Rerouting Europe's Gas Transit Landscape - Effects of Russian Natural Gas

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

Energy Policy 146 (2020) 111748

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Policy
journal homepage: http://www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Rerouting Europe’s gas transit landscape - Effects of Russian natural gas


infrastructure strategy on the V4
Borbála Takácsné Tóth *, Péter Kotek , Adrienn Selei
REKK, Corvinus University of Budapest, Budapest Fővám Tér 8, 1093, Hungary

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: The Russian gas transit through Ukraine and the possibility of circumnavigating the historically dominant route
Geopolitics poses a serious challenge to European gas markets. With the application of market modelling tools, this paper
Gas market modelling examines Russian export strategies to Europe using different transit route combinations. Although the cessation
Gas transit
of Ukrainian transit would not endanger the security of gas supply in Europe, it would result in higher prices in
Welfare analysis
Russia
all scenarios. In scenarios that include Nord Stream 2 and TurkStream 2, Ukrainian transit is non-essential for
V4 Russia to maintain its current share of EU gas imports. At the same time, the results show that limiting Ukrainian
transit is less profitable for Russia: even if all the planned infrastructure is completed, shutting this route would
result in losses of close to 5 billion € per year in Russian gas sales. Since it appears inevitable that Nord Stream 2
and TurkStream 2 will be built, a no transit scenario is a real possibility thereafter. In this case the V4 should
lobby for Balkan Stream, with investment costs borne by Gazprom. However, if there are continued deliveries via
Ukraine there is no need for Balkan Stream.

1. Introduction by the original deadline of January 2020 (Pirani et al., 2020).


Russian state-owned gas company Gazprom has invested into gas
The geopolitical nature of the gas markets in Europe are epitomized pipelines to reduce the transit risk it attributes to Ukraine while the EU
by the story of the Russian-Ukrainian gas relations and by extension the has installed a dedicated mechanism to identify and finance gas infra­
debate over investment in large gas trunk lines and smaller structure investments serving EU market integration and thereby
interconnectors. increasing competition and security of supply. Owing to stagnant Eu­
The previous gas transit contract between Russia and Ukraine was ropean gas demand much of the new-build infrastructure is substantially
concluded in 2009 putting an end to the largest gas disruption to date of underutilized, but it has served to smooth wholesale gas market prices
European natural gas supplies. That contract expired at the end of 2019. across a well-functioning internal EU gas market (ACER, 2018).
Although the Ukrainian transit route delivered nearly half of the Russian Geopolitics and changes in government have shaped Ukraine gas
gas exports in 2019, an agreement for future gas deliveries from January transit developments over the years from disputes on price and transit
2020 until 2024 was only reached at the eleventh hour, when political volumes to the ownership of the network, contractual terms and package
agreement paved the way for business considerations. The agreement deals. After 2006 geopolitics left business considerations little room for
was made for 65 bcm/year transit in 2020 and of 40 bcm/year between easy compromises. The annexation of Crimea in 2014 was a breaking
2021 and 2024 via the Ukrainian system (Pirani and Sharples, 2020). point bringing about the deepest crisis in EU–Russia relations since the
The deal was facilitated on the highest level by Russian, Ukrainian and end of the Cold War. (Bros et al., 2017; Siddi, 2018).
European Union politicians, and has reduced the largest supply security European institution’s response to this geopolitical challenge resul­
risk shadowing the EU gas markets, and provided Gazprom with time to ted in the Amendment of the Gas Directive1 agreed on in February 2019:
finish the ongoing large investment projects that could not be finished stating that unbundling rules must be applicable to offshore pipelines

* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: borbala.toth@rekk.hu (B.T. Tóth), peter.kotek@rekk.hu (P. Kotek), adrienn.selei@rekk.hu (A. Selei).
1
Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2009/73/EC concerning common rules for the internal market in natural gas was
agreed on 12 February 2019 in the Coreper and adopted by the Council 5 April 2019. https://data.consilium.europa.eu/doc/document/PE-58-2019-INIT/en/pdf.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2020.111748
Received 3 June 2019; Received in revised form 3 July 2020; Accepted 6 July 2020
Available online 17 August 2020
0301-4215/© 2020 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
B.T. Tóth et al. Energy Policy 146 (2020) 111748

Turkish, Bulgarian, Greek and North Macedonian contracts to the


Southern route. The rerouting of further contracts from the Ukrainian
route is set to continue with Gazprom planning to double the capacity of
Nord Stream and putting TurkStream 2 in operation (additional 55 bcm/
year and 15.75 bcm/year respectively) and build the connecting infra­
structure through Bulgaria, Serbia and Hungary to Baumgarten in
Austria (Balkan Stream), a project that is a sort of reboot of South
Stream.5
The transit contract between Russia and Ukraine over the last ten
years has not proven to be a stable framework for business relations,
with disagreements leading to the largest claims on record for a transit
agreement before the Stockholm Court of Arbitration lasting four years.
Gazprom won USD 2 billion in the first arbitration ruling on Russian gas
Fig. 1. Main gas transport routes into the EU and Turkey. supplies to Ukraine in December 2017 over gas that was delivered but
Source: Authors based on IEA database on European gas flows. Gas measured at not paid for by account of price disagreement. In February 2018, the
standard cubic meters. next case ruled that Gazprom should pay Naftogaz USD 4.56 billion in
damages for not transmitting the agreed amount of natural gas to Europe
such as Nord Stream 22 (Yafimava, 2019). It should come as no surprise, under the 2009 transit deal. This means that Naftogaz is owed a net USD
however, that Gazprom cried foul for discrimination against Nord 2.56 billion by Gazprom, a celebrated victory for Naftogaz, but still
Stream 2 as the only pipeline under construction being affected by the debated by Gazprom (Eyl-Mazzega, 2018; Pirani, 2018a).
Amendment of the Gas Directive. (Talus and Hancher, 2019), As a In the days following the ruling the agreed renewal of direct de­
consequence of TEN-E policies (Regulation 347/2013, 2013)3 regional liveries of gas from Russia to Ukraine that was supposed to start March 1,
governance structures to increase cooperation and solve coordination 2018 was cancelled which, together with cold weather, high demand
problems have been set up, the Connecting Europe Facility provided and an unexpected fall out of part of Norwegian supply, led to the largest
financial grants and facilitated energy project implementation. The ever price spike on European spot markets. Still, the European gas
actorness and impact of the EU with relation to natural gas infrastruc­ network and the internal market has proved to be resilient, and con­
ture and energy policy has been increased mainly because of the EC’s sumers could be supplied without major interruptions (Kotek et al.,
role as a regulator, gatekeeper and enforcer of the internal energy 2018).
market according to the analysis of Prontera and Plenta (2020). The new transit contract between Russian and Ukraine has brought
Meanwhile, adversely affected EU member states have little influ­ some important new compromises and positive developments: the
ence on the outcome of Russia’s diversification strategy. Debate and dispute over the previous contract has been set aside, and the ruling of
lobbying on Nord Stream 2 has been the loudest and most polarizing, but the Stockholm arbitration court was finally obeyed (Pirani and Sharples,
the Southern route4 has also shown discontent among member states 2020). The unbundling of the Ukrainian transmission system, with a
(Pirani and Yafimava, 2016.; Goldthau, 2016; Goldthau and Sitter, new transmission system operator (GTSOU) in place and Naftogaz being
2014; Kotek et al., 2016; Hecking and Weiser, 2017; Eser et al., 2019; the shipper has opened the way to further long awaited domestic market
Lochner and Bothe, 2007). reform, the development of a gas exchange, ending cross-subsidisation
At the moment, Nord Stream 2 is projected to be realised in several and chain of depts contributing to cleaning the corruption as well
stages by 2021–2022, allowing for the alternative route and possible (Pirani et al., 2020). The agreement has given precious time to all parties
reduction in Ukrainian transit flows (Pirani, 2018a, 2018b; Pirani and to rethink their strategies and hopefully to rebuild trust. The questions
Yafimava, 2016; Pirani et al., 2020). on the future of Ukrainian gas transit has been however not solved, only
Fig. 1 illustrates growing Russian sales amidst a successful diversi­ postponed.
fication strategy. Russian natural gas imports (about 150–200 billion This article provides a modelling-based analysis to examine the
cubic meter per year) constitute 35% of the EU28 plus Turkey gas economic rationale behind Russian export strategies to Europe under
consumption, showing substantial increase from 2015 to 2018. In the different transit route combinations. Ultimately it is for the seller to
1990s the Ukrainian system carried 140 bcm of gas which by 2019 is determine its optimal marketing strategy and transport route, and once
down to about 80 bcm after recovering from the historical low of 58 bcm alternative routes bypassing its transit are in place, Ukraine cannot force
in 2014. Gazprom to use its network. While examining the benefits and costs of
Since 2013, Ukrainian transit represents less than 50% of Russia’s certain marketing strategies for Russia, the role and exposure of the so
total natural gas export to Europe and Turkey. The decline continued called Visegrad 4 (V4) countries6 in the larger geopolitical game is given
from January 1, 2020 with TurkStream 1 (15.75 bcm/year capacity) special attention. With a common history of high Russian gas depen­
starting to deliver gas from Russia directly to Turkey, and rerouting all dence, the V4 welfare position will change with the rerouting of tradi­
tional gas supply in anticipation of reduced transit through Ukraine.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 pro­
vides the literature review, in Section 3 the modelling methodology and
2
Nord Stream 2 is the second string of the offshore Nord Stream pipeline main assumptions are introduced, Section 4 provides the modelling re­
connecting Russia directly with Germany. At the time of the writing of the sults, followed by a discussion and policy conclusions in Section 5.
article Nord Stream 2 is under construction. The capacity of the pipeline will be
55 bcm/year. The first string of Nord Stream operates already with 55 bcm/yr
capacity.
3
Regulation (EU) No 347/2013 of the European Parliament and of the
Council of 17 April 2013 on guidelines for trans-European energy infrastructure
and repealing Decision No 1364/2006/EC and amending Regulations (EC) No
5
713/2009, (EC) No 714/2009 and (EC) No 715/2009 Text with EEA relevance The South Stream project originally planned to connect Russia to Bulgaria
http://data.europa.eu/eli/reg/2013/347/oj. via an offshore pipeline and then run onshore through Bulgaria, Serbia and
4
The Southern corridor would deliver Russian gas via the Black Sea by the Hungary to Austria, was cancelled in December 2014 by Gazprom in favour of
TurkStream pipelines (two strings 15.75 bcm/yr each) and then further to TurkStream.
6
Bulgaria, Serbia, Hungary and to Baumgarten. The Czechia, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia.

2
B.T. Tóth et al. Energy Policy 146 (2020) 111748

2. Literature review incorporating the effects of Russian sales and marketing strategies with
the different infrastructure scenarios. The outputs follow a similar
The future of Ukrainian gas transit, the Russian diversification structure to these other authors – Russian profits from European gas
strategy and the potential impact of possible new infrastructures were sales and the welfare change across European markets is examined – but
extensively analysed using market modelling tools in the following with a special emphasis on the V4 countries.
studies.
Mitrova et al. (2016) examine several gas import scenarios, including 3. Methodology and main assumptions
disruption of Ukrainian transit, concluding that the European gas mix is
fairly robust and will maintain a significant share of natural gas from Using market modelling as a primary analytical tool this paper ex­
Russia in all scenarios, noting that the cessation of Ukrainian transit amines the effect of the possible Russian sales strategies under the
would increase the wholesale gas prices in those countries currently assumption of new transit pipelines and ensuing changes to delivery
supplied through Ukraine. Paltsev (2014) analysed Russian gas exports routes. The welfare effect in the V4 and EU28 along with profit change
to Europe using a general equilibrium model with the assumption that for Gazprom will be quantified in the different scenarios.
Nord Stream 2, South Stream and TurkStream are built, concluding that The analysis is carried out using the European Gas Market Model
Russian gas reaches relevant destinations even if the Ukrainian system is (EGMM),8 which is a competitive, dynamic, multi-market partial equi­
not used. Vatansever (2017) also argues that the Ukrainian route is not librium model that simulates the operation of the wholesale natural gas
necessary to serve Europe if Nord Stream 2 and TurkStream are con­ market across the whole of Europe. It includes a supply-demand repre­
structed. Analysing different infrastructure scenarios, he found that sentation of EU28 countries, the Contracting Parties of the Energy
Europe would suffer a significant price spike if Russian deliveries Community and Turkey, including gas storage and transportation link­
circumnavigate Ukraine. However, he also states that even with new ages. Large external markets, including Russia, Norway, Libya, Algeria,
infrastructure Gazprom can increase its revenues by maintaining the Azerbaijan, Iran and LNG exporters are represented exogenously with
Ukrainian route. Henderson and Sharples (2018) argue that Europe’s market prices, long-term supply contracts and physical connections to
growing need for gas imports due to decreasing inland production Europe.
cannot be satisfied without the Ukrainian system even if Nord Stream 2 The timeframe of the model covers 12 consecutive months and
and TurkStream are built. market participants have perfect information over this period. Dynamic
Hecking and Weiser (2017) analysed the capacity extension effect of connections between months are introduced by the operation of gas
the Nord Stream pipeline and found a significant increase in aggregate storages and take-or-pay constraints (minimum and maximum de­
EU28 consumer welfare, between €13 and €35 billion/year in the 2025 liveries are calculated over the entire 12-month period, enabling
scenario depending on LNG supply. Abrell, Chavaz, and Weigt (2016) contractual flexibility).
conclude that Nord Stream 2 would lower European gas prices by The modelling results reveal the market clearing prices, along with
around 6%, yielding around 1% growth in social welfare. These studies the production, consumption and trading quantities, storage utilization
assume that the Ukrainian system is not used for gas transit. decisions and long-term contract deliveries. Based on these outputs the
Our previous study (Kotek2016) analysed the effect of Nord Stream 2 model also calculates the components of social welfare: consumer sur­
on the European welfare and wholesale gas prices. Contrary to Hecking plus, producer surplus, profit of traders and infrastructure operators
and Weiser (2017) and Abrell et al. (2016), we assume that although (transmission system, LNG and storage operators) including operational
some long-term contracts are rerouted from Ukraine to Nord Stream 2, profits and congestion rents.
Russia continues to use the Ukrainian system for delivering LTCs7 to The literature spanning equilibrium models for European natural gas
Southern-Eastern Europe and selling spot gas. The results show that the markets is extensive. Prominent modelling tools are, for example,
modification of LTC routes can cause West-East congestion, marginally GASTALE (Boots et al., 2004; Egging and Gabriel, 2006), NATGAS
lowering prices in Western Europe while exerting more significant up­ (Zwart, 2009; Mulder and Zwart, 2006), TIGER (Lochner, 2011; Die­
ward price pressure in CEE (1–1.5 €/MWh). In our view, the results are ckhöner et al., 2013; Lochner and Bothe, 2007), GASMOD (Holz et al.,
mostly dependent on the assumption of future European gas demand: 2008), World Gas Model (Egging et al., 2010; Egging R., Gabriel, Holz
falling demand alleviates some of the congestion causing the West-East and Zhuang, 2008), Global Gas Model (Holz et al., 2013; Richter and
price spread. Stagnate or rising gas demand without Ukrainian transit Holz, 2015), GaMMES (Abada et al., 2013), and the EPRG-Gas Market
would result in greater price divergence between East and West even if Model (Chyong and Hobbs, 2014). Smeers (2008) provides an in-depth
Nord Stream 2 is built. analysis of the models prior to 2008.
Eser et al. (2019) simulate the impact of Nord Stream 2 and increased The EGMM differs from these in several ways. The most important
LNG flows to Europe in 2030 using gas market modelling. Their simu­ advantage it carries, particularly useful in this instance, is a detailed
lations show that cutting off Ukraine completely is a detrimental strat­ representation of long-term take-or-pay contracts and market con­
egy for Russia, as only 40% of Ukrainian transit can be re-routed via straints caused by delivery routes. Another advantage of our modelling
Nord Stream 2 in a short timeframe. Their results also suggest that approach is that the prices of Russian spot deliveries are set in a profit-
building Nord Stream 2 would cause serious loss of transit revenues for maximizing manner. These characteristics make our methodological
Ukraine and Poland. approach and results unique, as they are essential to analyse the sales
We found that previous literature has covered different infrastruc­ strategies (discussed in depth below) and the effect of changes to de­
ture scenarios extensively while largely neglecting the impact of livery routes due to new infrastructure.
possible Russian gas marketing strategies: how Russia might use the The scenario assessment is executed for the year 2025 when key
available infrastructure capacities for long term or flexible spot de­ pieces of infrastructure (Nord Stream 2 and TurkStream 1–2) will most
liveries and how the Russian gas can be priced to maximize the Russian probably be in place. Furthermore, by 2025 the domestic production in
profits. It follows that this paper aims to contribute to the discourse by Europe will have fallen dramatically setting a new normal for import

7
In this article the LTC abbreviation is used for the Russian long-term gas 8
A detailed mathematical description of the model can be found in (Kiss
supply contracts with the European buyers. These contracts are characterized
et al., 2016).
by a yearly contract quantity a price and a route with a given delivery point. To
allow for volume flexibility in the modelling scenarios LTCs do not include a
take-or-pay clause.

3
B.T. Tóth et al. Energy Policy 146 (2020) 111748

Table 1 transited through Ukraine independently from the possible


Modelled scenarios. alternatives.
TS1 TS1 and NS2 TS1, TS2 and NS2 • Scenarios in which transit through Ukraine is avoided, all the above
contacts are rerouted to alternative delivery points.
No transit (0) (1) TS1_0 (4) TS1_NS2_0 (7) TS1_TS2_NS2_0
Only long-term (2) TS1_LTC (5) TS1_NS2_LTC (8) TS1_TS2_NS2_LTC o If only TurkStream 1 is commissioned, all the above contracts are
contracted gas rerouted to this Southern route from Turkey, meaning only 36% of
(LTC) the contracts volume can be delivered due to capacity constraints.
LTC + spot (spot) (3) TS1_LTC (6) TS1_NS2_LTC (9) TS1_TS2_NS2_LTC (Scenario 1)
+ spot + spot + spot
o If Nord Stream 2 is also commissioned some contracts are rerouted
Source: REKK EGMM modelling. here: Hungary, Serbia, Bosnia and Croatia get the Russian gas via
Nord Stream 2. Remaining contracts arrive through Turkey. This
demand. comes close to meeting the entire contracted volumes. (Scenario 4)
All scenarios use the PRIMES reference scenario demand and pro­ o If TurkStream 2 is also commissioned, Hungarian, Serbian, Bos­
duction data.9 The infrastructure assumptions include existing inter­ nian and Croatian contracts are assumed to be delivered here,
connectors, storages and LNG terminals plus those projects that have keeping Nord Stream 2 capacities open for additional spot de­
already reached FID.10 The base case defines nine scenarios in two liveries. It is possible that some contracted quantities cannot be
dimensions. delivered. (Scenario 7)
The first dimension is the future of Russian gas international o In order to be freed from infrastructure constraints, an additional
pipelines:11 Scenario (7a) assumes all pieces of cross-border infrastructure are
built to allow contracted quantities to be delivered through
• TurkStream 1 materializes (TS1) Turkey13 (we refer to this additional infrastructure as Balkan
• TurkStream 1 and Nord Stream 2 materialize (TS1_NS2) Stream in this article).
• TurkStream 1–2 and Nord Stream 2 materialize (TS1_TS2_NS2)
In some scenarios Russia sells spot gas through Ukraine in addition to
The second dimension is the gas sales strategy of Russia through LTCs in a fashion that maximizes Gazprom’s profit. The prices of long-
Ukraine: term contracts are identical in all analysed scenarios and the spot gas
can reach German and Austrian markets by three routes: (i) via Nord
• No transit through Ukraine. The Russian long-term contracts Stream 2, (ii) via Yamal pipeline through Belarus and Poland and (iii)
currently delivered through Ukraine are rerouted (detailed below). via Brotherhood pipeline through Ukraine, Slovakia and Czechia. In the
(0) model, spot prices are exogenous and determined at the Russian border,
• Only long-term contracts are delivered through Ukraine. (LTC) allowing actual prices to differ from market to market according to cost
• Gazprom continues to use the Ukrainian system not only for deliv­ of transportation.
ering long-term contracted gas but also for short-term (spot) trading.
In these scenarios Russian spot gas is sold to German and Austrian 4. Modelling results
markets, however Gazprom does not sell gas directly to Ukraine.
(LTC + spot) 4.1. The effects of different marketing strategies

Combining the two dimensions results in nine scenarios numbered In this subsection the effects of the different Russian marketing
accordingly (see Table 1): strategies (detailed above) are examined. Scenario 3 (TS1_LTC + spot)
Beyond the abovementioned infrastructure assumptions and sales has been chosen as a reference point, whereby Russia uses the Ukrainian
strategies, the scenarios differ according to the routes and delivery system for delivering both long-term contracts and spot sales, which is
points of long-term contacts and price of spot gas sold by Russia. reflective of the market and the infrastructure situation from January
The routes of long-term contracts are determined as follows (for 2020.14
more details see the Annex): Social welfare will be measured for the V4, the EU28, Ukraine, and
Russia.15 First, changes in wholesale gas prices for the V4 and TTF are
• Scenarios in which Russia delivers long-term contracts through illustrated in Fig. 2.
Ukraine, long-term contracted gas to Hungary,12 Serbia, Bosnia, It should also be noted that the price spread within the V4 increases
Croatia, Romania, Moldova, Bulgaria, Greece and Macedonia are when there is no Ukrainian transit or only LTC volumes. Hungary is
always the most expensive market, far more vulnerable to the Russian
sales strategy than the other V4 countries and has the least to benefit
9 from the additional infrastructure.
PRIMES reference case (Capros, 2016) is not a forecast rather a prolonga­
tion of 2016 energy market trends to the 2050 time horizon. The scenario as­
The highest prices in all V4 countries occur when Russia does not
sumes that 2020 climate goals are met, and climate policies enacted until 2014 deliver gas through Ukraine under all infrastructure conditions (Sce­
December are in place. On the simulated time horizon natural gas keeps its narios 1, 4 and 7). Compared to these scenarios, prices are slightly lower
place in the primary energy mix, and the European gas consumption does not when only LTCs (~10 bcm transit) are delivered through Ukraine (in
change compared to the 2015 level. The reference scenario is considered a
conservative approach.
10
IT-CH, BG-RS (IBS), CH-FR, CH-DE, TR-GR (TAP), GR-IT (TAP), GE-TR
13
(TANAP), GR-BG (IGB), SI-HR, HR-SI, IT-AT, AT-DE, DE-AT, GR-AL (TAP), Gas deliveries to Turkey, Bulgaria, Greece, North Macedonia via the Turk­
RO-HU (BRUA), FI-EE (Balticconnector), PL-LT (GIPL), LT-PL (GIPL), EE-LT2, Stream 1 pipeline began on 1 January 2020.
14
LT-EE2, DK-SE2, AZ-GE, PL-SK, SK-PL, RO-BG, BG-GR, TR-BG, RO-MD, RS- Social welfare contains the following elements: consumer surplus, producer
HU (Southern Corridor) LNG terminal expansions in Poland, Greece and Spain. surplus, operational profit for infrastructure operators (TSO, LNG and storage
11
40% of the Hungarian contract is delivered to Hungary through Austria, operator), congestion rent for TSOs and infrastructure operators, profit of
which is unchanged in all scenarios. Assumptions detailed in main text concern traders.
15
the remaining 60%. The cost of gas exploitation and transportation is taken into consideration,
12
Missing infrastructure on the Bulgaria-Romania-Hungary and on the with new infrastructure investment costs accounted for in the capacity and
Bulgaria-Serbia-Hungary routes. volume fees applied on the entry and exit points.

4
B.T. Tóth et al. Energy Policy 146 (2020) 111748

Table 2
Welfare change of no Ukraine transit scenarios compared to Scenario 3 (mEUR).
TS1 TS1 and TS1, NS2 and TS2
NS2

M€/year (1) No (4) No (7) No (7a) No transit + Balkan


transit transit transit Stream
EU − 3747 − 339 897 1170
welfare
UA − 1718 − 1662 − 1674 − 1671
welfare
V4 − 1253 − 315 − 476 − 250
welfare

welfare of EU28 increases with TurkStream 2 if Nord Stream 2 is built


since some LTCs are rerouted to the southern route freeing capacity on
Nord Stream 2 to sell additional spot gas to West European customers at
favourable prices. However, this situation results in lower social welfare
for V4 countries (e.g. Scenario 7 is €161 million less than Scenario 4)
because missing southern infrastructure precludes delivery of a signifi­
Fig. 2. Price effects of the modelled scenarios, €/MWh. cant amount of LTCs. The supply for Central and Eastern Europe and for
Source: REKK EGMM modelling. the Balkans must be secured with additional spot purchases from the
north. If Balkan Stream is assumed to be built (Scenario 7a), V4 total
Scenarios 2, 5 and 8). When Russia delivers LTC and spot volumes welfare increases by yearly €226 million (compared to Scenario 7) at the
through Ukraine, significant price reductions can be observed (around 2 most, which is still significantly lower (by €250 million€) than the
€/MWh in V4 on average) (Scenarios 3, 6, 9). Generally, more infra­ welfare accrued in Scenario 3 when no additional infrastructure is added
structure results in lower prices. and Russia sells LTC and spot gas through Ukraine (see Fig. 3). It should
Shifting to the social welfare outcomes showed in Fig. 3, the worst- be noted that welfare change calculations did implicitly consider the
case outcome for all parties occurs when Gazprom does not deliver investment cost of new infrastructure through the applied tariffs on
gas through Ukraine - in all infrastructure scenarios. The highest social interconnection points.
welfare for the V4, EU28 and Ukraine occurs when Russia sells spot
volumes alongside LTCs through Ukraine. It is not only a more favour­ 4.2. Position change of V4 countries in the uncertain future
able strategy for gas purchasing parties, but – as it will be shown later –
also more profitable for Russia. This holds even if all the planned This subsection lays out the results for individual V4 countries.
infrastructure is commissioned (Scenario 9). From Fig. 4 it is evident that total Polish welfare is not impacted by
Fig. 3 also shows that the same sales strategy with Nord Stream 2 any scenario, meaning that the Polish position on pipeline policies is
increases social welfare both in the V4 and EU28, €491 million rather (geo)political. The Czechia is similarly immune to any potential
(comparing Scenarios 6 and 3) for the former, which is around 2.5 changes in gas flows and pipeline politics. Hungary and Slovakia are the
percent of the total V4 welfare. TurkStream 2 only leads to a significant most affected. Hungarian price (reflected in consumer welfare), is the
welfare effect if Russia ceases Ukrainian transit. most sensitive to Russian manoeuvres while in Slovakia the large swings
In line with our expectations, Ukraine can realize the highest social in total welfare are mostly explained by the loss of transit revenues
welfare in Scenario 3, when Russia sells both long-term contracted and Fig. 5. The only V4 TSO profiting from additional infrastructure is in
spot gas through Ukraine and neither Nord Stream 2 nor TurkStream 2 is Czechia.
built. The launch of Nord Stream 2 significantly reduces spot sales of
Russian gas via Ukraine (by 281 TWh/year) and associated transit rev­ 4.3. Position of Russia in the different scenarios
enue for the Ukrainian TSO. However, the new infrastructure increases
the welfare of Ukrainian consumers since the surplus of gas sources in This section examines the effect of different scenarios on Russian
the region results in lower prices (see Table 2). profit. Russian profit in this article is Gazprom’s profit on piped gas sales
Considering the no transit Scenarios (1, 4, 7, 7a), the total social to the EU, quantified as the difference between the revenues from long-
term contracted and spot gas sales on the different European markets

Fig. 3. Welfare results of modelled scenarios, million €/year. Fig. 4. Scenario effects on the total welfare in V4 countries, M€/year.
Source: REKK EGMM modelling. Source: REKK EGMM modelling.

5
B.T. Tóth et al. Energy Policy 146 (2020) 111748

volumes are sold, mostly because larger volumes can be sold only at
lower prices. Additionally, the cost of building an alternative interna­
tional pipeline system (through the tariffs) is borne by Russia.
Furthermore, Russian profit would be significantly lower in the no
transit scenarios with both TurkStream and Balkan Stream (Scenario 7a)
than under the current sales strategy using Ukraine for both long-term
contracted and spot gas with the existing infrastructure (Scenario 3).
In this sense, it is not in the economic interest of Russia or the profit
maximization strategy of Gazprom to stop Ukrainian transit. However, if
Russia follows its geopolitical interest and insists on avoiding Ukraine, it
would result in at least 15% profit loss. Among the no transit scenarios,
the highest profit can be reached in Scenario 7a; hence we expect Gaz­
prom to actively take part in open season auctions across the region. This
is further supported by modelling results that show: given TurkStream 1
and Nord Stream 2, TurkStream 2 is rational for Russia only if the
Fig. 5. Scenario effects on the operational profit of TSOs, M€/year. requisite capacities comprising the Balkan Stream are guaranteed to be
Source: REKK EGMM modelling. built (Scenario 7a).
If Russia could not have made an arrangement with Ukraine for
and variable costs of Gazprom.16 2020, Gazprom would have lost €9208 million profit assuming current
Under the assumption that Gazprom seeks to maximize profit and infrastructure (difference between Scenario 3 and Scenario 1). Addi­
market share, any threat to cut Ukrainian transit is not credible without tionally, Russia also loses significant profit (yearly €4844 million)
Nord Stream 2. Drawing from Fig. 6, in all infrastructure scenarios, LTC compared to the current situation if all the additional infrastructure
transit through Ukraine (rhombus) marginally increases Russian profit (including Balkan Stream) is completed to bypass Ukraine (Scenario 7a
by 1–3% compared to zero transit (triangles) because it frees capacities compared to Scenario 3).
on the Nord Stream route to sell additional spot volumes. However, this The last 2 rows in Table 3 illustrate that if Nord Stream 2 is
profit (rhombus) is still significantly lower than what Gazprom could commissioned, Ukrainian transit is unnecessary for maintaining Russia’s
achieve by selling LTC and spot gas through Ukraine (dots). Russia re­ current share of EU28 imports (~40%). And even though TurkStream 2
alizes the lowest profit levels in the no transit scenarios. could further increase its market share, Gazprom’s profits do not in­
Fig. 6 also illustrates that Russia can only marginally increase its crease despite the higher quantity sold.
profit with the additional infrastructure, even if significantly higher Across all of the different sales strategies it can be said that the use of
Ukraine’s transit system is profitable for Russia. If Gazprom uses
Ukrainian transit for spot sales it can increase sales by nearly 30% and
profit by 25%, even with Northern and Southern alternative routes in
place compared to the no transit scenarios with the same infrastructure
assumptions.

5. Conclusions and policy implications

The results leave no doubt that without Nord Stream 2 the threat of
ceasing Ukrainian transit is not credible and, following the conclusions
of Paltsev (2014), using the Ukrainian system for gas transit to Europe
and not investing into alternative routes is the highest profit option for
Russia. However, since the main goal of Russia’s strategy is route
diversification and bypassing the Ukrainian gas system, the no transit
option has to be analysed as well.
Similar to the results of Mitrova et al. (2016) we found that if every
proposed alternative Russian pipeline (Nord Stream 2 and TurkStream
2) is constructed, Ukrainian transit is not necessary to maintain Russia’s
current share (close to 40%) of European gas consumption. Still,
avoiding Ukrainian transit is a loss-making choice for Gazprom, costing
it €5 billion/year profit and a 50% market share.
The modelling results support our previous work (Kotek2016;
Takácsné Tóth, Kotek and Kaderják, 2017) and others (Mitrova et al.,
2016; Vatansever, 2017) that cessation of Ukrainian transit would result
Fig. 6. Change in Russian sales and Russian profits compared to Sc3, %.
in tighter supply and increased wholesale gas prices in Central and
Source: REKK EGMM modelling. Eastern Europe. This could be compensated partly but not entirely if all
infrastructure elements of the alternative Russian pipeline projects are
completed. For Slovakia, Hungary and to a lesser extent the Czechia, the
loss of Ukrainian transit cannot be compensated in welfare terms even if
all additional Russian projects (Nord Stream 2 and TurkStream 2 plus
16 Balkan Stream) are financed by Gazprom through capacity bookings.
Modelled Russian revenue from gas sales into Europe is €26,000-€42,000
million with profit €18,000-€27 000 million in the different scenarios. For These findings are supported by recent developments, when for the first
comparison, according to its annual report revenues of Gazprom from European time the Russian diversification strategy will materialize in project
gas sales was around €27,800–28,800 million in 2016–2017. Our modelled development in a V4 country. After lengthy negotiations on high polit­
prices for 2025 are significantly higher than those of 2016–2017, leading to the ical level on the renewal of the Hungarian long-term gas supply contract
higher revenues calculated for 2025. with Russia, a package deal was accomplished: in June 2020 the

6
B.T. Tóth et al. Energy Policy 146 (2020) 111748

Table 3
Change of Russian profit and exported quantity in the modelled scenarios.
TS1 TS1 and NS2 TS1, TS2 and NS2

(1) No (2) (3) LTC + (4) No (5) (6) LTC + (7) No (7a) No transit + (8) (9) LTC +
transit LTC spot transit LTC spot transit Balkan Stream LTC spot

Change of Russian profit, − 9208 − 9082 0 − 4963 − 4623 120 − 5119 − 4844 − 4659 67
million €/year17
Russian gas sales in EU28, TWh/ 1175 1213 2020 1891 1964 2459 1925 1965 1964 2459
year
Market share of Russia in EU 28 24% 24% 40% 38% 39% 49% 38% 39% 39% 49%
consumption

Source: REKK EGMM modelling.

framework of the supply contract has been agreed under the condition, defend the viability of Ukrainian transit. However, the EU remains
that Hungary’s energy regulator approved the investment for the project polarized between those that gain from Russian diversification projects
connecting the country to Turkish Stream pipeline through Serbia in the and those that do not.
countries Ten Year Network Development Plan. Accordingly FGSZ, the The V4 strategy to oppose and delay the Russian pipeline projects
transmission system operator will start operations of the new route from was intended to support the Ukrainian position in the transit dispute
October 1, 2021. The first 6 bcm per year capacity was approved un­ negotiations with Russia. V4 countries were united in that support, in­
conditional (being part of the regulatory asset base), while a further 2.5 dependent of how deeply they were individually impacted. We found
bcm/year capacity is conditional on the outcome of the Open Season substantial variation among V4 countries as to the impact of a complete
procedure (Hungarian Energy and Public Utility Regulatory Authority, or nearly complete cessation of Ukrainian gas transit. Polish welfare
2020). would not be impacted at all and Czechia is mostly immune to the
Slovakia’s welfare losses are mostly attributable to TSO revenues change in gas flows. Hungary and Slovakia are much more affected by
from lower transit flows, which explains why in the discourse analysis of these decisions - Hungary through the gas prices and Slovakia by the loss
Osička et al. (2018) found that between relevant V4 stakeholders of transit revenues. Modelling results show that natural gas wholesale
(Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Ministry of Economic Affairs, regulators prices in the EU and in all V4 countries always increase when Russia
and TSOs) the issue of future of gas transit is mentioned most in does not deliver gas through Ukraine, independent of new infrastruc­
Slovakia, and dominates the agenda. Our modelling findings are also in ture. The price would increase an average of €2/MWh in V4 countries if
line with the same discourse analysis results related to Hungary: in the Ukrainian route is not used by Russia, while the Western European
Hungary “future transit flows” are mentioned together with “missing price (TTF) would be largely unaffected.
infrastructure” and “harmonization”. The notion of future transit flows Our modelling scenario suggests that the economic rationale for
is even less of a priority in Czechia and in Poland, further supported by Gazprom and Russia strongly supports an agreement on transit even if
the modelling results: the Czech TSO revenues are not impacted by any additional infrastructure is completed, and even after the current
infrastructure or sales strategy change. 2020–2024 agreement will expire. This economic interest is also sup­
The divisive nature of the Nord Stream 2 project in the European ported by historical facts, with transit through Ukraine growing in
Union is captured well by the results: additional infrastructure will al­ recent years. This is because despite all of the political rhetoric the
ways increase EU28 welfare but the distributional effects favour West­ economic rationale for Gazprom to use the flexibility provided only
ern Europe. through the Ukrainian route to serve growing European gas demand.
Table 4 is summarizing the modelling results by assigning symbols to Furthermore, gas delivery has been uninterrupted even during the
the relative position change (in term of total welfare*) of the different annexation of Crimea and the ensuing frosty relationship between the
countries (regions) analysed compared to Scenario 3. Scenario 3 is the EU and Russia. This allows for some optimism that the situation can be
reference scenario, reflecting the infrastructure reality and the Russian remedied after 2020 as well, though rebuilding trust is not envisaged to
sales strategy based on the new transit contract at the beginning of 2020. be easily achieved (Mitrova et al., 2019; Pirani, 2019).
The modelling results show unequivocally the socio-economic As the Romanian offshore gas as an alternative source to Central
rationale for the EU28, and V4 countries in particular, to maintain Europe will not reach FID in the short to mid-term, Hungary will
Ukrainian transit in the future. Since Nord Stream 1 started operation, advocate for the completion of Balkan Stream, especially if investment
the European Commission and several member states have consistently costs are partly borne by Russia/Gazprom via long term capacity
opposed any large Russian route diversification projects precisely to bookings (Scenario 7a in Table 4). This unfortunate outcome would

Table 4
Summary results of change in the position of key stakeholders.
TS1 TS1+NS2 TS1, TS2 and NS2

(1) No (2) (3) LTC + (4) No (5) (6) LTC + (7) No (7a) No transit + Balkan (8) (9) LTC +
transit LTC spot transit LTC spot transit Stream LTC spot

EU28 − − − − ref – + ++ + + + ++
RU − − − − ref − − − − + − − − − − − 0
UA − − − − ref − − − − – − − − − − − –
V4 − − − − ref – – + – – – +
CZ − − − − ref – 0 ++ 0 0 0 ++
HU − − – ref – – + − − – – +
PL − − − − ref 0 0 ++ 0 0 0 ++
SK − − − − ref – – + – – – +

++: large relative welfare gains; + slightly positive welfare gain; 0 no considerable change.
− slightly negative welfare change, − − large welfare loss.
*For Russia results are categorized based on the profit change.

7
B.T. Tóth et al. Energy Policy 146 (2020) 111748

leave Ukraine further isolated and long-term capacity bookings on the Funding
southern route would present the very real prospect of losing its transit
in the mid to long-term. This scenario would lead to underutilization of This research did not receive any specific grant from funding
other pipelines in CEE that would become stranded assets embedded agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.
into the tariffs paid by consumers.
The decrease of Ukraine gas transit will probably accelerate the CRediT authorship contribution statement
development of its own gas production and invest more in energy effi­
ciency. In the long run, gas will probably lose relevance in Ukraine’s Borbála Takácsné Tóth: Conceptualization, Methodology, Writing -
domestic politics. Russian energy strategy, that has not been reviewed original draft, Writing - review & editing, Validation, Supervision. Péter
since 2009 has put the diversification of transit routes into the focus. Kotek: Software, Data curation, Visualization, Writing - original draft,
This has partly been implemented not only towards the European mar­ Writing - review & editing. Adrienn Selei: Methodology, Writing -
ket but also towards Asia with the Power of Siberia pipeline launched in original draft, Writing - review & editing.
December 2019 delivering 38 bcm/year gas to China. We agree with
Kutcherov et al. (2020) that the Russian energy strategy needs a revision Declaration of competing interest
as prospects of the European market are mixed for Russia. As competi­
tion of LNG and other suppliers keeps prices down, and green goals of The authors declare that they have no known competing financial
the new Commission will accelerate the transition from gas to clean interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence
technologies and reduce the demand on the long run, increased gas sales the work reported in this paper.
and growing market share in Europe can only reached at low prices and
would not increase Russian profit substantially. It must also be noted Acknowledgements
that in the current oversupplied global gas market redirecting gas to Asia
will not increase the bargaining power of Russia/Gazprom towards The authors are grateful for the useful debates and feedback from our
European buyers. REKK colleagues, in particular László Paizs and Enikő Kácsor for their
Overlapping interests between parties could provide a baseline for helpful comments. The authors are extremely grateful to Zombor
rebuilding trust and finding a way to ensure the utilization of the Berezvai and Pál Valentiny who read and commented on an earlier
Ukrainian pipeline system in a transparent and cost-efficient manner version of this paper. A special thanks also goes to Nolan Theisen who
under the European regulatory framework. In our estimate, the Ukrai­ read, commented and did the final editing. All opinions expressed and
nian system could still be economically rational for the delivery of about any errors remained are those of the authors.
two third of the current yearly transit to Europe, even with or without
Nord Stream 2, TurkStream 2 and Balkan Stream.

Annex. Delivery routes of long-term contracts in different scenarios

TS1 TS1 and NS2 TS1, TS2 and NS2

(1) No transit (2) LTC (3) LTC + (4) No transit (5) LTC (6) LTC + (7) No transit (8) LTC (9) LTC +
spot spot spot

Russian spot – – DE, AT – – DE, AT – – DE, AT


sales via
Ukraine
LTC via Yamal CZ, PL CZ, PL CZ, PL CZ, PL CZ, PL CZ, PL CZ, PL CZ, PL CZ, PL
LTC via Ukraine – BA, BG, GR, BA, BG, GR, – BA, BG, GR, BA, BG, GR, – BA, BG, GR, BA, BG, GR,
MK, MD, RO, MK, MD, RO, MK, MD, RO, MK, MD, RO, MK, MD, RO, MK, MD, RO,
HU, RS, HR HU, RS, HR HU, RS, HR HU, RS, HR HU, RS, HR HU, RS, HR
LTC via Nord AT, CZ, FR, DE, AT, CZ, FR, AT, CZ, FR, AT, BA, CZ, FR, AT, CZ, FR, AT, CZ, FR, AT, CZ, FR, DE, AT, CZ, FR, AT, CZ, FR,
Stream HU, IT, IT, NL, DE, HU, IT, DE, HU, IT, DE, HU, IT, NL, DE, HU, IT, DE, HU, IT, HU, IT, NL, SK, DE, HU, IT, DE, HU, IT,
SK, SI NL, SK, SI NL, SK, SI RS, SK, SI, HR NL, SK, SI NL, SK, SI SI NL, SK, SI NL, SK, SI
LTC via BA, BG, GR, TR TR BG, GR, MK, TR TR BA, BG, GR, TR TR
TurkStream MK, MD, RO, MD, RO, TR MK, MD, RO,
TR, HU, RS, HR TR, HU, RS, HR

References Capros, P., 2016. EU reference scenario 2016 energy, transport and GHG emissions
trends to 2050. Retrieved from. https://ec.europa.eu/energy/sites/ener/files/do
cuments/20160713%20draft_publication_REF2016_v13.pdf.
Abada, I., Gabriel, S., Briat, V., Massol, O., 2013. A generalized nash–cournot model for
Chyong, C., Hobbs, B., 2014. Strategic Eurasian natural gas market model for energy
the northwestern European natural gas markets with a fuel substitution demand
security and policy analysis: formulation and application to South Stream. Energy
function: the GaMMES model. Network. Spatial Econ. 13, 1–42. https://doi.org/
Econ. 44, 198–211. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2014.04.006.
10.1007/s11067-012-9171-5.
Dieckhöner, C., Lochner, S., Lindenberger, D., 2013. European natural gas infrastructure:
Abrell, J., Chavaz, L., Weigt, H., 2016. Pathways for the European Natural Gas Market.
the impact of market developments on gas flows and physical market integration.
13th International Conference on the European Energy Market (EEM), pp. 1–6.
Appl. Energy 102, 994–1003. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2012.06.021.
https://doi.org/10.1109/EEM.2016.7521360.
Egging, R., Gabriel, S., 2006. Examining market power in the European natural gas
Acer, 2018. ACER Market Monitoring Report 2017 - Gas Wholesale Markets Volume.
market. Energy Pol. 34, 2762–2778. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2005.04.018.
ACER.
Egging, R., Gabriel, S., Holz, F., Zhuang, J., 2008. A complementarity model for the
Boots, M., Rijkers, F., Hobbs, B., 2004. Trading in the downstream European gas market:
European natural gas market. Energy Pol. 36 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
a successive oligopoly approach. Energy J. 73–102. https://doi.org/10.2307/
enpol.2008.01.044.
41323043.
Egging, R., Holz, F., Gabriel, S., 2010. The World Gas Model: a multi-period mixed
Bros, A., Mitrova, T., Westphal, K., 2017. German-Russian gas relations - a special
complementarity model for the global natural gas market. Energy 35, 4016–4029.
relationship in troubled waters. SWP Research Paper.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2010.03.053.

8
B.T. Tóth et al. Energy Policy 146 (2020) 111748

Eser, P., Chokani, N., Abhari, R., 2019. Impact of Nord Stream 2 and LNG on gas trade Mulder, M., Zwart, G., 2006. Government involvement in liberalised gas markets; a
and security of supply in the European gas network of 2030. Appl. Energy 816–830. welfare-economic analysis of Dutch gas-depletion policy. CPB Doc. Retrieved from
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2019.01.068. https://econpapers.repec.org/paper/cpbdocmnt/110.htm.
Eyl-Mazzega, M.-A., 2018. The Gazprom - Naftogaz Stockholm arbitration award: time Osička, J., Lehotský, L., Zapletalová, V., Černoch, F., Dančák, B., 2018. Natural gas
for settlements and responsible behaviour. Édito Énergie. Retrieved from. https market integration in the Visegrad 4 region: an example to follow or to avoid?
://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/eyl-mazzega_gazprom_naftogaz_st Energy Pol. 112, 184–197. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2017.10.018.
ockholm_arbitration_awards_2018.pdf. Paltsev, S., 2014. Scenarios for Russia’s natural gas exports to 2050. Energy Econ. 42,
Goldthau, A., 2016. Assessing Nord Stream 2: regulation, geopolitics & energy security in 262–270. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2014.01.005.
the EU, central eastern Europe & the UK. Strategy Paper 10. Retrieved from. https Pirani, S., 2018a. After the Gazprom-Naftogaz Arbitration: Commerce Still Entangled in
://www.asktheeu.org/en/request/7115/response/23365/attach/2/Goldthau%20J Politics. Oxford Energy Insight, p. 31.
uly%202016.pdf?cookie_passthrough=1. Pirani, S., 2018b. Russian Gas Transit through Ukraine after 2019: the Options. Oxford
Goldthau, A., Sitter, N., 2014. A liberal actor in a realist world? The Commission and the Energy Insight, p. 41.
external dimension of the single market for energy. J. Eur. Publ. Pol. https://doi.org/ Pirani, S., 2019. Russia-Ukraine Transit Talks: the Risks to Gas in Europe. OXFORD
10.1080/13501763.2014.912251. ENERGY COMMENT. Retrieved from. https://www.oxfordenergy.org/wpcms/wp-
Hecking, H., Weiser, F., 2017. Impacts of Nord Stream 2 on the EU natural gas market. content/uploads/2019/05/Russia-Ukraine-transit-talks-the-risks-to-gas-in-Europe.
EWI Res. Rep. Retrieved from https://www.ewi.research-scenarios.de/cms/wp-cont pdf?v=35b5282113b8.
ent/uploads/2017/09/EWI-1163-17-Studie-Impacts-of-Nord-Stream-2-web.compr Pirani, S., Sharples, J., 2020. The Russia-Ukraine gas transit deal: opening a new chapter.
essed.pdf. OIES Energy Insight 64. Retrieved from. https://www.oxfordenergy.org/publicati
Henderson, J., Sharples, J., 2018. Gazprom in Europe – two “anni mirabiles”, but can it ons/the-russia-ukraine-gas-transit-deal-opening-a-new-chapter/.
continue? Oxford Energy Insight 28. Retrieved from. https://www.oxfordenergy.or Pirani, S., Yafimava, K., 2016. Russian Gas Transit across Ukraine Post-2019 - Pipeline
g/wpcms/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/Gazprom-in-Europe-%E2%80%93-two Scenarios, Gas Flow Consequences, and Regulatory Constraints. Oxford Institute for
-Anni-Mirabiles-but-can-it-continue-Insight-29.pdf?v=35b5282113b8. Energy Studies (blog). Retrieved from. https://www.oxfordenergy.org/pub.
Holz, F., Hirschhausen, C., Kemfert, C., 2008. A strategic model of European gas supply Pirani, S., Sharples, J., Yafimava, K., Yermakov, V., 2020. Implications of the Russia-
(GASMOD). Energy Econ. 30, 766–788. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. Ukraine gas transit deal for alternative pipeline routes and the Ukrainian and
eneco.2007.01.018. European markets. OIES Energy Insight 65. Retrieved from. https://www.oxfordene
Holz, F., Richter, P., Egging, R., 2013. The Role of Natural Gas in a Low-Carbon Europe: rgy.org/wpcms/wp-content/uploads/2020/03/Insight-65-Implications-of-the-
Infrastructure and Regional Supply Security in the Global Gas Model. Discussion Russia-Ukraine-gas-transit-deal-for-alternative-pipeline-routes-and-the-Ukrainian-an
Papers of DIW Berlin. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2239652. d-European-markets.pdf.
Hungarian Energy and Public Utility Regulatory Authority, 2020, June 26. Approval of Prontera, A., Plenta, P., 2020. Catalytic Power Europe and gas infrastructural policy in
the Ten Year Network Development Plan of the Hungarian Natural Gas System. the Visegrad countries. Energy Pol. 137 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
Decree 1596/2020. enpol.2019.111189.
Kiss, A., Selei, A., Takácsné Tóth, B., 2016. A top-down approach to evaluating cross- Regulation 347 2013, 2013. Regulation (EU) No 347/2013 of the European Parliament
border natural gas infrastructure projects in Europe. Energy J. 37 https://doi.org/ and of the Council of 17 April 2013 on Guidelines for Trans-European Energy
10.5547/01956574.37.SI3.akis. Infrastructure.
Kotek, P., Selei, A., Tóth, B., 2016. Az Északi-Áramlat-2 gázvezeték megépítésének Richter, P., Holz, F., 2015. All quiet on the eastern front? Disruption scenarios of Russian
hatása a gázárakra és a versenyre. In: Pál, V. (Ed.), Verseny És Szabályozás 2016. natural gas supply to Europe. Energy Pol. 80, 177–189. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
MTA KRTK Közgazdaság-tudományi Intézet, Budapest, pp. 241–261. enpol.2015.01.024.
Kotek, P., Takácsné Tóth, B., Mezősi, A., 2018. What caused the 2018 March price spike Siddi, M., 2018. The role of power in EU–Russia energy relations: the interplay between
on TTF? REKK Policy Brief. Retrieved from. https://rekk.hu/downloads/academi markets and geopolitics. Eur. Asia Stud. 70, 1552–1571. https://doi.org/10.1080/
c_publications/rekk_policybrief_02_2018_en.pdf. 09668136.2018.1536925.
Kutcherov, V., Morgunova, M., Bessel, V., Lopatin, A., 2020. Russian natural gas exports: Smeers, Y., 2008. Gas models and three difficult objectives. CORE Dis. Pap. Retrieved
an analysis of challenges and opportunities. Energy Strat. Rev. 30 https://doi.org/ from https://cdn.uclouvain.be/public/Exports%20reddot/core/documents/coreDP2
10.1016/j.esr.2020.100511. 008_9.pdf.
Lochner, S., 2011. Identification of congestion and valuation of transport infrastructures Takácsné Tóth, B., Kotek, P., Kaderják, P., 2017. Evaluating the 6 March PRISMA
in the European natural gas market. Energy 2483–2492. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. capacity auctions. REKK Hungarian energy market report 2017 Q2-3. Retrieved
energy.2011.01.040. from. https://rekk.hu/downloads/publications/REKK_Report_2017_Q2-Q3.pdf, 10-
Lochner, S., Bothe, D., 2007. From Russia with gas: an analysis of the Nord Stream 14.
pipeline’s impact on the European Gas Transmission System with the TIGER-Model. Talus, K., Hancher, L., 2019. Exploring the Limits of EU’s Unbelievable Behaviour on
In: EWI Working Paper. Retrieved from. https://www.researchgate.net/publicatio Nord Stream 2. EURACTIVE. Retrieved from. https://www.euractiv.com/sect
n/45134809_From_Russia_with_gas_an_analysis_of_the_Nord_Stream_pipeline’s_impa ion/energy/opinion/exploring-the-limits-of-eus-unbelievable-behaviour-on-nord-
ct_on_the_European_Gas_Transmission_System_with_the_TIGER-Model. stream-2/.
Mitrova, T., Boersma, T., Galkina, A., 2016. June 11-12). Some future scenarios of Vatansever, A., 2017. Is Russia building too many pipelines? Explaining Russia’s oil and
Russian natural gas in Europe. Energy Strat. Rev. 19–28. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. gas export strategy. Energy Pol. 108, 1–11. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
esr.2016.06.001. enpol.2017.05.038.
Mitrova, T., Pirani, S., Sharples, J., 2019. November). Russia-Ukraine gas transit talks: Yafimava, K., 2019. Gas directive amendment:implications for Nord Stream 2. Energy
risks for all sides. OIES Energy Insight 60. Retrieved from. https://www.oxfordenerg Insight 49. Retrieved from. https://www.oxfordenergy.org/wpcms/wp-content
y.org/wpcms/wp-content/uploads/2019/11/Russia-Ukraine-gas-transit-talks-risks /uploads/2019/03/Gas-Directive-Amendment-Insight-49.pdf?v=35b5282113b8.
-for-all-sides-Insight-60.pdf. Zwart, G., 2009. European natural gas markets: resource constraints and market power.
Energy J. 30, 151–166. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1310688.

You might also like