch. But not all investors can dis-
An investment strategy that can make you extra
money is writing calls on securities you already own.
entangle the cash flows from their frame, and cov-
. . . When you sell a call on a stock you own, you ered calls remain popular.
receive a premium. Think of these premiums as extra As Ross (1989) wrote, when standard finance
dividends. By careful selection of stocks and timing scholars are asked to explain the proliferation of
of writing calls, you have the opportunity to earn financial products and the features of their designs,
annual rates of returns of 11 percent to 19 percent: they tend to "fall back on old canards such as span-
regular dividends of 4 percent to 9 percent and pre- ning." Ross emphasized the role of marketing in the
mium "dividends" of 7 percent to 10 percent. world of financial products. Shefrin and I (1993a)
And here is an example of the exasperated response have shown that an understanding of the behavior of
of standard finance: individuals and institutions explains the design of
Even for long-term investors who plan "never" to covered calls, money market funds, and many other
sell their stocks, the premiums received from writing securities.
options against these stocks cannot be treated as
simply extra income to be added to the normal return
of the stocks, as some advertising in the options Behavioral Forces That Shape Financial
industry seems to suggest. (Merton, Scholes, and Regulations
Gladstein 1978)
"Do you know what the concept of suitability means
Why do investors continue to ignore the good in the context of investments?" I ask financial econo-
advice of standard finance? One part of the answer is mists. Few know, and few investment textbooks
that behavioral investors frame the cash flows of mention suitability. In contrast, suitability regula-
covered calls into separate mental accounts rather tions are well known to securities brokers. Perhaps
than integrate them as standard finance suggests. financial economists within standard finance ignore
Consider the way Gross (1982) frames covered calls suitability regulations because they are not impor-
in his manual for brokers: tant, or perhaps they ignore them because suitability
Joe Salesman: You have told me that you have not is difficult to fit into standard finance.
been too pleased with the results of your Suitability regulations revolve around the re-
stock market investments.
John Prospect: That's right. I am dissatisfied with
sponsibilities of brokers to their customers. Brokers
the return, or lack of it, on my stock portfolio. are required to ascertain that the securities they rec-
Joe Salesman: Starting tomorrow, how would you ommend are suitable for their customers based on the
like to have three sources of profit every time customers' financial conditions and needs. Consider
you buy a common stock? the experience of Charles Schwab & Company. Char-
John Prospect: Three profit sources? What are les Schwab is, of course, a discount.broker that pro-
they? vides no investment advice. An investor was trading
Joe Salesman: First, you could collect a lot of dol- options through Schwab and lost $500,000. Then,
lars-maybe hundreds, sometimes thou-
claiming that those investments were unsuitable for
sands-for simply agreeing to sell your
just-bought stock at a higher price than you
his financial condition and needs, he sued Schwab.
paid. This agreement money is paid to you Schwab's argument in its defense was that it does not
right away, on the very next business day- give advice; it merely trades what the investor wants
money that's yours to keep forever. Your sec- traded. The arbitration panel said that Schwab's ar-
ond source of profit could be the cash gument is irrelevant, the option trades were not suit-

20
able for that investor, and the fact that Schwab is a pay for IPOs. Should merit regulations be abolished
discount broker does not exempt it from suitability or, given the evidence on the returns IPOs provide,
regulations. should the regulations be tightened?
The typical reaction of financial economists when Suitability and merit regulations are not the only
they are told about suitability regulations is that these tools designed to help behavioral investors cope with
regulations are senseless and should be abolished. their shortcomings. Shefrin and I have analyzed suit-
Suitability regulations prevent investors from using ability, merit, and such other regulations as those
their investor sovereignty to choose the securities they pertaining to insider trading and mandatory disclo-
want and construct the portfolios that are, in their sure (Shefrin and Statman 1992, 1993b).
judgments, optimal. The role of a theory is to explain _
the evidence, however, not argue with it.
Conclusion
Suitability regulations make no sense in stand-
ard finance because, in standard finance, people are Standard finance is well built on the arbitrage princi-
assumed to be free of cognitive errors and problems ples of Miller and Modigliani, the portfolio construc-
of self-control. Suitability regulations are important, tion principles of Markowitz, and the CAPM of
however, for behavioral investors. Indeed, suitability Lintner and Sharpe. Standard finance does not do
regulations can be understood as tools that help be- well, however, as a descriptive theory of finance.
havioral investors control the effects of their cogni- Investors regularly overlook arbitrage opportunities,
tive errors and self-control problems. In that sense, fail to use Markowitz's principles in constructing
suitability regulations are analogous to "cooling-off" their portfolios, and fail to drive stock returns to
regulations. levels commensurate with the CAPM.
Consider the door-to-door sales of vacuum clean- People in standard finance are rational. They are
ers. By law, a customer has three days after making a not confused by frames, they are not affected by cog-
purchase, a cooling-off period, to cancel the transac- nitive errors, they do not know the pain of regret, and
tion. The existence of this law implies that people have they have no lapses of self-control. People in behav-
realized that sometimes they get too "hot" for their ioral finance may not always be rational, but they are
own good; they need time to cool off, think clearly, always normal. Normal people are often confused by
and regain their self-control. So, through the legisla- frames, affected by cognitive errors, and know the
tive process, people created a law that helps them pain of regret and the difficulty of self-control. I argue
control their cognitive errors and imperfect self-con- that behavioral finance is built on a better model of
trol. The same argument applies to securities. People human behavior than standard finance and the better
understand that cognitive errors and imperfect self- model allows it to deal effectively with many puzzles
control interfere with good decisions. So, through the that plague standard finance, among them, the puz-
law, they appoint a broker or investment advisor to zles discussed here-investor preference for cash
do for them what parents do for children-say no to dividends, investor reluctance to realize losses, the
choices that parents judge irresponsible. determination of expected returns, the design of secu-
Or consider state merit, or blue-sky, regulations. rities, and the nature of financial regulations.
Under them, a bureaucrat in, for example, Sacra- Finance offers many other puzzles. Some are
mento decides whether a particular security can or small-for example, why the practice of dollar-cost
cannot be sold to residents of California. The ration- averaging persists despite its inconsistency with
ale behind merit regulations is that people are sus- standard finance (Statman 1995). Some are large-
ceptible to cognitive errors and, left to their own for example, why investors ignore Markowitz's rules
devices, will overpay for securities. As in the case of of portfolio construction (Shefrin and Statman
suitability regulations, merit regulations are de- 1995b). These puzzles might be solved within behav-
signed to protect investors from themselves, protec- ioral finance.
tion that makes no sense in standard finance. Financial professionals who understand behav-
Consider merit regulations in light of the evi- ioral finance will understand their own behavior and
dence on the returns from initial public offerings. improve their decisions. Institutional investors who
Mounting evidence indicates that investors who buy understand behavioral finance will understand the
IPOs in the public market, on average, lose substan- beliefs and motives of their clients and will be better
tially. Left to their own devices, IPO investors over- at serving and educating them.

21
Question and Answer Session
Meir Statman
Question: What is "quality of Question: With all the informa- replacement for standard finance
management," and how do we tion available about the benefits as a descriptive theory. The re-
measure or quantify it? of indexing-eosts are low and turn anomalies are the pebbles in
managers have difficulty outper- the shoe that make one say,
Statman: Quality of manage- forming the indexes-why aren't "Enough! Standard finance does
ment is the rating of quality of more people indexing? not work." When standard theo-
management by respondents to ries of portfolio selection are in-
Fortune's survey of companies. Re- Statman: Indexing does not cor- consistent with the evidence and
spondents give each company a respond to investors' intuition when market forces are inconsis-
score on quality of management about the way the market works. tent with the predictions of the
ranging from zero (absolutely aw- I ask my students, "When you
CAPM, the wise move is to go
ful) to ten (glorious). The correla- buy a stock because you are confi-
back to an examination of the fi-
tions cited in the presentation are dent that it is a bargain, who do
based on the averages of those you think is the idiot who is on nancial decisions of individuals.
rankings from all the Fortune re- the other end of the transaction?" Moreover, the activities of in-
spondents. We do not know the Most have never thought about dividuals and institutions are a le-
respondents' thought processes in this question. Most people do not gitimate concern of the field of
assigning the ratings. think about the stock market as a finance even if they do not affect
zero-sum game relative to index prices. When corporations fail to
Question: Did you examine the funds. They do not consider the deploy their assets efficiently,
relationship between past stock likelihood that the trader on the welfare declines. Agency theory
performance and management rat- other side of the trade might be focuses on the issues that pertain
ings from the Fortune survey? an insider and that they, in fact, to welfare losses and mechanisms
are the patsy. for alleviating such losses (see Jen-
Statman: Yes, and the answer is sen and Meckling 1976). Welfare
in a paper that Roger Clarke and I Question: Some of the findings losses also exist when individuals
wrote (Clarke and Statman 1994). of decision theory suggest that in- fail to construct efficient portfo-
One of the characteristics of high- dividuals overpay for volatility, lios; a description of such losses
quality companies is that their whereas your research suggests and mechanisms for the allevia-
past stock returns are high. that individuals overpay for sta- tion of such losses are a concern
bility, or good companies. How
of finance practitioners and
Question: As a matter of com- do we reconcile these views?
should be a concern of finance
munication, can we educate our- academics.
selves and our clients to look at Statman: People frame their As behavioral finance devel-
portfolios rather than segments? money into those different pock-
ops, we ought to keep in mind
If so, how? ets. So, there is no unified attitude
that we need theory that contains
toward risk. Many people who
buy insurance also buy lottery testable hypotheses, not stories. I
Statman: It is possible to edu- take delight when somebody
cate people, but we need more tickets. Are they risk averse or
risk seeking? Investors divide finds evidence contrary to hy-
than education. I begin my talk potheses of behavioral finance. At
about portfolios in my invest- their money into"safe" money
and "risky" money (Shefrin and least nobody can say that our the-
ments class by telling students
that their intuition is likely to mis- Statman 1995a). ory is a just-so theory that cannot
lead them. What is really needed be refuted by evidence.
are structures that prevent us Question: A so-called new fi- Moreover, explaining the ex-
from acting on wrong intuition- nance is driven heavily by market isting anomalies is not enough.
for example, a work sheet with inefficiency. Where does behav- Behavioral finance will be tested
boxes that must be filled in-a ioral finance fit in this approach- in its ability to explain phenom-
framework that forces us to con- as a subset or as the keystone? ena that are not even recognized
sider factors that, acting on intui- today as anomalous within stand-
tion alone, we are likely to miss. Statman: Behavioral finance is a ard finance.

22

View publication stats

You might also like