Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 60

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF

TRANSNATIONAL POWER AND


PRODUCTION

How and why Mexico’s socioeconomic structure was transformed through pluto-
cratic preferences, US corporate strategies, and ideology—all powering transna-
tional processes of neoliberalization—are issues examined in this comprehensive,
carefully documented publication covering four crucial decades of metamorphosis.
The causes and consequences of the creation of a new, regional power bloc—the
North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA)—are extensively examined.
Readers will benefit from the many important demystifications presented here,
chronicling the asymmetric Mexico-US production system. The impacts of the
new transnational structure for labor on both sides of the border are matters of
centrality. Specialists and general readers alike will find an explicit and accessible
account of the powerful forces opening access to and profiting from millions of
low-wage workers enabling Mexico to become a strategic source of US imports.
Portrayed by mainstream economists and major policymakers as a “win-win” tri-
umph of “free trade” theory, this book documents the opposing reality imposed
by NAFTA and the US-Mexico-Canada Free Trade Agreement on both the US
and Mexican working classes. US economists foretold a dramatic narrowing of the
income gap—the US would benefit; Mexico would benefit even more. But instead,
the yawning gap increased for three decades, bringing devastation for workers while
debilitating Mexico’s national industrial base.

James M. Cypher is Emeritus Research Professor at the Universidad Autónoma


de Zacatecas, Mexico, and Emeritus Professor of Economics at California State
University, Fresno, USA.

Mateo Crossa is Research Professor at the Instituto de Investigaciones Dr. José


María Luis Mora, Mexico City, Mexico.
THE POLITICAL
ECONOMY OF
TRANSNATIONAL
POWER AND
PRODUCTION
Mexico’s Metamorphosis
1982–2022

James M. Cypher and Mateo Crossa


Designed cover image: © DALL.E 2 (openai.com/dall-e-2) and Chris Sturr
First published 2024
by Routledge
4 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN
and by Routledge
605 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10158
Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business
© 2024 James M. Cypher and Mateo Crossa
The right of James M. Cypher and Mateo Crossa to be identified as authors
of this work has been asserted in accordance with sections 77 and 78 of the
Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or
utilised in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now
known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in any
information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the
publishers.
Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or registered
trademarks, and are used only for identification and explanation without intent
to infringe.
British Library Cataloguing-in-Publication Data
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
ISBN: 978-1-032-30917-0 (hbk)
ISBN: 978-1-032-30918-7 (pbk)
ISBN: 978-1-003-30726-6 (ebk)
DOI: 10.4324/9781003307266
Typeset in Bembo
by SPi Technologies India Pvt Ltd (Straive)
CONTENTS

List of Figures vii


List of Tables viii
List of Focus Boxes ix
Acknowledgments x
Acronyms xii
Preface xiv

1 The Remaking of Mexico: The State, Economic Elite, and


US Capital 1982–92 1

2 From NAFTA to the PAN’s Implosion: Mexico Remade


for US TNCs 1992–2012 31

3 Stagnation and Income Dispersion Sink New PRI and


Fracture US Labor: 2012–8 68

4 López Obrador in Power, 2018–22: A Transformational or


Conformational Moment? 95

5 Export-Led Accumulation: Paradoxes of the Leading Auto Sector 128

6 Petroleum: A Strategic Resource for Houston’s TNCs or Mexico? 170


vi Contents

7 Mining and Agriculture: Supporting Pillars of the


Transnational Structure 199

8 Some Final Reflections on Dependence and Asymmetry 226

References 236
Index 260
FIGURES

5.1 Number of Workers in the Automotive Industry in


Mexico (Thousands) 139
5.2 US-Canadian Content in Cars Assembled in Mexico 141
5.3 Total Researchers in R&D Areas per Thousand Employees 152
5.4 Latin American Capital Goods Imports (Billions of Dollars) 153
5.5 Number of Employees by Auto Sub-branch in Mexico
and the US (2019) 161
5.6 Workers and Value-Added per Worker in the US
Assembly Industry and in Mexico’s Electrical and
Electronic Parts Production (2018) 161
5.7 Number of Workers and Monthly Wages by Auto
Sub-branches in Mexico (Monthly Wages in Mexican
Pesos 2018) 162
7.1 Direct Jobs in Metallic and Nonmetallic Minerals Mining
(Thousands) 211
7.2 Mexico’s Agricultural and Agro-industry Trade Balance
(Billions USD) 220
TABLES

2.1 Failure of the US/Mexico Income Convergence Hypothesis 58


3.1 Formal and Informal Sector “Subordinated Employees” 2013–18
(Millions or Percent) 71
4.1 Net New Foreign Investment and New Investment as % of
Nonfinancial Capital Inflows (Billions of Current US Dollars) 106
5.1 Mexico: Production by Auto TNCs 140
5.2 Total Vehicle Production and Auto-Related Private
R&D Investment (Millions of Vehicle or Billions of USD, 2018) 155
5.3 Main Vehicle Components Exported from Mexico to
the US (2021: in Percent) 160
FOCUS BOXES

1.1 Creation of the Maquila Regime 6


1.2 Abandonment of Mexico’s Sectorial Industrial Policies 20
1.3 The Mexican-Austrian Origins of Neoliberalism 25
2.1 The Unique Role of Monterrey Capital 33
2.2 A Champion of “Free Trade” Harbors Second Thoughts? 38
2.3 Emerging Fragmentation of National Capital’s Power 46
2.4 Waning Presidencialismo under Transnationalized Capital 51
2.5 Remittances: A Necessary Consideration 56
2.6 Growth Accounting: “Astounding” Numbers 60
3.1 Minimizing Labor’s Share 73
3.2 US Labor Force Displacement Due to NAFTA 80
4.1 De-fetishizing FDI 105
4.2 Build US-Buy US: Auto Sector IP in 2022 113
5.1 Industrial Fragmentations: A Brief Summary of Export
Manufacturing135
5.2 Absent “National Champion” Firms, Mexico Sites R&D Abroad 156
5.3 Labor Becomes Its Own, Best, Protagonist 164
6.1 Mexico’s Oil Nationalization in Context 171
6.2 Oil and Industrial Policy 176
6.3 Building National Innovation Capacity at the National
Petroleum Institute 182
6.4 The Petroleum Workers’ Union: Encrusted Power,
Zero Accountability 188
7.1 Technological Sophistication: The Basis of Mega-Mining 205
7.2 Emergence of Lithium? 212
7.3 From Ejido to TNC Agribusiness 214
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

We are grateful for the assistance received in researching and writing this book.
In particular, we thank the following individuals: Arnulfo Arteaga, Dean Baker,
Guillermo Foladori, Arthur MacEwan, Josefina Morales, Juan Carlos Moreno Brid,
Gabriel Ondetti, Gerardo Otero, Oscar Pérez Veyna, Richard Roman, Chris Sturr,
Darcy Tetreault, and Chris Tilly.
For facilitating our field research in Detroit, we thank Kristin Dziczek. In the
border region, we thank numerous maquila auto parts workers who must remain
anonymous. They graciously gave of their precious time to increase our understand-
ing of labor processes and working conditions and their struggles to outmaneuver
an entrenched union hierarchy devoted to keeping them in their place.
María Eugenia Correa Vásquez (1954–2021) was an unremitting supporter of
our past research efforts, some appearing in her journal Ola Financiera. Her cosmo-
politan scholarly acumen, her joie de vivre, and her guidance were sorely missed as
we toiled to give shape to this manuscript.
We are also grateful to two extremely supportive anonymous reviewers tapped
by our publisher, Routledge, to evaluate early drafts of selected chapters.
At the Instituto Mora in Mexico City, we thank Mónica Toussaint for resolutions
regarding administrative matters.
We further acknowledge the adroit investigative skills of California State
University Research Librarian Sarah McDaniel and her colleague Chris Langer
confirming M. Thatcher’s arrival in Mexico—coinciding with the calamity of pres-
ident-to-be Luis Donaldo Colosio’s murder on March 23, 1994. We cite her, prob-
ably undelivered, speech transcript planned for March 25 in Chapter 8. As well,
librarians Carol Doyle and David Drexler speedily provided needed manuscripts.
As has been the case with previous efforts, Routledge publishers know how
to support authors while offering sound advice on all aspects of publishing. In
Acknowledgments xi

particular, we thank Senior Economics Editor Kristina Abbotts and Economics


Editorial Assistant Christina Mandizha for suggestions and solutions large and small,
and, most especially, for providing needed flexibility.
Special thanks are due to Chris Sturr, the creative and diligent editor of the
US economics magazine Dollars & Sense, for designing the striking digital artwork
appearing on the cover, evoking the industrial mural art of the great Diego Rivera.
ACRONYMS

AMLO Andrés Manuel López Obrador


BIP Border Industrial Program
CCE Business Coordinating Council
CFE Federal Electricity Commission
COECE Coordinator of Foreign Trade Business Organizations
CTM Confederation of Mexican Workers
EOM Export-Oriented Manufacturing
EV Electric Vehicle
FDI Foreign Direct Investment
FTZ Free Trade Zone
GATT General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
GHG Greenhouse Gas Emissions
GVC Global Value Chain
IDB Inter-American Development Bank
ILO International Labor Organization
IMF International Monetary Fund
IMMEX Export Program of Manufacturing, Maquiladora and Service Industries
IMSS Mexican Social Security Institute
I-O Input-Output
IP Industrial Policy
LNG Liquefied Natural Gas
MBD Millions of Barrels per Day
NAFTA North American Free Trade Agreement
NPI National Petroleum Institute
OECD Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
OPEC Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries
Acronyms xiii

PAN National Action Party


PECE Economic Growth and Stability Pact
PEMEX Petróleos Mexicanos (Mexico’s National Oil Company)
PRD Party of the Democratic Revolutionary
PRI Institutional Revolutionary Party
PSE Economic Solidarity Pact (the Pacto)
R&D Research and Development
SAPS Structural Adjustment Programs
S&T Science and Technology
STPS Mexico’s Labor Secretariat
TAA Trade Adjustment Assistance
TNC Transnational Corporation
UAW United Auto Workers
USA*NAFTA US TNC lobby to promote NAFTA
USMCA US-Mexico-Canada Free Trade Agreement
USTR Office of the United States Trade Representative
WTO World Trade Organization
WB World Bank
PREFACE

“Blessed Mexico, so close to God, and no so far from the United States”
Andres Manuel López Obrador, President of Mexico
(August 2, 2022)

Within the span of a little over 200 years, Mexico’s always fraught relationship
with the US appears to have swung 180 degrees. At least, this would be the first
impression one might gather from the above quote. One thing that stands out with
regard to Mexico’s economic integration and subordination to the US between
that of the late 19th century and that of President López Obrador (2018–24) is the
structure that now defines Mexico in many respects—the North American Free
Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and its 2020 sequel known as the US-Mexico-Canada
Free Trade Agreement (USMCA)—that has bound Mexico’s fate since late 1993.
As we will maintain, this treaty had nearly nothing to do with so-called free trade
and everything to do with building a US-led, restrictive, largely neoliberal, eco-
nomic power bloc designed to promote US investment in Mexico and hinder all
economic rivals in creating a new transnational production zone. López Obrador
(AMLO) built his popular presidential campaign on the disparagement of neoliberal
socioeconomic policies. Now, his startling volte face (as noted in the epigram) sum-
marizes his assessment of how Mexico has fared under the USMCA and NAFTA.
How Mexico has actually fared, how the US has performed, and in what way a new
transnational system of power and production has been constituted between these
so dissimilar nations since the late 1980s is the subject of this book. We focus on
the political economy impacts affecting the majority of Mexicans and the millions
in the US working class. The focus of this book is both “worker-centric” and
“production-centric”.
It may be useful to attempt to define the scope and intent of the book through
a statement of what it is not:
Preface xv

First, it is not a “country study” of Mexico. Yes, the focus is to a considerable


degree, on Mexico: We have attempted to explicate the domain of transnational
production and its socioeconomic effects as experienced in both Mexico and the
US. Thus, we have consciously broken from a format that has dominated three
related fields of analysis: (1) Latin American Studies, (2) Mexican Studies, and (3)
U.S. Political Economy, to present a study based in International Political Economy.
Second, we have not sought to limit our analysis to what academicians define as
“primary sources” or “secondary sources”. Rather, to the degree that such consid-
erations have been warranted, we have conducted sufficient original field research,
in particular in Ciudad Juárez and Michigan, but also throughout a relevant swath
of Mexico—most particularly the Central-North states. In addition, we have been
actively researching the larger NAFTA themes since 1990, beginning with pro bono
research for the US Congress on what were at the time termed “twin plants” oper-
ations strung along the US-Mexico border, linking high wage processing in the
North with low-wage maquiladora operations in the South.
Third, this is not a book restricted to or centered on AMLO’s thus-far popular
administration: As with several preceding administrations examined here, we have
sought to convey the ideas and political economy initiatives of his (sometimes nation-
alist) regime. Conveyance of its essence is no simple proposition since opaque policy
positions shift, introducing a vexing element of elusiveness: For example, AMLO’s
frequent early references to the hegemony of “the mafia of power”, was reversed in
the fourth Presidential Informe (September 1, 2022) with the declaration that “the
oligarchy is no longer dominant”. But, the available evidence, some presented in this
book, suggests that the oligarch-producing processes of income, wealth, and power
concentration in Mexico (and in the US) have proceeded unabated.
Over the past 40-plus years, research that has informed our writing has occurred
in a variety of settings—including extensive field research via structured inter-
views, particularly with a substantial number of maquila managers and via in-plant
research—including, discussions and interviews conducted with operatives, local
functionaries and local TNC managers (particularly in industrial parks but also at
giant, stand-alone plants such as Nissan in Morelos and Aguascalientes). In addition,
we have conducted extensive interviews with government functionaries assigned
to implement state-level industrial development programs in several key industri-
alizing Mexican states (including Aguascalientes, Coahuila, Guanajuato, and San
Luis Potosí). We have engaged in discussions with representatives of the maquila
association, as well as exchanges with researchers (particularly those involved with
research and development (R&D) and innovation). We have met with labor leaders
and dissident workers (particularly in troubled Ciudad Juárez). We have participated
in and presented research at numerous national and international conferences. All
this research has culminated in numerous publications. As always, research sup-
porting the ideas, critiques, and conclusions presented in this book rests on moun-
tains of published official data, newspaper and other press accounts (which we have
carefully followed), academic journals, popular sources, published (often official)
reports, nonacademic sources, and books.
xvi Preface

We are confident that, in spite of our efforts, there are some materials we have
not accessed. This is due to the fact that a large body of difficult-to-access unre-
ferenced materials, often of limited circulation, particularly in Mexico, has intro-
duced tangible limits constraining our intended “comprehensive” research efforts.
Nevertheless, within these bounds, we have made every possible effort to find,
read, and digest the extant written materials, only some of which are cited in the
long bibliography. Many excellent studies have not been referenced—their absence
being a result of our decision to write a text of manageable length. We have sought
to compress a very important and very complex transnational metamorphosis that has
fundamentally restructured Mexico while extensively transforming the US—which
yet remains a process of further consolidation.
In the present era of the transnationalization of production, we prioritize the
emergence and consolidation of the cross-border system of power defining and
delimiting Mexico’s socioeconomic development. The striking epigram cited at
the outset denotes the vast gulf between the weary “realist” perspective—national
“interests are eternal and perpetual” and will be pursued, as famously stated by
Lord Palmerston in 1848—and AMLO’s “ahistorical-naïve” perspective regarding
Mexico’s interface with the US. Mexico’s socioeconomic subordination in the late
19th century during the “primary-export” regime built to extract resources needed
as the US consolidated its industrial dominance in a new age of monopoly capital
constituted an early system of limited, resource-based transnational production. In
this book, we explore the degree to which another famous epigram “plus ça change,
plus c’est la même chose” should resonate today in Mexico under the newly consoli-
dated export-led, manufacturing regime of dissonant, cross-border, asymmetrically,
integrated accumulation.
1
THE REMAKING OF MEXICO
The State, Economic Elite, and US Capital
1982–92

The Framework: A Prefatory Synopsis


How Mexico’s 1982–92 transformation occurred is difficult to summarize: Suffice
it to say that what had been a successful state-led process of rapid (if uneven) eco-
nomic development was confronted with a forking path in the 1970s—one path led
to continuation, the other promised new opportunity. The opportunity consisted of
a vast expansion in a far-from-new industry, oil. The 1970s, especially viewed from
the US, were convulsive: Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC)
seized the moment (after decades of patiently and quietly providing an ever-larger
mass of exports to the advanced industrial nations) to exercise c­ onsiderable con-
trol over global supply, sending prices skyrocketing at various moments as supplies
swung about. A decade or so before, the US had plenty of oil, but then its oilfields
reached what were considered the doldrums of “peak oil”.
In the midst of what was a very messy situation provoking recession tenden-
cies and stop-go processes of economic growth, Mexico’s then proud national oil
company, Pemex (the state’s crown jewel) hit some very big new discoveries. With
prices seemingly ever on the rise, and big-league oil exports looming around the
corner, Mexico refocused on quick gains—adopting a “something-for-nothing”
rentier strategy. But, in doing so, Mexico required considerable new investments in
drilling platforms, pipelines, oil tankers, and refinery capacity: Some high-­quality
steel and some ship-building could be provided nationally, much of the rest required
importation.
This need to pay for imported equipment and technologies coincided with the
emergence of so-called petro-dollars money flowing out of the Middle East into
European banks. Idle funds are a bankers’ curse: Mexico became a great place to
move Europe’s money surplus—oil being the ideal collateral for massive injections
of foreign loans. Lenders from around the world began calling Mexico, begging

DOI: 10.4324/9781003307266-1
2 The Remaking of Mexico

Pemex to take yet another loan. But, alas and predictably, all raw materials booms
simply presage busts. When the bust came at the end of the 1970s, getting worse
by 1981, oil prices plunged, loans stopped, and then things got worse: In inflation-­
adjusted terms, from 1980–7, oil prices fell by 27.4 percent and continued to drop–
down by 72 percent in 1988—further collapsing to 84 percent below the record
high 1980 price in 1998 (McMahan 2021). But, repayment schedules remained,
and the noose tightened.
This crucial juncture had a great deal to do with US policymaking and with the
odd monetarist ideas of Milton Friedman: In 1979, the US was experiencing, for
the second time in the 1970s, a relatively high rate of inflation (roughly 11 percent
at its peak, about the same as 1974–5). Unlike 1974–5, however, Friedman’s idea
that inflation could be contained by controlling the supply of money became influ-
ential among those setting monetary policy. This context, and the naïve nature of
President Jimmy Carter’s economic management, enabled Friedman devotee Paul
Volcker’s appointment to run the US Federal Reserve. Then, and now, global credit
markets generally follow the lead of the Fed as it sets basic lending rates. In October
1979, Volcker imposed dramatic new measures in attempting to restrict the money
supply. By December, the interest rate on intermediate bonds had soared to 10 per-
cent, then 12 percent by February 1980. Short-term interbank rates set by the Fed
shot to 19 percent by April; one-year loans financed at 7 percent in 1978 leaped to
17 percent in 1981 (Goodfriend and King 2005: 983, 985, 995–8).
In the US, recession ensued. International bank lending to Mexico slowed
moderately but then reaccelerated in 1981, reversing course subsequently and fall-
ing by about 20 percent in the following year. In 1981, the World Bank (WB)
made its largest loan ever to Mexico, apparently chiefly at the behest of Mexico’s
powerful Ministry of Budgeting and Programming, headed by future president
Miguel de la Madrid (1982–8) along with his top aide, economic and social pol-
icy director, another future president Carlos Salinas (1988–94), who convinced
most WB economists involved that Mexico’s problems were transitory—although
by then overall foreign debt had jumped by 119 percent from 1978–80 (Toussaint
2020). Only months before Mexico subsequently defaulted on its foreign debt
in August 1982—sending shock waves abroad—the head of the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) wrote to then President López Portillo (1976–82) that “the
recent setback for the Mexican economy is bound to be transient” after meeting
with his top aides, including, most likely, Carlos Salinas (Kapur, Lewis, and Webb
1997: 603).
Mexico flailed, but by late 1982, the gig was up. Mexico’s business elite was
watching events, having as always the inside track on information. They knew. And
so, starting probably sometime in 1981, wildly accelerating in 1982, they performed
the “sacadolares” dance: They grabbed up almost all the dollars that had been circu-
lating freely in Mexico’s banking system and engaged in massive capital flight, most
probably taking out, in a period of 18 months, about all of what had flowed into
Mexico via foreign loans since the mid-1970s. Massive capital flight, 1981–2, likely
reached 5 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) (Buffie and Krause 1989: 152).
The Remaking of Mexico 3

Capital flight along with the threat to withhold investment (or its converse, the
conditioned willingness to invest) are two crucial measures of capital’s structural
power—policy decisions are made on its behalf “without need for concerted polit-
ical action” when systemic forces result in a “correcting” procedure, or a reversal
or a marginalization of any initiative that might impinge upon capital’s prerogatives
(Fairfield 2015: 414–25). Instrumental power can be calibrated by taking into account
the crucial role of peak business associations, particularly in Mexico, in achieving
specific short-run objectives through “concerted political action” in terms of the
return on capital as the state acts as the instrument of capital. This chapter is con-
cerned with events, and responses to events, that shifted the underlying relations
of state and capital, reducing rapidly the autonomy of the former. In the US, if
less dramatically, a largely similar role regarding capital’s enhanced scope and sway
has been both theoretically detailed and empirically documented (Gilens and Page
2014; Romm 2021).
Mexico’s then president (López Portillo)—who had only pronounced a short
time before that Mexico’s problems had been reduced to “managing abundance”—
said he had a list of the “sacadolares” mafia—but he never released any data despite
his promise to do so. Instead, expressing justified pique, he nationalized the banks.
And, to everyone’s surprise, including conservative small business owners who were
aghast at what they considered to be the sudden arrival of “socialism”, for the
first time, the banks became responsive to everyday Mexicans as efficiency leaped
upward. But that did not last long—the banks were “privatized” in 1991—gifting
the public banks to the new elite of financiers in a process replete with favoritism.

The Crisis of 1982–3 and the Rise of Structural Adjustment


1982 was quite a year, and 1983 was not measurably better. The long period of
“stabilized growth” had given way to wild inflation, and the canceling of dol-
lar accounts at the bank with depositors eventually paid off in devalued pesos.
Necessities, like milk, suddenly could only be found on the black market, or not
at all. Wages collapsed; dignified professionals plunged straight down into penury.
The middle class felt abandoned, and they were. Engineers started driving cabs;
they never found a way back to professional employment. Mexico needed help; it
could not help itself.
Help came, at a price, from the US government and the IMF. The IMF wanted
“austerity”—cut government spending on necessary services, went the old refrain,
and “loosen” the labor market by inducing unemployment. Then, by some sort
of magic only found in the imagination of neoclassical economists, the economy
would recover. It did not. Following the IMF recipe by shrinking public sector
spending while forcing down wages, Mexico’s economy shrunk, as one would
expect. According to what are known as “Ricardian Equivalencies”, if economic
activity shrinks in one area (always assuming full employment of labor and all other
“resources”), it has to rise in another—namely, investment. When none of this pro-
grammed fantasy occurred (how could it?), when the “medicine” of the “money
4 The Remaking of Mexico

doctors” failed, the answer was…a larger portion of medicine. As the 1980s ground
on, the WB brought to Mexico the greatest ideas Washington had to offer—
Structural Adjustment Programs (SAPs). These programs were a leap into the
unknown, as never before. Structural adjustment essentially meant that the recipient
nation had to abandon its conventional sovereign practices, and the IMF (through
“cross-conditionality”) also participated in the WB-led program to remake Mexico
as the exemplar export-led economy.

Transforming the Production System: De-territorialization/


Re-territorialization
The crisis of 1982–3 was somewhat stanched by a $3.5 billion 90-day loan on
the part of the US, which, as it reached its limits in December 1982, was then
supplemented by a $3.8 billion loan from the IMF. This was coupled with a two-
year moratorium on $23 billion in public debt repayments with a large number
of US-owned commercial banks. Other exercises in financial re-engineering fol-
lowed, most particularly the “Baker Plan”, but overall, these resulted in failure:
In 1981, external debt was a manageable 36 percent of GDP, but a year later, it
had shot to 49 percent, while—even after the IMF intervened again in 1986 with
a $1.4 billion loan—external debt rose to 78 percent of GDP. But, in 1989, the
“Brady Plan” resulted in a restructuring of $50 billion in external debt either
by (1) waiving 35 percent of Mexico’s debts or (2) considerably reducing inter-
est payments, or (3) offering new loans on these debts over the period 1989–92
(Brinke 2013).
The Brady Plan allowed the Mexican government to reclaim usage of a signifi-
cant part of its budget, given that in early 1989, 60 percent had been diverted to pay
foreign creditors: Total foreign, and internal, debt dropped from 1988 to 1994, fall-
ing from 63 percent of GDP to 22 percent. But, the impacts of the devastating crisis
went far beyond debt reshuffling agreements: The IMF, the WB, and the US gov-
ernment (which effectively controls the IMF and the WB) initiated a broad range
of fundamental changes, particularly with regard to how Mexico could exercise its
own sovereignty. Under the state-led developmentalist policies that reigned from
1940–82, Mexico had promoted a vast array of industrial activities (Cypher 1990:
127–53), using a variety of measures to do so, including subsidies, quotas, and tariffs
to limit the importation of competing products (along with creating state-owned
enterprises to promote national industrialization and deal with “market failures”).
As dictated by the SAPs, of the 1,155 state-owned companies in 1982, only 259
remained in 1991(Ángeles 1992: 164). The Mexican state reduced its participation
in national production from 25 percent of GDP in 1983 to less than 16 percent in
1992, while state employment decreased almost 10 percent, with respect to total
occupation.
But then, either autonomously or through joint-determination with the IMF
and WB, Mexico joined the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT),
with President de la Madrid (1982–8) authorizing Mexico’s entry petition in late
The Remaking of Mexico 5

1985. Having entered GATT in 1986, the US arranged for Mexico to sign the
“US-Mexico Bilateral Framework Agreement on Trade and Investment” in 1987
(Erb and Greenwald 1989: 125). This was the initial step down the road that led to
NAFTA’s approval in 1993. The 1987 Agreement had been preceded by an outline
bilateral agreement at the behest of “interested business leaders” in late 1984 (Erb
and Greenwald 1989: 125). Thus, the “decision” to enter GATT, locking in Mexico
to policies that presaged the abandonment of the state-led industrialization project,
was one that originated, directly or indirectly from the US in 1984/5. By 1989,
restrictions on foreign ownership in many areas, excluding so-called strategic ones,
were greatly relaxed. By 1991, tariffs had been drastically reduced, quotas affected
only 20 percent of imports, and a massive sell-off of state firms was underway. The
US was particularly interested in setting up nonreversible arrangements with regard
to all transnational investments, actual and potential. The exercises in transnational
power intensified: By October 1989, Mexico had signed three trade and investment
accords with the US, one an “understanding on trade and investment facilitation”,
another designating specific sectors to be prioritized, and a third designed to “pro-
mote” transnational business opportunities” (Erb and Greenwald 1989: 127).
In large measure, this drive to impose transnational production structures on
Mexico came from large US corporations and their representative organizations,
particularly the Business Roundtable and the US Chamber of Commerce.1 But
also, especially in the crucial period 1983–91, many very powerful Monterrey-based
industrial firms—sometimes known as the Monterrey Group, which was formed
in the late 19th century from no more than 20 merchant, banking, and industrial
family-dominated enterprises (Gauss 2010: 207–20). Never loyal to the state-led
model (even as they grew and prospered as a result of it), they also advocated for a
transnationalized production and trade structure: As the ’80s crisis ground on, they
increasingly visualized a solution for their excess capacity through both large-scale
exports and establishing subsidiaries in the US.
Three decades later, of the 142 nationally controlled firms listed on the Mexican
stock exchange, 51 had become transnational corporations (TNCs) by 2019, but
only 10 were in manufacturing or resource-based heavy industry (Salas-Porras and
Medina-Hernández 2021: 5; 12–3; 16). In the fragile circumstances of the ’80s, the
Monterrey-based impresarios knew how to apply their economic power within the
political labyrinth in Mexico City. They, and a significant number of other business
leaders, to an unprecedented degree, broke with the underlying socio-political con-
sensus that had reigned for decades, by politically aligning with the right-wing PAN
(Partido Acción Nacional) party, created in 1939. Thus for presidents de la Madrid and
then Salinas, the rush to bend to the demands of transnational power were primarily
driven by pull factors emanating from the US, but also by push factors emanating
from AmCham de México members (then selling the output of their US-owned
branch plants into the shrinking internal market). Meanwhile, a powerful cluster of
national capital—the Monterrey Group in particular—also promoted the new turn.
Nonetheless, the largest units of capital, including bank capital, while alarmed by
López Portillo’s decision to nationalize the banks and critical of his petroleum-first
6 The Remaking of Mexico

strategy, sought conciliation with the traditional power base as operated by the mas-
sive, generally inclusive, and sophisticated Partido Revolucionario Institucional (PRI)
ruling continually from 1929 to 2000 (and then from 2012–18). Yet, the insurgency
of northern capital in the ’80s signaled an important rupture providing a new,
strong, and versatile national power base, which over time, eventually was ready and
able to capture emerging possibilities as they opened in the 1990s: There were two
merging vectors, one coming from large capital clustered in and around Monterrey,
where the powerful ultra-conservative employers association Coparmex (formed in
1929) held sway; the other—also in the north—arose from footloose capital migrat-
ing south from the US to take advantage of the Border Industrial Program (BIP) by
setting up maquila plants (see Focus 1.1).

FOCUS 1.1: CREATION OF THE MAQUILA REGIME

The BIP (or maquila program) began in 1965, shortly after the US ended a
temporary cross-border bracero labor program in order to induce some com-
pensating employment in the northern border region; it did not gain momen-
tum until 1983 when Mexico’s Secofi (the Trade Ministry) issued a Decree for
the Promotion and Operation of Maquiladoras (Hernández Laos 2000: 313).
Significantly, this was also the moment when the CNIMME (National Council
of Maquiladora and Export Manufacturers) formed—a generally little-noticed
emergence reflecting the ongoing structural and geographic shifting of the
accumulation process. Until 1985, the border maquila assembly plants enjoyed
singular status whereby neither their component imports nor manufactured
exports were taxed. In 1985, a program known as PITEX (Hernández Laos
2000: 317–8) allowed export-based firms heavily dependent on processing
imported components not located on the border to have virtually the same
privileges as did the official maquilas (i.e., exemption from import/export tariffs
and value-added taxes on components, fuels, machinery, and parts used in
production testing and research equipment, etc.)—an important step deep-
ening and broadening what was once the largely marginal BIP into “a new
Mexican industrial project” (Arregui Velasco 1993: 165). In 1987, ALTEX—
reserved for large exporters (more than $2 million in exports)—granted both
direct and “indirect” exporters (suppliers to export operations) special, rapid,
treatment with regard to border transactions and repayment of value-added
taxes. By 1995, the PITEX firms exceeded in number the maquila firms, while
their exports were valued at 75 percent of the maquilas’. In 2006, PITEX was
essentially generalized, permitting all direct and “indirect” export firms (sup-
plier firms) exemption from tariffs and trade regulations throughout all of
Mexico under the IMMEX (Export Program of Manufacturing, Maquiladora
and Service Industries) program (Gambrill 2008).
The Remaking of Mexico 7

We refer to the entire period from 1965 onward as “the maquila regime”
rather than limiting such usage only for 1965–85. PITEX transformed the BIP
program: What had once been an offhand concession to the long-neglected
border region—being initially a gap-filling measure to somewhat compensate
for the lost “bracero program” (1942–64)—partially addressed an endemic
labor surplus problem by attracting simple assembly plants to a narrow “Free
Trade Zone” just south of the long border. The pace of the setup of these
plants was initially very slow; five years after the program began, there were
only 120 plants employing 20,000 workers. But by 1974, employment had
increased 273 percent, now spread across 455 plants. Growth was periodically
interrupted by recessions in the US, but by 1985, when the PITEX program
commenced, there were 760 plants employing 212,000 low-wage workers. As
the crisis of the ’80s drug on, as Mexican workers’ real wages went down until
1984 (rising moderately thereafter until 1994, but only recovering their 1984
level in 2002) the maquila siting process boomed: By 1988, the plant count
reached 1,400, with employment registering 370,000 (Carrillo Huerta 1990:
32). From 1994 to 2002, maquila employment nearly doubled, reaching one
million (Cypher 2004: 362–3), while from 2004 to 2019, IMMEX workers rose
from 1.4 to 3 million. The exponential growth of maquilas in the northern bor-
der occurred parallel to the industrial decline of central regions in the country,
which had been pivotal in supplying the domestic market during the “import
substitution” (or state-led) period. This process was driven by the US’s counter-
ing of a surge of Japanese production capacity into its South.
The massive subsidies to the border plants and the PITEX firms, along with
low wages, actually constituted an atypical industrial policy: Instead of certain
sectors selected and promoted by the state, Mexico’s policy centered on guar-
anteeing low wages with an unlimited labor supply, in addition to offering any
temporary import-export firm (TIEF) an array of other incentives. Standing at
27 percent in 1980, by 1993, nearly 70 percent of all exports were processed
through the TIEFs either as maquilas or increasingly as PITEX operators, rising
to nearly 80 percent by 2002 (Puyana 2010: 8). Rarely mentioned were many
other TIEF subsidies in addition to those cited earlier: (1) usually comparatively
cheap water, gas and electricity; (2) low land rent and construction costs; (3)
possible exemptions, under one pretext or another, from corporate taxes; (4)
state-subsidized business financing; and (5) access to government-financed
labor training programs.

Resentment, arising from their relative exclusion from this large-firm/state-cap-


ital nexus centered in and near Mexico City, was strongest among medium-sized
firms, particularly in the north (Mizrahi 1992: 793). By 1975, medium-size indus-
trial firms had experienced stronger growth than the rest but remained a subor-
dinated faction—even as they held 35 percent of all industrial capital (Mizrahi
8 The Remaking of Mexico

1992: 753). As the crisis commencing in 1981 drug on, sometimes deepening,
northern capital—which was, relatively, not so beholden to the national gov-
ernment—was more willing to break with the state-led economic policies engi-
neered through the PRI/large capital alliance. Configuring this break effectively
meant embracing neoliberalism and one of its major tenets—an export-led
accumulation strategy. As the consensus between state and capital fractured due
to divisions among the owners of capital, the initiative for constructing a new
configuration arose from the provinces under the influence of Coparmex (very
much in alliance with US capital)—a process that increased throughout the 1980s
(Mizrahi 1992: 757). In 1970, Coparmex had only 7,000 members: It operated
in the shadows cast by the hegemonic alliance between the state and the large
industrial-financial conglomerates as instituted in the paradigm-setting Cárdenas
era, 1934–40 (Gauss 2010; Hamilton 1982). As the neoliberal turn gained
traction—this being the construction of a new nexus between state and capital to
build out an emerging transnational productive structure—Mexico’s national
project was not to shrink the state, or sideline it with regard to the economic
structure, but to redirect it. As this process gained traction, by 1990, employers
associated with Coparmex jumped to 36,000 (Mizrahi 1992: 757): State pol-
icy was coalescing on Coparmex’s anti-labor stance. As the ’80s commenced,
or shortly before, US firms dominating the Mexican auto industry from their
Mexico City region plants, but now facing union pressures and Japan’s more
efficient plants, relocated to the north to nonunionized, often nonindustrial
areas: This shift expressed and augmented the regional power of Coparmex and
the Monterrey Group.

Export Promotion
The shift to maquilization in the north as the new epicenter of capital accumulation
was noted early (Arregui Velasco 1993). With economic dynamics centering on
the north (Cypher 2004: 362–3; Félix and Dávila 2008), Mexico experienced a
structural shift as the external market became the macroeconomic driver—exports
leaped from an insignificant 4.8 percent of GDP in 1956–70 to 9.1 percent during
the oil boom 1978–81. Then they grew at an annual rate of 5.8 percent per year
from 1982 to 1993 and then (before the US economy began to swoon in 2007) by
a truly remarkable 11.1 percent per year from 1993 to 2006 (Moreno-Brid and Ros
2009: 101, 127, 181).
Foreign trade, measured as exports plus imports, rose from 27 percent of GDP
(1982–4, when the internal market shrunk) to 62.6 percent (2004–6)—most strik-
ing was the rapid rise in intra-industry cross-border movements—an indicator not
of trade but of integrated transnational production: Accounting for only 7 percent of
foreign trade in 1982, these interdependent intra-industry (often intra-firm) trans-
actions rose to 17 percent in 1987 as the new structure consolidated, quickly reach-
ing 30 percent by 1990 (Thacker 2000: 166).
The Remaking of Mexico 9

Instead of “international trade” based on highly differentiated products—here-


tofore the essence of cross-border trade—a new era of transnational production was
well underway, arising from, particularly, a dramatic drop in international transpor-
tation and communications costs—but also, importantly, from a new international
institution structure facilitating cross-border integrated production systems: This is
the complimentary double-movement undergirding a new era of accumulation—
the internationalization of capital. As part of the institutional structure that enabled
capital to shift across borders while denying labor any new options, it facilitated
“labor arbitrage” tactics to (1) make technologically complex portions of a final
product in advanced industrial nations, (2) ship the product to a nation in the
Global South (or Eastern Europe) where labor-intensive components were made
or assembled, and then (3) ship a finalized product across the border to a high-in-
come nation for final sale (Cypher 2021: 612–23). In fact, completing the process
of transnational production by producing a final consumer or capital good could
involve multiple border crossings, sometimes between two nations. (In the NAFTA,
now USMCA region, auto parts and components can cross borders eight times
before final assembly.)
From 1983 onward, as outlined in the 1983–9 National Development Plan (and
at a quickening pace through 1988), the Mexican government in its own right (and
increasingly in concert with the WB and IMF) orchestrated a number of changes
to realize the new turn based in export promotion. Many policy and program changes
were small, some more notable; all provided a cumulative effect (Cypher 1991:
87–93). As a result, the extremely influential neoliberal head of the Secretariat
for Trade and Industrial Promotion (Secofi), Héctor Hernández Cervantes (1988:
531), declared that Mexico had taken momentous steps to consolidate the most
important political economy shift in 70 years—which he termed a new growth model.
More accurately, Eduardo Gitli (1990: 161) declared this complex package of poli-
cies and initiatives as the “consolidation of an exportation model directed by trans-
national corporations”.
What has generally been lost in the ample documentation of this new turn
is the extent to which it was not consistent with the “commandments” of the
Washington Consensus or with neoliberalism, narrowly understood—it was not
a market-driven or “entrepreneurial” process. Instead, it was the result of massive
national and transnational government interventions, one element of which stands
out above all: the nationally owned export bank, Bancomext, showered subsidized
credits on private-sector export firms at a rate difficult to imagine: In 1990, the
credits extended amounted to the equivalent value of 7 percent of GDP, an aston-
ishing figure. Between 1982 and 1989—the crucial period in terms of policy for-
mation and implementation—Bancomext lent $56 billion to export firms, a sum
equal to 78 percent of the total value of all private-sector exports (Cypher 1991:
91, 105). Despite such obvious transgressions in terms of the market-driven “free
trade” policies that the WB and IMF proclaimed to be the only way to achieve
growth, these multilaterals (along with Bancomext) made the incredible claim that
Mexico had followed a process of neutrality (Cypher 1991: 100)—thereby ignoring
10 The Remaking of Mexico

completely these, and other massive state subsidies directed at export firms.
According to the government, the program was a horizontal industrial policy—
something the WB and IMF were willing to tolerate. But, it was actually a sub
rosa, vertical, large-firm, industrial policy, promoting especially only two key
industries that were of interest to the TNCs, electronics and auto vehicle and
parts production. Here are some of the export promotion measures taken from
1983 through 1989/90 (Cypher 1991: 98–9):

• The key government development bank, Nacional Financiera (Nafinsa), was


restructured to both finance export production and to engage its very exten-
sive cadre of economic specialists to advise and facilitate a transformation of
Mexico’s industrial base to enhance export-oriented manufacturing (EOM).
At that time, Nafinsa was renowned for its “state capacity”—highest of all gov-
ernment entities. This effort was seconded by Bancomext, which channeled
massive sums to support EOM. As well, Secofi supported and implemented the
procedures developed by Nafina and Bancomext.
• The government developed two financing programs, FICORCA and DIMEX,
to quickly make available to importers and exports subsidized hard currencies
(usually the hard-to-get US dollar (USD)), as well as providing for foreign-ex-
change risks when currencies fluctuated while allowing the large national con-
glomerate firms, or “national power groups” extensive access to subsidized hard
currencies in order to pay-down their non-peso denominated foreign debts.
• Certain exemptions from profit taxes due by importer/exporter firms were
provided, as well as relocation subsidies, as companies moved to the north,
while also allowing them accelerated depreciation write-offs on the purchase
of capital goods. In parallel, the state constructed freeways, railways, ports, and
communication systems to facilitate EOM.
• Mexico-based US TNCs—relative to their US-based expenditures—could
count on a 33 percent reduction in electricity costs, a 65 percent drop in nat-
ural gas prices, a 33–50 percent drop in the price of construction, a 60 percent
decline in the price of water, and land and installations rents of 20 percent to
50 percent below equivalent facilities in the US (Shaiken 1990: 92).
• FDI (foreign direct investment) activities at 100 percent ownership levels com-
menced on a “case by case basis” if firms agreed to a given export production
quota—a step that greatly facilitated the doubling of such investment, 1982–8.
The state streamlined/accelerated its heretofore clogged permissions processes
for EOM activities (a matter of major consideration in Mexico).

A New Growth Pole: A Theoretical Formulation of Mexico’s


Transnational Turn
Originally—as pioneered by François Perroux (1903–87)—the elusively abstract
growth pole concept combined geographic specificity with economic dynamics
rooted in production, not exchange; his analysis focused on (1) power (a matter elided in
The Remaking of Mexico 11

neoclassical economics) as an “inalienable component of economic activity” and (2)


the potential developmental effects of accelerating investment in industrial activi-
ties in specific geographic areas or regions: These were termed “growth poles” (de
Bernis 1994: 154; Hansen 1989). Perroux and others maintained that, through
agglomeration, complementarity, and synergy effects created when new plants and
equipment are supported by infrastructure investments, a specific industrial branch,
in a specific geographical area, could grow rapidly. Such growth would generate
dynamic “spread effects” into other geographic regions of the affected nation.
However, Mexico’s experience is one of cross-border reterritorialization/deter-
ritorialization; Perroux—so focused on power—would have understood the US
incursion as what he termed “the dominant economy” into a “marginal” area
(Mexico’s convulsed/impoverished border region). This fostered a new growth
pole—a case of what Perroux noted as “intentional dominance” (Guillén 2007–8:
16). In such an instance, what Perroux termed “the influence of the structure”—this
being the interdependent totally of socioeconomic relations—“is the dominance
exercised, in the medium and long term, of one structure over another. This can
be exercised between firms, industries, regions and nations” (Guillén, 2007–8: 16).
The question to be analyzed in an export-oriented economy (such as Mexico) is
the “optimal level of openness” to be achieved, wherein national control is sufficient
to overcome tendencies toward dominance and disarticulation that arise from “an
imprudent opening”: thus, either a nation can find the means to implement its
capacities and ambitions for change or it will fall onto a path of external subordina-
tion to a dominant nation, resulting in national disorganization/deterritorialization
wherein FDI both shapes the region and also leaves it bereft of nationally propagat-
ing production processes and innovation capabilities (Guillén, 2007–8: 20). As such, if
a nation succumbs to conditions of “intentional dominance”, the “influence of
the structure” results in the consolidation of an inauthentic transnational production
structure. In Perroux’s analysis, authentic growth included those processes driving
economic growth that result in (1) an increase in national wealth, and (2) improve-
ment in the well-being of all citizens, accompanied by (3) a rise in productivity
through the incorporation of new technologies (Guillén, 2007–8: 15).
Yet, after 40 years wherein this transnational region grew rapidly, the asymmet-
ric benefits produced via transnational production meant that Mexico failed on all
three counts: Most stark was the data provided by Mexico’s top poverty researcher,
Julio Boltvinik (2022a: 20) revealing the devastating scope of national poverty; only
27 percent of the population in 2020 (34.4 million) were not living below the pov-
erty level.3 Of the rural populace (29.3 million), only 11.7 percent were not living in
poverty (Boltvinik 2022a: 20). But, and this is extremely important with regard to
the idea of a “growth pole”, excluding Mexico City, the ten states with the highest
incidence of nonpoor (ranging from 36 percent to 44 percent of the population)
were all in the north, including all border states—indicating the lack of “spread”,
“externality” and “spill-over” effects (Boltvinik 2022b: 22).
For Perroux, development ultimately meant that the “costs of man” were ade-
quately met through the functioning and reproduction of the socioeconomic
12 The Remaking of Mexico

system: That is, all the citizenry are able to live their lives under conditions wherein
their life expectancy, their health, and their access to knowledge would be com-
mensurate with the existing state of science and productive capacities of any given
historical moment. Using this metric, the data provided by Boltvinik are an excel-
lent proximate measure of how drastically and pathetically inadequate has been
Mexico’s prolonged engagement with a transnational system of production under
conditions of “intentional dominance”.

Partially Resolving the US Dilemma


By the late 1970s, the US had become long-accustomed to being “the first among
equals”, the exceptional nation that—from the early 1940s onward as the “American
Century” unfolded—was the unquestioned, self-confident, global hegemonic power.
This perspective, however, increasingly failed to conform in the 1970s with an
emerging new configuration of production and power wherein the once largely uni-
polar structure of production was rapidly becoming tripolar—Europe reconfigured
and expanded, while Japan’s successful regional role in Asia gave rise to widespread
US perceptions of Japan as Number One—the title of Ezra Vogel’s influential 1979
book. Japan, by 1977, had set up (or was establishing) so-called Free Trade Zones
(FTZs) in Korea (Masan), Taiwan, the Philippines (Bataan, Mindanao), Singapore,
Indonesia (Asahan), and Malaysia (Penang), strategically using its FDI (foreign direct
investment), which had surged dramatically from 1972. By 1976, Japan’s ascendant
corporations were enjoying a combination of tariff and tax privileges, subsidies, and,
especially, cheap labor in more than 335 Asian FTZs (PARC 1977: 41).
The US, by then, had lost its edge in manufacturing. Neoclassical economists
argued that this did not matter, that the US would now specialize in higher val-
ue-added activities, and that “market forces” would direct formerly well-paid,
unionized, industrial workers to new, better, jobs in the service sector and/or into
new emerging high-tech activities. But, such bland assurances contrasted with the
known facts—the US industrial areas, particularly those dominated by heavy indus-
try, were sinking as plants closed and nothing new arose. As a series of penetrating
studies demonstrated (Zysman and Tyson 1983), the US had lost its lead in the steel
industry, color television production, and semiconductors, along with a range of
formerly viable labor-intensive industries—footwear, textiles, and apparel. Most
critical of all was the very symbol of US industrial prowess—the auto industry,
where Japan’s production efficiencies were so great that their costs were at least 20
percent below Europe’s. The US trade deficit with Japan in technology-intensive
products jumped from $2 billion in 1970 to $13.5 billion in 1979, roughly $53
billion in 2022 USD (Zysman and Tyson 1983: 33).

The Paradigmatic Case of RCA


Where once US-based electronics firms dominated at home and in the global mar-
ket, Japan, using export promotion policies as early as the mid-1960s, began to
The Remaking of Mexico 13

encroach on this lucrative market. The preeminent global firm was then RCA
(formed as a subsidiary of the US giant General Electric in 1919). In 1965, its sales
were greater than all other US electronics corporations combined, but by 1975, while its
sales had increased 95 percent, the sales of the three top Japanese electronics cor-
porations leaped ahead by 459 percent (PARC 1977: 42): Their combined sales in
1975 were 19 percent larger than RCA’s, even while this company maintained its
edge over all other US electronics firms. Even though RCA’s sales had nearly dou-
bled, between 1965 and 1975, profits had fallen by roughly 10 percent.
Mainstream international economic theory, until recently, presumed that capital
was nationally based: Finished goods and raw materials, according to classical/­
neoclassical formulations, crossed borders but capital did not (nor did parts and
components). Capital stayed “at home” according to David Ricardo’s famous the-
ory of comparative advantage because capitalists were habituated to their native
social formations—its customs, laws, conventional business practices, and so on.
And, until the dawning of the new era of transnational production (blossoming fully
in the course of the 1980s), Ricardo’s perceptions on this matter were generally
accepted (even as some manufacturers set up branch plant operations in Europe,
and especially in Latin America, from the 1950s to step-over national industrial
promotion policies that constrained US-based exports).
RCA fought-off Japanese competition by first moving its capital to the non-
union US South as early as 1965. But, (1) the opening up of the Mexican border
region, (2) the attempts to unionize RCA’s massive plant in the US South, and (3)
the resistance by its southern labor force to tactics intended to intensify (speed up)
the labor process led, in December 1970, to the closure of this US plant (Cowie
1999: 92). Instead, RCA focused on Mexico, with full knowledge of the special
competitive advantage that a move to Ciudad Juárez would produce. RCA sought
mostly young female workers with a rural nonindustrial background. A double
labor arbitrage operation was brought into existence since, first, workers were avail-
able at roughly one-tenth of the US wage, while, second, female workers could be
paid even less. For RCA (and other US companies to follow), this functioned to
combat the noxious combination of rising foreign competition, stagnate (or falling)
exports, and US labor resistance by reversing the decline in profit margins. Mexico
was available to source RCA’s labor-intensive operations, while others—the more
capital-intensive and technical aspects of its vast production web—were offshored
to Taiwan or remained in the US. It was the first “Fortune 500” company to enter
the BIP. Production on a limited scale began in 1968 when RCA was the 15th
largest corporation in the US.
In Mexico, RCA expanded slowly, employing enhanced methods of social con-
trol over a labor force unavailable north of the border—including by specifically
recruiting young women, 75 percent of its workers: To its great liking, RCA had
free access to a growing labor pool, as 38 popular colonias (poor peoples’ squat-
ter-shack communities) mushroomed around Ciudad Juárez. Here a majority of
workers lived in tiny hovels shared by at least five residents. Necessary expenses for
workers’ subsistence were cut, vis-à-vis the US because workers lived in miserable,
14 The Remaking of Mexico

self-built shanties on low-value land that had been, often, seized by the squatters
or relinquished by a governmental entity (without conceding land titles). US con-
sultants who worked with leaders in Juárez were convinced that the massive labor
surplus along the border and in the northern states was so great that whatever
capital the BIP might attract would never be large enough to push wages upward
(Cowie 1999: 112).
The BIP was initiated after Mexico’s secretary of trade and industrial promo-
tion (Secofi) had visited FTZs in Asia—seeing there a model to be followed. By
1973, there were 168 US electronics plants along the border—more than in either
Hong Kong or Taiwan. This was only the beginning. When RCA moved some of
its operations to Mexico in 1968, it secured a cheap labor force paid US$20 for a
48-hour workweek (42 cents per hour).
In 1970, Ciudad Juárez had an estimated 30,000 to 60,000 unemployed labor-
ers—meaning that the maquilas had their choice of pliant workers under conditions
of constant wages, but this combined with a productivity rate higher than US plants
in some instances (Cowie 1999: 117–8; Crossa 2022a: 7). Although generally over-
looked, and hard to document, such high productivity clashed directly with con-
ventional neoclassical economic perceptions: Mexico’s meager wages were no more
than a reflection of low labor productivity went their constant, comforting refrain.
But, beyond the disorienting ether of high economic theory, executives at
Whirlpool Corporation (until 1965 known as RCA Whirlpool) made a startling
announcement in 2005: At the company’s plant in Germany, production workers
were paid US$32 per hour vs. $23 in the US and $3 in Mexico (including bene-
fits). Their engineers determined that if Whirlpool’s Monterrey plant installed the
same advanced production technologies used in the German plant, there was no
question that Mexican workers would match the productivity of German workers
(Uchitelle 2005: 4): Thus, one Mexican worker, paid 9 percent of one German worker’s
wage, could produce the same amount of output per hour as his/her German counterpart;
Mexican workers, then, were, effectively, far more productive than US workers.
Comparatively low wages had nothing to do with low productivity and everything
to do with transnational corporate economic power. This has been the pull factor
bringing capital, especially from the US, to Mexico.

Capital Mobility and US Deindustrialization


The push factor was very strong, as well: US unions, particularly in electronics
manufacturing, from 1964 through 1978 were increasingly willing to strike, with
1964–9 being the years of strongest activity. However, by the late 1970s, the new
options available in Mexico, or Asia, served to undermine labor power, and strikes
collapsed (dropping from 200 per year in 1978 to almost zero from 1982 on) as cap-
ital moved, or threatened to move. As television production soared at the border—
largely at the world’s largest, most technologically advanced plant RCA built in
Ciudad Juárez—US workers in the industry declined from nearly 90,000 in 1968,
to slightly over 20,000 by 1986 (Cowie 1999: 130). All this was part of a process of
The Remaking of Mexico 15

“silent integration”—long before the US Senate set the stage for NAFTA’s approval
in 1991, the entire US electronics industry was folding and moving, mostly to
Mexico.
The RCA-Juárez dynamic was only a small part of a larger process wherein
the US rapidly entered a stage of deindustrialization in the 1970s and early 1980s.
While neoclassical economists were generally blasé in the face of these changes,
a very few sounded the alarm to no avail: Most outspoken were Stephen Cohen
and John Zysman who encapsulated their argument in the title of their crucial
book Manufacturing Matters (1987). Correctly, they argued that if the US offshored
its manufacturing, this would generate adverse linkage effects: Without a solid core
of manufacturing firms, the US would lose its edge in technological development
since manufacturing demanded the production of capital goods (machines to make
machines), and a strong capital goods industrial base was the underlying source of
technical change. Switching to a service sector–oriented economy would actually
slow productivity growth across the economy because technological innovations
developed in the manufacturing sector spilled over to the service sector—they were
compliments, not substitutes, in the maintenance of a dynamic economy. As Cohen
and Zysman emphasized (1987: 8–9),

First…production is where the lion’s share of value-added is realized. It is


where the “rent on innovation” is captured. Second…unless R&D is tightly
tied to manufacturing of the product…R&D will fall behind the cutting edge
of incremental innovation. For example, by abandoning the production of
televisions, the US electronics industry quickly lost its know-how to design,
develop, refine and competitively produce the next generation of that prod-
uct, the VCR. As a result we make no VCRs in [the US] and we are likely to
lose whatever position we still maintain in [R&D] products that derive from
mastery of that product and production technology. High-tech gravitates to-
ward state-of-the-art producers.

Without a strong manufacturing base, import dependence would grow. Powerful


nations that maintained their manufacturing base—then Japan and Germany—
would keep a technological advantage because they would find ways to limit trans-
ferring their cutting-edge breakthroughs, at least for a crucial period of time. But
until plans were formulated to build NAFTA, US “free traders” were contemptuous
of the arguments put forward by Cohen and Zysman and others: They envisioned
a textbook world where classroom models of free trade and specialization would
define a new world order based on “efficient” market-driven international trade
(astonishingly, by definition their models excluded transnational investments—capital
could not move). Meanwhile, international rivalry, not neoclassical economic har-
mony, based in national power increasingly exercised through IP (Industrial Policy)
became the watchword: The US power elite slowly, and incompletely, began to rec-
ognize this, and the US commenced building its own defensive/offensive regional
bloc, i.e., NAFTA (Cypher 1992).
16 The Remaking of Mexico

The lament and warning presented by Cohen and Zysman with regard to the
electronics industry were but one part of a much larger problem sweeping across a
broad range of industries, most particularly the industrial paradigm-setting US auto
industry: In 1970, the Big Three automakers (General Motors (GM), Ford, and
Chrysler—now Stellantis) were ranked in the Fortune 500 corporate listings as nos.
1, 3, 6. By 1980, a dramatic change had occurred, as reflected in the new rankings,
2, 4, 17. But, unlike their abandonment of the consumer electronics industry, US
policymakers were determined to save the dominant manufacturing industry by
imposing restraints on Japan’s market penetration: Its share of the US auto market
jumped from 18 percent to 27 percent from 1978 to 1980, as US auto output fell
from 9.3 million to 6.6 million (Destler 1991: 259). Threatening quotas, the US
imposed a “voluntary export restraint” agreement in 1981, which lasted through
the 1980s, holding the number of Japanese auto imports to 7.7 percent below the
1980 level.
With their exports to the US effectively contained by this quota, the Japanese
built auto plants in the US: Honda began in 1982, Nissan in 1983, and Toyota
in 1984. By 1989, they had nine fully operating plants, several in the nonun-
ion South, as part of a new “transplant corridor”, all well away from heavily
unionized centers (Dicken 2003: 392). Candace Howes’ extensive research on
these new plants revealed that they were actually no more than branch assembly
operations, with approximately 50 percent of all parts used sourced from captive
suppliers in Japan. Remaining parts were produced either directly in-plant or,
mostly, from nonunion US-based Japanese-owned suppliers, paying US workers
44 percent of the rate paid by parts companies that supplied the “Big Three”
(Howes 1993: 36, 44).
It could not have been a mere coincidence that at the precise moment Japan was
stealing a march on the US’s flagship industry, Mexico’s auto sector policies rotated
180 degrees. Part of this transformation involved turning Mexico into a low-
wage export platform guaranteeing the competitiveness of US auto firms as they
responded to the heightened tensions generated by the massive entry of Japanese
production into the US automotive market (Crossa 2022b: 534).
When the crisis of 1981/2 hit Mexico, policy positions in some areas shifted
rapidly and dramatically. The Mexican state imposed wage ceilings based on low
expected inflation and not past inflation, which in the 1980s shattered real wages
(inflation reached 159 percent in 1987). With wages falling, aggregate demand
was undercut, meaning that further private-sector investment was unwarranted.
The reduction in the public sector also resulted in a strong decline in government
capital formation. The results as measured from 1982 through 1988 were star-
tling, and contrary to what the IMF/WB anticipated, the economy grew annually
at the imperceptible rate of 0.07 percent while gross capital formation fell at the
annual rate of 5.2 percent—a cumulative drop of 43 percent (de María y Campos
1992: 21).
As always, the IMF demanded that an economy undergoing one of its “stabiliza-
tion” programs (SAPs) should increase its exports—which rose from 11 percent of
The Remaking of Mexico 17

GDP to 18 over the 1982–8 period (de María y Campos 1992: 22). Manufacturing
exports rose from 14 to 56 percent of total exports, led by metal products, machin-
ery, and equipment, most produced by a small number of TNCs (de María y
Campos 1992: 44). This shift to a cheap labor export platform was also mandated
by the WB—the structure had to be changed via a rapid, permanent rise in industrial
sector exports: Yet, by international standards, exports (at 13 percent of GDP in
1986) remained low. The impetus of rapidly rising internal demand that had dom-
inated (1940–80) was now displaced onto external demand growth—the economic
structure was turned upside down. But this shift—at the same time that real mini-
mum urban wages fell by 45 percent and real per capita income by 11 percent—was
insufficient to create overall conditions of economic growth: The shrinking of the
domestic economy and the surge in the size of the informal sector (of street ven-
dors, servants, car washers, lottery ticket sellers, etc.) inducing a rise in the level of
income inequality, had a negative impact, overwhelming any boost from the rise in
exports (de María y Campos 1992: 22).
A major role was accorded to the auto sector in the drive to expand exports.
The 1983 “Decree to Rationalize the Automobile Industry” forced transnational
auto firms to reduce the number of models produced to a maximum of five in
order to achieve economies of scale. While it promoted exports, the Decree was
also designed to eliminate the importation of most parts and components: Auto
firms had to have sufficient foreign currency earnings to pay for all parts, com-
ponents, royalty payments, technology transfers, and interest payments on foreign
loans. As is typical of a sectorial IP, domestic content requirements remained but
were reduced on exported autos (Moreno-Brid 1988: 15–7). These new policies
basically demonstrated a revision and continuation of industrial promotion strategies,
but not for long.
Mexico’s entry into the GATT in 1986 was one of the clearest indicators that a
new era had arrived. Joining this organization, long resisted by advocates of state-
led development policies, meant a dramatic drop in tariffs, barriers, quotas, import
licenses, and so on that had been designed to promote industrialization through the
consolidation of national firms (private and public) in an earlier era. As recorded in
the IMF’s official history, as Mexico was inching once again toward default on its
international loans, it desperately needed to conform to the IMF’s preference that
it join GATT. The IMF began to “press the initiative” in late 1983, along with the
WB, and thereafter “continued to make the case” until Mexico applied for mem-
bership in 1985 (Boughton 2001: 361). Quickly, tariffs fell to a low average of 11
percent by 1989; only 20 percent of imports were subject to licenses. Mexico’s rapid
opening to imports created unprecedented problems in manufacturing because,
beyond a few giant firms, producers had little access to credit and were slow to
adjust: “The massive supply of imported products resulted in the disarticulation
of some production chains and provoked the closing of thousands of principally
medium and small manufacturing firms” (Máttar and Peres 1997: 222). In addition,
the state was slow and inept in addressing unfair trade practices (including those of
the US) that sometimes explained rising imports.
18 The Remaking of Mexico

Resisting the Juggernaut


Renowned development economist Alice Amsden stressed that neither GATT nor
its 1995 successor, the World Trade Organization (WTO), constituted a deter-
ministic straitjackets for nations of the Global South (Amsden and Hikino 2000).
Unfortunately, for Mexico, this perspective was hardly ever acknowledged and rarely
applied. Instead, the Mexican state and the Mexican business elite were essentially
passive and accommodating with regard to GATT—a stance that reflected the ide-
ological victory of the rapidly embraced neoliberal perspective. Nevertheless, as the
fundamental changes shifting Mexico toward an export platform economic structure
proceeded apace, the premier institution of policy analysis and development projects
formation, Nafinsa—the national development bank—dissented. It published a brief
statement noting that in many respects joining GATT did not mean that Mexico was
devoid of a phalanx of measures that could be used to continue—perhaps with revi-
sions and new applications—projects of national industrial promotion. Mexico was
not under any clear mandate to indiscriminately open its industrial sectors to pow-
erful transnational corporations—particularly since they pursued predatory practices
to dominate or completely capture sectors and branches of industry (Pérez Aceves
and Valenzuela 1988: 67–70). These authors stressed that powerful nations, especially
the US, did not passively follow GATT-created policies. The Nafinsa economists
emphasized that “GATT rather than being an organization wherein a nation would
strictly adjust its basic governing rules, is actually a forum were rules and regulations
regarding international trade are discussed and then established,…and such regulations
are not always in fundamental agreement with…the liberalization of international
trade” (Pérez Aceves and Valenzuela 1988: 68, italics added).
The idea that Mexico had to passively conform to external “rules” was unwar-
ranted: But, Mexico largely did conform. The idea that GATT was some sort of
rigorous taskmaster was viewed as a misperception by Nafinsa and also, surprisingly,
by the economists who orchestrated the shift from the “old” industrial policy to
the “new” industrial policy (Sánchez, Fernando, and Motta 1994: 52). The unre-
stricted, rapid opening to overwhelming international economic forces was based
in the neoclassic premise that foreign competition would force private national
industry (now greatly expanded due to massive privatizations) to rationalize pro-
duction by investing in new imported technologies and improve managerial prac-
tices (which usually reflected the lackluster of family-owned firms). At the same
time, these “free trader” theorists argued, newly arrived foreign firms would also
impose market disciplining price and quality competition resulting in a general
revitalization of the industrial base: All such changes would be gradual and only
a “slight bit traumatic” according to Sánchez Ugarte, Fernández, and Pérez. Still,
these authors, importantly, argued that there was one “sui generis” exception—the
auto industry: It would continue for some time to benefit from state-led industrial
promotion policies (Sánchez, Fernando, and Motta 1994: 52–3; 55): And, by the
mid-1990s “Mexico [had]…become the largest developing-country exporter in
[the auto] sector in the world” (Moran 1999: 56).
The Remaking of Mexico 19

Capital’s Voice and Access: Structural and Instrumental Power


Top policymakers did recognize that Mexico had to maintain some policy space and,
at least in the auto sector, they understood the need for some continuity with the
Ancien Régime. Nonetheless, for the state, the powerful peak business associations
(discussed later in this chapter), and the TNCs (particularly after 1988), the impo-
sition of the new export regime consummated a structural power shift favoring
large TNCs and national corporate capital. At the same time this change subor-
dinated or eliminated the prior institutional structure that had upheld workers’
interests (Collier 1992; de la Garza 2006: 28–94). For a small number of very large
Monterrey-based firms, the new opening to foreign capital and exports facilitated a
reciprocal structural shift wherein—given the shrinkage and stagnation of the inter-
nal market—their capital moved abroad through cross-border mergers or stand-
alone FDI. They also realigned their nationally based production system toward
export markets. This entailed a new accommodation with the emerging forces of
transnationalized production. The large-firm Mexican business elite would now
deploy via a nonmutually exclusive array of options, including (1) the formation
of joint ventures with TNCs, (2) the brokering and/or supplier facilitation of
TNC activities in Mexico, (3) the empowerment of the Monterrey Group as they
adopted export-oriented policies. Small- and medium-sized firms faced annihi-
lation or marginalization. Significantly, a new agile, strata emerged consisting of
lawyers, accountants, service providers (sometimes providing “turnkey” manufac-
turing plants, or testing, cleaning, and packaging services in industrial parks), and
well-connected provincial operatives who coupled government and private-sector
interests: They functioned within the profitable niches in the new structure as rentier
facilitators of the export-led regime.
The new opening to cross-border investment and trade, by achieving economies
of scale, and by promoting foreign-owned production in low-wage manufacturing
(particularly in the maquila sector) appeared successful: Manufactured exports (as
a share of all US imports) doubled from 1985 to 1993 (Sánchez, Fernando, and
Motta 1994: 145). But this metric ignored a number of important facts, including
the collapse of the oil sector, stagnation in agriculture, the continued drop in wages
(discussed later in this chapter) the diminution of mining, and the toxic, domestic
market constricting impacts of the ongoing bouts of austerity measures urged by the
IMF and WB as willingly adopted by the neoliberal state apparatus.

Ruination of the National Industrial Base


Returning to Nafinsa’s dissenting position with regard to an unrestricted opening
of the economy, this powerful institution continued to advocate for a buildup of
the capital goods industry. Failure to do so would mean conceding defeat in the
quest for technological capacity because of the potential spin-offs, learning effects,
acquired innovation capacities, and positive externality effects they associated with
nations (such as Japan, Germany, and the US) that had promoted and consolidated
20 The Remaking of Mexico

a machine-building industry. Without it a considerable portion of whatever Mexico


exported would effectively be canceled out by machine imports (see note 2) and
more importantly the technological autonomy and productivity-enhancing attrib-
utes embedded in capital goods/machine building would be forfeited (Pérez Aceves
and Valenzuela 1988: 68–75). Further, Nafinsa’s economists urged continued fol-
low-through on programs to promote the textile industry and the electronics indus-
try (see Focus 1.2 on computer electronics).

FOCUS 1.2: ABANDONMENT OF MEXICO’S SECTORIAL


INDUSTRIAL POLICIES

What are termed “horizontal” industrial policies (IPs) were employed to estab-
lish the transnational production structure (wherein without preference to a
particular sector or activity, all firms can, potentially, be beneficiaries, as was
the case with the maquila and PITEX programs): For example, Mexico in the
late 1980s and onward became committed, at least officially, to promoting a
higher level of national R&D spending, wherein (in theory) all producers might
benefit from an economy that promoted innovation. What stands out, how-
ever, is that, in general, Mexico ceased to support many sectors—called vertical
IPs—including capital goods, computers, and pharmaceuticals.2 Such policies
were proscribed “interventions” according to neoliberal ideology (Sánchez,
Fernando, Motta, 1994: 35).
Now forgotten, Mexico prioritized the creation of a national computer
industry in the 1970s. The goal was to provide a framework for industrial pro-
motion by containing foreign firms in the sector, including restricting them to
minority ownership in joint ventures and requiring them to invest a minimum
of 3 percent of sales in R&D and fund training programs and research centers.
Mexican firms in the sector received tax credits and below-market loans from
state-owned development banks (such as Nafinsa). Domestic producers were
given preferential access to government procurement. Domestic content in
PCs was set at 45 percent of value-added. By the mid-1980s, the IP to promote
the computer industry was considered a success—through the establishment
of wholly owned Mexican firms, or through joint ventures. In 1987, national
supply met 56 percent of domestic demand, while roughly 50 percent of total
production was exported—meaning that this promoted sector was interna-
tionally competitive and provided scarce foreign exchange (Gallagher and
Zarsky 2007: 122–4).
But, in 1985, the US-based IBM corporation successfully fought the gov-
ernment and set up a 100 percent foreign-owned operation—by 1987, others
had followed suit. By 1990, as Mexico consolidated its neoliberal stance, the
The Remaking of Mexico 21

government moved to abandon all sectorial IPs because TNCs were anxious
to integrate their Mexican holdings into their new global supply chain pro-
duction strategies. This relegated Mexico, usually, to low value-added, labor-­
intensive parts manufacturing. (In the run-up to signing NAFTA in late 1993,
Mexico eliminated all remaining remnants of the IP for computers, and after
2001, when China entered the World Trade Organization, most foreign com-
puter firms reorganized, shifting their Mexico-based operations to China.) The
demise of Mexico’s fledgling capital goods (see note 2) and pharmaceutical
industries generally followed the same state-transnational-induced path into
oblivion.

Meanwhile, in the 1980s, high-level economic policymakers—working within


the still-reigning developmentalist paradigm of state-led industrialization—­
supported the promotion of a national pharmaceutical industry, as well as a deep-
ening of the petrochemical industry (Wionczek 1981: 975–80). The drive to make
Mexico a powerful producer of petrochemicals—an industry with an extremely
broad range of inter-industry linkage effects—came to a close at a point in time that
coincided with the IMF Stand-By loan in November 1986.
Such loans are months in preparation and come with specific conditions:
Given the IMF’s perception that public sector activities should either be reduced
to their lowest possible level or eliminated if possible, the fact that in October
1986 de la Madrid’s administration commenced a broad-based reclassification of
the petrochemical industry should clearly be understood not as happenstance but
rather part of IMF loan “conditionality” (Ángeles 1996: 41). Thirty-six “basic”
petrochemicals (those that could only be developed by the state-owned petro-
leum company, Pemex), became overnight “secondary” petrochemicals eligible
for private ownership: These state assets were then sold (essentially gifted) to
eager TNCs and well-connected Mexican firms. Such steps were complimented
by a new round of petrochemical privatizations as part of a 1989 IMF/WB loan
(under “cross-conditionality”), with the Fund’s share being $3.73 billion: This
was the third and final IMF loan of the 1980s, bringing the total to $8.54 billion,
constituting an exceptionally large 38 percent share of all IMF outstanding loans
in 1989. In this instance, President Salinas, in 1989, reclassified and privatized an
additional 16 petrochemicals, leaving state control over only 20 (Ángeles 1996:
42). In short, whether it was petrochemicals, pharmaceuticals—or any other
national industrial sector that had once been targeted as programas de rama (impor-
tant industrial branches selected to receive state promotion)—by 1989, if not
before, the new paradigm of export-orientation was restricted to being solely a
private-sector initiative, frequently subsidized through public-sector export pro-
motion programs, as mentioned earlier.
22 The Remaking of Mexico

The Pacto de Solidaridad (1987): The Linchpin of Structural


Change
For a very long time, Mexican industrial workers’ wages had grown in step with
the general economy, with annual industrial workers’ inflation-adjusted (real) wages
rising by almost 5 percent per year from 1959 to 1969 and then by 5.9 percent from
1971 to 1976—with the lowest-wage worker also included, as the minimum wage
rose 59 percent from 1970–6 (Cypher 1990: 62, 90). Anxious to ease deep tensions
between the state and capital that had emerged in the previous presidential term,
President López Portillo permitted rising inflation as the government largely ceased
to dissuade large private-sector firms from pushing up prices—minimum wages fell
in real terms by about 10 percent, while median wages fell 20 percent (1976–82)
during his term (Cypher 1990: 115; Moreno-Brid et al. 2019: 53).
Then, from 1982 to 1987, real wages drastically fell: The median wage dropped
by 55 percent (1980 = 100), while the minimum wage fell by 45 percent (Moreno-
Brid et al. 2019: 53). The then-powerful leader of the national labor confederation
(Confederation of Mexican Workers (CTM)) began to circulate a call for a general
strike. This was an unheard-of initiative since (until the 1980s) the labor confed-
erations considered themselves to be “partners” in a social pact designed to raise
living standards, at least in pace with the growth of the national economy (Cypher
1990: 195–6). Dissent and debate (which began in the early 1970s over demands for
union democratization during the so-called union insurgency) gave rise to a funda-
mental restructuring of the relationship between state, capital, and labor, emerging
as the “Solidarity Pact” (PSE) in November 1987. To be renewed annually through
early 1990, this “Pacto” called for three new conditions:

• First, government was to maintain prices on all state-controlled products


(including a large number of “basic” goods such as grains, meats, and dairy
products);
• Second, labor was to accept only periodic “adjustments” in wage levels, includ-
ing the minimum wage; and
• Third, private-sector firms were free to raise prices as they deemed fit, always
charging “all the traffic will bear”.

The effects of the Pacto were threefold:

• The inflation rate dramatically declined in 1988 and for several years thereafter;
• Wages were held to a 23 percent increase in the first year of the Pacto (while
prices rose by 52 percent, meaning that real wages fell by 31 percent); and
• The exchange rate was stabilized, putting an end to the massive devaluations of
previous years, and “import inflation”.

The overall macroeconomic effect reduced the wage share in national income
which, with a rising population already pushed to the margin of subsistence, was
The Remaking of Mexico 23

a brutal blow. The counterpart was to raise capital’s already extraordinary share of
national income. Generating these effects, the Pacto clearly played a critical role in
the defeat of the PRI’s presidential candidate in the summer of 1988, but then the
count was “adjusted” with the PRI’s candidate, neoliberal advocate Carlos Salinas,
given, via a well-documented process of electoral fraud, a free hand to rule, thereby
burying the possibility for a democratic option.
With Salinas in power, 1989 was a threshold year for labor as the social pact (con-
solidated under President Cárdenas in the 1930s) was definitively destroyed. First
under attack was the most powerful union—the oil workers’: Salinas imprisoned
the leader and commenced new programs of piecemeal privatization of Pemex.
Similarly, a threatened strike by 4,000 mining workers at the government-owned
copper mine Cananea brought about its privatization and the dismissal of all work-
ers. The state-labor collaboration had ended.
With the objective of increasing the profit margin for the private sector, the
Pacto became institutionalized in late 1989 (Ortega Riquelme 2006: 243–4). The
commission for the follow-through and evaluation of the Pact (CSEP) was cre-
ated with strong corporate representation from the peak business association CCE
(the Business Coordinating Council representing the largest firms).4 The manu-
facturers association (Canacintra), the Monterrey Groups’ employer confederation
(Coparmex), and the largest unions were then synchronized by the secretary of
labor within the 1989 follow-on framework of the PECE (Economic Growth and
Stability Pact), which remained in effect into 1994. The goal was to “obstruct the
future opposition of the participants”, meaning in practice the labor participants.
The objective of removing the power to set wage rates and labor conditions (which
had substantially rested with the unions) was achieved: Now such matters were left
to the powerful, captured Labor Secretariat (STPS), which generally pursued the
preferences of the CCE and Coparmex.
The results deepened the devastation for the working class: Because the Salinas
administration sought social support for NAFTA, a fictitiously financed expansion
occurred with real median wages rising slightly until 1994 (when another deep
crisis occurred). But such wages reached, at their highest moment, only approxi-
mately 75 percent of their 1980 level, while the real minimum wage fell to 40 of
1980 purchasing power (Moreno-Brid et al. 2019: 53). Thus, the real minimum
wage, then directly affecting an estimated 28 percent of the formal labor force fell
an additional 27 percent during President Salinas’ term.
The 1987 Pacto was, according to Valdés Ugalde (1996: 141), “the embryo of a
new relationship between economic and political elites—clearly a sin qua non for
a successful neoliberal reform of the state”. In the run-up to the final passage of
NAFTA in late 1993, the wage share of national income rose slightly as the state
endeavored to build the illusion of a successful remaking of Mexico’s economy
under the export-led program. For a brief moment, for some in Mexico, it appeared
that Salinas’ ambition to transform Mexico to become part of the “First World not
the Third World” was near realization. But, by early 1994, the data revealed that
Mexico’s economy was an unsustainable illusion, although most Mexicans looked
References
Aboites, Jaime and Claudia Milena Díaz Ríos . 2013. Innovación: instituciones, redes y
aprendizaje. México: UAM, Unidad Xochimilco.
Agarwala, N. and Chaudhary, R. D. 2019. “China’s Policy on Science and Technology:
Implications for the Next Industrial Transition”. India Quarterly 75 (2): 206–227.
Aguilar, Alonso . 2005. “Nacionalización y capitalismo monopolista de Estado” pp. 147–161 en
Morales, Josefina (ed.) Antología de Alonso Aguilar Monteverde, Vol. 2. México: IIEC-UNAM.
Aguirre Botello, Manuel . 2020. “Exportaciones de Petróleo Crudo 1974–2020” Sector
Energético Mexicano, Indicadores Anuales (31 de diciembre):
http://www.mexicomaxico.org/Voto/PetroCrudo.htm
Aguirre Botello, Manuel . 2022. “Evolución del Salario Mínimo en México de 1935 a 2021”
http://www.mexicomaxico.org/Voto/SalMinInf.htm
Ahmed, Salman and Rozyln Engel (eds.). 2020. Making US Policy Work Better for the Middle
Class. Washington, DC: Carnegie Endowment.
Aiginger, Karl and Dani Rodrik . 2020. “Rebirth of industrial policy and an agenda for the twenty-
first century” Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 20 (2): 189–207.
Alarcón Tosoni, G. 2005. “Reforma estructural en la integración de la industria maquiladora a la
economía mexicana” Problemas del Desarrollo 37(Núm. 141): 54–80.
Alba Vega, Carlos . 1996. “Los Empresarios y el Estado Durante el Salinismo” Foro
Internacional 36 (1–2): 31–79.
Alba Vega, Carlos . 1997. “La COECE: un caso de cooperación entre los sectores público y
privado en México” Comercio Exterior 47 (2): 149–158.
Alba Vega, Carlos . 2006. “Los Empresarios y la Democracia en México” Foro Internacional 46
(1): 122–149.
Alba Vega, Carlos . 2020. “Los empresarios mexicanos durante el gobierno de Peña Nieto”
Foro Internacional 60 (2): 538–627.
Alba Vega, Carlos . 2021. “Las relaciones de los empresarios organizados con el presidente de
México durante la pandemia” Desacatos 65: 156–177.
Alcaraz, Eduardo y Gabriela Alcaraz . 2001. “TLCAN, sector agropecuario mexicano y comercio
desleal” Revista Comercio Exterior 51 (6): 506–513.
Alegría, Alejandro . 2022a. “Inseguridad frena nuevas inversiones en maquila: Index” La
Jornada (24 de agosto): https://www.jornada.com.mx/notas/2022/08/24/economia/inseguridad-
frena-nuevas-inversiones
Alegría, Alejandro . 2022b. “Plan de política industrial es positivo y llega a tiempo, califica la IP”
La Jornada (22 de septiembre): p. 21.
Alemeida, Mansueto , Renato Lima-Olivera and Ben Ross Schneider . 2012. “Industrial Policy
and State-Owned Enterprises in Brazil: BNDES and Petrobras”. Brasilia, BR. IPEA.
Álvarez Acevedo, Carlos . 2022. “AMLO se lanza contra el WP” Zeta Tijuana (3 de agosto):
https://zetatijuana.com/2022/08/amlo-se-lanza-contra-el-wp-que-lo-llamo-peculiar-populista
Álvarez Medina, María de Lourdes . 2021. “Impact of the United States-Mexico-Canada free-
trade agreement on the automotive sector in Mexico” Revista Norteamérica 16 (2): 403–430.
Álvarez Medina, María de Lourdes , Jorge Carrillo and María Luisa González . 2014. pp.
109–132 en Lourdes Álvarez Medina , Jorge Carrillo and María Luisa González (coordinadores)
El auge de la industria automotriz en México en el siglo XXI. México D.F.: UNAM•FCA
Publishing.
Alves, Bruno . 2022. “Pemex’s exports of oil products from 2015 to 2021” Statista (June 20):
https://www.statista.com/statistics/1042702/pemex-oil-products-exports/
Amador, Octavio . 2022. “México rompe récord en importaciones de gas natural de EU” El
Economista (2 de marzo): https://www.eleconomista.com.mx/empresas/Mexico-rompe-record-
en-importaciones-de-gas-natural-de-EU-20220303-0019.html
Amsden, Alice . 1985. “The division of labour is limited by the rate of growth of the market: The
Taiwan machine tool industry in the 1970s” Cambridge Journal of Economics 9 (3): 271–284.
Amsden, Alice . 1989. Asia’s next Giant. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Amsden, Alice . 2001. The Rise of the Rest. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Amsden, Alice and Takashi Hikino . 2000. “The bark is worse than the bite: New WTO law and
late industrialization” The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 570:
104–114.
Andreoni, Antonio and Ha-Joon Chang . 2017. “Bringing production and employment back into
development” Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 10 (1): 173–187.
Ángeles, Sarahí . 1990. “Privatizaci6n monop6lica y desnacionalizaci6n de PEMEX” Problemas
del Desarrollo 21 (81): 135–155.
Ángeles, Sarahí . 1992. “Aspectos de la recomposición de capital” pp. 131–178 en Josefina
Morales (coordinadora) La Reestructuración Industrial en México. México, D.F.: Nuestro
Tiempo.
Ángeles, Sarahí . 1996. “Acerca de la importancia de la petroquímica y la privatizaci6n
desnacionalizadora” Problemas del Desarrollo 27 (1): 31–45.
Anner, Mark . 2015. Social downgrading and worker resistance in apparel global value chains”
pp. 152–170 in K. Newsome , P. Taylor , J. Bair and A. Rainnie (eds.) Putting Labour in its
Place. New York: Palgrave.
Arès, Mathieu . 2007. “El Estado Empresario” Foro Internacional 47 (2): 201–244.
Arregui Velasco, Edur . 2016. “Trazando el silencio: cómo sobrevivir sin representación”
Argumentos 29 (80): 103–121.
Arteaga, Arnulfo . (2003). Integración productiva y relaciones laborales en la industria
automotriz en México. México: UAM-Iztapalapa y Plaza y Valdez.
Arteaga, Arnulfo , Alberto Álvarez de la Rosa y Mateo Crossa . 2020. “El patrón de
reproducción de capital exportador de especialización productiva y la industria automotriz en
México” pp. 128–160 in en Geraldo Pinto , Sebastian Guevara and Arnulfo Arteaga García
(coordinadores). La industria automotriz en América Latina. México: UAM-Iztapalapa.
AS/COA (Americas Society/Council on the Americas) . 2022. “Rogelio Ramírez de la O,
Secretario de Hacienda” (29 de abril). Nearshoring: Impulsando oportunidades de inversión en
México: https://www.as-coa.org/watchlisten/mxcoa-2022-rogelio-ramirez-de-la-o-secretario-de-
hacienda
Aspe, Pedro . 1993. Economic Transformation the Mexican Way. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Aspe, Pedro . 1994. “La reforma financiera de México.” Comercio Exterior 44 (12): 1044–1048.
Atkinson, Anthony , Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez . 2011. “Top incomes in the long run
of history” Journal of Economic Literature 49 (1): 3–71.
Autor, David . 2022. “The labor market impacts of technological change” National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper 30074 (May): 1–38.
Azamar, Aleida . 2022. “El Litio en México: verdades y mentiras” pp. 27–46 en Isidro Téllez
Ramírez y Aleida Azamar (eds.) La minería en México. México, D.F.: Secretaria de Medio
Ambiente.
Bair, Jennifer and Marion Werner . 2011. “Commodity chains and the uneven geographies of
global capitalism: A disarticulations perspective” Environment and Planning 43 (5): 988–997.
Baker, Dean . 2007, “The productivity to paycheck gap”, Washington, DC: Center for Economic
and Policy Research.
Baker, Dean . 2013. “Nafta lowered wages, as it was supposed to do” New York Times
(December 5): https://www.nytimes.com/roomfordebate/2013/11/24/what-weve-learned-from-
nafta/nafta-lowered-wages-as-it-was-supposed-to-do
Banco Mundial . 2022. “Rentas mineras (% del PIB) – Mexico”:
https://datos.bancomundial.org/indicador/ny.gdp.minr.rt.zs?locations=MX
Baragán, Daniela . 2020. “Las empresas de outsourcing con EPN no sólo ayudaban a no
pagar” Sinembargo (7 de diciembre): https://www.sinembargo.mx/07-12-2020/3904384
Baran, Paul . 1962 [1957]. The Political Economy of Growth. New York, NY: Monthly Review
Press.
Barnes de Castro, Francisco . 2022. “Aportaciones para un nuevo Plan Estratégico de Gas
Natural – Parte segunda” Energía a Debate (18 de mayo):
https://energiaadebate.com/aportaciones-para-un-nuevo-plan-estrategico-de-gas-natural-parte-
segunda
Barrientos, Stephanie . 2019. Gender and Work in Global Value Chains: Capturing the Gains?
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Basave Kunhardt, Jorge . 2006. “Desempeño empresarial exportador e impacto económico” pp.
111–146 en María de los Ángeles Pozas (coordinadora) Estructura y dinámica de la gran
empresa en México. México, D.F.: El Colegio de México.
Bauer, P.T. 1984. “Remembrance of studies past” pp. 27–43 in Gerald Meier and Dudley Sears
(eds.) Pioneers of Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bebbington, Anthony , Denise Leonith Hinojosa , H. Bebbington , María Luisa Burneo and
Ximena Warnaars . 2008. “Contention and ambiguity: Mining and the possibilities of
development” Development and Change 39 (6): 887–914.
Becerril, Andrea . 2009. “El golpe de Calderón al SME, para acabar de entregar la industria
eléctrica: Bartlett” La Jornada (18 de octubre): p. 5.
Becerril, Isabel . 2013. “Sector de bienes de capital, al borde de la desaparición” El Financiero
(9 julio): https://www.elfinanciero.com.mx/economia/sector-de-bienes-de-capital-al-borde-de-la-
desaparicion/
Beltrán del Río, Pascal . 2020. “Petróleo, la maldición” El Tintero Noticias (22 de abril):
https://eltinteronoticias.com/nota/27018-pascal
Bennett, Douglas y Kenneth E. Sharpe . 1979. “La industria automotriz mexicana y la política
económica de la promoción de exportaciones, algunos problemas del control estatal de las
empresas trasnacionales” Trimestre Económico XLVI (3): 715–746.
Bensusán, Gabriela . 2021. “Determinantes institucionales y organizacionales del salario en la
industria automotriz de México” pp. 37–71 en H. García-Jiménez , J. Carrillo and G. Bensusán
(coordinadores) Salarios en tiempos de libre comercio: ¿ofrece la industria automotriz salarios
dignos en México? Tijuana, México: COLEF.
Bensusán, Gabriela and Alex Covarrubias . 2016. “Relaciones laborales y salariales en la IAM:
¿Vendrá el cambio de fuera?” pp. 198–219 en A. Covarrubias , G. Bensusán , S. Sandoval and
A. Arteaga (coordinadores). La industria automotriz en México: Relaciones de empleo, culturas
organizacionales y factores psicosociales. México D.F: AM Editores.
Bensusán, Graciela and Kevin J. Middlebrook . 2020. “Cambio político desde afuera hacia
adentro. Influencia comercial estadunidense y reforma de los derechos laborales en México”
Foro Internacional 60 (3): 985–1039.
Bivens, Josh . 2019. “Updated employment multipliers for the U.S. economy” Economic Policy
Institute Report (January 23): https://www.epi.org/160282
Bizberg, Ilán . 2020. “El fracaso de la continuidad: La economía política del sexenio de Enrique
Peña Nieto” Foro Internacional 60 (2): 629–682.
Blecker, Robert . 2014. “The Mexican and U.S. economies after twenty years of NAFTA”
International Journal of Political Economy 43 (2): 5–26.
Blair, John . 1978. [1977] The Control of Oil. New York, NY: Vintage Books.
BLS (US Bureau of Labor Statistics) . 2022. “All employees, thousands, motor vehicle parts:
1994–2022”: https://data.bls.gov/pdq/SurveyOutputServlet
Bluestone, Barry and Bennett Harrison . 1982. The Deindustrialization of America. New York,
NY: Basic Books.
BNamericas . 2022a. “Miners cautious as Mexico seeks lithium investment” BNamericas
(September 7): https://www.bnamericas.com/en/features/miners-cautious-as-mexico-seeks-
lithium-investment
BNamericas . 2022b. “Spotlight: Mexico’s US$48bn clean energy plan for Sonora” BNamericas
(December 20): https://www.bnamericas.com/en/analysis/spotlight-mexicos-us48bn-clean-
energy-plan-for-sonora
Boltvinik, Julio . 2022a. “México: país de pobres” La Jornada (4 Febrero): p. 20.
Boltvinik, Julio . 2022b. “Estratificación Social Básica por EF” La Jornada (11 Febrero): p. 22.
Boughton, James . 2001. Silent Revolution: The International Monetary Fund, 1979–1989.
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Brandenburg, Frank . 1964. The Making of Modern Mexico. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall,
Inc.
Briceño-Ruiz, José and Andrés Rivarola . 2017. Brazil and Latin America. Lanham, MD:
Lexington Books.
Brill, Michael , Corey Holman , Chris Morris , Ronjoy Raichoudhary and Noah Yosif . 2017.
“Understanding the labor productivity and compensation gap” Beyond the Numbers: Productivity
6 (6) (June) https://www.bls.gov/opub/btn/volume-6/understanding-the-labor-productivity-and-
compensation-gap.htm
Brinke, Koen . 2013. “The Mexican 1982 debt crisis” RaboResearch – Economic Research
(September 19). https://economics.rabobank.com/publications/2013/september/the-mexican-
1982-debt-crisis/
Bronfenbrenner, Kate . 1997. “We’ll close! Plant closings, plant-closing threats, union organizing
and NAFTA” Multinational Monitor 18(3) (March): 8–13.
Brooks, Wyatt , Joseph Kaboski , Yao Li and Wei Qian . 2019. “Exploitation of Labor? Classical
Monopsony Power and Labor's Share”, NBER Working Paper 25660:
http://www.nber.org/papers/w25660
Buffie, Edward and Allen Krause . 1989. “Mexico 1956–86” pp. 141–168 in J. Sachs (ed.)
Developing Country Debt and the World Economy. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Calderón-Villarreal, Cuauhtémoc , Gloria Lizeth Ochoa-Adame and Luis Huesca-Reynoso .
2017. “Mercado laboral y cambio tecnológico en el sector manufacturero mexicano
(2005–2014)” Economía, Sociedad y Territorio 17 (núm. 54): 523–560.
Camarena Luhrs, Margarita . 1981. La industria automotriz en México, Vol. 6. México: IIS-
UNAM.
CAM (Centro de Análisis Multidisciplinario) . 2018. “La depredación de las clases trabajadoras
durante el desgobierno de Enrique Peña Nieto” Reporte de Investigación 130 (18 de
diciembre): https://cam.economia.unam.mx/reporte-de-investigacion-130
Cañas, Jesus , Aldo Heffner and Jorge Herrera Hernández . 2017. “Intra-industry trade with
Mexico may aid U.S. global competitiveness” Southwest Economy: Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas (Second Quarter): pp. 1–6.
Canis, Bill , Vivian Catherine Jones and M. Angeles Villarreal . 2017. Nafta and Motor Vehicle
Trade. Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service.
http://sgp.fas.org/crs/row/R44907.pdf
Cárdenas Gracia, Jaime . 2009. En Defensa del Petróleo. México, DF: UNAM.
Carrillo, Alejandro . 1938. “Mexican people and the oil companies” World Affairs 101 (3):
171–178.
Carrillo, Jorge . 1997. “Maquiladoras automotrices en México: Clústers y competencias de alto
nivel” pp. 193–234 en Novick, M. y Gallart (eds.) Competitividad, redes productivas y
competencias laborales. Montevideo, Uruguay: OIT/Cinterfor.
Carrillo, Jorge . 2018. Manufactura dinámica en México y posibilidades de desarrollo regional:
sectores automotriz y aeroespacial pp. 89–110 en E. Dussel (coordinador) Cadenas globales
de valor. Metodología, teoría y debates. México, DF: UNAM.
Carrillo, Jorge , Gabriela Bensusán and Jordi Micheli . 2017. “El debate sobre innovación y el
progreso socio-laboral” pp. 35–87 en J. Carrillo , G. Bensusán and J. Micheli (coordinadores)
¿Es posible innovar y mejorar laboralmente? Estudio de trayectorias de empresas
multinacionales en México. México: UAM.
Carrillo, Jorge and Patricia García . 1987. “Etapas industriales y conflictos laborales: la industria
automotriz en México” Estudios Sociológicos 5 (14): 303–340.
Carrillo, Jorge and Red Gomis . 2005. “Generaciones de maquiladoras: Un primer
acercamiento a su medición” Frontera norte 17 (33): 25–51.
Carrillo, Jorge and Raúl Hinojosa . 2001. “Cableando el norte de México: la evolución de la
industria maquiladora de arneses” Región y Sociedad 13 (21): 79–114.
Carrillo Huerta, Mario . 1990. “Una interpretación del impacto de las maquiladoras en el
bienestar familiar y en el desarrollo regional” Estudios Fronterizos 21 (enero-abril): 29–68.
Casado, José María y María Teresa Sánchez . 2019. “Los mineros en el México neoliberal”.
Investigaciones geográficas 98: https://doi.org/10.14350/rig.59787
Casado, José María . 2020. “Empleo y salarios en la micro, pequeña y mediana minería”
Cuadernos Geográficos 59 (3): 178–196.
Caulfield, Norman . 2010. NAFTA and Labor in North America. Urbana-Champaign, IL:
University of Illinois Press.
Ceceña, Ana 2019. “Megaproyectos para el mercado mundial” Observatorio Latinoamericano
de Geopolítica. México D.F: IIEc, UNAM: pp. 3–10:
https://geopolitica.iiec.unam.mx/sites/geopolitica.iiec.unam.mx/files/2020-
03/Tren%20Maya.%20Avances%20de%20investigacio%CC%81n%202.pdf
Ceceña, José Luis . 1970. México en la órbita imperial. México, DF: El Caballito.
CEFP (Centro de Estudios de las Finanzas Públicas) . 2022. “Análisis de los Aspectos
Macroeconómico 2021” (22 de mayo) México, DF: Camera de Diputados.
CEPAL (Comisión Económica para América Latina y el Caribe) . 2020. La Inversión Extranjera
Directa en América Latina y el Caribe. Santiago, Chile: CEPAL.
CEPALSTAT . 2022. “Importaciones de bienes por grandes categorías económicas: Bienes de
capital” Bases de Datos y Publicaciones Estadísticas:
https://statistics.cepal.org/portal/databank/index.html?lang=es&indicator_id=2203&area_id=419
Cerutti, Mario , Isabel Ortega and Lylia Palacios . 1999. “Empresarios, empresa y grupos
económicos en el norte de México: Monterrey, del estado oligárquico a la globalización” História
Econômica & História de Empresas II (2): 103–137.
Chang, Ha-Joon . 2002. Kicking Away the Ladder. London, UK: Anthem Press.
Chapa, Sergio . 2022. “Mexico plans to become an export hub with US-drilled natural gas”
Bloomberg (August 12): https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2022-08-12/mexico-plans-to-
become-lng-export-hub
Choi, Jiwon , Ilyana Kuziemko , Ebonya Washington and Gavin Wright . 2021. “Local economic
and political effects of trade deals: Evidence from NAFTA” Department of Economics, Yale
University (November 19): 1–102.
Chu, Wan-Wen . 2011. “How the Chinese government promoted a global automobile industry”
Industrial and Corporate Change 20 (5): 1235–1276.
Cimoli, Mario . 2000. “Creación de redes y sistema de innovación: México en un contexto
global” El Mercado de Valores 60 (1): 3–17.
Clark, Don and Kellen Browning . 2022. “Taiwanese chip giant eyes upgrades to Phoenix plant”
New York Times (December 7): pp. B1, B4.
Cluster Industrial . 2022. “Nearshoring provoca 370 mil m2 de demanda en espacios industrial
en el 1T 2022: CBRE” (3 de junio):
https://www.clusterindustrial.com.mx/noticia/4902/nearshoring-provoca-370-mil-m2-de-
demanda-en-espacios-industrial-en-el-1t-2022-cbre
Coe, Neil M. and Henry Wai-chung Yeung . 2015. Global Production Networks: Theorizing
Economic Development in an Interconnected World. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Coe, Neil M. 2020. Global production networks: Mapping recent conceptual developments,
Journal of Economic Geography 19 (4): 775–801.
Cohen, Stephen and John Zysman (eds.). 1987. Manufacturing Matters. New York, NY: Basic
Books.
Coll-Hurtado, Atlantida , María Salazar y Josefina Morales . 2001. La minería en México.
México: UNAM.
Collier, Ruth . 1992. The Contradictory Alliance. Berkeley, CA: University of California,
International and Area Studies.
CONEVAL (Consejo Nacional de Evaluación de la Política de Desarrollo Social) . 2015.
“Evolución de las Dimensiones de la Pobreza 1990–2014”:
https://www.coneval.org.mx/Medicion/EDP/Paginas/Evolucion-de-las-dimensiones-de-la-
pobreza-1990-2014.aspx
CONEVAL . 2018. “Medicíon de Pobreza 2008–2018”:
https://www.coneval.org.mx/Medicion/MP/Paginas/Pobreza-2018.aspx
CONEVAL . 2020. “Medicíon de Pobreza 2020”:
https://www.coneval.org.mx/Medicion/Paginas/PobrezaInicio.aspx
CONEVAL . 2022a. “Evolución de las líneas de pobreza por ingresos”:
https://www.coneval.org.mx/Medicion/MP/Paginas/Lineas-de-Pobreza-por-Ingresos.aspx
CONEVAL . 2022b. “Medicíon de Pobreza 2022”:
https://www.coneval.org.mx/Medicion/Paginas/ITLP-IS_pobreza_laboral.aspx
Conine, Gary . 1992. “Mexico: Energy development and the state oil company” Tulsa Law
Review 27 (4): 625–645.
Contreras, Óscar , Jorge Carrillo and Jorge Alonso . 2012. “Local entrepreneurship within global
value chains: A case study in the Mexican automotive industry” World Development 40 (5):
1013–1023.
Contreras, Oscar and Paula Isiordia . 2010. “Local institutions, local networks and the upgrading
challenge. Mobilising regional assets to supply the global auto industry in Northern Mexico”
Automotive Technology and Management 10(2–3): 161–179.
Corrales, Salvador . (2020). “El uso industrial del agua en la cervecería Heineken en Monterrey”
Región y sociedad 32: https://doi.org/10.22198/rys2020/32/1298
Council of Economic Advisors . (2010). Economic Report of the President. Washington, DC:
USGPO.
Cortés, Pedro . 2022. “Producción de cerveza mexicana sube 4,8%” Infobae (2 de noviembre):
https://www.infobae.com/america/agencias/2022/11/02/produccion-de-cerveza-mexicana-sube-
48
Cortés, Ramón , Emma Zapata y María del Rosario Ayala . 2019. “Narrativas de despojo y
destrucción La megaminería en México” Política y Cultura 52: 113–139.
Covarrubias, Alex and Ortiz Bouzas . 2016. Empleo y políticas sindicales en la industria
automotriz de México. México: Fundación Friedrich Ebert, p. 7. https://library.fes.de/pdf-
files/bueros/mexiko/13017.pdf
Cowie, Jefferson . 1999. Capital Moves. Ithica, NY: Cornell University Press.
Cronin, Bruce . 2017. “The rise and decline of the business roundtable?” pp. 133–158 in
Alejandra Salas-Porras and Georgina Murray (eds.) Think Tanks and Global Politics: Key
Spaces in the Structure of Power, London: UK: Palgrave Macmillan,
Crossa, Mateo . 2022a. “Distorted linkages and labor devaluation: An exploration of automotive
value chain-driven ‘development’ in Ciudad Juárez, Mexico” Canadian Journal of Development
Studies 1–23.
Crossa, Mateo . 2022b. “Contorting transformations: Uneven impacts of the U.S.–Mexico
automotive industrial complex” Competition & Change 26 (5): 533–553.
Crossa, Mateo and James Cypher . 2021. “Behind the Virtuous Façade” Dollars & Sense
(May/June) 354: 21–28.
Crossa, Mateo and Raúl Delgado Wise . 2022. “Innovation in the era of generalized
monopolies: The case of the US–Mexico automotive industrial complex”Globalizations 19 (2):
301–321.
Crossa, Mateo and Nina Ebner . 2020. “Automotive global value chains in Mexico: A mirage of
development?” Third World Quarterly 41 (7): 1218–1239.
Cullell, Jon Martín . 2022. “La pobreza laboral cae en México pese a la inflación rampante” El
País (25 de mayo): https://elpais.com/mexico/2022-05-25/la-pobreza-laboral-cae-en-mexico-
pese-a-la-inflacion-rampante.html
Cutcher-Gershenfeld, Joel , Dan Brooks , Martin Malloy . 2015. “The decline and resurgence of
the U.S. auto industry” EPI Briefing Paper no. 399 (May 6).
Cypher, James . 1990. State and Capital in Mexico. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Cypher, James . 1991. “La política de México para la promoción de exportaciones” Revista
Mexicana de Sociología 53 (3): 81–110.
Cypher, James . 1992. “Renascent rivalry: Global low-wage manufacturing, U.S. decline and
emergent regionalism” pp. 84–107 in Chronis Polychroniou (ed.) Perspectives and Issues in
International Political Economy. Westport, CT: Praeger.
Cypher, James . 1993a. “The ideology of economic science in the selling of NAFTA” Review of
Radical Political Economics 25 (4): 146–163.
Cypher, James . 1993b. “Estimating the impact of the U.S.-Mexico free trade agreement on
industrial labor” pp. 85–96 in Mario Bognanno and Kathryn Ready (eds.) The North American
Free Trade Agreement. Westport, CN: Praeger.
Cypher, James . 1996. “Mexico: Financial fragility or structural crisis?” Journal of Economic
Issues 30 (2): 451–461.
Cypher, James . 2004. “Development diverted: Socioeconomic characteristics of mature
maquilization” pp. 343–382 in K. Kopinak (ed.) The Social Costs of Industrial Growth in
Northern Mexico. San Diego, CA: Center for U.S.-Mexico Studies, University of California, San
Diego.
Cypher, James . 2011. “Nearly two Trillion dollars were purloined from U.S. workers in 2009”
Dollars and Sense (July/August): 24–25.
Cypher, James . 2015. “The double economic bubbles of the 21st century” Working Paper no.
103 (January): Global Institute for Sustainable Prosperity: https://www.global-isp.org/working-
paper-no-103/
Cypher, James . 2018. “Energy privatization and land grabbing” pp. 43–80 in Darcy Tetreault
and Cindy McCulligh (eds.) Social Environmental Conflicts in Mexico.
Cypher, James . 2021. The Process of Economic Development. London, UK: Routledge.
Cypher, James and Mateo Crossa . 2019. “T-MEC en el espejo del TLCAN: Engañosas
ilusiones, brutales realidades” Ola Financiera 12 (34): 56–87.
Cypher, James and Mateo Crossa . 2020. “Arbitraje laboral en la globalización: La nueva
estructura de la dependencia” Ola Financiera 13 (36): 43–70.
Cypher, James and Raúl Delgado Wise . 2012. México a la deriva. Génesis, desempeño y
crisis del Modelo Exportador de Fuerza de Trabajo. México, DF: Miguel Ángel Porrúa.
Cypher, James and Aldo Pérez . 2013. “Instituciones y tecnología como factores claves en los
proyectos nacionales del desarrollo” CENES 32 (2): 105–138.
Damián, Araceli . 2017. “Inegi y Coneval cucharean datos de pobreza” Aresteguinoticias (4 de
septiembre): https://aristeguinoticias.com/0409/mexico/inegi-y-coneval-cucharean-datos-de-
pobreza/
Davidson, Carl and Steven Matusz . 2009. International Trade with Equilibrium Unemployment.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Dávila Jiménez, Gerardo . 1982. A política de precios y subsidies” pp. 228–249 en Héctor
González (ed.) El sistema económico mexicano. México, DF: La Red Jonas.
Davis, Bob . 2021. “Biden team promises new look in trade policy”, The Wall Street Journal
(January 24): https://www.wsj.com/articles/biden-team-promises-new-look-in-trade-policy-
11611484201
Davis, Steven . 2020. “Comment” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Spring): pp. 78–87.
De Bernis, Gerard . 1994. “Perroux, François” pp. 152–155 in Geoffrey Hodgson , Warren
Samules and Marc Tool (eds.) Institutional and Evolutionary Economics. Aldershot, England:
Edward Elgar Publishing.
De la Calle, Luis and Luis Rubio . 2010. Clasemediero. México, DF: CIDAC.
de la Cruz Gallegos, José Luis . 2019. “La responsabilidad de contar con una política industrial
integral” pp. 53–71 en Arturo Oropeza García (coordinador) Desarrollo industrial 2050. México,
DF: Instituto para el Desarrollo Industrial y el Crecimiento Económico.
de Ita, Ana . 2019. “Las reformas agrarias neoliberales en México” El Cotidiano no. 214:
95–107.
De la Garza, Enrique . (2014a). “¿ Innovación y aprendizaje tecnológicos sin trabajo?” RELET-
Revista Latinoamericana de Estudios del Trabajo 19 (31): 71–106.
De la Garza, Enrique . 2006. Restructuración productiva, empresas y trabajadores en México.
México, D.F.: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
De la Garza, Enrique . 2007. “The crisis of the maquiladora model in Mexico” Work and
Occupations 34 (4): 399–429.
De la Garza, Enrique 2014b. “¿ Innovación y aprendizaje tecnológicos sin trabajo? ” RELET-
Revista Latinoamericana de Estudios del Trabajo 19 (31): 71–106.
De la Vega, Ángel . 1999. Evolución del Componente Petrolero en el Desarrollo y la Transición
de México. México, DF: UNAM.
del Castillo Negrete, Miguel . 2015. La magnitud de la desigualdad en el ingreso y la riqueza en
México. Santiago, Chile: CEPAL.
Delgado, Gian Carlo . 2009. “Maquilización y dependencia tecnológica: el caso de México” El
Norte-Finnish Journal of Latin American Studies 4: 1–22.
Delgado Gómez, Álvaro . 2021. “Millones de archivos que documentaban privatizaciones de
Salinas fueron robados” Sin embargo (17 de agosto): https://www.sinembargo.mx/17-08-
2021/4015159
de María y Campos, Mauricio . 1992. Reestructuración y desarrollo de la industria automotriz
mexicana en los años ochenta: evolución y perspectivas. Estudios e Informes de la CEPAL no.
83 (agosto). Santiago, Chile: CEPAL, Naciones Unidas.
Destler, I. M. 1991. “U.S trade policy-making in the eighties” pp. 251–284 in Alberto Alesina and
Geoffrey Carliner (eds.) Politics and Economics in the Eighties. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Dicken, Peter . 2003. Global Shift. New York: The Guilford Press.
Dlouhy, Jennifer . 2022. “John Kerry woos Wall Street in bid to bolster US climate finance”
Bloomberg (September 28): https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2022-09-28/kerry-woos-
wall-street-in-bid-to-bolster-us-climate-finance
Dos Santos, Theotonio . 1979. “La tecnología y la restructuración capitalista: opciones para
América Latina” Comercio Exterior 29 (12): 1361–1370.
DOF (Darío Oficial de la Federación) . 1955. Diario Oficial. México, DF: 1955.
DOF (Darío Oficial de la Federación) . 1994. Sexto Informe de Gobierno, Carlos Salinas de
Gortari. México, D.F.: SEGOB.
DOF (Darío Oficial de la Federación) . 1995. “Ley de Impuestos y Fomento a la Minería” (31 de
diciembre): 13–19.
Domhoff, William , Clifford Staples and Adam Schneider 2022. “Interlocks and Interactions
among the Power Elite”
https://whorulesamerica.ucsc.edu/power_elite/interlocks_and_interactions.html
Dreiling, Michael and Derek Darves . 2011. “Corporate unity in American trade policy” American
Journal of Sociology 116 (5): 1514–1563.
Duhalt, Adrian . 2022. Mexico and the Soaring International Price of Fertilizers. Issue brief (no.
02.24.22) Houston, TX: Baker Institute for Public Policy, Rice University.
Eschenbacher, Stephanie and Anna Martinez . 2021. “Pemex’s U.S. refinery bet in Texas
hinges on expertise transfer” Reuters (Junne 2): https://www.reuters.com/world/us/pemexs-us-
refinery-bet-texas-hinges-expertise-transfer-2021
Economic Policy Institute . 2011. “Wages and compensation stagnating”, chart from The State
of Working America, 2011. Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institute:
https://www.stateofworkingamerica.org
EFE . 2022. “Empresarios mexicanos descartan ‘pelea’ con EE.UU. por conflicto energético”
Agencia EFE (16 de agosto): https://www.efe.com/efe/america/economia/empresarios-
mexicanos-descartan-pelea-con-ee-uu-por-conflicto-energetico/20000011-4868084
El Informador . 2018. “En 2017 se creó la mayor cantidad de empleos formales” Informador.MX
(12 de enero): https://www.informador.mx/economia/En-2017-se-creo-la-mayor-cantidad-de-
empleos-formales--20180112-0012.html
Erb, Guy and Joseph Greenwald . 1989. “U.S.-Mexico trade relations” pp. 107–148 in William
Glade and Cassio Luiselli (eds.) The Economics of Interdependence: Mexico and the United
States. San Diego, CA: Center for U.S.-Mexico Studies, University of California, San Diego.
Escobar, Agustin , Philip Martin and Omar Stabridis . 2019. Farm Labor and Mexico’s Export
Produce Industry. Washington, DC: Wilson Center:
https://www.wilsoncenter.org/sites/default/files/media/documents/publication/farm_labor_and_m
exico_export_produce_industry.pdf
Evans, Peter . 1995. Embedded Autonomy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Evans, Peter and Gary Gereffi . 1982. “Foreign investment and dependent development” pp.
111–169 in S. Hewlett and R. Weinert (eds.) Brazil and Mexico: Patterns in Late Development.
Philadelphia, PA: Institute for the Study of Human Issues.
Fairbrother, Malcom . 2014. “Economists, capitalists, and the making of globalization” American
Journal of Sociology 119 (5): 1324–1379.
Fairfield, Tasha . 2015. “Structural power in comparative political economy: Perspectives from
policy formulation in Latin America” Business and Politics 17 (3): 411–441.
Farías Hernández, José . 1997. “La fuga de capitales en México de 1989 a 1995” Este País 79
(octubre): 1–13.
Félix Verduzco, Gustavo and Alejandro Dávila Flores . 2008. “Apertura comercial y demanda en
el crecimiento de las entidades federativas de México” Comercio Exterior 58 (4): 258–270.
Feng, Justin . 2022. “The costs of U.S.-China semiconductor decoupling” New Perspectives on
Asia (May 25). Washington, DC: Center for Strategic and International Studies.
Fernández, B. M. 1990. “Los precios de garantía en México” Revista Comercio Exterior 40 (10):
938–942.
Fernández, Víctor Ramiro and Manuel Facundo Trevignani . 2015. “Cadenas globales de valor
y desarrollo: perspectivas críticas desde el sur global” Dados 58 (2): 499–536.
Fernández-Vega, Carlos . 2022. “México SA: AMLO, recuento neoliberal” La Jornada (16 de
agosto): https://www.jornada.com.mx/2022/08/16/opinion/023o1eco
Fischer-Daly, Mathew and Mark Anner . 2021. “Strawberry global supply chains in Mexico”
CGWR; https://www.solidaritycenter.org/wp-content/uploads/2021/09/Strawberry-Global-
Supply-Chains-in-Mexico.March-2021.pdf
Frank, Ellen . 2003. “Dear Dr. Dollar” Dollars & Sense (Sept/Oct):
http://dollarsandsense.org/archives/2003/0103dollar.html
FRED (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis) . 2019. “The U.S. auto labor market since NAFTA”
(April 19): https://www.stlouisfed.org/on-the-economy/2019/april/us-auto-labor-market-nafta
FRED (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis) 2022. “Labor force participation rate-men”:
https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/LNS11300001
Fuentes Flores, Noé , Alejandro Brugués Rodríguez and Gabriel González König . 2020. “Valor
agregado en el valor bruto de las exportaciones” Frontera Norte 32 (Art. 7): 1–13.
http://dx.doi.org/10.33679/rfn.v1i1.1990
Fujii, Gerardo and Rosario Cervantes . 2013. “México: Valor agregado en las exportaciones
manufactureras” Revista Cepal 109 (abril): 143–158.
Fuller, Thomas . 2022. “As homeless age, cities see surge in lonely deaths on the street” New
York Times (April 19): A1, A12.
Gallagher, Kevin and Lyuba Zarsky . 2007. The Enclave Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Gambrill, Mónica . 2008. “IMMEX: convergencia de la maquiladora y la industria manufacturera
de exportación” Comercio Exterior 58 (4): 315–321.
Gámez, Alberta . 2001. “Pólitica Interburocrática en la Pólitica Exterior de México 1988–1994”
Foro Internacional 41 (3): 474–500.
Garza, Humberto . 1996. “La política exterior de México: entre la dependencia y la
diversificación” Foro Internacional 36 (4): 641–666.
Gauss, Susan . 2010. Made in Mexico. University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University
Press.
Gavin, Michael . 1996. The Mexican Oil Boom. Working Papers Series 314. Washington, DC:
Inter-American Development Bank.
Geocomunes . 2021. “El Litio: la nueva disputa comercial dinamizada por el falso mercado
verde”: https://geocomunes.org/Analisis_PDF/Litio_Informe_Final_Enero2021.pdf
Gereffi, Gary and Miguel Korzeniewicz . 1994. Commodity Chains and Global Capitalism.
Westport, CT: Praeger.
Gereffi, Gary , John Humphrey and Timothy Sturgeon . 2005. “The governance of global value
chains” Review of International Political Economy 12 (1): 78–104.
Gerschenkron, Alexander . 1962. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. New York:
Praeger.
Gilens, Martin and Benjamin Page . 2014. “Testing theories of American politics” Perspectives
on Politics 12 (3): 564–581.
Gitili, Eduardo . 1990. “La dinámica del comercio exterior” pp. 157–163 en Rosa Garavito y
Augusto Bolívar (comps.) México en la década de los ochenta. México, DF: UAM.
Goldstein, Amy . 2017. Janesville: An American Story. New York, NY: Simon & Shuster.
Gómez Bruera, Hernan . 2021. “Entrevista a Blanca Heredia” Este País (22 de marzo):
https://estepais.com/tendencias_y_opiniones/politica/el-combate-a-la-corrupcion-ha-
contribuido-a-desmantelar-el-viejo-pacto-oligarquicoentrevista
González, Lilia . 2022a. “Economía y el CCE delinean ruta de política industrial” El Economista
(28 de julio): https://www.eleconomista.com.mx/empresas/Secretaria-de-Economia-detalla-
nueva-politica-industrial-con-empresarios-20220728-0074.html
González, Lilia . 2022b. “Economía e IP delinean política industrial; falta definir incentivos” El
Economista (20 de septiembre): https://www.eleconomista.com.mx/empresas/Secretaria-de-
Economia-presenta-su-estrategia-Rumbo-a-una-politica-industrial-20220920-0096.html
González Amador, Roberto . 2010. “En 1993, Salinas ofreció a EU abrir Pemex al capital
extranjero” La Jornada (27 de octubre): 7.
González Marín, María . 1996. La Industria de Bienes de Capital en México. México, DF:
Ediciones el Caballito.
González Razo, Felipe de Jesús , Samuel Rebollar , Juvencio Hernández Martínez , José Luis
Morales y Orsohe Ramírez, A. 2019. “Situación actual y perspectivas de la producción de
berries en México” Revista Mexicana de Agronegocios 44 (enero-junio): 260–272.
Goodfriend, Marvin and Robert G. King . 2005. “The incredible Volcker disinflation” Journal of
Monetary Economics 52: 981–1015.
Gordon, Sara . 1993. “La política social y el Programa Nacional de Solidaridad” Revista
Mexicana de Sociología 55 (2): 351–366.
Gould, Elise . 2020. “State of Working America Wages 2019” (February 20): Washington, DC:
Economic Policy Institute.
Greenhouse, David . 2010. “Most US Union Members are Working for the Government” New
York Times (January 23): B1, B5.
Guillén, Arturo . 2021. El régimen de acumulación en México. Cepal, Serie Estudios y
Perspectiva 190: Santiago de Chile: CL
https://repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/handle/11362/46794/1/S2100214_es.pdf
Guillén, Hector . 2007–8. “Francois Perroux: pionero olvidado de la economía del desarrollo”
Mundo Siglo XXI 11 (1): 11–22.
Gutiérrez, Julio . 2022. “Capital a exploración y extracción de crudo, en mínimos desde 2017”
La Jornada (18 de octubre): p. 21.
Guizar, Contreras and Mayra Vanessa . 2020. Capacidad para atraer la inversión extranjera
directa en México en el sector manufacturero y su impacto en la industria automotriz Cimexus
15 (2), 13–38.
Hamilton, Nora . 1982. The Limits of State Autonomy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Hansen, N. 1989. “Poles of development” pp. 286–290 in John Eatwell , Murray Milgate and
Peter Newman (eds.) The New Plagrave: Economic Development. New York, NY: W.W. Norton.
Hansen, Roger . 1971. Mexican Economic Development: The Roots of Rapid Growth.
Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Harris, Katelynn . 2020. “Forty years of falling manufacturing employment” Beyond the
Numbers: Employment & Unemployment 9 (16): https://www.bls.gov/opub/btn/volume-9/forty-
years-of-falling-manufacturing-employment.htm
Harris, Katelynn and Michael McCall . 2019. “The relative weakness in earnings of production
workers in manufacturing, 1990–2018” Monthly Labor Review (December):
https://doi.org/10.21916/mlr.2019.27
Harris, Lee . 2022. “Industrial policy without industrial unions” The American Prospect 33 (5):
24–31.
Hart, John . 2002. Empire and Revolution. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Hausmann, Ricardo , Luis Espinoza and Miguel Santos . 2015. The Low-Productivity Trap:
Chiapas Growth Diagnostics. CID Working Paper No. 304 (October) Harvard University,
Cambridge, MA: pp. 1–67.
Hermanson, Jeff and Enrique De la Garza Toledo . 2005. “El corporativismo y las nuevas
luchas en las maquilas de México” pp. 181–213 en E. Garza de la Toledo (coordinador).
Sindicatos y nuevos movimientos sociales en América Latina. Buenos Aires, Argentina:
CLACSO.
Hernández Cervantes, Héctor . 1988. “Lineamientos de la política comercial actual” Comercio
Exterior 36 (6): 528–531.
Hernández Laos, Enrique . 2000. La competitividad industrial en México. México, DF: Plaza y
Valdes.
Hernández López, Julio . 2022. “Astillero” La Jornada (21 de octubre):
https://www.jornada.com.mx/2022/10/21/opinion/010o1pol
Hickman, Alberto . 2012 “PEMEX: Crisis generada desde el gobierno” Lado B (19 de marzo):
https://www.ladobe.com.mx/2012/03/pemex-crisis-generada-desde-el-gobierno-2/
Hirschman, Albert . 1989. “Linkages” pp. 210–221 in John Eatwell , Murray Milgate and Peter
Newman (eds.) The New Palgrave: Economic Development. New York, NY: W.W. Norton.
Hoekman, Bernard . 1997. “Developing countries and the multilateral trading system after the
Uruguay Round” pp. 252–279 in Roy Culpeper , Albert Berry and Frances Stewart (eds.) Global
Development Fifty Years after Bretton Woods. New York, NY: St. Martin’s Press.
Howell, David and Arne Kalleberg . 2019. “Declining job quality in the United States:
Explanations and evidence” The Russell Sage Foundation Journal of the Social Sciences 5 (4)
1–53.
Howes, Candace . 1993. Japanese Auto Transplants and the U.S. Automobile Industry.
Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institute.
Hudson, Ray . 2007. “Regions and regional uneven development forever?” Regional Studies 41
(9): 1149–1160.
Huesca, Robert . 1988. “The Mexican Oil Expropriation and the Ensuing Propaganda War”
Working paper No. 88-04, Institute of Latin American Studies, University of Texas at Austin: pp.
1–32.
Hufbauer, Gary and Jeffrey Schott . 1992. North American Free Trade. Washington, DC:
Institute for International Economics.
Hufbauer, Gary . 2005. NAFTA Revisited. New York, NY: Columbia University Press.
Hufbauer, Gary and Cathleen Cimino-Isaacs . 2014. “NAFTA rejoinder: The US effects are
clearly positive for most workers” Peterson Institute for International Economics (July 30):
https://www.piie.com/blogs/trade-investment-policy-watch/nafta-rejoinder-
Iacovone, Leonardo , Rafael Muñoz Moreno , Eduardo Olaberria and Mariana de la Paz Pereira
López . 2021. Crecimiento de la productividad en México. México, DF: Banco Mundial.
Ibarra, Carlos . 2019. “Technical and structural change, and the fall in the manufacturing
output–capital ratio in Mexico, 1990–2015” Cambridge Journal of Economics 43 (3): 649–676.
Ibarra, Carlos and Jaime Ros . 2019. “La disminución de la participación del trabajo en el
ingreso en México, 1990–2015” El Trimestre Económico 96 (4): 853–899.
Ifill, Gwen . 1993. “Clinton recruits 3 presidents to promote trade pact” New York Times
(September 15): B12.
Ignatenko, Anna , Faezeh, Raei and Borislava Mircheva . 2019. “Global value chains: What are
the benefits and why do countries participate?” IMF Working Paper WP/19/18. pp. 1–31:
https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2019/01/18/Global-Value-Chains-What-are-the-
Benefits-and-Why-Do-Countries-Participate-46505
IDB (Inter-American Development Bank) . 2021. Vision 2025: Reinvest in the Americas, A
Decade of Opportunity (February 19). Washington, D.C.: IDB. pp. 1–45.
IDB (Inter-American Development Bank) . 2022. “Nearshoring can add annual $78 bln in
exports from Latin America and Caribbean” (June 7):
https://www.iadb.org/en/news/nearshoring-can-add-annual-78-bln-exports-latin-america-and-
caribbean
IMF (International Monetary Fund) . 2009. “Review of recent crisis programs” Appendix
(September 14): https://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2009/091409.pdf.
IMSS (Instituto Mexicano del Seguro Social) . 2020. Informe 2019–2020. México, D.F.: IMSS.
INEGI (Instituto Nacional de Estadística y Geografía) . 1985. Estadísticas Históricas de México,
Tomos I y II. México, DF: INEGI.
INEGI (Instituto Nacional de Estadística y Geografía) . 2020. Índice de precios al consumidor de
la canasta de consumo mínimo. México, DF: INEGI.
Infobae . 2022. “México y EEUU hicieron a un lado la disputa por temas energéticos: acordaron
plan para crear chips y autos eléctricos” Infobae (13 Septiembre):
https://www.infobae.com/america/mexico/2022/09/13/mexico-y-eeuu-hicieron-a-un-lado-la-
disputa-por-temas-energeticos-acordaron-plan-para-crear-chips-y-autos-electricos/
Iñiguez Montiel, Alberto and Javier Galán Figueroa . 2019. “Guerra contra las drogas y su
impacto económico en México, 2001–2012” Revista de Economía Mexicana Año 4 (4):
258–304.
Jaramillo-Molina, Máximo . 2021. “Los mitos de la política social de la 4T” Nexos (29 de julio):
https://economia.nexos.com.mx/los-mitos-de-la-politica-social-de-la-4t/
Jiménez, Néstor and Alonso Urrutia . 2022. “SE: quieren instalarse en México 400 empresas”
La Jornada (15 de noviembre): p. 21.
Jiménez, Néstor and Clara Zepeda . 2022. “El alza al minisalario beneficiará a 6.4 millones de
trabajadores” La Jornada (5 de diciembre): 23.
Kapur, Devesh , John Lewis and Richard Webb . 1997. The World Bank, Its First Half Century,
Vol. 1. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Kessler, Glenn . 2017. “The Trump administration’s claim that the U.S. government ‘certified’
700,000 jobs lost by NAFTA” Washington Post (August 18):
https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/fact-checker/wp/2017/08/18/the-trump-administrations-
claim-that-the-u-s-government-certified-700000-jobs-lost-by-nafta/
Kletzer, Lori . 2002. “Globalization and American job loss: Public policy to help workers”
Perspectives on Work 6 (1): 28–30
Kletzer, Lori . 2005. “Globalization and job loss, from manufacturing to services” Economic
Perspectives: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago (2Q): 38–46.
KNONEMA . 2022. “Oil: Mexico-total petroleum consumption” World Data Atlas. (May):
https://knoema.com/atlas/Mexico/topics/Energy/Oil/Petroleum-consumption
Krauss, Cliford . 2018. ¿López Obrador representa una amenaza para la industria petrolera
internacional? New York Times (26 de abril):
https://www.nytimes.com/es/2018/04/26/espanol/america-latina/petroleo-mexico-amlo.html
Kristal, Tali and Yinon Cohen . 2014. “The causes of rising wage inequality: The race between
institutions and technology” Socio-Economic Review 15 (1): 187–212.
Krugman, Paul . 2019. “Globalization: What did we miss?” pp. 113–120 in Luís Catão and
Maurice Obstfeld (eds.) Meeting Globalizations Challenges. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Krugman, Paul . 2022. “Why America is getting tough on trade” New York Times (December
13): A23.
La Botz, Daniel . 2010. “What happened to the American working class?” New Politics 12 (4)
(Winter 2010): 1–7.
Landa Díaz, Heri , Verónica Cerezo García and Ignacio Perrotini Hernández . 2020. “La
vulnerabilidad estructural de la economía Mexicana” Contaduría y Administración 65 (5): 1–14.
LaPedus, Mark . 2004. “Mexico to set up park for semiconductor makers” EE Times (July 6):
https://www.eetimes.com/mexico-to-set-up-park-for-semiconductor-makers/
Lara, Arturo and Jorge Carrillo . 2003. “Technological globalization and intra-company
coordination in the automotive sector: The case of Delphi – Mexico” International Journal of
Automotive Technology and Management 3(1): DOI:10.1504/IJATM.2003.003374
Larriva, Juan José and Amado Vega . 1982. “El comercio exterior de la industria automovilística
en México” Comercio Exterior 32 (12): 1358–1363.
Laureles, Jared . 2022. “Dan de baja 35 contratos colectivos de trabajo” La Jornada (14 de
mayo): 10.
Laureles, Jared , Arturo Sánchez and Alejandro Alegría . 2022. “Mayoría de obreros en GM
avalan contrato colectivo” La Jornada (28 de mayo): 9.
Laureles, Jared and César Arellano . 2022. “Dan banderazo a la última etapa de la reforma
laboral” La Jornada (4 de octubre): p. 7.
Laurell, Asa Cristina . 2003. “The transformation of social policy in Mexico” pp. 320–349 in
Kevin Middelbrook and Eduardo Zepeda (eds.) Confronting Development. Stanford, CA:
Stanford University Press.
Lederman, D. , Maloney, W. and Serven, L. 2004. Lessons from NAFTA for Latin America.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Léonard, Eric , Bruno Losch y Félix Mostajo . 2009. “La inserción de la agricultura mexicana en
el mercado norteamericano” Foro Internacional 49 (1): 5–46.
Lewis, W. Arthur . 1954. “Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor” Manchester
School of Economic and Social Studies 22 (May): 139–191.
Levy, Frank and Peter Temin . 2007. “Inequality and institutions in 20th century America” (June
27). MIT Department of Economics Working Paper No. 07-17 (June 27): pp. 1–59.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.984330
Liebman, Benjamin and Curtis Milhaupt . 2015. Regulating the Visible Hand? The Institutional
Implications of Chinese State Capitalism. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
López Salazar, Ricardo , A. Gracida Juárez and Jorge Carrillo . 2014. “Complejidad e
innovación en proveedores automotrices de logística. La experiencia de CAMEX México” pp.
170–181 en L. Álvarez , J. Carrillo and M. L. González (eds.) El auge de la industria automotriz
en México en el siglo XXI. México, DF: UNAM.
Lustig, Nora , Luis Lopéz-Calva and Eduardo Ortíz-Juarez . 2013. “Declining inequality in Latin
America in the 2000s” World Development 44 (C): 129–141.
Lutz Ley, América . 2020. “Minería y seguridad hídrica en el noroeste de México” Región y
sociedad 32: https://doi.org/10.22198/rys2020/32/1295.
MacArthur, John . 2000. The Selling of Free Trade. New York, NY: Hill and Wang.
MacEwan, Arthur . 2006. “Liberalization, Migration, and Development: The Mexico-U.S.
Relationship” Revista de Economía Mundial núm. 14: 57–85.
Mackinlay, Horacio . 2020. “La Reforma Agraria mexicana y la empresa paraestatal Tabamex
(1972–1990)” Polis 16 (1): 33–73.
Manetto, Francesco . 2021. “López Obrador persigue su sueño petrolero con un plan de
soberanía energética para México” El País (29 de diciembre): https://elpais.com/mexico/2021-
12-29/lopez-obrador-persigue-su-sueno-petrolero-con-un-plan-de-soberania-energetica-para-
mexico.html
Martínez González, María de Lourdes . 2017. “La generación Afore no tendrá pensión”
Frecuencia Laboral:
http://www.frecuencialaboral.com/aforeslageneracionaforesequedarasinpension2017.htm
Martínez-Martínez, Adriana and Jorge Carrillo . 2017. “¿Hay política industrial en Guanajuato?
Análisis de la industria automotriz” pp. 121–144 en J. Carrillo and A. Martínez (eds.)
Innovación, redes de colaboración y sostenibilidad. Experiencias regionales y tendencias
internacionales de la industria automotriz. México: UNAM.
Martínez Navarrete, Ifigenia . 1960. La distribución del ingreso y el desarrollo económico en
México. México, DF: Instituto de Investigaciones Económicas.
Massey, Doreen . (1995). Spatial divisions of Labour: Social Structures and the Geography of
Production. Londres: Macmillan International Higher Education.
Máttar, Jorge and Wislon Peres . 1997. “La política industrial y de comercio exterior en México”
pp. 219–262 en Wilson Peres (coordinador) Políticas de Competitividad Industrial. México, D.F.:
Siglo XXI.
Maurer, Noel . 2011. “The empire struck back: Sanction and compensation in the Mexican oil
expropriation”. Journal of Economic History 71 (3): 590–615.
McKinsey & Company . 2022 “Fifty years: Mexico 1970–2020”:
https://mckinseyfiftyyears.com.mx/
McMahon, Tim . 2022. “Historical crude oil prices” InflationData.com:
https://inflationdata.com/articles/inflation-adjusted-prices/historical-crude-oil-prices-table/
Méndez, José Luis . 2015. “El liderazgo político en la presidencia de Felipe Calderón
(2006–2012)” Foro Internacional 55 (1): 116–170.
Méndez, Rocío . 2022. “Programas de Bienestar llegan a 70% de hogares en México: AMLO”
MVS Noticias (22 de mayo): https://mvsnoticias.com/nacional/2022/5/22/programas-de-
bienestar-llegan-70-de-hogares-en-mexico-amlo-553187.html
Mendoza, Elva . 2012. “Con el ‘presidente del empleo’, más de 8 millones en la calle” Revista
Contralínea 282 (29 de abril): https://contralinea.com.mx/con-el-presidente-del-empleo-
Merrill, Tim and Ramón Miró . 1996. Mexico: A Country Study. Washington, DC: US Library of
Congress: http://countrystudies.us/mexico/78.htm
Mestries, Francis . 2009. “La crisis de la tortilla en los albores del sexenio de Felipe Calderón”
El Cotidiano (155): 87–93.
Meyer, Lorenzo . 1966 “El Conflicto Petrolero entre México y los Estados Unidos” Foro
Internacional 7 (1–2): 99–159.
Meyer, Lorenzo . 1993. “El presidencialismo” Revista Mexicana de Sociología 55 (2): 57–81.
Meyer, Lorenzo . 2020. “Recuperación que también fue final” Foro Internacional 60 (2):
331–365.
Miranda, Arturo Vicencio . 2007. “La industria automotriz en México: Antecedentes, situación
actual y perspectivas” Contaduría y Administración (Núm. 221): 209–246.
Mischel, Lawrence , Lynn Rhinehart and Lane Windham 2020. Explaining the Erosion of
Private-Sector Unions. Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institute pp. 1–64.
Mishel, Larry . 2022. “How automation and skill gaps fail to explain wage suppression or wage
inequality” Industrial and Corporate Change 22(2): 269–280.
Mizrahi, Yemile . 1992. “La nueva oposición conservador” Foro Internacional 32 (4): 744–771.
Molina, Daniel . 1989. “Pemex la privatización de facto” El Cotidiano 32 (noviembre-diciembre):
27–34.
Moody, Kim . 2007. US Labor in Trouble and Transition. London: Verso.
Morales, Josefina . 2002. “Trasnacionalización del capital minero mexicano”. pp. 51–83 en
Atlántida Coll-Hurtado and María Teresa Sánchez y Josefina Morales (eds.) La minería en
México. México DF: UNAM.
Morales, Josefina . 2010. La Maquila 1980–2008. México, Centroamérica y República
Dominicana. México: Tesis Doctoral, Posgrado en Estudios Latinoamericanas, UNAM.
Moran, Theodore . 1999. Foreign Direct Investment and Development. Washington, DC:
Institute for International Economics.
Moreno-Brid, Juan Carlos . 1988. Mexico’s Motor Vehicle Industry in the 1980s. Geneva: ILO.
Moreno-Brid, Juan Carlos . 1996. Mexicós auto industry after NAFTA: A successful experience
in restructuring? Working Paper, 232. The Helen Kellogg. Institute for International Studies,
University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN http://kellogg.nd.edu/documents/1527
Moreno-Brid, Juan Carlos , and Jaime Ros . 2009. Development and Growth in the Mexican
Economy. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Moreno-Brid, Juan Carlos , Luis Ángel Monroy-Gómez-Franco , Isabel Salat and Joaquín
Sánchez Gómez . 2019. “La evolución de los salarios: causa y reflejo de la desigualdad en
México” pp. 47–64 en Alicia Bárcena Ibarra and Rolando Cordera Campos (coordinadores)
Memoria del Seminario UNAM-CEPAL Cambio de Época. Santiago, Chile: CEPAL.
Morett-Sánchez, J. C. and C. Cosío-Ruiz . 2017. “Panorama de los ejidos y comunidades
agrarias en México” Agricultura, sociedad y desarrollo 14 (1): 125–152.
Muñoz, Juan Miguel . 1995. “Pemex pone a la venta 61 plantas petroquímicas” El País (19 de
marzo): https://elpais.com/diario/1995/03/20/economia/795654005_850215.html
Nación321 . 2019. “El proyecto empresarial que busca ser el contrapeso de AMLO y la 4T”
CIUDADANOS (08-05): https://www.nacion321.com/ciudadanos/el-proyecto-empresarial-que-
busca-ser-el-contrapeso-de-amlo-y-la-4t#.
Nadal, Alejandro . 2017. Pensar Fuera de la Caja. Santiago, Chile: CEPAL.
NAM (National Association of Manufacturers) 2022. “2019 advocacy advancements: A closer
look: Fighting for the USMCA” Annual Report: https://www.nam.org/2019-annual-
report/advocating-for-your-interests/
Navarro Ruiz, Gaspar . 2022. “AMLO-Kerry y Durazo hacen historia en Sonora” Crítica (28 de
octubre): https://www.critica.com.mx/vernoticias1.php?artid=99649&mas=18
Newman, Katherine . 1994. “Troubled times: The cultural dimensions of economic decline” pp.
330–358 in Michael Bernstein and David Adler (eds.) Understanding American Economic
Decline. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.
Observatorio de Salarios . 2018. “El sexenio del empleo precario y los bajos salarios” Análisis
de Coyuntura- Policy Brief No. 2 (15 de octubre): https://ibero.mx/prensa/durante-sexenio-de-
epn-no-se-valoro-empleados-con-posgrado-investigador
O'Connor, James . 1973. The Fiscal Crisis of the State. New York, NY: St. Martin’s Press.
OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development) . 2014. “Share of profit and
labour in value-added” in National Accounts at a Glance. Paris: OECD.
Olenin, Alice and Thomas Corcoran . 1942. Hours and Earnings in the United States, 1932–40.
Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Labor.
Olivares, Emir and Alonso Urrutia . 2022. “AMLO: este será el año con el mayor ingreso de
IED” La Jornada (26 de mayo): p. 19.
Ondetti, Gabriel . 2017. “The power of preferences: Economic elites and light taxation in
Mexico” Revista Mexicana de Ciencias Políticas y Sociales núm. 231 (septiembre-diciembre):
47–76.
Ortega Riquelme, Juan . 2006. “Acuerdos Tripartitas y Economía” Foro Internacional 46 (2):
227–262.
Otero, Walter . 2008. “GM pone el ejemplo en San Luis Potosí” Expansión. (28 de julio):
https://expansion.mx/negocios/2008/07/26/punta-de-lanza
Pakko, Michael . 2002. “The high-tech investment boom and economic growth in the 1990s”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review (March/April): 3–18.
Paelinck, Jean and Mario Polèse . 1999. “Modelling the regional impact of continental economic
integration: lessons from the European Union for NAFTA” Regional Studies 33 (8): 727–738.
Palma, José Gabriel . 1978. “Dependency: A formal theory of underdevelopment or a
methodology for the analysis of concrete situations of underdevelopment?” World Development
6 (7–8): 881–924.
Palma, José Gabriel . 2005. “The seven main ‘stylized facts’ of the Mexican economy since
trade liberalization and NAFTA” Industrial and Corporate Change 14 (6): 941–991.
PARC (Pacific Asian Resource Center) . 1977. Free Trade Zones & the Industrialization of Asia
(Special Issue), AMPO: Japan-Asia Quarterly Review, vols. 8(4) & 9(1–2). Tokyo, Japan:
PARC.
Parnreiter, Christof . 2018. Geografía económica: una introducción contemporánea. México:
UNAM, Facultad de Economía.
Pechlaner, Gabriela and Gerardo Otero . 2010. “The neoliberal food regime: Neoregulation and
the new division of labor in North America” Rural Sociology 75 (2): 179–208.
Peck, Jaime . 2010. Constructions of Neoliberal Reason. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Perdue, Doyle . 2019. National Sovereignty and the Mexicanization of the Compañía Minera de
Cananea, 1971 to 1989. Ph.D. dissertation, Florida International University:
https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/etd/4046
Pérez González, Gilberto (2021). Directrices de la reestructuración de la industria automotriz
mundial y sus implicaciones para México Norteamérica 16 (2): 35–55.
Pérez Aceves, Luis y Ignacio Echavarría Valenzuela . 1988. El Fomento a la Competitividad
Industrial Mexicana. México, DF: Nacional Financiera.
Pérez Caldentey, Esteban and Matias Vernengo (eds.). 2017. Why Latin American Nations Fail.
Oakland, CA: University of California Press.
Piketty, Thomas and Emmanuel Saez . 2001. “Income inequality in the United States,
1913–1998”, NBER Working Paper No. 8467. Washington, DC: National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Phelps, Christopher . 2010. “American idle”, The Nation 290 (5): 21–24.
Plehwe, Dieter . 2009. “The origins of neoliberal economic development discourse” pp. 238–279
in Phillip Mirowski and Dieter Plehwe (eds.) The Road From Mont Pèlerin. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Polanyi, Karl . 1944. The Great Transformation. New York, NY: Farrar & Reinhart.
Porter, Eduardo . 2016. “The jobs NAFTA saved” New York Times (March 30) p. B1.
Pozas, María de los Ángeles . 2002. Estrategia internacional de la gran empresa mexicana en
la década de los noventa. México, DF: El Colegio de México.
Pozas, María de los Ángeles . (compilador). 2006. Estructura y Dinámica de la Gran Empresa
en México. México, DF: El Colegio de México.
Price, Carter and Kathryn Edwards . 2020. Trends in Income, 1975–2018. Working Paper WR-
A516-1 (September). Santa Monica, CA: The RAND Corporation.
Pskowski, Martha . 2020. “Mexico’s fracking impasse” NACLA (October 27):
https://nacla.org/news/2020/10/22/mexico-fracking-impasse
Public Citizen . 2019. “NAFTA’s legacy: Lost jobs, lower wages, increased inequality” (October):
https://www.citizen.org/wp-content/uploads/NAFTA-Factsheet_Deficit-Jobs-Wages_Oct-
2019.pdf
Puga, Cristina . 2004. Los empresarios organizados y el Tratado de Libre Comercio de América
del Norte. México, DF: M. A. Porrúa.
Puyana, Alicia . 2010. The Impact of Trade Liberalization and the Global Economic Crisis on the
Productive Sectors, Employment and Incomes in Mexico. (Issue Paper No. 15) Geneva,
Switzerland: International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development.
Quintero, Cirila . 2019. Los claroscuros del movimiento laboral 20/32 de Matamoros.
http://www.colef.mx/opinion/los-claroscuros-del-movimiento-laboral-20-32-de-
matamoros/?e=correo-fronterizo
Quintero, Cirila . 2021. “El TMEC: derechos laborales y democracia syndical” Brujula
Ciudadana (133) (septiembre): https://www.revistabrujula.org/b-133-tmec-derechos-laborales-
democracia-sindical
Ramírez, Miguel . 1989. Mexico’s Economic Crisis. New York, NY: Praeger Publishers.
Ramos, Rolando . 2016. “EPN recibe Agenda 2030 del CEEG” El Economista (20 de
diciembre): https://www.eleconomista.com.mx/empresas/EPN-recibe-Agenda-2030-del-CEEG
Ramseur, Jonathan . 2022. Inflation Reduction Act Methane Emissions Charge. (August 29).
Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service.
Redacción . 2019a. “AMLO promete a EU aumentar cada año el salario mínimo por arriba de la
inflación para aprobar T-MEC” El Financiero (octubre 17):
https://www.elfinanciero.com.mx/economia/amlo-promete-a-eu-aumentar-salario-minimo-por-
arriba-de-la-inflacion-para-aprobar-t-mec/
Redacción . 2019b. “Refinería: los críticos ya olvidaron la historia petrolera” La Jornada (19 de
mayo): p. 17.
Raei, Faezeh , Anna Ignatenko and Borislava Mircheva . 2019. “Global value chains: What are
the benefits and why do countries participate?” International Monetary Fund:
http://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2019/01/18/Global-Value-Chains-What-are-the-
Benefits-and-Why-Do-Countries-Participate-46505
Redacción, El Economista . 2022. “Conflicto con Talos, independiente a las consultas de EU” El
Economista (27 de julio): https://www.eleconomista.com.mx/empresas/Conflicto-con-Talos-
independiente-a-las-consultas-de-EU-y-Canada-20220728-0018.html
Redacción RF Informa . 2022. “Entregan documentación sobre irregularidades en sindicato de
Pemex a la OIT en Suiza” Rodolfo Franco Informa (1 de abril):
https://rodolfofranco.com/2022/04/01/entregan-documentacion-sobre-irregularidades-en-
sindicato-de-pemex-a-la-oit-en-suiza/
Redacción Sin Embargo . 2022. “Candidata petrolera acusa a Deschamps y a Aldana en
Palacio: “¿Cómo se atreven?” Sin Embargo (24 de enero): https://www.sinembargo.mx/24-01-
2022/4109880
Reder, Melvin . 1988. “The rise and fall of unions” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2 (2):
89–110.
Rey Romay, Benito . 1984. La ofensiva empresarial contra la intervención del Estado. México:
Siglo XXI.
Réyes, José . 2022. “Empresarios retrasan legitimación de 544 mil contratos colectivos” Contra
Línea (30 de agosto): https://contralinea.com.mx/interno/semana/empresarios-retrasan-
legitimacion-de-544-mil-contratos-colectivos/
RMS . 2022. “Más allá de las fronteras: El T-MEC y la reforma laboral” RMS Sindicalista (30 de
Septiembre): https://rmsindicalistas.mx/2022/09/mas-alla-de-las-fronteras-el-t-mec-y-la-reforma-
laboral/
Robles, Ruth and Guillermo Foladori . 2019. “Una revisión histórica de la automatización de la
minería en México” Problemas Del Desarrollo 50 (197): 157–180.
Rogers, Katie . 2022. “Biden promotes US semiconductors” New York Times (October 7): p.
A17.
Romero Sotelo , Ma Eugenia . 2011. “Las raíces de la ortodoxia en México” Economíaunam 8
(24): 23–50.
Romm, Tony . 2021. “Corporate America launches massive lobbying blitz to kill key parts of
Democrats’ $3.5 trillion Economic Plan” Washington Post (August 31)
https://www.washingtonpost.com/us-policy/2021/08/31/businesslobbying-democrats-
reconciliation/
Romo, Daniel and Arturo Ortiz Ubilla . 2018 “Experiencias de un Centro de Investigación en un
país en Desarrollo: Caso del Instituto Mexicano del Petróleo” Economíaunam 15 (45) 152–163.
Romo, Yoanna . 2022. “Puerto Libertad será el centro de potencia energética con nueva planta”
El Sol de Hermosillo (8 de agosto): https://www.elsoldehermosillo.com.mx/local/puerto-libertad-
sera-el-centro-de-potencia-energetica
Rosenberg, Nathan . 1963. “Capital goods, technology, and economic growth ” Oxford
Economic Papers 15 (3): 217–227.
Rosenblum, Marc (coordinator). 2012. Mexican Migration to the United States. Washington, DC:
Congressional Research Service.
Ross Schneider, Ben . 2002. “Why is Mexican business so organized? ” Latin American
Research Review 37 (1): 77–118.
Ross Schneider, Ben . 2004. Business Politics and the State in Twentieth-Century Latin
America. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Rubio, Blanca . 2000. “Los campesinos latinoamericanos frente al nuevo milenio” Comercio
Exterior 50 (3): 265–273.
Rubio, Blanca . 2003. “¿Porque el campo mexicano no aguantó más? El dominio global de las
transnacionales y el movimiento campesino” Repositorio del IIS-UNAM:
http://ru.iis.sociales.unam.mx:8080/jspui/bitstream/IIS/24/1/Porque_el_campo_mexicano_no_ag
uanta_mas.pdf
Rubio, Blanca . 2006. “Voces de la desesperanza: La desestructuración alimentaria en México
(1994–2004)” Gaceta Laboral 12 (1): 71–92.
Rubio, Blanca and J. Moguel . 2018. “La agricultura mexicana en la encrucijada: un futuro
incierto” pp. 63–93 en Blanca Rubio (coordinadora) América Latina en la mirada: las
transformaciones rurales en la transición capitalista. México DF: UNAM.
Rubio Campos, Jesús . 2017. “Sindicalización y precariedad laboral en México” Región y
Sociedad 29 (Núm. 68): 37–75.
Ruiz Durán, Clemente . 2016. Desarrollo y estructura de la industria automotriz en México.
México, DF: Fundación Friedrich Ebert en México.
Sacristán, Roy Emilio 2006. “Las privatizaciones en México” Economíaunam 3 (9): 54–64.
Saez, Emmanuel . 2020. “Striking it richer” UC Berkeley: https://eml.berkeley.edu/~saez/saez-
UStopincomes-2018.pdf
Saez, Emmanuel and Gabriel Zucman . 2020. “The rise of income and wealth inequality in
America” Journal of Economic Perspectives 34 (4): 3–26.
Salas-Porras, Alejandra . 2019. “Los Arquitectos del Proyecto Neoliberal en México” pp.
143–167 en José Luis Calva (compilador) La Economía de México en el TLCAN. Chapingo,
México: Juan Pablos Editores.
Salas-Porras, Alejandra and Martí Medina-Hernández . 2021. “Transnationalization of the
Mexican corporate elite” Review of International Political Economy. DOI:
10.1080/09692290.2021.1961841
Saldierna, Georgina and Enrique Méndez . 2022. “Entregó el Estado 45 mil mdp a
trasnacionales para hacer ‘ciencia neoliberal’” La Jornada (5 de agosto): p. 16.
Salles, Sainz and Grant Thornton . 2021. “Perspectiva de la Inversión Extranjera Directa en
México” Boletín de economía 3 (Marzo): 2–11.
Sánchez, María Teresa and José Casado . 2018. “Transformaciones en la estructura
empresarial y productiva y en la organización territorial de la minería mexicana, 1980–2012” pp.
121–157 en María Teresa Sánchez y María Teresa Gutiérrez (eds.) Globalización, políticas
neoliberales y transformaciones México, DF: UNAM.
Sánchez, Miguel . 1998. “La minería mexicana de finales del siglo XX” Economía y Sociedad 3
(4): 55–70.
Sánchez Ugarte , Fernando, Manuel Fernández Pérez and Eduardo Pérez Motta . 1994. La
política industrial ante la apertura. México, DF: SECOFI.
Sánchez Valente, J. and Toledo Antonio, J. 2017. Instituto Mexicano del Petróleo. Mundo Nano.
Revista Interdisciplinaria En Nanociencias Y Nanotecnología 9 (17): 141–158.
Sandoval Ramírez, Luis . 2009. “La reforma energética y la inversión extranjera directa en el
petróleo mexicano” Dimensión Económica 1(O): 1–4
https://rde.iiec.unam.mx/revistas/cero/articulos/articulo3/articulo3cap31.html
Semo, Ilán . 1996. “The Mexico Political Pretransition” pp. 107–126 in Gerardo Otero (ed.)
Neoliberalism Revisited. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Scheiber, Noam . 2022. “Ford plans 6,000 new jobs in Midwest” The New York Times (June
3):B6.
Schroeder, Pete . 2019. “U.S. chief executives back revised USMCA trade deal” Reuters
(December 11): https://www.reuters.com/article/us-usa-ceos-trade/u-s-chief-executives-back-
revised-usmca-trade-deal
Schumpeter, Joseph . 1950. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy 3rd ed. New York, NY:
Harper & Row Publishers.
Scott, Robert E . 1996. “North American Trade After NAFTA: Rising Deficits, Disappearing
Jobs”. Economic Policy Institute, Briefing Paper. Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institute: pp.
1–19.
Scott, Robert E . 1999. “Nafta’s Pain Deepens: Job destruction accelerates in 1999” Economic
Policy Institute Briefing Paper. Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institute: 1–7.
Scott, Robert E . 2014. “The effects of NAFTA on US trade, jobs, and investment, 1993–2013”
Review of Keynesian Economics 2 (4): 414–428.
Scott, Robert and Zane Mokhiber . 2020. Growing China trade deficit cost 3.7 million American
jobs between 2001 and 2018. Economic Policy Institute Report. Washington, DC: Economic
Policy Institute: 1–85.
Selwyn, Benjamin and Dara Leyden . 2022. “Oligopoly-driven development: The World Bank’s
trading for development in the age of global value chains in perspective” Competition & Change
26 (2): 174–196.
Sepúlveda, Bernardo and Antonio Chumacero . 1973. La inversión extranjera en México.
México, DF: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Shaiken, Harley . 1990. Mexico in the Global Economy. San Diego, CA: Center for U.S.-
Mexican Studies.
Sheilds, John . 2001. “Mexican pipeline: The future of oil under Vicente Fox” NACLA 34 (4):
31–37.
Sidaoui, José , Manuel Ramos-Francia and Gabriel Cuadra . 2010. “The global crisis and policy
response in Mexico” BIS Paper no. 54 (December 24): 279–298.
Skonieczny, Amy . 2001. “Constructing NAFTA: Myth, representation, and the discursive
construction of U.S. foreign policy” International Studies Quarterly 45 (3): 433–454.
Slaper, Timothy . 2019. “Automation and offshoring in durable goods manufacturing” Economic
Development Quarterly 33 (1):19–38.
Smith, John . 2016. Imperialism in the Twenty-First Century. New York: Monthly Review.
Solis, Leopoldo . 1986. La Realidad Económica Mexicana. 15th ed. México: Siglo XXI.
Solís Rosales, R. 1990. Precios de garantía y política agraria” Revista Comercio Exterior 40
(10): 923–937.
Sosa Barajas, Sergio . 2005a. “La industria automotriz de México: de la sustitución de
importaciones a la promoción de exportaciones” Análisis Económico 20 (Segundo
cuatrimestre): 191–213.
Sosa, Barajas Sergio . 2005b. La sustitución de importaciones en el crecimiento económico de
México. México, DF: Editorial Tlaxcallan.
Stansbury, Anna and Larry Summers . 2020. “The Declining Labor Power Hypothesis”
Brookings Paper on Economic Activity (Spring): pp. 1–78.
Statista . 2022. “IED en la Minería en México”.
https://es.statista.com/estadisticas/1132084/inversion-extranjera-directa-mineria-mexico/
Stavenhagen, Rodolfo , Fernando Paz Sánchez , Cuauhtémoc Cárdenas y Arturo Bonilla .
1980. Neolatifundismo y explotación. De Emiliano Zapata a Anderson Clayton & Co . México,
DF: Editorial Nuestro Tiempo.
Sturgeon, Timothy , Johannes Van Biesebroeck and Gary Gereffi . 2008. “Value chains,
networks and clústers: reframing the global automotive industry” Journal of Economic
Geography 8 (3): 297–321.
Swanson, Ana . 2022a. “U.S. will challenge Mexico on energy policy” New York Times (July 21):
p. B4.
Swanson, Ana . 2022b. “50 billion to bolster chip makers” New York Times (September 6): pp.
B1, B4.
Swanson, Ana . 2022c. “U.S. Sees Mexico as manufacturing hub, but investors are wary” New
York Times (September 14): p. A6.
Swanson, Ana . 2022d. “US targeting China’s access to technology” New York Times (October
8): p. A1.
Swanson, Ana . 2022e. “Car supply chains are tied to labor abuses in Xinjiang” New York Times
(December 7): p. B1, B5.
Swiecki, Bernard and Debbie Menk . 2016. “The growing role of Mexico in the North American
automotive industry” Ann Arbor, MI, Center for Automotive Research.
http://www.cargroup.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/02/The-Growing-Role-of-Mexico-in-the-
North-American-Automotive-Industry-Trends-Drivers-and-Forecasts.pdf
Taglioni, Daria and Deborah Winkler . 2016. Making Global Value Chains Work for
Development. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Téllez, Isidro . 2022. “La subcontratación laboral en el Distrito Minero de Fresnillo” pp. 153–166
en Isidro Téllez y Aleida Azamar (eds.) La minería en México. México, DF: Secretaria de Medio
Ambiente.
Téllez, Isidro and María Sánchez Salazar . 2018. “La expansión territorial de la minería
mexicana durante el periodo 2000–2017” Investigaciones geográficas (96), 1–18.
Téllez, Isidro . 2021. “Concesiones mineras y acaparamiento del subsuelo” pp. 1–18 En P.
Wong González , J. Isaac Egurrola , E. Morales García y A. Treviño (eds.) La dimensión global
de las regiones y sus reconfiguraciones económicas y urbanas. México: D.F.: UNAM.
Téllez Ramírez, Isidro and Aleida Azamar . 2021. “La política de concesiones a los grupos
mineros de México” Problemas del desarrollo 52 (206): 35–59.
Tello, Carlos and Rolando Cordera .1981. La disputa por la nación. México, DF: Siglo XXI.
Teichman, Judith . 1995. Privatization and Political Change in Mexico. Pittsburg, PA: University
of Pittsburg.
Tetreault, Darcy . 2013. “La megaminería en México” Letras verdes, No. 14 (septiembre):
214–234.
Tetreault, Darcy . 2022. “Two sides of the same coin: increasing material extraction rates and
social environmental conflicts in Mexico” Environment, Development and Sustainability 24:
14163–14183.
Tevlin, Stacy and Karl Whelan . 2000. “Explaining the investment boom of the 1990s”, Finance
and Economics Discussion Series 2000–11. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
Thacker, Strom . 2000. “Private sector trade politics in Mexico” Business and Politics 2 (2):
161–187.
Thatcher, Margaret . 1994. “Speech in Mexico” (March 25):
https://www.margaretthatcher.org/document/108332
The Conference Board . 2016. “International comparison of hourly compensation costs in
manufacturing, 2016”: https://www.conference-board.org/ilcprogram/index.cfm?id=38269
The White House . 1993. “Remarks by the president to business roundtable” (June 9):
https://clintonwhitehouse6.archives.gov/1993/06/1993-06-09-presidents-remarks-to-business-
roundtable.html
The White House . 2022a. “FACT SHEET: Biden-Harris administration bringing semiconductor
manufacturing back” (January 21): https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-
releases/2022/01/21/fact-sheet-biden-harris-administration-bringing-ssemiconductor-
manufacturing-back
The White House . 2022b. “FACT SHEET: CHIPS and science act will lower costs, create jobs,
strengthen supply chains, and counter China” (August 9): https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-
room/statements-releases/2022/08/09/fact-sheet-chips-and-science-act-will-lower-costs-create-
jobs-strengthen-supply-chains-and-counter-china/
The White House . 2022c. “FACT SHEET: President Biden Signs Executive Order” (September
15): https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2022/09/15/fact-sheet-
president-biden-signs-executive-order-to-ensure-rob[ust-reviews
The White House . 2022d. “FACT SHEET: Biden-Harris administration driving U.S. battery
manufacturing” (October 19): https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-
releases/2022/10/19/fact-sheet-biden-harris-administration-driving-u-s-battery-manufacturing-
and-good-paying-jobs/
Tijerina, Walid . 2018. “Desarrollismo subnacional para el nuevo siglo ” Problemas del
desarrollo 49 (núm. 192): 169–192.
Tirado, Ricardo . 2006. “El poder en las cámaras industriales de México” Foro Internacional 46
(2): 197–226.
Tooze, Adam . 2018. Crashed. New York, NY: Viking.
Toribio Morales, María Adelina , César Adrián Ramírez y Miriam Aidé Núñez . 2019 “Expansión
del agronegocio aguacatero” Eutopía 16: 51–72.
Toscana Aparicio, Alejandra . 2021. “Población en situación de calle en la Ciudad de México
durante la pandemia por la COVID-19” Denarius, revista de economía y administración 40
(enero-junio): 153–174.
Toussaint, Eric . 2020. “La crisis de la deuda mexicana y el Banco Mundial” en 76 años de
intervenciones del Banco Mundial y del FMI (August 4): https://www.cadtm.org/La-crisis-de-la-
deuda-mexicana-y-el-Banco-Mundial
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistic . 2010a. Table A: Employer cost for
employee compensation. (USDL-10-1687, December 8): bls.gov.
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistic . 2010b. “Current labor statistics” Monthly
Labor Review 133 (7): bls.gov.
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistic . 2011. Economic news release: Table B-6,
employment of production and non-supervisory employees, (January 7): bls.gov.
U.S. International Trade Administration . 2022. “Mexico – country commercial guide – mining
and minerals”: https://www.trade.gov/country-commercial-guides/mexico-mining-and-minerals
Uchitelle, Louis . 2005. “Globalization: It’s not just wages” New York Times (June 17): C1, 4.
Urrutia, Alonso and Emir Olivares . 2022. “Tenemos mucho atractivo para la inversión
extranjera: AMLO” La Jornada (3 de junio): p. 19.
Valadez Rodríguez, Alfredo . 2022. “Miles de zacatecanos, expulsados por grupos criminales y
grandes empresas” La Jornada (28 de junio): p. 29.
Valdés Ugalde, Francisco . 1996. “The private sector and political regime change in Mexico” pp.
127–148 in Gerardo Otero (ed.) Neoliberalism Revisited. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Valencia, Ramón , Horacio Sánchez Bárcenas y David Robles Ortiz . 2019. “Soberanía
Alimentaria de granos básicos en México” Análisis económico 34 (87): 223–248.
Valdenebro, Alex . 2020. Mexican competitive advantage in NAFTA: A case of social dumping?
International Journal of Automotive Technology and Management 20 (3): 239–257.
Van den Bossche, Patrick . 2022. The tides are turning: 2021 Reshoring Index. Chicago, IL:
A.T. Kearny: https://www.kearney.com/operations-performance-transformation/us-reshoring-
index
Vega López, Eduardo . 2016. “Víctor L. Urquidi: insatisfacción ilustrada de un polémico
economista mexicano” Economíaunam 13 (núm. 38): 112–121.
Velasco Arregui, Edur . 1993. “Industrial restructuring in Mexico during the 1980s” pp. 163–176
in Ricardo Grinspun and Maxwell Cameron (eds.) The Political Economy of North American
Free Trade. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Viega, Josué . 2019. “La Cuarta Transformación viaja en tren” Observatorio Latinoamericano de
Geopolítica. México: IIEc, UNAM: pp. 11–52:
https://geopolitica.iiec.unam.mx/sites/geopolitica.iiec.unam.mx/files/2020-
03/Tren%20Maya.%20Avances%20de%20investigacio%CC%81n%202.pdf
Villanueva, Dora . 2021. “Intereses ya superan el costo de la deuda del antiguo Fobaproa” La
Jornada (20 de septiembre): p. 20.
Villanueva, Dora . 2022a. “Coneval: equivalen remesas a 70% de los ingresos salariales” La
Jornada (30 de mayo): p. 20.
Villanueva, Dora . 2022b. “En México, 9% en pobreza extrema; crece fortuna de 13 megaricos”
La Jornada (27 de enero): https://www.jornada.com.mx/notas/2022/01/27/economia/aumento-
11-riqueza-de-los-13-
Villanueva, Dora . 2022c. “El minisalario recuperó 65% de su poder adquisitivo” La Jornada (6
de septiembre): p. 20.
Villanueva, Dora . 2022d. “El PIB per cápita, 7.1% abajo de los niveles de antes de la
pandemia” La Jornada (28 de noviembre): p. 28.
Villanueva, Dora . 2022e. “Se recupera 11.2% el poder de compra de los ingresos laborales” La
Jornada (29 de noviembre): p. 20.
Villarreal, Héctor and Alejandra Macías . 2020. El sistema de pensiones en México. Serie
Macroeconomía del Desarrollo, N° 210. Santiago, Chile: Comisión Económica para América
Latina y el Caribe.
Villarreal, Angeles and Ian F. Fergusson . 2017. The North American Free Trade Agreement
(NAFTA). Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service.
Villareal, Angeles . 2020. U.S.-Mexico Economic Relations: Trends, Issues, and Implications.
(June 20). Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service.
Wade, Robert . 1990. Governing the Market. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Wade, Robert . 2010. “After the crisis: Industrial policy and the developmental state” Global
Policy 1 (2): 150–161.
Wasserman, Mark . 1979. “Foreign investment in Mexico, 1876–1910” The Americas 36 (1):
3–21.
Waxman, Olivia . 2018. “4 things to know about the history of NAFTA, as Trump takes another
step toward replacing it” Time (November 30): https://time.com/5468175/nafta-history/
Weisbrot, Mark , David Rosnick and Dean Baker . 2004. “Nafta at 10: The Recount” Center for
Economic Policy Research, Briefing Paper. Washington, DC: Center for Economic Policy
Research: pp. 1–12.
Werner, Marion . 2015. Global Displacements. Oxford, UK: John Wiley & Sons.
Wingrove, Josh and Akayla Gardner . 2023. “Biden Quietly Urges Mexico to Pounce on US Shift
From Asia Chips” Bloomberg (January 10): https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2023-01-
10/-three-amigos-agree-to-meeting-on-semiconductor-investment
Wionczek, Miguel . 1981. “Las experiencias de México en la industria farmacéutica
internacional” El Trimestre Económico 48 (4): 965–991.
World Bank 2022a. “IBRD loans and IDA credits (DOD, current US$) – Mexico”:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/DT.DOD.MWBG.CD?locations=MX
World Bank . 2022b. “Income Share Held by Lowest & Second %-Mexico”:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SI.DST.02ND.20?locations=MX;
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SI.DST.FRST.20?locations=MX
World Bank . 2022c. “GDP per capita growth (annual %) – Mexico”:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.KD.ZG?locations=MX
World Bank 2022d. “GDP growth (annual %) – Mexico”:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZG?locations=MX
World Bank 2022e. “GDP (constant 2015 US$) – Mexico”:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD?locations=MX
World Bank 2022f. “GDP per capita growth (annual %) – United States”:
https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.PCAP.KD.ZG?locations=US
Yergin, Daniel . 1990. The Prize. New York, NY: Simon & Schuster.
Yoon, Jang Seob . 2021. “Automotive industry in South Korea – statistics & facts” Statista (April
1): https://www.statista.com/topics/5249/automotive-industry-in-south-korea/#dossierKeyfigures
Zarate-Hoyos, Germán . 2005. “The development impact of migrant remittance in Mexico” pp.
159–191 en D. Terry and S. Wilson (eds.) Beyond Small Change: Making Migrant Remittances
Count. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
Zhou, Weihuan , Huiqin Jiang and Qingjiang Kong . 2020. “Technology transfer under China’s
foreign investment regime” Journal of World Trade 54 (3): 1–20.
Zysman, John and Laura Tyson (eds.) 1983. American Industry and International Competition.
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

You might also like