Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 49

Economic Roots of Civil Wars and Revolutions in the Contemporary World

Author(s): Carles Boix


Source: World Politics, Vol. 60, No. 3 (Apr., 2008), pp. 390-437
Published by: Cambridge University Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/40060203
Accessed: 30-05-2018 17:27 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

Cambridge University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to World Politics

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL
WARS AND REVOLUTIONS IN THE
CONTEMPORARY WORLD

By CARLES BOIX*

RESEARCH
as onasthe
civil wars or sources
guerrilla of modern
warfare, has gone political violence,
through several theo-whether
retical turns since its inception as a comparative endeavor almost fifty
years ago. Modernization scholars explained rebellions as a function of
economic inequality, the impact of social and economic development,
and the status and political claims of particular social groups.1 That
strand of inquiry was joined by a second line of research relating violent
conflict to ethnic nationalism and the distribution of resources along
ethnic lines.2 In recent years, however, almost all scholars have shifted
away from those explanations that emphasize the structure of economic
relations, the importance of existing grievances, or the role of political
ideologies in igniting violent conflicts; they stress instead the context
of economic and political opportunities in which potential rebels may
decide to engage in violent action. On the one hand, Collier and Hoef-
fler have linked the emergence of rebellious activities to the availability
of both financing (namely, abundant natural resources) and potential
recruits (individuals with very reduced prospects of material advance-

* Previous versions of this paper were presented at the Yale Conference on Order, Conflict and Vi-
olence, the Macroeconomics Workshop at Boston University, the Department of Politics at Princeton
University, and Nuffield College at Oxford University. I thank the the participants for their comments,
particularly Robert Bates, Stathis Kalyvas, David Laitin, and Nicholas Sambanis. I also thank Alicia
Adsera and the editors and anonymous referees of World Politics for their comments.
On inequality and violence, see Bruce M. Russett, Inequality and Instability: The Relation of
Land Tenure to Politics," World Politics 16 (April 1964); Jefferey M. Paige, Agrarian Revolution (New
York: Free Press, 1975); Manus I. Midlarsky, "Rulers and the Ruled: Patterned Inequality and the On-
set of Mass Political Violence," American Political Science Review 82 (June 1988); Edward N. Muller,
"Income Inequality, Regime Repressiveness, and Political Violence," American Sociological Review 50
(February 1985). On the effects of development, see Samuel Huntington, Political Order in Changing
Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968); Eric R. Wolf, Peasant Wars in the Twentieth Century
(New York: Harper and Row, 1969); Ted Gurr, "The Revolution- Social Change Nexus," Comparative
Politics 5 (April 1973).
2 Donald L. Horowitz, Ethnic Groups in Conflict (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985);
Walker Connor, Ethnonationalism: The Quest for Understanding (Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1994).

World Politics 60 (April 2008), 390-437

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 391

ment through peaceful activity).3 On the other hand, Fearon and Lait
have emphasized that grievances are not a sufficient condition to gen
erate political violence since there is an almost infinite supply of them
across the world.4 They hypothesize, instead, that "financially, organ
zationally, and politically weak central governments render insurgenc
more feasible and attractive due to weak local policing or inept an
corrupt counterinsurgency practices" and conclude that civil wars hap
pen in "fragile states with limited administrative control of their pe-
ripheries."5 Writing from a different angle and rooting his examinatio
of the micrologic of violence deployed in civil wars, Kalyvas downplay
the presence of single, sociologically unique motivations and describes
civil wars as "imperfect, mutilayered, and fluid aggregations of high
complex, partially overlapping, diverse, and localized civil wars wi
pronounced differences from region to region and valley to valley."6
The advocates of these different strands of work have generally pr
sented them as advancing opposite explanations of political violen
Yet each one of them offers partial and, when considered separate
insufficient insights into the same empirical puzzle - with the forme
literature focused on the reasons actors may have to engage in vi
lence and the latter centered on their opportunities to do so. However
a more satisfactory theory of political violence needs to subsume both
approaches. To paraphrase Collier and Hoeffler, political violence,
the commission of any crime, requires both "motive and opportunity
I take up this task in this article. Accordingly, I start by specifying t
set of conditions that may motivate actors to engage in political violen
Since the literature on political opportunities and the organizatio
failures of states correctly points out that the notion of acute "griev
ances" is especially difficult to pin down and that economic resentmen
ethnic antagonisms, and personal or clique grudges are too common o

3 Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler, "Justice Seeking and Loot-Seeking in Civil War" (Manuscript
World Bank, 1999).
4 James D. Fearon and David Laitin, "Ethnicity, Insurgency, and Civil War," American Polit
Science Review 97 (February 2003).
5 Ibid., 75-76, 88. Beyond the literature on civil wars, a long tradition in political science
insisted that organization and resources are an essential prerequisite for social mobilization, prote
and violence. See Charles H. Tilly, From Mobilization to Revolution (Reading, Mass: Addison-Wesle
1978). Moore and Skocpol also stressed that agrarian grievances did not translate directly into rev
lutionary action and in fact required the organized mobilization by particular groups, such as stud
and parties. See Barrington Moore, Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasan
the Making of the Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press, 1966), 479; Theda Skocpol, States and Soc
Revolutions (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1979), 114-15.
6 Stathis Kalyvas, The Logic of Violence in Civil War (New York: Cambridge University Press, 20
371.
7 Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler, "Greed and Grievance in Civil War," Oxford Economic Papers
(2004), 563.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
392 WORLD POLITICS

widespread to specify the ca


I offer a more precise model
der which political actors m
nutshell, I predict that the us
arena will most likely occur
where wealth is mostly immo
tors (such as landowners or g
resources in rentier states) ten
by democratic means. The loss
mechanisms voted by the maj
larly, resorting to violence to
to those who do not own most
sizable fraction of the econom
inequality, which played a cen
civil wars, the article shows a
fies in unequal economies in
well-off sectors can engage in
they win, no assets will be mo
more likely within the wealth
bile assets, its members have a
armed activities to grab the p
larly if the sectors that are lea
thus hardly threatening).8
Within this model of materia
recent work on civil wars, w
state capacity, by explicitly m
activities into the decision o
costs of employing violent me
the organizational capabilitie
and, on the other hand, with
of terrain, the distribution of
The contribution of this arti

8 In part, these conditions can be traced


the one hand, the article brings back in to
economic inequality. On the other hand, i
at least initially, explained the occurrence o
fueled by the abundance of natural resour
and by the relatively low life chances of p
ment for males). These two latter factors
of abundant natural resources (rather than
any type of illegal activity and therefore
with the idea that only fixed assets can be
attainment also points to the type of asset

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 393

of detailed data, the first structural models of political violence were


poorly tested. More recently, researchers have generated much more
systematic studies of the causes of violence.9 But their analyses have
mostly looked at the opportunities for violence and have been restricted
to civil wars (after 1950). In addition, their central social and economic
indicator has been reduced to per capita income - which, among all
the theoretical interpretations it may be given, has been chosen as an
indicator of the organizational capabilities of the state. By contrast, I
develop more fine-grained and direct measures of the nature and dis-
tribution of wealth (without giving up on the exploration of the eco-
nomic, geographical, and technological factors that may determine the
presence of violent conflict). In addition, I extend the empirical analysis
to examine the occurrence of civil wars between 1850 and 1999 and to
explore the correlates of guerrilla warfare and revolutionary outbreaks
between 1919 and 1997.

Theory

To identify the conditions under which political violence takes place, I


describe an economy characterized by two main traits: the distribution
of assets among individuals and the extent to which those assets are
mobile and can be actually taxed. In this economic context, economic
agents, who are endowed with some organizational and military re-
sources, choose the political strategy that is likely to maximize their
wealth. The use of violence to choose political institutions (and to de-
termine the extent to which wealth will be redistributed) is one of these
political strategies. That is the focus of this article.10

Economy

Assume an economy with two types of individuals, poor and wealthy.


Poor individuals P hold a total capital stock K . In turn, wealthy in-
dividuals W hold aggregate capital stock Kw. By definition, P are the
majority of society, that is, P> W. The economy-wide stock of capital is
K+Kw=K. For notational convenience, the aggregate share of capital of
each group can be represented as k.= K/K so that k +&w=l- The capital
held by each poor individual is k *=k /P and by each rich individual is

9 Collier and Hoeffler (fn. 7); Fearon and Laitin (fn. 4).
10 This model builds on previous work published in Carles Boix, Democracy and Redistribution
(New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003). But it differs mainly in two respects. First, it explores
in more detail the use of violence in the choice of institutions. Second, it extends the model to examine
the effects of democracy in the use of violence and to allow for open warfare within the wealthy elite.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
394 WORLD POLITICS

kJ=kw/W. By definition, k
equals K/(W+P). The differenc
of income inequality.
Production is constant return
ized to y.=k.,j=w,p. Capital var
which it is used. The higher th
its value when it is moved abr
contrast, high skills and finan
ate similar returns across coun
given by the productivity of
measured by the parameter O
produce y=ky produces abroad

Political Strategies and Political Regimes

Given a particular economic structure (and the position of indiv


in it), both the wealthy and the poor engage in a set of political
to choose the political regime that will maximize their wealt
precisely, they play a game with the following sequence:
(1) First, the wealthy decide whether to establish an autho
regime or to accept democracy. If they move to democracy,
accept and everybody votes to set the level of taxes and redistr
(The model assumes that the poor are better off under democra
under a revolutionary outcome. In Appendix 3 I relax this
tion and consider the possibility that the poor revolt under dem
Broadly speaking, this increases the occurrence of authoritar
Assume, following standard political economy models, that t
taxes agents with a linear tax x on their income y (so that ea
vidual pays Xy.) and distributes revenue equally among all in
(so each individual receives Tyj). n In a democracy, the media
(who, given our assumptions, is a poor individual) sets taxes t
mize transfers to herself, taking into account the welfare losses
tion (which for simplicity may be assumed to be given by a qua
function T2/2) and constrained by the decision of the wealthy t
their income abroad. Formally,12

max(i-T)j;+J/;T-j/;^L (l)
11 T. Persson and G.Tabellini, Political Economics (Cambridge: MIT Press, 2000).
12 This formalization (particularly the constraint) assumes that the timing of the polit
is such that each individual wealthy voter can choose to move his income abroad and still
transfer. This is a Nash equilibrium assumption: the deviation by each voter, in deciding t
capital abroad takes the transfers in the economy as given. Altering this assumption so that
country must be done before obtaining transfers slightly complicates the algebra but does
any of the analysis that follows.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 395

such that (1 - x)yj > (1 - o)y\

Solving this maximization problem, the tax is

T* = min(l-:Z,G). (2)
J a

This result simply implies th


rate equal to the smaller of two
and the ratio of inequality (exp
by the average income per per
wealth. With low capital mobili
tion of income inequality becau
exit in response to heavy taxe
proaches 0), the tax rate becom
wealthy will move their capital
tax rate declines.
(2) If, instead of accepting dem
tain an authoritarian regime, th
If they acquiesce, the result is
system in which only the wealt
transfers. Since wealthy voters
to themselves (particularly give
fect on the economy), the tax r
of such a regime will require in
that the tax is 0, the wealthy i
person has assets k\
(3) If the less well off revol
the resources of each party in
reassertion of the right-wing a
of a left-wing regime (in which
ated).14 If a left-wing regime
they have expropriated all the
the poor individual gets k ' + oK

13 For the sake of simplicity I disregard th


public goods.
14 In the model, agents live for only one period and do not care about leaving a bequest to their
children. Hence, they undertake a sequence of one-period optimizations. The only links between the
different periods is the state of the political system at the start of the period and the capital stock at the
start of the period. In each period wealthy and poor agents observe the political system inherited, the
distribution of wealth, and its specificity, and they play a game that determines the choice of political
regime and, given the latter, the tax rate. The solution concept used is perfect Bayesian equilibrium, as
agents play what is essentially a different game in each period.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
396 WORLD POLITICS

war) and the rich obtain their


sion, (l-G)k ' - r \
(4) Finally, once the poor h
(rebelling or acquiescing), the
possibility of challenging th
group - with a view to accum
more dominant in the conte
intraelite or intraclass conflic
tationally, fighting implies in
i (against another wealthy in
can keep only her nonspecific
As will be examined shortl
within this setup to engage
the distribution and nature of
the actors' strength (political,
the varying strength of the p
sion costs of the wealthy to r
bear very low repression costs
alone succeeds at repressing
costs (rw/ow) denote a situatio
are the stronger party: once c
reassert an authoritarian outc
together (but not if they act s
occur when the wealthy (eve
poor. Here the poor always wi
The variation in repression cos
assets: in extremely unequal soc
advantage over everyone else to d
ular resources. Yet, as the conc
to associate with others to rea
less, repression costs could als
capacity of each group, the te
and the geographical character
located. Thus, for example, th
the least well off are complet
makes the suppression of polit
or the government receives th
lies. By contrast, the costs of
organize in political parties a
tainous terrain, which may br
or when the state has poor ro

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 397

Given this potential variation in the strength of political actors, vi


olence erupts precisely because there is some lack of information
some uncertainty about the costs of repression and the ability of each
side to win in a violent contest. If everybody knew the strength of i
adversary, then the weaker party would not contest the regime impose
by the other party and there would never be open conflict. If weak, th
wealthy would not choose an authoritarian strategy, knowing that th
would be defeated. Similarly, faced with a strong party of wealthy ind
viduals, the poor would not challenge authoritarianism.
More precisely, the model assumes the following information
structure. The poor do not know about the strength of the wealthy wi
certainty and need to estimate the likelihood that they will succeed i
a civil war before rebelling. Formally, they estimate the cost of repr
sion to the elite to be high with probability q and to be low (or ve
low) with probability (1 - q). In turn, the rich know their type (weak
strong, or very strong) vis-a-vis the poor. Nevertheless, the wealthy a
face some uncertainty: they are unsure about the internal distributio
of power within their own group and therefore about whether they ca
successfully defeat one of their own kind should they decide to do so

Peace versus Violent Conflict

PEACEFUL CONDITIONS

Violence will not take place under both low and medium levels
equality and asset specificity. When the level of either inequal
wealth specificity is sufficiently low, democracy takes place regar
of the cost of repression.15 This is so because for sufficiently low
of inequality or asset specificity the tax rate in a democratic settin
be low enough to make the introduction of democracy cheaper th
maintenance of an authoritarian regime (even when repression co
low or very low).
The likelihood of having a democracy declines in those case
which either wealth inequality or asset specificity increases so th
though they are low, they are not sufficiently low for democrac
preferred to repression in all cases. The type of political regim
prevails (for medium levels of inequality and specificity) varies wit
type of repression costs in place. If repression costs are low or ver
the wealthy prefer to repress rather than to permit democratic e
tions. The poor do not contest the authoritarian regime becaus
15 1 discuss the choice of political regimes (under peaceful conditions) very briefly to focu
on the causes of violence.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
398 WORLD POLITICS

know that for the rich to r


ate inequality and asset spec
and that, therefore, a revolut
then the wealthy simply mov
political outcome is identical
is very equal or assets scarce
political violence between wea

OUTBREAKS OF INTERCLASS VIOLENCE

As the levels of inequality and asset specificity go up, the cost o


tion under democracy always becomes higher than the cost of rep
borne by the wealthy to maintain an authoritarian regime. Und
circumstances, the excluded majority may resort to violence wh
the expected gain of revolting is larger than the value of accept
authoritarian regime:

q(kp+<5Kw/P-<*)>kf. (3)
Sustained violence occurs when the wealthy decide to resp
rebellion by the poor. If the costs of repression are low, the ric
always repress, knowing that an authoritarian regime will ev
prevail. If the costs of repression are high, the wealthy lack a d
strategy. On the one hand, they will not always choose repre
they did, the poor would systematically try their luck and revo
would make a repressive strategy not optimal when repress
indeed expensive. On the other hand, the rich will not alway
repression either. A nonrepressive strategy would make the p
lieve that those who repress can do so at low cost. This would
give the wealthy an incentive to repress (and exploit the beliefs
poor) even when the cost of repression was high. Since the w
cannot follow a pure dominant strategy, they will simply follow
strategies to make the poor indifferent between revolution and
escence. Appendix 1 formally develops the equilibrium that dete
the wealthy 's strategy as well as the poor's probability of revol
shown in that appendix, within the high inequality/high spe
equilibrium, the probability of the revolt increases as income in
and particularly asset specificity increase.
Figure 1 summarizes the insights of the model. The vertic
captures the level of inequality. The horizontal axis measures the
of asset specificity. Democracy prevails at either low levels of in
ity or low levels of asset specificity (or both). The probabilit

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS OC REVOLUTIONS 399

Figure 1
Political Outcomes as a Function of Inequality and
Specificity of Wealth

authoritarian regime rises as both economic parameters go up. For


sufficiently high levels of inequality and fixed wealth, violent clashes
become increasingly likely. To sum up, we should expect civil wars,
guerrilla warfare, and revolutionary activity to be clustered in the up-
per-right corner of Figure 1. This result, which I explore empirically
below, coincides with the outbreak of a substantial number of civil wars
and revolutionary events in agrarian and unequal economies such as
parts of Southern and Eastern Europe, Central and Latin America,
and China and Southeast Asia in the twentieth century.

OUTBREAKS OF INTRACLASS CONFLICT

I have thus far modeled the conditions under which violence takes
places between economic classes. However, conflict may also happen
within the wealthy elite: each wealthy individual may have an incentive
to expropriate the assets of other members of his group. In the game I
just constructed, once the wealthy have established an authoritarian re-
gime and once the poor have decided whether to rebel or to acquiesce,
one or some of the members of the wealthy class may choose to fight
with others of their own group.
Under what conditions will intraclass conflict emerge? The fre-
quency of intraclass conflict will depend, in the first place, on the re-
pression costs of the wealthy (vis-a-vis the poor). If repression costs are

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
400 WORLD POLITICS

high and the poor decide to re


elite conflict because they wo
addition, lose the extra costs o
volted, the wealthy will not fi
costs are low. As previously n
wealthy can defeat the poor o
elite conflict leads to the sam
defeat before the poor plus ex
may engage in intraelite con
poor when repression costs
individual can defeat the po
happen with some positive pro
elite conflict does not jeopard
ther because the rest of the p
it can be contained).16
For the sake of simplicity,
the one just described for the
poor decide whether to revo
randomly by nature) decides w
ing the assets of other wealth
individual knows whether he
als. The other individuals do n
retains his initial wealth. If a
the demand is made may acq
respond with force. Given the
has about the distribution of
some chance open conflict wil
Appendix 2 formally develo
sult of the model is that as as
a stronger incentive to fight
from each other.17 As assets b
everyone from fighting over
intraelite conflict takes place
(in which the least well off
cause intraelite wars would dis
happen in developed nations.
wars clustered in the right-ha

16 If those costs are inversely related to in


highly unequal places.
17 The likelihood of war also goes up wh
requires relaxing the model's assumption t

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 401

relatively unequal societies, since those are the ones in which the wealt
have enough resources to neutralize the least well off. This analyti
result seems to fit the historical record well. Many nineteenth-centur
civil wars in Latin America involved oligarchical elites in the conte
of little mobilization of the least-well-off sectors. To name a few, con
sider the Venezuelan wars of 1868-70 and 1888-89, the Colombia
wars in the second half of the nineteenth century, Chile in 1851, 185
and 1891, and Argentina's interterritorial fights.18 Similar wars did n
happen in the industrial core of Europe. And they also disappeared
class-based mobilization grew in the twentieth century.

Empirics of Political Violence

To explore the validity of the explanatory model, which predicts th


political violence increases with inequality and wealth specificity, c
ditional on the costs of choosing violent means of action, I exam
data on the occurrence of the following types of violent events:
wars, guerrilla warfare, and revolutionary episodes.
Broadly speaking, a civil war is any conflict in which military ac
takes place between agents of (or claimants to) a state and organ
nonstate groups that seek to take control of the state (in the e
country or in part of the country) or to change governmental
cies, and in which the conflict exceeds a certain threshold of de
As shown in Sambanis, current data sets of civil war incidence emp
partially different coding strategies to operationalize such a ge
definition and therefore generate partly different lists of war onset
terminations.19 Since, with few exceptions, most explanatory varia
are very sensitive to the data set employed by the researcher, here I
ploy four data sets. To examine the incidence of civil wars since the
half of the nineteenth century, I examine the data set of the Corr
of War (cow) project as updated by Sarkees, which includes data fro
1816 through 1997.20I then turn to the three most recent and prob

18Huntington (fn. 1); Miguel Centeno, Blood and Debt: War and the Nation-State in Latin Am
(University Park: The Pennsylvania State University Press, 2002).
19 For a full analysis of the coding strategies employed in each data set, see Nicholas Samb
"What Is Civil War? Conceptual and Empirical Complexities of an Operational Definition," J
of Conflict Resolution 48 (December 2004). Most of the disagreement is related to the definiti
violence and death thresholds employed in each data set. For example, whereas the Correlates
project seems to require a minimum of one thousand battle deaths to code a conflict as a war,
and Laitin (fn. 4) further qualify a civil war as a conflict where at least one hundred were kil
both sides.
20 Meredith Reid Sarkees, "The Correlates of War Data on War: An Update to 1997," Co
Management and Peace Science 18, no. 1 (2000).

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
402 WORLD POLITICS

best documented data sets on c


Laitin, the Uppsala-Prio dat
Sambanis.21
The data on guerrillas are t
from 1919 to 1997.22 Episodes
ity, sabotage, or bombings car
or irregular forces and aimed
I complement this analysis wi
civil conflicts reported by Gle
flicts that have experienced
in a given year.
Finally, the data on revolut
extend from 1919 to 1997. R
or forced change in the top
a change, or any successful o
winning independence from t

Graphic Evidence

I first investigate the validity of the theory graphically. I then en


more systematic econometric work to show that the rather strikin
terns revealed in Figures 2-7 (and which certainly meet John Tuk
famous "interocular traumatic test")25 survive more thorough sta
tests.

Figures 2-7 examine the economic sources of civil war onsets, guer-
rilla warfare onsets, and revolutionary events across the world by plot-
ting two sets of data in each graph. The first set of data consists of all
the country-year observations for the period of investigation, regardless
of whether there was violence, along two dimensions: the average level
of industrialization and urbanization (on the x-axis) and the percent-
age of family farms (on the y-axis). These data are represented using
small black dots. The second set of data consists of the country-year in

21 Fearon and Laitin (fn. 4); Nils Petter Gleditsch, Peter Wallensteen, Mikael Eriksson, Marga-
reta Sollenberg, and Havard Strand, "Armed Conflict 1946-2001: A New Dataset," Journal of Peace
Research 39 (September, 2002); Sambanis (fn. 19). Fearon and Laitin code 101 war onsets and 893
years with civil war from 1950 to 1997; Gleditsch et al. code 89 war onsets from 1950 to 1999 and 347
years at war; and Sambanis lists 135 war onsets and 911 years at war from 1950 to 1999. According to
Sambanis, the correlation (for war incidence) across data sets is about 0.7.
22 Arthur S. Banks, "Cross National Time Series: A Database of Social, Economic, and Political
Data," http://www.databanks.sitehosting.net (1997).
23Gleditschetal.(fn.21).
24Banks(fn.22).
25 Robert D. Putnam, Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton: Princ-
eton University Press, 1993), 13.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 403

which there was an outbreak of violence. These data points are marked
with the abbreviated name of the country (in which it took place).
Before I continue with the discussion of the evidence, let me con-
sider the appropriateness of the two measures I have chosen for the
figures: percentage of family farms and average of industrialization and
urbanization. The percentage of family farms captures the degree of
concentration and therefore inequality in the ownership of land. That
measure, gathered and reported by Vanhanen, is based on defining as
family farms those "farms that provide employment for not more than
four people, including family members, [...] that are cultivated by the
holder family itself and [...] that are owned by the cultivator family
or held in ownerlike possession/'26 The definition, which aims at dis-
tinguishing family farms from large farms cultivated mainly by hired
workers, is not dependent on the actual size of the farm; the size of
the farm varies with the type of product and the agricultural technol-
ogy being used.27 The data set, reported in averages for each decade,
ranges from 1850 to 1999. An extensive literature has related the un-
equal distribution of land to an unbalanced distribution of income. For
the period after 1950, and excluding the cases of socialist economies,
the correlation coefficient among the Gini index and the percentage
of family farms is -0.50.28 For the purposes of investigating the causes
of violence, the measure is appropriate for the following reason. In the
model violence results only from the presence of unequal conditions
in the agrarian or fixed-assets sector. Again, remember that as assets
become less fixed or specific, the incentives to engage in violent action
decline, even when inequality in the distribution of mobile wealth is
still high. The average of industrialization (measured as the average
of the percentage of nonagricultural population) and urban population
(defined as percentage of population living in cities of twenty thousand
or more inhabitants) is also taken from Vanhanen and is employed to
approximate the extent to which assets may be mobile.29 It is true that
both measures (or their average) are only imperfect proxies for asset
nonspecificity. Modernization scholars have claimed that industrializa-

26Tatu Vanhanen, Prospects of Democracy: A Study of 172 Countries (London: Routledge, 1997), 48.
27 It varies from countries with 0 percent of family farms to nations where 94 percent of the agri-
cultural land is owned as family farms: the mean of the sample is 30 percent with a standard deviation
of 23 percent. A detailed discussion and description of the data can be found in Vanhanen (fn. 26),
49-51 and the sources quoted therein.
28 Socialist economies are excluded from this calculation because most of them nationalized all
or most of agrarian property, therefore driving the percentage of family farms to 0 (equivalent to an
extremely unequal landowning economy).
29 Vanhanen (fn. 26). This average has a mean of 35 percent and varies from 3 to 99 percent.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
404 WORLD POLITICS

tion and urbanization may pr


as specific cultural attitudes o
with less violence. I deal with t
analysis below I consider addi
modernization effects of tho
measures of asset immobility, s
the variables proxying for asset
effect on violence. This last res
would be difficult to disentang
accounts. But since the measu
provided inequality is high, s
most of their appeal.
Notice that in all figures bot
(decreasing in value as one mo
high inequality/high specificity
permits comparison with the b
Figure 2 explores the distribut
1944. Again, the black dots, wh
regardless of whether there wa
vations is close to 4,600), show
in how industrialized countrie
sectors were. To help interpre
dotted line in the upper-left
from right to left) correspon
story of continuous industriali
erably concentrated (yet progr
A symmetrically opposite case
in which family farms account
in 1850 and about 84 percent
sluggish.
The cases in which a civil war (as defined by the Correlates of War
data set) started are then marked with the abbreviated name of the
country in which it took place. As predicted in the theoretical model
(summarized in Figure 1), most civil wars (53 out of 56) occur in coun-
tries where both the agrarian sector is still dominant and land is dis-
tributed unequally: basically within the triangle to the right of a diago-
nal going from no industrialization and less than 50 percent of the land
to middle levels of industrialization with no family farms at all. The
American civil war, the Austrian civil conflict of 1934, and the Greek
war of 1944 are the only conflicts that fall outside the boundaries of the
theoretical expectations of the article.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 405

Figure 2
Economic Structure and Civil Wars before 1945

Figure 3 represents the cases of civil war onsets after 1945. The
abbreviations in large font correspond to the cow database. The abbre-
viations in small font correspond to additional wars coded by Fearon
and Laitin.30 In addition, the graph denotes war onsets in oil-exporting
countries with a diamond. The dots that represent all the country-year
observations regardless of whether there was an episode of violence
total over 6,900 and cover the entire figure. In line with our expec-
tations, most civil war onsets fall squarely within the area defined by
high inequality and high asset specificity. Several cases that are closer
to the middle (that is, farther away from the upper-right corner) have
considerable oil resources and so conflict there may be related to asset
immobility. The distribution of observations in the graph has the ad-
ditional advantage of making it easier to identify in a clear manner the
few outliers to an otherwise relatively parsimonious model: Argentina,
the United Kingdom, Croatia, Georgia, and Djibouti.
Figures 4 and 5 depict the distribution of guerrilla warfare before
and after 1945, respectively. Two traits deserve attention. First, the
location of guerrillas is still similar to civil wars: violence is heavily
concentrated in unequal agrarian economies. Second, the occurrence

30 Fearon and Laitin (fn. 4).

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
large font = correlates of war
small font = additional wars in Fearon and Laitin
diamonds = war onsets in oil exporters

Figure 3
Economic Structure and Civil Wars after 1945

Figure 4
Economic Structure and Guerrillas before 1945

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 407

Figure 5
Economic Structure and Guerrillas after 1945

of guerrillas is more widespread than systematic civil wars. This is in


line with the model, for the following reason. The model predicts that
given a certain economic structure, the level and type of violence will
be shaped by the costs of violence. More expensive forms of violence
will be less frequent than cheaper and more sporadic types. Although
also hard to organize, guerrilla warfare is easier to generate and sustain
than a full-scale war.
Figures 6 and 7 display the distribution of revolutionary events be-
fore and after 1945. As predicted by the model, they also cluster in
unequal agrarian economies: pre-Second World War Southern and
Eastern Europe, Czarist Russia, Central and South America, Cuba,
mid-twentieth-century China, Vietnam, Cambodia, and most sub-
Saharan and Middle Eastern states.

Estimation

The graphical evidence presented thus far supports the model of the ar-
ticle. But, naturally, we need to control for the impact of other variables
in the current literature on political violence (such as per capita income,
population, political regime, geography, and ethnic and religious com-
position) to probe the validity of this article's theoretical model. Tables

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Figure 6
Economic Structure and Revolutionary Events before 1945

Figure 7
Economic Structure and Revolutionary Events after 1945

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 409

1 and 3 report the multivariate analysis of the factors influencing both


onset and incidence of civil wars. Table 4 examines the correlates of
guerrilla warfare. Table 6 considers revolutionary events.
For each class of political violence I consider three types of specifi-
cations. The first one includes data prior to 1950 (since 1860 for civil
wars and since 1919 for the rest of violent events); this data set maxi-
mizes the number of observations, which range from about 8,900 to
6,200 country-years but cannot include variables such as ethnic or reli-
gious composition, for which good information is available only for the
post-World War II period.31
To expand the number of independent variables that may compete
with the models explanation, the second specification includes data only
for the second half of the twentieth century: the number of observations
drops by about a third, but the list of controls is much longer. Gener-
ally speaking, all coefficients remain very stable across the two models;
whenever they change, they do not affect the thrust of the argument.
Finally, the third specification substitutes direct measures of income
inequality (the Gini index) for the distribution of property. This latter
model is run only for post-World War II. The pooled data are much
smaller than in the other two models: the number of observations falls
to about 700. But even with these limitations, its results validate the
core of the theory.

INDEPENDENT VARIABLES

In the first two specifications, I employ the following independent v


ables:
1. Lagged Value of War Incidence y that is, whether there was an o
ing war or guerrilla warfare in the previous year or not.
2. Percentage of Family Farms.
3. Index of Occupational Diversification, that is, the average of in
trialization and urbanization.32
4. Interaction of the two previous variables. Our theoretical expec
tion is that the interactive coefficient should be statistically signif
and with a negative sign.
31 The use of Correlates of War data reduces the danger of missing data bias considerably. F
period from 1800 to 1999 there are 14,792 country-year observations of sovereign states. For
riod from 1850 to 1999 there are 12,972 country-years. The Correlates of War data set covers
country-years and 12,289 country-years, respectively. The Vanhanen data include 10,462 co
years since 1850 or about 85 percent of the data. Two-thirds of the data not covered by the Va
data belong to small countries (those with fewer than six million inhabitants). The fall to less
8,900 observations in Table 1 results from employing income, population, and political regime
32 1 have also used each variable (industrialization and urbanization) separately without any c
in the results I reproduce below.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
410 WORLD POLITICS

In the third specification, wh


equality employing direct mea
2\ Gini Index of Income Ineq
and adjusted to control for cr
to measure income distribution
3'. Average Share of Agricultu
4\ Interaction between Gini
The coefficient of this variab
nificant.

CONTROL VARIABLES

I add the following control variables in all specifications:


5. Log Value of Population, taken from Banks.34
6. Log Value of Per Capita Income. This variable is built wit
reported in the Penn World Tables 6.1, covering the period from
to 1999, plus data from Maddison that provides observations f
period previous to 1950 (essentially for developed countries an
large Asian and Latin American cases), adjusted to make it com
with the Summers-Heston data set, and some interpolated data
Bourguignon and Morrison.35 Per capita income is given in co
dollars of 1996.
7. Democracy. This variable is taken from Boix and Rosato,
code all sovereign countries from 1800 to 1999 as either democrat
authoritarian. Countries are coded as democracies if they meet
conditions: elections are free and competitive; the executive is acc
able to citizens (either through elections in presidential systems o
the legislative power in parliamentary regimes); and at least 50 pe
of the male electorate is enfranchised.36
33 Klaus Deininger and Lyn Squire, "A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequality," World
Economic Review 19 (September 1996).The cross- national variation is a function of the choi
recipient unit (individual or household), the use of gross versus net income, and the use of ex
or income. Following the suggestions of Deininger and Squire, the adjusted Gini is equal to
coefficient plus 6.6 points in observations based on expenditure (versus income) and 3 points
vations using net rather than gross income. The results reported do not vary if I use unadju
coefficients. The year-country adjusted Gini coefficient employed in the sample is a five-yea
of adjusted Gini coefficients. This procedure minimizes the volatility in the inequality mea
maximizes the number of observations (approximately doubling them).
34Banks(fn.22).
35 Alan Heston, Robert Summers, and Bettina Aten, Penn World Table Version 6.1 (Ce
International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania, 2002); Angus Maddison, M
the World Economy, 1820-1992 (Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Deve
1995); Francois Bourguignon and Christian Morrison, "Inequality among World Citizen
1992," American Economic Review 92 (September 2002). For the post-1950 period I use th
and Laitin (fn. 4) definition of per capita income.
36 Carles Boix and Sebastian Rosato, "A Complete Data Set of Political Regimes, 1800
(Manuscript, University of Chicago, 2001).

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 411

ADDITIONAL CONTROL VARIABLES AFTER 1950

For the specifications including postwar data only, I add the following
variables:
8. Log of Percentage of Mountainous Territory,
9. Noncontiguous Territory, A dummy variable coded 1 if the state
is composed of noncontiguous territories. Both this variable and the
previous one test for the presence of structural (geographical) barriers
to violence.
10. Oil Exports. A dummy variable coded as 1 if oil represents more
than one-third of the country's exports. (Following Humphreys and
Ross I have also substituted fuel production and fuel reserves per capita
for the dummy variable. Fuel reserves per capita should mitigate some
endogeneity problems since conflict or the anticipation of conflict may
affect actual oil production).37
11. Political Instability. A dummy variable indicating whether a
country has a change of three or greater in the Polity IV regime index
in the three years prior to the country-year in question. The last four
variables are taken from Fearon and Laitin.38
11. Ethnic Fractionalization.This measure is computed as one minus
the Herfindhal index of ethnolinguistic group shares, with new data
gathered and calculated in Alesina et al.39
12. Religious Fractionalization, computed as one minus the Herfind-
hal index of religious groups, taken from Alesina et al.40 For both frac-
tionalization measures I include their square transformation.
13. Percentage of Muslims, Catholics y and Protestants, taken from
LaPorta et al.41
14. Rate of Economic Growth (in the year before the observed event).

Civil Wars

Table 1 reports the covariates of civil war from 1860 to 1997, employ-
ing the coding of the Correlates of War data set. In Models 1-3 th
dependent variable is war onset, coded as 1 when there is a war start,

37 Macartan Humphreys, "Natural Resources, Conflict, and Conflict Resolution: Uncovering the
Mechanisms ," Journal of Conflict Resolution 49 (August 2005); Michael Ross, "A Closer Look at Oil
Diamonds, and Civil War," Annual Review of Political Science 9 (2006).
38 Fearon and Laitin (fn. 4).
39 Alberto Alesina, Arnaud Devleeschauwer, William Easterly, Sergio Kurlat, and Romain Wacz-
iarg, "FractionzHzation" Journal of Economic Growth 8 (June 2003).
40 Ibid.
41 Rafael LaPorta, Florencio Lopez de Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, "The Quality
of Government," Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 15 (March 1999).

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
c

J$
f ^ ^ ^ ^ ^ t ^ ^ '2
On ^ CO O»^ ^ (NvO ^ Op ^ O^O ^ voo ^ N»O ^ 2
> H t (NT-HrHTHO^U^(N0000OU^ G
^lO"t pppppppTHrHpOCN W
^^ncoo do do do do do do g

S Ov f _ t ^
"^ ^i f ^n ^ ^ 5 _ ,- v ^ 5 ^ ^ ^ OOsO
QiorH r^vooot^u^mvooosovocnt^rs^ ^ oo I
"b»ooco ooooco^-«\oo^-icn^cor>I<N \o ■*■
fS H 00 pppppptHi-H^-jOtHrHoO^H ^ J«
(NO 000000000000^0000 ^

« vO t <N(Nr-HTt^Ht^ON(^r^00sOt^ ^

K -§i ^ ^ PppppOp^-Ji-Hpi-H<N ^
i^os^cod K ooododododoo §
"^ ^ T *o
« *^ «Ko^ u^io iovo n9 ioon" foP oon \o^ so *£
^ «^om ooooco^-ix-Hascocr»NO<NaNP <n S
^ il to^1^ PPPPPP^P^IPP1"!1^^ ^ a
•^ ^3 C^3C^3P3P3<0*3C*3V>0§00' 4r
I ' 2
< ^ 3^°^ u^O(N<NcOTfcot^KT-ir^t^ -rt
I> R *S *-• <*> (NT-l(N^-lrHCOOONT-l\OlO<N O
|> ^ ^.vq^ ppppppt-Hp^-|pp<N O g

hOS; ISA. . i
SOT* R S ^ r*00^ Ot Ml^ MM Hio ^ON vOO vOfS 00 <*
pq^JL
^ O ^ Rppppppi-jprHprH^-H^-,-
O ^ ^S<N\O ^ ^S<N\O ^ M On 0000(NT-HTj-as(N(N
XT) M .tJ
H^to ^ V^ (0*3c^3P3P3<0'3c^300c^00' 2

2 ^ ov ^-oo o9 coin on^o on^ oo9 cn9 vofq <noo r^ §


W n ^jI tnt-icnr^oooo<N^HmooNcoi-icni-Hco oo 5
W ^jw-> cnoqp^nppppppcN^HppptHco^: vq £
Q ~^so\ rHooddoodoooddoodu*>^-'oo v^ w w w ^^ ^^
•g<^ l^-^l^-' v^ w | w | w ^^ ^^ Cp g
"1 ^ t5
sJ^j^ \o^-HONT-i\o^tvoioK(NcocoovOrHrNi)0£2 ^o S
•jj^j ^mrHmoooorsjT-itNONCNCNmfNS;^ ^ ^
^yS^ ^^^^iPPPPPP^ip^-jpqTHgsd p ^
><g rHooddddooooodood ^od Go

|^§^ looHMM?io^Hfs^i^Tr^g^ 3 ^
^^ck ^^""J^PPPPPP^P^.PP^oo^ P t
fcSv© r-ldddddddododddod
jCS^Oo
^"^ ^-^ ^^ v-*' ^-^ n-^ ^Ood i « g
I ^"^ ^-^ ^^ v-*' i ^-^ i n-^ w|>^ i «
Is ^ ^c
1
i
1 *r Jr
rt ^ k. ,S th

s | p 81 ^^ 8.^ | ? 1122 ll
j 3 UUiSSiSSi iSU 'I

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS OC REVOLUTIONS 413

0 otherwise.42 The estimation is done through probit an


1 reports the results for the period from 1860 to 1997, m
the period from 1900 to 1997, and model 3 shows t
1945 to 1997. In all cases, the interactive term of fam
nonagrarian assets is statistically significant and has
pressing impact on the occurrence of civil wars. This res
graphical evidence and our theoretical expectations.4
that the coefficient increases in size as we move closer to our contem-
porary period.45
A simulation of the results (in model 1) is shown in Table 2 (with
all the remaining variables set at their median value, except the lagged
value of civil war and, naturally, family farms and occupational diversi-
fication). In countries with either less than 20 percent of the land held
by family farms or an average urbanization and industrialization be-
low 25 percent, the probability of a civil war starting (that is, with the
lagged value of the dependent variable set at 0) is more than 5 percent
over the course of a five-year period. Notice as well that, as predicted
in the discussion of the model of intraelite conflict, in predominantly
agrarian societies civil wars occur with a similar probability regardless
of the distribution of land. With growing economic diversification,
conflict declines. But it is when both equality and industrialization in-
crease that the probability of a civil war declines quickly. In countries
where family farms control more than 50 percent of the cultivated land
and average industrialization and urbanization are also over 50 percent,
the probability of a civil war occurring over a period of five years drops
below 1 percent.
Confirming all existing studies on the causes of civil wars, both pop-
ulation and per capita income are statistically significant and behave in
the theoretically expected direction. Per capita income decreases the
risk of civil war. With all other variables at the median values, the an-
nual probability of war onset declines from 2.4 percent for a per capita
income of $500 (in 1996 dollars) to 1.6 percent for $1,000 and less
than 0.5 percent for $5,000. Population increases the probability of a

42 Alternatively, I have coded war onset as 1 at the start of a war, 0 if there is no war, and missing
for all observations of ongoing war after the first observation. These alternative specifications do not
alter the results in any substantive manner.
43 Logit analysis does not change any of the results.
44 For the period 1850 to 1997, the interactive term is very similar in substantive terms to the coef-
ficient in column 1, close to statistical significance (p=0.137) alone and fully significant in a joint test
with the separate terms of the interaction.
45 Dropping income, population, and democracy as control variables, the number of observations
rises to 10,462 (or about 85 percent of all sovereign country-years) and the coefficients of the variables
of interests remain statistically significant and similar in size.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
414 WORLD POLITICS

1 ABLE 2
Predicted Probability of Civil War Onset over 5 Years by Size of
Agrarian Sector and Landholding Inequality

Share of Family Farms over Total Cultivated Land (Percentiles)


10 30 50 70 90

10 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.08


Index of 30 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02
Occupational 50 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.01
Diversification 70 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.00
90 0.04 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00

Lagged value of civil war set to 0; all other


Source: Simulation based on Table 1, colu

civil war. For all other variabl


of a civil war rises from 1 per
inhabitants to 1.7 percent in a
in a nation of half a billion i
small countries are less prone
countries is deceptive for two
has already pointed out that
old of conflict-related deaths
some underreporting of civil w
tion size has declining margin
Holding other things constan
inhabitants has a 2.7 percent c
year. If we split it into five c
at least one of them falls into
rally, the scale of the civil war
the actual occurrence of violen
tion involved. Finally, the coef
tistically significant.47
Models 3-6 in Table 1 explor
of civil wars. The estimation

46Sambanis (fn. 19); Nicholas Sambanis an


sults on Civil War Onset," Journal of Conf
by the fact that if we run the same model
sample), the coefficient of population beco
using the lower half). Conversely, excluding
statistically not significant if we only use th
47 Substituting democracy as defined in
the results.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 415

in which I calculate the effect of the independent variables


the likelihood of starting a war and the likelihood of sustaining
conditional on the initial state (peace or ongoing war). The d
probit model generates two sets of parameters: beta and alph
first parameter (the beta coefficient) estimates the probability o
tion from a situation of peace to one of civil war. The sum of t
coefficients (beta and alpha) indicates the probability that an
civil war will continue to take place. Once more, each column re
different time period: model 4 examines the period from 1860
model 5 looks at the twentieth century, and model 6 is restricted
post-World War II period.
Population increases the chances of a war onset but has no
on duration. Per capita income ceases to be significant. A mo
agrarian distribution and more industrialization have (as separat
ables) no impact on war starts but they seem to lengthen existi
flicts. However, even this last result stops being significant aft
(models 5 and 6). More important, the interactive term of fami
and nonagrarian assets continues to be strongly significant: it r
both the chances of a war onset and the length of conflicts.
Table 3 reports all (probit) estimations of civil war onsets
period after 1950. Models 1-3 employ the data sets of Fearon
Sambanis, and Uppsala-Prio with the specification of family far
nonagrarian assets. Models 4-6 employ the Gini index as a direct
sure of inequality. Estimating the models through dynamic pro
reported here for space limitations, leads to very similar results.
In models 1-3 the interaction of family farms and nonagra
sets is always statistically significant and has an even bigge
from a substantive point of view than in Table 1. In models 4-6
inequality is measured through the direct measure of the Gi
results are weaker but in the same direction. The interaction of
ture and income inequality is statistically significant in the
data set. In the Fearon-Laitin data set it achieves statistical sign
in a joint test. According to the results using the Sambanis data
increase in the interactive term of inequality and agriculture f
25th percentile to its 75 th percentile raises the likelihood of wa
to 26.4 percent (with all the other variables at their median var
Population and per capita income remain significant in mo
in Table 3; they do not, however, in models 4-6. Being an oil ex

48 For the estimation and properties of the dynamic probit model, see Takeshi Amemiy
Econometrics (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1985), chap. 11.
49 Results can be obtained from the author.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 3
Probit Analysis of Civil War Onsets after 1950

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

Fearon- Uppsala- Fearon- Uppsala-


Laitin Sambanis Prio Laitin Sambanis Prio
1950-97 1950-99 1950-99 1950-97 1950-99 1950-99

Constant -3.254*** -3.396*** -3.939*** -29.205 8.059 12.810

(1.121) (1.028) (1.297) (23.433) (9.058) (12.689)

Prior War -0.429** -0.186 -0.531* -1.620 -0.266

(0.170) (0.138) (0.311) (1.112) (0.388)

Percentage of 0.020*** 0.015*** 0.023***


Family Farms (0.007) (0.006) (0.008)

Index of Occupational 0.012 0.006 0.022***


Diversification (0.008) (0.007) (0.008)

Family Farms* -0.040** -0.026* -0.041**


Occupational Divers. (0.016) (0.013) (0.017)

Gini Index of Inequality -0.076A -0.178* -0.060


(0.145) (0.092) (0.101)

Share of Agriculture -0.134A -0.203 -0.129


over GDP (0.186) (0.125) (0.166)

Gini Index* 0.550A 0.617* 0.249

Agriculture/GDP (0.488) (0.350) (0.403)

Log of Population t-1 0.131*** 0.103** 0.107** -0.143 -0.141 -0.075


(0.049) (0.044) (0.054) (0.363) (0.229) (0.244)

Log of per Capita -0.254* -0.160 -0.247* 0.314 -0.699 -1.634**


Income t-1 (0.134) (0.120) (0.146) (0.723) (0.621) (0.819)

Growth rate t-2 to t-1 -0.083 -0.783 -1.429* 3.559 0.062 -6.662
(0.847) (0.681) (0.786) (4.311) (3.103) (4.265)

Democracy t-1 0.135 -0.011 0.051 0.306 0.110 0.169


(0.144) (0.136) (0.163) (0.587) (0.433) (0.535)

Log (Percentage 0.085* 0.086* 0.154** 0.122 -0.047 0.028


Mountainous) (0.049) (0.044) (0.061) (0.318) (0.241) (0.295)

Noncontiguous State 0.105 -0.028 0.084 0.927 1.149* 1.878**


(0.167) (0.153) (0.181) (0.956) (0.592) (0.858)

Oil Exporter 0.203 0.305* 0.174 0.867 0.995


(0.180) (0.159) (0.192) (0.836) (0.958)

Political Instability 0.272** 0.344*** 0.282** 0.381 0.141 0.512


(0.127) (0.115) (0.140) (0.507) (0.458) (0.565)

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 417

Table 3, cont
Mode/1 Mode/2 Mode/3 Mode/4 Model 5 Model 6

Fearon- Uppsala- Fearon- Uppsala-


Lai tin Sambanis Prio Laitin Sambanis Prio
1950-97 1950-99 1950-99 1950-97 1950-99 1950-99

Ethnic Fractionalization 1.063 0.530 0.394 2.696 2.698 7.130

(1.071) (0.960) (1.242) (6.286) (3.174) (5.203)

(Ethnic -0.965 -0.203 0.334 -1.394 -3.784 -11.364


Fractionalization)2 (1.116) (0.982) (1.254) (9.712) (4.540) (7.333)

Religious 1.297 2.438** 0.412 70.767 9.639 3.870


Fractionalization (1.127) (1.079) (1.325) (48.509) (9.238) (14.836)

(Religious -1.226 -2.428* 0.780 -45.697 -6.695 -3.068


Fractionalization)2 (1.343) (1.279) (1.670) (30.331) (6.412) (9.925)
Percentage of Muslims 0.004* 0.002 0.004 0.006 -0.000 -0.001
(0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.008) (0.008) (0.009)

Percentage of Catholics 0.004 0.002 0.006* -0.001 0.006 0.005


(0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.012) (0.008) (0.010)

Percentage of Protestants 0.002 -0.001 -0.020* -0.174 -0.028 -0.075


(0.006) (0.006) (0.011) (0.295) (0.053) (0.119)

Observations 4239 4239 4239 705 705 694

Log Likelihood -276.30 -341.47 -218.40 -28.37 -45.30 -27.36


Prob>chi2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0023 0.0045 0.1699
PseudoR2 0.1109 0.1129 0.1396 0.4112 0.3008 0.3010

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%; A


Estimation: probit analysis; standard errors in parentheses

does not lead to more civil wars except in th


significant result in the Sambanis data set is p
that it codes a significantly larger number o
ers than in other data sets, for example, elev
Fearon and Laitin.51 Geography has a partial
mountainous terrain is positive and significa

S0In model 4 oil drops out because it predicts all failures perf
production per capita and fuel reserves per capita does not chan
from Humphreys (fn. 37).
51 For a discussion of the effect that oil may have in strengthen
increased possibilities for rebels," see James D. Fearon, "Primar
Journal of Conflict Resolution 49 (August 2005), 487.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
418 WORLD POLITICS

trast, the effect of noncontig


Political instability is positivel
Neither ethnic fractionaliza
statistically significant in mo
of Muslims and Catholics has a
not in a systematic manner
the existing literature, econ
violence. 53

Guerrilla Warfare

Table 4 reports the covariates of guerrilla warfare. Models 1 an


the data coded by Banks for the period 1919-97.54 Because t
data set does not distinguish between guerrilla onsets and
ing years with ongoing guerrilla warfare, the estimation loo
incidence of guerrilla warfare and is done through a dynam
model.55 Model 1 runs the model for the whole period 1919-97.
2 restricts the analysis to the period after 1950 to expand the nu
control variables. Model 3 substitutes the Gini index for the pe
of family farms. Finally, models 4 and 5 estimate the covariate
onset of those violent conflicts coded as "minor conflicts" (that
with a number of deaths between 25 and 999) in the Uppsala-Pr
set. These two latter models employ a probit specification: the
looks at the impact of family farms and nonagrarian assets; th
one employs the Gini index as an independent variable.
The results for guerrilla incidence parallel those for civil war
effect of inequality and asset specificity is very similar in statis
nificance and substantial size for both guerrilla war and civil w
interaction reduces the incidence of guerrilla warfare. Table 5 s
the probability of a guerrilla starting (setting the lagged v
over a five-year period (the remaining variables are set at their
value). For low levels of family farms and industrialization, the

52 The variable of anocracy or semidemocracy (any case that scores between -5 and
substract the measure of democracy from the measure of autocracy in Polity IV) has no
significance and has been dropped from the estimations. Similarly, a variable measuring
independence" (under the assumption that states gain in stability over time) is not statisti
cant and does not change any of the results presented in this article.
53 On economic crises and violence, see Collier and Hoeffler (fn. 7); Edward Migu
Satyanath, and Ernest Sergenti, "Economic Shocks and Civil Conflict: An Instrument
Approach," Journal of Political Economy 112 (August 2004).
54Banks(fn.22).
55 In a probit model with guerrilla onsets as the dependent variable and the lagged value
guerrilla as an independent variable, the latter predicts failures perfectly and drops out of
tions jointly with a large number of observations.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 419

ability fluctuates around 35 percent. In fact, it increases slightly wit


each value separately - this may be capturing the fact that societ
with family farms may organize violence more easily. Nonetheless, as
both variables increase, the probability drops: it falls below 10 percen
at the median values of both variables and below 5 percent for val
common in developed countries.
Since guerrilla warfare is a far more widespread phenomenon th
civil wars, factors other than land inequality and asset mobility must
account for the formers higher probability.56 Per capita income b
comes not significant from a statistical point of view in most models
Population continues to be associated with violent events. Democ
racy now increases the likelihood of guerrilla movements in the whol
sample. This may be related to the fact that, at least for small-sc
violence, democracy may have weaker short-run repressive capaci
than dictatorships. It is the variables of ethnicity and geography that
turn out to be relevant. Ethnic fractionalization, which becomes s
tistically significant, has a substantial, hump-shaped effect. With
other values at their median, a highly fragmented country (with an i
dex of 0.08, which corresponds to the 10th percentile of the universe
of observations) has an annual probability of having a guerrilla move-
ment of about 5.7 percent. This probability peaks at 7.6 percent amon
countries with an ethnic fractionalization of 0.45 (about the 60th per
centile) and then declines to 3.7 percent for the most homogeneo
country in the sample (with an ethnic fractionalization index of 0.93)
Not unexpectedly, geography also plays a stronger role than for c
wars. Mountainous terrain leads to more guerrillas: with all other
rameters at their medians, the probability changes from 5.4 percent fo
the minimum value to 7.5 percent for the 50th percentile and to 10.0
percent for the maximum value. Noncontiguous states are also mu
more prone to violence: the probability of a guerrilla increases by 12.
percent (relative to contiguous countries).

Revolutionary Outbreaks

Table 6 examines the sources of revolutionary events. All estimatio


are done through a dynamic probit analysis because, as in the data
guerrilla warfare examined in Table 4, the Banks data set does not dis
tinguish between revolutionary outbreaks and successive years of rev-
olutionary activities. Model 1 reports the results for the period from
1919 to 1997. Models 2 and 3 examine the period from 1950 to 199

56 Again, all these comments are mostly based on models 1 and 2, which are based on large data sets.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
** ^ > tj- ov m h oon v^m oi- noo
^~D>^£ ^ onooono Ttcoo^or^iosOT-H
« •§ *q r ^ ^ ^ ^ qq ho oh nn
O ^ >£ O (NLooo oooooooo

c>G-'vL> (NmTHTj-comLomvoo rsco


.s \1 S ^ tosocootNOtNO^rH oom

<

w o o* Tj-f^r^^vn^ONf^"
^SOncO w i^ir) tM ON >^t
<L toN pppH(Nrv|H(N

1^ <
_ \}psO OpHp(NrHrHp

^ ^ ^ ^ ^ ^ ^
^ O q CT^ 00 CT^ 00 vO OO ^5 t"*"* O^ ^-O
hJ ^r* i»^ 00 ^J" ^5 C^ ^D C3 ^D t-H 00 l/*>

~ <-> vj _f^oo ir^ tJ- oo tt vo oo hN


c^> ? ^vOto OOOO(NO COCS
f-i -^ «! Nvq pppppp <~!P
Z *q °Qcsio oooopo oo

h fe i ^ _ ♦ ^ ^ ! ^
<! M IO OOHOOrH HCO
4^,1-hoo pppppp ^~!P
^jcno oooooo 90'

^«Os(N
1^ M^CO ^
(N
i ~
^ CO HI? ~ 00,-s
i
«5hcO OOOOCNO OsOO
^(N^ pppppp ^ '"I
^coo^ 00^00^03 ^3

1 lill lif !itf

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
"^ «w. "& eNONOocN^NOcNcoooHONinTi-ONvooNr^sOHONor^
R-g "*3 R OfO vOfO i;O| HH ^-co vO^t OM NN q4 NOq (NO
O<^^0
■Vj Qoo^^^oo^oooooooorHi-HcocsicotncoTfr | ^-^
^ | ^-^ **S | "»- • V_^ V_X V_X V«^/ **S V^^
j V»^ | "»-I •V_
V_^• V_X V_X V

.S^~^»^ oooNONLocootocou^T-HaN(NoaNOcocoooTHr^ooco
^ §R ^OOOlOOfHOO^Hi-jOtHOO^f^Ot^^Ht^rHON
I^O od do od do do do do ho ho ho ho

w OsON (N^ ON00 ^r^» ONCO t-lO OOTf (NNOOav^OOOO


^S w On N 0000 O"4- H ^- O^ On^ \O(N (O N H n OO H lo
^^ ^^ <- ?°^ ^t"^ ^^i ^^ ^ ^ ^^ ^t1"! ^O1"! ^^ ^O1^:

IT? °^ v~^

(NvO t-hvO U-^00 rf<N W On 00^-t noP ^O^ ^On" (N^ (N^
Q OOIO On M ^"^ "<Ti-H VOCO \Ot-I IO 00 00 O U-) t- I vO"^T ^J"O
- N \» ^^ ^^ ^^ (- I *"*. ^^ ^^ ^.^i ^^9 ^^ ^i1^ ^"1^:
•3 QQ OOcOoioOOOOOOOOO(N^^*rsi\diOU^co

^ ^- S X-V /--N ^- S $ /^-V /- X •-V /*->. /^-S X-^ /^-S


5> ?S fOO> ^- S (NM X-V ION /--N N't ^- S ^Ot /^-V MO /- X tvO •-V O>N /*->. N^cnfS^vO /^-S X-^
*- ^ ?S LnTtcovootncovorssotncsooir>t^iovor^<NTft^^H
^ ^OH v£)ON HH OO COH fO(N HH NH TffS NCO O^N
•ii ^ ododododododddHHHHOHHH T-T-T-T
| T-T-T-T-T-T- - _,_T- -
l||
v* \OvO>(NONNOONHOO>ONsO<Nir)TfHOHOOtor^(NTfcOs
R 5S 0000 (NM O>O0 NfN) O>O> \OH NO> NO> HU^ rSl/1 t^
«& ^5 OOr^toHOOO^OOHOOU^ii-ju-)\q<N\pfSt^

I
^ H H P ^

m On vo CO O
h2 O va i-i t^
^ <o> a> cn q

2 S frills
i-H
r^i *2
§ "' S§ § S § 'g »3 I 1- "
A I fi 8 I 3 i -si 4 •&!

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
*O ^ ^-v ^

*- ^ < I- ^Y- 100

^ 1 - ~ ~
.R^;§^ OOOOOO^fNO«Ti
<; ^ v^t>^ vooo

i 88 88 SS
^ o d o d d d

(N^1 O^" OnO^ cOOOO^1 <2


-^ ^joooooor^-xor^ J«
-^ •g oqdddddd PPt ^
§ I
^ .S
L§ ^ ^ ^ B


4 ii
§,888838 | »
^pddddd *-^

•g ociddddpd^oP^ S ^

o ^ # s

^ T s *

^ «
^
CN
-I1
CO O On
-3
- T3
"g ^ 00 O vO | - O
On O O u-^ •-

s4 S O f£ "5 o S
ill H
S ooog^g *j ^
0> D W O »^i fSI 4-> "

i f 0> ip D f W |ls?
I s s s S^y -I 1 1

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 423

Table 5
Predicted Probability of Guerrilla Warfare Onset over 5 Years by
Size of Agrarian Sector and Landholding Inequality

Share of Family Farms over Total Cultivated Land (Percen tiles)


10 30 50 70 90

10 0.36 0.37 0.38 0.40 0.41


Index of 30 0.36 0.32 0.28 0.24 0.21
Occupational 50 0.36 0.27 0.20 0.14 0.10
Diversification 70 0.36 0.23 0.14 0.08 0.04
90 0.37 0.19 0.09 0.04 0.02

Lagged value of guerrilla warfare set to 0;


Source: Simulation based on Table 4, colu

Both the distribution and th


nificant and behave in the pre
effect in Table 7 (employing m
years the combination of lan
probability of a revolutionary
tion of family farms and an i
percent) to 28 percent for valu
percent in very industrialized,
Per capita income now enters
other values at their median, t
event is 15.2 percent for a cou
income, 11.5 percent at the m
centile. Only population is sign
matter. Geography is irrelevan
may raise the length of revolu
not statistically significant. Et
ability of revolutionary event
societies are either very fragm

Regional and Feriod Effects

All the variables of interest (on type and nature of assets) in


3, 4, and 6 are robust to the addition of dummies for each
tal region (but one) and for each decade (but one). Broadly
regional dummies are not statistically significant. By contras
dummies have statistical significance and tend to capture the
fluctuations in occurrence of violence across the world.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 6
Determinants of Revolutionary Outbreaks

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3


1850-1997 1950-97 1950-97

Beta Alpha Beta Alpha Beta Alpha


Constant -0.010 1.138 0.337 -1.977 2.642-170.449**
(0.409) (0.826) (0.670) (1.442) (3.602) (76.926)
Percentage of Family 0.002 -0.000 0.009** -0.006
Farms t-1 (0.003) (0.005) (0.004) (0.008)
Index of Occupational 0.003 0.010* 0.008* 0.001
Diversification t-1 (0.003) (0.006) (0.004) (0.010)
Family Farms t-1* -0.022*** 0.013 -0.027*** 0.043**
Occupational Divers. (0.006) (0.014) (0.009) (0.021)
Gini Index of Inequality t-1 -0.071*** 0.440*
(0.025) (0.244)
Share of Agriculture -0.185*** 0.526
over gdp t-1 (0.051) (0.407)
Gini Index * 0.492*** -0.911
Agriculture over gdp t-1 (0.123) (0.980)
Log Population t-1 0.044*** 0.032 0.027 0.015 0.064 0.475
(0.017) (0.034) (0.028) (0.062) (0.077) (1.187)
Log (per Capita Income) t-1 -0.207*** -0.091 -0.298*** 0.082 -0.464* 5.735*
(0.053) (0.105) (0.084) (0.162) (0.270) (3.330)
Growth Rate t-2 to t-1 -0.714 0.177 1.279 -4.032
(0.533) (0.886) (1.891) (9.625)
Democracy t-1 0.032 0.077 0.015 0.182 -0.043 3.437**
(0.067) (0.128) (0.088) (0.174) (0.210) (1.447)
Log (Percentage 0.009 0.128** 0.018 -1.026
Mountainous) (0.028) (0.060) (0.094) (0.706)
Noncontiguous State 0.100 0.104 0.127 -4.567
(0.102) (0.211) (0.259) (4.373)
Oil Exporter 0.189* -0.439** 0.306
(0.113) (0.213) (0.311)
Political Instability 0.350*** -0.042 0.503** 2.256
(0.084) (0.147) (0.220) (1.992)
Ethnic Fractionalization -1.029* 3.513*** 1.106 23.302
(0.604) (1.294) (1.319) (20.015)
(Ethnic 1.369** -3.252** -3.110* -14.675
Fractionalization)2 (0.654) (1.343) (1.793) (29.347)
Religious Fractionalization 0.152 2.605* 5.484 215.639**
(0.666) (1.424) (3.726)(107.935)

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS &C REVOLUTIONS 425

Table 6, cont.

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3


1850-1997 1950-97 1950-97

Beta Alpha Beta Alpha Beta Alpha


(Religious -0.340 -1.764 -4.352-130.691*
Fractionalization)2 (0.785) (1.800) (2.735) (67.527)
Percentage of Muslims -0.000 0.004 -0.005 0.027
(0.002) (0.003) (0.003) (0.037)
Percentage of Catholics 0.003** 0.003 -0.004 0.045
(0.001) (0.003) (0.003) (0.037)
Percentage of Protestants -0.006 0.006 -0.010 1.037**
(0.004) (0.009) (0.009) (0.406)
Observations 6243 3937 699

Log Likelihood -2140.76 -1275.64 -154.77


Prob>chi2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
PseudoR2 0.1954 0.2322 0.3503

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** si

Table 7
Predicted Probability of Revolutionary Events over 5 Years by
Economic Structure and Land Inequality

Share of Family Farms over Total Cultivated Land (Percentiles)


10 30 50 70 90

10 0.77 0.77 0.76 0.76 0.75


Index of 30 0.65 0.56 0.48 0.40 0.34
Occupational 50 0.54 0.39 0.28 0.19 0.13
Diversification 70 0.45 0.27 0.15 0.08 0.04
90 0.37 0.18 0.08 0.03 0.01

Lagged value of revolutionary outbreak set


Source: Simulation based on Table 6, colu

Lndogeneity

When exploring the impact that the nature and distribution of we


has on political violence, we need to address the issue of reverse cau
that is, the probability that violence affects the types of economic
ity and income distribution and not the other way around.
An alternative account (to the model of the article) - in whic
equality and asset specificity do not lead to political violence b

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
426 WORLD POLITICS

which, instead, it is civil wars


ate a particular distribution o
lines. At some initial moment
social conditions. Only those e
unknown or random reasons)
as a result, remained stuck in
Accordingly, the interpretatio
ticle would be wrong: we wou
the underdevelopment and ine
place (and where the former
lence in some type of vicious
A strict interpretation of th
litical violence precedes pove
given what we know about t
and patterns of wealth distrib
the patterns of ownership (an
of the process of state buildin
established to secure external
tion of wealth, ranging from
tively equal farming commun
by different kinds of militar
the presence or absence of in
competing with the rulers, an
or less hierarchical and more
of a specific political (and ec
contemporary period by mass
this article, this is, civil wars
intensity of the violence depe
of assets and on the progres
accelerated in the nineteenth
litical actors and social groups
tern may suffice here to clari
in which settlers organized t
property of land determined
chances to grow and acquire
the Spanish colonies were stru

57 Douglass C. North, "A Framework for


in Economic History 16 (July 1979); Dougla
York: Norton, 1981); Mancur Olson, Power
58 See also Carles Boix and Frances Rose
Height Inequality" (Manuscript, Princeton

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 427

arrangements, the Northeastern colonies and Canada were settled by


communities of farmers.59 After independence and as political mobi-
lization grew, violence varied accordingly. Latin America experienced
considerable levels of violence in the nineteenth and twentieth cen-
turies. Canada and the Northern states of the United States did not.
Similarly, the distribution of land in Russia or the American South
also preceded and generated the Soviet revolution and the Civil War,
respectively.60
To tackle the extent to which modern political violence precedes eco-
nomic conditions or simply shapes them, I engage in two exercises. First,
I take advantage of the time dimension of the panel of world nations and
conduct a Granger causality test between types of political violence and
wealth inequality and asset specificity. Second, I instrument for the inde-
pendent variable interacting inequality and capital specificity.
The Granger causality test - with individual equation estimates for
one and two lags - is presented in Table 8. To have a long data series, I
explore only the data from the COW and Banks sets (which extend be-
fore World War II). Except for revolutionary events, the lagged values
of the interaction of agrarian property and weight of agriculture affect
significantly - or jointly significantly for two lags - the occurrence of
political violence in the expected direction. By contrast, the past occur-
rence of political violence does not significantly enter in the regression
of the interaction of type and distribution of wealth.
Table 9 reproduces the instrumentation exercise. Showing that non-
European countries where Europeans faced high mortality rates and
where the latter emigrated in small numbers resulted in stagnant polit-
ical economies, some recent empirical work has attributed the outcome
of underdevelopment to the design of inefficient political institutions.61
However, some recent contributions link the patterns of European
settlement to the distribution of land, to differential rates of invest-
ment on human capital formation, and therefore to overall inequality.62

59 Elisa Mariscal and Kenneth L. Sokoloff, "Schooling, Suffrage, and the Persistence of Inequal-
ity in the Americas, 1800-1945," in Stephen Harber, ed., Political Institutions and Economic Growth
in Latin America: Essays in Policy, History, and Political Economy (Stanford, Calif: Hoover Institution
Press, 2000), chap. 5.
60To put it differently, this article does not deny that the construction of the state was intertwined
with the use of violence. What it simply does is to focus in the analysis of violence after a given political
and economic arrangement had been constituted.
61 Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson, The Colonial Origins of Compara-
tive Development: An Empirical Investigation," American Economic Review 91 (December 2001).
62 E. Glaeser, R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Shleifer, Do Institutions Cause Growth?
Journal of Economic Growth 9 (September 2004); Stanley L. Engerman and Kenneth L. Sokoloff,
"Colonialism, Inequality, and Long- Run Paths of Development," nber Working Paper no. 11057
(January 2005).

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 8
Granger Causality Test

A. Civil War
Mode/1 Mode/2 Mode/3 Mode/4

Civil War Family. Farms Civil War Fam


* Occ. Diversif. * Occ. Diversif.
Constant -0.037** 0.992*** -0.041*** -0.279
(0.015) (0.358) (0.014) (0.351)
Civil War t-1 0.509*** 0.744 0.471*** 0.285
(0.026) (0.610) (0.022) (0.553)
Civil War t-2 -0.146*** -0.668
(0.028) (0.637)
Percentage of Family Farms t-1 0.002** 0.023 0.002*** 0.009
(0.001) (0.021) (0.000) (0.011)
Percentage of Family Farms t-2 -0.000 -0.012
(0.001) (0.021)
Index of Occupational 0.003** -0.176*** 0.001*** 0.069***
Diversification t-1 (0.001) (0.028) (0.000) (0.010)
Index of Occupational -0.002 0.297***
Diversification, t-2 (0.001) (0.031)
Family Farms.t-1 * -0.004* 0.722*** -0.003*** 0.919***
Occup. Diversif. t-1 (0.002) (0.044) (0.001) (0.019)
Family Farms t-2 0.002 0.192***
(0.002) (0.048)
Observations 1743 1877 1894 2057
Adjusted R-squared 0.1482 0.8989 0.1536 0.8844

B. Guerrilla
Modell Model2 Model 3 Model4

Guerrilla Family Farms Guerrilla


* Occ. Diversif. * Occ. Diversif.
Constant -0.000 -0.600 0.003 0.671
(0.035) (0.711) (0.030) (0.636)
Guerrilla t-1 0.338*** 0.067 0.332*** 0.293
(0.033) (0.667) (0.027) (0.582)
Guerrilla t-2 0.009 1.061*
(0.031) (0.635)
Family Farms t-1 0.002* -0.001 0.003*** 0.012
(0.001) (0.026) (0.001) (0.016)
Family Farms t-2 0.000 -0.005
(0.01) (0.027)

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Table 8, cont.

B. Guerrilla
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

Guerrilla Family Farms Guerrilla F


* Occ. Diversif * Occ. Diversif.
Occupational Div. t-1 -0.001 -0.161*** 0.002** 0.096***
(0.002) (0.036) (0.001) (0.016)
Occupational Div. t-2 0.003 0.333***
(0.002) (0.040)
Family Farms t-1 * -0.004 0.694*** -0.004*** 0.815***
Occup. Diversification t-1 (0.003) (0.056) (0.001) (0.030)
Family Farms t-2 0.000 0. 126**
Occup. Diversification t-2 (0.003) (0.061)
Observations 1083 1138 1320 1375
Adjusted R-squared -0.0014 0.7999 0.0101 0.7821

C. Revolutionary Events
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
Revolutions F. Farms Revolutions F Farms
* Occ. Div. * Occ. Div.

Constant 0.014 -0.736 0.038 0.673


(0.061) (0.717) (0.050) (0.641)
Revolutions t-1 0.359*** -0.545 0.337*** -0.053
(0.037) (0.450) (0.029) (0.375)
Revolutions t-2 0.032 0.584
(0.036) (0.419)
Family Farms t-1 0.001 0.000 0.001 0.013
(0.002) (0.026) (0.001) (0.016)
Family Farms t-2 0.001 0.000
(0.002) (0.027)
Occupational Div. t-1 -0.003 -0.162*** 0.002 0.096***
(0.003) (0.036) (0.001) (0.016)
Occupational Div. t-2 0.005 0.340***
(0.003) (0.040)
F. Farms * Occup. t-1 -0.000 0.694*** -0.002 0.812***
(0.005) (0.056) (0.002) (0.030)
F. Farms * Occup. t-2 -0.002 0.116*
(0.005) (0.061)
Observations 1083 1138 1320 1375

Adjusted R-squared

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant a

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
430 WORLD POLITICS

Accordingly, to instrument f
ploy the percent of European
which is well correlated with
of -0.58), gives us observatio
forces us to drop all European
latitudinal distance to equator
areas with a climate similar
are well captured by distance
ment of Europeans, the mor
more equal and the more ind
This second instrument allow
observations (including now
Models 1 and 2 in Table 9 repo
family farms and economic di
by latitude distance to equ
on civil wars (using the Fea
look at guerrillas. Models 5 an
events. The interaction of equ
ing latitude holds very well (m
violence and it is statistically
the percentage of European po
(except for revolutions, where
icance. It is significant, howev
(with which the index is subst
per capita income (which doe
the first-stage estimation), th
cance. Overall, the results con
the level of inequality and asse
Still, the results of this artic
ing the hypothesis that politi
ment. Some researchers hav
that political violence reduces
consider a more eclectic argum

63 An alternative variable, the rate of Eu


observations (forty versus more than sixt
of Europeans in 1900 as an instrument to
civil war onsets. See Simeon Djankov and
(Manuscript, May 2007), http://ssrn.com/
64 Robert Hall and Charles Jones, "Why
Worker than Others?" Quarterly Journal o
65 Roberto Perotti, "Growth, Income Dis
of Economic Growth 1 (June 1996); Robert
Press, 1997).

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 431

Table 9
Instrumenting for Inequality and Asset Specificity
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

Dependent Variable: Civil Wars (F-L) Guerrillas

Constant -1.165* -0.632 -1.786*** -0.937** -0.406 0.378

(0.654) (0.578) (0.533) (0.438) (0.399) (0.342)


Family Farms* -0.011** -0.008A -0.014*** -0.007 -0.009*** -0.002AA
Index of Divers. (0.005) (0.006) (0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.003)

Log of Population 0.086*** 0.102*** 0.080*** 0.080*** 0.025* 0.015


(0.021) (0.027) (0.017) (0.021) (0.013) (0.016)

Log of Income 0.092 -0.003A 0.190*** 0.065 0.060 -0.042AA


per Capita (0.082) (0.065) (0.067) (0.049) (0.050) (0.039)
Observations 86 60 86 60 86 60

R-squared 0.09 0.23 0.07 0.25 0.02 0.14


First Stage
Constant -75.946*** 16.528 -75.945*** 16.528 -75.945*** 16.528
(13.661) (13.920) (13.661) (13.920) (13.661) (13.920)

Distance from Equator 38.206*** 38.208*** 38.208***


(8.116) (8.116) (8.116)

Percentage of European 0.339*** 0.339*** 0.339***


Population in 1900 (0.057) (0.057) (0.057)
Log of Population 0.933 1.775*** 0.933 1.775*** 0.933 1.775***
(0.799) (0.659) (0.798) (0.659) (0.798) (0.659)

Log of Income 9.414*** 0.587 9.415*** 0.587 9.415*** 0.587


per Capita (1.639) (1.735) (1.639) (1.735) (1.639) (1.735)
R-Squared 0.689 0.688 0.688 0.688 0.688 0.688

* significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%; A signific


inequality interaction and per capita income; AA significant at 5% in joi
parentheses

ture research) along the following lines. First, the distribution of wealth
(in conjunction with the type of assets), which took shape as a result
of a particular pattern of state formation, colonization, conquest, and
so on, determines the occurrence of political violence with some prob-
ability. Second, those countries marred by violence are likely to remain
trapped in poverty; that is, they are unable to develop economically
beyond the exploitation (if at all) of their natural resources (land and
minerals).66 In short, initial conditions may lead to violence with some

66 It is less clear how political violence may shape inequality. It is not violence itself but the outcome
resulting from violence (the victory of one party, the change of regime) that may alter the distribution
of wealth. Still, it is true that, by leading to economic stagnation or collapse, violence may depress the
wages of certain economic sectors and exacerbate economic inequalities.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
432 WORLD POLITICS

probability, and if violence oc


and feed into the cycle of vi
more mobile forms of wealth.

Conclusions

Combining several strands of the literature on political violence - the


literature on material grievances and motivations and recent research
on the geographical and organizational opportunities that foster con-
flict - I offer a formal model to account for the distribution of civil
wars, guerrillas, and rebellious actions across the world in contempo-
rary times. The model is successfully tested with a comprehensive data
set that covers most of the twentieth century and goes back to the mid-
nineteenth century for civil wars.
Modern political violence (particularly violence of an organized
nature) occurs in states in which assets are immobile and unequally
distributed. In relatively equal societies, peaceful, democratic means of
solving conflict are advantageous to all parties and violence happens
with little probability. In economies where wealth is either mobile or
hard to tax or confiscate, sustained political violence to grab those as-
sets does not pay off since their owners can either leave in response to
the threat of confiscation or are indispensable to the optimal exploita-
tion of assets. These two simple parameters (inequality and specificity
of assets) capture and systematize in an analytical manner the set of
intuitions previous scholars have employed to examine the underlying
motivations that generate violence, such as the role of inequality or the
idea that "lootable assets" correlate with the presence of civil wars.
Besides depicting the motives of political violence, the model in-
corporates the notion that opportunities, of an organizational or geo-
graphical nature, drive the costs of engaging in violence and therefore
determine the likelihood that overt conflict will occur (as well as the
likelihood that different types of violence will be employed).
The examination of the four data sets on civil wars as well as of data
on guerrilla warfare and revolutionary outbreaks validates the model of
the article and outperforms previous research on this question. Spells
of organized political violence in the world tend to cluster in a rela-
tively tight manner in states where inequality is high and the economy
is mainly agrarian. By contrast, ethnic and religious traits play only
a sporadic role: the distribution of ethnic groups is relevant only for
guerrilla warfare, and the proportion of religious groups has no effect
on violence. Geography matters in a less than systematic way: moun-

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 433

tainous terrain matters for civil wars; noncontiguous states are in tur
more prone to guerrilla warfare.
The empirical strength of the model, which naturally has to be rea
in probabilistic terms, has an additional advantage: it allows us to thin
in a fruitful way about all the variance that is left unexplained. A sec
ond look at the visual information conveyed in the figures of the artic
shows that although most cases of organized political violence (war
guerrillas, and rebellions) occur within the upper-right area of inequa
ity and asset specificity, there are a few cases that do not. Most of tho
seem to belong to the cases of "urban terrorism." Our theories for tho
cases are thus far wanting. Again, this calls for stepping up our effor
at establishing their theoretical underpinnings.

Appendix 1: Interclass Conflict

To see the conditions under which violence occurs in the mod


member that after the wealthy establish an authoritarian regime
poor either acquiesce or rebel. If they rebel and the wealthy are s
the rebellion is quelled and authoritarianism is reasserted. The co
curred by each wealthy member in a successful civil war is r a
individual income of each wealthy person is kj - rw /gJ. In turn
assumption, the poor lose their assets and their income becomes y
If the wealthy are weak, the poor win the war and impose a regi
which the wealth of the rich that is country specific, and therefo
not be moved abroad, is confiscated. Hence, each wealthy person
(1-oJkJ - rwhi y When winning a civil war, the poor incur CO. Ea
of them will then get kj + oK/P - CO*.
The excluded majority resort to violence whenever the exp
gain of revolting is larger than the value of accepting an authori
regime. Formally,
q(kf+oZm/P-<0)>A, (1.1)
Sustained violence occurs when the wealthy decide to respond to the
poor's rebellion. If the costs of repression are low, the rich will always
repress, knowing that an authoritarian regime will eventually prevail. I
the costs of repression are high, the wealthy have no dominant strategy
to follow and simply follow mixed strategies to make the poor indiffer-
ent between revolution and acquiescence.
To construct such an equilibrium, beliefs about the probability of
victory by the poor in a revolution ((J) must be such that the poor are
indifferent between provoking a civil war and not doing anything:

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
434 WORLD POLITICS

P(*,+a*;/p- ©; = *,. (i.2)


This implies beliefs given by

V = k/(kp+GKw/P-a>). (1.3)
The beliefs of the poor are determined by the actual strategy of the
wealthy by Bayes rule. Representing the probability that the wealthy
choose to repress when repression costs are high as pA, and imposing
that these beliefs be correct determines/)^ as a function of P:

^'Pa^(Pa9*(H))- d-4)
Substituting P from (1.3) the probability of rep
is high is

pA = (l-q/q) (l-K/(okw-*>)). (1.5)

In turn, pR or the probability that the poor revolt is determined by


the indifference condition of the wealthy who face a high repression
cost. The wealthy are indifferent when the probability of maintaining
their wealth under authoritarianism without the poor challenging them
is equal to their income after transiting to democracy (denoted as yj:

('-/>*) (^-O=X- d-6)


Hence the probability of the poor revolting is

p*-i-(A.'(y.-rJ)> (i-7)
That is, within the high inequality/high specificity
income inequality and asset specificity increase, the pr
revolt increases (since the income under democracy re
under authoritarianism declines therefore making^
the marginal impact of inequality and mobility is diff
equality increases the numerator relative to the denom
sion (1.7) and so leads to a lower probability of revo
capital mobility leaves, instead, the denominator unch
increases the potential income of the wealthy under d
reducing/)^ . Thus, within the high inequality/high sp
volts should be concentrated in very highly specific ec

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS & REVOLUTIONS 435

Appendix 2: Iintraelite Conflict

After the poor decide whether or not to revolt, a wealthy indivi


/ (randomly selected by nature) has the right to make a demand ove
any other wealthy individual^' asking the latter to give up his wealth
In this game, the demander knows her own type - either strong (wi
war costs C0; ) or weak (war costs CO^). By contrast, those that face
demand do not know whether the demanders are strong or weak. On
i makes her demand, j may acquiesce or fight back. If the demander
does not demand anything, all individuals retain their initial wealth
and kj> respectively). If i makes a demand and 7 acquiesces, i rece
kj + ckj andy keeps (1-c) kj. Kj fights back but loses, the payoffs
kj + okj - C07 for i and (1- a) kj - cofory*. If; wins, the payoffs are
k * : - CO, for i and kJ + ck % ' - CO for /.
As in the interclass game, there is a set of a values close enough to
(that is, high capital mobility) that makes C07 > okj so that indididu
has no incentive to make any demand on individual j.
As asset specifity increases, the assets that can be grabbed from in
dividual y* grow to a point where they are larger than low war costs
still less than high war costs (co^ > okj > C0;). In those circumstan
a separating equilibrium follows. If the demander / has low war cost
she makes a demand and individual^' acquiesces because he knows that
given the medium levels of a, she would not make a demand if she h
high war costs. If individual / has high war costs, she has no incenti
to make a demand, since she is better off maintaining the status quo
Finally, for sufficiently high levels of asset specificity, ckj > CO^ > C
an individual i has an incentive to make a demand onj. In turn, in
vidualy fights back if he is better off doing so in expected terms:

q (kj + Okj - ©; + (1-q) ((1- O) kj - «; > (1- O) ij. (2.

Here q denotes the probability thaty wins. Individual /' always ma


a demand if her costs are low. If war costs are high, she follows mix
strategies to make individual j indifferent between acquiescing a
fighting back. Simplifying (2.1) and using Bayes' theorem to determ
the strategy of individual i to make individual j indifferent shows t
the former will make the demand when war costs are high with pro
ability p = co / (o( kj - kj) - co/
In turn, any individual^' will fight back with a probability that mak
the demander i indifferent between making a demand (and j not
sponding) and not making any demand:

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
436 WORLD POLITICS

(1-/0 UJ + akj) = kj. (2.2)

Hence the probability of/ fighting back is

p^ok'Vfk' + ok'). (2.3)

This result implies that, within a context of rel


asset specificity, the probability of j fighting bac
specificity. Relaxing the assumption of an equal d
within the elite, that is, making kj ^ kj, would
disparities within the elite would increase conflic

Appendix 3: Democracy and Conflict

The model developed in the article assumes that the poor are always
better off under a democratic regime. Here I relax this assumption and
allow them to entertain the possibility of revolutionary action (even
after the wealthy move to democracy). Three scenarios are possible.
1. In cases of low inequality and specificity, where the wealthy are
alwaysJJ better
J x off1 under
Jw democracy J (that x ,is,Jw
J w w/ow 1 Jw y > J y - r w/ow
whigh .. . ,7> Jw
, y - r .. . 7 ,
where y is the income of the wealthy under d
always move to democracy. Even if they are st
in repressing because democracy is their bes
revolt. If the wealthy are weak, repressing w
weak, giving the poor an incentive to revolt an
of the poor and in a payoff for the wealthy ((l-
than any other alternative. In turn, the poor w
q(y + OyJ)- (Notice that for similar levels of i
reduces even more any incentive the poor may
2. For cases of medium inequality and asset sp
ever y w/ow
</ w - r w/ow , >
, Jw J w Jw y
whigh1 > O
,. ,, J y - r ,. ,, we should d
the wealthy are strong (yw- rwlow > x)> they always repres
better off under authoritarianism (and they can suppress
If the wealthy
J ^Jw J Jw
are whigh''
weak (y ^Jw > Jw y - r ,), their reaction
the payoff of the poor. If the poor are better
under a revolutionary outcome ( y > q(y + Oy
to democracy, knowing than no revolt will
the poor are better off by revolting (y < q(y
low a repressive strategy. They repress oecaus
would understand that the wealthy are weak
ately revolt. The wealthy would be defeat

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ECONOMIC ROOTS OF CIVIL WARS OC REVOLUTIONS 437

yw - rwhi h. This would be less than the payoff under auth


which would be some weighted average of yw - rwbi h (the
authoritarianism with the poor acquiescing) and \l-c)yw -
payoff after the poor revolt and defeat the wealthy). T
tertaining the possibility that the poor may revolt und
reduces the feasibility of democracy (and naturally increa
in which revolts may occur).
3. Finally, if inequality and asset specificity are very
J'w " rw/ow > yw' rwbi b > X>> t^ie strategies each party plays
If the rich are strong, they always repress. If they are wea
repress as long as the poor are better off after revolution
democracy (y < q(y + OyJ). The reasons are the same
the previous paragraph: if the wealthy did not repress, th
know they face a weak enemy and would always revolt
prefer to go for some lottery between losing and keeping
out being challenged. If the poor are better off under dem
will have no incentive to revolt (if the wealthy conced
Under this circumstance, the wealthy may play a mixed s
away with authoritarianism with some probability and he
their payoff.

This content downloaded from 131.111.184.109 on Wed, 30 May 2018 17:27:51 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like