Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 124

FINANCIAL Inside the issue:

Announcement of

ANALYSTS the 2022 Graham


and Dodd Award
Winners

JOURNAL ®
Volume 79 Number 1
First Quarter 2023

REDEFINING THE OPTIMAL


5
RETIREMENT INCOME STRATEGY
David Blanchett, CFA
ALLOCATING TO THEMATIC
18
INVESTMENTS
Koye Somefun, Romain Perchet, Chenyang Yin,
and Raul Leote de Carvalho

37
TARGETING MACROECONOMIC
EXPOSURES IN EQUITY
PORTFOLIOS: A FIRM-LEVEL
MEASUREMENT APPROACH FOR
OUT-OF-SAMPLE ROBUSTNESS
Mikheil Esakia and Felix Goltz SUPPLY CHAIN CLIMATE
58
EXPOSURE
Greg Hall, Kate Liu, Lukasz Pomorski, and
Laura Serban

77
TRADE INFORMATIVENESS IN
MODERN MARKETS
Samarpan Nawn, CFA, and Gaurav Raizada
99
OPTION PRICING VIA BREAKEVEN
VOLATILITY
Blair Hull, Anlong Li, and Xiao Qiao
Financial Analysts Journal

58 Supply Chain Climate Exposure

CONTENTS Greg Hall, Kate Liu, Lukasz Pomorski, and


Laura Serban

All companies, even green ones, can


Volume 79 Number 1 | First Quarter 2023 have material climate exposure. The
authors propose a better measure of
supply-chain climate risks that captures
price movements, shows performance
PERSPECTIVES patterns, and can be applied to portfolio
5 Redefining the Optimal Retirement
Income Strategy
decisions.

David Blanchett, CFA 77 Trade Informativeness in Modern


Markets
This paper introduces a cohesive series Samarpan Nawn, CFA, and Gaurav Raizada
of models designed to improve retirement
income projections. The framework can
The authors demonstrate that trade
produce guidance that differs from the
informativeness is highest for institutions
advice generated by models that use
and lowest for the retail group of traders.
more basic assumptions.
Algorithmic trading generally provides
advantages versus manual trading,
especially in certain scenarios.

18 Allocating to Thematic Investments


Koye Somefun, Romain Perchet,
Chenyang Yin, and Raul Leote de Carvalho 99 Option Pricing via Breakeven
Volatility
Allocating to thematic investments can be Blair Hull, Anlong Li, and Xiao Qiao
difficult because they have exposures to
multiple risk factors. The authors propose Calculating breakeven volatility based on
using a framework based on robust S&P 500 options data, this study builds
portfolio optimization to make themes fit a predictive model that provides a link
in traditional multi-asset portfolios. between option characteristics and
breakeven volatility. A simulated trading
strategy demonstrates the model’s
economic value.
RESEARCH
37 Targeting Macroeconomic
Exposures in Equity Portfolios: A
Firm-Level Measurement Approach
for Out-of-Sample Robustness
Mikheil Esakia and Felix Goltz

The authors propose a method that uses


firm-level measures of macroeconomic
exposures to produce better estimations
for equity strategies versus standard
methods. This approach has applications
for equity portfolio construction.

UFAJ_I_79_1_GN_pages.indd 1 16-01-2023 14:42:26


FINANCIAL EXECUTIVE EDITOR William Goetzmann
Yale School of Management, USA
MANAGING EDITOR Luis Garcia-Feijóo, CFA, CIPM
ANALYSTS® Florida Atlantic University and EIA Economic Index
Associates, USA

JOURNAL
A publication of CFA Institute
CO-EDITORS Nicole Boyson
Northeastern University, USA
Daniel Giamouridis
Bank of America Merrill Lynch, UK

ADVISORY COUNCIL EDITORIAL BOARD

Stephen J. Brown Steven Thorley, CFA Richard B. Evans Russ Wermers


Monash Business School and BYU Marriott School of Business, Darden Graduate School of Smith School of Business,
New York University Stern School, USA Business, University of Virginia, University of Maryland, USA
USA USA
Maria Vassalou Fanesca Young, CFA
Joanne M. Hill Vassalou Capital Management, William W. Jennings, CFA GIC, USA
CBOE Vest, USA USA US Air Force Academy, USA
Maureen O’Hara K.C. John Wei Sebastien Page, CFA
Cornell University, USA Hong Kong Polytechnic University, T. Rowe Price, USA
Hong Kong SAR, China

CFA INSTITUTE OFFICERS

Margaret Franklin, CFA


President and CEO
Paul Andrews
Managing Director, Research,
Advocacy, & Standards

Issues of the Financial Analysts Journal are available online at www.tandfonline.com/ufaj.

UFAJ_I_79_1_GN_pages.indd 2 16-01-2023 14:42:30


CFA INSTITUTE BOARD OF GOVERNORS 2022–2023

Chair Daniel J. Fasciano, CFA Punita Kumar-Sinha, CFA


Mark Lazberger, CFA GW&K Pacific Paradigm Advisors LLC
Omnia Capital Partners United States India/United States
Australia
Oyebanji Fehintola, CFA Yimei Li, CFA
Vice Chair Africa Finance Corporation ChinaAMC
Tricia Rothschild, CFA Nigeria China
United States
Mei Gao, CFA Geoffrey Ng, CFA
CFA Institute President and CEO IDG Capital Fortress Capital Asset Management
Margaret Franklin, CFA China/United States Malaysia
CFA Institute
Canada Joanne Hill Maria Wilton, CFA
Cboe Vest Victorian Funds Management
Marshall Bailey, CFA United States Corporation
MUFG Securities EMEA plc Australia
United Kingdom Heinz Hockmann
Lovell Minnick Partners
Alexander Birkin Germany
Ernst & Young
United Kingdom

Abstract/indexed in: Business Periodicals Index.


Financial Analysts Journal (Print ISSN 0015-198X, Online ISSN 1938-3312) is published quarterly in January, April, July, and October for a total of 4 issues per year by
Taylor & Francis Group, LLC, 530 Walnut Street, Suite 850, Philadelphia, PA 19106, +1 215 625 8900. Periodicals postage paid (Permit no. 571-200) at the Post Office
in Charlottesville, VA, and additional mailing offices.
US Postmaster: Please send address changes to Financial Analysts Journal, c/o The Sheridan Press, PO Box 465, Hanover, PA 17331.
Subscription records are maintained at Taylor & Francis Group, 4 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, OX14 4RN, UK.
Subscription information: For more information and subscription rates, please see tandfonline.com/pricing/journal/ufaj. Taylor & Francis journals are available in
a range of different packages, designed to suit every library’s needs and budget. This journal is available for institutional subscriptions with online only or print &
online options. This journal may also be available as part of our libraries, subject collections, or archives. For more information on our sales packages, please visit:
librarianresources.taylorandfrancis.com.
For support with any institutional subscription, please visit help.tandfonline.com or email our dedicated team at subscriptions@tandf.co.uk.
Subscriptions purchased at the personal rate are strictly for personal, non-commercial use only. The reselling of personal subscriptions is prohibited. Personal
subscriptions must be purchased with a personal check, credit card, or BAC/wire transfer. Proof of personal status may be requested.
Back issues: Taylor & Francis Group retains a current and one-year back issue stock of journals. Older volumes are held by our official stockists to whom all orders
and enquiries should be addressed: Periodicals Service Company, 351 Fairview Ave., Suite 300, Hudson, New York 12534, USA. Tel: +1 518 537 4700; email: psc@
periodicals.com.
Ordering information: To subscribe to the Journal, please contact: T&F Customer Services, Informa UK Ltd, Sheepen Place, Colchester, Essex, CO3 3LP, United
Kingdom. Tel: +44 (0) 20 7017 5544; email: subscriptions@tandf.co.uk.
Taylor & Francis journals are priced in USD, GBP and EUR (as well as AUD and CAD for a limited number of journals). All subscriptions are charged depending on
where the end customer is based. If you are unsure which rate applies to you, please contact Customer Services. All subscriptions are payable in advance and
all rates include postage. We are required to charge applicable VAT/GST on all print and online combination subscriptions, in addition to our online only journals.
Subscriptions are entered on an annual basis, i.e., January to December. Payment may be made by sterling check, dollar check, euro check, international money
order, National Giro or credit cards (Amex, Visa and Mastercard).
Copyright © 2023 CFA Institute. All rights reserved. CFA®, Chartered Financial Analyst®, GIPS®, and Financial Analysts Journal® are registered trademarks
owned by CFA Institute. CFA Institute is a Virginia not-for-profit corporation devoted to the advancement of investment management and security analysis. To
view a complete list of CFA Institute trademarks and a guide for the use of our marks, please visit our website at www.cfainstitute.org. No part of this publication
may be reproduced, stored, transmitted, or disseminated, in any form, or by any means, without prior written permission from Taylor & Francis Group, to whom all
requests to reproduce copyright material should be directed, in writing.
Disclaimer: CFA Institute and our publisher Taylor & Francis Group, LLC (“T&F”), make every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”)
contained in our publications. However, CFA Institute and our publisher T&F, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as
to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views
of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by CFA Institute or our publisher T&F. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should
be independently verified with primary sources of information and any reliance on the Content is at your own risk. CFA Institute and our publisher T&F make no
representations, warranties or guarantees, whether express or implied, that the Content is accurate, complete or up to date. CFA Institute and our publisher T&F,
shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused aris-
ing directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://
www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions
Taylor & Francis Group, LLC, grants authorization for individuals to photocopy copyright material for private research use, on the sole basis that requests for such
use are referred directly to the requestor’s local Reproduction Rights Organization (RRO). The copyright fee is exclusive of any charge or fee levied. In order to
contact your local RRO, please contact International Federation of Reproduction Rights Organizations (IFRRO), rue du Prince Royal, 87, B-1050 Brussels, Belgium;
email ifrro@skynet.be; Copyright Clearance Center Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA; email info@copyright.com; or Copyright Licensing Agency,
90 Tottenham Court Road, London, W1P 0LP, UK; email cla@cla.co.uk. This authorization does not extend to any other kind of copying, by any means, in any form,
for any purpose other than private research use.
Permissions: See help.tandfonline.com/Librarian/s/article/Permissions
Submission Information: See tandfonline.com/ufaj
All Taylor & Francis Group journals are printed on paper from renewable sources by accredited partners.
January 2023

UFAJ_I_79_1_GN_pages.indd 3 16-01-2023 14:42:30


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute Perspectives
https://doi.org/10.1080/0015198X.2022.2129947

Redefining the Optimal


Retirement Income
Strategy
David Blanchett, CFA
David Blanchett, CFA, is the head of Retirement Research, PGIM DC Solutions, Newark, NJ. Send correspondence to David Blanchett at
david.blanchett@pgim.com.

This paper introduces a cohesive etirement is seldom as simple as assumed in research and finan-
series of models designed to
improve retirement income projec-
tions. First, the retirement income
goal (i.e., liability) is decomposed
R cial planning tools. Too often, the retirement spending goal is
assumed to be some constant (static) amount, in today’s dollars
(i.e., in real terms), where the efficacy of a given strategy is determined
using metrics such as probability of success, which is the frequency
based on assumed spending elasti- with which the goal is completely accomplished in a given simulation.
city (e.g., “needs” and “wants”). These flawed assumptions can result in estimates for required savings
Second, spending is assumed to or retirement spending in research and financial planning tools that are
evolve throughout retirement using significantly different than if a more realistic model is used.
a dynamic withdrawal strategy lev-
eraging the funded ratio concept. In this paper, a cohesive series of models are introduced that are
Third, optimal strategies are deter- designed to improve retirement income projections. The models in
mined using an expected utility this research are far more evolutionary, rather than revolutionary,
model based on prospect theory, given the decades of existing research in the retirement income space
which also yields a client-friendly on these topics. This research is primarily focused on functional imple-
outcomes metric. Overall, this mentation, where the respective models introduced are designed to
framework can result in advice and specifically address some of the more obvious shortfalls in existing
guidance that is notably different models in a way that can be realistically (and practically) implemented.
than models using more basic (and
First, we decompose the retirement spending goal (liability) into two separ-
common) assumptions, especially
ate goals: needs and wants, which reflects the fact that retirees typically
approaches relying on probability of
have varied levels of elasticity (or required certainty) associated with differ-
success-related metrics.
ent types of expenditures. For example, spending on travel is generally
more flexible than spending on healthcare. Second, we introduce a model
Keywords: financial planning;
where spending levels (i.e., portfolio withdrawals) evolve throughout retire-
retirement; wealth management
ment based on how the retiree’s funded ratio (i.e., financial situation)
changes over time. This approach can explicitly incorporate nonconstant
cash flows, which is a key weakness of most existing approaches. Third, an
expected utility model based on prospect theory is introduced to determine
Disclosure: PGIM DC Solutions is currently optimal strategies that better capture the expected satisfaction associated
developing a series of solutions based on
this research and methodologies. This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons
Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits
unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original
PL Credits: 0.75 work is properly cited.

Volume 79, Number 1 © 2022 The Author(s). Published with license by Taylor & Francis Group, LLC. 5
Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

with accomplishing different levels of spending in retire- Portfolio withdrawals, which are assumed to reflect
ment. The certainty-equivalent spending estimate from retiree spending, are generally static and change only
our utility model (the “goal completion score”) is a client- based on inflation and are not adjusted based on
friendly outcomes metric that can be used to relay the portfolio performance. This is obviously overly sim-
efficacy of a given strategy to a household. plistic and consistent with life-cycle consumption
smoothing only under a very limited set of implaus-
Overall, this analysis suggests that approaches that ible preference parameters (Milevsky and Huang
more accurately capture the retirement liability can 2011). In reality, retirees headed toward certain ruin
result in advice and guidance that is notably different (i.e., portfolio depletion) would likely adjust with-
than models using more basic (and common) assump- drawals to prolong the life of the portfolio.
tions, especially approaches relying on probability of
success-related metrics. Collectively, this research A number of concepts that are commonly used when
provides a framework that can help households make modeling retiree liabilities and determining optimal
better decisions about retirement-related issues such retirement strategies have been borrowed from best
as optimal spending levels, optimal portfolio risk lev- practices in the defined benefit (DB) space (e.g., the
els, and optimal allocations to guaranteed income. concept of liability driven investing, or LDI). Unlike in
DB plans, though, which have “hard” liabilities that are
legally mandated, retirees typically have some control
Redefining the Retirement over expenses (i.e., they could be perceived as “soft,”
Income Goal to some extent, as discussed by Idzorek and Blanchett
[2019]). In other words, retirees typically have the
Early research on retirement spending predominately
ability to cut back on spending as situations warrant.
focused on estimating “safe” initial withdrawal rates.
Bengen’s (1994) research on the “4% Rule” is perhaps The “pain” associated with cutting back on spending
the most widely known example.1 With initial withdrawal depends to some extent on the respective expend-
rates, the noted percentage is multiplied by the respect- iture. While some expenditures, such as healthcare,
ive balance and that initial withdrawal amount (not the may be relatively painful for retirees to scale back on
initial percentage) is assumed to be withdrawn from the (and would therefore be considered relatively inelas-
portfolio for the duration of retirement (i.e., 30 years), tic), other expenditures, such as travel, could be
typically adjusted annually for inflation. For example, reduced more easily as situations warrant (and would
with a 4% initial withdrawal rate, if the balance at retire- be considered more elastic). Therefore, understanding
ment is $1 million, the withdrawal in the first year of the composition of retiree spending is important
retirement would be $40,000 and that initial amount when assessing the efficacy of the common modeling
($40,000) would be increased by inflation until death. assumption that all retiree expenditures are inelastic.
Past research determining optimal portfolio withdrawal To better understand the composition of retiree
rates has generally used some type of stochastic (i.e., expenditures, data from the 2020 Interview file of the
random) component, typically with respect to the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CES)2 was reviewed.
return series, based on actual historical time-series data The analysis only includes respondents between the
or some type of Monte Carlo simulation. Early research ages of 65 and 80 (inclusive) where the household is
predominately relied on historical U.S. returns, although coded as being retired. Expenditures are categorized
more recent research has considered international as being either elastic or inelastic. Figure 1 includes
time-series data (e.g., Pfau 2010). There has also been the average percentage of total household expendi-
an increased focus on using expected (or forecasted) tures that are estimated to be inelastic for various
returns given the relatively low interest rate environ- total expenditure groups.
ment today (e.g., Fink, Pfau, and Blanchett 2013).
While approximately 65% of total retiree expendi-
Optimal outcomes in financial planning tools are typic- tures are estimated to be inelastic (i.e., “needs”), on
ally determined based on achieving some acceptable average, households with higher total expenditures
probability of success (e.g., 90%), which is defined by clearly have higher allocations to more elastic expen-
the user. The probability of success is the percentage ditures, on average (i.e., the more retirees spend, the
of runs (or trials) where the retiree accomplishes the more flexibility they appear to have with respect to
respective retirement goal. Probability-of-success met- what they are spending money on). There is also an
rics completely ignore the magnitude of failure, which increasing level variability in the breakdown of inelas-
is a notable weakness of the metric. tic expenditures as total expenditures increase.

6
Redefining the Optimal Retirement Income Strategy

Figure 1. Inelastic Expenditures as a Percentage of Total Expenditures

100
83

Inelastic Expenditure % of
78
80 73 74

Total Expenditures
70

60 54 51
45
41
40

20

0
<$20k $20k- $40k- $60k- $80k- $100k- $125k- $150k- >=$200k
$40k $60k $80k $100k $125k $150k $200k
Total Household Expenditures

While these findings are not especially novel, since it amortized current portfolio value using the length of
is intuitive that some degree of retiree spending the remaining distribution period and expected port-
should be flexible, relatively few financial planning folio rate of return; Guyton (2004) suggests guardrails;
tools explicitly incorporate the notion of spending Stout and Mitchell (2006) develop a model based on
flexibility into the retirement forecast. In other both portfolio performance and remaining life expect-
words, financial planning tools overwhelmingly ancy; and Blanchett and Frank (2009) link adjustments
assume that retirees are unable and unwilling to to the ongoing likelihood of failure.
adjust spending throughout retirement, despite rela-
tively straightforward evidence to the contrary, espe- Recently, Waring and Siegel (2015, 2018) utilized an
cially among households with higher expenditures intertemporal budget constraint, accompanied by a regu-
levels (who are more likely to use financial advisors). larly recalculated spending amount, to develop a fairly
simple spending approach with little or no chance of ruin.
While there are decades of research exploring various The budget constraint, coupled with revisiting the annuiti-
approaches to adjusting portfolio withdrawals over zation decision annually, allows this method to incorpor-
time, commonly referred to as dynamic spending (or ate volatile portfolios that are invested in risky assets.
withdrawal) rules, these approaches are generally diffi-
cult to implement and can significantly complicate The other line of early research on spending is quite dif-
financial planning tools. For example, when implement- ferent in its origin, coming out of stochastic dynamic-pro-
ing some type of dynamic spending approach, not only gramming and utility-maximizing (life cycle) models, often
do a series of rules need to be developed to determine in the context of the intertemporal asset pricing litera-
how spending should (or will) evolve over time, but the ture. One of the earliest life cycle models was developed
outcomes metric also needs to be able to incorporate a by Merton (1969). Another example is Rubinstein’s
range of potential scenarios, which “break” more com- model (1976), which explicitly derives a spending rule in
mon binary metrics, like the probability of success. the multi-period asset pricing context. While many of the
dynamic spending models appear in the context of asset
The unique contribution of this research to the litera- pricing, there are some that were developed explicitly for
ture is that it attempts to address these various the spending problem, notably Milevsky and Huang
retirement modeling issues simultaneously in a rela- (2011) and Habib, Huang, and Milevsky (2017).
tively straightforward series of cohesive models.
Relatively few, if any, of the dynamic withdrawal rules
that have been introduced in past research have actu-
Dynamic Spending ally been implemented in financial planning tools used
The literature on dynamic spending rules has evolved today. This can largely be attributed to the fact that
over the last few decades and can generally be split the approaches are either too computationally complex
into two groups. For the first group, the emphasis is on or they cannot handle the myriad of household situa-
the rules themselves: Bengen (2001) suggests a floor/ tions that exist in real life (or both). The existence of
ceiling approach; Pye (2001) suggests withdrawing the nonconstant cash flows significantly increases the com-
lower of the previous amount (in real terms) or the plexity of a simulation. For example, a scenario with

Volume 79, Number 1 7


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

spouses retiring at different ages, claiming Social assets available to fund the wants spending goal
Security benefits at different ages, and receiving future (w g) are reduced by the needs income goal liability.
sources of guaranteed income (e.g., a longevity annuity 0 PT cpst Pt PT cpst n gt 1
starting at age 85) is something that most dynamic At þ 
B t¼0 ð1þrp Þ t t¼0 ð1þrn Þt C
spending rules are simply not designed to consider. W FRt ¼ max@ PT cpst w gt , 0A
t¼0 ð1þrw Þt
In summary, while many dynamic spending rules have (2)
been developed for research purposes, they are not
robust enough to capture the actual varied situations
The initial spending level for each of the two goals
for retiree households that exist in the real world.
(needs and wants) would be based on their respective
Our dynamic spending rule is specifically designed to
portion of the total retirement goal. For example, if
be robust enough to capture the varied situations
the initial retirement income goal was $100,000, of
(and cash flows) of retirees while being something
which 70% is assumed to be needs, the initial “needs”
that can be implemented in practice. The model is
withdrawal amount would be $70,000 and the initial
based on the concept of the “funded ratio,” which is
“wants” withdrawal amount would be $30,000. Those
conceptually similar to an approach introduced by
spending amounts could evolve in future years based
Kaplan and Blanchett (2021).
on the adjustments applied to the respective target
The funded ratio is a metric commonly used to describe values or other key assumptions (e.g., inflation).
the health of pension plans, but it can more generally
This research uses relatively simple spending adjust-
be used to estimate the overall financial situation for
ment schedules to adjust needs and wants spending
any goal (i.e., retiree consumption). The funded ratio is
the total value of the assets, which includes both cur- throughout the simulation. The needs goal is assumed
rent balances and future expected income, divided by to be completely inelastic and increases only with
the liability, which would be all current and future inflation annually (i.e., does not vary depending on
expected spending. A funded ratio of 1.0 would imply portfolio performance). This replicates how the entire
that an individual has just enough assets to fully fund retirement spending goal is commonly modeled today
that goal. A funded ratio greater than 1.0 implies that (i.e., effectively static in real terms) and is consistent
the individual has a surplus, while a funded ratio of less with more general pension liabilities (which are “hard”
than 1.0 implies that an individual has a shortfall. in nature). In reality, though, even the needs spending
would likely be adjusted if the retiree becomes signifi-
For our analysis, we estimate funded ratios for two cantly underfunded and therefore models used in
goals: “needs” (inelastic) spending and “wants” practice may want to consider this.
(elastic) spending. The model could easily be
expanded to consider additional spending goals For wants spending, the assumed spending level is
(e.g., “wishes” and/or “dreams”) if further differenti- adjusted based on the funded ratio for the end of
ation is desired. the previous year for that trial. The specific wants
spending adjustment schedule used for this analysis
More technically, the formula used to estimate the is included in Table 1.
needs funded ratio (N FRt ) is included in Equation (1),
where T is the total number of simulation years; At is Looking at the schedule in Table 1, if the wants
total portfolio value at year t; cpst is the cumulative spending amount was $50,000 and the wants funded
probability of surviving to year t; Pt includes all ratio was 1.40, the wants spending amount would
future inflows, which are primarily assumed to be increase by 2% in the following year (to $51,000).
pension benefits such as Social Security retirement The rate of adjustment in Table 1 clearly varies
benefits; n gt is the assumed needs income goal for depending whether the retiree is overfunded versus
that specific year (t); and r is the assumed discount overfunded, where the changes are larger (in abso-
rate (which can vary by cash flow). lute terms) if the retiree is underfunded. This effect-
P cps P ively assumes diminishing marginal utility of
At þ Tt¼0 ð1þrt tÞt consumption, which is consistent with the expected
N FRt ¼ PT cps n gt
p
(1)
t utility model introduced in the following section.
t¼0 ð1þrn Þt

This dynamic spending adjustment used for this


The wants funded ratio (W FRt ), which is included in research is intentionally simplistic. Alternatively, an
Equation (2), is conceptually identical to the needs equation, or series of equations, could be used to
funded ratio calculation (in Equation (1)), but the determine adjustments. For example, a time component

8
Redefining the Optimal Retirement Income Strategy

needs liability they could be allocated to wants spend-


Table 1. Real Spending Adjustment ing, and to the extent a surplus exists (i.e., the wants
Thresholds by Funding Ratio Level goal is overfunded), remaining monies could even be
for Wants Spending invested in an “excess” portfolio (or just be invested in
a wants portfolio). This concept is depicted visually in
Funded Ratio Change % Figure 2 for three different hypothetical households.
0.00 –20% In Figure 2 we see that the potential portfolio alloca-
0.25 –15% tions vary materially depending the asset and liability
0.50 –10%
composition. The underlying portfolios for the
0.75 –5%
respective liabilities could vary both in terms of the
1.00 0%
1.25 2% allocation to risky assets (e.g., equities) as well as
1.50 4% underlying asset classes (e.g., weights to nominal ver-
1.75 8% sus inflation-linked bonds).
2.00 10%
This idea of segmenting assets based on the objective
is very much related to the growing field of goals-
could also be considered (e.g., remaining duration of based investing. Thaler (1985) introduced the idea of
goal), in addition to funded status, type of goal (e.g., mental accounting (“buckets”), and Shefrin and
needs versus wants), portfolio risk level, and so on. The Statman (2000) more formally introduced the idea of
goal of this research is not to opine on optimal model- behavioral portfolio theory. Creating distinct portfolios
for each goal may result in strategies that are more
ing parameters, since these are going to be at least
behaviorally efficient, something that has been dis-
somewhat endogenous to the other modeling assump-
cussed by Brunel (2003), Nevins (2004), and Chhabra
tions (e.g., asset returns, mortality assumptions, dis-
(2005), among others, and results in portfolios that
count rates), but rather to provide a general framework
are not necessarily any less efficient than strategies
that can easily be iterated on (and improved by others).
employing more traditional methods depending on the
The dynamic spending model is conceptually similar to evaluation metrics used (Das et al. 2010).
some existing approaches, yet is more functional
The “matching” aspect of the funded ratio methodology
because it is more comprehensive in nature. For
to respective spending goals may be attractive to asset
example, Waring and Siegel (2015) determine spending
managers who want more targeted individualized port-
dynamically based on an annually recalculated virtual
folios and may be explored further in future research.
annuity. While the Waring and Siegel approach should
work reasonably well in a projection with constant cash
flows, it focuses on the portfolio assets and does not
jointly consider liabilities as well as future potential
Redefining the Optimal Outcome
Retirees clearly have the ability to adjust spending
cash flows (e.g., income from a deferred income annu-
(i.e., portfolio withdrawals) during retirement (i.e., the
ity) and therefore is unlikely to yield optimal guidance
retirement goal is not entirely inelastic), and we have
across a more robust set of retiree scenarios.
introduced a model that can dynamically adjust with-
drawals and that accounts for varying levels of
Asset/Liability Mapping spending elasticity. Next, we introduce a utility model
to more accurately capture the expected satisfaction
One potential benefit associated with splitting up the
of accomplishing a retirement goal.
retirement income goal is that it allows more targeted
portfolios to be created, where assets can be While utility metrics are relatively common in academic
“mapped” to the respective spending liability. This has research on optimal retirement strategies (e.g., used by
attractive behavioral implications and is consistent Yaari [1965] in his pioneering research on the potential
with other approaches such as bucketing, which is a value of annuities) and are far more adaptive than suc-
time segmentation approach. For example, if the cess-related metrics, they are relatively rare in financial
assumed target funded ratio for needs spending planning tools. Utility functions can be somewhat
(N FRt ) is one, the amount of portfolio assets (At ) unstable and often do not yield outcomes metrics that
required to fund that respective spending goal could would be generally accessible to financial advisors and
be determined and monies could be invested specific- especially clients, two potential reasons for their gen-
ally to fund that goal. If available funds exceed the eral lack of popularity among non-academics.

Volume 79, Number 1 9


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Figure 2. Portfolio Allocations Based on Asset and Liability Structure

The most common utility functions in retirement Total utility is based on the percentage of the overall
research assume Constant Relative Risk Aversion goal that is defined as a need (n), or is nondiscretion-
(CRRA), which is based on the idea of diminishing ary, as well as the assumed income risk aversion level
marginal utility. In this framework, each additional unit (c) for that level income. The risk aversion parameter is
of some good (e.g., consumption) is assumed to result based on whether spending is satisfying a needs goal
in more satisfaction (utility), but at a decreasing rate. or wants goal, based on Equations (3), (4), and (5).
This means that retirees want to spend as much as ! !
i 1
possible, but they must balance the desire to spend If  n then ut ¼ it
n g (3)
g cn
more with a potential shortfall, where shortfalls are ðgðnÞÞ
typically more painful than additional spending. i i
If > n and  1 then
g g
More complex utility functions distinguish risk aversion 0 00 1 11
1 (4)
in a single period from intertemporal risk aversion by ut ¼ @ðgðnÞÞ þ @@ ð1  nÞAAg
using a recursive utility function described by Epstein ðit ðgðnÞÞÞ A
cw
ðgðgðnÞÞÞ
and Zin (1989), where volatility in consumption within 0 1
a given run or assumed lifetime (defined as the elasti- 1
Else ut ¼ @ ce Ag (5)
city of intertemporal substitution) is considered separ- it
g
ately from the volatility of consumption across runs
(generally defined as general risk tolerance).
Although the model only assumes two primary types
For this research, we use a utility function based on of goals (needs and wants), the model could easily be
prospect theory, a field introduced by Kahneman and extended to consider additional types of spending
Tversky (1979). Prospect theory suggests that individu- goals (e.g., wishes).
als evaluate outcomes based on a specific reference
point and that deviations from this value (positive and If we assume an income risk aversion levels of 4, 1,
negative) are valued differently (i.e., losses receive more and 0.25 for cn , cw , and ce , respectively, we can gen-
weight than gains). More specifically, prospect theory erate expected utility values for various levels of
suggests that individual utility functions are concave in spending. These are included in Figure 3, where the
the domain of gains and convex in the domain of losses. assumed “need” (n) is either 50% or 90% of the total
retirement income goal, in Panels A and B, respectively.
Our research uses a utility model with three specific
ranges, where the utility derived from a given level of Figure 3 demonstrates that the expected level of utility
spending (i.e., consumption) depends on how that from a given spending level using this model can vary
spending relates to the retiree’s total income goal for significantly depending on the composition of a retire-
that respective year. More specifically, the expected ment goal (i.e., needs versus wants), even if the same
utility (u) of a given amount of income (i) for a given income level is achieved. For example, if we assume the
year (t) is based on the respective total income goal (g). total income goal is $100,000 and the retiree realizes

10
Redefining the Optimal Retirement Income Strategy

Figure 3. Utility of Income for Various Goal Funding and Needs Levels

A. Need = 50% of Goal B. Need = 90% of Goal

1.20 1.20
1.00 1.00
0.80 0.80
Utility

Utility
0.60 0.60
0.40 0.40
0.20 0.20
0.00 0.00
0% 25% 50% 75% 100% 0% 25% 50% 75% 100%
% of Total Retirement % of Total Retirement
Goal Funded Goal Funded

Need Want Need Want

$50,000 (i.e., 50% of the target), the result would be considered equally in the calculation, q would be set
0.5 units of utility if the need represents 50% of the to zero, where the resulting statistic would be a sim-
goal (Panel A) versus only approximately 0.1 units of ple average of annual income utility levels.
utility if the need represents 90% of the goal (Panel B).
The overall expected utility of a given strategy is
These differences demonstrate how two retirees with measured using the CRRA utility function with a risk
similar total spending goals (and income levels) could tolerance parameter (k) as noted in Equation (7), where
have very different retirement funding strategies R is the number of paths (or runs), pi is the probability
depending on the composition of their assets and of path i occurring (which is set to 1/R, i.e., the num-
overall funded status. For example, allocating to guar- ber of runs), and Ut would be the certainty-equivalent
anteed income would generally be more attractive for of the stochastic utility-adjusted income II:
retirees whose “needs” represent a higher portion of " #k1
the spending goal to reduce the uncertainty (and asso- XR
k
Ut ¼ pi ðIIi Þ (7)
ciated shortfall), especially for those who do not i¼1
already have guaranteed income sources (e.g., Social
Security retirement benefits) to cover needs spending. When considering multiple strategies (e.g., spending lev-
Given the expected utility for a level of spending in a els, portfolio risk levels, annuity allocations) the optimal
given year (ut ), estimated using Equations (3), (4), and/ strategy would be the one that maximizes Ut :
or (5), we can estimate the constant amount of income We generate an outcomes metric that should be rela-
with the same utility as the actual income path (II). This tively accessible to investors by dividing the cer-
would be the utility-equivalent constant income level tainty-equivalent utility-adjusted income (Ut ) by the
and provides insight into the elasticity of intertemporal income goal (g), yielding a metric we refer to as the
substitution. This is given by Equation (6), where ut is “goal completion score” as noted in Equation (8).
the utility-adjusted income in year t, qt is the probabil-
ity of surviving to at least year t, T is the final year of Ut
Goal Completion Score ¼ (8)
retirement (i.e., the length of the assumed simulation), g
and q is the investor’s subjective real discount rate.
0 P 1 This metric provides context around the percentage of
T t
q ð 1 þ qÞ u the goal completed, adjusted for utility. The goal com-
B t¼0 t t
C
II ¼ @ PT t A
(6) pletion score can be used to convey the overall effi-
q
t¼0 t
ð1 þ q Þ
cacy of a given strategy to a retiree, that is in the spirit
of more common metrics used in financial plans, such
To assume a fixed retirement period (e.g., 30 years), a as the probability of success (higher is better, with a
user would set qt to one and T to the target length target of 100), but is more holistic in that it considers
of retirement. If a user wanted each year to be preferences around spending elasticity.

Volume 79, Number 1 11


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

The utility model developed in this paper is focused on male and female, both aged 65, retiring immediately.
accomplishing a single type of goal. In reality, a house- The retiree couple has an $80,000 total retirement
hold may have multiple financial goals that could differ income goal, that is assumed to increase annually by
significantly in terms of timing, size, and scope (e.g., inflation, of which 70% is classified as being a “need”
retirement income, bequest, college funding). With ($56,000 of the total $80,000 goal).
respect to this model, each goal should likely be con-
The retiree couple will receive $40,000 in annual Social
sidered separately; however, assets available for fund-
Security benefits (which increase with inflation) and will
ing each goal could be considered jointly, which would
therefore have to generate the remaining $40,000 from
require some ordering logic given potential competing
$1 million in assumed total retirement savings (i.e.,
priorities. Alternatively, specific accounts could be allo- which is consistent with the often-noted “4% Rule”).
cated to fund each goal without overlap. While in the-
ory, all goals could be considered jointly, as a single Key model parameters are included in Appendix A and
goal, this utility model is designed for goals that are the assumed equity glide path in retirement is
relatively similar over time. Nevertheless, there are included in Appendix B. Figure 4 provides insight into
ways to adjust the respective weights if multiple goals the distribution of income at various percentiles, as
are considered, for example, goals based on how the well as context around where the respective income
income utility values are weighted and combined. level falls across the needs and wants income goals.

One additional potential concern with the utility We can see that for the vast majority of runs, the
function is that it would generally suggest that “needs” goal is fully achieved for the entire duration
underfunded households (i.e., those headed toward of retirement. Even for the worst one in 20 runs (the
ruin) would prefer a riskier portfolio, which may not fifth percentile) the goal is still accomplished up until
be practical. This issue is not necessarily unique to the last year of retirement, where the total income
this model though. Therefore, while this model is generated is $42,263, or 75% of inflation-adjusted
designed to more accurately capture retiree preferen- needs goal for that year. Note, had the income
amount not been adjusted downward throughout the
ces than other more common metrics (e.g., the prob-
simulation, the portfolio would have been depleted
ability of success), it is not without its weakness.
sooner, potentially much sooner based on the trial.

While total spending is expected to decline, in real


Analysis terms, for approximately 30% of scenarios moving
This section provides additional context on the model through retirement (with the spending level below the
in a stochastic setting. For our base scenario, we initial $80,000, in today’s dollars), the reductions largely
assume the retiree household to be a joint couple, only affect the “wants” spending goal, and in

Figure 4. Distribution of Simulation Outcomes

$120
Real Annual Total Income ($0,000s)

Wants
$100

$80

$60
Needs
$40

$20

$0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30
Year of Retirement

Percentiles: 5th 25th 50th 75th 95th

12
Redefining the Optimal Retirement Income Strategy

approximately 70% of scenarios total real income is


actually expected to increase during retirement. Viewing Table 2. Optimal Retirement Strategies
the continuum of potential retirement outcomes through Using Goal Completion Score as
this lens (i.e., as the distribution of potential income) pro- the Outcomes Metric
vides a very different perspective than one using a trad-
itional analysis with a static spending assumption where Need % of Goal
the outcome is defined based on the probability of suc- 30% 50% 70% 90%
cess. For example, the probability of success for this
simulation is 70.2% (assuming a static real income goal), A. Optimal initial withdrawal rate (%)
while the goal completion score is 98.2%. Pension Income $10k 4.1 4.0 4.0 3.8
$30k 4.5 4.4 4.2 3.9
While a probability of success of 70.2% is not neces- $50k 5.1 4.8 4.6 4.0
sarily a bad outcome, it does not convey the same $70k 5.4 5.3 5.0 4.0
level of (high) certainty as a 98.2% goal completion $90k 5.3 5.4 5.4 4.0
B. Optimal portfolio static equity allocation (%)
score. In other words, while the probability of success
Pension Income $10k 50 40 40 25
implies a decent amount of uncertainty regarding the
$30k 55 55 45 35
retirement income goal (29.8% probability of failure, $50k 65 60 45 40
or adjustment, depending on one’s perspective), the $70k 70 65 50 40
actual likelihood of the retirees in this scenario not $90k 75 75 55 45
largely accomplishing their retirement income goal, C. Optimal annuity allocation (%)
especially the amount they need, is incredibly low. Pension Income $10k 50 50 50 50
$30k 25 30 35 40
This model can lead to notable differences in recom- $50k 10 15 30 30
mendations around factors like safe initial withdrawal $70k 0 0 15 25
rates, optimal portfolio equity allocations, and recom- $90k 0 0 5 10
mendation to annuities across various household scen-
arios. We demonstrate this in various panels in Table 2,
which are based on an additional set of analyses.
For example, in Table 2, optimal initial withdrawal
In Panel A, we solve for the initial withdrawal rate that rates (Panel A) and equity allocations (Panel B)
yields a 95% goal completion score3 for various scen- are highest for retirees who have higher levels of
arios. In Panel B, we solve for the optimal portfolio guaranteed income and more elasticity with
equity allocation, assuming a 5% initial withdrawal respect to retirement spending, while annuity alloca-
rate. In Panel C, we solve for the optimal allocation to tions (Panel C) are highest for retirees who have
an immediate annuity, assuming a 5% initial withdrawal lower levels of guaranteed income and less elasticity
rate and a nominal annuity payout rate of 4.75% (with with respect to retirement spending using this model.
a maximum potential allocation of 50%).
The differences in Table 2 can have notable implica-
As a reminder, if the outcomes metric is the probability tions for things like required retirement savings. For
of success, then the percentage of the goal that is example, focusing on withdrawal rates (Panel A), an
defined as needs and the relative amount of guaranteed initial withdrawal rate of 3.8% (low pension income
income (holding the portfolio value constant) has no and high needs goal) effectively requires 36.8% more
impact on optimal initial withdrawal rates, equity alloca- savings than an initial withdrawal rate of 5.2% (high
tion, or annuity allocations, especially if taxes are pension income and low needs goal). This is a stag-
ignored. In other words, the values in Panels A, B, and C gering difference. Alternatively, the higher with-
should not vary if the probability of success is the out- drawal rate implies the household could spend
comes metric. This is because the probability of success significantly more in retirement. Additionally, the
focuses entirely on the marginal role of the portfolio potential benefit of allocating to an annuity (Panel C)
when it comes to funding the liability and does not con- varies, whereby retirees who already have high levels
sider magnitude of failure (or allow for dynamic adjust- of guaranteed income and a relatively flexible spend-
ments). The results in Table 2, though, clearly ing goal clearly benefit less from annuitization.
demonstrate that a more nuanced perspective of house-
hold assets and preferences can have a significant Overall, the results of this section suggest that using
impact on optimal retirement strategies if appropri- the retirement income models introduced in this
ately considered. piece, which incorporate dynamic withdrawals and

Volume 79, Number 1 13


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

spending elasticity and can account for expected util- the expected satisfaction across outcomes. While
ity across income levels, can lead to notably different there are a number of other existing approaches simi-
retirement recommendations for retirees, especially lar to those introduced in this research, most of these
when compared to outputs generated from probabil- approaches are relatively narrowly focused and cannot
ity of success-related metrics. easily be used to generate a more comprehensive per-
spective on retirement modeling. This research is
unique in introducing models specifically designed to
Conclusions work together that be easily configured and allow for
Despite significant advances in computing power and a variety of client scenarios and user assumptions.
a relatively extensive body of research on the nature
of retirement, assumptions in retirement research There are a number of potential extensions associ-
and income planning tools have evolved only mod- ated with this research, such as extending the model
estly over the last 30 years. This lack of evolution has to include additional goals (e.g., wishes), determining
created an environment where many financial advi- optimal portfolio allocations for the different types of
sors and online calculators provide overly simplistic “mapped” goals (e.g., needs and wants), determining
advice on one of the most important (and expensive) the optimal parameters to use with the funded ratio
decisions made by households: how much they need dynamic spending rule, as well as exploring the more
to save for retirement (and can spend during it). general parameters in the model.

This research builds off of decades of existing litera- In closing, given the significant time and energy asso-
ture in the retirement income space and introduces a ciated with funding retirement, it is important that
series of models that can improve retirement income the estimate be as accurate as possible. This research
projections by better understanding the elasticity of demonstrates that existing retirement planning
spending, modeling changes in spending based on frameworks (and tools) have notable deficiencies that
changes in finances, and determining the optimal should be addressed to ensure retirees (and savers)
strategy using a utility function that better quantifies receive the best guidance and advice possible.

Appendices

Appendix A. Modeling Assumptions

Assumption Regarding Variable Value

Income goal g $80,000 (varies)


% of goal that is need n 70% (varies)
Risk aversion factor for needs spending cn 4
Risk aversion factor for wants spending cw 1
Risk aversion factor for excess spending ce 0.25
Length of projection/end of retirement T 30
Number of simulation runs/trials R 1,000
Probability of survival qt 1 (fixed retirement period)
Discount rate for EOIS calculation q 0
Risk aversion factor for certainty-equivalent k 2
Nominal discount rate for needs spending rn 5%
Nominal discount rate for wants spending rw 4%
Nominal discount rate for inflows (guaranteed income) rp 3%
Inflation 2%
Equity, annual arithmetic return 7.5%
Equity annual standard deviation 20%
Bonds, annual arithmetic return 2.5%
Bonds, annual standard deviation 5%
Stock/bond correlation 0.0
Taxes are ignored for the analysis

EOIS ¼ Elasticity of intertemporal substitution.

14
Redefining the Optimal Retirement Income Strategy

Appendix B. Equity Glide Path

100%

80%
Equity Allocation

60%

40%

20%

0%
50 60 70 80 90 100
Age

Editor's Note
Submitted 11 February 2022
Accepted 26 September 2022 by William N. Goetzmann

Notes
1. Other notable research includes Milevsky, Ho, and 3. This is a subjective target and can obviously vary by user
Robinson (1997) and Cooley, Hubbard, and Waltz (1998). or client.

2. https://www.bls.gov/cex/pumd.htm

References
Bengen, William. 1994. “Determining Withdrawal Rates Using Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 45 (2): 311–34.
Historical Data.” Journal of Financial Planning 7 (4): 171–80. doi:10.1017/S0022109010000141.
Bengen, William. 2001. “Conserving Client Portfolios during Epstein, Larry G., and Stanley E. Zin. 1989. “Substitution Risk
Retirement, Part IV.” Journal of Financial Planning 14 (5): 110–9. Aversion and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and
Asset Returns: A Theoretical Framework.” Econometrica 57 (4):
Blanchett, David, and Larry Frank. 2009. “A Dynamic and
937–69. doi:10.2307/1913778.
Adaptive Approach to Distribution Planning and Monitoring.”
Journal of Financial Planning 22 (4): 52–66. Finke, Michael, Wade D. Pfau, and David M. Blanchett. 2013. “The 4
Brunel, Jean. 2003. “Revisiting the Asset Allocation Challenge Percent Rule Is Not Safe in a Low-Yield World.” Journal of Financial
through a Behavioral Finance Lens.” The Journal of Wealth Planning 26 (6): 46–55. https://www.financialplanningassociation.
Management 6 (2): 10–20. doi:10.3905/jwm.2003.320479. org/article/4-percent-rule-not-safe-low-yield-world

Chhabra, Ashvin. 2005. “Beyond Markowitz: A Comprehensive Guyton, Jonathan. 2004. “Decision Rules and Portfolio
Wealth Allocation Framework for Individuals.” The Journal of Management for Retirees: Is the ‘Safe’ Initial Withdrawal Rate
Wealth Management 7 (4): 8–34. doi:10.3905/jwm.2005.470606. Too Safe?” Journal of Financial Planning 17 (10): 54–62.

Cooley, Phillip, Carl Hubbard, and Daniel Waltz. 1998. Habib, Faisal, Huaxiong Huang, and Moshe Milevsky. 2017.
“Retirement Spending: Choosing a Sustainable Withdrawal “Approximate Solutions to Retirement Spending Problems and
Rate.” Journal of the American Association of Individual Investors the Optimality of Ruin.” Working paper, version March 31 2017.
20 (2): 16–21.
Idzorek, Thomas, and David Blanchett. 2019. “LDI for Individual
Das, Sanjiv, Harry Markowitz, Jonathan Scheid, and Meir Portfolios.” The Journal of Investing 28 (1): 31–54. doi:10.3905/
Statman. 2010. “Portfolio Optimization with Mental Accounts.” joi.2019.28.1.031.

Volume 79, Number 1 15


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos Tversky. 1979. “Prospect Theory: Rubinstein, Mark. 1976. “The Strong Case for the Generalized
An Analysis of Decision under Risk.” Econometrica 47 (2): Logarithmic Utility Model as the Premier Model of Financial
263–91. doi:10.2307/1914185. Markets.” The Journal of Finance 31 (2): 551–71. doi:10.2307/
Kaplan, Paul, and David Blanchett. 2021. “A Dynamic Spending 2326626.
Rule for All Retirees.” Working Paper. Shefrin, Hersh, and Meir Statman. 2000. “Behavioral Portfolio
Merton, Robert. 1969. “Lifetime Portfolio Selection under Theory.” The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 35
Uncertainty: The Continuous-Time Case.” The Review of (2): 127–51. doi:10.2307/2676187.
Economics and Statistics 51 (3): 247–57. doi:10.2307/1926560.
Stout, Gene, and John Mitchell. 2006. “Dynamic Retirement
Milevsky, Moshe, Kwok Ho, and Chris Robinson. 1997. “Asset Withdrawal Planning.” Financial Services Review 15:117–31.
Allocation via the Conditional First Exit Time or How to Avoid
Outliving Your Money.” Review of Quantitative Finance and Thaler, Richard. 1985. “Mental Accounting and Consumer
Accounting 9 (1): 53–70. doi:10.1023/A:1008278910581. Choice.” Marketing Science 4 (3): 199–214. doi:10.1287/mksc.4.
3.199.
Milevsky, Moshe, and Huaxiong Huang. 2011. “Spending
Retirement on Planet Vulcan: The Impact of Longevity Risk Waring, Barton, and Laurence Siegel. 2015. “The Only
Aversion on Optimal Withdrawal Rates.” Financial Analysts Spending Rule You Will Ever Need.” Financial Analysts Journal
Journal 67 (2): 45–58. doi:10.2469/faj.v67.n2.2. 71 (1): 91–107. doi:10.2469/faj.v71.n1.2.
Nevins, D. 2004. “Goals-Based Investing: Integrating Traditional Waring, Barton, and Laurence Siegel. 2018. “What Investment
and Behavioral Finance” Journal of Wealth Management 6 (4): Risk Means to You, Illustrated: Strategic Asset Allocation, the
8–23. doi:10.3905/jwm.2004.391053. Budget Constraint, and the Volatility of Spending during
Pfau, Wade. 2010. “An International Perspective on Safe Retirement.” The Journal of Retirement 6 (2): 7–26. doi:10.
Withdrawal Rates from Retirement Savings: The Demise of the 3905/jor.2018.1.041.
4 Percent Rule?” Journal of Financial Planning 23 (12): 52–61. Yaari, Menahem. 1965. “Uncertain Lifetime, Life Insurance, and
Pye, Gordon. 2001. “Adjusting Withdrawal Rates for Taxes and the Theory of the Consumer.” The Review of Economic Studies
Expenses.” Journal of Financial Planning 14 (4): 126–36. 32 (2): 137–50. doi:10.2307/2296058.

16
Perspectives Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute
https://doi.org/10.1080/0015198X.2022.2112895

Allocating to Thematic
Investments
Koye Somefun, Romain Perchet , Chenyang Yin, and
Raul Leote de Carvalho
Koye Somefun is the head of Multi-Asset and Solutions in the Quant Research Group at BNP Paribas Asset Management,
Herengracht, Amsterdam, The Netherlands. Romain Perchet is the head of Multi-Assets in the Quant Research Group at BNP Paribas
Asset Management, Paris, France. Chenyang Yin is an analyst in Multi-Assets in the Quant Research Group at BNP Paribas Asset
Management, Paris, France. Raul Leote de Carvalho is the deputy head of the Quant Research Group at BNP Paribas Asset
Management, Paris, France. Send correspondence to Romain Perchet at romain.perchet@bnpparibas.com.

We introduce the notion of Introduction


themes as an additional invest- raditionally, investors categorise their investments into different
ment dimension beyond asset
classes, regions, sectors and
styles, and propose a framework
to allocate to thematic invest-
T asset classes: sovereign bonds, corporate bonds, equities and
others. In each of these, they tend to distinguish between
regions and sectors. Portfolio construction takes this classification into
account, with investors seeking diversification across asset classes
ments at a strategic because doing so can meaningfully reduce the risk of significant losses
asset allocation level. Allocating as each asset class can respond differently to market conditions and
to themes requires discipline changes in the economic environment. Additionally, investors seek to
because thematic investments are diversify across sectors and regions in each asset class because this
not only exposed to the theme helps to mitigate systematic risks caused by factors affecting asset
but also to the traditional risk fac- returns from a given industry or region.
tors. Our approach uses a frame-
work based on robust portfolio Style factors may also be used, in particular for equities (Fama and
optimisation, which accounts for French 1992; Haugen and Baker 1996) but also for corporate bonds
the expected excess return from (Houweling and van Zundert 2017; Israel, Palhares, and Richardson
the exposure to the theme and 2018; Heckel et al. 2019) and sometimes for other asset classes
from exposures to traditional risk (Asness, Moskowitz, and Pedersen 2013). For example, value factors
factors. We provide an example identify assets that are thought to be trading at a discount relative to
to illustrate how thematic invest- their respective fundamental value. Momentum, another style, relies
ments fit in traditional multi- on factors that identify assets by trends in either their prices or in
asset portfolios. their fundamental values. Styles are used because they also tend to
explain some of the correlation of returns of the assets exposed to
Keywords: asset allocation; core the same underlying factors.
satellite; portfolio construction;
portfolio optimisation; thematic Thematic investing brings a new dimension that transcends the
investing; themes classifications based on regions, sectors and styles. Themes are
structural trends expected to significantly impact economies and
Disclosure: The authors report no We are grateful to the editor and to the reviewers for their comments and sugges-
conflicts of interest. The authors alone tions that helped us to significantly improve the manuscript. We are also grateful for
are responsible for the content and valuable comments from Alexander Bernhardt, Clement Dupire, Daniel Morris,
writing of the paper. Edward Lees, François Soupe, Frederic Surry, Guy Davies, Jane Ambachtsheer,
Marco Barbaro, Michael Victoros, Pieter Oyens, Tarek Issaoui, Thomas Heckel, Ulrik
Fugmann, and Yannick Leite Velho.
PL Credits: 0.75

18 © 2022 CFA Institute. All rights reserved. Volume 79, Number 1


Allocating to Thematic Investments

redefine business models. Thus, it is natural to What Is Thematic Investing?


expect themes to play a role in explaining the
We see themes as structural trends expected to sig-
returns and risks of investments with greater nificantly impact economies and business models.
exposure to those structural trends. However, not Thematic investing is about investing in the assets
all themes matter equally, and thematic investing that are more likely to benefit from value creation
offers more than just a single compelling opportun- derived from those themes. Taking into account the
ity. The goal of thematic investing is to identify the growing interest in this type of investment it is nor-
assets that have their returns impacted by the mal to expect some confusion about what should
structural changes underlying the theme. These and should not be considered as thematic invest-
changes come about through megatrends that ments. In the remainder of this section, we define
shape societies: demographic shifts, social or attitu- what we see as thematic investing and how it differs
dinal changes, environmental impact, resource scar- from just investing in growth stocks, or in selected
city, economic imbalances, transfer of power, sectors or industries, and also how it differs from
technological advances and regulatory or political more broad concepts such as ESG investing (taking
changes. An investment theme aims to transform environmental, social and governance factors expli-
one such megatrend into a relevant investment citly into account) or long-term investing.
opportunity.
Is Thematic Investing Just about
According to Morningstar (2021), over the three
Investing in Growth Companies? This is a
years through March 2021, collective assets under
question asked often. The short answer is no. First,
management in thematic funds more than tripled to
themes do not necessarily relate only to equities or
USD 595bn from USD 174bn worldwide. While the-
corporate bonds. For example, some themes may be
matic portfolios have mainly focused on equities,
played via other assets such as public infrastructure
there is also a growing trend to define themes
investments. Second, when it comes to equities or
in fixed income or even in other asset classes. In a
corporate bonds, this is also not necessarily the case.
survey of institutional investors, Walmsley
(2021) reports that approximately 60% of respond- Themes can be relevant to companies in all stages of
ents are already using sustainable thematic invest- their growth cycle. Indeed, some themes may relate
ment strategies in fixed income, as are 50% more to disruption through innovation, for example,
in alternatives. Despite the growing interest in the- disruptive tech, often involving smaller capitalization
matic investing, literature is still scarce, in particular growth firms, whereas other themes such as environ-
when it comes to proposing a robust framework to mental sustainability may see a much larger spectrum
allocate to thematic investments at strategic alloca- of companies taking the lead, including larger capital-
tion level. ization incumbents. What is important when looking
for companies exposed to a theme is that the
In this paper, we contribute to the literature on the- selected firms have a significant exposure or commit-
matic investments in three ways. First, we give an ment of their business to activities related to the
introduction to the topic, highlighting what should be theme and either generate or plan to generate a sig-
considered as thematic investing and what it should nificant part of their revenues from selling products
not be confused with. In particular, we defend why or services related to the theme.
we believe that themes can bring an additional
dimension to an asset’s risk decomposition. Second, Is Thematic Investing Just a Wager on a
we propose a framework to allocating to thematic Particular Industry or Sector? Again, the
investments which are based on robust portfolio short answer is no. For example, a theme may favour
optimisation and that takes into account the expo- a sub-industry or a group of companies that can dis-
sures of thematic investments to the traditional risk rupt an industry because of some cost or size advan-
factors used in asset allocation. This framework tage; or because of new products or services
offers a robust solution to the problem of allocating (particularly if these require patents or licences); or
both traditional assets and to thematic investments due to regulatory protection; or because such groups
in a given portfolio. Third, we illustrate the imple- of companies are motivated by the megatrends that
mentation of the framework with an example that shape societies. Anything that can give a group of
goes beyond allocating only to equity thematic companies a significant advantage that disrupts entire
investments by also including thematic fixed income industries can be useful to identify themes. For this
investments. reason, some narrower themes may come with some

Volume 79, Number 1 19


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

exposure to some sectors but thematic investments change, which is perhaps the biggest challenge
should not be just a bet on a given sector humanity has ever faced and is already having a pro-
or industry. found impact on weather systems and economic out-
comes. Investing around this theme means finding
In recent years, globalisation, regulation and de-regu-
companies well positioned to generate a measurable
lation trends, digitalisation and innovation, and
impact while profiting from this structural change.
energy transition are examples of themes that have
Indeed, most impact investing is thematic investing.
played an important role in changing the balance of
It is worth noting that we would not consider inves-
forces that can make certain industries more or less
ting in the market capitalisation index re-weighted
susceptible to disruption.
after excluding just a few of the biggest carbon emit-
Thematic, ESG, and Long-Term Investing ters as an example of thematic or impact investing.
Are Easily Confused. It is also important to Such an approach is typically just a low tracking error
make the difference between thematic investing, ESG climate risk mitigation strategy designed to limit
investing and long-term investing. downside risk from the transition to low carbon,
rather than a higher tracking error investment in
While thematic investing entails a focus on trends energy transition leaders.
that often materialise in the medium to longer term,
this is not always the case. Some themes may run What Is the Appeal of Thematic
their course faster and find themselves discounted
Investing? Thematic investing provides investors
by the market quicker than others. It is important to
with the means to focus on investments well posi-
evaluate to what extent a theme still remains a good
tioned to profit from transformative changes, identi-
investment opportunity. Some themes of the past
fying the current and future champions for each
may have reached maturity and it is important to
trend. Those champions should benefit from an out-
judge to what extent they remain an attractive
sized impact from value creation. It is also a means
investment opportunity. Moreover, the granularity of
to stay out of assets more negatively exposed to
themes may be important. This is because some
such trends. The flipside of the coin is that investors
themes within a broader theme can run their course
may need to accept choppy returns in the shorter
while the overarching drivers remain relevant and
term from less diversified portfolios exposed to
investable, simply with a different set of companies.
In such cases, a bottom-up investment strategy may themes, as the outsized returns tend to be less fre-
be a compelling approach to allocate to sub-themes quent and can arrive suddenly. Moreover, too much
within a given theme. Thematic investing can be exposure to high concentration thematic investments
more subtle than just finding undervalued opportuni- may also result in investors missing out by not inves-
ties to hold over long investment horizons. ting in companies not exposed to their particular
chosen themes. Portfolio construction is thus of
A similar argument can be made for thematic versus paramount importance when it comes to integrating
ESG investing. Not all ESG investing is necessarily thematic investing in a larger portfolio.
thematic investing. There is a difference between
companies simply pursuing sustainable practices and Allocating to Thematic Investing. Thematic
those deriving or committed to derive a significant investing may be appealing, but how can we add it
component of their revenues from services and prod- to a portfolio? There is no single answer as it
ucts related to sustainable themes such as energy depends on a number of parameters such as the size
transition or environmental sustainability. Investors
and the level of diversification of the portfolio. One
turn to ESG in search of investments that integrate
simple approach is to rely on a core-satellite frame-
material environmental, social or governance factors
work adding thematic investments to the satellite.
in the pursuit of greater financial risk-adjusted
Scherer (2015) proposes the use of this framework
returns, which is something that transcends thematic
for deciding about the allocation to passive and
investing: ESG integration does not necessarily focus
active managers. Here we extend the application to
on investing in a specific sustainable theme
an allocation that includes thematic investments. This
or themes.
is an adequate solution for many investors, in par-
A desire to drive change in society can also be a ticular for large portfolios investing in low-capacity
motive for thematic investing. A good example is themes, or for smaller investors who prefer to limit
energy transition, a necessary step to address climate their active allocations to thematic investments.

20
Allocating to Thematic Investments

In any case, to do this effectively it is important to and combine the returns of such funds into a return
investigate the impact of adding thematic invest- time series representative of the theme.
ments to the overall risk and return characteristics of
the aggregate portfolio. Therefore, it is preferable Once the times series of returns representing a
and more straightforward to integrate thematic theme is created, we can assess how it relates to
investments directly in the overall allocation. To do other assets selected for the portfolio. In the robust
so, it is necessary to understand each thematic portfolio optimization approach employed in the next
investment in terms of expected risk, return and section, the optimizer allocates by taking into
interaction with other investments. While this may account the systematic exposures of the non-the-
not be easy, quantitative approaches can help, as we matic and thematic investments to a set of risk fac-
shall discuss below. tors whilst potentially adding the expected alpha
from the thematic exposure. Hence, we estimate the
Understanding What Is behind Each exposures of the time series of returns representing
Theme. Allocating to thematic investments requires the theme to the set of risk factors used in the risk
a deep understanding of how they interact with model. The expected returns of thematic investments
other investments. If thematic investments are con- are constructed by taking into account the returns
structed from investing in stocks and bonds then derived from systematic risk exposures to the risk
their expected returns, risk and correlations can be factors and from an additional thematic alpha sized
derived (i) from their exposure to those traditional as a function of how much residual risk is found. The
asset classes, (ii) from their exposure to the trad- thematic alpha should be forward-looking.
itional risk factors of those asset classes such as
For themes that relate to specific sectors of the
regions, styles or sectors and (iii) from an additional
economy, it is not unusual to see those thematic
specific component related to the theme. In other
funds only benchmarked against a relevant sector
words, we need to investigate the extent to which
index. In such cases, it is important to assess the
thematic investments bring something new on top of
expected added value from biasing the selection
their exposures to traditional assets. This is all that is
towards the companies more exposed to the theme
required to integrate thematic investments into our
when compared to the sector and to take into
strategic asset allocation process.
account that an exposure to the sector will itself cre-
How does this work in practice? The more common ate tracking error and excess returns relative to the
themes can usually be represented by existing the- broad equity market. Making sure that the thematic
matic benchmark indices, e.g., those provided by the investment generates sufficient residual risk relative
standard index vendors. Moreover, those indices are to sectors is important because otherwise the the-
often used as benchmarks for the thematic mutual matic investment will be nothing more than just a
funds where active management aims at outperform- sector bet. Diversifying across themes that are biased
ing such benchmarks. Finally, sometimes those indi- towards different sectors is a way of minimising the
ces are also replicated by exchange-traded funds problem of sector exposures.
(ETFs). Thus, thematic benchmark indices are a good
For equity thematic investments, valuations also
starting point.
need to be checked, in particular that the stocks
However, while using thematic benchmark indices behind a given theme are not overpriced. If valua-
brings the advantage of standardisation, return dis- tions are high even after correcting for any sector
persion of investments related to a theme can be exposures, that may suggest that the theme has run
large because there is less consensus on which assets its course. Negative exposure to quality factors not
should be part of a portfolio representing the theme explained by sector tilts is another example of a style
than there is for regions, sectors or perhaps even exposure that needs to be taken into account when
style factor benchmarks. One alternative is to use forecasting thematic returns. In this respect, Blitz
benchmark indices for the same theme from more (2021) found that thematic indices proposed by S&P
than one index provider. Another alternative is to and MSCI, two index providers, invested mainly in
rely on the return time series of the funds selected high volatility, low quality and high valuation stocks.
to invest in a given theme, combining them into a Such style biases, if not just caused by sector biases,
representative return series. When more than one are likely to create a drag on returns that need to be
benchmark index or fund is used, machine learning counter-balanced with sufficiently high thematic
algorithms such as Lasso regressions1 against trad- alpha. If the risk not explained by traditional risk fac-
itional risk factors could be used to efficiently select tor exposures is small then, even if the thematic

Volume 79, Number 1 21


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

alpha is positive, there is a high likelihood that the vehicles to invest in the selected themes, typically
alpha is small and that such thematic indices mutual funds or ETFs replicating thematic indices.
under-perform. Here we consider five themes: (i) disruptive tech, (ii)
environmental sustainability, (iii) sustainable water,
Here we address some of the concerns raised by (iv) sustainable food and (v) energy transition. We
Blitz (2021). Namely, we used thematic indices from selected these themes just as examples to illustrate
other providers than just S&P and MSCI, we diversi- the implementation of the proposed framework for
fied by combining thematic indices from different the allocation of thematic investments. Their choice
providers for the same theme, we chose themes with
was motivated by the fact that we could find the-
different levels of beta, we chose themes with low
matic indices from different providers to represent
exposures to the factors highlighted by Blitz (2021)
them and, as we shall see later, because a sufficiently
and with significant risk derived from more specific-
large portion of the risk of those indices is not
ally from the theme. Moreover, we also investigated
explained by traditional risk factors. That means that
sector exposures, which we believe can be more
these thematic indices do bring some different sour-
important for equity thematic investments than
ces of risk to the portfolio.
style exposures.
Each theme is represented by two equally weighted
thematic equity indices. While more indices could
Allocating to Thematic have been used for each theme, we chose to keep
Investments the example simple. The environmental sustainability
We shall now go through an example of how to allo- theme is also represented separately by a fixed-
cate to thematic investments. income thematic index, which allows us to allocate to
this theme not only using equities but also using
The first step towards an allocation to thematic fixed income. In Table 1, we show the indices
investments starts with the selection of themes and selected to represent the themes.

Table 1. Thematic Indices Used to Represent the Selected Themes


Theme Benchmark Ticker Bloomberg Start_date

Equities Disruptive tech Morningstar Exponential Tech MSEXPONU Index 4-Mar-2015


Net Total Return USD Index
Nasdaq CTA AI NTR Index NQINTELN Index 24-Mar-2008
Sustainable water MSCI Global Sustainable NGESW Index 1-Sep-2010
Water Net Return Index
FTSE Environmental EOWR Index 13-Nov-2008
Opportunities Water
Technology Index
Sustainable food MSCI ACWI IMI Food MXACIFDP Index 30-Nov-2016
Revolution Index
Foxberry Tematica Research FXBYFOOD Index 20-Mar-2015
Sustainable Future of Food
NTR Index
Energy transition ECPI Global Renewable Energy GALPLRWN Index 3-Jan-2011
Liquid NTR
FTSE Environmental EORE Index 13-Nov-2008
Opportunities Renewable
and Alternative Energy Index
Environmental MSCI ACWI IMI Efficient MXACIEEG Index 31-May-2013
sustainability Energy Index Net USD
MSCI Global Environment Net M1CXUNB Index 15-Jul-2016
Return USD Index
Fixed income Environmental Bloomberg MSCI Global Green GBGLTRUU Index 14-Oct-2014
sustainability Bond Index Unhedged USD

Source: Bloomberg, ECPI, Foxberry, FTSE, Morningstar, MSCI and NASDAQ.

22
Allocating to Thematic Investments

In the next two sections, we use time series analysis sustainable food have the lowest volatility, signifi-
to investigate the extent to which the themes repre- cantly lower than that of the high beta equity
sented by these index combinations show persistent themes. In Table 2, we also include the volatility of
exposures to traditional risk factors. In Section the residual returns after removing the beta compo-
“Exposure of Thematic Investments to Regions, nent from returns. This ranges from 6.7% to 13% for
Sectors and Styles,” we use Lasso regressions to find equity themes. The fixed income theme is only 2%,
the exposures of these themes to regions, styles and relatively small compared to the volatility of
sectors represented by a large number of indices. In the index.
Section “Exposure of Thematic Investments to
Traditional Macro Risk Factors,” we use regressions Table 2 also sheds light on the importance of each of
to find the exposures of these themes to the macro the three orthogonal components of thematic indices
risk factors from the asset allocation risk model used returns. Sustainable water equities, energy transition
in the portfolio optimization. equities and environmental sustainability equities do
not have any significant exposure to style factors.
Exposure of Thematic Investments to Sustainable food equities have a small exposure to
Regions, Sectors and Styles. In this section, USA Small Cap Growth while disruptive technology
we investigate the exposure of these themes to equities are slightly more exposed. We also found a
regions, styles and sectors. In our empirical analysis number of sector exposures for some of these
we used 128 equity indices and 46 fixed income indi- themes. Nevertheless, it is important to highlight that
ces representing regions, styles and sectors, which most of these systematic exposures contribute rela-
can be found in Table A2 in Appendix A. In our ana- tively little to risk. The contributions of regions,
lysis, we first estimated the beta of the equity the- styles and sectors to the risk of the beta adjusted
matic indices and its residual returns from a CAPM excess returns of these thematic indices are small
type regression using the MSCI AC index to repre-
except for disruptive tech equities and environmental
sent the global equity market. We did the same for
sustainability fixed income.
the bond thematic index using the Bloomberg
Barclays Global Aggregate Index to represent the glo- It is important to note that the methodology pre-
bal bond market. Finally, we did the same for all sented in this section is quite general and can be
regional, style and sectors indices. In this step, we used to analyze other thematic indices or funds. It
removed the exposure to the market from all those can be helpful for the selection of themes or bench-
indices used as explanatory variables in regressions. mark indices to represent themes.
We then used Lasso regressions to find the regions,
styles and sectors with significant contribution to Exposure of Thematic Investments to
each theme. These regressed the residuals of the Traditional Macro Risk Factors. Here we
thematic indices on the residuals of the region, style look at the exposures of the themes to the factors of
and sector indices. We used data from June 2017 a traditional risk factor model used in asset allocation
through May 2022. The details of the methodology problems. Following the methodology proposed by
are given in Appendix A. Bass, Gladstone, and Ang (2017) and Issaoui et al.
All market data was sourced from Bloomberg. We (2021), we constructed a statistical factor model
used weekly net total returns in USD calculated from using Principal Component Analysis (PCA) to select
Wednesday to Wednesday. All index returns were the set of most significant statistical risk factors from
converted into USD when required. Most global the- the correlation matrix of monthly local currency
matic indices are reported in USD2 without hedging returns of 17 global major assets. The risk model was
the currency risk. The results of our analysis can be estimated with returns from 2003 through 2021. The
found in Table 2. In this table, we retained only indi- list of 17 assets is given in Table A1 in Appendix A.
ces for which significant exposures were found. For
We identified six statistical (but interpretable) risk
this reason, the vast majority of the indices used in
factors that correspond to the first six eigenvectors
the Lasso regression are not included in the table
of the correlation matrix and their corresponding
and can be found only in Appendix A.
eigenvalues. These explain about 87% of the vari-
The results from Table 2 show that only disruptive ance, which is consistent with the finding of Bass
tech and environmental sustainability tend to have et al. (2017) and Issaoui et al. (2021). Table A1 in
high beta. All other themes have neutral or lower Appendix A shows the six eigenvectors represented
beta and lower volatility. Sustainable water and as long-short portfolios.

Volume 79, Number 1 23


24
Table 2. Exposure of Themes to the Market Factor, to Sectors, and to Styles
Equities Fixed Income
Disruptive Sustainable Sustainable Energy Environmental Environmental
Themes Tech Water Food Transition Sustainability Sustainability

Beta Against global market index 1.28 0.93 0.96 1.01 1.26 1.34
Volatility of In excess of cash 22.7% 18.0% 17.2% 19.5% 24.5% 8.3%
thematic returns In excess of beta exposure 8.5% 9.5% 6.7% 9.9% 13.0% 2.0%
In excess of beta, region, style and sector exposures 7.0% 5.8% 2.7% 2.3% 0.0% 1.8%
Explained by regions, style and sectors exposures 4.8% 7.6% 6.2% 9.7% 13.0% 1.0%
Contribution to From regions, styles and sectors exposures 68.3% 36.8% 16.2% 5.5% 0.0% 75.7%
volatility of In excess of regions, styles and sectors exposures 31.7% 63.2% 83.8% 94.5% 100.0% 23.0%
thematic returns
in excess of beta
R2 of regression Thematic returns in excess of beta on 68% 37% 16% 5% 0% 76%
On indices Region, style and sector returns in excess of beta
Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

selected
by Lasso
Beta on styles MSCI USA Small Cap Growth 0.39 0.25
Beta on sectors MSCI Japan Info Tech 0.15
MSCI Emerging Markets Info Tech 0.15
STOXX Europe 600 Oil Gas 0.78
MSCI US Industrials 0.48
MSCI US Info Tech 0.36
MSCI US Utilities 0.26
MSCI Canada Energy 0.33
Bloomberg Barclays Pan Euro Corporate Health Care 0.33
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-European Agg. Local Authorities 0.16

Note: The calculations are based on weekly returns and follow the framework detailed in the appendix. The volatility is annualized with the square root of the time frequency.
Source: Bloomberg, ECPI, Foxberry, FTSE, Morningstar, MSCI and NASDAQ. Authors’ calculations.
Allocating to Thematic Investments

Table 3. Exposures of Themes to Traditional Risk Factors from Asset Allocation Risk Model
Equities Bonds
Environmental Environmental
Disruptive Sustainable Sustainable Energy Sustainability Sustainability
Themes Tech (%) Water (%) Food (%) Transition (%) (%) (%)

Risk factors
Market risk 15.7 8.2 8.3 10.7 15.1 1.7
Duration 3.8 3.8 3.9 4.2 4.3 3.4
EM/Commodities 2.0 0.6 0.6 2.5 2.6 0.6
Corporate spreads 1.9 0.4 0.4 1.1 2.3 0.2
US 3.3 3.8 3.9 2.0 4.1 0.4
Asia/Japan 0.7 3.6 3.6 1.3 1.5 0.3
Systematic volatility 16.7 10.5 10.6 12.1 16.6 3.9
Specific volatility 5.0 4.0 4.0 2.9 5.1 0.8
Thematic volatility 7.9 10.1 8.1 9.7 12.1 0.4
Total volatility 19.2 15.1 13.9 15.8 21.2 4.0

Note: Exposures are measured in units of volatility of returns. The risk model is estimated using returns from Jan-2003 through
Dec-2021. The projections of thematic indices on the factors of the risk model are calculated from a regression against 17 core
assets returns using 5 years of weekly returns from Jun-2017 to May-2022.
Source: Bloomberg, ECPI, Foxberry, FTSE, Morningstar, MSCI and NASDAQ. Authors’ calculations.

The risk factors were named according to the eco- Asia/Japan risk factor. The disruptive tech equity and
nomic interpretation of the underlying long-short environmental sustainability equity themes have add-
portfolios in Table A1. The market risk factor is a itional small positive exposures to the EM/commod-
portfolio invested mainly in risky assets such as equi- ities factor while the other themes have a small but
ties and corporate bonds while excluding government negative exposure to this factor. The environmental
bonds. The duration factor is a portfolio invested sustainability bond theme has a larger exposure to
mainly in interest rate-sensitive assets, including gov- the duration risk factor and a small exposure to the
ernment bonds, corporate credit and emerging debt. market risk factor. Exposures to all other factors are
The corporate spreads factor is a portfolio invested negative but small.
in corporate bonds and short equities and treasuries.
It should not come as a surprise that some of the
The EM/commodity factor is a portfolio mainly
risk of the themes is explained by exposures to the
invested in emerging market assets and commodities.
traditional risk factors in the risk model, as shown in
The US and the Asia/Japan factors are portfolios
Table 3. The systematic volatility refers to the risk
mainly invested in US and Asia/Japan assets, respect-
arising from exposures to the six statistical factors in
ively. These risk factors are orthogonal to each other
the model. The specific volatility in Table 3 is meas-
in the sense that the correlation of returns resulting
ured by taking into account that the risk model relies
from the long-short linear combinations of the under-
only on the first six eigenvectors of the variance
lying equity, fixed income and commodity indices is
covariance matrix and that 13% of total variance is
exactly zero in the sample used to construct the
left unexplained. Finally, the thematic volatility is the
risk model.
risk component that is specific to the themes and is
In Table 3, we show the exposures of the themes to neither accounted for by the systematic risk or the
these six macro risk factors. Themes represented by specific risk of traditional asset classes. The thematic
equity indices have a large component of their total volatility is significant for all equity themes as shown
risk explained by the market risk factor. They also in Table 3.
have a small negative exposure to the duration risk
It is interesting to highlight that in both Tables 2 and
factor, a small positive exposure to the corporate 3, disruptive tech equities exhibit a smaller propor-
spreads risk factors and a small positive exposure to tion of thematic risk than other equity themes.
the US risk factor. Disruptive tech equity, energy
transition equity and environmental sustainability These exposures play an important role in determin-
equity also has a small negative exposure to the ing the final allocation to themes. The fact that the

Volume 79, Number 1 25


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

themes come such exposures to traditional risk fac- remunerated with an information ratio of 0.3. A dif-
tors needs to be taken into account when deciding ferent information ratio could have been used
about the optimal allocation to each theme. depending on the level of confidence that a given
theme will be able to add alpha in the future. While
Strategic Asset Allocation to Thematic we believe most investors choose to allocate to the-
Investments. We considered five different risk matic investments because they expect positive
profiles in our example. This starts with the conser- alpha, in fact, even a zero information ratio could
vative profile for the most risk-averse investors and have been used. In that case, thematic investments
goes all the way to the aggressive profile, for those would only add diversification, much like diversifica-
prepared to take the most risk. The three intermedi- tion assets, which would simply reduce the size of
ate risk profiles are moderately conservative, moder- their allocation in portfolios.
ate and moderately aggressive, in order of falling
risk aversion. The estimated returns for each core asset, for each
diversifying asset and for each thematic investment,
We separate assets into four high-capacity core along with the asset allocation risk model, were used
assets and twelve lower-capacity satellite assets. as inputs for the portfolio construction. We used a
The core assets are Equity Europe, Equity North robust optimisation approach to portfolio construc-
America for equities and Bond EUR Investment tion. Unlike mean-variance optimisation, robust opti-
Grade Aggregate and Bond USD Investment Grade misation takes into account the uncertainty in the
Aggregate, which include treasuries and corporate asset return estimates and significantly reduces the
bonds, for fixed income. In turn, the twelve satellite sensitivity of the final portfolio to small changes in
assets are divided into two groups. The first is made expected returns. The description of the framework
of six diversification assets: Equity Eurozone Small based on robust optimisation can be found in Yin,
Cap, Equity North America Small Cap, Equity Pacific Perchet, and Soupe  (2021). Details about how the
Japan, Equity Global Emerging Markets, Equity allocation of robust portfolios is constructed from
Listed Real Estate Pan Europe, Bond Global the robust optimisation algorithm was investigated
Emerging Market. The second is made of one secu- by Perchet et al. (2016).
lar theme, Disruptive Tech Equities, and four sus-
tainable themes, Sustainable Water Equities, The results from applying this framework to the con-
Sustainable Food Equities, Energy Transition struction of three portfolios for each of the five risk
Equities and Environmental Sustainability Equities profiles are shown in Tables 4 and 5. For each risk
and Bonds. This last theme will be invested using profile, we constructed three different portfolios. The
equities and bonds. first, A, is allowed to invest only in core assets. The
other two, B and C, are based on a core-satellite
We shall skip the information about the core and approach where the portfolio is also allowed to
diversification asset exposures to the traditional fac- invest in diversification assets for B, and in diversifi-
tors in the asset allocation risk model. However, as cation assets and thematic investments for C.
should be expected, these were taken into account Investments in diversification assets and in themes
in the portfolio construction along with the expo- represent the satellite of such portfolios. An aversion
sures in Table 3 for the thematic investments. to tracking error relative to the portfolio of the same
We used long-term estimates of asset returns going risk profile invested only in core assets, A, regulates
as far back as 1954 for the core and the diversifica- the size of the satellite. The portfolios are con-
tion assets in the portfolio construction step. Long- strained to be fully invested, i.e., neither leverage nor
term Sharpe ratio of traditional asset classes varies short-selling is allowed.
between 0.3 and 0.4. These were used to construct
long-term expected returns for the six traditional risk  Portfolio A—Core assets only
factors in our risk model since they are just linear As should be expected, for portfolios invested in
combinations of traditional assets. For the diversify- core assets only, A, the allocation to riskier assets
ing assets and for the thematic investments, the increases as the risk aversion is reduced. While the
expected returns were constructed by taking into conservative portfolio invests almost 60% in cash,
account their exposures to the traditional risk factors the riskier aggressive portfolio invests only in equi-
over the last five years. For the thematic invest- ties. The falling Sharpe ratio is a consequence of the
ments, we added an additional expected positive fully invested constraint. Nevertheless, despite the
alpha by assuming that the thematic risk will be lower Sharpe ratios, the riskier portfolio is still

26
Table 4. Asset Weights for Five Strategic Asset Allocation Portfolios with Different Risk Profiles
Portfolio Weights (%)

Satellite

Volume 79, Number 1


Core Diversification Thematic Investments

Equities Bonds Cash Equities Bonds Equities Bonds Equities

EUR USD Euro North Global Listed Global


North Investment Investment Zone America Pacific Emerging Real Estate Emerging Disruptive Sustainable Sustainable Energy Global Env.
Risk Profile Europe America Grade Agg. Grade Agg. Cash Small Cap. Small Cap. Japan Markets Pan Europe Markets Tech Water Food Transition Environment—Equities Sustainability—Bonds

A Conservative 6.1 7.3 10.2 17.6 58.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Moderately 17.3 20.8 22.7 39.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
conservative
Moderate 27.4 32.8 12.9 26.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Moderately 36.9 43.9 3.3 15.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
aggressive
Aggressive 49.2 50.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
B Conservative 4.4 3.8 13.6 14.5 55.4 1.3 1.8 0.7 0.8 1.5 2.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Moderately 14.0 13.8 26.0 33.2 0.0 2.2 3.8 0.8 1.0 2.3 2.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
conservative
Moderate 23.6 24.2 15.9 20.9 0.0 2.8 4.8 0.9 1.1 2.5 3.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Moderately 32.9 34.5 6.1 10.0 0.0 3.1 5.3 0.9 1.1 2.6 3.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
aggressive
Aggressive 44.0 40.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 4.0 5.2 1.9 1.6 2.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
C Conservative 2.9 0.0 6.4 8.2 53.6 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.0 1.3 1.6 3.0 1.6 1.6 2.3 1.1 15.1
Moderately 11.8 8.9 16.9 23.3 0.0 2.0 0.0 0.4 0.0 2.4 1.9 3.6 2.5 2.8 3.0 1.8 18.7
conservative
Moderate 21.2 19.2 7.5 11.5 0.0 2.6 0.0 0.4 0.0 2.6 1.9 3.8 2.8 3.3 3.3 2.1 17.7
Moderately 30.4 29.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.8 0.0 0.5 0.0 2.7 2.2 3.9 3.0 3.6 3.4 2.3 15.7
aggressive
Aggressive 42.1 35.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.9 0.8 0.9 0.0 2.2 0.0 5.2 1.9 1.9 2.8 2.6 0.0

Note: Risk model estimation from Jan-2003 through Dec-2021 using monthly USD returns. The projections of thematic indices on the factors of the risk model are based on regres-
sions using five years of weekly returns from Jun-2017 to May-2022. Estimates of long-term returns rely on data from Jan-1954. For illustration purposes only. Past performance is
not indicative of future performance.
Source: Bloomberg, ECPI, Foxberry, FTSE, Morningstar, MSCI and NASDAQ. Authors’ calculations.

27
Allocating to Thematic Investments
28
Table 5. Portfolio Statistics and Aggregated Asset Weights for the Five Strategic Asset Allocation Portfolios with Different Risk
Levels in Table 4
Portfolio Statistics Portfolio Weights (%)
Satellite
Annualized Tracking
Excess Return Annualized Sharpe Error Relative Thematic
Risk Profile over Cash (%) Volatility (%) Ratio to Core (%) Equities Bonds Cash Core Satellite Diversification Investments
Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

A Conservative 0.8 1.8 0.46 0.0 13.4 27.8 58.8 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Moderately conservative 2.3 5.0 0.45 0.0 38.1 61.9 0.0 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Moderate 3.3 8.0 0.41 0.0 60.3 39.7 0.0 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Moderately aggressive 4.3 11.0 0.39 0.0 80.8 19.2 0.0 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Aggressive 5.2 14.0 0.37 0.0 100.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
B Conservative 1.1 2.2 0.51 0.7 14.3 30.3 55.4 91.7 8.3 8.3 0.0
Moderately conservative 2.6 5.4 0.48 0.8 38.0 62.0 0.0 86.9 13.1 13.1 0.0
Moderate 3.6 8.3 0.44 0.9 60.0 40.0 0.0 84.6 15.4 15.4 0.0
Moderately aggressive 4.6 11.3 0.41 0.9 80.5 19.5 0.0 83.5 16.5 16.5 0.0
Aggressive 5.3 14.0 0.38 0.7 100.0 0.0 0.0 85.0 15.0 15.0 0.0
C Conservative 1.4 2.3 0.62 0.8 15.2 31.2 53.6 71.1 28.9 4.2 24.7
Moderately conservative 3.0 5.4 0.55 1.1 39.1 60.9 0.0 60.9 39.1 6.6 32.5
Moderate 4.1 8.3 0.49 1.1 61.5 38.5 0.0 59.4 40.6 7.5 33.0
Moderately aggressive 5.0 11.3 0.45 1.2 82.1 17.9 0.0 60.0 40.0 8.2 31.8
Aggressive 5.7 13.9 0.41 1.0 100.0 0.0 0.0 77.7 22.3 7.9 14.4

Note: Based on the same calculations used for Table 4. For illustration purposes only. Past performance is not indicative of future performance.
Source: Bloomberg, ECPI, Foxberry, FTSE, Morningstar, MSCI and NASDAQ. Authors’ calculations.
Allocating to Thematic Investments

Table 6. Risk Exposures of Selected Asset Allocation Portfolios from Table 4


Conservative Moderate Aggressive
Portfolios A (%) B (%) C (%) A (%) B (%) C (%) A (%) B (%) C (%)

Risk factors
Market risk 1.6 2.1 2.2 7.4 7.8 7.9 12.5 12.6 12.6
Duration 0.3 0.5 0.5 1.3 1.1 1.1 4.2 4.2 4.1
EM/Commodities 0.4 0.4 0.3 1.6 1.5 1.4 2.5 2.5 2.3
Corporate spreads 0.4 0.3 0.3 1.0 0.9 0.9 1.2 1.3 1.3
US 0.3 0.2 0.3 1.2 1.1 1.1 1.6 1.6 1.6
Asia/Japan 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.6
Systematic volatility 1.8% 2.2 2.3 7.8 8.2 8.2 13.5 13.6 13.6
Specific volatility 0.2 0.2 0.0 1.7 1.4 1.3 3.4 3.1 3.0
Thematic volatility 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.0 0.0 0.6 0.0 0.0 0.6
Total volatility 1.8 2.2 2.3 8.0 8.3 8.3 14.0 14.0 13.9

Note: Based on the same calculations used for Table 4.


Source: Bloomberg, ECPI, Foxberry, FTSE, Morningstar, MSCI and NASDAQ. Authors’ calculations.

expected to deliver higher returns than the less risky in A ranging from 0.8% for the conservative portfolio
portfolios invested only in core assets. to 1.2% for the moderately aggressive portfolio.

It is interesting to see that some sustainable thematic


 Portfolio B—Core assets and diversifica-
investments in C simply replace some of the diversifi-
tion satellite
cation assets in B, as is the case for Global Equity
If we allow for a satellite invested in diversifying
Emerging Markets which no longer shows up in the
assets, then we find higher expected returns for the
portfolios. The allocation to core assets is also
core-satellite portfolios than for their counterparts
affected, with the allocation to core equities and
invested only in core assets. The size of the satellite
core fixed income significantly reduced. Finally,
in portfolio B increases with falling risk aversion from
Environmental Sustainability bonds, less risky than
about 8% for the conservative portfolio to more than
equity thematic investments, take a larger weight in
15% for the riskier portfolios. The allocation to riskier
the satellite. Of course, the choice of themes and
assets in the satellite increases with falling risk aver-
their exposures to traditional risk factors, as well as
sion, for example if the aggressive portfolio no longer
the expected returns used as an input, play a key
invests in emerging bonds. As expected, all Sharpe
role in explaining these results. The fact that the-
ratios and expected returns are higher for this more
matic investments come with an additional positive
diversified portfolio in B than for their respective
alpha plays an important role in the final allocations.
counterparts in A. The tracking error resulting from
the satellite ranges from 0.7% for the conservative
Strategic Risk Allocation to Thematic
and aggressive portfolios to 0.9% for the moderate
Investments. In Table 6, we show the factor risk
and the moderately aggressive portfolios. Long only
exposures of the portfolios in Table 4 for the
constraints make it more attractive to reduce slightly
Conservative, Moderate and Aggressive risk profiles.
the tracking error for the aggressive portfolio.
The results are calculated by linearly combining the
exposures of core, diversification and thematic assets
 Portfolio C—Core assets, diversification and
to the model risk factors. For the risk not explained
thematics satellite
by exposures to the model risk factors we distinguish
When thematic investments are also allowed, C, then between that arising from either specific risk from
we find that the Sharpe ratios and expected returns core or diversification assets, which we call specific
increase further when compared to their respective volatility in Table 6, and that from thematic assets,
counterparts in B or A. The size of the satellite port- which we call thematic volatility.
folio increases further, to about 29% for the conser-
vative portfolio and almost 41% for the moderately We find that as we allow portfolios to diversify, from
aggressive portfolio, resulting in a tracking error rela- A to B, the exposures to risk factors are about the
tive to their counterparts invested only in core assets same. Portfolios B are just more diversified, with

Volume 79, Number 1 29


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 7. Tracking Error of Portfolios C Relative to Portfolios B of Similar Risk Profile in


Table 4
Moderately Moderately
Portfolio C—Portfolio B Conservative (%) Conservative (%) Moderate (%) Aggressive (%) Aggressive (%)

Risk factors
Market risk 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Duration 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1
EM/Commodities 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2
Corporate spreads 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
US 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1
Asia/Japan 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Systematic tracking error 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2
Specific tracking error 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.0
Thematic tracking error 0.4 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.6
Tracking error 0.4 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.7

Note: Based on the same calculations used for Table 4.


Source: Bloomberg, ECPI, Foxberry, FTSE, Morningstar, MSCI and NASDAQ. Authors’ calculations.

lower specific volatility, in particular for the Thematic investing can be seen as an additional
Moderate and Aggressive profiles. However, port- dimension in portfolios that transcends the classifica-
folios C add specific risk (thematic volatility) derived tions regions, styles and sectors while not being fully
from allocations thematic investments. This is not independent from them. Constructing portfolios with
surprising since we attribute a positive alpha to this thematic investments requires adequate risk manage-
risk—the portfolio will seek to mimic the exposures ment in order to assess by how much a given theme
to other risk factors while creating exposure to the- is exposed to traditional risk factors and to assess
matic volatility. However, even if we had not done how much alpha a given theme is likely to add to the
so, thematic investments would still appear in the portfolio in excess of such exposures. We provide
portfolios for as long as they would also bring add- guidance on how to investigate the exposures of
itional diversification. themes to traditional risk factors. We also propose a
framework based on robust optimisation as an allo-
Finally, it is also instructive to investigate the track- cating tool capable of handling the different risk
ing error of portfolios C relative to portfolio B for exposures of assets and themes while taking into
the different risk profiles, respectively. As shown account the expected returns from the different
in Table 7, most of the tracking error created assets and the expected alphas for themes. With this,
with the introduction of thematic investments is we give a detailed example with an allocation to five
made of thematic volatility. As expected, the port- different themes played in equities and bonds, and
folio optimiser seeks to allocate to thematic assets show how the allocation changes according to the
so as to create an exposure to the specific risk of level of risk aversion of the investor. The results
thematic assets to which we attributed a posi- shown in the paper are for illustrative purposes only,
tive alpha. not meant for investment advice, and illustrate how
the framework can be used to allocate to thematic
investments.
Conclusions Extensions of this work could include the use of
Themes are structural trends expected to significantly more detailed risk models. For example, when
impact economies and redefine business models. For designing an allocation for equity only portfolios we
this reason, they should have an impact on the may envisage using a risk model that explicitly
returns and risks of investments with greater expos- includes styles and sectors as factors. The framework
ure to those structural trends. Thematic investing here proposed can be easily adapted for the purpose.
allows portfolios to earn excess returns generated That would require more inputs, but would allow for
from assets that have their returns impacted by the better allocating to themes with stronger exposures
structural changes underlying relevant themes. to styles or sectors than the examples used here.

30
Allocating to Thematic Investments

Appendix A: Asset Allocation Model Risk Factors

Table A1. Statistical Risk Factors from Risk Model


Statistical Factors
Market Duration Emerging Corporate Asia/Japan
Tickers Risk (%) (%) /Commodities (%) Spreads (%) US (%) (%)

Equity EMU NDDLEURO Index 28.2 14.7 25.6 16.5 3.1 10.3
Equity EMU Small Cap NCLDEMU Index 29.1 12.0 21.2 2.9 0.6 12.5
Equity UK NDDLUK Index 27.5 9.3 10.1 23.2 4.1 22.1
Equity USA NDDUUS Index 28.8 12.8 2.4 19.6 8.1 9.4
Equity USA Small Cap RU20INTR Index 27.0 16.7 3.3 16.8 12.4 15.4
Equity Pacific Japan NDDLJN Index 21.8 20.9 17.4 18.2 14.9 79.7
Equity NDUEEGF Index 28.2 5.5 27.8 17.6 6.6 14.0
Emerging Global
Bond EUR Sovereign LEATTREU Index 3.0 47.8 32.5 22.9 38.4 10.0
Bond EUR Corporate LECPTREU Index 21.8 33.5 19.0 25.6 30.6 9.4
Investment Grade
Bond EUR High Yield LF88TREU Index 28.3 2.4 2.4 51.2 1.9 8.8
Bond USD Sovereign LUATTRUU Index 6.6 49.6 7.8 39.3 18.1 10.8
Bond USD Corporate LUACTRUU Index 19.5 42.5 6.0 14.3 12.5 2.8
Investment Grade
Bond USD High Yield LF89TRUU Index 28.8 3.8 9.6 40.9 21.1 2.0
Bond EMD HC JPGCCOMP Index 26.0 26.4 19.4 4.3 19.2 5.8
Sov Global
Bond EMD LC JGENVUUG Index 24.4 13.1 38.4 25.1 22.8 15.9
Sov Global
Diversification Real TRNHUE Index 25.4 1.6 32.6 0.9 7.3 36.1
Estate Pan Europe
Diversification BCOMXAL Index 17.9 8.4 56.3 1.7 72.1 19.9
Commodity Global

Note: Risk model estimation from Jan-2003 through Dec-2021 using monthly USD returns based on a PCA model.
Source: Bloomberg (Bond and Commodities), FTSE EPRA (Listed Real Estate), MSCI (Equities except US Small Caps) and FTSE
Russell (US Small Caps). Authors’ calculations.

Empirical Framework for Region, Style, estimate each component while making sure they are
and Sector Exposures. The returns of thematic orthogonal to each other, the following methodology
indices in excess of cash, XRthematic , can be decom- was used:
posed into three components:
 Step 1: The thematic index i returns in excess of cash
XRthematic ¼ XRthematic
market þ XRregion style sector þ XRpure theme
thematic thematic
(1) were regressed against the global market index (MSCI
ACWI Index is used for equity indices and Bloomberg
where XRthematic
market is a term representing what is Barclays Global Aggregate Index for bond indices)
explained by the exposure to the equity market as a returns in excess of cash:
whole, XRthematic
region style sector is a term representing what is XRthematic; i ¼ a þ bmarket
thematic; i XRmarket þ ethematic; i
market
(2)
explained by regions, styles and sectors and
Where XRthematic; i the vector of excess returns of the-
XRthematic
pure theme is what cannot be explained from matic i over cash, ethematic
market; i the vector of residual from the
correlations with the equity market as a whole regression and XRmarket the vector of excess returns of
or with regions, styles or sectors. In order to global market index over cash.

Volume 79, Number 1 31


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

 Step 4: The pure thematic returns dpure theme


thematic, i is calculated
 Step 2: The returns of each regional, style and sector
index j in excess of cash are regressed against the returns as the residual of the linear regression of ethematic
market on the
of global market index in excess of cash: selected j region, style or sector residual returns:
  pure theme
emarket
thematic; i ¼ bregion style sector; j eregion style sector; j þ dthematic; i
market market
(5)
XRregion style ector; j ¼ a þ bmarket
region style sector; j XRmarket

þ emarket
region style sector; j (3)
Lasso regressions used in Step 3 reduce overfitting
Where XRregion style sector, j the vector of excess returns of since 128 equity and 46 fixed income explanatory
regional, style and sector index j and emarket
region style sector, j rep- variables were considered while there are only 260
resents the vector of residual from each regression, weekly returns in each regressed thematic time ser-
respectively. ies. When applying Lasso regression, we chose to
estimate the k shrinkage parameter using the meth-
odology proposed by Friedman, Hastie, and
 Step 3: A Lasso regression, as originally proposed by
Tibshirani (2010) retaining the k that yields the
Tibshirani (1996), is used to find the region, style and sector
residuals relative to the global market, as in Step 2, that mean-squared error from cross-the validation pro-
have the highest and most significant contributions towards cess that is within one standard error of the min-
explaining the thematic residuals relative to the global mar- imum. The complete list of region, style and sector
ket, as in Step 1: indices used in this framework can be found in
X
T X
J X
J   Table A2.
ðemarket 2 bj 
thematic; i; t  bj emarket
region style sector; j; t Þ þk (4)
t¼1 j j¼1

Table A2. List of Region, Style, and Sector Equity Indices and Bond
Indices Used in Lasso Regressions
Index for Regions Ticker

MSCI EMU MXEM Index


MSCI UK NDDLUK Index
MSCI Europe Small Cap NCEDE15 Index
MSCI USA NDDUUS Index
MSCI USA Small Cap NCUDUS Index
MSCI Japan NDDLJN Index
MSCI Pacific Ex Japan NDDUPFXJ Index
MSCI Emerging Markets NDUEEGF Index
Index for Styles Ticker

MSCI EMU Growth M7EM000G Index


MSCI EMU Value M7EM000V Index
MSCI EMU Large Value MLVLEMUN Index
MSCI EMU Small Value MSVLEMUN Index
MSCI EMU Large Growth MLGLEMUN Index
MSCI EMU Small Growth MGSLEMUN Index
MSCI UK Small Cap NCLDUK Index
MSCI UK Value NDLVUK Index
MSCI UK Growth NLDGUK Index
MSCI USA Value M1US000V Index
MSCI USA Growth M1US000G Index
MSCI USA Quality M1USQU Index
MSCI USA Momentum M1USMMT Index
MSCI USA Mid Cap M1USMC Index
MSCI USA Large Cap M1USLC Index
MSCI USA Small Cap Value MXUS00SV Index
continued

32
Allocating to Thematic Investments

Table A2. List of Region, Style, and Sector Equity Indices and Bond
Indices Used in Lasso Regressions (continued)
Index for Styles Ticker

MSCI USA Small Cap Growth MXUS00SG Index


MSCI USA Small Cap Multi-Factor M1USDM Index
MSCI Japan Small Cap NCLAJN Index
MSCI Japan Value NAVLJN Index
MSCI Japan Growth NAGLJN Index
MSCI Japan Quality M4JPQU Index
MSCI Japan Small Growth M7JP00SG Index
MSCI Japan Large Growth M7JP0002 Index
MSCI Japan Large Value M7JP0001 Index
MSCI Japan Small Value M7JP00SV Index
MSCI Pacific Ex Japan IMI Value MIVLPXJN Index
MSCI Pacific Ex Japan IMI Growth MGILPXJN Index
MSCI Pacific Excluding Japan Small Cap GCALPXJ Index
MSCI Pacific Ex Japan Small Growth MGSLPXJN Index
MSCI Pacific Ex Japan Small Value MSVLPXJN Index
MSCI Pacific Ex Japan Large Value MLVLPXJN Index
MSCI Pacific Ex Japan Large Growth MLGLPXJN Index
MSCI Pacific Ex Japan Large Cap MLCLPXJN Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Large Cap M1EFLC Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Mid Cap M1EFMC Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Small Cap M1EFSC Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Value M1EF000V Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Growth M1EF000G Index
MSCI Emerging Markets SMID Value M1EF0009 Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Large Growth M1EF0002 Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Large Value M1EF0001 Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Mid Value M1EF0003 Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Mid Growth M1EF0004 Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Small Value M1EF0005 Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Small Growth M1EF0006 Index

Index for Sectors Ticker

MSCI Japan Consumer Discretionary MXJP0CD Index


MSCI Japan Consumer Staples MXJP0CS Index
MSCI Japan Information Technology MXJP0IT Index
MSCI Japan Energy MXJP0EN Index
MSCI Japan Financials MXJP0FN Index
MSCI Japan Industrials MXJP0IN Index
MSCI Japan Real Estate MXJP0RE Index
MSCI Japan Telecommunications and Services MXJP0TC Index
MSCI Japan Utilities MXJP0UT Index
MSCI Japan Health Care MXJP0HC Index
MSCI Japan Materials MXJP0MT Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Consumer Discretionary M1EF0CD Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Consumer Staples M1EF0CS Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Energy M1EF0EN Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Financials M1EF0FN Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Health Care M1EF0HC Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Industrials M1EF0IN Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Information Technology M1EF0IT Index
MSCI Emerging Markets Materials M1EF0MT Index
continued

Volume 79, Number 1 33


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table A2. List of Region, Style, and Sector Equity Indices and Bond
Indices Used in Lasso Regressions (continued)
Index for Sectors Ticker

MSCI Emerging Markets Telecommunications and Services M1EF0TC Index


MSCI Emerging Markets Utilities M1EF0UT Index
MSCI EMU Materials NDLUMAT Index
MSCI EMU Consumer Discretionary NDLUCDIS Index
MSCI EMU Consumer Staples NDLUCSTA Index
MSCI EMU Telecommunications and Services NDLUTEL Index
MSCI EMU Energy NDLUENR Index
MSCI EMU Health Care NDLUHC Index
MSCI EMU Utilities NDLUUTI Index
MSCI EMU Industrials NDLUIND Index
MSCI EMU Information Technology NDLUIT Index
MSCI EMU Financials NDLUFNCL Index
MSCI EMU Real Estate NDLURE Index
STOXX Europe 600 Automobiles SXAR Index
STOXX Europe 600 Banks SX7R Index
STOXX Europe 600 Construction SXOR Index
STOXX Europe 600 Health Care SXDR Index
STOXX Europe 600 Insurance SXIR Index
STOXX Europe 600 Media SXMR Index
STOXX Europe 600 Oil and Gas SXER Index
STOXX Europe 600 Technology SX8R Index
STOXX Europe 600 Telecommunications SXKR Index
STOXX Europe 600 Energy S600ENR Index
STOXX Europe 600 Industrials SXIDUR Index
STOXX Europe 600 Utilities SX6R Index
STOXX Europe 600 Basic Materials SXBSCR Index
MSCI UK Consumer Discretionary MXGB0CD Index
MSCI UK Consumer Staples MXGB0CS Index
MSCI UK Energy MXGB0EN Index
MSCI UK Financials MXGB0FN Index
MSCI UK Utilities MXGB0UT Index
MSCI UK Industrials MXGB0IN Index
MSCI UK Materials MXGB0MT Index
MSCI UK Information Technology MXGB0IT Index
MSCI UK Health Care MXGB0HC Index
MSCI UK Telecommunications and Services MXGB0TC Index
MSCI US Energy M1US0ENE Index
MSCI US Consumer Discretionary M1US0CDE Index
MSCI US Consumer Staple M1US0CSE Index
MSCI US Healthcare M1US0HCE Index
MSCI US Materials M2US0MTI Index
MSCI US Industrials M1US0INI Index
MSCI US Financials M1US0FNI Index
MSCI US Information Technology M1US0ITI Index
MSCI US Telecommunications and Services M1US0TCI Index
MSCI US Utilities M1US0UTI Index
MSCI Australia Materials GICS Sector MXAU0MT Index
MSCI Australia Energy GICS Sector MXAU0EN Index
MSCI Australia Telecommunications and Services MXAU0TC Index
MSCI Canada Materials MXCA0MT Index
MSCI Canada Energy MXCA0EN Index
MSCI Canada Telecommunications and Services MXCA0TC Index
continued

34
Allocating to Thematic Investments

Table A2. List of Region, Style, and Sector Equity Indices and Bond
Indices Used in Lasso Regressions (continued)
Index for Sectors Ticker

EPRA Europe RPRA Index


EPRA USA RUUS Index
EPRA Japan RYJP Index

Index for Bonds Ticker

Bloomberg Barclays Euro Agg Government LEEGTREU Index


Bloomberg Euro Govt Inflation-Linked Bond All Maturities BEIG1T Index
Bloomberg Euro Aggregate Corporate LECPTREU Index
Bloomberg Euro High Yield Bond LF88TREU Index
Bloomberg US Government LUAGTRUU Index
Bloomberg US Treasury Inflation Notes LBUTTRUU Index
Bloomberg US Corporate LUACTRUU Index
Bloomberg US Corporate High Yield LF98TRUU Index
ICE BoAML Japan Government G0Y0 Index
ICE BoAML Japan Corporate JC00 Index
ICE BoAML Asian Dollar High Yield Corporate ACHY Index
J.P. Morgan Emerging Markets Bond Global JPEICORE Index
J.P. Morgan Emerging Local Markets JPPUELM Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan Euro Corporate Health Care H31360EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-European Aggregate Utility I02552EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Euro Corporate 500 Industrials Technology H04374EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays US Agg Industrial LUAITRUU Index
Bloomberg Barclays US Agg Utility LUAUTRUU Index
Bloomberg Barclays US Agg Finance LUAFTRUU Index
Bloomberg IG Health Care I00383US Index
Bloomberg IG Building Materials I00360US Index
S and P USD Global IG Corporate Bond Information Technology SPUGIITT Index
Bloomberg IG Consumer Noncyclical Total Return I00379US Index
Bloomberg IG Consumer Cyclical Total Return I00367US Index
Bloomberg IG Energy Total Return I00388US Index
Bloomberg IG Communications Total Return I00711US Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-European Aggregate Industrial I02551EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-European Aggregate Finance I02550EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-European Aggregate Local Authorities I09540EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Basic Industrial H31335EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Chemicals H31336EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Metals and Mining H31337EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Paper H31338EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Capital Goods H31339EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Aerospace Defense H31340EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Building Materials H31341EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Diversified Manufacturing H31342EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Construction Machinery H31343EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Packaging H31344EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Consumer Non-Cyclical H31356EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Beverage H31357EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Food H31359EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Environmental H31345EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Pharmaceuticals H31361EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Energy H31365EU Index
Bloomberg Barclays Pan-Euro Corporate Technology H31371EU Index

Volume 79, Number 1 35


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Editor's Note
Submitted 16 February 2022
Accepted 10 August 2022 by William N. Goetzmann

Notes
1. Lasso (least absolute shrinkage and selection operator) is overfitting or solve an ill-posed problem (for more on
a regression analysis method that performs both Lasso regressions see Hastie, Tibshirani, and
variable selection and regularisation in order to Wainwright 2015).
enhance the prediction accuracy and interpretability of
the resulting statistical model. Regularisation is the 2. The major thematic index providers including S&P Kensho,
process of adding information in order to prevent MSCI and FTSE report their thematic indices in USD while
ECPI in EUR.

References
Asness, C. S., T. J. Moskowitz, and L. H. Pedersen. 2013. Houweling, P., and J. van Zundert. 2017. “Factor Investing in
“Value and Momentum Everywhere.” The Journal of Finance 68 the Corporate Bond Market.” Financial Analysts Journal 73 (2):
(3): 929–85. doi:10.1111/jofi.12021. 100–15. doi:10.2469/faj.v73.n2.1.

Bass, R., S. Gladstone, and A. Ang. 2017. “Total Portfolio Israel, R., D. Palhares, and S. Richardson. 2018. “Common
Factor, Not Just Asset, Allocation” The Journal of Portfolio Factors in Corporate Bond Returns.” Journal of Investment
Management 43 (5): 38–53. doi:10.3905/jpm.2017.43.5.038. Management 16:17–46.

Blitz, D. 2021. “Betting against Quant: Examining the Factor re, F. Soupe
Issaoui, T., R. Perchet, O. Retie , C. Yin, and R.
Exposures of Thematic Indexes.” The Journal of Index Investing Leote de Carvalho. 2022. “Mass Customization of Asset
Allocation.” Journal of Investing 31 (3): 73–97. doi:10.3905/joi.
12 (3): 5–14. doi:10.3905/jii.2021.1.111.
2021.1.217.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French. 1992. “The Cross-Section of
Morningstar. 2021. “Explore the Global Thematic Funds
Expected Stock Returns.” The Journal of Finance 47 (2):
Landscape.” https://www.morningstar.com/lp/global-thematic-
427–65. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1992.tb04398.x. fund-landscape.
Friedman, J., T. Hastie, and R. Tibshirani. 2010. “Regularization Perchet, R., X. Lu, R. Leote de Carvalho, and T. Heckel. 2016.
Paths for Generalized Linear Models via Coordinate Descent.” “Insights into Robust Robust Portfolio Optimisation:
Journal of Statistical Software 33 (1): 1–22. doi:10.18637/jss. Decomposition into Mean-Variance and Risk-Based Portfolio.”
v033.i01. Journal of Investment Strategies 6 (1): 1–24.
Hastie, T., R. Tibshirani, and M. Wainwright. 2015. “Statistical Scherer, B. 2015. “Core–Satellite Investing: Budgeting Active
Learning with Sparsity: The Lasso and Generalizations.” In Manager Risk.” In Portfolio Construction and Risk Budgeting,
Monographs on Statistics & Applied Probability. Boca Raton: edited by B. Scherer, Chapter 14, 5th ed. London: Risk Books.
Chapman & Hall/CRC.
Tibshirani, R. 1996. “Regression Shrinkage and Selection via the
Haugen, R. A., and N. Baker. 1996. “Commonality in the Lasso.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series B
Determinants of Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Financial (Methodological) 58 (1): 267–88. doi:10.1111/j.2517-6161.
Economics 41 (3): 401–39. doi:10.1016/0304- 1996.tb02080.x.
405X(95)00868-F. Walmsley, D. 2021. Targeting Impact: Integrated ESG and the
nie, and R. Leote de
Heckel, T., Z. Amghar, I. Haik, O. Laple Role of Thematic Strategies in Asset-Owner Portfolios. Stamford,
Carvalho. 2019. “Factor Investing in Corporate Bond Markets: CT: Coalition Greenwich, CRISIL.
Enhancing Efficacy through Diversification and Purification!” . 2021. “A Practical Guide to
Yin, C., R. Perchet, and F. Soupe
The Journal of Fixed Income 29 (3): 6–21. doi:10.3905/jfi.2019. Robust Portfolio Optimisation.” Quantitative Finance 21 (6):
1.074. 911–28. doi:10.1080/14697688.2020.1849780.

36
Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute Research
https://doi.org/10.1080/0015198X.2022.2150500

Targeting Macroeconomic
Exposures in Equity
Portfolios: A Firm-Level
Measurement Approach for
Out-of-Sample Robustness
Mikheil Esakia and Felix Goltz
Mikheil Esakia is quantitative research analyst at Scientific Beta, Nice, France. Felix Goltz is research director at Scientific Beta and associate
researcher at EDHEC Business School, Nice, France. Send correspondence to Felix Goltz at felix.goltz@edhec.edu

We propose firm-level measures of Introduction


exposures to macroeconomic risks his paper proposes a method of targeting exposures to macro-
that substantially improve out-of-sam-
ple robustness compared to standard
estimation approaches. Systematic
equity strategies constructed from
T economic risks in equity investing. Managing macroeconomic
risks is an important task for equity investors because their port-
folios may come with substantial exposures to not only stock market
risk but also broader macroeconomic risks, such as interest rate risk,
such measures offer more consistent inflation risk, or recession risk.
macro exposures out of sample than
strategies that allocate across sectors Beyond the exposure that the broad market index may have to such
or equity-style factors. We do not macroeconomic factors, investors may pick up cross-sectional differ-
find significant cost to the perform- ences in exposure. There is ample evidence that such differences in
ance of such systematic strategies in stocks’ macro exposures can be substantial. For example, Chen, Roll,
exchange for targeting exposures to and Ross (1986) found that portfolios sorted on market-capitalisation
macroeconomic risks, such as interest had different exposures to various macroeconomic variables, including
rates, term spread, credit spread, or the term spread and the credit spread. Similar findings were docu-
inflation. Our methodology can be mented by Petkova (2006) across double-sorted portfolios on book-
used to construct equity portfolios to-price and market capitalisation and by Boons (2016) across
for investors who have hedging stock-level returns. Such implicit exposures will not necessarily align
demands or active views regarding with what an investor would target when considering macroeconomic
macroeconomic conditions. risk exposures explicitly. If an investor is already exposed to a given
macroeconomic risk outside their equity allocation, the total portfolio
Keywords: macroeconomic risks;
out-of-sample exposure; systematic will not be well diversified and suffer losses if a given macroeconomic
equity strategies risk materialises. For example, an increase in credit spreads often sig-
nals a slowdown in economic activity and a negative impact on labour
Disclosure: No potential conflict of interest
was reported by the author(s).
income. Investors who take above-average exposure to credit risk in
We would like to thank No€el Amenc, two anonymous referees, and the editors of
PL Credits: 2.0 the journal for helpful comments and suggestions.

Volume 79, Number 1 © 2022 CFA Institute. All rights reserved. 37


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

their equity portfolios might load up on exposure different macroeconomic variables, such as inflation,
they already have through their labour income. growth, term spread, and credit spread. Bali, Brown,
Similarly, the liabilities of an investor increase with and Caglayan (2014) used monthly estimates of
declining interest rates. Investors with liabilities thus macroeconomic uncertainty to measure firm-level
should consider how their equity portfolio reacts to exposures using OLS regression. Levi and Welch
changes in interest rates. (2017) find that roughly two-thirds of the papers
published in the top academic finance journals
In practice, managing macro risks is often done via
between 2013 and 2015 estimate betas using a
allocation across asset classes. There are various
monthly frequency over samples of 1 to 5 years.1
studies that focus on constructing mimicking port-
Whilst the use of simple estimation procedures is
folios of different economic variables through
suitable for ex-post analysis of investment strategies,
dynamic asset allocation (see, e.g., Jurczenko and
the reliability of out-of-sample exposures is the key
Teiletche 2020 and Swade et al. 2021). In contrast,
this paper focusses on a single asset class. Focussing concern when investors’ objective is to target these
on equity portfolios poses challenges because expos- macro exposures in their portfolios.
ure to macroeconomic risks may be less diverse and The empirical evidence shows that estimating the
more difficult to measure. However, investors may relation between equities and macroeconomic varia-
have preference to manage macroeconomic risks in re, and Signori (2012) authored
bles is hard. Ang, Brie
equities for different reasons. For example, equities one of the few studies specifically focussing on the
have delivered the largest premium historically out-of-sample reliability of macro betas. They find
amongst traditional asset classes. Investors could be
that a portfolio of stocks with high inflation betas
better off if they can achieve their macro risk objec-
over the recent past has inflation betas that are
tives whilst collecting the long-term equity premium,
indistinguishable from zero out of sample. Fama and
especially during the times when compensation for
French (1997) emphasise that exposures of industry
other asset classes, such as long-term bonds or infla-
portfolios to equity risk factors are measured with a
tion-protected securities, are at historical lows.
high margin of error. Boons (2016) acknowledges
In a related paper, Chousakos and Giamouridis (2020) that estimating exposures to macroeconomic varia-
assess the premia in equity markets associated with bles is difficult and proposes various statistical adjust-
macro risks, such as growth, fragility, and volatility. ment to achieve out-of-sample reliability.2 In general,
Whilst their paper focusses on pricing and perform- naïve estimation techniques that are common in
ance enhancements from new types of macro fac- academic studies, such as standard regression betas
tors, our paper focusses on measurement of estimated on a low frequency, are not suitable for
exposures and robustness out of sample to long- out-of-sample measurement of risk exposures.
established macro-state variables.
In light of the difficult measurement of macro expo-
A better understanding of how to measure exposures sures, investment decisions in practice are often dis-
reliably is valuable for investors. Reliable measure- cretionary. For example, some actively managed
ment of how different stocks are exposed to macro- funds explicitly aim at strong outperformance in high
economic risks would allow investors to build equity inflationary periods. However, discretionary choices
portfolios that hedge undesired macro risks. In add- to target macro exposures are hard to evaluate given
ition, targeting macroeconomic exposures is useful their lack of transparency and replicability.
for investors who have views on the future eco-
nomic conditions. To target macro exposures of equity portfolios, the
approach of choice in investment practice is to allo-
However, this is easier said than done. One of the cate across predefined asset classes, such as sectors
major challenges to efficiently managing macro risks or factors. However, whilst such building blocks are
in equity portfolios is to reliably estimate the expo- readily available, they have never been designed to
sures. Most academic studies are concerned with ex- reliably capture macro risks. Using such blunt tools
post analysis over the long term. Common estimation may in fact compound the measurement challenges
techniques available in the literature do not consider when trying to target macro exposures.
out-of-sample reliability. For example, one of the ear-
liest influential studies on this subject by Chen, Roll, In contrast to popular practice, we propose a system-
and Ross (1986) applied the ordinary least-squares atic approach that is transparent and replicable. We
(OLS) approach to monthly returns to obtain betas to also go beyond analysing sector differences and

38
Targeting Macroeconomic Exposures in Equity Portfolios

instead exploit the firm-level heterogeneity of risk information is reflected in asset prices, in particular
exposures. Our approach relies on three ingredients. treasury bond prices. Similarly, the aggregate credit
spread reflects investors’ risk tolerance and whether
First, we choose forward-looking macroeconomic future economic conditions are expected to alter
variables that are derived from financial markets. This firms’ ability to meet their obligations.
allows us to identify links between stock-level
returns and macroeconomic risks. Commonly used We primarily rely on U.S. data. However, our
macroeconomic variables, such as realised inflation or approach can be easily extended to other geograph-
growth, are backward looking and do not reflect ical areas where the respective macro variables are
investor expectations. They also come at a lower fre- available. Below, we list the macro variables that we
quency that aggravates the challenge of exposure use in our analysis:4
measurement. Our macroeconomic variables are
derived from asset prices, such as fixed-income 1. Short-term interest rates, defined as a yield on
securities. They are available at higher frequency and 3-month U.S. Treasury bills.
naturally incorporate investor expectations, thus 2. Term spread, defined as a difference between
improving the reliability of exposure measurement. yields on 10-year and 1-year U.S. Treasury bonds.
3. Credit spread, defined as a difference between
Second, we apply robust measurement tools to esti- yields on Moody’s Corporate Baa and Aaa bonds.
mate stock-level macro exposures out of sample. Our 4. Expected inflation, defined as a difference
estimation technique is superior to the naïve between the yields of nominal 10-year Treasury
approach that uses OLS on data that come at a rela- bonds and 10-year Treasury Inflation Protected
tively lower frequency. Securities (TIPS).
Third, we construct dedicated equity portfolios from
stock-level exposures in a fully systematic way. We Note that all four macro variables are derived from
show that our stylised strategies can provide stronger asset prices and thus reflect investors’ perception on
out-of-sample macro exposures than other popular economic conditions. Amenc et al. (2019) provide a
approaches in the industry that allocate across preex- protocol for selecting relevant state variables and
isting equity products, such as sector or factor indi- show that such variables5 are useful in predicting
ces. This finding is consistent across all the macro aggregate economic conditions and provide informa-
variables that we test. tion on the aggregate risk tolerance of investors.6

In addition to capturing macroeconomic exposures in Short-term interest rates are highly influenced by
a reliable fashion, our stylised strategies come with monetary policy actions, and they are also considered
performance in line with market returns, irrespective as a proxy for the risk-free rate. Surprises in short
of the macroeconomic risks they target. Therefore, rates not only reflect central bank actions but also
such strategies provide access to the long-term reflect the demand on safe assets in a “flight to qual-
equity premium along with targeting the macroeco- ity” (Longstaff 2004). The term spread is one of the
nomic risks that an investor might be con- most often used macro variables to forecast eco-
cerned with.3 nomic growth and recessions (Campbell 1987;
Estrella and Trubin 2006). It is also considered a gen-
Selecting Forward-Looking Variables. In eral measure of compensation for exposure to shocks
general, realised quantities of fundamental economic on long-term discount rates.7 The default spread sig-
measures are not suited when analysing movements nals risk aversion during adverse economic condi-
in asset prices. In liquid markets, information is tions, when equity and bond investors require higher
quickly reflected in prices. Prices of financial assets compensation for bearing risk. Fama and French
that are claims to future cash flows depend on (1989) and Keim and Stambaugh (1986) provide
investors’ expectations. Therefore, looking at realised empirical evidence for such a link. Finally, expected
measures of economic variables that lack information inflation determines the purchasing power of future
about future economic conditions does not allow to cash flows. It therefore has a direct impact on asset
capture the relation between asset prices and eco- prices, especially those that produce cash flows
nomic conditions. Instead, we rely on macro-state adjusted for inflation (such as TIPS). The four state
variables that are forward looking and quickly incorp- variables provide information about aggregate
orate available information. For example, if investors’ expectations about different dimensions of eco-
expectations about future interest rates change, this nomic conditions.

Volume 79, Number 1 39


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Also note that our macro-state variables are available When it comes to estimating anticipated changes in a
at high frequency, which is not the case for back- macroeconomic variable, there are various methods
ward-looking economic fundamental measures, such available. The standard approach followed in litera-
as realised inflation or growth. High-frequency data ture is to use a vector auto-regressive model (VAR).
are beneficial in statistical estimation procedures, as In our case, we can simply use the change of macro
we will discuss in detail later in this section. variables as it delivers similar results to a more
involved model, such as a VAR model.8 As shown in
Surprises Matter, Not Levels. Another Figure 1, the VAR innovations are not distinguishable
important aspect of our methodology is to use sur- from simple first-order differences in breakeven infla-
prises, or innovations, in macro variables instead of tion. We find a similar picture when looking at other
levels. The current value of assets already reflects macro variables.
information that is known to investors today. As new
information arrives, asset prices, including stock pri- Statistical Estimates of Macro Exposures.
ces, adjust accordingly. Therefore, we are interested We now describe the necessary ingredients for
in surprises. In fact, the observed level of a macro- robust estimates of macro exposures. Our objective
economic variable that was fully anticipated by is to exploit differences in stock-level macro expo-
investors will not lead to different price reactions sures without altering access to the market premium.
across stocks. Therefore, we control for the market exposure when
we estimate stock-level macro exposures. We start
Consider the example of surprises in expected inflation.
from a simple bivariate linear model:
In Figure 1, we plot the levels as well as innovations in
breakeven inflation over a selected period around the Ri, t  RRF, t ¼ ai þ bMKT
i ðRMKT, t  RRF, t Þ
2008/2009 global financial crisis. More specifically, we  
þ bmacro
i Macro t  EðMacro tjt1 Þ
consider a period from 2006 to 2012. Looking at the
level of breakeven inflation, we see that in December þei, t (1)
2008, breakeven inflation is very low (close to zero).
From December 2008 to July 2009, inflation rises The first independent variable corresponds to the
strongly to about 1.7% but remains at levels that are equity market premium and the second to innova-
far below earlier levels of about 2.5%. In the first half tions in the relevant macro variable. In addition, we
of 2009, inflation levels were low but innovations in take several important steps to ensure that expo-
breakeven inflation were actually high, as the U.S. sures estimated on past data stay reliable out
economy rebounded from the financial crisis. of sample.

Now consider a stock which benefits from high levels First, we use observations at weekly frequency. The
of inflation and suffers when they are low. During the data that we rely on are also available at daily fre-
first half of 2009, all else being equal, you would quency, but we use weekly observations to avoid
expect such a stock to achieve positive performance problems due to differences in closing times between
because markets would be likely to reprice it whilst bond and equity markets. Levi and Welch (2017)
moving from a very low inflation environment to one show that using such higher-frequency data provides
of moderate inflation (though the price of such a stock substantial improvements in accuracy of estimated
might still be below its prior value, as inflation was betas over using monthly returns data. Having higher
much higher at 2.5% before 2008). Still, the inflation frequency leads to more observations, which helps to
sensitivity of such a stock will show up in price move- reduce estimation error. This is, however, very
ments over the short term. To pick up the sensitivity uncommon in the literature, especially when working
of stock returns with inflation, we need to look at the with macro variables (see Levi and Welch 2017).
contemporaneous changes in breakeven inflation that
were not anticipated by investors, rather than looking Second, we manage to account for recent dynamics
at the level of inflation. Of course, this argument also in macro betas whilst maintaining deep historical
applies to other macro variables, such as the term samples for estimation. Estimation problems face a
spread, credit spread, and interest rates. basic trade-off between sample size and reactivity to
changes in exposures. Using historical data that are a
In general, the current value of assets already reflects decade old provides a large sample but does not
information that is known to investors, such as the seem ideal as the given firm might have drastically
current values of macro variables. As new informa- changed over this period. On the other hand, relying
tion arrives, stock prices will adjust accordingly. on a short window of estimation, such as only the

40
Targeting Macroeconomic Exposures in Equity Portfolios

Figure 1. Innovations in Macro Variables Are Different from Levels: The Case of
Breakeven Inflation

most recent year, will lead to imprecise estimates of beta estimates. The idea behind this adjustment is
due to small sample size. We overcome this trade-off to shrink estimated coefficients to a prior. We
by a using long-term history of stock-level returns choose the cross-sectional average exposure esti-
(20 years if available) and attributing decreasing mates as a prior, which is close to 0 most of the time
importance to observations as we go further back in as we control for the market beta in the model. The
history.9 Our methodology differs from commonly intensity of shrinkage towards the prior will depend
used rolling-window approaches in investment prac- on the magnitude of estimation error for a respective
tice because we fit the model using the weighted- beta estimate.
least squares method.
nX o !
T lnð2Þ
min e 2
 e jTtj 260
(2) r2i, TS r2i, TS
t¼1 t
bfinal
i ¼ bprior
i þ bestimate
i 1
r2i, TS þ r2XS r2i, TS þ r2XS
lnð2Þ
The term 260 specifies that, as T approaches infinity, (3)
half of the total weights are attributed to the first
260 weeks (i.e., 5 years). Our estimation approach where by TS we refer to sampling variance and by XS
benefits from a large sample whilst also capturing the we refer to the cross-sectional variance across esti-
recent dynamics of macro exposures. mated beta coefficients.
Third, we explicitly account for estimation risk at the The final estimate10 is the weighted average of prior
firm level. Treating macro exposures of identical mag- beta and estimated beta. The higher the estimation
nitude for two stocks as equal would ignore estima- error, the more importance is given to the prior, and
tion risk. Even if macro betas for two stocks are vice versa.
estimated to be identical in magnitude, they may dif-
fer in terms of the uncertainty around the point esti- We can summarise the estimation process in
mate. Therefore, we also account for the differences three steps:
in uncertainty across stocks and adjust macro expo-
sures that are estimated imprecisely. Vasicek (1973)  The first key ingredient of our methodology is to
proposes Bayesian shrinkage to improve the accuracy use surprises in forward-looking variables.

Volume 79, Number 1 41


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

possible to create an inflation proxy that also covers


 Second, we employ various statistical adjustments
the earlier sample period and thus allows for long-
to generate robust estimates of stock-level
term analysis. In particular, we created an economic
macro exposures.
tracking portfolio that invests in broad asset classes
 Third, we use the estimated stock-level macro
to mimic surprises in breakeven inflation. We find
exposures to create dedicated building blocks
that the conclusions of our analysis remain intact
instead of allocating across existing portfolios
when using such an inflation proxy over a long-
(such as sector or factor portfolios).
term period.13

The macro exposures are estimated in a bivariate


model that includes the market factor and the corre-
In the following section, we analyse how our estima-
sponding macro factor (see equation 1). We estimate
tion approach performs in terms of out-of-sample
realised exposures using standard OLS as our aim is
reliability and how it compares with alterna-
not to produce out-of-sample reliable estimates, but
tive approaches.
to observe what happens ex-post, over the long-
term period.
Assessing the Reliability of Macro Before evaluating whether our approach allows cre-
Exposures Estimates ating mimicking portfolios with the desired exposure
out of sample, we briefly test mimicking portfolios to
We evaluate the reliability of macro exposure esti-
backward-looking variables that are commonly used
mates by constructing mimicking portfolios. For each
when analysing the sensitivity of equity returns to
macro variable, we create a long-short portfolio that
economic conditions. More specifically, we look at
buys stocks with the highest macro exposure esti-
economic growth proxied by industrial production
mates (top 30%) and sells stocks with the lowest
index, as it is available at a monthly frequency (unlike
macro exposures estimates (bottom 30%). The equal-
other measures, such as GDP, which is available at a
weighted long-short portfolio is formed each quarter
quarterly frequency). For example, Chen, Roll, and
and held until the next quarterly rebalancing. The
Ross (1986) use industrial production growth as one
estimation is only based on data available at the
of the factors in their asset pricing model. Ung and
rebalancing date, and the realised macro exposures
Luk (2016) look at the realised growth in GDP to
are computed over the holding period. Because the
measure sensitivity of different equity-style factors
macro mimicking portfolio buys stocks with high
to economic conditions. Devarajan et al. (2016) also
exposure and sells stocks with low exposure, we
propose using GDP growth to measure the cyclical
expect that the mimicking portfolio will demonstrate
variation of equity factors.
positive realised macro exposure when we go out of
sample. If that is the case, we can conclude that ex- We also look at inflation, proxied by realised changes
ante macro exposure estimates are reliable (and in the consumer price index. We apply a naïve esti-
stocks in long leg have higher out-of-sample expo- mation approach that uses 5 years of recent data at
sures than stocks in the short leg). a monthly frequency to estimate stock-level betas to
a given macro variable.
Our analysis starts in June 1970 and spans over
52 years, ending in June 2022. The equity universe Indeed, whilst economic growth and realised inflation
consists of the largest 500 stocks in CRSP universe11 are key forces describing macroeconomic conditions,
and is reviewed each quarter on the third Friday of asset prices would typically lead and reflect informa-
March, June, September, and December. We focus tion about growth and inflation before it is observ-
on the United States, which represents a significant able through the respective measures (see Fama,
share of global equity markets in terms of market 1981). This is one of the reasons that the relation
capitalisation. The data for U.S. macro variables cover between asset returns and economic variables is
a long history, whilst data for other developed coun- often found to be weak.
tries cover substantially shorter periods.12
The results in Table 1 show that exposure estimates
The data for breakeven inflation start only in January to backward-looking variables are unreliable, confirm-
1997. Therefore, when evaluating portfolios that re,
ing earlier results on inflation betas of Ang, Brie
mimic changes in breakeven inflation, we start the and Signori (2012). The realised exposures of mimick-
analysis in March 2002 because we require at least 5 ing portfolios to these variables are not distinguish-
years of data for estimation of macro exposure. It is able from zero.

42
Targeting Macroeconomic Exposures in Equity Portfolios

This analysis illustrates that drawing on commonly relevant information than backward-looking variables,
used variables and estimation techniques is not suit- such as the growth and realised inflation.
able for measuring macro exposures. Using back-
ward-looking variables does not support robust The second row of Table 2 shows the results when
estimation of firms’ sensitivity to economic condi- using weekly returns for estimation, but without any
tions. Even though economic growth and inflation further adjustments, such as dynamic weights or
could be important drivers of asset prices, backward- Bayesian shrinkage. Therefore, the only difference
looking information on these dimensions is unlikely with the naïve approach is the frequency at which
to be relevant for stock returns. Choosing the right the macro betas are estimated. The realised expo-
proxy is essential to establish the link between asset sures of macro mimicking portfolios that use weekly
prices and economic fundamentals. returns are much stronger. We see positive and
highly significant realised exposures for all macro var-
We now move to analysing mimicking portfolios that iables. On average, we observe that realised macro
rely on different exposure measures to forward-look- betas increase from 1.71 when using a monthly esti-
ing variables. Table 2 shows realised macro expo- mation frequency to 2.40 when using a weekly fre-
sures as well as the corresponding t-statistics quency. Moreover, the t-statistics increase from 2.53
adjusted for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation. to 4.17 on average. This increase is substantial and
The exposures are reported for different mimicking clearly indicates that estimating exposures using a
portfolios that rely on different estima- weekly frequency is superior to using a
tion techniques. monthly frequency.
In the first row, we show realised macro exposures The third row shows the results obtained when
for mimicking portfolios that use naïve estimation applying the weighted least-squares (WLS) approach
techniques. More specifically, macro betas are esti- using a weekly frequency (but still without any
mated on a monthly frequency over the recent 5 shrinkage). Compared to OLS, using WLS improves
years, using the OLS method. As noted by Levi and the realised exposures to all four variables, as shown
Welch (2017), this naïve estimation approach is com- by higher t-statistics. On average, the magnitudes of
monly used in academic studies. The results suggest out-of-sample exposures as well as corresponding
that some portfolios created using naïve estimation t-statistics are higher when using WLS compared
do not come with statistically significant exposures to OLS.
out of sample. In particular, the mimicking portfolio
for the credit spread comes with out-of-sample The final row shows the outcome when using weekly
exposure that is far from being statistically signifi- frequency and all statistical adjustments, namely the
cant, with a t-statistic of only 1.44. However, the dynamic weighting of past observations and Bayesian
realised exposures to all variables are positive and shrinkage. Compared to the third row, where we do
more reliable than the exposures we obtained when not apply the shrinkage, we find that results are
using the naïve estimation approach to estimate mostly similar across all the macro variables.
exposure to backward-looking variables. This con- However, we still observe mild improvements when
firms that our macroeconomic variables contain more looking at the average realised betas and

Table 1. Out-of-Sample Exposures of Mimicking Portfolios to Backward-


Looking Variables
United States
30 June 1970–30 June 2022 Realised Macro Beta t-Statistic

Mimicking portfolios to backward-looking variables using naïve estimation techniques


Industrial Production Growth 0.01 0.28
Consumer Price Index Growth (CPI) 0.23 0.97

Notes: The realised macro exposures are estimated in a bivariate regression that includes the market factor and the
corresponding macro variable. Standard errors are adjusted for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation following
Newey and West (1987). We follow Andrews (1991) when determining data-dependent bandwidth/lag truncation
parameters, which are estimated in a first-order autoregressive model (AR(1)) with a maximum likelihood method.
Statistical significance is indicated by a single asterisk () for results that are significant on a 5% basis and double
asterisks () for results that are significant on a 1% basis.

Volume 79, Number 1 43


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 2. Reliability of Macro Beta Estimates Using Different Regression Specifications: Out-
of-Sample Betas with Targeted Macro Variables
Estimation Estimation Bayesian Breakeven
Frequency Method Shrinkage Short Rates Term Spread Credit Spread Inflation Average

Monthly OLS No 1.07 1.20 1.84 2.73 1.71


(4.08) (2.56) (1.44) (2.04) (2.53)
Weekly OLS No 0.83 1.25 2.16 5.37 2.40
(5.23) (4.33) (3.90) (3.23) (4.17)
Weekly WLS No 0.83 1.34 2.21 5.32 2.43
(5.62) (4.51) (3.98) (3.36) (4.37)
Weekly WLS Yes 0.81 1.34 2.28 5.36 2.45
(5.49) (4.49) (4.12) (3.45) (4.39)

OLS: ordinary least-squares; WLS: weighted least-squares.


Notes: The analysis has been done from 19 June 1970 to 30 June 2022. The only exception is breakeven inflation, for which the
analysis starts in 31 March 2002. The out-of-sample macro exposures are estimated in a bivariate regression that includes the
market factor and innovations in corresponding macro variable. The estimation frequency and frequency when calculating realised
exposures are the same. Standard errors are adjusted for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation following Newey and West
(1987). We follow Andrews (1991) when determining data-dependent bandwidth/lag truncation parameters, which are estimated
in a first-order autoregressive model (AR(1)) with a maximum likelihood method. Statistical significance is indicated by a single
asterisk () for results that are significant on a 5% basis and double asterisks () for results that are significant on a 1% basis.

corresponding t-statistics. The limited impact of findings about out of sample macro exposures are
shrinkage is not surprising in our setting because we not driven by outliers.
are forming portfolios, which already reduces the
estimation error compared to stock-level estimates.
Designing Equity Portfolios from
To summarise, we have seen that our statistical
approach to estimate macro betas leads to reliable Stock-Level Measures of
classification of high- and low-exposures stocks. The Macro Exposures
mimicking portfolios for each macro variable have We have already seen that our macro exposure esti-
positive and highly significant exposures out of sam- mates can reliably distinguish between stocks with
ple. This is not the case when using a naïve estima- high and low exposure to macro risks. This allows us
tion technique that is commonly used in academic to construct long-only portfolios that come with
studies. The average t-statistic of realised macro exposure to the broad stock market index as well as
exposures is 2.53 for the naïve approach, whilst with targeted macro exposures. We test stylised
using our statistical approach leads to an average t- strategies that simply select 30% of the stocks with
statistic of 4.39 and a minimum t-statistic of 3.45. the highest or lowest macro exposure estimates and
weight them equally across all selected stocks. Note
We provide additional plots to show the relation
that these strategies simply correspond to the long
between (market-beta adjusted) returns of mimicking
and the short legs of the macro mimicking portfolios
portfolios and innovations in the corresponding
introduced above. We refer to such strategies as
macro variables. We rely on our preferred estimation
macro dedicated portfolios. This gives us four port-
approach, which uses weekly returns and applies
folios that correspond to high exposure or Macro
Bayesian shrinkage and dynamic weighting (WLS). Exposure(þ) to a given variable and four low expos-
Figure 2 shows returns of mimicking portfolios on a ure or Macro Exposure() portfolios for the same
scatterplot where the horizontal axis corresponds to four state variables.
weekly innovations in macro variables, and the verti-
cal axis corresponds to weekly returns. The plots also An alternative to building portfolios from stock-level
indicate correlation coefficients. Across different exposures would be to use a set of existing portfolios
mimicking portfolios, the correlations of returns with and allocate across them based on the estimated
shocks in the corresponding macro variable are macro exposure. Investment practice often uses sec-
above 10%. The inflation mimicking portfolio yields tor rotation or factor allocation to gain desired macro
the highest correlation of around 25%. Visual inspec- exposures, as opposed to building dedicated port-
tion of these scatterplots also suggests that our folios from stock-level information. We provide a

44
Targeting Macroeconomic Exposures in Equity Portfolios

Figure 2. Relation between Returns on Macro Mimicking Portfolios and Macro Variables

comparison with these alternative approaches to we attribute equal weights to each sector. We refer
illustrate the importance of creating macro-dedicated to such strategies as sector allocations.
portfolios. Note that, when we test allocation across
factors or sectors, we use the same robust estimation Table 3 shows the realised macro exposures for
method for macro exposures that we use to build these different approaches. Panel A shows results for
dedicated portfolios. macro dedicated equity portfolios. The results sug-
gest that dedicated macro portfolios constructed
The first approach that we compare allocates equal from stock-level data achieve out-of-sample expo-
weights across two out of six equity-factor portfolios sures that are in line with the target. For example,
with the most desirable macro exposures. We con- the short-rates (þ) strategy has a realised beta of
sider six factor portfolios: mid-cap, value, high 0.20, which is statistically significant with a t-statistic
momentum, low volatility, high profitability, and low of 2.49. Moreover, all macro dedicated portfolios
investment. The single-factor portfolios select 30% of have statistically significant exposures out of sample,
the stocks with the best factor scores and equally whether targeting positive or negative exposure.
weights them. We refer to such strategies as factor
allocations. The second approach allocates across If we look at panel B of Table 3, we see quite different
sectors following the Thomson Reuters Business clas- results. Even though factor allocation strategies mostly
sification.14 We select the three sectors with the display exposures that have the desired sign, they are
most suitable macro exposure from a total of 10 sec- often statistically insignificant. For example, the alloca-
tors. Sector indices weight stocks by market cap, and tion strategy is unsuccessful at capturing positive

Volume 79, Number 1 45


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 3. Realised Macro Exposures of Different Equity Macro Strategies


United States
19 June 1970–30 June 2022 Short Rates Term Spread Credit Spread Breakeven Inflation

Panel A: macro dedicated portfolios


Macro Exposure þ 0.20 1.07 1.31 4.56
(2.49) (6.39) (4.44) (4.68)
Macro Exposure  0.60 0.26 0.97 0.81
(6.49) (2.08) (3.13) (2.64)
Differences in Macro Exposures 0.81 1.33 2.28 5.37
(5.25) (4.96) (3.94) (4.22)
Panel B: factor allocation
Macro Exposure þ 0.01 0.48 0.35 1.71
(0.12) (3.71) (0.99) (4.15)
Macro Exposure  0.28 0.07 0.48 0.20
(3.12) (0.54) (1.67) (0.93)
Differences in Macro Exposures 0.29 0.41 0.84 1.51
(2.32) (2.27) (1.82) (3.23)
Panel C: sector allocation
Macro Exposure þ 0.43 0.84 0.51 6.41
(3.69) (3.63) (0.97) (5.33)
Macro Exposure  0.51 0.36 0.88 0.55
(3.71) (1.45) (1.49) (0.87)
Differences in Macro Exposures 0.94 1.19 1.39 5.86
(5.21) (3.55) (1.75) (4.31)

Notes: The analysis has been done from 19 June 1970 to 30 June 2022. The only exception is breakeven inflation, for which the
analysis starts in 31 March 2002. The out-of-sample macro exposures are estimated in a bivariate regression that includes the
market factor and innovations in corresponding macro variable. Standard errors are adjusted for heteroskedasticity and autocorrel-
ation following Newey and West (1987). We follow Andrews (1991) when determining data-dependent bandwidth/lag truncation
parameters, which are estimated in a first-order autoregressive model (AR(1)) with a maximum likelihood method. The null hypoth-
esis that the differences in macro exposures are zero is tested by Welch’s test. The Welch’s t-statistics may not equal to the t-sta-
tistics of the null hypothesis that the macro mimicking portfolio has zero exposure, reported in Table 2. Statistical significance is
indicated by a single asterisk () for results that are significant on a 5% basis and by double asterisks () for results that are sig-
nificant on a 1% basis.

exposures to short rates and credit spread. In addition, heterogenous enough to create portfolios with reli-
factor allocations were unable to achieve negative able macro sensitivity out of sample. Industry practi-
exposures to breakeven inflation and the term spread. ces that try to achieve these macro exposures
through sector rotation or factor allocation strategies
Sector allocations produce relatively better perform- might be problematic. We find that the cross-section
ance than factor allocation, as shown in panel C of of stocks provides more diverse exposures that allow
Table 3. The exposures are in line with the objective creating portfolios with stronger out-of-sample macro
for three out of four variables, but sometimes they exposures, consistently across all macro variables.
are not statistically significant. Some exposures are
the opposite of what was targeted: The sector alloca- As an alternative to selecting a fixed number of
tion targeting negative exposure to breakeven infla- stocks according to estimated exposures, one may
tion comes with positive out-of-sample exposure. also consider the statistical significance of exposure
estimates when selecting stocks. We also test mim-
Our results clearly indicate that selecting stocks icking portfolios where the long and short legs are
based on their macro exposures leads to more con- formed by selecting only those stocks that have stat-
sistent and pronounced exposures out of sample istically significant exposure estimates at the
than allocating across sectors or factors. This may 5% level.15
not be surprising, as sectors or factors were not
designed to proxy certain macroeconomic risks, Before forming portfolios, we first consider whether
whilst this is the case for macro dedicated portfolios. we have enough stocks in our universe at each point
Macro exposures of sectors or factors are not in time with either positive or negative exposures to

46
Targeting Macroeconomic Exposures in Equity Portfolios

the given macro variable. Having a sufficient number report the out-of-sample exposures of portfolios that
of stocks is necessary to ensure that our test port- select a fixed number of stocks (30%) in panel A,
folios are not overly concentrated. Figure 3 below whilst panel B focusses on portfolios that only select
reports the percentage of stocks in our universe that stocks with statistically significant macro exposures
have statistically significant exposures. We observe (but at least 5% of stocks).
that, at times, stocks with significantly negative or
positive exposure to a given macro variable only As expected, we find that more aggressive stock
make up less than 5% of the universe. This means selection improves the magnitude of out-of-sample
that the mimicking portfolio would be highly concen- betas on average. However, there is no improve-
trated. To avoid extreme levels of concentration, we ment when looking at average t-statistics of realised
impose that at least 5% of the stocks are selected. exposures. Using a fixed threshold of selecting 30%
of stocks allows for better diversified portfolios,
Table 4 repeats the analysis from and reports out-of- which leads to more out-of-sample robustness than
sample exposures of macro dedicated portfolios. We forming concentrated portfolios of stocks that have

Figure 3. Percentage of Stocks with Statistically Significant Macro Exposures across Time

Volume 79, Number 1 47


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

the most significant exposures on a stand- exposures become small and statistically insignificant
alone basis. in most cases.

Why Do Equity-Style Factors Not Suffice Second, dedicated macro portfolios are always able
to Manage Macro Risks? The factor allocation to achieve stronger realised exposures than any of
strategies in Table 3 do not allow managing macro the six equity factors, whether positive or negative.
This suggests that if investors’ objective is to gain
risks as efficiently as macro dedicated strategies.
pronounced exposure to a given macro variable, they
However, it has been documented that different fac-
would be better off using macro dedicated strategies.
tors do react differently to economic conditions (see
In addition, selecting amongst equity factors does not
Amenc et al. 2019). Below, we show why—despite
allow gaining both positive and negative exposures
this heterogeneity—factor allocation is not a suffi-
to three out of four macro variables. For example,
cient tool to manage macro exposures. We consider
we find that four out of six factor portfolios come
six long-only factors constructed in a highly liquid
with significantly positive exposure to the term
universe, namely the mid-cap, value, momentum, low spread, but none of the factors provide significantly
volatility, high profitability, and low investment factor negative exposure. This is true not just for the term
portfolios. In addition to the long-term realised macro spread but also for short-rates and breakeven infla-
exposures, we report ex-ante estimated exposures at tion. Hence, using standard equity factors not only
each quarter. Table 5 reports realised long-term delivers relatively weak macro exposures, but it also
exposures as well as descriptive statistics for ex-ante renders some exposure targets infeasible.
exposures estimated each quarter. For reference, we
also report the exposure of macro dedicated port- Last, but not least, we find that the macro exposures
folios for each macro variable. of equity-style factors are not necessarily consistent
across time. We find that the estimated ex-ante
As expected, realised macro exposures are different macro exposures of most equity factors take both
across equity factors, as shown in Table 5. For positive and negative values in different periods of
example, the low-volatility portfolio comes with a our sample. For instance, the 25th percentile of ex-
credit spread beta of 0.58, whilst the high-profitabil- ante betas to the credit spread are negative for all
ity portfolio has beta of 0.61 to innovations in term six factors, whilst the 75th percentiles are positive
spread. However, once we look at the average expo- for all factors. This implies that, for 25% of the quar-
sures across six equity factor portfolios, the realised ters in our sample, a factor has a positive credit

Table 4. Reliability of Macro Beta Estimates Using an Alternative Method to Form


Mimicking Portfolios
United States
19 June 1970–30 June 2022 Short-Rates Term Spread Credit Spread Breakeven Inflation Average

Panel A: macro dedicated portfolios—30% EW selection


Macro exposure þ 0.20 1.07 1.31 4.56 1.78
(2.49) (6.39) (4.44) (4.68) (4.50)
Macro exposure  0.60 0.26 0.97 0.81 0.66
(6.49) (2.08) (3.13) (2.64) (3.59)
Panel B: macro dedicated portfolios—EW significant exposures (min 5%)
Macro exposure þ 0.38 1.22 1.73 5.65 2.25
(2.60) (4.78) (3.12) (5.23) (3.93)
Macro exposure  0.72 0.60 0.81 0.86 0.75
(5.31) (2.37) (1.61) (0.77) (2.51)

Notes: The analysis has been done from 19 June 1970 to 30 June 2022. The only exception is breakeven inflation, for which the
analysis starts in 31 March 2002. The out-of-sample macro exposures are estimated in a bivariate regression that includes the
market factor and innovations in corresponding macro variable. The estimation frequency and frequency when calculating realised
exposures are the same. Standard errors are adjusted for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation following Newey and West
(1987). We follow Andrews (1991) when determining data-dependent bandwidth/lag truncation parameters, which are estimated
in a first-order autoregressive model (AR(1)) with a maximum likelihood method. Statistical significance is indicated by a single
asterisk () for results that are significant on a 5% basis and double asterisks () for results that are significant on a 1% basis.
EW ¼ equal weighted.

48
Table 5. Ex-Ante and Realised Exposures of Equity-Style Factors
Average Macro Macro
19 June 1970–30 Low High Low across Exposure Exposure
June 2022 Mid-Cap Value Momentum Volatility Profitability Investment 6 Factors (þ) ()

Volume 79, Number 1


Exposures to short rates
Realised exposure 20.16* 20.28** 20.06 20.32** 0.07 20.24** 20.17 0.20* 20.60**
Mean ex-ante exposure 0.12 0.17 0.12 0.22 0.09 0.18 0.12 1.45 1.75
Min 0.75 0.64 0.60 0.76 0.31 0.68 0.50 0.35 3.84
25th percentile 0.37 0.39 0.35 0.40 0.07 0.40 0.30 0.61 2.41
Median 0.13 0.19 0.18 0.26 0.04 0.22 0.15 0.98 1.45
75th percentile 0.00 0.03 0.01 0.02 0.28 0.08 0.04 2.26 1.05
Max 1.11 1.35 1.12 0.44 0.71 1.34 0.39 4.84 0.81
Exposures to term spread
Realised exposure 0.42** 0.67** 0.06 0.26* 0.12 0.44** 0.33* 1.07** 20.26*
Mean ex-ante exposure 0.21 0.28 0.18 0.10 0.17 0.22 0.25 2.04 1.59
Min 0.80 0.85 0.73 0.75 0.77 0.77 0.74 0.97 4.75
25th percentile 0.07 0.05 0.13 0.24 0.03 0.02 0.05 1.26 2.43
Median 0.19 0.27 0.17 0.08 0.14 0.15 0.23 2.05 1.12
75th percentile 0.52 0.52 0.47 0.46 0.31 0.50 0.50 2.42 0.67
Max 0.96 0.98 1.04 0.93 0.95 0.92 0.88 4.80 0.27
Exposures to credit spread
Realised exposure 20.22 0.04 0.14 0.58* 20.61** 0.29 0.04 1.32** 20.97**
Mean ex-ante exposure 0.11 0.30 0.22 0.46 0.16 0.32 0.35 3.86 3.43
Min 1.77 1.85 1.78 1.18 1.93 1.41 1.55 2.21 7.12
25th percentile 0.64 0.41 0.41 0.17 0.53 0.24 0.22 2.92 4.96
Median 0.29 0.51 0.29 0.54 0.09 0.52 0.49 3.76 3.40
75th percentile 0.65 0.80 0.77 0.96 0.24 0.81 0.74 4.73 1.77
Max 2.30 2.24 2.28 2.47 1.27 2.00 1.87 6.52 1.21
Exposures to breakeven inflation (31 March 2002–30 June 2022)
Realised exposure 0.23** 0.20* 0.36* 0.34 0.20** 0.42** 0.29** 4.54** 20.82**
Mean ex-ante exposure 1.30 1.39 0.86 0.27 1.01 1.00 0.65 5.37 2.58
Min 0.39 0.17 0.51 0.49 0.11 0.07 0.24 3.50 4.19
25th percentile 0.76 0.62 0.30 0.08 0.79 0.45 0.36 4.56 2.93
Median 1.40 1.57 0.75 0.33 1.00 1.13 0.45 5.23 2.53
75th percentile 1.75 1.91 1.40 0.63 1.31 1.28 0.91 5.82 2.04
Max 2.29 3.02 2.46 1.04 1.83 2.59 1.63 8.67 1.78

Notes: The equity-style factor portfolios select 30% of the stocks with the best factor scores and equally weights them. The equity universe consists of 500 largest stocks in the
U.S. and is reviewed quarterly, on the third Friday of March, June, September, and December. The percentile values are taken from the time series of ex-ante beta estimates for a
given equity factor and a given macro variable. Realised exposures were computed over the full sample. Realised macro exposures are estimated in a bivariate regression using

49
Targeting Macroeconomic Exposures in Equity Portfolios

weekly observations, where explanatory variables are the market excess return and innovations in a given macro variable. Ex-ante exposure measures are estimated following our
proposed methodology. Statistical significance is indicated by a single asterisk () for results that are significant on a 5% basis and double asterisks () for results that are significant
on a 1% basis. We test statistical significance only for full-sample realised exposures. Values set in bold are realised (i.e., ex-post) exposures. Realised exposures of dedicated macro
portfolios are highlighted in yellow when they are unique in the sense that none of the equity style factors provide significant exposures with the same sign.
Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

spread beta, but for 25% of the quarters the same example, the term spread (þ) portfolio outperforms
factor has a negative beta. We observe similar its market benchmark by around 12 percentage
instability across time in ex-ante exposure to other points per year when surprises in term spread are
macro variables, at least for some of the positive. Similarly, we see the opposite for term
equity factors. spread () portfolio, which underperforms the market
in positive surprises but outperforms when it is
Because their macro exposures are relatively weak meant to (i.e., when the surprises in term spread are
and unstable over time, standard equity factors may negative). We see that all portfolios outperform in
not be suitable tools to build portfolios that target macro conditions that they target. The only excep-
macro exposures. In contrast, dedicated macro port- tion is the short-rates (þ) portfolio that comes with
folios allow for more effective targeting of statistically insignificant, albeit positive, outperform-
macro exposures. ance during the times of positive interest rate sur-
prises. The inflation (þ) portfolio demonstrated a
Conditional Performance of Dedicated very strong performance when expected inflation
Macro Exposure Portfolios. We now show rises: The annualised returns are more than 20 per-
how desired macro exposures translate into returns
centage points higher than that of the market port-
of the macro dedicated portfolios. We split the sam-
folio during positive inflation shocks.
ple into positive and negative surprises (top/bottom
25%) for each given macro variable. A portfolio that The dedicated macro strategies deliver economically
targets positive exposure to a given macro variable large and statistically significant outperformance
should outperform the market when the surprise in when innovations in the targeted variable are in the
this variable is positive, and vice versa. Figure 4 desired direction, with the exception of short rates
reports average annualised returns adjusted for mar- (þ). Whilst it is beyond the scope of this paper to
ket exposure for all dedicated macro portfolios in analyse particular applications of such portfolios, it is
respective conditions of macro surprises. For clear that the reliable conditionality of macro

Figure 4. Conditional Relative Performance of Macro Dedicated Portfolios

The plot shows average annualised returns of macro dedicated portfolios after adjusting for their market exposure (CAPM beta).
The analysis was done from 19 June 1970 to 30 June 2022 for all portfolios, except for the inflation portfolios, for which the ana-
lysis starts on 31 March 2002. Positive (negative) surprise periods are defined as calendar weeks (Friday to Friday) when the change
in a given macro variable was amongst the top (bottom) 25% of historical observations. Returns that are statistically significant at a
5% level are presented in bars with solid fill, whilst returns that are not statistically significant at 5% are presented in bars filled
with diagonal stripes.

50
Targeting Macroeconomic Exposures in Equity Portfolios

dedicated portfolios can be of great use for investors. Table 8 shows the results of seven-factor regressions
For example, an investor with a large allocation to that include the market as well as six long-short
credit could offset the losses by investing their equity factors widely used in the literature. We find
equity portfolio in a credit spread (þ) strategy, thus that market betas of dedicated macro portfolios range
outperforming the market during the periods of posi- between 0.87 and 1.06. Exposures to other equity
tive surprises in credit spread. As another example, factors are small in magnitude for most strategies and
for an active investor who thinks that inflation rarely exceed 0.30 in magnitude. Another pattern that
expectations will rise unexpectedly in the future, we observe consistently across all strategies is a posi-
using an inflation (þ) portfolio can provide strong tive exposure to the size factor, which is expected
performance for their equity portfolio in times when because we weight the selected stocks equally.
surprises in breakeven inflation are positive.
Table 8 also provides interesting insights regarding
Overall, the results suggest that macro dedicated the multifactor alphas of macro dedicated portfolios.
portfolios can provide strong and economically sig- In particular, we find that seven out of eight port-
nificant outperformance over the market portfolio in folios have an alpha that is statistically indistinguish-
desired macro conditions. Investors who are con- able from zero. The credit spread (þ) portfolio has a
cerned with substantial movements in certain macro- positive and significant alpha in the multifactor
economic variables can benefit by investing in the model. None of the eight portfolios display a signifi-
corresponding macro dedicated portfolio. cantly negative multifactor alpha over the sample
period. This suggests that investors, who had
Performance and Risk of Dedicated focussed on targeting their desired macro exposure,
Macro Exposure Portfolios. The macro dedi- would not have born a cost of underperformance
cated portfolios deliver positive outperformance over (negative alpha), regardless of which of the eight pos-
the market portfolio during times of surprises, either sible exposures they had targeted.
positive or negative, in a targeted macro variable. We
now analyse the unconditional performance and risk Our results imply that equity investors can target
of these strategies. As a reference, we use the cap- desired macro exposures without paying a premium.
weighted market portfolio. To further evaluate the potential performance implica-
tions of targeting macro exposures, we also estimate
Table 6 reports unconditional performance of various the trading costs of macro dedicated portfolios. Table
macro dedicated portfolios. The results suggest that 9 reports transaction costs as well as performance
the performance of macro-dedicated portfolios is not measures net of transaction costs for different macro
markedly different from the reference index. The strategies. We follow Corwin and Schultz (2012) and
statistical significance test of the differences in Chung and Zhang (2014) to estimate the proxy of
Sharpe ratios indicates that only the credit spread (þ) effective bid-ask spread.16 These two approaches have
portfolio has a Sharpe ratio greater than the market been shown to yield to reliable and accurate proxies
portfolio. Risk-adjusted performance of all other of intra-day effective spreads. The measures proposed
macro dedicated portfolios is statistically indistin- by Chung and Zhang (2014) is more accurate, but it
guishable from that of the reference index. The devi- can only be applied starting in 1993, because the clos-
ations in relative returns are small, ranging between ing bid and ask prices that are used for computing the
0.53% and 1.76%. The p values of relative returns effective bid-ask spread are only available from that
are all above 5%, meaning that none of these return point. Hence, we rely on effective spreads following
differences are statistically significant. Corwin and Schultz (2012) before 1993 and following
Chung and Zhang (2014) afterwards.
Note that we have omitted the inflation portfolios
from this analysis because they are only available The results in Table 9 indicate that the annual trans-
staring in March 2002. Table 7 reports the same ana- action costs of macro dedicated portfolios are below
lysis for inflation portfolios, but over the period start- 35 basis points. Therefore, the impact on the per-
ing on 31 March 2002 and ending on 30 June 2022. formance is mild, and our conclusions from the ana-
Our findings are very similar to those above. The dif- lysis of gross returns remain intact. In particular,
ferences in Sharpe ratio as well as relative returns macro strategies do not come with significantly lower
are statistically insignificant. Overall, we do not find Sharpe ratios, and the multifactor alphas are statistic-
that any macro dedicated strategies bear significant ally indistinguishable from zero for the portfolios tar-
cost relative to the market index in our sam- geting either positive or negative exposures to the
ple period. short rates and term spread. The only significant

Volume 79, Number 1 51


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 6. Unconditional Performance of Macro Dedicated Portfolios


United States
19 June
1970–30 Short Rates Short Rates Term Spread Term Spread Credit Spread Credit Spread
June 2022 Cap-Weighted (þ) () (þ) () (þ) ()

Absolute 10.70% 11.35% 11.87% 11.28% 11.93% 12.45% 11.22%


return
Volatility 17.08% 18.61% 16.69% 18.78% 16.51% 15.97% 18.97%
Sharpe ratio 0.35 0.36 0.43 0.35 0.44 0.48 0.34
p value of the – 83.6% 22.6% 76.0% 10.8% 1.5% 60.2%
differences
in Sharpe
ratio
Relative return – 0.66% 1.18% 0.59% 1.23% 1.76% 0.53%
p value of – 25.9% 29.7% 40.9% 19.4% 9.3% 32.5%
relative
return
Tracking error – 5.45% 6.73% 7.16% 5.52% 5.85% 5.90%
Information – 0.12 0.17 0.08 0.22 0.30 0.09
ratio

Notes: The table reports performance and risk measures for macro dedicated portfolios. The analysis was done using daily returns
in USD, from 19 June 1970 to 30 June 2022. The annualised returns are computed as geometric average, whilst the statistical
tests of differences in Sharpe ratio and relative returns use arithmetic average. The p values of the differences in Sharpe ratios are
computed following the methodology proposed by Ledoit and Wolf (2008). Statistical significance of the differences in relative
returns and Sharpe ratios is indicated by a single asterisk () for results that are significant on a 5% basis and double asterisks ()
for results that are significant on a 1% basis.

Table 7. Unconditional Performance of Inflation Targeting Portfolios


United States
31 March 2002 to 30 June 2022 Cap-Weighted Inflation (þ) Inflation ()

Absolute return 7.88% 6.31% 9.42%


Volatility 19.65% 26.12% 18.61%
Sharpe ratio 0.33 0.19 0.44
p value of the differences in Sharpe ratio – 16.3% 17.3%
Relative return – 1.56% 1.55%
p value of relative return – 89.1% 34.6%
Tracking error – 10.37% 5.56%
Information ratio – 0.15 0.28

Notes: The table reports performance and risk measures for macro dedicated portfolios. The analysis was done using
daily returns in USD, from 31 March 2002 to 30 June 2022. The annualised returns are computed as geometric aver-
age, whilst the statistical tests of differences in Sharpe Ratio and relative returns use arithmetic average. The p-values
of the differences in Sharpe ratios are computed following the methodology proposed by Ledoit and Wolf (2008).
Statistical significance of the differences in relative returns and Sharpe ratios is indicated by a single asterisk () for
results that are significant on a 5% basis, and double asterisks () for results that are significant on a 1% basis.

performance difference observed in our analysis is find no evidence that portfolios that come with posi-
for the credit spread (þ) portfolio, which outperforms tive or negative exposure to breakeven inflation
the market and the multifactor benchmark, even cause reduction in the performance relative to the
after accounting for transaction costs. market portfolio or a multifactor benchmark. Note
that the transaction costs for inflation portfolios are
The results are similar in Table 10, where we focus substantially smaller than those reported in Table 9.
on inflation portfolios over a more recent period. We This is mainly due to the differences in sample

52
Targeting Macroeconomic Exposures in Equity Portfolios

Table 8. Factor Exposure Analysis of Macro Dedicated Portfolios


United States
19 June Credit Credit
1970a–30 Short Rates Short Rates Term Spread Term Spread Spread Spread Inflation Inflation
June 2022 (þ) () (þ) () (þ) () (þ) ()

Unexplained 1.14% 1.53% 1.45% 1.36% 2.00% 1.13% 1.54% 0.37%


Market 1.05 0.87 0.94 0.99 0.88 1.04 1.06 0.99
Size 0.15 0.37 0.32 0.15 0.24 0.19 0.27 0.17
Value 0.08 0.06 0.26 0.05 0.19 0.07 0.37 0.10
Momentum 0.05 0.10 0.07 0.10 0.05 0.06 0.14 0.12
Volatility 0.01 0.05 0.28 0.30 0.00 0.11 0.16 0.22
Profitability 0.32 0.15 0.12 0.14 0.20 0.30 0.44 0.12
Investment 0.08 0.01 0.15 0.24 0.04 0.20 0.10 0.10
R-squared 90.95% 85.87% 89.79% 88.22% 87.24% 90.96% 92.26% 93.26%

Notes: The table reports factor exposures of macro dedicated portfolios. The analysis was done using weekly returns in USD, from
19 June 1970 to 30 June 2022. aThe only exception is portfolios targeting exposure to breakeven inflation, for which the analysis
starts in 31 March 2002. Factor intensity is the sum of all factor exposures except for the market factor. The unexplained returns
are annualised. Statistical significance is indicated by a single asterisk () for results that are significant on a 5% basis and double
asterisks () for results that are significant on a 1% basis.

Table 9. Performance of Macro Dedicated Portfolios Net of Transaction Costs


Short Rates Term Spread Credit Spread
31 December Broad U.S.
1977–30 June 2022 Cap-Weighted (þ) () (þ) () (þ) ()

Gross annual return 11.41% 12.09% 11.84% 11.63% 12.53% 13.13% 11.60%
Net annual return 11.39% 11.79% 11.60% 11.31% 12.21% 12.85% 11.26%
Annual transaction cost 1 bps 30 bps 24 bps 32 bps 32 bps 27 bps 34 bps
Annual turnover 2.90% 51.77% 42.67% 53.49% 52.79% 48.45% 56.22%
Net Sharpe ratio 0.40 0.40 0.43 0.37 0.49 0.53 0.37
p value – 80.6% 63.2% 43.7% 13.3% 2.6% 38.1%
Net multifactor alpha 0.00% 0.80% 0.81% 0.64% 1.18% 1.84% 0.43%
p value – 36.3% 39.3% 48.0% 19.1% 3.5% 62.1%

Notes: Transaction cost is estimated as a difference in gross annualised performance and annualised performance net of transac-
tion costs. The stock-level transaction costs are estimated from daily prices. Prior to 1993, we use the methodology proposed by
Corwin and Schultz (2012), whilst after 1993, we rely on the methodology of Chung and Zhang (2014). The reported turnover is a
one-way turnover, computed quarterly and annualised by multiplied the average by 4. The p values of the differences in Sharpe
ratios are computed following the methodology proposed by Ledoit and Wolf (2008). The analysis was done from 31 December
1977 to 30 June 2022. The analysis starts only in 1977 due to data quality and availability of intra-day high and low prices.
Statistical significance of the differences in net Sharpe ratios and net multifactor alphas is indicated by a single asterisk () for
results that are significant on a 5% basis and double asterisks () for results that are significant on a 1% basis.

period.17 The transaction costs have declined dramat- rebalancing. Such rules could be used to further
ically over recent decades, as the market structure reduce transaction costs in practice (see Novy-Marx
has improved, in particular through the reduction in and Velikov 2016).
minimum tick size for trading (see Bruno et al.
2019). Therefore, historical estimates of trading Overall, our findings are consistent with empirical evi-
costs, such as the ones in Table 9, are inflated com- dence in a recent study by Herskovic, Moreira, and
pared to the costs that investors face today. Also Muir ([2019) which finds that hedging exposures to dif-
note that we did not apply further implementation ferent macro risks, including the credit spread and term
rules, such as buffers in stock selection or invest- spread, has little to no impact on expected returns.
ability rules that reduce the amount of trading at Moreover, the empirical asset pricing literature has

Volume 79, Number 1 53


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 10. Performance of Inflation Portfolios Net of Transaction Costs


Breakeven Inflation
31 March 2002–31 December 2019 Broad U.S. Cap-Weighted (þ) ()

Gross annual return 8.20% 7.71% 9.12%


Net annual return 8.20% 7.56% 8.99%
Annual Transaction cost <1 bps 14 bps 13 bps
Annual turnover 3.50% 47.58% 43.29%
Net Sharpe ratio 0.36 0.25 0.42
p value – 33.8% 32.6%
Net multifactor alpha 0.00% 1.41% 0.25%
p value – 35.6% 80.2%

Notes: Transaction cost is estimated as a difference in gross annualised performance and annualised performance net of transac-
tion costs. The stock-level transaction costs are estimated from daily prices following the methodology proposed by Chung and
Zhang (2014). Statistical significance of the differences in net Sharpe ratios and net multifactor alphas is indicated by a single
asterisk () for results that are significant on a 5% basis and double asterisks () for results that are significant on a 1% basis.

established a set of workhorse models to explain the rely on innovations in forward-looking variables that
cross -section of stock returns that have evolved over quickly incorporate investors’ expectations about eco-
time (from the Fama and French [1993] three-factor nomic conditions, such as short-term interest rates, the
model to the Fama and French [2018] six-factor model term spread, the credit spread, and breakeven inflation.
or the Hou, Mo, Xue, and Zhang [2021] five-factor To capture exposure of stocks to these macro sur-
model). Whilst these models draw on slightly different prises, we apply statistical tools to improve robustness.
sets of equity-style factors, none of them includes We then construct dedicated portfolios from the result-
macroeconomic factors, such as the variables studied in ing firm-level measures of macro exposure. Such equity
this paper. This is in line with the idea that such macro- strategies come with statistically and economically sig-
economic factors do not offer risk compensation over nificant exposures out of sample.
and above what the typical equity-style factors capture.
Our robust measurement procedure delivers a more
In contrast, several papers argue that some macro- robust and reliable classification of stocks than stand-
economic factors may be separately priced in the ard estimation approaches. When constructing equity
cross-section. Boons (2016) finds that the term portfolios that target high or low macroeconomic
spread and credit spread are priced factors in a broad exposure, our procedure leads to more than 40%
cross-section of U.S. equities (including small- and
higher realised out-of-sample exposures and more
micro-cap stocks), but the short rate is not. Petkova
than 70% improvements in t-statistics associated with
(2006) finds that exposures to short rates are priced
these exposures, compared to naïve estimation.18
along with term spread, but the credit spread is not.
Such studies, however, have not led to a generally Our approach of building dedicated portfolios using
accepted inclusion of macro factors in workhorse stock-level exposures also captures macro exposures
models used to explain the cross-section of stock more reliably than using off-the-shelf building blocks,
returns. In our setting, where we analyse a universe such as sector or factor indices. We show that allo-
of liquid stocks and account for a broad set of style cating across sectors or factors leads to weaker
factors, macro exposures are not associated with exposures than our dedicated macro portfolios and
separate risk premiums. An interesting avenue for sometimes even leads to exposures that are incon-
future research is to assess risk premia for macro sistent with the objective. The reason behind this is
exposures whilst accounting for the fact that risk that sectors or factors are not designed to discrimin-
premia may be dynamic and may change sign over ate assets by macroeconomic risk exposures, whilst
time (see, e.g., Boons et al. 2020, 2021).
the stock-level approach can fully exploit the hetero-
geneity of exposures in the cross-section of equities.
Conclusion In addition, our proposed strategies are fully system-
We have proposed a methodology to estimate stock- atic and do not rely on common beliefs or the discre-
level exposures to different macroeconomic risks. We tionary choices of an asset manager.

54
Targeting Macroeconomic Exposures in Equity Portfolios

Finally, we showed that our macro exposure strategies Overall, we show that our macro exposure measures
do not suffer from lower performance compared to a can add value for investors with a dual objective,
broad equity portfolio. The stand-alone returns of eight which is to harvest the long-term equity premium
macro exposure strategies as well as their Sharpe ratios and protect their total portfolio from sudden changes
are not significantly different from the market portfolio in economic conditions (or bet in favour of certain
in our sample. They also do not come with negative economic conditions). In practice, such measures
alphas in a multifactor model that includes the usual could be used for a variety of applications such as
style factors. Our conclusions hold when accounting tilting long-only portfolios to target the desired
for trading costs of dedicated macro portfolios. macro sensitivities.

Editor's Note
Submitted 8 March 2022
Accepted 11 November 2022 by William N. Goetzmann

Notes
1. An incomplete list includes Novy-Marx (2013) and Bali, Exposures we measure with respect to these variables
Brown, and Caglayan (2014). are not necessarily reliable out of sample. This suggests
that relying on market-based macro variables that
2. As we will see later, the statistical adjustments proposed reflect shocks in investor expectations is important to
by Boons (2016) are similar to the ones we use. successfully detect a link with equity returns (see
However, there are two key differences between our Amenc et al. [2019] for a detailed discussion of
analyses. First, we use higher frequency for estimation this argument).
than Boons (2016). It has been shown that higher
frequency increases sample size and improves the 5. Amenc et al. (2019) have not included expected inflation
accuracy (see Levi and Welch 2017). Second, Boons in their analysis.
(2016) looks at all common stocks in the CRSP universe,
which is much larger than our investable universe that 6. For a more detailed discussion on each state variable,
consists of the largest 500 stocks in U.S. Our mission is please refer to Amenc et al. (2019).
more difficult because distinguishing amongst high- and
7. Various studies document that term spread predicts
low-exposure stocks in a smaller universe requires
returns on long-term asset classes. See, for example,
more precision.
Fama and French (1989) for equities and bonds, Campbell
3. For clarity, we focus on a single objective of targeting (1996) for human capital, Hong and Yogo (2012) for
macro exposures. An interesting area for future research commodities, and Ang, Nabar, and Wald (2013) for
would be to assess how investors can combine real estate.
objectives in terms of factor exposures aimed at
8. We have also tested innovations from VAR(1,1) model,
improving unconditional returns with objectives in terms and our findings are unaffected by this change. Using
of macro exposures aimed at targeting VAR model was proposed by Campbell (1996) in this
conditional returns. context and has been followed by various other studies
more recently (e.g., Petkova 2006, Boons 2016). Each
4. We have also analysed the out-of-sample reliability of
macro variable is modelled as a linear function of the past
exposures to various other macro variables using our
values of all macro variables considered.
estimation approach, and the results are reported in the
Online Supplemental Material. First, we have estimated 9. We also require that at least 208 weekly observations are
exposures of stocks to macro variables that are based available for a given stock, which is equivalent to 80% of
on market prices that reflect investor expectations, such total observations in 5 years. For other estimation
as commodities, interest rates on U.S. Treasuries with approaches, which use OLS or monthly frequency, we
different maturities and inflation swaps. Our estimation also require that at least 80% of the total observations in
approach leads to highly reliable out-of-sample a five-year period are available.
exposures to these variables. In addition, we have
looked at aggregate economic indicators based on 10. Beyond information in returns, one might also
macro fundamentals, such as the Aruoba-Diebold-Scotti exploit information in company risk disclosures using
Business Conditions Index (ADS) and Bloomberg Weekly textual analysis. We have conducted additional
Consumer Comfort Index (CCI). These two macro analysis augmenting our returns-based measures using
variables aim to nowcast the economic activity, such as textual analysis. This approach also delivers robust
growth (for ADS) and consumer confidence (CCI), and exposures out of sample but is not reported here
are available at daily and weekly frequency, respectively. for brevity.

Volume 79, Number 1 55


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

11. Our universe excludes ADRs. approach can be considered an alternative to shrinkage,
as both approaches try to account for the uncertainty
12. We also tested the out-of-sample reliability of our around point estimate.
estimation approach in an Asian universe. Results can be
found in the Online Supplemental Material. 16. Our analysis accounts for the effective bid-ask spread,
but ignores the costs such as brokerage commissions,
13. Results of this long-term analysis can be found in the exchange taxes, and financial transaction taxes. Such
Online Supplemental Material. costs are difficult to account for because they may vary
widely depending on the bargaining power of investors.
14. The sectors are (1) energy, (2) basic materials, (3)
industrials, (4) cyclical consumer, (5) non-cyclical 17. We report more detailed analysis of turnover and
consumer, (6) financials, (7) healthcare, (8) technology, (9) transaction costs over different time periods for all macro
telecoms, and (10) utilities. dedicated portfolios in the Online Supplemental Material.

15. Note that we use exposure estimates before shrinkage, 18. The average out-of-sample beta increases from 1.71 to
because the standard errors of those exposures 2.45, whilst the average t-statistic increases from 2.53 to
correspond to “unshrunk” beta estimates. Such an 4.39, as shown in Table 2.

References
Amenc, N., M. Esakia, F. Goltz, and B. Luyten. 2019. Chousakos, Kyriakos, and Daniel Giamouridis. 2020. “Harvesting
“Macroeconomic Risks in Equity Factor Investing.” The Journal Macroeconomic Risk Premia.” The Journal of Portfolio
of Portfolio Management 45 (6): 39–60. doi:10.3905/jpm.2019. Management 46 (6): 93–109. doi:10.3905/jpm.2020.1.149.
1.092.
Chung, Kee H., and Hao Zhang. 2014. “A Simple Approximation
Andrews, D. W. K. 1991. “Heteroskedasticity and of Intraday Spreads Using Daily Data.” Journal of Financial
Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation.” Markets 17 : 94–120. doi:10.1016/j.finmar.2013.02.004.
Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 59 (3):
817–858. doi:10.2307/2938229. Corwin, Shane A., and Paul Schultz. 2012. “A Simple Way to
Estimate Bid-Ask Spreads from Daily High and Low Prices.” The
re, and O. Signori. 2012. “Inflation and
Ang, A., M. Brie
Journal of Finance 67 (2): 719–760. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.
Individual Equities.” Financial Analysts Journal 68 (4): 36–55.
2012.01729.x.
doi:10.2469/faj.v68.n4.3.
Devarajan, M., V. Naik, A. Nowobilski, S. Page, and N.
Ang, A., N. Nabar, and S. Wald. 2013. “Searching for Common
Factor in Public Private Real Estate Returns.” The Journal of Pedersen. 2016. Factor Investing and Asset Allocation – a
Portfolio Management 39 (6): 120–133. doi:10.3905/jpm.2013. Business Cycle Perspective. Charlottesville, VA: The CFA
39.6.120. Institute Research Foundation. http://library.asue.am/open/
5334.pdf.
Bali, T. G., S. J. Brown, and M. O. Caglayan. 2014.
“Macroeconomic Risk and Hedge Fund Returns.” Journal of Estrella, A., and M. R. Trubin. 2006. “The Yield Curve as a
Financial Economics 114 (1): 1–19. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2014. Leading Indicator: Some Practical Issues.” Current Issues in
06.008. Economics and Finance, Federal Reserve Bank of New York 12 (5).
https://msuweb.montclair.edu/lebelp/
Boons, M. 2016. “State Variables, Macroeconomic Activity, and
the Cross Section of Individual Stocks.” Journal of Financial EstrellaYieldCurveIndicatorFRBNY200608.pdf.
Economics 119 (3): 489–511. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2015.05. Fama, E. F. 1981. “Stock Returns, Real Activity, Inflation, and
010. Money.” The American Economic Review 71 (4): 545–565.
Boons, Martijn, Fernando Duarte, Frans De Roon, and Marta Fama, E. F., and K. R. French. 1989. “Business Conditions and
Szymanowska. 2020. “Time-Varying Inflation Risk and Stock Expected Returns on Stocks and Bonds.” Journal of Financial
Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 136 (2): 444–470. doi:
Economics 25 (1): 23–49. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(89)90095-0.
10.1016/j.jfineco.2019.09.012.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French. 1993. “Common Risk Factors in
Bruno, G., M. Esakia, and F. Goltz. 2019. Towards Cost
the Returns on Stocks and Bonds.” Journal of Financial
Transparency: Estimating Transaction Costs for Smart Beta
Economics 33 (1): 3–56. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(93)90023-5.
Strategies. Nice, France: Scientific Beta.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French. 1997. “Industry Costs of Equity.”
Campbell, J. Y. 1987. “Stock Returns and the Term Structure.”
Journal of Financial Economics (18) (2): 373–399. doi:10.1016/ Journal of Financial Economics 43 (2): 153–193. doi:10.1016/
0304-405X(87)90045-6. S0304-405X(96)00896-3.

Campbell, J. Y. 1996. “Understanding Risk and Return.” Journal Fama, E. F., and K. R. French. 2018. “Choosing Factors.” Journal
of Political Economy 104 (2): 298–345. doi:10.1086/262026. of Financial Economics 128 (2): 234–252. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.
2018.02.012.
Chen, N.-F., R. Roll, and S. A. Ross. 1986. “Economic Forces
and the Stock Market.” The Journal of Business 59 (3): 383–403. Herskovic, B., A. Moreira, and T. Muir. 2019. Hedging Risk
doi:10.1086/296344. Factors (Working paper). https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3148693

56
Targeting Macroeconomic Exposures in Equity Portfolios

Hong, H., and M. Yogo. 2012. “What Does Futures Market Covariance Matrix.” Econometrica 55 (3): 703–708. doi:10.
Interest Tell Us About the Macroeconomy and Asset Prices?” 2307/1913610.
Journal of Financial Economics 105 (3): 473–490. doi:10.1016/j.
jfineco.2012.04.005. Novy-Marx, R. 2013. “The Other Side of Value: The Gross
Profitability Premium.” Journal of Financial Economics 108 (1):
Hou, K., H. Mo, C. Xue, and L. Zhang. 2021. “An Augmented q- 1–28. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.01.003.
Factor Model With Expected Growth.” Review of Finance 25 (1):
1–41. doi:10.1093/rof/rfaa004. Novy-Marx, R., and M. Velikov. 2016. “A Taxonomy of
Anomalies and Their Trading Costs.” Review of Financial Studies
Jurczenko, Emmanuel, and Je  ro
^ me Teiletche. 2020. Macro 29 (1): 104–147. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhv063.
Factor-Mimicking Portfolios (Working paper). https://doi.org/10.
2139/ssrn.3363598 Petkova, R. 2006. “Do the Fama–French Factors Proxy
for Innovations in Predictive Variables?” The Journal of
Keim, D. B., and R. F. Stambaugh. 1986. “Predicting Returns in Finance 61 (2): 581–612. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.
the Stock and Bond Markets.” Journal of Financial Economics 17 00849.x.
(2): 357–390. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(86)90070-X.
Swade, Alexander, Harald Lohre, Mark Shackleton, Sandra
Ledoit, O., and M. Wolf. 2008. “ Robust Performance Nolte, Scott Hixon, and Jay Raol. 2021. “Macro Factor
Hypothesis Testing With the Sharpe Ratio.” Journal of Empirical Investing With Style.” The Journal of Portfolio Management 48
Finance 15 (5): 850–859. doi:10.1016/j.jempfin.2008.03.002. (2): 80–104. doi:10.3905/jpm.2021.1.306.
Levi, Y., and I. Welch. 2017. “Best Practice for Cost-of-Capital Ung, D., and P. Luk. 2016. “What is in Your Smart Beta
Estimates.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 52 (2):
Portfolio? A Fundamental and Macroeconomic Analysis.” The
427–463. doi:10.1017/S0022109017000114.
Journal of Index Investing 7 (1): 49–77. doi:10.3905/jii.2016.7.
Longstaff, F. A. 2004. “The Flight-to-Liquidity Premium in U.S. 1.049.
Treasury Bond Prices.” The Journal of Business 77 (3): 511–526.
Vasicek, O. A. 1973. “A Note on Using Cross-Sectional
doi:10.1086/386528.
Information in Bayesian Estimation of Security Betas.” The
Newey, W. K., and K. D. West. 1987. “A Simple, Positive Semi- Journal of Finance 28 (5): 1233–1239. doi:10.1111/j.1540-
Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent 6261.1973.tb01452.x.

Volume 79, Number 1 57


Research Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute
https://doi.org/10.1080/0015198X.2022.2129946

Supply Chain
Climate Exposure
Greg Hall, Kate Liu, Lukasz Pomorski, and Laura Serban
Greg Hall is an executive director at AQR Capital Management, LLC, Greenwich, CT. Kate Liu is an executive director at AQR Capital
Management, LLC, Greenwich, CT. Lukasz Pomorski is a managing director at AQR Capital Management, LLC, Greenwich, CT. Laura
Serban is a managing director, AQR Capital Management, LLC, Greenwich, CT. Send correspondence to Lukasz Pomorski at
lukasz.pomorski@aqr.com.

We propose an intuitive measure Introduction


of supply chain climate risks, limate-related risks and opportunities have become some of the
reflecting the fact that even a
green company may have material
climate exposure if its customers
or suppliers face climate risks.
C most pressing priorities for investors. For most, climate-aware
investing means managing a portfolio’s carbon emissions, or its
exposure to carbon reserves or green revenues. This is a natural starting
point but is unlikely to offer a complete, holistic view of a portfolio’s cli-
Our measure captures price mate risk. Importantly, most traditional metrics will not capture expo-
movements around climate news sures along the supply chain. The few climate metrics that have a supply
better than traditional climate chain component (e.g., scope 3 emissions) are usually motivated by car-
data and shows performance pat- bon accounting rather than climate risk and are generally thought to be
terns consistent with re-pricing of extremely noisily estimated.1 We fill this gap by proposing a simple and
climate risks. The metric is more intuitive measure of supply chain climate exposure. The measure reflects
suitable for risk measurement the strength of economic connections along the supply chain and is thus
than scope 3 emissions and more likely to capture risks; it can also be readily computed by investors
requires raw data that is broadly or their data providers for a broad cross-section of firms and using data
accessible for large cross-sections that is verifiable and of arguably high quality.
of stocks and is of higher quality
than currently available scope 3 To motivate our approach, we consider an example of a real-world
data. We discuss applications for payments services company from a sector (IT) and industry (IT serv-
both portfolio and corporate deci- ices) that are rarely associated with climate risks.2 In fact, based on
sion-making. standard climate data such as carbon intensity or carbon footprint,
this company seems green even compared to its sector or industry
Keywords: carbon emissions; peers. For example, its scope 1 and 2 emissions are lower than the
climate; emissions offshoring; industry and sector median, and its scope 3 emissions are in the
ESG; greenhouse gas emissions; We thank two anonymous referees, Steffen Bixby, David Blitz, Nicole Boyson, Alfie
scope 3; supply chain Brixton, Jeff Dunn, Shaun Fitzgibbons, Andrea Frazzini, Luis Garcia-Feijoo, Jess
Gaspar, Will Goetzmann, Antti Ilmanen, Lasse Pedersen, Roberto Rigobon, Luke
Taylor, Dan Villalon, Eddie Watts, and Jing Zhang for helpful discussion and com-
ments. AQR Capital Management is a global investment management firm which
may or may not apply similar investment techniques or methods of analysis as
described herein. The security mentioned herein was selected merely as an example
and is not a recommendation to buy, sell, or hold. The views expressed here are
those of the authors and not necessarily those of AQR.
Disclosure: No potential conflict of This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons
interest was reported by the author(s). Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives License (http://creativecommons.org/
licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and
reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited, and is not
PL Credits: 2.0 altered, transformed, or built upon in any way.

58 © 2022 AQR Capital Management, LLC. Published with license by Taylor & Francis Group, LLC. Volume 79, Number 1
Supply Chain Climate Exposure

greenest quartile within its industry. Based on this chain climate exposure measure but also giving invest-
information alone, we may conclude that the com- ors a blueprint for testing other climate indicators.
pany has little climate risk exposure. However, our
assessment may change once we look at its custom- We show that our measure has intuitive, but rela-
ers. For example, the company’s 2012 10Ks state tively low correlations with traditional climate data.
that its top three strategic relationships with major More importantly, it helps explain stock price reac-
oil companies represented in the aggregate approxi- tions to climate-related news sentiment, supporting
mately 20% of its consolidated revenue. The large our interpretation of climate risk exposure. The cor-
economic exposure to oil majors may indicate that relations we find (about 0.2) are similar in magnitude
the company might be indirectly, but possibly materi- to the correlations of measures explicitly designed to
ally, exposed to disruptions and potential loss of rev- track climate sentiment (e.g., Engle et al. 2020). In
enue caused by climate-related risks. addition, our measure subsumes climate-related
information that is contained in third-party measures
This motivating example captures the economic intuition (e.g., scope 1, 2, or 3 emissions). We also demon-
behind our framework. In essence, we propose measur- strate that it exhibits intuitive patterns around those
ing supply chain climate exposure as a business- few climate-related events that have already materi-
weighted average of standalone climate exposure of a alized in our sample. For example, in the month fol-
firm’s customers and suppliers. For example, the down- lowing the G8 declaration to reduce emissions in
stream (customer-oriented) measure we analyze empiric- 2009 (an example of positive climate news), the
ally in this paper is a revenue-weighted average of stocks we identify as green on our measure outper-
customers’ own scope 1 þ 2 carbon intensity. Our meas- form the brown stocks by about 5%. Conversely, in
ure is higher for those firms that derive a large share of the month following the US presidential election of
revenue from carbon-heavy customers, with the idea 2016 (an example of negative climate news, given
that climate risks harming those customers would also President Trump’s vocal comments), green stocks
harm the firm’s revenues. The lens of revenues makes it lagged brown stocks by about 2%.
clear why supply chain climate exposure may be rele-
vant for a firm’s fundamentals (as would be any other In addition, we found strong historical performance
exposure that potentially affects revenues: e.g., Kolay, of long-short, market-neutral portfolios based on our
Lemmon, and Tashjian [2016] document large costs measure. Historically, such portfolios realized a
incurred by suppliers to economically distressed firms). Sharpe ratio of about 0.85. This performance is not
driven by broad country or sector bets (the country-
While our empirical analyses focus on the downstream adjusted within-industry version of the portfolio real-
supply chain, the framework we present here can be ized a Sharpe ratio of more than 0.7) and is not
employed to define an upstream metric: a cost- explained by standard academic factor models (the
weighted average of suppliers’ exposures. This meas- portfolio has annualized alphas of 6.5% to 9%). This
ure would also capture an aspect of a firm’s funda- is consistent with the market pricing in supply chain
mentals, with the idea that firms that rely on suppliers climate risks, possibly because they are deemed to
exposed to climate risks may face disruptions to their be increasingly material or because investors have
supply chains when such risks materialize. Beyond the less appetite for holding these risks. At the same
downstream and upstream measure, a third stand- time, we show that downstream supply chain expos-
alone metric that may round out the analysis is the ure also predicts fundamentals such as earnings or
portfolio company’s own climate exposure, for sales surprises, beyond what is captured by trad-
example, its carbon intensity, a measure already very itional quality, fundamental, or price momentum sig-
popular in investment practice (e.g., CFA Institute nals. This is consistent with our measure capturing a
2020, and the case studies included in that report). new facet of quality and potentially generating for-
ward-looking returns, similar to other quality signals.
We next empirically validate our downstream supply
chain measure. This is a challenge rarely attempted in Finally, and importantly, the supply chain measures
prior literature due to a paucity of data and the reality we propose are not meant to be a replacement for
that the most severe climate risks may not have yet scope 3 emissions data. They are related and can
materialized. Nonetheless, we believe investors should answer similar questions but differ in their explicit
insist on such analyses before they use a new metric in focus on financial risk exposure. For example, a com-
practice. We propose a series of such data tests, with pany may have zero scope 3 emissions but still score
the goal of not only increasing conviction in our supply very poorly on our downstream measure because it

Volume 79, Number 1 59


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

derives material revenue from customers with high Practical Applications of the
climate exposure and vice versa. Another clear differ-
ence is that scope 3 isolates those supply chain emis-
Supply Chain Climate
sions that are attributable to the company’s products, Exposure Measures
making it a preferred measure for carbon accounting The downstream supply chain measure we analyze in
purposes. In contrast, our measure may double-count detail in this paper and its upstream supply chain
a company’s emissions (e.g., a customer firm’s overall analogue (cost-weighted average exposure of a firm’s
emissions are counted separately for each of the suppliers) lend themselves most naturally to portfolio
firm’s suppliers), which is not ideal for carbon context applications, but they are also useful for cor-
accounting but in our view is acceptable as it leads porate decision-makers.
to a more comprehensive climate exposure
risk measure. We motivate our framework by its potential to cap-
ture climate risks in the supply chain of a portfolio
Given the strong interest in scope 3 emissions, company and in the sections below validate this
Figure 1 compares scope 3 and our downstream sup- claim empirically. Hence, the most obvious applica-
ply chain measure and the key ingredients necessary tion is risk monitoring and measurement, for
to compute them. The arrows illustrate the focus of example, highlighting situations when a portfolio
each metric: scope 3 captures emissions from suppli- drifts toward stocks with increased supply chain
ers into the product and from the product to custom- exposure and possibly triggering a further investiga-
ers; our measure instead depends on the economic tion of such stocks. The measures we propose can
revenue from customers to the company and from also be easily incorporated as a linear constraint in
the company to suppliers. portfolio optimization, for example, targeting a

Figure 1. A Simplified Comparison between Scope 3 Emissions and Downstream Supply Chain
Climate Exposure

Scope 3: accounng for the emissions traceable to a company’s products and services
Company A
Company A’s suppliers Some of A’s own emissions Company A’s customers
product specific emissions e.g. business travel product specific emissions

Product 1
.
.
.
Product n

Supply chain climate exposure: accounng for the strength of economic links with, and overall
emissions/climate exposure of a company’s customers and suppliers

Company A’s suppliers’ Company A Company A’s customers’


overall emissions/climate exposure overall emissions/climate exposure

Cost of supplies Revenue

Note: The schematic shows which data inputs are relevant for each climate measure, highlighting the product-centric nature of scope 3
emissions and the economic linkage-centric nature of the downstream supply chain climate exposure measure proposed in this paper.
Source: AQR. For illustrative purposes only.

60
Supply Chain Climate Exposure

specific reduction in exposure versus a benchmark. Report, IBM (2020) stated that “the assumptions that
Some investors may also decide to formally incorpor- must be made to estimate Scope 3 emissions in most
ate them into a risk model, with the goal of hedging categories do not enable credible, factual numbers.”
out climate-type risks, possibly along the lines sug- Busch, Johnson, and Pioch (2022) not only find large
gested in Engle et al. (2020). In addition, our finding inconsistencies in scope 3 estimates but also find
of return patterns associated with the downstream that such inconsistencies actually increase over time,
measure suggests that it may potentially improve an suggesting that the growing investor and perhaps
investor’s investment view, for example, by enhanc- also regulatory interest in this measure has not yet
ing the understanding of a company’s quality profile. led to any unified reporting. Ducoulombier (2021)
We anticipate that such applications may be of inter- points out that reporting on scope 3 remains largely
est to both discretionary and systematic investors. voluntary today (even if some important regulators
such as the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission
Moreover, the data inputs underlying our approach
may require it in the near future), that existing
are broadly available to investors and are of relatively
reporting standards do not support comparisons
high quality, resulting in excellent data coverage of
between firms, and that data providers producing
our measure. These features support the use of the
scope 3 estimates typically take insufficient consider-
measure for reporting purposes, allowing compari-
sons across mandates or even asset classes (because ation of firm-level circumstances. In contrast, our
the measure is at the issuer level, it can inform both measure may not only be more material to a com-
equity and credit allocations). pany’s risks (as we argue above), but it will also be
far easier for a corporation to compute and will be
Our indicator may also be useful in stewardship, for more comparable across companies. Corporations
example, by identifying companies with abnormally know precisely who their customers and suppliers
high supply chain exposures as potential targets for are and how much revenue and cost they account
engagement or by measuring the progress that port- for. They still need the data on the overall emissions
folio companies make in engaging with their own of a customer or a supplier, but that data can be esti-
supply chain partners. This may be particularly rele- mated more precisely: Indeed, unlike scope 3 emis-
vant for emissions offshoring, which occurs when a sions, they are self-reported by the majority of
company switches from making the most carbon- companies in broad indexes such as MSCI World
intense components inhouse to buying them from (e.g., Bixby, Brixton, and Pomorski 2022; Bolton,
suppliers instead.3 When such components are pro- Kacperczyk, and Samama 2022). In addition, an
duced using company-owned assets, they increase important advantage of our approach is that it can
the company’s scope 1 emissions; when they are be adjusted to address at least some of the data
bought from suppliers instead, they only affect scope weaknesses that are a perennial problem in ESG. For
3 emissions. Because most investors today focus on example, when customers’ scope 1 þ 2 carbon emis-
scope 1 and 2, emissions offshoring may artificially sions data is not available (perhaps because they are
increase investors’ assessment of how green a port- private firms that do not report emissions), one could
folio company is. In principle, this behavior would be reasonably assume that their own climate exposure is
apparent in a firm’s scope 3 emissions, but as we in line with that of their peers. For example, even a
mention above, such data is unfortunately very noisy simple regression of scope 1 þ 2 emissions on indus-
(e.g., Andersson, Bolton, and Samama 2016; Callan try dummies explains more than 40% of the variabil-
2020; Cheema-Fox et al. 2021; Ducoulombier 2021). ity in emissions. This flexibility extends the resulting
Our measure can at least partially fill this gap by
data coverage for an investor and makes it easier for
helping identify companies that dramatically reduce
a corporate entity to compute its own supply chain
their scope 1 emissions but at the same time look
climate exposure.
increasingly brown on our measure.

Finally, we believe our measure will be useful not


only to investors but also to the portfolio companies. Data
Corporations face pressure to report environmental, For our empirical analyses below, we focus on large-
social, and governance (ESG)–type information, cap developed stocks, roughly equivalent to the hold-
increasingly including information related to their ings of the MSCI World Index. Importantly, we do
supply chains, e.g., scope 3 emissions. Unfortunately, not restrict the universe of customers or suppliers of
estimating product-related emissions is a daunting such stocks: For example, if a global developed firm
challenge. For example, in its 2020 Environment in our sample has emerging markets customers, we

Volume 79, Number 1 61


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

will utilize data on such customers to assess the on. Our methodology easily accommodates
firm’s supply chain climate exposure. such measures.

To measure downstream supply chain climate expos- Finally, we use a variety of standard returns and
ure, we need two core pieces of data. First, we need financials data from XpressFeed and a variety of
data on the commercial linkages between a company ESG-related metrics from MSCI and Trucost, as indi-
and its customers. This data has been popularized by cated below. Overall, our sample spans the period of
academic papers going back to Cohen and Frazzini May 2009 through December 2021.
(2008) and Menzly and Ozbas (2010). The supply
chain data we utilize here is blended from multiple Missing Data and Limitations of the
third-party vendors. These vendors use data from Supply Chain Climate Exposure Measure.
regulatory filings, earnings transcripts, company and Missing data is an inevitable part of research, and
industry publications, and news sources to compre- how missing data is dealt with may meaningfully
hensively track global supply chains and the strengths influence the analysis. We assume that a company
of linkages. We merge vendor data to maximize with missing carbon intensity data has similar carbon
coverage and precision. The linkages data we utilize intensity as its same-sector peers. This is preferable
to ignoring customers or suppliers with missing data
provides the best coverage we are aware of for our
and effectively giving them a free pass even when
universe of large-cap developed stocks: For example,
they are in sectors that are very pollutive. As we dis-
as of December 2021, we can identify at least one
cuss below, when dealing with missing data on the
customer for 87% of the stocks in our sample.
fraction of revenue companies have from a given
Ideally, the data would reflect not only a commercial customer, we impute the strength of the relationship
link between two companies but also the strength of using both the number of customers with missing
this link, for example, the fraction of a firm’s revenue revenue data and their market cap, so that same-
from a particular customer. For instance, Cohen and sized customers account for the same fraction
Frazzini (2008) collect this type of revenue data, lev- of revenue.
eraging disclosure regulations in the U.S. market
One potential weakness of our approach is that we
(companies must report customers accounting for
may not observe a customer–supplier linkage in the
more than 10% of revenues). We have at least partial
first place (We note that if portfolio companies self-
data on revenues for 58% of the companies with any
report on such measures, they of course have full
linkage data. While this coverage falls short of 100%, information about their own economic links). To par-
we use state-of-the-art data, utilized in multiple other tially address this, we normalize the data we have to
research papers, and are not aware of a dataset with 100%. For example, if the data at our disposal cap-
better systematic coverage. Moreover, even with tures only 70% of a firm’s revenue, we rescale it so
imperfect coverage, we capture the more material that it sums up to 100%. This implicitly assumes that
economic linkages (e.g., in the U.S., where these must the missing firms are as green as a typical customer
be reported to investors). Conditional on having rev- on which we do have coverage. This is not ideal
enue figures for at least one customer, our data cap- because, in some circumstances, the missing data
tures 19.4% of total revenues for the average firm. may be statistically biased. For instance, our data
does not include companies’ retail customers. One
The second piece of data we need is a measure of a
might expect that retail customers have a different,
customer’s (or a supplier’s) own climate exposure. In
perhaps “greener” profile than that of a typical cor-
the analyses below, we opted for a simple measure
porate customer. Unfortunately, we do not know
that we believe will resonate with investors: scope
how much of the missing data covers retail versus
1 þ 2 carbon intensity of customers and suppliers, as
corporate customers, making it challenging to adjust
reported in the Trucost database. We use this as an
the measure. Similarly, companies that may be off-
intuitive indicator of which customers and suppliers
shoring emissions, as we discuss in the Practical
are relatively greener or browner. We do not claim
Applications section, may strategically seek suppliers
that this simple indicator is necessarily the “best”
less likely to be covered by data providers (e.g., pri-
measure of climate risk exposure. We expect that
vate firms, or firms in emerging or frontier markets).4
investors interested in our approach will instead sub-
stitute their favored instruments, whether carbon In our assessment, data quality is sufficient for prac-
emissions from another vendor such as MSCI or cli- tical applications, in spite of the concerns above.
mate VaRs, Implied Temperature Rise scores, and so Data on customer linkages may not be perfect, but it

62
Supply Chain Climate Exposure

features prominently in academic and practitioner realistic, we assume that we have that data for two
research, so it seems fair to assume that much of the customers, A and B, and that the data is missing for
industry is familiar and perhaps even comfortable customers C and D. Table 1 summarizes the data for
with it.5 our example.

Another potential weakness of our analyses below is We first impute the missing revenue data for custom-
that we use scope 1 þ 2 emissions to gauge custom- ers C and D by normalizing the total revenue to
ers’ own climate exposure. This is only one of the 100%. This implicitly imposes the assumption that
many climate metrics investors may consider, but our the company only has four customers, that is, that
approach easily extends to other metrics. To the we are not missing any customer linkage. For most
extent an investor is comfortable using a different firms in our sample, this is likely to be an approxima-
variable to gauge climate exposure of a portfolio tion only, but we would expect that our data would
company, it stands to reason that the investor should include at least the most important commercial rela-
be comfortable using the same variable to gauge sup- tionships of each firm. For example, for U.S. compa-
ply chain climate exposure. nies, we know all relationships that account for more
than 10% of revenue, given the regulatory require-
ment to report them. In Table 1, we assume that cus-
Constructing the Downstream tomers C and D are equally important; in our
Supply Chain Climate empirical tests below, we impute the fraction of rev-
Exposure Measure enue using both the number of customers and their
size, arriving at higher imputed revenue for custom-
To make our downstream measure more tangible,
ers with a higher market cap.
we start with a hypothetical example, showing how
our measure is computed. Consider a firm with four Once we have the data on both customers’ own cli-
customers, whom we label with subscript j below mate exposure, Cj , and their relative revenue, wij ,
(so, j ¼ A, B, C, or D for the four customers). As our downstream supply chain climate exposure meas-
mentioned above, we do not restrict the customers ure for company i is simply the revenue-weighted cli-
to be in the same investment universe: For example, mate exposure, as per Equation (1):
the firm we study may be a large-cap developed
stock, while its customers may be small-cap and Downstream Supply Chain Climate Exposurei
X
emerging markets companies. To compute our ¼ w Cj ,
j ij
(1)
measure, we need to know each customer’s climate
exposure, Cj : In our applications below, Cj is cus- where in our empirical tests below Cj is customer j’s
tomer j’s scope 1 þ 2 carbon emissions intensity. In scope 1 þ 2 carbon intensity, defined as scope 1 þ 2
our example, we assume we have this data for each emissions divided by sales. We normalize by sales
of our hypothetical customers; in practice, missing rather than using overall emissions in tons, as the lat-
data could be replaced by industry or sector aver- ter would skew the metric toward large companies (a
ages. We also need data on the fraction of revenue large company will generally have higher overall car-
each customer j represents. To make our example bon emissions).

Table 1. Computing Downstream Supply Chain Climate Exposure for a Hypothetical


Company, i, with Four Customers, j ¼ A, B, C, and D
Customer’s Carbon
  Intensity Imputed % Revenue
Cj % Revenue from Each Customer ðwij Þ
Customer A 200 40% 40%
Customer B 100 30% 30%
Customer C 100 NA 15%
Customer D 50 NA 15%

Source: AQR. For illustrative purposes only.

Volume 79, Number 1 63


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

We focus on the downstream (customer) version of emissions than to either scope 1 or scope 2.6 In con-
the supply chain measure in our subsequent discus- trast, at the index level, estimated supply chain cli-
sion. The upstream (supplier) version can be com- mate exposure is meaningfully higher than that
puted analogously: implied by traditional emissions data. This is driven
by larger firms having higher supply chain exposure
Upstream Supply Chain Climate Exposurei
X (indeed, we see a strong correlation between supply
¼ v Cj ,
j ij
(2) chain exposure and market capitalization).

where vij is the fraction of business that company i Figure 2 suggests that our measure is correlated with
does with supplier j and Cj is supplier j’s scope 1 þ 2 standard carbon emissions metrics. For example, we
carbon intensity. The resulting metric is a cost- observe correlations of 0.1 to 0.15 between our
weighted climate exposure of a company’s suppliers. measure and scope 3 emissions. This may seem low
given that the two metrics both focus on the supply
chain, but—as we point out in the introduction—they
Summary Statistics of Downstream capture fundamentally different dimensions. More
Supply Chain Climate Exposure surprisingly, perhaps, our measure correlates with
We begin by comparing our supply chain measure to scope 1 emissions, meaning that firms that produce
the typical carbon emissions metrics: scope 1, 2, and more emissions from company-controlled sources
3 carbon intensity. Our analysis deals with large-cap also have customers who emit a lot. In this case, the
developed equities, so not surprisingly the resulting correlations increase to a more meaningful but still
data coverage is excellent. Our supply chain measure relatively low level of 0.3 to 0.4. This is partially
can be computed for 93% of the index weight in the because our measure depends on customers’ scope 2
average sample quarter and covers 96% of the index emissions: At least some of these will be the same as
toward the end of our sample; standard intensity scope 1 emissions of a given firm (in line with this
measures, as reported in the Trucost data, cover 87% intuition, the correlation is about twice as high for
of the index weight on average and 95% toward the Utilities than for firms in other sectors).
end of our sample. While the resulting coverage hap- We now turn to the distribution of our measure
pens to be similar for our measure and for standard across sectors and geographies, as presented in
carbon intensity data, we note that this is not guar- Figure 3. For ease of presentation, we show the
anteed. We can compute our metric even for those results in terms of the contribution of each sector (in
stocks that are not covered by Trucost, as long as we Panel A) and each region (in Panel B) to the overall
can identify at least some of their customers. In fact, index level. For comparison, we also show the index
we can compute our measure even if we do not weight of each sector and region. We compute the
have such customers’ own carbon intensity data, contributions for each quarter in our sample and
because we can leverage sector or industry member- then show the contribution for the average quarter
ship of these companies and use sector or industry in Figure 3.
averages as proxies. For example, an IT services com-
pany that received 10% of its revenue from an Oil In Panel A, we see that our downstream measure
and Gas customer is likely exposed to supply chain spikes for Utilities, Energy, and Materials, the three
climate risks, whether we explicitly have the custom- sectors that are also associated with high scope 1
er’s emissions data or not. These features of our emissions, suggesting that their (revenue-weighted)
approach may be particularly important in those average customer is also carbon-intense. This may
investment universes where the coverage of standard not be surprising: Companies that are important cus-
emissions data is poor, for example, for small-cap tomers for these sectors, and therefore use a lot of
equities or for private issuers in credit. energy, oil, gas, or minerals, are likely companies that
also have substantial greenhouse gas emissions.
Figure 2 presents supply chain and standard emis-
sions statistics for both a typical MSCI World con- The distribution by sector also shows that the down-
stituent and for the MSCI World Index overall. As stream carbon metric may capture different informa-
explained in the earlier sections, our downstream tion than scope 1, 2 and 3 carbon intensity. For
supply chain climate exposure measure is a revenue- example, we see a relatively higher downstream
level average of the carbon intensities of each firm’s exposure for Industrials than one may expect from
customers. The median stock’s downstream exposure traditional emissions data. Similarly, Financials have
is smaller than, but relatively closer to, scope 3 relatively larger downstream supply chain climate

64
Supply Chain Climate Exposure

Figure 2. Carbon Emissions Statistics over Time

A. Median Stock Carbon Emissions Exposures


140

median stock's emissions intensity 120


100
80
60
40
20
0

Jul-13

Jul-20
Jun-09
Jan-10

Mar-11

Feb-14

Jun-16
Jan-17

Mar-18
Dec-12

Nov-15

Dec-19

Feb-21
Aug-10

Oct-11

Sep-14
Apr-15

Aug-17

Oct-18

Sep-21
May-12

May-19
Downstream supply chain Scope 1 Scope 2 Scope 3

B. MSCI World Index–Weighted Carbon Emissions Exposures


400
MSCI World emissions intensity

350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
Jan-10
Jun-09

Mar-11

Jul-13

Jun-16
Jan-17

Mar-18

Jul-20
Sep-14
Dec-12

Feb-14

Nov-15

Dec-19

Feb-21
Aug-10

Oct-11

Aug-17

Oct-18

Sep-21
May-12

Apr-15

May-19

Downstream supply chain Scope 1 Scope 2 Scope 3

Note: The downstream supply chain climate exposure and scope 1, scope 2, and scope 3 emissions intensity for the median MSCI
World constituent in Panel A and for the overall MSCI World Index in Panel B for the period of June 2009 to December 2021.
Source: AQR, MSCI, Trucost.

exposure relative to scope 1, 2, and 3 carbon inten- mentioned in our data section, our customer data
sities. This suggests that some industrials and finan- does not include data on retail customers who may
cial companies provide goods and services to be relatively more important for Consumer Staples;
customers who may be subject to significant climate however, for this to explain the patterns in Figure 3,
risk, despite these companies’ stand-alone processes retail customers would need to be more carbon-
being relatively green. In contrast, downstream heavy than corporate customers. Finally, we note
exposure is relatively less pronounced for Consumer that supply chain climate exposure is relatively less
Staples, at least compared to the scope 3 emissions concentrated at the sector level than scope
of that sector. This is perhaps surprising. As we 1 exposure.

Volume 79, Number 1 65


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Figure 3. Sector- and Country-Level Contributions to MSCI World Index–Level Carbon


Emissions Metrics

A. Sector Contribuon to Various Carbon Emissions Metrics


50%
%contribution to MSCI World

45%
40%
35%
30%
25%
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%

weight Scope 1 Scope 2 Scope 3 Downstream supply chain

B. Country–Level Contribuon to Various Carbon Emissions Metrics


70%
%contribution to MSCI World

60%

50%

40%

30%

20%

10%

0%
USA Europe ex UK FRA JPN CAN Other
UK&FRA

weight Scope 1 Scope 2 Scope 3 Downstream supply chain

Note: Each sample quarter, percentage contributions to MSCI World Index are calculated from each sector (Panel A) and each coun-
try or broader region (Panel B) as of December 31, 2021. The charts show the time series averages of these contributions. In Panel
A, the historically deprecated Telecommunication is omitted from the chart.
Source: AQR, Trucost, MSCI.

66
Supply Chain Climate Exposure

Panel B of Figure 3 repeats the analysis by geog- it is a very poor excuse not to look at data. Markets
raphy, looking at the countries with the highest do react to potential future risks, so climate risks
weight in the MSCI World Index. We observe some may well affect historical stock prices even before
variability related to size (e.g., USA stands out in they materialize. Realistically, climate may account
absolute terms, but not when compared to the index only for a small fraction of a stock’s total or even
weight of that region), but no significant concentra- residual volatility—clearly less than, say, market beta,
tion beyond that. A couple of countries stand out in industry membership, and so on. For this reason, we
that their downstream supply chain exposure is sharpen the empirical tests below by conditioning
noticeably different than the traditional scope 1, 2, them on climate-related variables, for example, look-
or 3 exposure. For example, the UK contributes 4% ing at returns around climate-related news, when cli-
to 8% to MSCI World overall scope 1, 2, 3 weighted mate risk is more likely to be priced in or re-priced.
average carbon intensity but as much as 10% to the
index’s downstream supply chain exposure (for com- We first relate our downstream supply chain measure
parison, the average index weight of the UK is about to more traditional climate data, including
8%). On the flipside, Japan contributes less to index- Environmental (E-pillar) scores and carbon emissions.
level downstream exposure than it does to scope 1, A positive correlation with related third-party climate
2, or 3 emissions, suggesting that it does business data would lend credibility to our measure. If we
with relatively greener customers than its own emis- instead saw zero correlation with “standard” climate
sions profile would suggest. Last, we see that com- data, it would be difficult for us, or for the investor
modity-based economies such as Canada contribute community, to accept this measure, no matter how
more to the downstream supply chain exposure than plausible the intuition behind it. Second, we test
their weight in the index or their scope 3 emissions. whether downstream climate exposure correlates
It seems intuitive that commodity producers have with climate sentiment. That is, we check whether
carbon-heavy customers, but it is perhaps more sur- the companies identified by our measure as relatively
prising that they score as “browner” on our supply green or relatively brown experience returns, with
chain measure than they do on scope 3 emissions. intuitive signs, versus measures of market-wide senti-
Canada’s contribution to index-level downstream ment following climate news. Third, we use an event
exposure is twice as high as its scope 3 contribution study methodology to gauge the price behavior of
(Australia, while lumped into “Other” in Panel B, also stocks around meaningful macro-level climate news,
contributes twice as much to the supply chain expos- as a function of stocks’ downstream supply chain
ure as it does to scope 3). One explanation for this exposure. These tests may be circumstantial, but we
pattern is that the customers of commodity-produc- believe that the preponderance of evidence justifies
ing countries are relatively browner not just because the use of our proposed metric in invest-
of those countries’ own scope 3 emissions but also ment practice.
because of other sources of emissions; another is
that scope 3 data may be missing some components
Comparison to Third-Party Climate-
of customers’ scope 1 þ 2 emissions that we explicitly
Related Metrics. To compare our downstream
supply chain climate risk measure with other climate
account for here.
data, we regress it on scope 1, 2, and 3 emissions
intensity, as reported by Trucost, and on E-pillar and
climate change theme scores, as reported by MSCI.
Validating the Measure
Our approach to measuring supply chain climate Table 2 shows that downstream supply chain climate
exposure is based on a clear and intuitive economic exposure is strongly related to third-party measures
idea. However, before we can advocate practical use of emissions, in most cases with the intuitive signs.
of any measure, we want to go beyond the intuition For example, we expect a higher (riskier) downstream
and to the extent possible to also verify it with data. exposure for those companies that also have high
Unfortunately, this is a significant challenge for ESG carbon emissions intensity, at least in terms of scope
measures broadly speaking and for climate measures 1 and 3 emissions.7 Similarly, we find intuitive signs
in particular. This is because the outcome variables for climate-related measures from MSCI ESG data:
we care about here—instances of climate risks affect- Higher downstream supply chain carbon exposure
ing company valuations—are rare in historical data; correlates with lower (i.e., less attractive) overall
the most severe climate events, whether related to MSCI E score in regression (2) and lower Climate
physical or transition climate risks, may only occur in Change theme scores, the component of E that is
the coming years and decades. This may be true, but most related to our measure, in (3).8 We pool the

Volume 79, Number 1 67


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 2. Explaining Downstream Supply Chain Carbon Exposure with


Traditional Climate Data
(1) (2) (3) (4)

ln CO2 intensity, scope 1 0.29 0.08


(56.08) (14.43)
ln CO2 intensity, scope 2 0.09 0.01
(8.63) (1.76)
ln CO2 intensity, scope 3 0.15 0.09
(13.03) (6.83)
MSCI E-pillar score 0.05 0.00
(4.16) (0.90)
MSCI climate change score 0.04 0.02
(5.40) (3.93)
Sector þ region indicator NO NO NO YES
Observations 77,194 84,249 65,727 55,970
R2 0.280 0.011 0.010 0.461
Number of x-sections 51 51 36 36

Note: Estimates are from Fama-MacBeth regressions of the downstream supply chain carbon exposure (in logs)
on scope 1, 2, 3 carbon intensity (in logs), MSCI E-pillar, and MSCI Climate Change theme. Regressions (1)–(3)
do not include any additional explanatory variables; regression (4) also includes sector and regional indicator
variables. The regressions are run quarterly from June 2009 to December 2021 for the developed large-cap
universe (MSCI World); the table presents time series estimates t-statistics adjusted for heteroskedasticity and
auto-correlation with Newey-West procedure with 4 lags.
Indicates significance on a 5% basis and Indicates significance on a 1% basis.
Source: AQR, Trucost, MSCI.

explanatory variables and add sector and region indi- climate data, this might mean that our measure sim-
cators in regression (4) and again find strong positive ply does not capture any climate-related information.
correlations with scope 1 and 3 emissions. This time, The third-party measures we use here, and similar
surprisingly, we find a positive rather than a negative measures we did not have access to for this paper,
coefficient on the MSCI Climate Change theme, come from well-known, reputable data providers
counterintuitively suggesting that issuers with a who work with some of the most sophisticated
higher (i.e., more attractive) climate change score also investors and consultants. These measures may be
have higher downstream supply chain carbon expos- noisily estimated, but we posit that they capture at
ure. The sign flip is likely driven by the correlations least some climate-related information, meaning that
between the various climate variables; the interpret- we should expect at least some correlation with our
ation of the coefficient on MSCI Climate Change own metric.
score is more difficult when these correlated varia-
bles are included in the regression.9 At the same time, it is comforting that the correlation
is imperfect. Had we found R2 values close to 1.0,
Importantly, while we find strong and mostly intuitive we would have concluded that our measure effect-
correlations with typical ESG data, these third-party ively conveys the same information as what is
variables only capture a small amount of the variabil- already captured by traditional providers. This would
ity in our measure. R2 values in Table 2 range from
reduce the potential usefulness of our idea to
1% for high-level E and Climate Change scores to
those allocators who already subscribe to the stand-
20% to 30% when controlling for emissions-based
ard climate data. Of course, finding correlations lower
measures. Even in our “kitchen sink” regression (4),
than 1.0 is not a sufficient condition for success: The
where we also control for sector and region member-
low correlations might after all be attributable to
ship, traditional climate data and sector/country fixed
white noise that carries no incremental information
effects capture less than half of the variability of
about climate. To test whether this may be the case,
our measure.
and to isolate the incremental information in our
This combination of findings is encouraging. If we measure, we resort to sentiment analysis in the
found no correlations whatsoever with third-party next section.

68
Supply Chain Climate Exposure

Correlation with Climate News correlation is 1.76. To put these correlations in con-
Sentiment. While the most meaningful climate risk text, we note that our supply chain measure does
events may materialize only in the future, their likeli- not utilize any news data. For comparison, portfolios
hood of occurrence and potential impact are certainly explicitly optimized to correlate with climate news
discussed in the news media today. We can leverage sentiment in Engle et al. (2020) also show out-of-
such discussions to validate our measure: If it indeed sample correlations of about 0.2.
captures climate risk, then stocks with relatively
We believe that these positive correlations are an
higher exposure should do poorly when negative cli-
important validation of our measure, indicating that
mate news arrives; stocks with relatively lower
downstream supply chain climate exposure captures
exposure should do well. The advantage of this
information that the market subsequently deems
approach is that we rely on the overall market, rather
important in the climate context.
than on individual analysts, to assess which stocks
are more exposed to climate risks. Of course, we do We still need to check whether such information
not observe such market assessment directly, but we might simply be a function of some relatively obvious
can infer it implicitly from price movements around characteristics, such as sector or industry member-
climate news events, as explained in Engle et al. ship (for example, as we saw above, Utilities stand
(2020) and AQR (2021). Moreover, we can use this out on our measure). To address this, Figure 4 also
insight to check whether our measure captures infor- shows portfolios that are defined entirely within
mation not yet contained in standard climate data. industry. We still see a positive correlation here,
We do this by sorting stocks on a version of supply even if it is somewhat lower than before. Another
chain exposure that is orthogonalized to other cli- potential concern is that our measure is to some
mate data. extent correlated with traditional climate data (as we
To carry out this analysis, we need data on climate saw in the prior section) and the return correlations
sentiment. We utilize the Media Climate Change with climate news might be indirectly attributable to
Concern index (MCCC) from Ardia et al. (2021), such third-party data and not to our downstream
made publicly available from these authors, and supply measure per se. Figure 4, Panel A shows that
measure the arrival of (signed) climate news by look- this is not the case: We find similar levels of correla-
ing at the monthly changes to the index. This climate tions also for factors that were orthogonalized to
news sentiment data was used in other papers as scope 1, 2, and 3 emission and to MSCI’s Low
well, for example, in Pastor, Stambaugh, and Taylor Carbon Transition (LCT) scores.11
(2021), and was available until June 2018.10 Strikingly, the reverse does not hold when we
To measure the relationship between downstream instead analyze factors based on traditional climate
supply chain climate exposure and climate news sen- data in Figure 4, Panel B. On their own, factors based
timent, we form hypothetical factor portfolios that on greenhouse gas emissions, or on MSCI Low
long 50% of stocks with low downstream supply Carbon Transition scores, show correlations that are
chain climate exposure (we refer to these as “green relatively similar to those in Panel A. However, as
stocks”) and short the other 50% of stocks (“brown soon as we control for industry membership, these
stocks”). To avoid unintended bets, we form these correlations disappear for LCT scores or even turn
portfolios in a country-neutral manner, with or with- negative for scope 3 emissions. We still find low
out industry adjustments, and target zero beta positive correlations for scope 1 þ 2 emissions, but
(equity market neutral) and 7% ex ante volatility. As they decrease to almost zero when we orthogonalize
before, we use large-cap developed market stocks the factors to our downstream supply chain measure.
for this analysis. Figure 4 presents the (monthly) cor- We conclude that the correlations between trad-
relations between these factors and climate itional climate data and climate news either are due
news sentiment. to industry membership or are subsumed by our
downstream supply chain metric.
Figure 4 shows that factors based on downstream
supply chain climate exposure co-move with the cli- Reaction to Macro-Level Climate Change
mate news sentiment, with the positive correlation of News. Our last validation test relies on a simple
0.15 to 0.2. That is, the stocks we identify as greener event study methodology: We utilize the long-short
outperform the stocks we identify as brown at times factors based on downstream supply chain carbon
of increased climate concerns. Given the length of exposure data, introduced above, and assess how
our sample (109 months), the t-statistic on this they behave around major climate events. This

Volume 79, Number 1 69


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Figure 4. Correlation of Market-Wide Climate Sentiment with Factors Built Using Downstream
Supply Chain Carbon Exposure

A. Correlations of Downstream Supply Chain Factors with Climate News Sentiment


0.20
Correlation w/climate sentiment

0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
-0.05
-0.10
-0.15
-0.20
Base Orthogonal to Orthogonal to Orthogonal to Orthogonal to
Scope 1+2 Scope 3 MSCI LCT all three

Overall Within Industry


B. Correlations of Traditional Climate Data with Climate News Sentiment
0.20
Correlation w/climate sentiment

0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
-0.05
-0.10
-0.15
-0.20
Scope 1+2 Scope 3 MSCI LCT

Overall Within Industry


Overall, orth. to supply chain Within ind, orth. to supply chain

Note: The top panel shows monthly return correlations with the monthly changes in climate news sentiment index of Ardia et al.
(2021) for factors based on downstream supply chain climate exposure overall and within-industry exposure as well as after remov-
ing the commonality with other typical climate-related data. The bottom panel shows similar correlations for a hypothetical long-
short portfolio based on typical climate-related data, removing the commonality with the downstream supply chain measure, as indi-
cated in the chart. The hypothetical portfolio ranks stocks on (negated) downstream supply chain carbon exposure; neutralizes coun-
try and, as indicated, industry exposures; removes market exposures based on ex-ante beta; and targets 7% ex ante volatility. This
hypothetical portfolio is rebalanced monthly. Returns are gross of transaction costs, financing costs, and fees. Given the available cli-
mate sentiment data, the sample period is June 2009 through June 2018. Hypothetical performance results have many inherent lim-
itations, some but not all of which are described herein. No representation is being made that any fund or account will or is likely
to achieve profits or losses similar to those shown herein. Hypothetical performance results are presented for illustrative purposes
only. Hypothetical performance is gross of advisory fees and transaction costs and includes the reinvestment of dividends. If the
expenses were reflected, the performance shown would be lower.

70
Supply Chain Climate Exposure

Figure 5. Stock Reaction to Climate News Events

A. Example Posive Climate News Event: G8 Agrees to Reduce GHG Emissions by 80% by 2050
6%
Beta-adjusted returns
4%

2%

0%

-2%

-4%

-6%
-30 -27 -24 -21 -18 -15 -12 -9 -6 -3 0 3 6 9 12 15 18 21 24 27 30
Days relative to the event

Long Short

B. Example Negave Climate News Event: President Trump Withdraws the U.S. from Paris
Agreement
2%
Beta-adjusted returns

1%

0%

-1%

-2%

-3%

-4%
-30 -27 -24 -21 -18 -15 -12 -9 -6 -3 0 3 6 9 12 15 18 21 24 27 30
Days relative to the event

Long Short

Note: Daily cumulative beta-adjusted returns to the longs and shorts from the downstream supply chain climate exposure factor, in
the 30-day window surrounding two climate events: G8 committing to reducing emissions by 80% by 2050 on 9th July 2009 (Panel
A) and President Trump withdrawing the U.S. from the Paris Agreement on 1st June 2017 (Panel B). The long and short side are
beta-adjusted using the MSCI World Index benchmark. Universe of large-cap developed markets stocks, similar to MSCI World
Index constituents. The long-short factor portfolio ranks stocks on their (negated) supply chain carbon exposure, neutralizes country
and industry exposures, removes market exposures based on ex ante beta, and targets 7% ex ante volatility. This hypothetical port-
folio is rebalanced monthly. Returns are gross of transaction costs, financing costs, and fees.
Source: AQR.

experiment is obviously related to the climate senti- we illustrate this approach with two sample events,
ment analysis above and may be noisier in that the choosing one that is positive for climate (G8 commit-
information about such macro events may have been ting on 9th July 2009 to reduce greenhouse gas
telegraphed to the media, and thus also the market, emissions by 80% by 2050) and one that is negative
before the event itself took place. At the same time, (President Trump pulling the U.S. from the Paris
this approach has the benefit of a straightforward Agreement on 1st June 2017). Given the construc-
intuition and is arguably more transparent than the tion of our factors, we would predict them to do well
more sophisticated natural language processing tech- around positive climate news (i.e., we would expect
niques behind sentiment measures. For this reason, the long leg of the factor to appreciate relative to

Volume 79, Number 1 71


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

the short leg of the factor) and do poorly around


negative climate news (longs depreciate relative to Table 3. Portfolio Performance for
shorts). Figure 5 tests whether this is the case, show- Longshort Portfolios Based on
ing market beta-adjusted cumulative performance of Downstream Supply Chain
the longs and shorts in the 30-day window around
Climate Exposure
the two events in question. The “0” date on the x-
axis corresponds to the event itself. Unadjusted Within-Industry

The results in Figure 5 are more mixed, but we still Average return 7.4% 6.5%
Standard deviation 8.7% 9.0%
observe some encouraging patterns. For positive
of returns
news in Panel A, the short side of the factor (brown
Sharpe ratio 0.85 0.72
stocks) has negative market-adjusted performance Beta to MSCI World 0.07 0.05
after the event happens. The long side (green stocks) Hit ratio 56% 56%
is more muted and noisier. For negative news, it is
the long side that reacts more strongly, with more Note: Universe of large-cap developed markets stocks, similar
pronounced negative market-adjusted performance. to MSCI World constituents. The long-short portfolio ranks
stocks on (negated) downstream supply chain carbon exposure,
neutralizes country and, when indicated, industry exposures,
Of course, the two events we highlighted here are only
and removes ex-ante market exposures and targets 7% ex ante
a fraction of possible climate events one may consider. volatility. This hypothetical portfolio is rebalanced monthly.
As we explained above, we showcase them here to Returns are gross of transaction costs, financing costs, and
fees. The sample period is June 2009 to December 2021.
illustrate the overall approach but would argue that the
Source: AQR.
news sentiment analysis in the previous section is a
more informative way to validate the measure.

industry) and using the same universe of stocks as


Performance that used for the portfolio. We believe that such fac-
Our final section discusses the performance of stocks tors lead to a more conservative assessment in that
sorted on the downstream supply chain climate they match the most important design choices of the
exposure measure, utilizing the long-short portfolio portfolio being tested. The estimated alphas slightly
we introduced in our climate sentiment analysis decrease to 3.8% to 6% p.a. but remain economically
above. Hypothetical performance, gross of fees and sizeable and, with the exception of regression (9), sig-
transaction costs, is presented in Table 3. nificant at the 5% level.

We find strong performance for portfolios long in Table 4 also indicates that the downstream supply
green stocks and short in brown stocks, identified chain factor tends to have a positive growth exposure,
using our measure. The portfolio formed ignoring similarly to the green portfolio in Pastor, Stambaugh,
stocks’ industry membership realized a Sharpe ratio and Taylor (2021); estimated coefficients on other
of 0.85 over this period. This strong performance is investment factors are not consistent across specifica-
not subsumed by sector allocation (e.g., short Energy, tions. We have verified that the value spread of the
long IT) as we also find a relatively similar Sharpe portfolio does not meaningfully widen over this period,
ratio for the industry-neutral version of the portfolio. as might be expected if our results were driven primar-
As we show in Table 4, the performance is not ily by ESG investment flows. We also see at least as
explained by exposures to well-known investment strong performance in the first half of our 2009 to
factors such as Value or Momentum. 2021 sample as we do in the second half. In additional
robustness checks, we find that the performance is not
When the baseline portfolio is regressed on standard driven by a single country or region.
academic factors (Fama-French three- or five-factor
models, potentially augmented with momentum and While this strong performance is arguably good
betting against beta [BAB]), it still shows economic- news, we do not view it as strictly necessary for the
ally and statistically significant abnormal returns of validation of our measure. Our key research objective
6.5% to 9.4% p.a. As in Table 3, the within-industry is to study (downstream) supply chain climate expos-
results are slightly weaker but still strong in regres- ure, and it is at least theoretically possible that such
sions (4)–(6). In regressions (7)–(9), we apply an even exposures may not have strong performance implica-
more conservative test, redefining factors to match tions. Having said that, we note that this perform-
the portfolio construction (within-country, within- ance can be consistent with the market pricing in

72
Volume 79, Number 1
Table 4. Factor-Adjusted Performance of Downstream Supply Chain Climate Exposure (DSChCE) Long-Short Portfolios
Unadjusted DSChCE Portfolio Within-Industry DSChCE Portfolio Within-Industry DSChCE Portfolio
Unadjusted Academic Factors Unadjusted Academic Factors Within-Industry Academic Factors
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

Alpha 6.48% 9.41% 8.92% 5.31% 4.95% 6.55% 5.98% 4.85% 3.80%
(2.70) (3.92) (3.41) (2.15) (1.91) (2.35) (2.45) (1.97) (1.46)
Mkt-rf 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.03
(0.52) (1.12) (1.03) (0.22) (0.16) (0.31) (0.35) (0.52) (0.59)
Size 0.05 0.23 0.25 0.17 0.19 0.26 0.19 0.21 0.21
(0.38) (1.71) (1.75) (1.26) (1.32) (1.75) (2.24) (2.52) (2.40)
Value 0.39 0.56 0.53 0.44 0.57 0.51 0.40 0.27 0.18
(4.58) (4.34) (3.56) (4.99) (4.08) (3.17) (5.13) (3.03) (1.24)
Profitability 0.73 0.75 0.01 0.05 0.18 0.17
(4.10) (4.08) (0.04) (0.26) (2.24) (2.19)
Conservatism 0.02 0.05 0.31 0.33 0.14 0.15
(0.10) (0.23) (1.34) (1.37) (2.06) (2.15)
Momentum 0.02 0.13 0.07
(0.24) (1.27) (0.44)
BAB 0.04 0.23 0.11
(0.36) (1.88) (1.19)
Observations 151 151 151 151 151 151 151 151 151
R2 0.142 0.233 0.235 0.151 0.162 0.184 0.160 0.208 0.217

Note: Monthly returns of the downstream supply chain climate exposure long-short portfolio are regressed on the factors indicated in row labels. Regressions (1)–(3) use the port-
folio defined both across- and within-industry; in (4)–(9), the portfolio is based on within-industry supply chain exposures only. Regressions (1)–(6) use academic factors (Market,
Size, Value, Profitability, Conservatism, and Momentum are Mkt-rf, SMB, HML, RMW, CMA, and UMD, respectively from Ken French’s Data Library; BAB is from the AQR Data
Library), and regressions (7)–(9) use the within-industry versions of those factors, defined using equivalent stock characteristics (e.g., market cap for Size, book-to-price for Value,
etc.). Alphas are annualized, and t-statistics are shown in parentheses. The sample period is June 2009 to December 2021.
 indicates significance on a 5% basis and  indicates significance on a 1% basis.
Source: AQR, Ken French’s Data Library.

73
Supply Chain Climate Exposure
Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 5. Regressions Relating Quarterly EPS and Sales Surprises to Downstream Supply
Chain Climate Exposure
Unadjusted Industry Demeaned
Additional Controls EPS Sales EPS Sales

No additional controls 9.30 5.64 3.83 1.72


Analyst revisions 7.77 5.02 3.04 0.79
Analyst revisions þ Profitability þ DProfitability þ Momentum 9.24 5.55 3.38 1.03

Note: Each quarter, EPS and Sales surprises, as indicated in column headers, are regressed on a given firm’s downstream supply
chain climate exposure and additional controls prior to the earnings announcement, as indicated by row labels. The table shows
the t-statistics of the coefficient on supply chain climate exposure, obtained from the time series of cross-sectional regressions
using the Fama-MacBeth method. The t-statistics are adjusted for heteroskedasticity and auto-correlation with Newey-West pro-
cedure with four lags. Profitability is defined as return on net operating assets; Fundamental Momentum is defined as 1-year
change in Profitability; and Price Momentum is based on the total return of stocks in the past 12 months excluding the most
recent month. The data in the right panel is industry-demeaned. The sample period is June 2009 to December 2021. Universe is
large-cap developed markets stocks, similar to MSCI World constituents.
Indicates significance on a 5% basis and  Indicates significance on a 1% basis.
Source: AQR.

climate risks. Arguably, markets have paid increas- price momentum ahead of the earnings
ingly more attention to climate, so as long as they announcement.
care about the downstream supply chain exposure,
the prices of issuers with high exposure may have Table 5 indicates that companies with “greener”
fallen relative to the prices of issuers with low expos- downstream exposure on average experience larger
ure, leading to the positive returns in Tables 3 and 4. EPS surprises than other companies. This effect
Pedersen, Fitzgibbons, and Pomorski (2021) show persists also when controlling for analyst revisions
how such repricing occurs in response to changes in and price and fundamental momentum, with or
the preferences of, or the information available to, without industry adjustment. We see similar results
market participants. for sales surprises, although we lose significance
when variables are industry-demeaned. While this
At the same time, there are alternative explanations: relationship with fundamentals might be explained
For example, our climate exposure measure might be by risk exposures, we believe it is more likely to
indicative of higher production efficiency and higher reflect a facet of Quality, perhaps related to the
overall quality, as suggested in a related context in resource efficiency of a company along its supply
Garvey, Mohanaraman, and Nash (2018). While trad- chain. If so, then the strong historical returns are
itional measures of quality (e.g., profitability, or even consistent with the premium we observe for other
emissions, as in Garvey, Mohanaraman, and Nash Quality-type variables, say, profitability. In this case,
2018) relate to a specific portfolio company, it is pos- we may expect such premia to persist going for-
sible that quality extends also across the supply ward as well.
chain. For example, firms that have customers of
higher quality, including in the dimension of carbon
emissions, may be well positioned going forward Conclusions
because their customers are less likely to experience We propose a novel method to measure a firm’s cli-
adverse risk events. To test such alternative explana- mate risk exposure in the supply chain, leveraging
tions of abnormal performance, we turn to Table 5, the firm’s economic linkages. We make a simple but,
where we assess whether downstream supply chain to our knowledge, not-yet-proposed point that such
climate exposure can help predict companies’ quar- risks can be modeled as revenue-weighted climate
terly EPS and sales surprises. To do so, we run exposures of a company’s customers or a cost-
Fama-MacBeth regressions of surprises at quarterly weighted climate exposure of its suppliers. Our
earnings announcements on a given company’s framework can be utilized with one’s preferred meas-
downstream supply chain exposure and a range of ure of exposure, potentially capturing physical cli-
controls, meant to capture analyst revisions, profit- mate risks, transition opportunities, green revenues,
ability characteristics, fundamental momentum, and and so on. In our empirical validations, we find that

74
Supply Chain Climate Exposure

downstream supply chain climate exposure captures some investors. Moreover, while we focus on public
co-movement of stock returns around climate news equities in this article, investors can leverage our idea
events, largely subsuming relevant information from also in other asset classes. This is most obvious in
other traditional climate data, and that its perform- credit, but also holds in sovereign fixed income,
ance is consistent with the market (re)pricing climate where one could consider trade-weighted exposure
risk exposures. to countries that produce more emissions or are
otherwise exposed to climate risks.
Our measure is similar to, but not a replacement for,
the often-discussed scope 3 emissions. It captures The flexibility of our intuitive methodology, good
somewhat different information that we argue may data coverage, and the additional validations we pre-
be more material for issuers’ financial risks. It also sent here bode well for the usefulness of this
has a meaningful advantage of being easier to assess, approach to measure and report risks of individual
using data that is already broadly familiar to the assets and broad portfolios. We believe our approach
investment community. While our measure is not will also interest corporate decision-makers, both for
available “off the shelf” from third-party vendors, the their own risk analyses and also as an intuitive and
straightforward methodology we explain in detail in relatively easy-to-compute reporting item.
this article can be implemented in-house by at least

Editor's Note
Submitted 4 June 2022
Accepted 26 September 2022 by William N. Goetzmann

Notes
1. For example, Busch et al. (2022) find that scope 3 7. While scope 2 emissions show a negative sign in
estimates are very rarely reported by portfolio companies regression (1), this is likely driven by the correlations
and third-party estimates are essentially uncorrelated between scope 1, 2, and 3 emissions. When we regress
across data providers; Callan (2020) found no our measure on scope 2 alone, with or without sector
respondents who use scope 3 data in investment practice. and region controls, we find reliably positive
coefficients.
2. To identify a company suitable for an illustrative example,
we sorted firms on their downstream supply chain 8. We also confirmed a similar finding using MSCI Low
exposure and on their own emissions, focusing on those Carbon Transition scores (results available by request).
that are at the top of the distribution of the former and We do not report this regression given a shorter time
at the bottom of the latter. We then analyzed the public series for that variable (6 quarters of data, as opposed
statements the companies made to identify the ones that to 36 or 51 quarters for other climate variables
disclosed the importance of customers who may have we use).
large climate exposure (e.g., oil majors).
9. (3) and (4) have somewhat different samples because of
3. See, e.g., Ben-David et al. (2021) and Dai et al. (2022). data coverage, but when (3) is estimated using the same
Offshoring may also be an issue for sovereign emissions. sample as (4), the coefficient on MSCI Climate Change
theme is clearly negative, 0.05 (t-statistic ¼ 10.3).
4. These biases could perhaps be alleviated by leveraging Without the region/sector dummies but with all other
data on revenues from geographic segments and climate variables from (4), the coefficient is still positive,
assessing the climate exposure in each region in which a 0.03 (t-statistic ¼ 11.61).
company does business. We believe this approach is
coarser than what we propose; in addition, it would 10. We have repeated all analyses below also with a different
require data on climate exposures of specific regions or source of sentiment data: the Crimson Hexagon series,
countries, which itself may pose challenges. used in Engle et al. (2020). The results are very similar to
what we presented here. We chose to highlight the Ardia
5. For example, a sampling of papers utilizing such data et al. data in our paper because the data is publicly
include Cohen and Frazzini (2008), Menzly and Ozbas available and because it has a somewhat longer time
(2010), Agarwal et al. (2017), or Lee et al. (2019). series (the Crimson Hexagon data at our disposal ended
in mid-2017).
6. The jump in early 2010 is driven by adding an additional
provider of customer-supplier data; from 2010 onward, 11. LCT data has a relatively short sample, so we assume a
we have supply chain linkages data from all company’s historical LCT scores are the same as when
underlying providers. MSCI first reports them.

Volume 79, Number 1 75


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

References
Agarwal, Ashish, Alvin Chung Man Leung, Prabhudev Konana, Cohen, Lauren, and Andrea Frazzini. 2008. “Economic Links and
and Alok Kumar. 2017. “Co-Search Attention and Stock Return Predictable Returns.” The Journal of Finance 63 (4): 1977–2011.
Predictability in Supply-Chains.” Information Systems Research doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.2008.01379.x.
28 (2): 265–88. doi:10.1287/isre.2016.0656. Dai, Rui, Rui Duan, Hao Liang, and Lilian Ng. 2022.
Anderson, Mats, Bolton Patrick, and Frederic Samama. 2016. “Outsourcing Climate Change.” working paper, ECGI.
“Hedging Climate Risk.” Financial Analysts Journal 72 (3): 13–32. Ducoulombier, Frederic. 2021. “Understanding the Importance
doi:10.2469/faj.v72.n3.4. of Scope 3 Emissions and the Implications of Data Limitations.”
The Journal of Impact and ESG Investing 2021: jesg.2021.1.018.
AQR. 2021. “Can Machine Learning Help Manage Climate
doi:10.3905/jesg.2021.1.018.
Risks?” AQR Alternative Thinking Q4: 2021.
Engle, Robert, Stefano Giglio, Bryan Kelly, Heebum Lee, and
Ardia, David, Keven Bluteau, Kris Boudt, and Koen
Johannes Stroebel. 2020. “Hedging Climate Change News.” The
Inghelbrecht. 2021. Climate Change Concerns and the Review of Financial Studies 33 (3): 1184–216. doi:10.1093/rfs/
Performance of Green versus Brown Stocks, working paper, hhz072.
National Bank of Belgium.
Garvey, Gerald, Mohanaraman Iyer, and Joanna Nash. 2018.
Ben-David, Itzhak, Yeejin Jang, Stefanie Kleimeier, and Michael “Carbon Footprint and Productivity: Does the 'E' in ESG
Viehs. 2021. “Exporting Pollution: Where Do Multinational Firms Capture Efficiency as Well as Environment?” Journal of
Emit CO2?” Economic Policy 36 (107): 377–437. doi:10.1093/ Investment Management 16 (1): 59–69.
epolic/eiab009.
IBM. 2020. “2020 IBM and the Environment Report.” https://
Bixby, Steffen, Alfie Brixton, and Lukasz Pomorski. 2022. www.ibm.com/ibm/environment/annual/IBMEnvReport_2020.
“Looking Forward with Historical Carbon Data.” In Climate pdf
Investing: New Strategies and Implementation Challenges, edited Kolay, Madhuparna, Michael Lemmon, and Elizabeth Tashjian.
by E. Jurczenko. London: Wiley and ISTE. 2016. “Spreading the Misery? Sources of Bankruptcy Spillover
Bolton, Patrick, Marcin Kacperczyk, and Frederic Samama. in the Supply Chain.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative
2022. “Net-Zero Carbon Portfolio Alignment.” Financial Analysts Analysis 51 (6): 1955–90. doi:10.1017/S0022109016000855.
Journal 78 (2): 19–33. doi:10.1080/0015198X.2022.2033105. Lee, Charles, Stephen Sun, Rongfei Wang, and Ran Zhang. 2019.
“Technological Links and Predictable Returns.” Journal of Financial
Busch, Timo, Matthew Johnson, and Thomas Pioch. 2022.
Economics 132 (3): 76–96. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2018.11.008.
“Corporate Carbon Performance Data: Quo Vadis?” Journal of
Industrial Ecology 26 (1): 350–63. doi:10.1111/jiec.13008. Menzly, Lior, and Oguzhan Ozbas. 2010. “Market Segmentation
and Cross-Predictability of Returns.” The Journal of Finance 65
Callan. 2020. Callan 2020 ESG Survey. (4): 1555–80. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01578.x.
CFA Institute. 2020. “Climate Change Analysis in the Investment Pastor, Lubos, Robert Stambaugh, and Lucian Taylor. 2021.
Process.” “Dissecting Green Returns.” Working Paper, University of
Cheema-Fox, Alexander, Bridget Realmuto LaPerla, George Chicago.
Serafeim, David Turkington, and Hui (Stacie) Wang. 2021. Pedersen, Lasse, Shaun Fitzgibbons, and Lukasz Pomorski.
“Decarbonizing Everything.” Financial Analysts Journal 77 (3): 2021. “The ESG-Efficient Frontier.” Journal of Financial
93–108. doi:10.1080/0015198X.2021.1909943. Economics 142 (2): 572–97. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2020.11.001.

76
Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute Research
https://doi.org/10.1080/0015198X.2022.2126590

Trade Informativeness in
Modern Markets
Samarpan Nawn, CFA , and Gaurav Raizada
Samarpan Nawn, CFA, is an assistant professor in the Department of Finance and Accounting at the Indian Institute of Management
Udaipur, Udaipur, Rajasthan, India. Gaurav Raizada is a founder at Irage Capital and visiting faculty at the Indian Institute of Management
Ahmedabad, Ahmedabad, Gujarat, India. Send correspondence to Samarpan Nawn at samarpan.nawn@iimu.ac.in.

Using transactions-based calendar hich group of traders are informed among institutional, pro-
time (TBCT) portfolio analysis, we
investigate informativeness of trades
of investor categories, namely insti-
tutions, proprietary traders, and
W prietary, and retail client (i.e., non-institutional and non-pro-
prietary)? While such a question has widely interested
academicians and practitioners alike, the literature primarily has
chosen to concentrate on one of the groups—institutions
retail clients. We find that trade (Hendershott, Livdan, and Schu € rhoff 2015) or retail (Odean 1999;
informativeness is positive for insti- Barrot, Kaniel, and Sraer 2016; Boehmer, Fong, and Wu 2021)—or at
tutional and negative for retail-client most make a comparison between institutions and retail (Stoffman
investors. The informativeness of 2014). Additionally, as Boehmer, Fong, and Wu (2021) mention, most
liquidity-demanding trades are less of the existing studies are conducted on datasets that comprise only a
than the informativeness of liquid- small part of the overall market. For example, Odean (1999) use data
ity-supplying trades for all trading from a single U.S. retail brokerage firm and Barrot et al. (2016) use
groups, over both long and short data from a single French brokerage firm. Only Barber et al. (2009)
horizons. We also find that institu- provide an analysis that uses data from the entire equity market of
tions are benefitted by algorithmic Taiwan; however, their analysis uses data (pre-2000) from a period
executions compared to manual that did not see algorithmic trading (AT), and hence their results may
executions and this benefit is ele- not be representative of the current trading landscape across the
vated on days of high volume and world. While Boehmer, Fong, and Wu’s (2021) data is from a recent
volatility. Proprietary algorithmic period and represents a sizeable fraction of the U.S. market, their ana-
traders (high-frequency traders) gen- lysis focuses on only retail traders and uses a proxy to measure retail
erate positive alpha for their trades marketable order flow (ignoring their limit orders). Finally, proprietary
only from their liquidity-supply- traders seem to be almost entirely missing from informativeness ana-
ing trades.
lysis even though they contribute significantly to the overall volume.
Keywords: algorithmic trading; HFT; In contrast to the extant literature, using a clean, rich, exact, and
informativeness; institutional exhaustive (exchange-provided) trading group identification, we pro-
traders; limit orders; market orders vide a comprehensive informativeness analysis of all trading groups
using a 3-year (2013–2015) complete order and trade-level data from
the National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India. NSE is the tenth largest
stock exchange in the world in terms of market capitalization1 (ranked
just below the London Stock Exchange and the TMX Exchange of
Canada). The additional advantage of using NSE data is that the stock
markets in India can be considered unfragmented as NSE accounts for
Disclosure: No potential conflict of interest
was reported by the author(s). more than 80% of the total trading volume, with the Bombay Stock
Exchange (BSE) accounting for the remaining. Thus, a comprehensive
informativeness analysis done on the NSE data is almost as good as
PL Credits: 2.0 one performed on the entire Indian stock market.

Volume 79, Number 1 © 2022 CFA Institute. All rights reserved. 77


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Apart from providing a clean identification of each Lehnert 2000) and, thus, the proportion of “noise”
order and trade—on whether it is from the institu- traders in the retail trading group is lower, contribu-
tional, proprietary, or retail-client traders—the data ting to the divergence in findings.
also provides a flag to enable us to identify whether
it is coming from an algorithmic terminal. While we We work with all stocks listed in the NSE of India.
start the analysis with the institutional, proprietary, However, to ascertain that our results of institutional
and retail-client trading group partition, we later use informativeness are not driven by any particular
the algorithmic flag and provide insights into the dif- group of stocks, we segregate the stocks into three
ference between algorithmic and non-algorithmic groups by size—(1) the top or 50 largest stocks
traders within institutions and proprietary groups. (accounting for approximately 60% of total market
One particularly interesting subgroup is proprietary capitalization), (2) the following 450 stocks (account-
traders using algorithmic services, often called high- ing for 35%), and (3) the remaining stocks (accounting
frequency traders (HFTs; SEC 2010). A stark reality is for 5%)—and find that institutions (retail) have posi-
that the architecture of modern markets has changed tive (negative) and significant alpha for all three
after the emergence of AT technology. AT is growing groups of stocks.
throughout globally (Boehmer, Fong, and Wu 2021)
In spirit with much of the literature (Fong, Gallagher,
and, currently, most of the trading in major stock
and Lee 2014), we equate the alpha from the four-
markets is happening through AT. In India, AT was
factor model with informativeness. However, the
allowed in 2008, but it only started becoming popu-
alpha could also stem from other factors such as
lar after the advent of direct market access (allowing
investor ability to process public information and
traders to rent rack space in the premises of the
behavioral biases. Specifically, Seasholes and Zhu
exchange itself) in 2010. Nawn and Banerjee (2019)
(2010) link the informativeness of trades to investors’
found in the NSE-listed top 50 stocks (accounting for
ability to exploit non-public information. Thus, for
60% of the exchange’s market capitalization), 43% of
the robustness of our main results, we repeat our
total trading volume and 85% of total order mes-
analysis on a group of stocks with zero analyst cover-
sages in 2013 emanated from AT. Thus, similar to
most active exchanges of the world, NSE sees a age. Very low–analyst coverage stocks are taken as a
heavy presence of AT. proxy for stocks with high information asymmetry
(Hong, Lim, and Stein 2000; Chae 2005; Kovacs
Using the transactions-based calendar time (TBCT) 2010). The alpha achieved in these stocks can be
method (Seasholes and Zhu 2010; Fong, Gallagher, mostly attributed to informativeness. We do find that
and Lee 2014), our primary finding is that institutions our main results of institutions having significantly
have a significantly positive alpha over all holding positive alphas and retail clients having significantly
periods, while the retail-client group has a signifi- negative alphas in both long and short horizons con-
cantly negative alpha. For example, the risk-adjusted tinue for the stocks with zero analyst coverage. Our
alpha for institutions is 7 basis points (bp) for a 1-day results from this section provide robustness to our
holding period. The proprietary group primarily has main analysis.
an insignificant alpha throughout. Our results on
retail traders link more closely with the traditional lit- Traditional research assumed that informed traders
erature suggesting they are naive (Odean 1999; were more likely to use market orders (O’Hara 1995;
Barber et al. 2009) than with the recent literature Easley et al. 1996), due to their execution certainty.
suggesting otherwise (Kaniel, Saar, and Titman 2008, Limit orders have been known to face adverse selec-
Kelley, and Tetlock 2013; Welch 2022) not only tion and free option risk (Copeland and Galai 1983).
because our data for the group is a more comprehen- An overall informativeness analysis may not reveal
sive representation but also perhaps for the compos- the true story where the relative usage of market
ition of the trading group. The retail-client trading and limit orders differ among the trading groups. This
volume is quite significant in India (close to 50%), is especially relevant because retail traders are
with many individuals directly trading in the market. known to supply immediacy to institutional traders
This is similar to the Taiwanese market structure, (Kaniel, Saar, and Titman 2008). In the spirit of Fong,
where more than 80% of the trading volume gener- Gallagher, and Lee (2014), we next examine the
ates from retail order flow. In the United States, this informativeness among our three groups of traders
percentage is significantly lower. It is possible that separately on the trades they initiate (trading through
many are exposed in the equities markets there market orders) and on the trades they supply liquid-
through pension funds and mutual funds (Engen and ity to (trading through limit orders).

78
Trade Informativeness in Modern Markets

Our rich and detailed data allows us to correctly result is in line with previous research (Domowitz
identify the liquidity-demanding and liquidity-supply- and Yegerman 2005), which suggests that orders
ing leg for each trade. Therefore, we do not need to executed through algorithms have lower implementa-
rely on any trade classification algorithms. Our results tion shortfall costs than manual orders, providing evi-
in this section are reassuring and enticing in parallel. dence of how execution algorithms provide value to
For trades conducted using market orders, the insti- their clients. We further restrict our analysis to (1)
tutions have positive and significant alphas at both only high-volume stock days and (2) only high-volatil-
long and short horizons, while proprietary and retail- ity stock days. We find that the difference in execu-
client traders have negative and significant alphas tion alphas between institutional algorithmic and
and the retail-client group has a more negative alpha. manual trades is positive and significant and is of
For trades conducted using limit orders, both institu- greater magnitude (8 bp) compared to the full-sample
tions and proprietary traders have positive alphas, (2 bp) results. Thus, our results suggest that algorith-
with institutions having greater alphas compared to mic executions become more valuable on high-vola-
proprietary traders. The retail-client group has insig- tility and high-volume days.
nificant alphas over both long and short horizons
when using limit orders. The reassuring part of the We attempt to identify channels through which algo-
result is that the rank ordering of alphas among the rithmic executions are able to provide value to insti-
three trading groups remains valid whether we exam- tutions compared to manual executions. We find two
ine trades conducted through market orders or channels: The first is able to continuously monitor
trades conducted through limit orders. The enticing the market and trade at favorable junctures. For
part of the results is that for all three trading example, institutional algorithms monitor stock liquid-
groups—institutions, proprietary, and retail client—we ity and trade using relatively more limit orders when
find that the liquidity-supplying trades have greater the liquidity is scarce (and hence expensive) and
alphas compared to liquidity-demanding trades at all trade using relatively more market orders when the
horizons (short and long). liquidity is plentiful (and hence cheap). The second
channel is that algorithms are less affected by behav-
While the alphas estimated from limit order trades ioral biases. The one example we find is that com-
are high, the entire alpha could represent the com- pared to manual executions, algorithmic executions
pensation for liquidity provision. The compensation have much less tendency to trade at round numbers,
for supplying immediacy is earning the bid-ask spread a well-known behavioral bias that generates losses
(Handa, Schwartz, and Tiwari 1998). We use the Roll (Bhattacharya, Holden, and Jacobsen 2012).
(1984) model, which utilizes the short-term return
reversal in trade prices, to estimate bid-ask spread Last, we concentrate on the profitability of the HFT
for each stock day. From these estimates, we find trading group (proprietary algorithmic traders). We
that while half-spread can explain a part of the alpha simply ask whether HFT trades are informative (on
of the liquidity-supplying trades, there is still a signifi- both the short and long horizon) and how informative
cant part of the alpha that remains unexplained and are their liquidity-demanding in relation to liquidity-
thus can be attributed to informed traders’ relative supplying trades. The TBCT results on HFT provide
use of more limit orders than market orders in mod- important insights. First, we see that HFT trades are
ern algorithmic markets. informative, from the very short horizon (day of the
trade) to a longer horizon of up to 20 days. Second,
In the final section of the paper, we use the algorith- HFTs’ liquidity-demanding (-supplying) trades have a
mic flags provided by the exchange. We first ask negative (positive) and significant alpha in both long
whether the algorithmic executions provide value to and short horizons. Our results indicate that HFTs
the institutions. We separate the institutional trades make consistent profits from their liquidity provision
as manual or algorithmic. The institutional trades, or market-making strategies. Part of this alpha from
which are algorithmic, are in essence executed the liquidity-supplying trades of HFT can be
through broker execution algorithms. We do a differ- explained by the estimated half-spread, which is the
ence in TBCT alphas2 of algorithmic and manual exe- compensation for providing liquidity; however, the
cutions for the day of the trading and find that this remaining alpha should be attributed to informed
difference is positive and significant. Thus, broker HFTs’ use of limit orders (Brogaard, Hendershott, and
execution algorithms are able to create a value to Riordan 2019).
their customers (the institutions), especially managing
their trades well and the institutional gain by hiring HFTs are expected to rely on speed primarily, and
these execution algorithms. The implication of the thus the TBCT analysis of the holding period from

Volume 79, Number 1 79


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

the end of the trading day to 6 months may not be groups of traders remained more or less stable
appropriate for them. We provide additional analysis between these two time periods in the NSE.
for this group of traders—an intraday TBCT where
the holding period ranges from the end of the trading
minute to 60 minutes. Here we see that HFT trades Institutional Features of the NSE,
are significantly informative across the intra- Data, and Descriptive Details
day horizon. The NSE was established in 1992 and has played an
There are several implications of our study. If a port- instrumental role in the evolution of Indian capital
folio mimicking the holdings of institutions is man- markets in its present state. It is a completely elec-
aged, then it can provide an economically significant tronic order-driven exchange without designated
alpha to the manager who can replicate the portfolio. market makers. Trading takes place by an order-
For example, institutions generate an alpha of 3.2 bp matching mechanism: matching the marketable sell
for a 5-day holding period after accounting for Fama- (buy) orders with the best available limit buy (sell)
orders. The orders are entered and matched at strict
French-Carhart factors. The positive and negative
price, visibility, and time priority. After a 15-minute
informativeness of trades by institutional and retail-
pre-opening session (call auction), the exchange gets
client trader category has practical implications for
ready for continuous trading at 9:15 AM. The single
brokerages and market makers. These intermediaries
continuous session runs from 9:15 AM to 3:30 PM
in a way can differentiate between the informed and
with a T þ 2 rolling settlement cycle. The exchange
uninformed order flow and act accordingly.
freely displays live, on its website, the five top bid
Our finding of the lack of informativeness of the and ask quotes and the number of shares demanded
retail-client group requires further mention. As AT or offered at those quotes for all traded securities.
has been competing against individual investors in
The NSE’s completely order-driven market structure
liquidity supplying role in recent years, the return
mimics some of the world’s most important non-U.S.
predictability by individual trading may have weak-
stock exchanges, such as the Tokyo Stock Exchange,
ened (Tian et al. 2015). Given that retail investors
HKEX, and Euronext Paris. The NSE is one of the
have less of an information advantage in the market
most active stock exchanges in the world. It has con-
and their aggressive orders further reduce trading
sistently ranked in the top five exchanges of the
profits, an insight for retail traders is to be patient world in terms of the number of trades for the last
when trading by using limit orders as much as pos- several years (according to the World Federation of
sible. The institutions would do better if they hire Exchanges statistics). According to the latest report,
execution algorithms to trade on their behalf. In case the NSE ranks fourth according to this parameter.4
of algorithmic versus manual execution, algorithmic Even in terms of market capitalization, the NSE has
execution provides an advantage of 2 bp on the exe- been steadily growing over the last several years and
cution day and 8.6 bp on high-turnover days. currently ranks tenth globally, with a market capital-
We acknowledge that the data period used in the ization of $2.55 trillion. The only exchanges ahead of
paper (2013–2015) is slightly dated. However, post the NSE are the NYSE ($26.23 trillion), NASDAQ
($19.06 trillion), Shanghai Stock Exchange ($6.97 tril-
2016, Indian markets saw a stupendous and continu-
lion), Japan Exchange Group ($6.71 trillion), HKEX
ous bull run right up to February 2020. In compari-
($6.13 trillion), Euronext ($5.44 trillion), Shenzhen
son, 2013 to 2015 saw a more normal scenario, with
Stock Exchange ($5.23 trillion), LSE ($4.04 trillion),
the market going up in the first 2 years and falling in
and Toronto Stock Exchange ($2.6 trillion). Many of
the third year. Thus, we believe an informativeness
the well-known stock exchanges of the world, such
analysis done in the 2013 to 2015 period is more
as the ASX and the Deutsche Boerse, rank behind
generalizable compared to an analysis done in a
the NSE in market capitalization. Finally, in terms of
period of only bull run or one that includes special
dollar traded volume, the NSE ranks twelfth globally,
events such as the COVID-19 crisis. Additionally, by
with $1.8 trillion worth of shares traded, just behind
2013, the AT activity had already stabilized in the
the LSE ($2.1 trillion) and Deutsche Boerse
NSE.3 Thereafter, there has not been a significant
($2 trillion).
structural shift in the trading landscape in Indian mar-
kets. An unreported analysis by Banerjee and Roy Similar to other important exchanges of the world,
(2022) compares 2015 to 2019 and finds that the the NSE sees a heavy presence in algorithmic trading.
that the trading volume distribution among different Algorithmic trading was introduced in the NSE in

80
Trade Informativeness in Modern Markets

Figure 1. Share of Algorithmic Trading and Importance of the NSE

100.00%

90.00%

80.00%

70.00%

60.00%

50.00%

40.00%

30.00%

20.00%

10.00%

0.00%
2010-11 2011-12 2012-13 2013-14 2014-15 2015-16 2016-17 2017-18 2018-19 2019-20 2020-21

Share of algo trading in NSE Share of NSE in overall Indian stock markets

The figure illustrates the proportion of traded value in cash equities generated through algorithmic trading in the National Stock
Exchange (NSE) of India from 2010–11 to 2020–21. It also provides the share of the NSE in the Indian stock markets’ trad-
ing volume.

2008, but the system became popular after coloca- to indicate that they prefer the NSE over the BSE,
tion services5 were introduced in 2010. The and perhaps that has paved the way for further con-
exchange provides (against a charge) live tick-by-tick solidation of trading volume to the NSE. The NSE
market data, generating a broadcast for every order has always been a pioneer and frontrunner in intro-
message to supplement the colocation service. Nawn ducing technological innovation, and despite the BSE
and Banerjee (2019) find that algorithmic traders are being an older exchange (it started in the 19th cen-
responsible for 85% of the order messages in the tury), the NSE has been able to leapfrog the BSE.
fifty NIFTY 50 index stocks in 2013. Biais and Foucault (2014) express concern that it is
sometimes difficult to generalize trading group–spe-
The share of trading volume emanating from algorith- cific research conducted in a single exchange of a
mic terminals has been consistently on the rise in the fragmented market, as sophisticated traders may
NSE over the last decade (Figure 1), approaching have taken the opposite or hedging positions in other
50% in recent years. This has coincided with the exchanges. As discussed, our results would not face
steady increase in the proportion of overall Indian such concerns.
equities market trading volume to the NSE. An
important characteristic of the Indian equity trading The data contains the complete orders and transac-
microstructure is its near unfragmented nature. There tions history on the NSE from January 1, 2013,
are only two major stock exchanges in India (the through December 31, 2015. Each order contains
Bombay Stock Exchange [BSE] is the other). Almost fields for the market session (regular/auction), order
all the major stocks are listed in both the exchanges, number, order entry time, order side (buy/sell), order
however, the NSE is by far the dominant exchange in type (new/revision/cancel), order price, and size. The
terms of trading volume. While the NSE’s share was trades data includes the date and time of the trans-
already quite high (75%) in 2010, it has increased to action, a stock identifier, transaction price, and the
nearly 90% by 2020 (Figure 1). While correlation is number of shares traded. An algorithmic flag and a
not causation and we do not claim causality, verbal client flag earmark each order message and each
conversations with algorithmic traders in India seem trade (both legs of the trade) in the data obtained

Volume 79, Number 1 81


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 1. NSE Firms and Turnover Year-Wise from 2013 to 2015


No. of Average Daily Market
No. of Trades Turnover Turnover Average Trade Capitalization
Year Securities (Millions) (Billion INR) (Billion INR) Value (INR) (Billion INR) Turnover Ratio

2013 1711 160003 28220 112.88 19402 64248 0.44


2014 1839 215933 38763 158.86 22490 84119 0.46
2015 1777 219551 43568 175.68 23380 98458 0.44

The table provides summary statistics for trades in the National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India. The number of securities available
for trading and total number of trades are shown in the first two columns, respectively. The annual turnover and average daily
turnover for the stock segment show the growth in exchange volumes. The average trade value is the turnover divided by the
number of trades. The turnover ratio is calculated as the average yearly turnover of domestic shares divided by their average
year-end total market capitalization.

from the NSE. The two flags help identify whether categorized as being from HFTs, but if the same
an order was from an algorithmic terminal and trader uses algorithms to conduct client trades, those
whether the order was for a proprietary account, a will not be categorized as being from HFTs. This
custodian account, or a non-proprietary and non-cus- advantage overcomes a known limitation of popular
todian (others) account. HFT-identifying databases that classify HFTs at the
firm level (e.g., the Nasdaq HFT database does not
The custodian group consists of traders who are not classify proprietary algorithmic trades from broker-
allowed to conduct their own clearing and settlement dealer firms such as Goldman Sachs or Morgan
and must do that through custodians. This group Stanley as being from HFTs).
consists primarily of foreign institutional investors,
mutual funds, and financial institutions, and we refer Table 1 provides the year-wise summary statistics of
to this group as institutions for the rest of the study. the NSE from 2013 to 2015. It provides information
Proprietary traders consist of broker members about the monthly and daily turnover, number of
engaged in trading on proprietary trading capital. trades monthly, as well as average trade size. The
These may fall in the category of speculators and day average turnover velocity is around 0.45 times the
traders who trade frequently. They may also fit in market capitalization. The turnover velocity is calcu-
the category of “pseudo” market makers providing lated as the average monthly turnover of domestic
liquidity on both the buy and sell sides of the market. shares, divided by their average month-end total
The rest of the traders, who are non-institutional and market capitalization.
non-proprietary, are referred to as retail client. The Table 2 provides the investor-wise turnover across
primary constituent in this category is the traditional the period from 2013 to 2015. We find that institu-
retail traders using manual or non-algorithmic plat- tional trading amounts to 32% of the total turnover,
forms. However, there are a small group of algorith- while proprietary trading is around 22%. Retail-client
mic traders who are included in the retail-client trading accounts for the largest share (46%) of the
group. These traders are using client money and total turnover. We further subdivide the turnover
algorithms for primarily day trading (thus, they are across the six investor categories. Algorithmic execu-
non-institutional and non-proprietary by definition). tion accounts for most of the institutional, propri-
They constitute only 5% of the trading volume, etary group, but manual execution dominates the
whereas the non-algorithmic (or simply “retail”) group retail-client group.
constitutes 40% of the volume. Regardless of the
main results of the overall retail-client group, in unre- We include all stocks listed and trading in the NSE in
ported tests, we find the results for the only “retail” our empirical results. However, for a better under-
group mimic the results of the overall retail-cli- standing of the performance of each trading group in
ent category. large-, mid-, and small-cap stocks, we divide the
stocks into three groups: (1) the top 50 stocks or the
An important feature of the identification is that constituents of the benchmark index NIFTY 50, (2)
trading group classification is at a message-level the next 450 stocks or the constituents of index
granularity. For example, when a trader uses algo- NIFTY 500 that are not included in NIFTY 50, and (3)
rithms to conduct proprietary trades, those are all other stocks. The top 50, the next 450, and the

82
Trade Informativeness in Modern Markets

Table 2. Trade Descriptive Statistics by Investor Category for the Period 2013–2015
Top 50 Next 450 Rest of Stocks
Investor Turnover Mode of Turnover Turnover Turnover Turnover
Category (Billion INR) Trading (Billion INR) (Billion INR) (Billion INR) (Billion INR)

Institutions 70432 (32%) Algo 44817.43 (20%) 29172.88 (25%) 13399.08 (13%) 0.17 (1%)
Non-algo 26244.69 (12%) 26244.69 (23%) 15343.54 (15%) 0.34 (2%)
Proprietary 47174 (22%) Algo 28500.13 (13%) 14926.41 (13%) 11853.17 (12%) 0.14 (1%)
Non-algo 18673.94 (8%) 6614.53 (6%) 9861.50 (10%) 3.1 (22%)
Retail clients 101653 (46%) Algo 14340.30 (7%) 7268.07 (6%) 6299.20 (6%) 0.18 (1%)
Non-algo 87312.42 (40%) 30845.67 (27%) 42939.38 (43%) 10.19 (72%)

The table shows total turnover and turnover percentage executed by each investor category: institutions, proprietary trading, and
retail clients. Further, the turnover is broken down by the mode of trading into “algo” and “non-algo” participants. The turnover is
subdivided into the stock categories based on market capitalization of “top 50,” “next 450,” and “the rest of stocks.” Our sample
includes all stocks traded at the National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India and the time period of our sample is 1st January 2013 to
31st December 2015.

rest of the stocks account for approximately 60%, price movements. Chakrabarty et al. (2020) track hid-
35%, and 5% of the total market capitalization of the den orders of HFT using the same NSE data, and
exchange, respectively. We check for the turnover their findings are qualitatively similar to their findings
across NIFTY 50, the next 450, and the rest of the from NASDAQ data. Also, their findings on hidden
stocks for each of the investor categories. orders of the manual traders match the findings of
Institutional trading has a higher percentage turnover Bessembinder et al. (2009), who use Euronext Paris
from the NIFTY 50, while retail-client trading has data of 2003 (hence, all trading was manual then).
more turnover in the next 450 stocks. The rest of The robust findings of Nawn and Banerjee (2019)
the stocks have extremely low volumes. Most of the and Chakrabarty et al. (2020) lend credence that
volumes in the rest of the stocks are contributed by results achieved with NSE data are more likely to be
retail-client trading. generalizable than not.

In the latter part of the study, we put particular focus


on the trading group with the algorithmic flag as Related Literature and Main
affirmative and client flag as “proprietary” and call
these traders HFTs, per the SEC (2010). The litera-
Research Questions
ture indicates that the way HFTs operate would gen- The extant literature on trading group informative-
erate a very high order-to-trade ratio compared to ness provides seemingly isolated findings. The early
other traders (Hendershott, Jones, and Menkveld research on the topic suggests that institutions are
2011; Jørgensen, Skjeltorp, and Ødegaard 2018). We informed (Sias and Starks 1997; Chakravarty 2001)
next verify whether we see the same pattern in our and retail traders are naive (Odean 1998; Odean
data. We compare HFTs’ order-to-trade ratio with 1999; Barber and Odean 2000). However, recent evi-
that of other traders who use trading algorithms and dence has shown that retail traders are indeed not
traders who do not use algorithms. We see that naive. Kaniel, Saar, and Titman (2008) find that
HFTs’ order-to-trade ratios are ten times higher than stocks with intense buying by individuals outperform
other algorithmic traders and about 100 times higher stocks with intense selling by individuals in a short
than traders who operate manually.6 horizon of 20 days. Kaniel et al. (2012) study trading
before earnings announcements and document that
Using data from the same stock exchange, Nawn and aggregate individual buying (selling) predicts large
Banerjee (2019) show that the proprietary algorith- positive (negative) abnormal returns on and after the
mic traders can be taken as the HFTs. Additionally, announcements in both a very short horizon (2 days)
they find that these traders increase the supply of and a relatively long horizon (60 days). Fong,
liquidity when short-term volatility is high or when Gallagher, and Lee (2014) provide evidence that
price movement is extreme. These results corrobor- trades via full-service retail brokers are significantly
ate the finding of Brogaard et al. (2018) using informative over both the long and short horizon
NASDAQ data that HFTs increase their net supply of compared to trades via discount retail brokers. Their
liquidity during periods of extreme stock-specific analysis indicates that there may be various

Volume 79, Number 1 83


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

categories of retail investors implied by their choices market and limit orders differ among the trading
of brokerage houses, and such consideration should groups, especially with traditional academic literature
be kept in mind while generalizing informativeness of having assumed that informed traders were more
retail traders.7 Using marketable retail order flow, likely to use market orders (O’Hara 1995; Easley
Boehmer, Fong, and Wu (2021) show that individual et al. 1996) due to their execution certainty.
stocks with net buying by retail investors outperform
stocks with net selling by approximately ten basis The analysis assumes additional significance due to
points over the following week. Finally, a very recent the mixed evidence on the recent literature regarding
strand of literature focuses on trades from an ultra- the informativeness of different trading groups while
low-cost brokerage platform, “Robinhood Markets using market and limit orders. Kaniel, Saar, and
Inc” (expected to cater to less sophisticated invest- Titman (2008) emphasizes that contrarian liquidity
ors) and suggest that “Robinhood” investors do not provision by retail traders earn them positive returns.
appear to be naive (Angel 2021; van der Beck and However, Barrot et al. (2016) suggest that individuals
Jaunin 2021; Welch 2022). However, Barber et al. do not reap the rewards from liquidity provision as
(2009) use the complete trading history of traders in they reverse their trades long after the excess
Taiwan and conclude that individuals lose on average returns from liquidity provision are dissipated,
4% per annum, while institutions garner 1.5% per although their theoretical long-short portfolio delivers
annum. Hendershott et al. (2015) suggest that intu- a significant positive annualized return. Kelley and
itional order flow is informed about news announce- Tetlock (2013) find that retail market orders can cor-
ments. Taking all news from Reuters between 2003 rectly predict upcoming news. Barber et al. (2009)
and 2005, they conclude that institutions can trade find that retail traders lose on trading through market
ahead of macroeconomic news, earnings announce- orders, while institutions’ aggressive and passive
ments, and any news related to the firm’s long-term trades generate positive alpha. Thus, we ask whether
fundamental information. the institutional and proprietary market (limit) order
trades are more informative than retail market (limit)
The different conclusions to the aforementioned order trades.
studies can be partially attributed to the type of data
used. There are major differences in the samples in
terms of different exchanges and brokerage houses. Methodology
Most importantly, the majority of the studies use
data that is only a small part of the overall market
and, therefore, generalization of the results on any
Transaction-Based Calendar Time
group of traders may not be feasible.
Methodology. Most studies use daily buy-sell
imbalances for investor categories to test for return
Because institutions are known to have superior predictability. However, Fama (1998) recommends
information-gathering and -processing skills, have the usage of calendar time portfolios in analysis of
economies of scale to monitor many sources of infor- the stock price performance, primarily for the rea-
mation, employ professionals with superior skills and sons of avoiding the bad model problem and also
unlike retail traders, and communicate directly with due to the advantage that cross-correlations of
firms (Hendershott et al. 2015), our prior expectation event-firm abnormal returns are automatically
is that institutional trades would be more informative accounted for in the portfolio variance. The distribu-
than retail trades if a comprehensive analysis is done tion of this estimator is better approximated by nor-
with all traders in the population. Similarly, because mal distribution, allowing classical
proprietary traders are likely to be skilled, profession- statistical inference.
ally hired personnel, the expectation is that their
We utilize the TBCT methodology proposed by
trades would be more informative than that of retail
Seasholes and Zhu (2010) to calculate the returns at
traders. Thus, in our first research question, we ask
whether institutional and proprietary trades are more various time horizons for each trader category. TBCT
informative than retail trades. methodology allows aggregation of the buy and sell
trades across trading participants and stocks into a
While the first research question focusses on overall single return series per trader category. This single
trades by each group, a trade can happen either time series of returns also eliminates the problem of
through a limit order or through a market order. An cross-sectional dependence. In addition, it allows
informativeness analysis perhaps will not describe value-weighting of trades and thus eliminates any
the complete picture where the relative usage of volume or stock bias. The transactions-based

84
Trade Informativeness in Modern Markets

approach allows measurement of abnormal returns (Linnainmaa and Saar 2012; Seasholes and Zhu
under different holding periods (1 day, 1 week, 1 2010). For all investor categories, we compute the
month, etc.) and investigation of whether there is TBCT portfolio using a variety of horizons from the
any time-sensitive information in stock trades. end of the trading day to 125 trading days (6 months)
such that we can capture information of different
There can be several issues with aggregating cat-
longevity associated with trades of all the investor
egory data, and they are addressed below.
categories. In order to compute abnormal returns,
TBCT returns are regressed against the Fama-
 Individualistic fallacy: An attempt to impute French-Carhart four-factor model to assess the
aggregate relationships from individual trader/ trader category alpha.
firm relationships. There could be a significant
loss by a trading entity which is offset by another Measuring Abnormal Returns. We measure
entity in the same trading category. At an aggre- the abnormal returns using the Fama-French-Carhart
gate level, this shall not be factored into four-factor model. We estimate the following time
the model. series models using daily data:
 Small-stock bias: As noted in Seasholes and Zhu
(2010), small stock performance can bias the rp, t ¼ a þ bp ðrm, t  rf, t Þ þ bSMB SMBt
returns significantly; hence, value-weighting the þ bHML HMLt þ bUMD UMDt þ et (1)
transactions portfolios addresses the small-stock
bias. We segment stocks into large, medium, and where r(p,t) is the TBCT return on the buys minus
small to account for this issue. sells portfolio of an investor category and r(m,t) is
 Heterogeneity in investor categories: Barber and returns on market portfolio, estimated as the value-
Odean (2000) report that the quintile of the most weighted portfolio of all the stocks involved in the
active traders underperforms the quintile of the estimation of SMB, HML, and WML portfolios.8 r(f,t)
least active traders by about 6% per year after is computed using the 91-day T-bill rate. The four-
trading costs are taken into account. Active trad- factor data series has been taken from Agarwalla,
ers trade much higher volumes than less active Jacob, and Varma (2014). Our primary interest is in
traders. The holding periods and profitability are the estimation of alphas (intercept) on the buy minus
also highly varying. However, from the perspec- sell portfolios of investor categories.
tive of the investor category and trading technol-
ogy, these are homogenous.
Empirical Results: TBCT across
Three Investor Categories
The TBCT portfolio methodology requires aggregat-
ing the number of shares in each buy trade to a cal-
endar time “buy” portfolio and in each sell trade to a Overall Informativeness across the
calendar time “sell” portfolio. These shares are held Institutions, Proprietary, and Retail
in the portfolio for a fixed amount of time and are Client. The TBCT returns of the three mutually
then removed from the portfolio’s holdings. The port- exclusive and exhaustive groups of traders—institu-
folio’s value and composition change over time as tions, proprietary, and retail client—are first com-
shares are added and removed from the holdings. puted by subtracting the “sell” portfolio returns from
Seasholes and Zhu (2010) compute daily value- the “buy” portfolio returns for different investment
weighted returns for portfolios by marking the hold- horizons: end of the day of the trade, 1 day, 5 days,
ings and new trades to daily close prices. We follow 10 days, 20 days, 60 days, and 125 days (trading
Fong, Gallagher, and Lee (2014) by using the actual days), using the method described in the previous
transaction price of a trade instead of the end-of- section. Thereafter, we estimate Equation (1) for
the-day price in adding a trade to the portfolio. The each of the groups and report the risk-adjusted alpha
informed nature of aggregated trades of an investor for the different investor groups for each horizon.
category over a calendar time horizon is measured by Table 3 provides the details.
the mean daily difference between returns on the
buy portfolio and returns on the sell portfolio. First, we find that trades by institutions generate an
alpha that is high at the trade-day horizon. The aver-
In prior studies, TBCT has been used for assessing age value of the alpha at the close of the first day is
both short- and long-lived information. TBCT has 9.0 bp. This implies that if the trades are offset at the
been used from a horizon of 5 minutes to 1 year end of the trade day, the portfolio of the buy trades

Volume 79, Number 1 85


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

and sell trades generates a net return of 9.0 bp after

–0.053 (–22.624) –0.037 (–4.666) –0.017 (–3.176) –0.011 (–3.059) –0.008 (–3.105) –0.005 (–2.725) –0.004 (–2.267)
0.004 (2.091)

intercept in the regression of the buys-minus-sells portfolio return on the Fama-French-Carhart factors (i.e., market, size, value factors, and momentum over stock returns over the
Exchange (NSE) of India for the period 2013–2015. It reports the daily alpha in percentage from horizon of the end of trade day (EOD) to 125 days. The alpha is computed as the
–0.001 (–2.009) –0.000 (–0.853)
risk adjustment. It is equivalent to an annual alpha of
125 Days

25.2%, which is economically significant. Similarly,

This table presents the transactions-based calendar time (TBCT) buys-minus-sells portfolio alphas for institutions, proprietary traders, and retail clients in the National Stock
retail-client trades generate an alpha of 5.3 bp,
which is equivalent to 12.4% annualized returns.
The alpha of the proprietary traders is economically
insignificant. However, as Fong, Gallagher, and Lee
0.008 (3.172)

(2014) note, the large positive (negative) alpha of the


institutions (or of the retail client) is hypothetical in
60 Days

the sense that we do not observe the actual horizon


of each trade, and it is quite unlikely one category of
traders liquidates all trades at the end of the day of
day. Barrot et al. (2016) report that individual invest-
ors do not reap the rewards from liquidity provision
0.015 (3.799)

because they experience a negative return on the


–0.001 (–1.557)

day of their trade. Thus, it is also important to note


20 Days
Table 3. TBCT Alphas for Institutions, Proprietary Traders, and Retail Clients for All Trades

the alpha at longer horizons.

Alphas computed at longer holding periods show


slightly lower trading informativeness. The positive
alphas of the institutional trades continue to remain
0.022 (3.739)

significant at 1-day, 5-day, 10-day, 20-day, and 60-


0.000 (0.047)

day horizons. If the portfolios of institutions are liqui-


10 Days

dated at the end of the 60-day period, then a daily


alpha of 0.7 bp or annualized returns of 2.02% can
be expected after risk adjustment. In contrast, we
past 12 months).  and  denote statistical significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.

see negative and significant alphas for trades by retail


clients until the 60-day horizon. At the 60-day hori-
0.032 (3.783)

zon, a daily alpha of 0.5 bp or annualized returns of


0.001 (0.869)

1% are seen. The alphas generated by trades of


5 Days

proprietary investors are not significant for any hori-


zon except for 60 days, where it is 1 bp.

Overall, the results in Table 3 additionally support


two points. First, the trade of proprietary traders,
0.070 (5.150)

despite constituting a quarter of the exchange turn-


0.002 (0.909)

over, does not indicate trading informativeness.


1 Day

Perhaps, it reinforces that proprietary traders are


largely performing the uninformed market makers’
role in modern markets. Second, there is a remark-
able similarity between the magnitude of the alphas
of the institutions and retail-client group across all
0.090 (23.976)

horizons. Retail-client traders alphas reflect their


information disadvantage when they are trading
0.001 (0.626)
EOD

against institutional investors.

We consider the four-factor alpha as a measure of


informativeness. However, the alpha could also stem
from other factors such as investor ability to process
Category/Horizon

public information. Seasholes and Zhu (2010) link


informativeness to investors’ ability to exploit non-
Retail clients
Proprietary
Institutions

public information. Thus, we reran our analysis on a


sample of stocks with greater information asymmetry
for robustness purposes. Alphas generated in stocks
with high information asymmetry can be attributed

86
Trade Informativeness in Modern Markets

to investor ability to exploit non-public information alpha of liquidity-demanding trades extends till the
with greater certainty. We consider stocks that are 60-day horizon. The alphas from both the legs of
covered by no analyst across all three of our sample proprietary traders balance out to a near-zero overall,
years9 as a sample of high–information asymmetry which we observe in Table 3.
stocks. Low analyst coverage has been well used as a
proxy for high information asymmetry in the litera- For the retail-client group, we found negative and
ture (Hong, Lim, and Stein 2000; Chae 2005; Kovacs significant alphas for all horizons in Table 3. Here we
2010). The unreported results10 validate our main see that all the lack of informativeness of this group
results: Institutions (retail clients) have positive (nega- stems from the liquidity-demanding trades. The
tive) and significant alphas. alphas are negative and significant from the end of
the day of trading to the 60-day horizon. In parallel,
Informativeness for Liquidity-Demanding the liquidity-supplying trades of the group have zero
and -Supplying Trades. Trading through market informativeness. This particular result almost mirrors
and limit orders has different implications in trad- the findings of Barber et al. (2009) on the inform-
itional microstructure research. While the informed ativeness of individual traders’ trades conducted
are expected to use more market orders (Easley et al. using aggressive and non-aggressive orders.
1996), limit order traders face adverse selection and
Reassuringly, regardless of whether we look at trades
free option risk. An overall informativeness analysis
may not state the full story, as there could be differ- conducted through limit orders or at trades con-
ences in the relative proportion of the market and ducted through market orders, we find that institu-
limit order usage by different groups. In this section, tions are most informed, followed by the proprietary
following Fong, Gallagher, and Lee (2014), we segre- group. The informativeness of the retail-client group
gate the trades as market order trades and limit is the lowest under both setups. Thus, the main
order trades and focus on the informativeness of result of Table 3 is not an artifact of the trading
three trading groups on both. To do the same, we through market or limit orders.
follow the same method of “buy” portfolio minus Interestingly, we find that aggressive trades have
“sell” portfolio returns for different horizons but lower informativeness than passive trades across all
restrict ourselves first to only liquidity-demanding horizons for all three trading groups. While surprising
trades of each group and then to only liquidity-sup- at first glance, the results align with very recent lit-
plying trades. The results are provided in Table 4 erature. Several papers have found that market order
(Panels A and B).
imbalance no longer is related to information trading
The liquidity-demanding trades of institutions are in both the long and short run. In examining a sample
informative, but the informativeness is weaker at the of corporate information events, Kim and Stoll (2014)
longer horizon. The 20-day alpha is not significantly find that order imbalances do not reveal private
different from zero. The highest alpha occurs at a information about posterior events. Collin-Dufresne
horizon of 1 day. In contrast, their liquidity-supplying and Fos (2015) find that activist traders (who move
trades show greater informativeness. All the alphas prices) make very limited use of market orders and
are significant at the 1% level from the end-of-day use them only at times of high available liquidity.
horizon to the 60-day horizon. Numerically, at all Easley, de Prado, and O’Hara (2016) find that market
horizons, the alpha from the liquidity-supplying order imbalance is not related to the very short-term
trades is greater than the corresponding alphas from future bid-ask spread. O’Hara (2015), in her seminal
the liquidity-demanding trades. For example, the paper on contemporary microstructure, explains
alpha at the close of the trading day is 3.4 (14.7) bp these phenomena by suggesting that sophisticated
for liquidity-demanding (supplying) trades, which is traders rely primarily on limit orders in modern algo-
equivalent to 8.87% (44.37%) annually. rithmic markets. She suggests that the architecture of
the markets has changed so fundamentally after the
The informativeness in liquidity-demanding and -sup- advent of machine traders that many of the trad-
plying trades of proprietary traders show quite a sig- itional microstructure models and assumptions are no
nificant contrast. In both long and short horizons, the longer valid.
liquidity-supplying trades have positive alphas,
whereas the liquidity-demanding trades have nega- One economic explanation could be that the higher
tive alphas. The positive alphas of liquidity-supplying alpha of liquidity-supplying trades is perhaps entirely
trades are significant from the day of the trade to a compensation for liquidity provision. The limit
the 20-day horizon. The significance of the negative orders earn the half bid-ask spread, and the market

Volume 79, Number 1 87


88
Table 4. TBCT Alphas for Institutions, Proprietary Traders, and Retail Clients: Liquidity-Demanding and Liquidity-
Supplying Trades
Panel A: Liquidity-demanding trades
Category/Horizon EOD 1 Day 5 Days 10 Days 20 Days 60 Days 125 Days
Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Institutions 0.034 (5.865) 0.041 (3.513) 0.018 (1.978) 0.012 (2.186) 0.007 (1.817) 0.004 (1.629) 0.003 (1.648)
Proprietary –0.029 (–11.672) –0.017 (–5.941) –0.010 (–6.163) –0.006 (–5.118) –0.004 (–4.144) –0.001 (–2.246) 0.000 (–0.440)
Retail clients –0.118 (–28.892) –0.081 (–10.050) –0.040 (–6.958) –0.027 (–6.771) –0.015 (–5.769) –0.006 (–3.131) –0.003 (–1.756)
Panel B: Liquidity-supplying trades
Category/Horizon EOD 1 Day 5 Days 10 Days 20 Days 60 Days 125 Days

Institutions 0.147 (22.166) 0.097 (6.977) 0.043 (4.897) 0.030 (4.729) 0.019 (4.591) 0.008 (2.774) 0.003 (0.981)
Proprietary 0.031 (13.093) 0.021 (7.714) 0.012 (6.805) 0.006 (5.807) 0.002 (2.331) 0.000 (0.025) 0.000 (–0.471)
Retail client 0.002 (0.479) –0.001 (–0.120) 0.001 (0.157) 0.000 (–0.036) –0.001 (–0.438) –0.001 (–0.793) 0.000 (–0.238)

This table presents the transactions-based calendar time (TBCT) buys-minus-sells portfolio alphas for institutions, proprietary traders, and retail clients for liquidity-demanding trades
(Panel A) and liquidity-supplying trades (Panel B) in the National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India for the period 2013–2015. It reports the daily alpha in percentage from horizon of
the end of trade day (EOD) to 125 days. We refer to the side of an electronic limit order book trade that initiated the trade as a liquidity-demanding trade and the other side of the
trade as a liquidity-supplying trade. The alpha is computed as the intercept in the regression of the buys-minus-sells portfolio return on the Fama-French-Carhart factors (i.e., mar-
ket, size, value factors, and momentum over stock returns over the past 12 months).  and  denote statistical significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.
Trade Informativeness in Modern Markets

orders pay the half spread. We estimate the spread we provide an additional analysis that allows us to
for each stock each day using the Roll (1984) model, understand the flow of information in the market
which utilizes the short-term return reversal in trade among the three trading groups more clearly. For the
prices. The average estimated spread for the top 50 same, we use an analysis proposed by Stoffman
stocks is 4.4 bp. For the next 450 stocks, it is (2014), who used only two groups of traders—institu-
24.3 bp, and for the rest of the stocks, it is 100.4 bp. tions and households (or individuals)—and examined
Thus, an approximate value-weighted average bid-ask how prices moved when one group buys from the
spread is 16 bp. The end-of-day alpha of institutions other and vice versa. To recognize how prices are
from liquidity-supplying trades is 147 bp, and that affected by the interaction of different groups of
from liquidity-demanding trades is 34 bp. From these investors in the market, we examine the relation
estimates, we find that while half-spread can explain between stock returns and the proportion of trading
a part of the extra alpha of the liquidity-supplying within and between each group of investors. We
trades, the majority part of the alpha remains unex- estimate the regression:
plained and thus can be attributed to informed trad- ri, t ¼ bI, I ðI=IÞi, t þ bI, P ðI=PÞi, t þ bI, R ðI=RÞi, t
ers’ relative use of more limit orders than market
þ bP, I ðP=IÞi, t þ bP, P ðP=PÞi, t þ bP, R ðP=RÞi, t
orders in modern algorithmic markets.
þ bR, I ðR=IÞi, t þ bR, P ðR=PÞi, t þ bR, R ðR=RÞi, t
Informativeness across Different Levels X
3 X
3
of Market Capitalization. A stock’s informa- þ fk ri, tk þ  k RMi, tk
k¼1 k¼0
tional environment can change with the size of the
stock, and thus the trading environment can also X
3
þ nk ABNVOLi, tk þ ei, t
consequently change (Fong, Gallagher, and Lee
k¼0
2014). The NIFTY 50 stocks see higher coverage
(2)
from brokerage analysts and media. We saw in Table
2 that stocks that are part of the NIFTY 50 index where ri, t denotes return for stock i on day t. The
have higher participation from institutions, whereas explanatory variables represent the fraction of trad-
the smaller stocks have relatively greater participa- ing in stock i on date t that is accounted for by trad-
tion from the retail-client group. ers of type X buying from traders of type Z, and the
types “I,” “P,” and “R” indicate institutions, propri-
We next examine whether the informativeness of the etary, and retail clients, respectively. Three lags of
three groups of traders is different across the differ- the stocks’ daily return and the lags and contempor-
ent market capitalization groups. The overall TBCT aneous values of stocks’ abnormal volume (the daily
results are inherently value-weighted and thus may volume divided by its trailing 20-day average) and
not reflect the performance in smaller stocks well. As the market return are included as controls.
discussed before, we divide the stocks into three
groups—the 50 stocks of NIFTY 50, the next 450 We run the regression for the three market capital-
stocks, and the rest of the stocks—and for each ization groups of stocks separately, and the results
group of stocks, we compute the TBCT returns by are reported in Table 6. As expected, within-group
subtracting the sell portfolio returns from the buy trading does not explain returns, but between-group
portfolio returns for all the time horizons. Table 5 trading does. For the top 50 stocks, we find that bI,R
provides the details. Panels A, B and C provide the is positive and significant (at the 1% level) and bR,I is
results of the first 50, the next 450, and the rest of negative. Thus, when institutions buy from retail cli-
the stocks. ents, prices move up, and when they sell to retail cli-
ents, prices move down (weakly). Similarly, when
The institutions outperform in all market capitaliza- proprietary traders buy from retail clients, prices
tion categories. Their positive alpha is significant move up, and when they sell to retail clients, prices
across all the board. In the case of small stocks, the go down (both significant at the 1% level). None of
alpha is higher and lasts up to the 125-day horizon. the other main explanatory variables is significant,
The retail client loses in all market capitalization cate- including the trade variables between institutions and
gories. The proprietary traders have positive and sig- proprietary.
nificant alpha only in the small-stock category.
For the next 450 stocks, we find that prices move up
Trading Informativeness–Flow of when institutions buy from either retail-client or pro-
Information among Groups. To complement prietary groups, as bI,R and bI,P are both positive and
the informativeness analysis using the TBCT method, significant. We also find that when the proprietary

Volume 79, Number 1 89


90
Table 5. TBCT Alphas for Investor Categories of Institutions, Proprietary Traders, and Retail Clients across Stock Categories of
Top 50, Next 450, and the Rest of Stocks
Category/
Horizon EOD 1 Day 5 Days 10 Days 20 Days 60 Days 125 Days

A: top
50 stocks
Institutional 0.048 (11.310) 0.040 (3.972) 0.021 (2.336) 0.017 (2.739) 0.011 (2.717) 0.005 (1.721) 0.002 (0.692)
Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Proprietary 0.003 (1.109) 0.006 (1.514) 0.004 (2.267) 0.002 (1.549) 0.000 (–0.030) 0.000 (–0.633) 0.000 (0.138)
Retail client –0.045 (–14.762) –0.036 (–3.915) –0.021 (–2.327) –0.019 (–2.878) –0.012 (–2.785) –0.006 (1.900) –0.003 (–0.883)
B: next
450 stocks
Institutional 0.161 (25.956) 0.111 (5.717) 0.044 (4.076) 0.029 (4.004) 0.016 (3.566) 0.005 (2.297) 0.003 (1.656)
Proprietary –0.004 (–2.024) –0.004 (–2.055) –0.003 (–2.557) –0.003 (–3.287) –0.002 (–3.745) –0.001 (–3.212) 0.000 (–2.224)
Retail client –0.069 (–25.351) –0.046 (–5.163) –0.019 (–3.366) –0.012 (–3.445) –0.007 (–3.090) –0.002 (–2.059) –0.001 (–1.346)
C: the rest
of stocks
Institutional 0.213 (13.372) 0.117 (8.482) 0.044 (4.073) 0.028 (3.158) 0.020 (2.724) 0.017 (2.984) 0.016 (2.911)
Proprietary 0.025  (5.971) 0.011  (2.795) –0.002 (–0.666) 0.001 (0.372) 0.002 (0.833) 0.001 (0.538) –0.001 (1.358)
Retail client –0.048 (–15.928) –0.027 (–9.463) –0.011 (–4.350) –0.007 (–3.235) –0.004 (–2.207) –0.003 (–2.404) –0.003 (–2.284)

This table presents the transactions-based calendar-time (TBCT) buys-minus-sells portfolio alphas for institutions, proprietary traders, and retail clients across stock categories “top
50,” “next 450,” and “the rest” of stocks in the National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India for the period 2013–2015. It reports the daily alpha in percentage from horizon of the end
of trade day (EOD) to 125 days. We compute the alpha as the intercept in the regression of the buys-minus-sells portfolio return on the Fama-French-Carhart factors (i.e., market,
size, value factors, and momentum over stock returns over the past 12 months).  and  denote statistical significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.
Trade Informativeness in Modern Markets

Table 6. Flow of Information across Three Trading Groups


Top 50 Stocks Next 450 Stocks Rest of Stocks

Inst/Inst 0.021 0.047 0.100


Inst/Prop 0.008 0.040 0.019
Inst/Ret-Cl 0.068 0.014 0.000
Prop/Inst –0.024 –0.107 0.031
Prop/Prop 0.013 –0.055 0.046
Prop/Ret-Cl 0.176 0.095 0.009
Ret-Cl/Inst –0.037 0.021 0.000
Ret-Cl/Prop –0.148 0.033 –0.015
Ret-Cl/Ret-Cl 0.016 –0.020 0.000
Return(t-1) –0.002 –0.001 –0.002
Return(t-2) –0.002 –0.001 –0.002
Return(t-3) –0.001 –0.001 –0.001
AbVol 0.002 –0.025 –0.029
AbVol(t-1) 0.006 0.009 0.009
AbVol(t-2) –0.000 0.003 0.003
AbVol(t-3) –0.001 0.001 0.003
Market_ret 0.008 –0.002 0.008
Market_ret(t-1) 0.000 –0.000 0.001
Market_ret(t-2) –0.000 –0.002 –0.002
Market_ret(t-3) –0.002 0.006 0.008

The table provides an analysis of the flow of information among and within the three groups of trad-
ers: institutions (Inst), proprietary (Prop), and retail client (Ret-cl). The cells represent the regression
coefficient in estimating Equation (2). The dependent variable is the return of stock i on day t. The
explanatory variables represent the fraction of trading in stock i on date t that is accounted for by
traders of type X buying from traders of type Z (X/Z). Three lags of the stocks’ daily return and the
lags and contemporaneous value of stocks’ abnormal volume (the daily volume divided by the trailing
20-day average) and market return are included as controls. Our sample is formed using all stocks at
the National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India and stocks are divided according to market capitalization
into “top 50,” “next 450,” and “the rest” of stocks, The time period is 2013–2015.

group buys from the retail client, prices move up, could very well be the case that an institution may split
and when they buy from institutions, prices go down. an order for the same stock with two or more brokers,
The fact that institutions are most informed, followed one of whom uses an algorithmic system and the other
by proprietary groups, is validated by the information broker executes manually. We aim to see whether
flow analysis of Stoffman (2014).11 there is any difference in alpha on the day of the trade
between algorithmic trades and manual trades of the
Trading Informativeness of Institutions institution. We do not go on and check the difference
Using Algo and Non-Algo Execution in informativeness across longer horizons since that will
Systems. The institutions, through their brokers, can not provide insight on the value added by the execu-
choose to use algorithmic or non-algorithmic execution. tion services (i.e., algorithmic versus manual).
In this section, we aim to see whether it beneficial for
Methodologically, we use again the Fama-French-
the institutional traders to go for algorithmic execu-
Carhart four-factor model. We estimate the following
tions. Institutional traders can have various methodolo-
time series models using daily data:
gies and time horizons for executing and holding the
positions, for example, they could be large market cap rpalgo, t  rpnonalgo, t ¼ a þ bp ðrm, t  rf, t Þ
funds, diversified funds, or small-cap funds. These trad- þ bSMB SMBt þ bHML HMLt
ers empanel brokers to execute their trades. These
þ bUMD UMDt þ et
brokers can use either algorithmic trading systems or
manual terminals manned by dealers to handle the exe- (3)
cution. The funds may deem it appropriate to use dif- where r(p-algo,t) and r(p-non-algo,t) are the returns on the
ferent brokers for different sets of stocks based on buys minus sells portfolios of the institutional algo
liquidity, size and value of trade, and brokerage fees. It and non-algo investor categories.

Volume 79, Number 1 91


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 7. TBCT Difference between Alphas for Algo and Non-Algo Institutions on Trade Day
EOD EOD Liquidity-Demanding EOD Liquidity-Supplying

All stocks 0.020 (2.128) 0.076 (6.765) 0.010 (0.866)


NIFTY 50 stocks 0.016 (2.033) 0.033 (3.837) 0.009 (0.906)
Next 450 stocks 0.073 (5.899) 0.016 (8.455) 0.029 (1.498)
Rest of stocks 0.066 (1.607) 0.149 (3.504) 0.033 (0.792)

This table presents the transactions-based calendar-time (TBCT) alpha difference for algo and non-algo institutional trades in the
National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India for the period 2013–2015. The dependent variable in the “algo minus non-algo” alpha cal-
culation is the buys-minus-sells portfolio return of trades via algo minus the return of trades via non-algo. The alphas for TBCT
portfolios based on liquidity-demanding and liquidity-supplying trades are reported. We refer to the side of an electronic limit
order book trade that initiated the trade as a liquidity-demanding trade and the other side of the trade as a liquidity-supplying
trade. The daily alpha in percentage at the end of trade day (EOD) is reported.  and  denote statistical significance at the 1%
and 5% levels, respectively.

In Table 7, we provide the estimates of the alphas and Riordan (2013) find that algorithms take liquidity
and show that the end-of-day alphas for algorithmic (trade via market orders) when it is cheap and supply
executions are greater than manual executions for liquidity (trade via limit orders) when it is expensive,
institutional trades. while human traders do the opposite. We compare
days of extremely high volatility (top 20th percentile)
To further probe the usefulness of the trading algo- with days of extremely low volatility (bottom 20th
rithms, we examine their differential performance on percentile). The bid-ask spreads are expected to be
high-volume and high-volatility days. Those days, in
very high during the former and very low during the
particular, are important for institutional investors as
latter (Wyart et al. 2008). We define passivity ratio
there may be some news that requires them to
as the number of shares traded as liquidity suppliers
unwind a large position or some index reconstitution
over the total number of shares traded and find that
that forces them to buy and sell large quantities
the passivity ratio of institutions using algorithms is
of stocks.
higher by 1.5% (significant at the 1% level) on days
We thus create two sets of TBCT portfolios. One set of high volatility compared to days of low volatility.
of portfolios is created with only stock-days trades When we see the manual executions of institutions,
that have more than two times the 21-day rolling the situation is completely the opposite. The passivity
volume. The second set of portfolios is created with ratio is 3.6% less (significant at a 1% level) on days
trades of stock days that have a difference between of high volatility compared to days of low volatility.
the high and low price that is greater than 3% of the Thus, the ability to monitor the markets continuously
open price. We then re-estimate Equation (3), but and switching between market and limit orders
only for these high-volume and high-volatility port- depending on the market condition (depending on
folios. We see that the end-of-day difference in whether liquidity is cheap or expensive) is one of the
alphas between algorithmic and manual execution is value additions of executing through algorithms.
positive and statistically significant on high-volume
The other value-providing channel of algorithms is
and high-volatility days at the 5% and 1% levels,
that they are much less prone to cognitive biases.
respectively. What is more important, the magnitude
One of the well-known characteristics of financial
of the difference in the alpha is 8.6 bp (4.8 bp) for
markets is price clustering or trading at round num-
high-volume (-volatility) days is more than four (two)
bers (Ahn, Cai, and Cheung 2005; Aitken et al. 1996).
times the corresponding alpha in the full sample
The clustering tendency can create losses, and
(Table 7). Thus, we find that there is more value to
sophisticated traders can devise profitable trading
algorithmic executions for the institutional traders in
strategies such as cluster undercutting to take advan-
days of high volume and high volatility.
tage of this phenomenon (Bhattacharya et al. 2012).
How do algorithms help create value over manual Davis, Van Ness, and Van Ness (2014) argue that
executions? First, algorithms have the technology to trades done through algorithms should see much less
monitor markets in real time and do it without any clustering tendency than trades done manually. The
explicit cost. This advantage enables the algorithms NSE has a uniform tick size of 5 paise or (` 0.05).
to find suitable window of trading opportunities and We define a trade as a clustered trade if the trade
choose the route of trade accordingly. Hendershott price is of the form ` X.00 or ` X.50.12 We find that

92
Trade Informativeness in Modern Markets

institutional manual trades have a clustering ten-

0.000 (7.060) 0.000 (8.063)

limit order book trade that initiated the trade as a liquidity-demanding trade and the other side of the trade as a liquidity-supplying trade. The daily alpha in percentage from horizon
India for the period 2013–2015. The alphas for TBCT portfolios based on liquidity-demanding and liquidity-supplying trades are also reported. We refer to the side of an electronic
0.001 (2.078)
Liquidity-demanding –0.017 (–6.942) –0.008 (–2.830) –0.005 (–3.374) –0.003 (–2.900) –0.002 (–3.373) –0.001 (–1.952) 0.000 (–0.091)

This table presents the transactions-based calendar-time (TBCT) alphas for proprietary algorithmic traders (high-frequency traders [HFTs]) in the National Stock Exchange (NSE) of
dency of 33%, whereas the institutional algorithmic

125 Days
trades have a clustering tendency of only 22% (with
the difference significant at 1% level). Thus, we see
that algorithmic executions provide value in terms of
reducing one of the behavioral biases of humans: the
tendency to cluster. There are several other cognitive
biases operating in financial markets that we are not

0.001 (1.191)
60 Days
able to examine in our study, and we sense that exe-
cuting through trading algorithms mitigates
those biases.

Trading Informativeness of Proprietary


Algorithmic Traders or HFTs. One of the

0.001 (7.213)

0.003 (2.890)
more intriguing facts in modern algorithmic markets

of the end of trade day (EOD) to 125 days is reported.  and  denote statistical significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.
20 Days
is the presence of HFTs. With superior speed, HFTs
are often accused of having an unfair advantage in
the stock market over other participants. Academic
literature has argued that HFT adversely selects
other traders due to its speed advantage (Biais,

0.002 (7.401)

0.007 (5.512)
Foucault, and Moinas 2015) and its liquidity-demand-
ing orders look out for stale quotes (Van Kervel and

10 Days
Menkveld 2019) from other market participants while
its liquidity-supplying orders avoid the adverse selec-
tion themselves by quick modification or cancellation
(Hoffmann 2014).

In this section, we simply ask whether the HFT earns


Table 8. TBCT Alphas for Proprietary Algorithmic Traders (HFTs)

0.003 (7.376)

0.012 (6.969)
risk-adjusted trading alphas and whether their liquid-
5 Days

ity-demanding and liquidity-supplying orders primarily


contribute to the same. To accomplish the task, we
re-estimate Equation (1) again for all the horizons,
restricting ourselves to only HFTs’ trades (proprietary
traders with algorithmic trading). We already saw in
0.007 (6.077)

0.037 (15.232) 0.025 (9.083)

Table 3 that overall proprietary traders’ alphas are


not significantly different from zero. However, in
1 Day

Table 8, we find that HFTs’ trades show positive


risk-adjusted alpha that is significant until a horizon
of 10 days. Thus, HFTs’ trades are informative.

Next, we segregate the trades as either liquidity-


demanding or liquidity-supplying and compute the
0.007 (3.417)

HFT alphas for all horizons. We find that for all hori-
zons from the end of the trading day to 60 days,
EOD

HFTs’ liquidity-demanding trades have negative and


significant alphas. On the other hand, for all horizons
from the end of the trading day to 20 days, HFT
liquidity-supplying trades have positive and signifi-
cant alphas. Comparing the liquidity-supplying alpha
Liquidity-supplying
Category/Horizon

with the estimate of half-spread derived earlier, we


see that a significant part of HFTs’ liquidity-supplying
alpha cannot be explained by compensation for
All trades

trades

trades

liquidity provision. Our result here again goes back to


O’Hara’s (2015) argument that sophisticated traders
primarily use limit orders to trade.

Volume 79, Number 1 93


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 9. Intraday TBCT Alphas for Proprietary Algorithmic Traders (HFTs)


Category/Horizon EOM 1 Minute 5 Minutes 20 Minutes 60 Minutes

All Trades 0.0247 (404.544) 0.0113 (208.570) 0.0031 (84.337) 0.0006 (26.34) 0.0001 (8.887)

This table presents the intraday transactions-based calendar-time (TBCT) alphas for proprietary algorithmic traders (high-frequency
traders [HFTs]) in the National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India for the period 2013–2015. The alphas are calculated using the one-
factor market model. The alphas (expressed in percentages) are calculated at several horizons, starting at of the end of trade
minute (EOM) to 60 minutes post-trade.  and  denote statistical significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.

To cap off our informativeness analysis of HFT, we Finally, we provide evidence on HFTs’ daily net clos-
perform an intraday TBCT analysis for this group. ing position, which should indicate whether the HFT
Since the essence of high-frequency trading is speed, plays the role of the modern market maker
HFTs could be reversing their trades many times (Menkveld 2013; Hagstro € mer and Norde
n 2013). If
within the day. Thus, a higher-frequency TBCT port- the HFT acts as a voluntary market maker or liquidity
folio may be more appropriate to track the inform- provider, then we should see HFT trading on both
ativeness of HFTs. What is not trivial is the sides of the market. To analyze the same, we focus
frequency at which the HFT activity should be on the following quantity on a stock-day level:
tracked. Given that the NSE is ranked fourth in the ABS Scaled net volume
world in terms of the number of transactions, HFT  
Shares boughtShares sold
activity in the NSE is quite intense. We choose a 1- ¼ ABS
minute benchmark for this analysis, keeping the same Shares bought þ Shares sold
in mind. The method we follow is the same as
defined earlier, with the unit of analysis shifted from If a trading group is trading on both sides of the mar-
trading day to trading minute; the holding periods ket and reversing their positions, then we should see
are now the end of the trading minute, 1 minute, this quantity close to 0. However, if a trading group
5 minutes, 10 minutes, 20 minutes, and 60 minutes. is trading on one side of the market on a trading day,
Additionally, we compute the alpha from the one-fac- then we should see this quantity close to 1. For each
tor market model, as the size and the book-to-market trading group and mode of execution (algorithmic
and momentum factors are not expected to be sig- and manual), we compute the stock-day average of
nificant at high-frequency intervals. We also make this quantity. Figure 2 provides the details. HFTs’
sure that no holding period continues over to the value of this variable is closest to 0 at 6.2%. Among
next day. all trading groups, HFTs reverse their trades most
intraday and end their day at near-flat inventory,
Table 9 provides details. We find that the TBCT atypical of market makers. Whether trading manually
alpha for the end-of-trading minute is positive and or through algorithms, institutions primarily trade on
highly significant at the 1% level. The TBCT alphas one side of the market on a day; their absolute
go down in magnitude as we increase the holding scaled net volume are respectively 70.5% and 67.9%,
period; however, they remain highly significant at the very close to 1.
1% level throughout. The economic magnitude of the
end-of-minute TBCT alpha (2.4 bp) of HFTs is quite
high and should be interpreted with caution. Because Robustness
the actual horizon of the HFT holding period could Our analysis for this paper uses 3 years of data, from
be a few milliseconds to few hours, it may be difficult 2013 to 2015. Over this period, the Indian stock
to state whether the HFT is actually able to realize market initially rose for the first 2 years and then fell
this alpha. However, the results no doubt reflect that in the final year. In this section, we provide evidence
HFT trades are strongly informative intraday at vari- on whether our results could be influenced by the
ous horizons. Overall, our results in this section con- market conditions during the sample period. We div-
tribute to the widely growing literature on HFT ide the sample into two parts—1) the bull period
informativeness (Baron et al. 2019; Brogaard, from 1st January 2013 to 28th February 2015, and
Hendershott, and Riordan 2019). 2) the bear period from 1st March 2013 to 31st

94
Trade Informativeness in Modern Markets

Figure 2. Average Absolute Scaled Volume

80.00%

70.00%

60.00%

50.00%

40.00%

30.00%

20.00%

10.00%

0.00%
Instuons algo Instuons non- HFT Prop non-algo Retail-Client algo Retail non-algo
algo

Absolute Scaled Net Volume

The figure illustrates the average values of the abs(shares bought  shares sold)/(shares bought þ shares sold) for each investor
type-execution type. Our sample includes all stocks traded at the National Stock Exchange (NSE) of India, and our sample period is
2013 to 2015.

December 2015. The NIFTY index increased from institutional trades show a positive and significant
5950.9 to 8901.9 in the first period and went down risk-adjusted alpha. Similarly, the retail-client group
to 7946.4 in the second period. We run the TBCT shows a negative and significant risk-adjusted alpha
analysis in both periods separately and find that our for similar horizons. The proprietary traders have an
results are qualitatively similar in both subperiods.13 insignificant alpha. Further, we find that the rank
ordering of alphas of the three groups of traders
Finally, we provide evidence that our results remain remains valid when either we look at only limit-order
unaffected if we use a one-factor market model or trades or we look at only market-order trades. More
the Fama-French three-factor model instead of the interestingly, the alpha from the limit-order trades
four-factor model we use in our main results.14 exceeds the alpha for market-order trades for all
trading groups (even after controlling for the bid-ask
spread), suggesting that informed traders make use
Conclusion of limit orders more than market orders.
We provide a comprehensive analysis of informative-
ness for three mutually exclusive and exhaustive Finally, we make use of the exchange-provided algo-
trading groups—institutions, proprietary, and non- rithmic flags to do two additional investigations. First,
institutional non-proprietary (or retail-client) groups— we see whether algorithmic executions carry any
using 3-year complete order- and trade-level data for value over manual execution for institutional traders.
all stocks trading on the NSE of India. Past studies of We do a difference in TBCT portfolio returns on the
informativeness were primarily done on data that day of the trade between institutional algorithmic
was non-comprehensive for the market, have mostly trades and institutional manual trades and find that
focused on one or two of the trading groups, and the alpha is positive and significant (even more so on
were done in non-algorithmic markets. days of high volume and high volatility), suggesting a
non-trivial value provided by algorithmic executions.
Our main finding is that institutions are informed, Second, we separately examine the profitability of
and the retail-client group is uninformed. For all hori- proprietary algorithmic traders or HFTs. We find that
zons starting from the end of the day to 60 days, the over all horizons starting from the day of the trade

Volume 79, Number 1 95


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

to 10 days, HFT alphas are positive and significant. broker execution algorithms. We find that algorithmic
We also find that the HFT alpha coming from the executions provide value to institutions, especially
liquidity-supplying trades is positive and significant, during high-volume and high-volatility days. The
while that coming from liquidity-demanding trades is source of this alpha comes from the trading algo-
negative and significant. rithm’s ability to monitor the market continuously at
a near-zero cost and the fact that algorithms are
An important implication of our results for retail trad- much less affected by behavioral bias compared to
ers is that they should be patient and trade using humans. As a limitation, we believe that the data
limit orders. On the whole, they have an information period in our study is perhaps on the shorter side.
disadvantage in the market, and this disadvantage Future research should attempt a more robust study
gets attenuated when they use limit orders to trade that uses data for a much longer period, subject to
as they receive compensation for liquidity provision. the availability of the data.
An implication for institutions is that they should use

Editor's Note
Submitted 22 October 2021
Accepted 15 September 2022 by William N. Goetzmann

Notes
1. World Federation of Exchanges 2020 report. momentum factor constructed by subtracting the returns
of a portfolio of losing stocks from the returns of a
2. Alphas are risk adjusted (Fama-French-Carhart portfolio of winning stocks.
four factor).
9. As an alternative, we also create a sample of stocks with
3. The direct market access was provided in 2010. fewer than three analysts covering in all the 3 years. The
results are qualitatively similar.
4. https://www.world-exchanges.org/our-work/articles/
2020-annual-statistics-guide. 10. Available from the authors.
5. Colocation services amount to renting rack space in the 11. Finally, for the group of the rest of stocks, we do not
premises of the exchange itself to reduce latency, i.e., to see any major information flow from this method.
reduce the time gap between an order being placed and it Table 2 suggests that the retail client contributes
actually reaching the exchange. almost 75% of the turnover in this group of smallest
stocks. Such a skew in the distribution perhaps makes
6. The results are available on request from the authors. this analysis on the group of the rest of stocks
incomprehensible.
7. Odean (1998), Odean (1999), and Barber and Odean
(2000) use trading account data from a discount
12. Thus, the trades of the form (` X.05, ` X.10, ` X.15, … , `
brokerage house. X.45, ` X.55, ` X.60, … ., ` X.90, ` X.95) are termed as
8. SMB is the Fama-French size factor constructed by non-clustered.
longing a portfolio of small firms and shorting a portfolio 13. Unreported, available from the authors.
of big firms. HML is the Fama-French value factor
constructed by longing a portfolio of high-value firms and 14. Unreported, available from the authors.
shorting a portfolio of low-value firms. UMD is the

References
Agarwalla, S. K., J. Jacob, and J. R. Varma. 2014. “Four Aitken, M., P. Brown, C. Buckland, H. Y. Izan, and T. Walter.
Factor Model in Indian Equities Market.” Indian 1996. “Price Clustering on the Australian Stock Exchange.”
Institute of Management, Ahmedabad Working Paper Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 4 (2–3): 297–314. doi:10.1016/
(2013-09), 05. 0927-538X(96)00016-9.
Ahn, H. J., J. Cai, and Y. L. Cheung. 2005. “Price Clustering on Angel, J. 2021. “Gamestonk: What Happened and What to do
the Limit-Order Book: Evidence from the Stock Exchange of About It.” Available at SSRN 3782195.
Hong Kong.” Journal of Financial Markets 8 (4): 421–51. doi:10.
1016/j.finmar.2005.07.001. Banerjee, A., and P. Roy. 2022. "Are High Frequency Traders
Really Market-Makers." SSRN working paper.

96
Trade Informativeness in Modern Markets

Barber, B. M., Y. T. Lee, Y. J. Liu, and T. Odean. 2009. “Just Copeland, T. E., and D. Galai. 1983. “Information Effects on the
How Much Do Individual Investors Lose by Trading?” Review of Bid-Ask Spread.” The Journal of Finance 38 (5): 1457–69. doi:
Financial Studies 22 (2): 609–32. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhn046. 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1983.tb03834.x.

Barber, B. M., and T. Odean. 2000. “Trading is Hazardous to Davis, R. L., B. F. Van Ness, and R. A. Van Ness. 2014.
Your Wealth: The Common Stock Investment Performance of “Clustering of Trade Prices by High-Frequency and Non–High-
Individual Investors.” The Journal of Finance 55 (2): 773–806. Frequency Trading Firms.” Financial Review 49 (2): 421–33. doi:
doi:10.1111/0022-1082.00226. 10.1111/fire.12042.

Baron, M., J. Brogaard, B. Hagstro€ mer, and A. Kirilenko. 2019. Domowitz, I., and H. Yegerman. 2005. “The Cost of Algorithmic
Trading: A First Look at Comparative Performance.” The Journal
“Risk and Return in High-Frequency Trading.” Journal of
of Trading 1 (1): 33–42. doi:10.3905/jot.2006.609174.
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 54 (3): 993–1024. doi:10.
1017/S0022109018001096. Easley, D., M. L. de Prado, and M. O’Hara. 2016. “Discerning
Information from Trade Data.” Journal of Financial Economics
Barrot, J. N., R. Kaniel, and D. Sraer. 2016. “Are Retail Traders
120 (2): 269–85. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2016.01.018.
Compensated for Providing Liquidity?” Journal of Financial
Economics 120 (1): 146–68. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2016.01.005. Easley, D., N. M. Kiefer, M. O’Hara, and J. B. Paperman. 1996.
“Liquidity, Information, and Infrequently Traded Stocks.” The
Bessembinder, H., M. Panayides, and K. Venkataraman. 2009. Journal of Finance 51 (4): 1405–36. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.
“Hidden Liquidity: An Analysis of Order Exposure Strategies in 1996.tb04074.x.
Electronic Stock Markets.” Journal of Financial Economics 94 (3):
361–83. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2009.02.001. Engen, E. M., and A. Lehnert. 2000. “Mutual Funds and the US
Equity Market.” Fed. Res. Bull 86:797.
Bhattacharya, U., C. W. Holden, and S. Jacobsen. 2012. “Penny
Fama, E. F. 1998. “Market Efficiency, Long-Term Returns, and
Wise, Dollar Foolish: Buy–Sell Imbalances on and around
Behavioral Finance.” Journal of Financial Economics 49 (3):
Round Numbers.” Management Science 58 (2): 413–31. doi:10.
283–306. doi:10.1016/S0304-405X(98)00026-9.
1287/mnsc.1110.1364.
Fong, K. Y., D. R. Gallagher, and A. D. Lee. 2014. “Individual
Biais, B., and T. Foucault. 2014. “HFT and Market Quality.”
Investors and Broker Types.” Journal of Financial and
Bankers, Markets & Investors 2014 (128): 5–19. Quantitative Analysis 49 (2): 431–51. doi:10.1017/
Biais, B., T. Foucault, and S. Moinas. 2015. “Equilibrium Fast S0022109014000349.
Trading.” Journal of Financial Economics 116 (2): 292–313. doi: € mer, B., and L. Norde
Hagstro n. 2013. “The Diversity of High-
10.1016/j.jfineco.2015.03.004. Frequency Traders.” Journal of Financial Markets 16 (4):
Boehmer, E., K. Fong, and J. J. Wu. 2021. “Algorithmic Trading 741–70. doi:10.1016/j.finmar.2013.05.009.
and Market Quality: International Evidence.” Journal of Financial Handa, P., R. A. Schwartz, and A. Tiwari. 1998. “The Ecology of
and Quantitative Analysis 56 (8): 2659–88. doi:10.1017/ an Order-Driven Market.” The Journal of Portfolio Management
S0022109020000782. 24 (2): 47–55. doi:10.3905/jpm.24.2.47.
Boehmer, E., C. M. Jones, X. Zhang, and X. Zhang. 2021. Hendershott, T., C. M. Jones, and A. J. Menkveld. 2011. “Does
“Tracking Retail Investor Activity.” The Journal of Finance 76 (5): Algorithmic Trading Improve Liquidity?” The Journal of Finance
2249–305. doi:10.1111/jofi.13033. 66 (1): 1–33. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01624.x.

Brogaard, J., A. Carrion, T. Moyaert, R. Riordan, A. Shkilko, and €rhoff. 2015. “Are
Hendershott, T., D. Livdan, and N. Schu
K. Sokolov. 2018. “High Frequency Trading and Extreme Price Institutions Informed about News?” Journal of Financial
Movements.” Journal of Financial Economics 128 (2): 253–65. Economics 117 (2): 249–87. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2015.03.007.
doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2018.02.002. Hendershott, T., and R. Riordan. 2013. “Algorithmic Trading
Brogaard, J., T. Hendershott, and R. Riordan. 2019. “Price and the Market for Liquidity.” Journal of Financial and
Discovery without Trading: Evidence from Limit Orders.” The Quantitative Analysis 48 (4): 1001–24. doi:10.1017/
S0022109013000471.
Journal of Finance 74 (4): 1621–58. doi:10.1111/jofi.12769.
Hoffmann, P. 2014. “A Dynamic Limit Order Market with Fast
Chae, J. 2005. “Trading Volume, Information Asymmetry, and
and Slow Traders.” Journal of Financial Economics 113 (1):
Timing Information.” The Journal of Finance 60 (1): 413–42. doi:
156–69. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.04.002.
10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00734.x.
Hong, H., T. Lim, and J. C. Stein. 2000. “Bad News Travels
Chakrabarty, B., T. Hendershott, S. Nawn, and R. Pascual.
Slowly: Size, Analyst Coverage, and the Profitability of
2020. “Order Exposure in High Frequency Markets.” Available Momentum Strategies.” The Journal of Finance 55 (1): 265–95.
at SSRN 3074049. doi:10.1111/0022-1082.00206.
Chakravarty, S. 2001. “Stealth-Trading: Which Traders’ Trades Jørgensen, K., J. Skjeltorp, and B. A. Ødegaard. 2018.
Move Stock Prices?” Journal of Financial Economics 61 (2): “Throttling Hyperactive Robots–Order-to-Trade Ratios at the
289–307. doi:10.1016/S0304-405X(01)00063-0. Oslo Stock Exchange.” Journal of Financial Markets 37:1–16.
doi:10.1016/j.finmar.2017.09.001.
Collin-Dufresne, P., and V. Fos. 2015. “Do Prices Reveal the
Presence of Informed Trading?” The Journal of Finance 70 (4): Kaniel, R., S. Liu, G. Saar, and S. Titman. 2012. “Individual
1555–82. doi:10.1111/jofi.12260. Investor Trading and Return Patterns around Earnings

Volume 79, Number 1 97


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Announcements.” The Journal of Finance 67 (2): 639–80. doi:10. O’Hara, M. 2015. “High Frequency Market Microstructure.”
1111/j.1540-6261.2012.01727.x. Journal of Financial Economics 116 (2): 257–70. doi:10.1016/j.
jfineco.2015.01.003.
Kaniel, R., G. Saar, and S. Titman. 2008. “Individual Investor
Trading and Stock Returns.” The Journal of Finance 63 (1): Roll, R. 1984. “A Simple Implicit Measure of the Effective Bid-
273–310. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.2008.01316.x. Ask Spread in an Efficient Market.” The Journal of Finance 39
(4): 1127–39. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1984.tb03897.x.
Kelley, E. K., and P. C. Tetlock. 2013. “How Wise Are Crowds?
Insights from Retail Orders and Stock Returns.” The Journal of Seasholes, M. S., and N. Zhu. 2010. “Individual Investors and
Finance 68 (3): 1229–65. doi:10.1111/jofi.12028. Local Bias.” The Journal of Finance 65 (5): 1987–2010. doi:10.
1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01600.x.
Kim, S. T., and H. R. Stoll. 2014. “Are Trading Imbalances
Indicative of Private Information?” Journal of Financial Markets Securities and Exchange Commission. 2010. “Concept Release
20:151–74. doi:10.1016/j.finmar.2014.03.003. on Market Structure.”
Kovacs, T. 2010. “Equity Issues and Temporal Variation in Sias, R. W., and L. T. Starks. 1997. “Return Autocorrelation and
Information Asymmetry.” Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (1): Institutional Investors.” Journal of Financial Economics 46 (1):
12–23. 103–31. doi:10.1016/S0304-405X(97)00026-3.
Linnainmaa, J. T., and G. Saar. 2012. “Lack of Anonymity and Stoffman, N. 2014. “Who Trades with Whom? Individuals,
the Inference from Order Flow.” The Review of Financial Studies Institutions, and Returns.” Journal of Financial Markets 21:
25 (5): 1414–56. 50–75. doi:10.1016/j.finmar.2014.08.002.
Menkveld, A. J. 2013. “High Frequency Trading and the New Tian, X., B. Do, H. N. Duong, and P. S. Kalev. 2015. “Liquidity
Market Makers.” Journal of Financial Markets 16 (4): 712–40. Provision and Informed Trading by Individual Investors.” Pacific-
doi:10.1016/j.finmar.2013.06.006. Basin Finance Journal 35:143–62. doi:10.1016/j.pacfin.2014.11.005.
Nawn, S., and A. Banerjee. 2019. “Do Proprietary van der Beck, P., and C. Jaunin. 2021. “The Equity Market
Algorithmic Traders Withdraw Liquidity during Market Implications of The Retail Investment Boom.” Available at SSRN
Stress?” Financial Management 48 (2): 641–76. doi:10.1111/ 3776421.
fima.12238.
Van Kervel, V., and A. J. Menkveld. 2019. “High-Frequency
Odean, T. 1998. “Are Investors Reluctant to Realize Their Trading around Large Institutional Orders.” The Journal of
Losses?” The Journal of Finance 53 (5): 1775–98. doi:10.1111/ Finance 74 (3): 1091–137. doi:10.1111/jofi.12759.
0022-1082.00072.
Welch, I. 2022. “The Wisdom of the Robinhood Crowd.”
Odean, T. 1999. “Do Investors Trade Too Much?” American Journal of Finance 77 (3): 1489–1527. doi:10.1111/jofi.13128.
Economic Review 89 (5): 1279–98. doi:10.1257/aer.89.5.
Wyart, M., J. P. Bouchaud, J. Kockelkoren, M. Potters, and M.
1279.
Vettorazzo. 2008. “Relation between Bid–Ask Spread, Impact
O’Hara, M. 1995. Market Microstructure Theory. New York: and Volatility in Order-Driven Markets.” Quantitative Finance 8
Wiley. (1): 41–57. doi:10.1080/14697680701344515.

98
Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute Research
https://doi.org/10.1080/0015198X.2022.2100234

Option Pricing via


Breakeven Volatility
Blair Hull, Anlong Li, and Xiao Qiao
Blair Hull is a founder and chairman of Hull Tactical Asset Allocation, LLC, Chicago, IL. Anlong Li is a senior financial engineer at Hull
Tactical Asset Allocation, LLC, Chicago, IL. Xiao Qiao is an assistant professor at the City University of Hong Kong and Hong Kong Institute
for Data Science, Hong Kong, China. Send correspondence to Xiao Qiao at xiaoqiao@cityu.edu.hk.

The fair value of an option is given Introduction


by breakeven volatility, the value of he advent of option pricing models (Black and Scholes 1973;
implied volatility that sets the profit
and loss of a delta-hedged option to
zero. We calculate breakeven vola-
tility for 400,000 options on the
T Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein 1979) launched a revolution in modern
finance that saw explosive growth in options markets and mas-
sive interest in option pricing in the subsequent decades. Although
the option pricing literature contains a multitude of models, the
S&P 500 and build a predictive approaches often share a common idea: The value of an option is equal
model for these volatilities. A two- to that of a replication portfolio with the same eventual payoffs
stage regression approach captures (Merton 1973). The most natural implementation of this simple and ele-
the majority of the observed vari- gant idea is to build a distribution of outcomes from a large set of repli-
ation. By providing a link between cation portfolios using historical data, which can then be used to price
option characteristics and breakeven additional options. However, the implementation of this approach turns
volatility, we establish a non-para- out to be fraught with issues. Zou and Derman (1999) point out that
metric approach to pricing options
such replication can be time-consuming, and hedging errors due to
without the need to specify the
inaccurate volatility forecasts or infrequent hedging make the exercise
underlying price process. We illus-
difficult. As a result, most researchers opt for a more structural
trate the economic value of our
approach: Specify a return process for the underlying asset, derive the
approach with a simulated trading
pricing relationships, then calibrate the model to data.
strategy based on breakeven volatil-
ity predictions. We set out to build a non-parametric option pricing model based on
Merton’s (1973) original insight. In the past 20 years, computing power
Keywords: options; prediction; has grown rapidly and option databases have become more compre-
trading strategy; volatility hensive. These developments enable us to overcome the limitations
cited in Zou and Derman (1999). The first step towards an option pric-
ing model is to build a measure for the appropriate value of options.
Using historical prices, we calculate the fair value of an option, the
value of implied volatility (IV) that sets the profit and loss of a delta-
Disclosure: The authors report no funding hedged option position to zero. This value is called breakeven volatil-
sources. The authors alone are responsible ity (BEV).
for the content and writing of the paper.
Hull Tactical Asset Allocation, LLC is a The profit and loss from a dynamically hedged option position recover
registered investment adviser that deploys the difference between implied volatility and realized volatility, which
strategies, such as the one described in
this paper in investment products including indicates a
separately managed accounts and an The authors thank William Goetzmann (Executive Editor), Luis Garcia-Feijoo
exchange-traded fund. All errors are our (Managing Editor), Daniel Giamouridis (Co-Editor), two anonymous referees, Petra
own. Bakosova, Yeguang Chi, Jake DeSantis, Ruslan Goyenko, Steve Heston, Ray
Iwanowski, Craig Iseli, Kris Jacobs, Jason Wei, Lei Wu, Qi Wu, and Zonghao Yang
for helpful comments. We are especially grateful to Ben Albert for extensive discus-
PL Credits: 2.0 sions and data processing.

Volume 79, Number 1 © 2022 CFA Institute. All rights reserved. 99


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

positive or negative risk premium (Bakshi, Cao, and positions tend to earn positive profits for out-of-
Chen 1997; Christoffersen et al. 2018). In computing the-money (OTM) puts, an empirical regularity con-
breakeven volatility, we set the profit and loss to firmed in the literature (Coval and Shumway 2001;
zero, removing risk premia embedded in market pri- Bakshi and Kapadia 2003).
ces. To the extent market implied volatility of an
option differs from its breakeven volatility, the mar- We build a predictive model of breakeven volatility
ket price contains either a risk premium or a dis- using 12 variables and their transformations. In
count. If the IV were higher than the BEV, a delta- addition to typical parameters used in option
hedged short position in this option would result in a pricing, such as moneyness and time to expiration,
positive profit. If the IV were lower than the BEV, a we also include variables that have the potential to
delta-hedged long position would show a positive bring added predictive power, such as the CBOE
profit. In this sense, breakeven volatility provides the VIX Volatility Index (VVIX), the difference between
fair value of an option to both sides of the contract the delta of the option and the ATM delta, and the
(Dupire 2006). sensitivity of the option price with respect to vola-
tility. We use a two-stage regression approach to
We build a large set of breakeven volatility values build a statistical model that connects the predictor
for options on the S&P 500 Index (SPX), and we variables and breakeven volatility. The first stage
construct a predictive model that connects option produces forecasts of logged breakeven volatility,
characteristics to BEV. By providing a link and the second stage makes an adjustment such
between moneyness, time to expiration, and that the predicted breakeven volatility values
other observable characteristics and the fair are unbiased.
value of the option, the predictive relation can be
interpreted as a non-parametric option pricing Our statistical model provides a reliable fit to break-
model.1 Given a new option with its own set of even volatility. The two-stage model captures 90%
characteristics, we can quickly determine its of the variation in breakeven volatility. Model diag-
fair value. nostics reveal that the model performs best
between volatility values of 5 and 50%, but has dif-
Parametric approaches are favored over non-para- ficulties if breakeven volatility is below 5%. Our
metric ones when the underlying asset’s return model predictions exhibit convexity in volatility
dynamics are known, but this is rarely the case in space, and option prices are consistent with an
practice. The non-parametric approach to option underlying return distribution that exhibits negative
pricing can be data-intensive, but it offers a promis- skew and excess kurtosis. While the above features
ing alternative to standard parametric pricing models can be carefully engineered into a parametric model,
when parametric restrictions are violated. Since they arise naturally in our approach as we learn
non-parametric models do not rely on restrictive from data.2
assumptions, such as log-normality or sample-path
continuity, they are robust to the specification We test the economic value of our statistical model
errors that plague parametric models (Ait-Sahalia through a simulated trading strategy that exploits the
and Lo 1998). difference between implied volatility and our forecast
of breakeven volatility. For a particular option, if its
We construct delta-hedged positions for nearly implied volatility were lower than the predicted BEV,
400,000 S&P 500 options with a variety of strike the market price of the option is too low, and we
prices and time to expiration ranging from 5 to 74 take a delta-hedged long position. If the implied vola-
trading days. The empirical distribution of breakeven tility were higher than the predicted BEV, the market
volatility is similar to, but distinct from, that of price is too high, so we take a delta-hedged short
implied volatility. We construct volatility smirks for position. We trade options whose breakeven volatil-
both measures of volatility, and we uncover the fol- ity values differ more than $1 compared to the mid-
lowing pattern: Breakeven and implied volatility are point price.
almost identical in the at-the-money (ATM) region,
but as we move further away from the ATM strike In our testing period from January 2015 to
prices, the two measures diverge. Implied volatility November 2020, our statistical model achieves an
is higher than breakeven volatility for strike prices impressive out-of-sample R-squared of 0.71. The
lower than the underlying price, as well as for BEV-based strategy identifies 6,783 trading oppor-
strikes exceeding the underlying. The shapes of the tunities, earning 6.8% per year with an annual vola-
volatility smirks indicate that delta-hedged short tility of 4.5%. With a Sharpe ratio of 1.50, this

100
Option Pricing via Breakeven Volatility

strategy outperforms three alternative options strat- relaxes the constant breakeven volatility assumption
egies in terms of expected returns per unit of risk. and allows for a term structure of BEV, which is
The BEV strategy also provides a more attractive then solved by backward recursion. In doing so, we
risk-return tradeoff compared to a buy-and-hold use the implied volatility path as well as the stock
strategy in the S&P 500, which has a Sharpe ratio of price path for the calculation. Breakeven volatility
0.79 in our sample period. values calculated from our approach do not allow
for arbitrage.
We are not the first to use historical data to com-
pute terminal distributions and option prices. Our paper is also related to the literature on non-
Stutzer (1996) and Zou and Derman (1999) also use parametric approaches to option pricing. A strand of
historical data to compute option prices. Rather literature first developed in the 1990s. Hutchinson,
than looking at the replicated value of an option, Lo, and Poggio (1994) use neural networks to
these papers compute a risk-neutral distribution approximate the Black-Scholes formula. Ait-Sahalia
from the empirical distribution of the underlying and Lo (1998) propose a kernel density estimator of
asset. Stutzer (1996) notes the shortcoming of not the risk-neutral distribution, effectively providing a
incorporating market information related to option link between option characteristics and the second
prices into his approach, stating “there is need for a derivative of the volatility smirk. These pioneering
more detailed comparison of … non-parametric papers led to more recent literature on using
model values to actual transaction prices.” We machine learning methods to approximate the rela-
answer Stutzer’s call to action by using actual tionship between model inputs and outputs. Liu,
transaction prices to inform us about the fair Oosterlee, and Bohte (2019) propose a neural net-
values of options. Furthermore, Zou and Derman’s work model to approximate the Black-Scholes and
(1999) goal is relative pricing: Take exchange- Heston (1993) models. Manzo and Qiao (2021) use
traded option prices as given, build a pricing neural networks to approximate nine different credit
model, then calculate the prices of less liquid, over- risk models. Compared to these papers, we do not
the-counter options. In contrast, our goal is try to approximate existing option pricing models—
absolute pricing—to determine the fair value of indi- we let the data dictate how option characteristics
vidual options based on their observable and prices are related. Furthermore, our target option
characteristics. price is based on a fair valuation calculation rather
Some papers have used breakeven volatility as a than the market price.
diagnostic tool for market prices. Dupire (2006)
builds breakeven volatility surfaces and explains that
BEV is a fair volatility for both sides of an option Breakeven Volatility
contract. He highlights using BEV surfaces as a tool
to understand market volatility surfaces. Mitoulis Data. We obtain option prices, implied volatility,
(2019) carries out breakeven volatility calculations and deltas from SpiderRock Platform Services LLC.
using simulations, comparing delta-hedging results SpiderRock is an options trading platform provider
using Black and Scholes (1973) and Heston (1993) and data vendor based in Chicago that serves trad-
models. Neither paper attempts to forecast BEV val- ing desks at large banks, hedge funds, and propri-
ues or explore trading implications of the differences etary trading firms. SpiderRock’s historical data and
between implied and breakeven volatilities. As far as option analytics include implied volatility, option
we know, we are the first to build a non-parametric Greeks, risk metrics, and volatility surfaces derived
option pricing model via a predictive model of break- from the live data from SpiderRock’s trad-
even volatility. ing systems.

A crucial distinction between our paper and the Since OptionMetrics is commonly used in academic
existing literature is the calculation of breakeven studies, we would like to point out two differences
volatility. Zou and Derman (1999), Dupire (2006), between SpiderRock and OptionMetrics data (Please
and Mitoulis (2019) all construct a constant BEV refer to Appendix A for more details). First, daily
throughout the life of an option of a given strike options and underlying prices are recorded differ-
price and time to maturity. This calculation requires ently across the two databases. OptionMetrics uses
perfect foresight of the path of the option and is option prices at 3:59 p.m. Eastern Time and stock
not feasible in real-time. Additionally, the resulting settlement prices at market close at 4 p.m., whereas
BEV surfaces often admit arbitrage. Our approach SpiderRock uses the same option price at 3:59 p.m.

Volume 79, Number 1 101


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

but also uses stock prices at 3:59 p.m. Second, we start our computation when the call has five days
SpiderRock data imposes put-call parity whereas until expiration, which is taken to be T in the above
OptionMetrics maintain separate volatility surfaces expressions. The call value at time T is taken to be
for puts and calls. Even if OptionMetrics were to the market value. For the previous day, at time T 
synchronize the option and stock quotes, one may 1, we compute the fair value of the call option that
still prefer using forward prices derived from put-call sets the profit and loss of the delta-hedged position
parity in implied volatility calculation.3 For these rea- on that day to be zero. We then solve for the fair
sons, we choose to use SpiderRock data. These data value of the call option until we reach a time to
are used for the computation and prediction of expiration of 74 trading days, so we can build a term
breakeven volatility values in an attempt to use real- structure of breakeven volatility for a variety of time
time market data that traders rely on to create trad- to expiration ranging from 5 to 74 days.5 We com-
ing signals. pute the breakeven volatility for call and put options
available from SpiderRock that have 5–74 days until
Variables used to predict breakeven volatility are expiration, including every option with a non-zero
obtained from SpiderRock and Bloomberg. In particu- bid price.6
lar, the strike price, days until expiration, implied
volatility, and other information related to the under- We transform the fair values into volatility space
lying are from SpiderRock. The CBOE Volatility Index using the Black and Scholes (1973) model. A trans-
(VIX), the CBOE VIX Volatility Index, and variables formation of prices into volatilities aids a compari-
used to construct a realized volatility forecast of the son between breakeven volatility and implied
S&P 500 are from Bloomberg. Our sample is from volatility. Volatilities are also more well-behaved
January 2013 to November 2020. compared to dollar amounts, which facilitates build-
ing a predictive model. Because the Black-Scholes
Calculation of Breakeven Volatility. The equation is only used to transform option prices
breakeven volatility is the value that sets the profit into a more convenient space, much like an affine
and loss from a delta-hedged option position to be transformation or taking logarithms, this transform-
zero. Suppose we want to calculate the breakeven ation does not require that the Black and Scholes
volatility for a call option. The delta-hedged profit (1973) model is the correct pricing model
and loss are given as follows:4 (Shimko 1993).
X
T
To delta-hedge the call options, we take the deltas
PnLt ðrÞ ¼ cT  ct  Ds1 ðSs  Ss1 Þ (1)
from SpiderRock, calculated using the Cox-Ross-
s¼1
Rubinstein (CRR, Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein 1979)
where cT is the payoff of the call option at maturity, binomial tree model.7 We compute the fair value of
ct is the call price at the time of initiating the the option until five trading days before maturity.
position, Ds is the option delta at time s, and Ss is We do not hold the option until expiration due to
the price of the underlying asset at time s: The two reasons. First, due to the high gamma exposure
profit and loss of the delta-hedged option in the few days immediately before expiration,
depend on the volatility of the underlying. By volatility calculations can be quite noisy, and the
changing the volatility, we can trace out PnLt ðrÞ as associated volatility curves are not smooth func-
a function of volatility. The breakeven volatility is tions of strike prices.8 Second, option traders often
the value that sets PnLt ðrÞ to zero. We can also do not roll over their positions on the expiration,
compute breakeven volatility in a similar manner but rather a several days before expiration. Our
using put options. range of 5–74 trading days until maturity covers
the typical time to expiration options traders
To operationalize the above expression, we compute
engage in.9
the breakeven volatility as follows:
PnLT1 ðrT1 Þ ¼ cT  cT1 ðrT1 Þ  DT1 ðST  ST1 Þ Figure 1 provides a time series plot of the number of
options we use to calculate breakeven volatility. On
average, we have 278 strikes each day. This value is

somewhat biased upwards, by the extreme days with
PnLt ðrt Þ ¼ ctþ1  ct ðrt Þ  Dt ðStþ1  St Þ (2) more than 750 strikes; the median number of strikes
we use is 244. Although the equity index options
For day s, we solve for the breakeven volatility rs market is already quite liquid at the beginning of our
such that PnLs is set equal to zero. For a call option, sample in 2013, the number of strikes steadily

102
Option Pricing via Breakeven Volatility

Figure 1. Number of Options Used to Calculate Breakeven Volatility

Table 1. Summary Statistics


S&P 500
Variable Mean SD 10th 25th Median 75th 90th

BEV 25.4% 16.2% 9.5% 14.1% 22.1% 32.2% 45.0%


IV 27.2% 15.6% 10.9% 15.4% 24.1% 34.8% 46.5%
BEV-IV 1.8% 9.8% 7.2% 4.2% 2.3% 0.3% 3.0%

This table presents summary statistics for breakeven volatility and implied volatility of the S&P 500 Index. 10th, 25th, 75th, and
90th represent the quantile values. Our sample is from January 2013 to November 2020.

increased towards the later part of our sample. In those for implied volatility. In our sample
total, we compute breakeven volatility for period, the implied volatility of options on the
396,899 options. S&P 500 index average 27.2%, with a median value
of 24.1%. The standard deviation of implied volatil-
Panel A of Table 1 presents the summary statistics ity, 15.6%, is somewhat lower compared to break-
for breakeven volatility. From January 2013 to even volatility. The percentiles of implied volatility
November 2020, the average value of all the com- are also similar compared to those of breakeven
puted breakeven volatilities is 25.4%, and the volatility. We also present the difference between
median is 22.1%. We observe a broad range of val- BEV and IV to understand their joint distribution.
ues—the 10th percentile of the empirical distribu- On average, BEV is lower than IV by 1.8%. Their
tion is just 9.5%, whereas the 90th percentile is difference has a standard deviation of 9.8%. BEVs
45.0%. The standard deviation of breakeven volatil- are generally lower than IVs, as indicated by the
ities is 16.2%. The distributional statistics for negative percentile values up to the 75th, which
breakeven volatility are similar, but not identical to, reflects that in our sample, many options appear to

Volume 79, Number 1 103


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Figure 2. Volatility Smirks of BEV and IV hedging make the exercise difficult.” Greatly
improved computing power in the past 20 years, as
well as more comprehensive option datasets, over-
come much of Zou and Derman’s (1999) concerns.
Mitoulis (2019) carries out breakeven volatility calcu-
lations using simulations but stops short of a more
complete empirical analysis. Having constructed BEV
values for a large set of S&P 500 options, we com-
pare the behavior of breakeven volatility and
implied volatility.

Figure 2 compares volatility smirks using breakeven


and implied volatilities. We average across all dates
and maturities to trace out the unconditional distri-
butions for these volatility measures. We plot the
volatility curves as a function of the normalized
strike, the ratio of the log moneyness of the option
divided by its scaled volatility.10 Defined this way,
This figure shows the volatility smirks constructed from break-
the normalized strike provides a better measure to
even volatility and implied volatility for the S&P 500 Index,
averaged across the full sample period and smoothed. The sam- compare options that have very different volatility
ple period is from January 2013 to November 2020. levels or time to expiration. There is a limited number
of listed call options with high strike prices, which
causes the volatility calculations to be truncated on
the right side, whereas the left side extends much
be trading at a premium relative to their further. This asymmetry around the number of strikes
fair values. around the at-the-money value is commonly found in
the literature (e.g., Figlewski and Malik 2014). Since
Existing papers focusing on isolating a variance risk
the 1987 stock market crash, equity index options
premium (VRP) often do so in the form of excess
have shown a persistent skew to OTM puts. The
returns of delta-hedged positions (Bakshi, Cao, and most common explanation for this pattern is that
Chen 1997; Goyenko and Zhang 2020; Bali et al. market participants want to protect against the possi-
2021). A delta-hedged short position that earns an bility of a large market crash, but they do not neces-
average positive return indicates implied volatility is sarily purchase deep OTM calls in anticipation of a
on average higher than subsequent realized volatility. large upward move. This sort of market participant
By setting the delta-hedged profit and loss to zero, preference can explain why we observe many more
the breakeven volatility is a measure that sets the strike values below the current price of
VRP to zero for each individual option. In this way, the underlying.
BEV calculations are more flexible than a single esti-
mate of realized volatility, since we retain the flexibil- In the vicinity of the at-the-money region, breakeven
ity of having different volatility values for options volatility and implied volatility are largely similar.
with the same maturity but different strike prices. When we get farther away from ATM strike prices,
Therefore, breakeven volatilities provide richer infor- the two volatility measures diverge. In the regions
mation set on the realized distribution. where the strike price exceeds the underlying price—
the normalized strike is negative—implied volatility is
Volatility Smirks. The idea of constructing repli- higher than breakeven volatility, indicating that delta-
cating portfolios using historical data has been dis- hedged short positions in puts or calls with these
cussed in the literature, but implementation has been strikes tend to have positive profits on average.
limited. Zou and Derman (1999) note that theoretic- Similarly, in the regions where the strike price is
ally, the appropriate implied volatility for a given lower than the underlying price, the breakeven vola-
option is determined by the cost of replicating that tility is also lower than the implied volatility. The
option throughout its lifetime. However, the authors implications for the profitability of delta-hedged posi-
do not pursue this idea because “such replication can tions from Figure 2 are consistent with documented
be time-consuming, and the hedging errors due to empirical facts in the literature. Coval and Shumway
inaccurate volatility forecasting and infrequency of (2001) and Bakshi and Kapadia (2003) find that short

104
Option Pricing via Breakeven Volatility

delta-hedged positions are profitable for out-of-the- 5. lsk is a measure of the moneyness of the
money puts. option calculated as the natural log of the
price of the underlying over the strike price.
This variable is motivated by the empirical
A Data-Driven Valuation Process finding that volatility is not constant across
In the previous section, we used historical data to moneyness (Zou and Derman 1999), and it
build a database of nearly 400,000 breakeven volatil- allows the breakeven volatility to vary as a
ities for options of different moneyness and time to function of moneyness.
expiration. While this exercise presents us with the 6. ATM.IV is the implied volatility of the option
fair values of options, the breakeven volatility calcu- closest to at-the-money, calculated using the
lation uses future information, so it cannot be com- Black and Scholes (1973) model.
puted in real-time. Suppose an investor wants to 7. ImpliedVol is the market implied volatility of
know what an option with a time to expiration of the option calculated using the Black and
70 days should be worth. She cannot calculate the Scholes (1973) model.
breakeven volatility for this option without knowing 8. RR is the difference between the delta of the
its future price path. To compute the fair value of an option and the ATM delta. This variable pro-
option in real-time, we require a model that estab- vides another way to capture higher volatilities
lishes a link between the current observable charac- in the wings compared to ATM options.
teristics of an option to its breakeven volatility. To 9. vega is the sensitivity of the option price
this end, we build a predictive model for breakeven with respect to volatility. We use the ffi Black-
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
volatility using a variety of input variables. The map-
Scholes vega, equal to St N0 ðd1 Þ T  t, where
ping from input variables to the breakeven volatility
St is the price of the underlying, N0 ðÞ is the
probability density function of standard nor-
learned by our model constitutes an option pric-
mal distribution, d1 comes from the Black-
ing model.
Scholes formula,11 and T  t is the time
Volatility Predictors. We consider the to expiration.
following set of predictors for breakeven volatility. 10. gamma is the rate of change in the delta
Whereas some predictors are motivated by with respect to changes in the underlying
financial theory, others are included for their likely price, or the second derivative of the option
potential to contain strong predictive power. Since price with respect to the price of the underly-
our primary goal is to make a robust prediction for
ing. We calculate the Black-Scholes gamma,
N0p
ð d1 Þ
ffiffiffiffiffiffi , where r is the volatility of
breakeven volatility, we are not restricted to only St r Tt
the underlying.
using variables that have a strong economic motiv-
11. vrt is defined as the VIX multiplied by the
ation. All variables are calculated at the
square root of time to p expiration.
ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi This variable is
daily frequency.
a construction of r T  t from the Black-
Scholes model. Breaking up the Black-Scholes
1. VIX captures the market’s expectation for the
model into its constituent parts allows for add-
implied volatility of the S&P 500 Index over the
itional flexibility in predicting breakeven volatility.
next 30 days. It is commonly used by investors
12. vvt2 is defined as the VIX squared multiplied
to gauge market sentiment. We use the log of by the time to expiration. This variable is
the CBOE Volatility Index at the market close. another piece in the Black-Scholes
2. VVIX is a volatility of volatility measure that model, r2 ðT  tÞ:
2

captures the expected volatility of the 30-day


forward price of the VIX. We use the closing
value of the CBOE VVIX Index. We also include some transformations of the
3. rv is a GARCH forecast of the volatility of the S&P above variables. lsk2 is the squared value of lsk,
500 returns over the same horizon as the time to motivated by the empirical observation that volatil-
expiration of the option, including an adjustment ity measures are a convex function of moneyness.
for the overnight component of volatility. ImpliedVol2 is equal to ImpliedVol squared. RR2 and
4. rt provides a measure for the time to expir- RR3 are the squared and cubed values of RR, moti-
ation. It is calculated as the square root of the vated by interpolation methods used in the litera-
number of trading days to expiration divided ture to build volatility curves that try to capture the
by 252. curvature in the volatility surface through a cubic

Volume 79, Number 1 105


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 2. Summary Statistics of Predictors


Variable Mean SD 10th 25th Median 75th 90th

VVIX 97.67 18.31 79.53 85.83 93.97 106.01 118.94


VIX 18.08 8.93 11.53 12.85 15.00 20.10 27.96
rt 0.39 0.10 0.24 0.32 0.40 0.47 0.52
lsk 0.15 0.21 0.07 0.00 0.12 0.26 0.40
lsk2 (10) 0.68 1.73 0.00 0.03 0.17 0.70 1.63
ATM.IV 16% 8% 10% 12% 14% 18% 25%
ImpliedVol 27% 16% 11% 15% 24% 35% 46%
ImpliedVol2 10% 14% 1% 2% 6% 12% 22%
RR 0.21 0.35 0.45 0.01 0.40 0.47 0.49
RR2 0.17 0.08 0.02 0.11 0.20 0.23 0.24
RR3 0.04 0.07 0.09 0.00 0.07 0.11 0.11
vega 1.50 1.55 0.09 0.25 0.88 2.40 3.88
vega2 4.63 7.87 0.01 0.06 0.78 5.77 15.08
gamma (x100) 1.14 1.72 0.10 0.17 0.39 1.28 3.43
vrt (x10) 0.63 0.34 0.29 0.41 0.57 0.75 1.01
vvt2 (x100) 0.25 0.36 0.04 0.08 0.16 0.28 0.51
rv 0.24 0.18 0.14 0.16 0.19 0.27 0.39

This table presents summary statistics for the different variables used to predict breakeven volatility. The sample period is from
January 2013 to November 2020.

spline (Malz 2014; Neuberger 2012). vega2 is we take the residual of the regression, VIX.res, as
vega squared. the new predictor in place of VIX. We repeat the
same process for rv to obtain rv.res. By construc-
Table 2 shows the summary statistics for the pre- tion, VIX.res and rv.res are uncorrelated with
dictor variables, and Table 3 provides the pairwise ATM.IV. Additionally, they are also only 0.33 corre-
correlations. This table highlights the diversity of lated with each other. We do not orthogonalize
our predictors; most variables are weakly correlated ImpliedVol or ImpliedVol2, since these have greater
with others. For example, the realized volatility fore- variation depending on the moneyness of the
cast rv is basically uncorrelated with the time to option and tend to bring significantly different
expiration rt or the moneyness measures lsk and information compared to the previous three volatil-
lsk2, but it is positively correlated to volatility varia- ity variables.
bles, such as the at-the-money implied volatility,
VIX, VVIX, as well as vrt and vvt2. Variable transfor- ATM.IV, VIX.res, and rv.res are all included as predic-
mations are often highly correlated with the original tors in our model. Presumably, the idiosyncratic com-
variables: lsk and lsk2 have a correlation of 0.77, ponent of each volatility measure contributes to
ImpliedVol and ImpliedVol2 have a correlation of predicting breakeven volatility, rather than just the
0.93, and vega and vega2 have a correlation of common component. If only the common component
0.94. Some variable pairs show large negative corre- of the volatility measures mattered for prediction, it
lations. Gamma has a 0.79 correlation with RR, would not be necessary to retain all three volatility
whereas RR2 has correlations of 0.90 and 0.79 measures—some form of average would suffice. For
with vega and vega2. example, we could construct a derived predictor as
the largest principal component (Hull and Qiao
We include several volatility measures as predic- 2017). Because the three volatility measures capture
tors, including VIX, ATM.IV, and rv. As one would different information related to breakeven volatility,
expect, these variables are highly correlated with we choose to include all three in the predic-
one another. To limit multicollinearity, we reduce tion model.
the correlations among these predictors through
orthogonalization, via a Gram-Schmidt process The first row of Table 3 contains correlations among
(Cheney and Kincaid 2009). We run an ordinary the predictor variables and breakeven volatility, our
least squares regression of VIX on ATM.IV, then prediction target. Correlation is one measure of how

106
Option Pricing via Breakeven Volatility

Table 3. Correlation Matrix of Predictors

This table presents the pairwise correlations for the predictor variables and breakeven volatility. Positive correlations are shown in
shades of red, whereas negative correlations are shown in shades of blue. The shade of the cell indicates the strength of the cor-
relation. The sample period is from January 2013 to November 2020.

well each variable would do in univariate predictive prediction target is BEVi, K, t, T for option i with
regressions. Almost all the predictors exhibit consid- strike price K and time to expiration T  t: Because
erable correlations with our prediction target, the BEV calculation requires knowledge of the path
although the relationship can be positive or negative. of the option and the underlying, it is only known on
VVIX, lsk, RR, and vrt all have a positive relationship the expiration date T: We use predictor variables at
with breakeven volatility; vega, vega2, and gamma time t, Xi, m, t , to form a conditional expectation of
have a negative relationship with BEV. Suggestive the actual BEV value at time T: To simplify notation,
economic interpretations of a positive or negative we will denote the target and predictor variables as
correlation with BEV can be found in our description BEVi and Xi, m with the understanding that they are
of the predictor variables. known at different times.

The raw BEV values are truncated at zero and show


Statistical Model. Our goal is to make good pre- significant right skew. In the first stage, we transform
dictions of breakeven volatility. To the extent linear the dependent variable, BEV, into its logarithms. By
models can offer good predictions for the target vari- working in the log space of BEV, we obtain a distri-
able, they are preferred over more complex models bution well-approximated by a normal distribution,
given their simplicity and interpretability. Our and the predicted breakeven volatility value will be

Volume 79, Number 1 107


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

guaranteed to be positive. Our first-stage regression Empirically, the residuals from the first-stage
models logged BEV as a linear function of the pre- regression are not normally distributed. If we were
dictor variables: to apply Equation (4), the resultant breakeven
volatility values differ significantly from the actual
X
M
logðBEVi Þ ¼ b0 þ Xi, m bm þ ei (3) values. Equation (5) provides a better adjustment
m¼1 factor, but the resulting BEV values still make
poor predictions for the actual values. To
where BEVi is the breakeven volatility linked to a par-
overcome this retransformation issue, we use
ticular set of parameters including time to expiration a more general, supervised approach to
and moneyness, Xi, m are the M predictors associated estimate the adjustment factor in a second-stage
with BEVi , and ei is the prediction error. regression:13
For a given set of predictor variables, Equation (3) d
BEVi ¼ ceE½logðBEVi Þ þ ei (6)
provides unbiased estimates for the expectation of
logged BEV, E½logðBEVÞ: However, our goal is to find where logðd BEVi Þ are the predicted values from the
the best prediction for the expectation of BEV, first-stage regression in Equation (3). Equation (6)
E½BEV: The approach to retransform a predicted is estimated without an intercept, adhering to the
quantity back to its original scale is known as a constant multiple relationships derived in Duan
“smearing adjustment” in statistics (Duan 1983; (1983), and c is an estimate of the multiplicative fac-
Taylor 1986). We cannot simply exponentiate our tor that wedges between E½BEV and eE½logðBEVÞ : The
prediction from Equation (3), because eE½logðBEVÞ  final prediction of the breakeven volatility comes
E½BEV by Jensen’s inequality.12 This point has been from the predicted component of Equation (6),
d
emphasized by Duan (1983), who asserts that ^c eE½logðBEVi Þ : Combining the two stages, the following
unbiased and consistent predictions on a transformed expression links the predictor variables with the final
scale (using a monotonic function) do not transform prediction of BEV:
into unbiased or consistent quantities on the untrans- P
M
bb0 þ Xi, m bbm
formed scale.
E½BEVi  ¼ ^c e m¼1 (7)
If the residuals from Equation (3) were normally
distributed, there is a closed-form transformation The in-sample results of the first-stage regression are
of the prediction of Equation (3), E½logðBEVÞ, into shown in Table 4. The predictors are all statistically
E½BEV : significant at the 1% level, indicating strong
predictive power of these variables for logged
E½BEV ¼ eE½logðBEVÞ e2g
1 2
(4) values of breakeven volatility. Taken together, the
predictor variables can explain 53% of the variation
where g is the standard deviation of the residuals
in BEV. The adjusted R-squared is nearly identical to
ei of Equation (3). For residuals that are approxi-
the unadjusted R-squared because we have many
mately normally distributed, the above expression
observations compared to the number of
provides a fairly precise adjustment from the regressors.14
logged values to the original values (Duan 1983).
However, the adjustment does not work well if the In-sample R-squared can overstate the predictive
residuals were not normally distributed. In the case power of our model. To more accurately assess how
of non-normal residuals, Duan (1983) proposes the well our model can predict breakeven volatility, we
following: use a 10-fold cross-validation approach to calculate
the coefficient of determination. We partition our
1X N
E½BEV ¼ eE½logðBEVÞ eej (5) data into 10 subsamples of roughly equal size. For
N j¼1 each subsample, we fit our statistical model on the
remaining 90% of data and use the fitted model to
where N is the number of data points used to esti- make predictions on the subsample. We repeat this
mate Equation (3), and ej s are the residuals. Duan procedure to obtain 10 validation R-squareds and
(1983) posits that like Equation (4), our desired quan- take their average to be the cross-validated R-
tity E½BEV and the exponentiated prediction from squared. The cross-validated R-squared is very close
Equation (3) eE½logðBEVÞ differ by a constant multiple. to the full-sample R-squared, indicating that our pre-
Whereas normal theory implies a multiplicative factor diction model performs with a high degree of stability
P
of e2g , Duan’s is N1 Nj¼1 eej :
1 2
on this dataset. Indeed, the 10 validation R-squareds

108
Option Pricing via Breakeven Volatility

Table 4. Predicting Logged Table 5. Smearing Adjustment of Breakeven


Breakeven Volatility Volatility Prediction
Estimate SE t-Stat Estimate SE t-Stat

(Intercept) 1.85 0.02 116.7 FirstStagePrediction 1.03 0.001 1310


VVIX 0.187 0.009 20.6 R squared 0.90
VIX.res 0.002 0.001 2.6 Adj. R squared 0.90
rt 0.59 0.03 19.7 10-Fold CV R-squared 0.66
lsk 0.69 0.02 30.0 Number of observations 396,899
lsk2 0.11 0.01 7.6
ATM.IV 1.71 0.06 28.1 This table shows the second stage of the predictive model for
ImpliedVol (coef  10) 2.08 0.04 52.7 breakeven volatility. We regress breakeven volatility values on
ImpliedVol2 0.01 0.00 44.8 the predictions from the first stage.
RR 0.15 0.01 15.5 d
RR2 0.90 0.03 26.8 BEVi ¼ ceE½logðBEVi Þ þ ei
RR3 1.29 0.06 22.3 where BEVi is the breakeven volatility and logðdBEVi Þ is the pre-
vega 2.05 0.37 5.5 dicted value from the first-stage regression. c is an estimate of
vega2 0.54 0.04 12.3 the smearing adjustment. Standard errors and t-statistics are
adjusted for heteroskedasticity.
gamma 67.53 1.44 46.8
vrt 4.33 0.20 21.7
vvt2 33.74 0.85 39.5 penalization parameter we select using 10-fold
rv.res 0.43 0.01 34.1
cross-validation. We find that the optimal
R-squared 0.53
penalization parameter is zero, indicating that the
Adjusted R-squared 0.53
10-Fold CV R-squared 0.53 optimally-selected ridge model is equivalent to
Number of observations 396,899 ordinary least squares. We further explore a range
of possible values for the penalization parameter,
This table shows the first stage of the predictive model for and we confirm that the model with the lowest
breakeven volatility. We use linear regression to predict the mean squared error is the one with the penalization
logged values of breakeven volatility.
parameter set to zero. These results suggest that
X
M multicollinearity does not pose a major issue for
logðBEVi Þ ¼ b0 þ Xi, m bm þ ei our model.15
m¼1
where BEVi is the breakeven volatility linked to a particular set Table 5 presents the smearing adjustment according
of parameters including time to expiration and moneyness, Xi, m to Equation (6). As implied by the equation, this
are the M predictors associated with BEVi , bm are regression
coefficients. The coefficients associated with VVIX, ATM.IV, second-stage regression does not include an inter-
ImpliedVol, ImpliedVol2, vega, vega2, and rv.res are multiplied cept term. The smearing adjustment indicates
E½BEV ¼ 1:03 eE½logðBEVÞ , consistent with the impli-
by 100 for ease of exposition. Standard errors and t-statistics
adjusted for heteroskedasticity are shown.
cations of Jensen’s Inequality eE½logðBEVÞ  E½BEV:
This adjustment procedure shows a close
show a narrow range between 0.51 to 0.56, with a
relationship between the predicted log breakeven
standard deviation of just 0.012. The regression coef- volatility values and actual BEV—the full-sample R-
ficients show a high level of stability across valid- squared is 0.90, and so is the adjusted R-squared.
ation folds. The 10-fold cross-validated R-squared is somewhat
If high correlations among the predictors lead to lower but still suggests that the majority of the
multicollinearity issues, the statistical integrity of variation in breakeven volatility is captured by
our model.
the model may be compromised. While ordinary
least squares estimates remain unbiased, their Our approach attempts to estimate breakeven volatil-
variances can be large. Ridge regression helps to ities as a fixed function of certain characteristics of
resolve multicollinearity by allowing for better options, such as the current level of the underlying
convergence of the variance-covariance matrix and moneyness. If our model captures the data well,
and introducing a small degree of bias to produce its functional form should be relatively stable over
more reliable estimates. We check the robustness time, although the actual breakeven volatility predic-
of our prediction using ridge regression, whose tions can change over time or across strike prices if

Volume 79, Number 1 109


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

the characteristics on which the prediction is based a measure of the fair value of an option.
on change. However, the relationship between the predictor
variables and BEV is learned from a large database
Our predictive model takes a data-driven approach of historical BEV values and predictors, which
to quantifying the value of an option, which stands allows for more flexibility compared to the exam-
in contrast to commonly used structural approaches ples above.
to option pricing. Existing approaches typically spe-
cify key parameters necessary for calculating Researchers have explored non-parametric option
options prices—volatility, time to expiration, volatil- pricing models in the past. Hutchinson, Lo, and
ity of volatility, etc., then use these parameters to Poggio (1994) use neural networks to approximate
derive the value of an option. In comparison, a data- the Black-Scholes formula, but the paper does not
driven approach learns the relationship between the consider a non-parametric estimation of the relation-
variables that are important for option valuation, ship between option characteristics and option pri-
rather than specifying the model parameters ces. Ait-Sahalia and Lo (1998) propose a kernel
in advance. regression estimator of the risk-neutral distribution
conditional on option characteristics, such as the
Any pricing model must provide a link between a price of the underlying, strike price, and time to
set of input variables and output variables, typically expiration. In the same spirit, we also try to capture
taken to be the option prices or volatilities. For the relationship between predictor variables and
example, the Black-Scholes model provides a map- option values in a data-driven manner. Our approach
ping between the model parameters (the price of is different in that our target is breakeven volatility,
the underlying, volatility of the underlying, time to which serves as an estimate for the fair value of
expiration, strike price, and interest rate) and the an option.
dollar value of an option. The Heston (1993) model
stipulates a different mapping for a set of model Model Diagnostics. Although economic intu-
parameters and the price of an option. Our ition may guide us in thinking about the univariate
approach also establishes a link between the relationships among predictors and breakeven
predictor variables and the breakeven volatility, volatility, it is much more difficult to determine

Figure 3. Probability Densities of Actual and Predicted Values

The figures below show density plots of the first and second-stage regressions. In each plot, kernel densities of the prediction target
and their predicted values are shown. In the first-stage regression, the prediction target is logged breakeven volatilities. In the
second stage, the target is the level of breakeven volatility.

110
Option Pricing via Breakeven Volatility

the signs of these relationships in a multivariate prices, K1 and K2 : To prevent risk-free profits,
setting. Rather than focus on the contribution of we need the following condition to hold:
individual predictors, we conduct model diagnostics p2  p1 for K2 > K1 (8)
to identify the strengths and weaknesses of our
predictive model. We investigate the statistical val-
If the above condition were violated, risk-free profit
idity of the model, as well as the economic implica-
would be available. If p2  p1 , a portfolio that com-
tions of the volatility predictions. To start, we
bines a long position in p2 and short position in p1 is
inspect the differences between the prediction tar-
costless to initiate, and will offer a non-negative pay-
get and the predicted values. In Figure 3, we plot
off in all possible states of the world. The no-arbi-
the kernel densities of the prediction target and the
trage condition for put spreads compels put prices to
predicted values in the same figure. A comparison
be an increasing function of the strike price, an intui-
of the two densities can reveal where our model is
tive condition that keeps the volatility curve
doing well and where it is failing. In the first-stage
well-behaved.
regression, the prediction target is the logarithm of
breakeven volatilities. The predictions match the For put prices to be a convex function of the strike
target values reasonably well in the middle part of price, the no-arbitrage condition for butterfly
the distribution but deviate from the target in the spreads must be satisfied. A butterfly spread uses
tails. In both the left and right tails, there are too three contracts: Buy a put at the lowest strike, buy
few predicted values compared to the target distri- a put at the highest strike, and write two puts at an
bution, and there are too many predicted values intermediate strike. These positions form a portfolio
hovering in the center of the distribution. The mod- that earns the maximum payoff if the underlying
el’s predictive power appears to be the strongest does not move—a short volatility position. The no-
when the breakeven volatility is between 5 arbitrage condition for butterfly spreads is the fol-
and 50%. lowing:
In the second-stage regression, the left-hand vari- K3 K2 K2 K1
p2  p1 þ p3 (9)
able is breakeven volatility and the right-hand vari- K3  K1 K3  K1
able is a transformation of logged BEV values. Like for
the first-stage regression results, the centers of the
two distributions mostly overlap, although it is clear K3 > K2 > K1
that the predicted values are more concentrated in
the middle of its distribution than the tails. The In the above expressions, K1 , K2 , and K3 are strike
model predictions have the greatest difficulty with prices of increasing value. p1 , p2 , and p3 are the put
the left tail; there are too few predicted values com- prices associated with the respective strikes. This
pared to the actual breakeven volatility values, condition states that the put price associated with
especially if BEV is <5%. The predicted distribution the intermediate strike, p2 , must be less than a
and the actual distribution of breakeven volatilities weighted average of the put prices associated with
are more closely matched in their right tails, albeit the highest and lowest strikes.16 The absence of arbi-
we still observe too few predictions compared to trage from butterfly spreads implies that put prices
the target density. must be a convex function of the strike price, such
that the shape of the volatility curve matches its
We verify that the predicted volatilities do not well-known empirical profile (Bollen and
violate arbitrage conditions. Orosi (2015) derives Whaley 2004).
static no-arbitrage conditions for call options:
Prices must be a decreasing and convex function For each unique combination of date and time to
of the strike price. We check the parallel expiration, options with different strike prices
conditions for puts: Prices are an increasing and trace out a volatility curve. We examine the pre-
convex function of the strike price. These dicted BEV values using the above conditions, and
conditions can be verified by checking whether we find that none of the volatility curves
put prices violate arbitrage conditions implied by admit arbitrage.
putting spreads and butterfly spreads. A put
spread combined buying and writing put options
with the same expiration but different strike prices. Volatility Arbitrage
Suppose we have two put options p1 and p2 , with In the previous section, we built a predictive model
the same expiration date but different strike for breakeven volatility, the fair value of an option

Volume 79, Number 1 111


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

that does not admit any risk premia. Implied volatility arbitrage in the strict sense, but rather refers to
from market prices includes the risk attitudes of mar- whether the investor can make a sufficiently
ket participants and therefore embeds risk premia. accurate forecast for future realized volatility to
To the extent our predictive model can make accur- lock in a trading profit. To illustrate the
ate forecasts of breakeven volatility, we can poten- economic value of our predictive model, we
tially convert the difference between implied and construct a trading strategy that exploits the
breakeven volatility into trading profits. In this way, difference between our predicted breakeven
the economic value of our model can be understood volatility values and implied volatility from mar-
through a simulated trading strategy. The purpose of ket prices.
this section is to evaluate whether the difference
between implied volatility and predicted breakeven We keep the trading strategy simple because we
volatility can generate profitable trading want to test the accuracy of our statistical predic-
opportunities. tions. If we were to proceed with a more complex
trading strategy—for example, adding in a layer of
Simulated option trading strategies have often been portfolio optimization—it becomes more difficult to
used in the literature to determine the difference evaluate the accuracy of our breakeven volatility
between implied and realized volatility. Coval and forecasts. In a strategy that combines BEV forecasts
Shumway (2001) and Bakshi and Kapadia (2003) with sophisticated portfolio optimization, we would
find large returns to delta-hedged options and inter- be testing the transformation of our trading signals
pret this result as a volatility risk premium. Bollen into portfolio positions as well as the accuracy of the
and Whaley (2004) attempt to match the profits of BEV forecasts, resulting in a “joint hypothesis prob-
delta-hedged positions with net buying pressure in a lem.” By keeping the simulated trading strategy sim-
demand-based asset pricing framework. Zou and ple, we can test the accuracy of the BEV forecasts
Derman (1999) ask, “How is an investor to know with limited confounding factors. Therefore, our
which strike and expiration provide the best empirical choices in the simulated trading strategy
value? What metric can option investors use to closely mirror those we made in the construction of
gauge their estimated excess return?” Existing our predictive model.
approaches to option strategies do not offer
answers to these questions, as they are not able to We use an initial training period from January
determine which options offer relatively more 2013 to December 2014 to fit our model. We fix
attractive investment opportunities or what the model parameters and make predictions for
expected returns we should expect from delta- breakeven volatilities throughout 2015, and we
hedged positions. refit the model at the end of 2015 using all the
data from 2013 through 2015. We then make new
Our non-parametric option pricing model based on predictions using the updated model parameters.
the prediction of breakeven volatility readily Each subsequent year, the model is refit using an
answers the above questions. The investor can expanding window. These predictions only use the
make breakeven volatility predictions for several information available at the time of the forecast, so
options and compare her predictions against implied they can be made in real-time. The final set of pre-
volatilities. If the predicted BEV and IV for an option dictions goes from January 2015 to
are different, the investor may initiate a position November 2020.
with positive expected returns. If implied volatility
were lower than the predicted breakeven volatility, In the modeling section, we showed that our statis-
the market price of the option is too low, and the tical model achieves high in-sample R-squared.
investor can “buy cheap” by taking a long delta- However, good in-sample performance does not
hedged position. Conversely, if implied volatility always imply generalizable results. This point is
were higher than the predicted breakeven volatility, emphasized in return predictability studies where
the market price of the option is too high, and the the goal is to produce the best predictions of future
investor can “sell dear” by taking a short delta- market returns (e.g., Welch and Goyal 2008;
hedged position. Campbell and Thompson 2008). Our expanding win-
dow predictions constitute out-of-sample (OOS)
Simulated Trading Strategy. Trading the forecasts of breakeven volatility, and we evaluate
difference between a volatility prediction and the out-of-sample predictive performance of our
implied volatility is commonly called “volatility model compared to the historical mean. We assess
arbitrage” (Ammann and Herriger 2002). It is not the volatility forecasts using the mean squared

112
Option Pricing via Breakeven Volatility

forecast error (MSFE), calculated for our prediction lower than the mid-price, we sell one contract. If the
and the historical mean: breakeven price were higher than the mid-price, we
purchase one contract. All trades are delta-hedged
^e 0, i ¼ BEVi  BEV i (10)
and held until five days to expiration, at which time
di
^e 1, i ¼ BEVi  BEV (11) the positions are closed out. Portfolio returns are cal-
d i is
where BEVi is the actual breakeven volatility, BEV culated by summing up the daily profit and loss and
dividing by the aggregate notional value of the
the predicted value of breakeven volatility, and BEV i
contracts.18
is the historical mean estimated using the same infor-
d i : The mean squared forecast error
mation set as BEV
is calculated as the sum of squared forecast errors
across the full set of N forecasts:
Results
In the simulated trading strategy, the predictive
XN
dk¼1
MSFE ^e 2 , k ¼ 0, 1 (12)
model makes out-of-sample forecasts of breakeven
N i¼1 k, i volatility. We first assess these OOS forecasts before
evaluating the trading strategy. The OOS forecasts
provide a valuable perspective for understanding the
Based on the Clark and West (2007) procedure,
validity of our predictive model. The out-of-sample
Dong et al. (2022) develop a test for a difference in
R-squared is 0.71, indicating that our predictive
the population of the MSFEs:
model for breakeven volatility significantly outper-
H0 : MSFE0  MSFE1 , H1 : MSFE0 > MSFE1 (13) forms the historical average estimate—the mean
squared forecast error is 71% smaller for our fore-
Campbell and Thompson (2008) propose an alterna- casting model compared to the historical mean.
tive method to evaluate competing forecasts via an
out-of-sample R-squared statistic: Table 6 presents a confusion matrix of the implied
trading strategy from the breakeven volatility fore-
d1
MSFE casts. The confusion matrix compares the number of
R2OS ¼ 1  (14)
d0
MSFE long and short investment decisions implied by the
model predictions with the decisions that an investor
Dong et al. (2022) show that the Clark and West would make if she could perfectly observe the actual
(2007) statistics to test Equation (13) is equivalent to BEV values. For example, suppose an option with
testing whether the out-of-sample R-squared of 30 days to expiration has an IV of 25% and BEV of
Campbell and Thompson (2008) is positive or nega- 28%. With 30 days to go, we would not observe the
true BEV value. Suppose our predicted BEV value is
tive. We follow Dong et al. (2022) to evaluate the
d i captures more 24%. In this case, we would take a short position in
predictive power of our model. If BEV
the option, whereas if we could observe the true
variation of actual breakeven volatility than the his-
BEV value, we would have taken a long position.
torical mean, the sum of squared errors in the
Since the options literature has documented a robust
numerator would be smaller than the denominator,
indicating our predictive model forecasts BEV better
than its historical average. In this case, the out-of-
sample R-squared R2OS would be positive, correspond- Table 6. Confusion Matrix of BEV
ing to the alternative hypothesis in Equation (13). If Predictions
d i captures less variation of BEVi than BEV i , the
BEV
out-of-sample R-squared would be negative, corre- Predicted
sponding to the null hypothesis in Equation (13). Short Long

Every OOS prediction of breakeven volatility allows Actual


for a comparison with implied volatility. Starting in Short 3002 1467
January 2015, each day, we scan through all available Long 0 2314
OTM options with time to expiration between five
This table shows the out-of-sample BEV predictions for those
and 74 days, and we identify those with a predicted observations that show favorable trades. Each year, we retrain
profit remaining >$1.17 Profit remaining is calculated our forecasting model for breakeven volatility using as much
as the difference between the breakeven dollar value historical data as possible, and we use this model to make pre-
dictions throughout the year. If the breakeven price were lower
and the midpoint between the bid and ask prices. than the mid-price, we sell one contract. If the breakeven price
For a particular option, if the breakeven price were were higher than the mid-price, we purchase one contract.

Volume 79, Number 1 113


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Table 7. Strategy Performance


A. Raw values
BEV Short Options Short Puts Short Calls Buy-and-Hold S&P

Average returns 6.8% 4.2% 3.1% 1.1% 10.4%


Volatility 4.5% 4.3% 3.0% 1.6% 13.0%
Sharpe ratio 1.50 0.99 1.04 0.68 0.79
Max drawdown 3.2% 5.1% 4.7% 2.1% 19.8%

B. Option strategies scaled to the same volatility as the S&P 500


BEV Short Options Short Puts Short Calls Buy-and-Hold S&P

Average returns 19.6% 12.9% 13.5% 8.9% 10.4%


Volatility 13.0% 13.0% 13.0% 13.0% 13.0%
Sharpe ratio 1.50 0.99 1.04 0.68 0.79
Max drawdown 9.3% 15.7% 20.3% 17.7% 19.8%

C. Including transaction costs


One Tick Two Ticks Three Ticks

Average returns 4.4% 3.2% 2.1%


Volatility 4.5% 4.5% 4.5%
Sharpe ratio 0.98 0.72 0.46
Max drawdown 4.9% 7.2% 11.5%

This table presents the performance statistics of our simulated trading strategy and several other investment strategies. “BEV” is a
strategy that uses breakeven volatility forecasts to select and invest in options. “Short Options” is a strategy that takes short posi-
tions in all available options. “Short Puts” and “Short Calls” only invest in puts or calls separately. Panel A shows the statistics for
the raw returns of the strategies. Panel B scales the options strategies to have the same volatility as that of the S&P 500. Panel C
includes transaction costs for the BEV strategy (each tick is five cents, see text for details).

variance risk premium (Carr and Wu 2009; Bollerslev, positions is 67% of the total actual number of short
Tauchen, and Zhou 2009), our trading strategy will positions an investor would take if she could per-
have a default bias towards short positions. In this fectly observe breakeven volatilities. F1 score, the
sense, the short positions are the “positive” class in harmonic mean of precision and recall, provides a
the confusion matrix, and the long positions are the holistic evaluation of the predictive power of the
“negative” class. model that balances false positives and false nega-
tives. The F1 score is 0.80 in our case. By looking at
Our out-of-sample predictions cover 6,783 observa- the predictions from our regression model through
tions that display an investing edge. Of these, 3,002 the lens of classification, we gain an additional per-
are true positives—the model short positions match spective on its performance.
the actual BEV implied short positions, and 2,314
are true negatives. Therefore, the accuracy of the We provide a summary of the performance of our
model, measured as the total correct predictions BEV-based trading strategy in Table 7. We include
divided by the total number of observations, is 78%. three additional options strategies for comparison: A
Precision measures the ratio of correctly predicted portfolio of delta-hedged short positions in all avail-
positive observations to the total predicted positive able options, a portfolio of delta-hedged short posi-
observations. This number comes out to be 100%— tions in all puts, and a portfolio of delta-hedged short
in this particular sample, every predicted short pos- positions in all calls. Finally, we include a buy-and-
ition with an expected profit remaining of more hold S&P 500 strategy. The BEV-based strategy
than $1 turned out to be correct. Recall, that the earns an annual return of 6.8% with a volatility of
ratio of correctly predicted positive observations to 4.5%, achieving the highest Sharpe ratio and the
all the actual positive observations, is 67%, indicat- highest ratio of expected to maximum drawdown
ing that the number of correctly predicted short among all the options strategies. A buy-and-hold

114
Option Pricing via Breakeven Volatility

strategy in the S&P 500 Index performed well in our return and Sharpe ratio, and increases the maximum
sample period, earning 10.4% per year with 13% drawdown. Unless the investor can limit her transac-
volatility. Its Sharpe ratio of 0.79 shows an attractive tion costs, a strategy based on breakeven volatility
risk-return tradeoff between 2015 and 2020, higher will not offer attractive risk-adjusted returns.
than its historic longer-term value.

Due to the differences in volatility, it is difficult to com- Conclusion


pare average returns and maximum drawdowns across
In this paper, we build a non-parametric option pric-
strategies. In Panel B of Table 7, we scale all the option
ing model whose output is the fair value of an option
strategies such that their annual volatilities are all equal
as measured by breakeven volatility, the value of
to that of the S&P 500. Putting all the strategies on
implied volatility that sets the profit and loss of a
the same scale makes clear the distinct investment
delta-hedged option to zero. We compute breakeven
opportunities available to investors. At annual volatility
volatilities for a large set of S&P 500 index options,
of 13%, the BEV strategy earns 19.6% per year with a
and we use these historical values to construct a pre-
maximum drawdown of 9.3%, providing the highest
dictive model. A two-stage regression approach cap-
average return and the lowest tail risk. In comparison,
tures the majority of the variation in breakeven
the other options strategies earn between 8.9% and
13.5%, with maximum drawdowns between 15.7 and volatility, and the resulting predictions satisfy no-
20.3%. The buy-and-hold S&P strategy has a max- arbitrage conditions. The predictions from our model
imum drawdown of 19.8%. can be used to formulate a volatility arbitrage strat-
egy that exploits the difference between implied
Margins and transaction costs are major factors that volatility and the predicted breakeven volatility.
can impact the return of option strategies (Zhan
et al. 2022). While our return calculation makes a There are several interesting future directions to
conservative assumption about margin requirement— explore. A natural and immediate extension would be
fully collateralized positions—we did not include a careful comparison of the different ways of delta
transaction costs thus far. We explore the impact of hedging. We used deltas associated with individual
transaction costs for our BEV strategy in Panel C of options, but alternative choices may include using the
Table 7. The tick size for SPX options is five cents. at-the-money delta or a delta calculated from a real-
For far out-of-the-money options, the bid-ask spread ized volatility forecast. A deeper analysis of the rela-
is often five cents. For at-the-money options, the tionship between breakeven volatility, realized
typical bid-ask spread ranges from 20 to 30 cents. To volatility, and realized skewness would contribute to
incorporate costs, we assume we can trade the E- the existing literature on modeling and forecasting
mini futures contract (which we use to hedge) one higher moments of asset distributions. Garleanu,
tick worse than the midpoint price, and we assume Pedersen, and Poteshman (2009) show that option
three values for trading SPX options: One tick, two prices are associated with demand pressure from
ticks, and three ticks.19 According to Muravyev and option end-users, which may serve as an additional
Pearson (2020), the average quoted bid-ask spread is predictor variable in an option pricing model. An
8.1 cents for stock index options, and the average investigation of the connection between breakeven
effective spread is 6.2 cents. For sophisticated trades volatility and the Recovery Theorem of Ross (2015)
that take into account the expected future price could shed light on the viability of Ross’s assumptions.
movement of the options, the average effective
For a fixed time to expiration, the second derivative
spread is just 1.3 cents. The authors point out that
of option prices with respect to strike prices gives
proprietary traders or institutional investors who
the risk-neutral distribution (Breeden and
have algorithms or use brokerage firm execution
Litzenberger 1978). To the extent breakeven volatil-
algorithms pay closer to 1.3 cents than 6.2 cents. In
ities are different for options with different strike pri-
light of the findings of Muravyev and Pearson (2020),
ces, the second derivative of the prices associated
our transaction cost assumptions are on the conser-
with BEVs provides another distribution. Because pri-
vative side.
ces associated with breakeven volatilities do not
Panel C shows that if we trade one tick worse than admit any risk premia, this distribution does not
the midpoint price for SPX options, the average return embed the risk attitudes of market participants. A
reduces to 4.4%, the Sharpe ratio reduces to 0.98, breakeven volatility surface that changes as a func-
and the maximum drawdown rises to 4.9%. Incurring tion of moneyness and time to expiration may be of
larger transaction costs further reduces the average interest for additional investigation.

Volume 79, Number 1 115


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

Another interesting research direction is to expand Appendix A


beyond equity indices to individual equity options. It
The table below outlines some differences between
would be worth exploring whether one can use the
the closing price methodology for the SpiderRock
same predictive model for BEVs in different sectors,
platform and OptionMetrics. We refer to the IvyDB
and what sort of adjustments may be necessary.
Europe Reference Manual v2.4 for OptionMetrics,
Researchers have documented distinct patterns for
and we refer to the SpiderRock technical notes for
variance risk premium and option skewness for
calculating volatility surfaces and forward rates.
equity index options compared to individual equity
While both firms capture market data and use volatil-
options. Presumably, these discrepancies would
ity surface calculations to report these values, they
translate to differences between breakeven volatility
have different approaches. OptionMetrics has long
and implied volatility. One may also consider expand-
been the standard for academic and institutional
ing the analysis to options traded on other asset
research, whereas SpiderRock is widely used by prac-
classes, such as bond indices or commodity futures.
titioners to support valuation in live trading environ-
Consistent empirical findings across asset classes can
ments and recently started to provide full datasets
prevent overfitting and promote a common explan-
going back at 10 years.
ation for the behavior of option prices.

Data Item OptionMetrics Approach SpiderRock Approach

Marking closing prices and Stock and option close: settlement/last/ Stock close: bid/ask mid logic
characteristics bid/ask mid waterfall Option: bid/ask/surface
Closing prices use the last trade or SpiderRock closing prices include the
closing prices for the close. Implied surface price are taken 1 min before
volatility calculations use underlying the option market close. Implied
prices that are time synchronized with volatility is synchronized with the
options bid, ask, or last quotes underlying market
Closing theoretical surface Option prices used to calculate the Call and put bid and ask markets are
price for options implied volatility are selected as the fitted directly as a component of the
first available price in the following: (1) volatility surface shape fitting process.
settlement, (2) last trade, (3) bid-ask The instantaneous surface price is
average, (4) bid, (5) ask determined by aligning the surface
shape with the underlying mid-price
and ATM volatility in real-time.
Surface-fitting approach to Vega-weighted kernel fit to options Price fits have an adaptive number of
determine the surface price implied volatility space. Standardized spline points. The result is a multi-
options are interpolated from all point spline that describes a single
options (all terms and strikes) for volatility curve for both calls and
that day. puts for each expiry. Curves for
normalized maturities are also
generated as part of this process.
Alignment of call and Surface fits for calls and puts are fit Call and put prices are fit
put surfaces independently. Calls and puts are independently, and the price data
interpolated with a weighted scheme are transformed into a single
that penalizes when option types volatility curve for both calls
are different. and puts.
Forward calculation and Forward fit to normalized maturities Forward prices are calculated using a
dividend rate calibration using a forward rate curve. continuous forward dividend rate
curve with an adjustment based on
aligning call and put volatility as part
of the curve fitting process.
Calculation of time Continuous calendar time A hybrid time convention that takes
to expiration both trading day and continuous
calendar time into account

116
Option Pricing via Breakeven Volatility

Appendix B
Left-Hand Variable: BEV-IV
The figure shows a histogram of the difference
between breakeven volatility and implied volatility Estimate SE t-Stat
for options on the S&P 500 Index. The sample is
(Intercept) 7.46 0.16 47.0
from January 2013 to November 2020. VVIX 0.043 0.001 48.1
VIX.res 0.188 0.006 30.3
rt 11.22 0.30 37.3
lsk 24.99 0.24 106.0
lsk2 8.82 0.14 61.4
ATM.IV 0.53 0.01 88.4
ImpliedVol (coef  10) 6.03 0.04 156.8
ImpliedVol2 (coef  100) 1.22 0.03 45.0
RR 0.75 0.10 7.6
RR2 36.38 0.34 105.9
RR3 16.68 0.59 28.1
Vega 2.48 0.04 64.8
vega2 (coef  10) 1.03 0.05 22.4
gamma 137.00 14.23 9.6
vrt 15.81 2.01 7.9
vvt2 52.55 0.88 60.0
Appendix C rv.res (coef  10) 2.11 0.01 146.0
This table presents a predictive model for the differ- R-squared 0.13
ence between breakeven volatility and implied Adjusted R-squared 0.13
volatility:
X
M
BEVi  IVi ¼ b0 þ Xi, m bm þ ei
k¼m overvalued or undervalued relative to its
In this specification, rather than first predicting breakeven volatility. We include the same
log(BEV) followed by a transformation, we predictor variables used in the first stage
directly try to predict whether an option is regression as shown in Table 4.

Editor's Note
Submitted 2 February 2022
Accepted 7 July 2022 by William N. Goetzmann

Notes
1. Traditional option pricing models typically try to match 3. For stock indices, deviation from put-call parity is
the market price of options, whereas our pricing model typically small. For individual stocks that are hard-to-
provides the fair value. In this sense, traditional models borrow, deviation from put-call parity could be
are positive models that capture how the world is, much larger.
whereas our model is normative.
4. This expression is approximate. To be precise, the
2. Parametric models, such as Black-Scholes can be summation is missing a borrowing or lending term equal
constrained in matching certain empirical patterns. to (Dt1 St1  ct1 Þ: At the daily frequency, this term is
Stochastic volatility models may have difficulty eliminating very close to zero, especially in a low-interest
pricing errors in short-term option prices because the environment that our data span.
distribution of the underlying does not have enough
kurtosis. Jump models may have issues with longer-term 5. The iterative approach we take was used for a different
options because they revert too quickly to the Black- purpose by Dumas et al. (1998), who try to determine
Scholes prices as the time to expiration increases. whether the delta-hedging component matched the
Nonparametric models can be more flexible in capturing changes in option prices. They show that the Black-
the features of the data, which must be pre-specified and Scholes model provides the best approximation for option
built into parametric models. price changes.

Volume 79, Number 1 117


Financial Analysts Journal | A Publication of CFA Institute

6. Our calculation of breakeven volatility requires knowing where St is the price of the underlying, K is the strike
the future path of the option, so it cannot be price, r is the interest rate, r is the volatility of the
implemented in real time. To compute BEV in a real-time underlying, and T  t is the time to expiration.
implementation, we would require a predictive model that
uses currently available information to forecast the 12. The exponential function, eðÞ , is convex. Jensen’s
eventual BEV values. inequality states that for a convex function
f, f ðE½XÞ  E½f ðXÞ:
7. There are a number of alternatives ways of hedging. One
could choose to hedge at market open rather than at 13. We compare our supervised approach with the parametric
market close, use delta calculated from the at-the-money methods of Duan (1983) and we find that our approach
volatility or forecasted volatility, hedge only when the achieves the lowest mean squared error.
net delta exceeds a certain threshold, or adjust the
hedge ratio depending on whether the order flow is 14. With 396,899 observations and 17 predictors, the
believed to be informed. Different hedging methods adjusted R-squared is 1.00004 times larger compared to
correspond to different objectives, and there is no single the unadjusted R-squared.
best method. On a practical note, the BEV calculation
should match the specific trading desks’ preferred 15. We thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion.
hedging policy.
16. If Equation (9) were violated, a costless arbitrage profit
8. More frequent delta hedging (i.e., intraday) can may be earned by writing a put with strike price K2 ,
alleviate the issue of large changes in gamma in the buying KK33 K
K1 units of the put with strike price K1 , and
2

volatility calculations near maturity, especially for buying K2 K1


units of the put with strike price K3 :
K3 K1
ATM options.
17. We also explore thresholds of $0.50, $2, and $3, and we
9. Extending our calculation to the expiration date will not
find our results are qualitatively unchanged. A higher
significantly change our results. We do find that
trading threshold has two offsetting effects: We have
numerical computation of breakeven volatilities in the
more conviction on each trade, but we may miss some
last several days just before expiration to be more
profitable opportunities that do not exceed the threshold.
difficult, as more volatility calculations do not converge
In our sample, these two effects apparently have similar
in the days immediately before expiration. More
magnitudes such that changing the threshold has only a
frequent delta hedging can improve this
marginal effect on the strategy performance.
convergence issue.
 rðTtÞ 
log Se K 18. Our return calculation is on the conservative side. By
10. Normalized Strike ¼ ATM:IV p ffiffiffiffiffiffi for underlying price S,
Tt taking the notional value as the denominator, we have
strike price K, the at-the-money implied volatility ATM:IV,
made the implicit assumption that the option positions
and time to expiration T  t: The annualized interest rate
are fully collateralized with 100% margin requirement. In
r is set to 0.5%.
practice, margin requirements typically range between 5
11. d1 in the Black-Scholes model is given by the following and 30% for puts and calls on the S&P 500 Index.
expression: "    #
 19. Private correspondence with option traders indicates that
1 St r2 unless one wants immediate execution, transacting one
d1 ¼ pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi log þ rþ ðTt Þ
r Tt K 2 tick from the midpoint price is achievable with very high
probability.

References
Ait-Sahalia, Y., and A. W. Lo. 1998. “Nonparametric Estimation Bali, T. G., H. Beckmeyer, M. Moerke, and F. Weigert. 2021.
of State-Price Densities Implicit in Financial Asset Prices.” The “Option Return Predictability with Machine Learning and Big
Journal of Finance 53 (2): 499–547. doi:10.1111/0022-1082. Data.” Available at SSRN 3895984.
215228.
Black, F., and M. Scholes. 1973. “The Pricing of Options and
Ammann, M., and S. Herriger. 2002. “Relative Implied-Volatility Corporate Liabilities.” Journal of Political Economy 81 (3):
Arbitrage with Index Options.” Financial Analysts Journal 58 (6): 637–654. doi:10.1086/260062.
42–55. doi:10.2469/faj.v58.n6.2485.
Bollen, N. P., and R. E. Whaley. 2004. “Does Net Buying
Bakshi, G., C. Cao, and Z. Chen. 1997. “Empirical Performance Pressure Affect the Shape of Implied Volatility Functions?” The
of Alternative Option Pricing Models.” The Journal of Finance Journal of Finance 59 (2): 711–753. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.
52 (5): 2003–2049. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb02749.x. 2004.00647.x.

Bakshi, G., and N. Kapadia. 2003. “Delta-Hedged Gains and the Bollerslev, T., G. Tauchen, and H. Zhou. 2009. “Expected Stock
Negative Market Volatility Risk Premium.” Review of Financial Returns and Variance Risk Premia.” Review of Financial Studies
Studies 16 (2): 527–566. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhg002. 22 (11): 4463–4492. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhp008.

118
Option Pricing via Breakeven Volatility

Breeden, D. T., and R. H. Litzenberger. 1978. “Prices of State- Hull, B., and X. Qiao. 2017. “A Practitioner’s Defense of Return
Contingent Claims Implicit in Option Prices.” The Journal of Predictability.” The Journal of Portfolio Management 43 (3):
Business 51 (4): 621–651. doi:10.1086/296025. 60–76. doi:10.3905/jpm.2017.43.3.060.

Campbell, J. Y., and S. B. Thompson. 2008. “Predicting Excess Hutchinson, J. M., A. W. Lo, and T. Poggio. 1994. “A
Stock Returns out of Sample: Can Anything Beat the Historical Nonparametric Approach to Pricing and Hedging Derivative
Average?” Review of Financial Studies 21 (4): 1509–1531. doi: Securities via Learning Networks.” The Journal of Finance 49 (3):
10.1093/rfs/hhm055. 851–889. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1994.tb00081.x.

Carr, P., and L. Wu. 2009. “Variance Risk Premiums.” Review of Liu, S., C. W. Oosterlee, and S. M. Bohte. 2019. “Pricing
Financial Studies 22 (3): 1311–1341. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhn038. Options and Computing Implied Volatilities Using Neural
Networks.” Risks 7 (1): 16. doi:10.3390/risks7010016.
Cheney, E. W., and D. R. Kincaid. 2009. Linear Algebra: Theory
and Applications. Jones & Bartlett Learning. Malz, A. M. 2014. “A Simple and Reliable Way to Compute
Option-Based Risk-Neutral Distributions.” FRB of New York
Christoffersen, P., R. Goyenko, K. Jacobs, and M. Karoui. 2018. Staff Report 677.
“Illiquidity Premia in the Equity Options Market.” The Review of
Financial Studies 31 (3): 811–851. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhx113. Manzo, G., and X. Qiao. 2021. “Deep Learning Credit Risk
Modeling.” The Journal of Fixed Income 31 (2): 101–127. doi:10.
Clark, T. E., and K. D. West. 2007. “Approximately Normal 3905/jfi.2021.1.121.
Tests for Equal Predictive Accuracy in Nested Models.” Journal
of Econometrics 138 (1): 291–311. doi:10.1016/j.jeconom.2006. Merton, R. C. 1973. “Theory of Rational Option Pricing.” The
05.023. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4 (1):
141–183. doi:10.2307/3003143.
Coval, J. D., and T. Shumway. 2001. “Expected Option
Returns.” The Journal of Finance 56 (3): 983–1009. doi:10. Mitoulis, N. 2019. “Breakeven Volatility.” Technical Report,
1111/0022-1082.00352. University of Cape Town.

Cox, J. C., R. A. Ross, and M. Rubinstein. 1979. “Option Pricing: Muravyev, D., and N. D. Pearson. 2020. “Option Trading Costs
A Simplified Approach.” Journal of Financial Economics 7 (3): Are Lower than You Think.” The Review of Financial Studies 33
229–263. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(79)90015-1. (11): 4973–5014. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhaa010.

Dong, X., Y. Li, D. E. Rapach, and G. Zhou. 2022. “Anomalies Neuberger, A. 2012. “Realized Skewness.” Review of Financial
and the Expected Market Returns.” The Journal of Finance 77 Studies 25 (11): 3423–3455. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhs101.
(1): 639–681. doi:10.1111/jofi.13099. Orosi, G. 2015. “Estimating Option-Implied Risk-Neutral
Duan, N. 1983. “Smearing Estimate: A Nonparametric Densities: A Novel Parametric Approach.” The Journal of
Retransformation Method.” Journal of the American Statistical Derivatives 23 (1): 41–61. doi:10.3905/jod.2015.23.1.041.
Association 78 (383): 605–610. doi:10.1080/01621459.1983. Ross, S. 2015. “The Recovery Theorem.” The Journal of Finance
10478017. 70 (2): 615–648. doi:10.1111/jofi.12092.
Dumas, B., J. Fleming, and R. E. Whaley. 1998. “Implied Shimko, D. 1993. “The Bounds of Probability.” Risk 6 (4):
Volatility Functions: Empirical Tests.” Journal of Finance 53 (6): 33–37.
2059–2106. doi:10.1111/0022-1082.00083.
Stutzer, M. 1996. “A Simple Nonparametric Approach to
Dupire, B. 2006. “Fair Skew: Break-Even Volatility Surface.” Derivative Security Valuation.” The Journal of Finance 51 (5):
Technical Report, Bloomberg L.P. 1633–1652. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1996.tb05220.x.
Figlewski, S., and F. Malik. 2014. “Options on Leveraged ETFs: Taylor, J. M. 1986. “The Retransformed Mean after a Fitted
A Window on Investor Heterogeneity.” Available at SSRN Power Transformation.” Journal of the American Statistical
2477004. Association 81 (393): 114–118. doi:10.1080/01621459.1986.
10478246.
Garleanu, N., L. H. Pedersen, and A. M. Poteshman. 2009.
“Pricing Options in an Extended Black-Scholes Economy with Welch, I., and A. Goyal. 2008. “A Comprehensive Look at the
Illiquidity: Theory and Empirical Evidence.” Review of Financial Empirical Performance of Equity Premium Prediction.” Review
Studies 22 (10): 4259–4299. of Financial Studies 21 (4): 1455–1508. doi:10.1093/rfs/
hhm014.
Goyenko, R., and C. Zhang. 2020. “The Joint Cross Section of
Option and Stock Returns Predictability with Big Data and Zhan, X., B. Han, J. Cao, and Q. Tong. 2022. “Option Return
Machine Learning.” Available at SSRN. Predictability.” The Review of Financial Studies 35 (3):
1394–1442. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhab067.
Heston, S. L. 1993. “A Closed-Form Solution for Options with
Stochastic Volatility with Applications to Bond and Current Zou, J., and E. Derman. 1999. Strike-Adjusted Spread: A New
Options.” Review of Financial Studies 6 (2): 327–343. doi:10. Metric for Estimating the Value of Equity Options. SSRN. https://
1093/rfs/6.2.327. ssrn.com/abstract=170629

Volume 79, Number 1 119


Taylor & Francis takes seriously its contribution to protecting our environment.
In addition to all paper used in our journals being FSC-certified, this journal has gone
plastic-free and no longer uses plastic cover lamination or polywrap for mailing.

You might also like