Safari - Jan 10, 2024 at 12:25 AM 2 PDF

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 1

Search Wikipedia

Division of labour
Article Talk

The division of labour is the separation of the tasks in any economic system or organisation so that
participants may specialize (specialisation). Individuals, organizations, and nations are endowed with or
acquire specialized capabilities, and either form combinations or trade to take advantage of the capabilities
of others in addition to their own. Specialized capabilities may include equipment or natural resources as
well as skills. Training and combinations of equipment and other assets acting together are often important.
For example, an individual may specialize by acquiring tools and the skills to use them effectively just as an
organization may specialize by acquiring specialized equipment and hiring or training skilled operators. The
division of labour is the motive for trade and the source of economic interdependence.

Historically, an increasing division of labour is associated with


the growth of total output and trade, the rise of capitalism,
and the increasing complexity of industrialised processes.
The concept and implementation of division of labour has
been observed in ancient Sumerian (Mesopotamian) culture,
where assignment of jobs in some cities coincided with an
increase in trade and economic interdependence. Division of
labour generally also increases both producer and individual
worker productivity.
Visiting a Nail Factory by Léonard Defrance (18th
After the Neolithic Revolution, pastoralism and agriculture led century)
to more reliable and abundant food supplies, which increased
the population and led to specialization of labour, including new
classes of artisans, warriors, and the development of elites. This
specialization was furthered by the process of industrialisation, and
Industrial Revolution-era factories. Accordingly, many classical
economists as well as some mechanical engineers, such as Charles
Babbage, were proponents of division of labour. Also, having workers
perform single or limited tasks eliminated the long training period Division of labor CPU and GPU

required to train craftsmen, who were replaced with less-paid but


more productive unskilled workers.[1]

Contents

Pre-modern theories
Plato

Xenophon

Augustine of Hippo

Medieval Persian scholars

Modern theories
William Petty

Bernard de Mandeville

David Hume

Henri-Louis Duhamel du Monceau

Adam Smith

Immanuel Kant

Karl Marx

Henry David Thoreau and Ralph Waldo Emerson

Émile Durkheim

Ludwig von Mises

Friedrich A. Hayek

Globalisation and global division of labour

Contemporary theories
Styles of division of labour

Labour hierarchy

Limitations

Gendered division of labour

Industrial organisational psychology

Division of work

Disaggregated work

See also

References

Further reading

External links

Pre-modern theories

Plato

In Plato's Republic, the origin of the state lies in the natural inequality of humanity, which is embodied in the
division of labour:

Well then, how will our state supply these needs? It will need a farmer, a builder, and a
weaver, and also, I think, a shoemaker and one or two others to provide for our bodily needs.
So that the minimum state would consist of four or five men....

— Republic (Penguin Classics ed.), p. 103

Silvermintz (2010) noted that "Historians of economic thought credit Plato, primarily on account of
arguments advanced in his Republic, as an early proponent of the division of labour."[2] Notwithstanding
this, Silvermintz argues that "While Plato recognises both the economic and political benefits of the division
of labour, he ultimately critiques this form of economic arrangement insofar as it hinders the individual from
ordering his own soul by cultivating acquisitive motives over prudence and reason."[2]

Xenophon

Xenophon, in the 4th century BC, makes a passing reference to division of labour in his Cyropaedia (a.k.a.
Education of Cyrus).

Just as the various trades are most highly developed in large cities, in the same way, food at
the palace is prepared in a far superior manner. In small towns, the same man makes
couches, doors, ploughs and tables, and often he even builds houses, and still, he is thankful if
only he can find enough work to support himself. And it is impossible for a man of many
trades to do all of them well. In large cities, however, because many make demands on each
trade, one alone is enough to support a man, and often less than one: for instance one man
makes shoes for men, another for women, there are places even where one man earns a living
just by mending shoes, another by cutting them out, another just by sewing the uppers
together, while there is another who performs none of these operations but assembles the
parts. Of necessity, he who pursues a very specialised task will do it best.[3]

Augustine of Hippo

A simile used by Augustine of Hippo shows that the division of labour was practised and understood in late
Imperial Rome. In a brief passage of his The City of God, Augustine seems to be aware of the role of
different social layers in the production of goods, like household (familiae), corporations (collegia) and the
state.[4]

…like workmen in the street of the silversmiths, where one vessel, in order that it may go out
perfect, passes through the hands of many, when it might have been finished by one perfect
workman. But the only reason why the combined skill of many workmen was thought
necessary, was, that it is better that each part of an art should be learned by a special
workman, which can be done speedily and easily, than that they should all be compelled to be
perfect in one art throughout all its parts, which they could only attain slowly and with
difficulty.

— The City of God (tr. Marcus Dods), VII.4

Medieval Persian scholars

The division of labour was discussed by multiple medieval Persian scholars. They considered the division of
labour between members of a household, between members of society and between nations. For Nasir al-
Din al-Tusi and al-Ghazali the division of labour was necessary and useful. The similarity of the examples
provided by these scholars with those provided by Adam Smith (such as al-Ghazali's needle factory and
Tusi's claim that exchange, and by extension the division of labour, are the consequences of the human
reasoning capability and that no animals have been observed to exchange one bone for another) led some
scholars to conjecture that Smith was influenced by the medieval Persian scholarship.[5]

Modern theories

William Petty

Sir William Petty was the first modern writer to take note of the division of labour,
showing its has worth in existence and usefulness in Dutch shipyards. Classically,
the workers in a shipyard would build ships as units, finishing one before starting
another. But the Dutch had it organised with several teams each doing the same
tasks for successive ships. People with a particular task to do must have discovered
new methods that were only later observed and justified by writers on political
economy.

Petty also applied the principle to his survey of Ireland. His breakthrough was to Sir William Petty
divide up the work so that large parts of it could be done by people with no extensive
training.

Bernard de Mandeville

Bernard de Mandeville discussed the matter in the second volume of The Fable of the
Bees (1714). This elaborates many matters raised by the original poem about a
'Grumbling Hive'. He says:

But if one will wholly apply himself to the making of Bows and Arrows,
whilst another provides Food, a third builds Huts, a fourth makes Petty - Economic
Garments, and a fifth Utensils, they not only become useful to one Writings, 1899

another, but the Callings and Employments themselves will in the same
Number of Years receive much greater Improvements, than if all had
been promiscuously followed by every one of the Five.

David Hume

When every individual person labors apart, and only for himself, his force is
too small to execute any considerable work; his labour being employed in Fable of the
Bees by
supplying all his different necessities, he never attains a perfection in any Bernard
particular art; and as his force and success are not at all times equal, the least Mandeville

failure in either of these particulars must be attended with inevitable ruin


and misery. Society provides a remedy for these three inconveniences. By the
conjunction of forces, our power is augmented: By the partition of
employment, our ability increases: And by mutual succour we are less
exposed to fortune and accidents. 'Tis by this additional force, ability, and
security, that society becomes advantageous.

- David Hume, A Treatise on Human Nature

Henri-Louis Duhamel du Monceau

In his introduction to The Art of the Pin-Maker (Art de l'Épinglier, 1761),[6] Henri-Louis
Duhamel du Monceau writes about the "division of this work":[6]

There is nobody who isn't surprised of the small price of pins; but we
shall be even more surprised, when we know how many different
operations, most of them very delicate, are mandatory to make a good
pin. We are going to go through these operations in a few words to
stimulate the curiosity to know their detail; this enumeration will supply Facsimile of the first
page of du
as many articles which will make the division of this work.… The first Monceau's
operation is to have brass go through the drawing plate to calibrate it.… introduction to Art
de l'Épinglier, with
By "division of this work," du Monceau is referring to the subdivisions of the text "division de ce
travail" highlighted
describing the various trades involved in the pin making activity; this can also be
described as a division of labour.

Adam Smith

In the first sentence of An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the
Wealth of Nations (1776), Adam Smith foresaw the essence of
industrialism by determining that division of labour represents a
substantial increase in productivity. Like du Monceau, his example
was the making of pins.

Unlike Plato, Smith famously argued that the difference between a


street porter and a philosopher was as much a consequence of the
division of labour as its cause. Therefore, while for Plato the level of
specialisation determined by the division of labour was externally
determined, for Smith it was the dynamic engine of economic
progress. However, in a further chapter of the same book, Smith
criticised the division of labour, saying that it makes man "as stupid
and ignorant as it is possible for a human creature to become" and
Adam Smith portrait
that it can lead to "the almost entire corruption and degeneracy of
the great body of the people.…unless the government takes some pains to prevent it."[7] The contradiction
has led to some debate over Smith's opinion of the division of labour.[8] Alexis de Tocqueville agreed with
Smith: "Nothing tends to materialize man, and to deprive his work of the faintest trace of mind, more than
extreme division of labor."[9] Adam Ferguson shared similar views to Smith, though was generally more
negative.[10]

The specialization and concentration of the workers on their single subtasks often leads to greater skill and
greater productivity on their particular subtasks than would be achieved by the same number of workers
each carrying out the original broad task, in part due to increased quality of production, but more
importantly because of increased efficiency of production, leading to a higher nominal output of units
produced per time unit.[11] Smith uses the example of a production capability of an individual pin maker
compared to a manufacturing business that employed 10 men:[12]

One man draws out the wire; another straights it; a third cuts it; a fourth points it; a fifth grinds it
at the top for receiving the head; to make the head requires two or three distinct operations; to
put it on is a peculiar business; to whiten the pins is another; it is even a trade by itself to put
them into the paper; and the important business of making a pin is, in this manner, divided into
about eighteen distinct operations, which, in some manufactories, are all performed by distinct
hands, though in others the same man will sometimes perform two or three of them. I have seen a
small manufactory of this kind, where ten men only were employed, and where some of them
consequently performed two or three distinct operations. But though they were very poor, and
therefore but indifferently accommodated with the necessary machinery, they could, when they
exerted themselves, make among them about twelve pounds of pins in a day. There are in a
pound upwards of four thousand pins of a middling size. Those ten persons, therefore, could
make among them upwards of forty-eight thousand pins in a day. Each person, therefore, making
a tenth part of forty-eight thousand pins, might be considered as making four thousand eight
hundred pins in a day. But if they had all wrought separately and independently, and without any
of them having been educated to this peculiar business, they certainly could not each of them
have made twenty, perhaps not one pin in a day.

Smith saw the importance of matching skills with equipment—usually in the context of an organisation. For
example, pin makers were organised with one making the head, another the body, each using different
equipment. Similarly, he emphasised a large number of skills, used in cooperation and with suitable
equipment, were required to build a ship.

In the modern economic discussion, the term human capital would be used. Smith's insight suggests that
the huge increases in productivity obtainable from technology or technological progress are possible
because human and physical capital are matched, usually in an organisation. See also a short discussion of
Adam Smith's theory in the context of business processes. Babbage wrote a seminal work "On the Economy
of Machinery and Manufactures" analysing perhaps for the first time the division of labour in factories.[13]

Immanuel Kant

In the Groundwork of the Metaphysics of Morals (1785), Immanuel


Kant notes the value of the division of labour:[14]

All crafts, trades and arts have profited from the division of
labour; for when each worker sticks to one particular kind of
work that needs to be handled differently from all the others,
he can do it better and more easily than when one person does
everything. Where work is not thus differentiated and divided,
where everyone is a jack-of-all-trades, the crafts remain at an
utterly primitive level.

Karl Marx

Marx argued that increasing the specialisation may also lead to


Kant
workers with poorer overall skills and a lack of enthusiasm for their
work. He described the process as alienation: workers become more and more specialised and work
becomes repetitive, eventually leading to complete alienation from the process of production. The worker
then becomes "depressed spiritually and physically to the condition of a machine."[15]

Additionally, Marx argued that the division of labour creates less-skilled workers. As the work becomes
more specialised, less training is needed for each specific job, and the workforce, overall, is less skilled than
if one worker did one job entirely.[16]

Among Marx's theoretical contributions is his sharp distinction between the economic and the social
division of labour.[17] That is, some forms of labour co-operation are purely due to "technical necessity", but
others are a result of a "social control" function related to a class and status hierarchy. If these two divisions
are conflated, it might appear as though the existing division of labour is technically inevitable and
immutable, rather than (in good part) socially constructed and influenced by power relationships. He also
argues that in a communist society, the division of labour is transcended, meaning that balanced human
development occurs where people fully express their nature in the variety of creative work that they do.[18]

Henry David Thoreau and Ralph Waldo Emerson

Henry David Thoreau criticised the division of labour in Walden (1854), on the basis that it removes people
from a sense of connectedness with society and with the world at large, including nature. He claimed that
the average man in a civilised society is less wealthy, in practice than one in "savage" society. The answer
he gave was that self-sufficiency was enough to cover one's basic needs.[19]

Thoreau's friend and mentor, Ralph Waldo Emerson, criticised the division of labour in his "The American
Scholar" speech: a widely informed, holistic citizenry is vital for the spiritual and physical health of the
country.[19]

Émile Durkheim

In his seminal work, The Division of Labor in Society, Émile Durkheim[20] observes that the division of labour
appears in all societies and positively correlates with societal advancement because it increases as a
society progresses.

Durkheim arrived at the same conclusion regarding the positive effects of the division of labour as his
theoretical predecessor, Adam Smith. In The Wealth of Nations, Smith observes the division of labour
results in "a proportionable increase of the productive powers of labour."[21] While they shared this belief,
Durkheim believed the division of labour applied to all "biological organisms generally," while Smith believed
this law applied "only to human societies."[22] This difference may result from the influence of Charles
Darwin's On the Origin of Species on Durkheim's writings.[22] For example, Durkheim observed an apparent
relationship between "the functional specialisation of the parts of an organism" and "the extent of that
organism's evolutionary development," which he believed "extended the scope of the division of labour so
as to make its origins contemporaneous with the origins of life itself…implying that its conditions must be
found in the essential properties of all organised matter."[22]

Since Durkheim's division of labour applied to all organisms, he considered it a "natural law" and worked to
determine whether it should be embraced or resisted by first analysing its functions.[22] Durkheim
hypothesised that the division of labour fosters social solidarity, yielding "a wholly moral phenomenon" that
ensures "mutual relationships" among individuals.[23]

As social solidarity cannot be directly quantified, Durkheim indirectly


studies solidarity by "classify[ing] the different types of law to
find...the different types of social solidarity which correspond to
it."[23] Durkheim categorises:[24]

criminal laws and their respective punishments as promoting


mechanical solidarity, a sense of unity resulting from individuals
engaging in similar work who hold shared backgrounds, traditions,
and values; and

civil laws as promoting organic solidarity, a society in which


individuals engage in different kinds of work that benefit society
and other individuals.

Durkheim believes that organic solidarity prevails in more advanced


societies, while mechanical solidarity typifies less developed
societies.[25] He explains that in societies with more mechanical
Émile Durkheim
solidarity, the diversity and division of labour is much less, so
individuals have a similar worldview.[26] Similarly, Durkheim opines that in societies with more organic
solidarity, the diversity of occupations is greater, and individuals depend on each other more, resulting in
greater benefits to society as a whole.[26] Durkheim's work enabled social science to progress more
efficiently "in…the understanding of human social behavior."[27]

Ludwig von Mises

Marx's theories, including his negative claims regarding the division of labour,
have been criticised by the Austrian economists, notably Ludwig von Mises.
The primary argument is that the economic gains accruing from the division of
labour far outweigh the costs, thus developing on the thesis that division of
labor leads to cost efficiencies. It is argued that it is fully possible to achieve
balanced human development within capitalism and alienation is downplayed
as mere romantic fiction.

According to Mises, the idea has led to the concept of mechanization in which
a specific task is performed by a mechanical device, instead of an individual
labourer. This method of production is significantly more effective in both yield
and cost-effectiveness, and utilises the division of labour to the fullest extent Ludwig von Mises
possible. Mises saw the very idea of a task being performed by a specialised
mechanical device as being the greatest achievement of division of labour.[28]

Friedrich A. Hayek

In "The Use of Knowledge in Society", Friedrich A. Hayek states:[29]

The price system is just one of those formations which man has
learned to use (though he is still very far from having learned to
make the best use of it) after he had stumbled upon it without
understanding it. Through it, not only a division of labour but
also a coordinated utilisation of resources based on an equally
divided knowledge has become possible. The people who like to
deride any suggestion that this may so usually distort the
argument by insinuating that it asserts that by some miracle just
that sort of system has spontaneously grown up which is best
suited to modern civilisation. It is the other way round: man has Friedrich Hayek portrait
been able to develop that division of labour on which our
civilisation is based because he happened to stumble upon a
method which made it possible. Had he not done so, he might
still have developed some other, altogether different, type of
civilisation, something like the "state" of the termite ants, or
some other altogether unimaginable type.

Globalisation and global division of labour

The issue reaches its broadest scope in the controversies about globalisation, which is often interpreted as
a euphemism for the expansion of international trade based on comparative advantage. This would mean
that countries specialise in the work they can do at the lowest relative cost measured in terms of the
opportunity cost of not using resources for other work, compared to the opportunity costs experienced by
countries. Critics, however, allege that international specialisation cannot be explained sufficiently in terms
of "the work nations do best", rather that this specialisation is guided more by commercial criteria, which
favour some countries over others.[30][31]

The OECD advised in June 2005[32] that:

Efficient policies to encourage employment and combat unemployment are essential if


countries are to reap the full benefits of globalisation and avoid a backlash against open
trade... Job losses in some sectors, along with new job opportunities in other sectors, are an
inevitable accompaniment of the process of globalisation... The challenge is to ensure that the
adjustment process involved in matching available workers with new job openings works as
smoothly as possible.

Few studies have taken place regarding the global division of labour. Information can be drawn from ILO and
national statistical offices.[33] In one study, Deon Filmer estimated that 2.474 billion people participated in
the global non-domestic labour force in the mid-1990s. Of these:[34]

around 15%, or 379 million people, worked in the industry;

a third, or 800 million worked in services and

over 40%, or 1,074 million, in agriculture.

The majority of workers in industry and services were wage and salary earners—58 per cent of the industrial
workforce and 65 per cent of the services workforce. But a large portion was self-employed or involved in
family labour. Filmer suggests the total of employees worldwide in the 1990s was about 880 million,
compared with around a billion working on their own account on the land (mainly peasants), and some 480
million working on their own account in industry and services. The 2007 ILO Global Employment Trends
Report indicated that services have surpassed agriculture for the first time in human history:[33]

In 2006 the service sector's share of global employment overtook agriculture for the first time,
increasing from 39.5 to 40 per cent. Agriculture decreased from 39.7 per cent to 38.7 per cent.
The industry sector accounted for 21.3 per cent of total employment.

Contemporary theories

This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding
citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (July
2020) (Learn how and when to remove this template message)

This section's tone or style may not reflect the encyclopedic tone used on Wikipedia. See
Wikipedia's guide to writing better articles for suggestions. (January 2020) (Learn how and when to
remove this template message)

In the modern world, those specialists most preoccupied in their work with theorising about the division of
labour are those involved in management and organisation.

In general, in capitalist economies, such things are not decided consciously.[35] Different people try
different things, and that which is most effective cost-wise (produces the most and best output with the
least input) will generally be adopted. Often, techniques that work in one place or time do not work as well
in another.

Styles of division of labour

Two styles of management that are seen in modern organisations are control and commitment:[36]

1. Control management, the style of the past, is based on the principles of job specialisation and the
division of labour. This is the assembly-line style of job specialisation, where employees are given a
very narrow set of tasks or one specific task.

2. Commitment division of labour, the style of the future, is oriented on including the employee and
building a level of internal commitment towards accomplishing tasks. Tasks include more responsibility
and are coordinated based on expertise rather than a formal position.

Job specialisation is advantageous in developing employee expertise in a field and boosting organisational
production. However, disadvantages of job specialisation included limited employee skill, dependence on
entire department fluency, and employee discontent with repetitive tasks.[36]

Labour hierarchy

It is widely accepted among economists and social theorists that the division of labour is, to a great extent,
inevitable within capitalist societies, simply because no one can do all tasks at once. Labour hierarchy is a
very common feature of the modern capitalist workplace structure, and the way these hierarchies are
structured can be influenced by a variety of different factors, including:[36]

Size: as organisations increase in size, there is a correlation in the rise of the division of labour.

Cost: cost limits small organisations from dividing their labour responsibilities.

Development of new technology: technological developments have led to a decrease in the amount of
job specialisation in organisations as new technology makes it easier for fewer employees to accomplish a
variety of tasks and still enhance production. New technology has also been helpful in the flow of
information between departments helping to reduce the feeling of department isolation.

It is often argued that the most equitable principle in allocating people within hierarchies is that of true (or
proven) competency or ability. This concept of meritocracy could be read as an explanation or as a
justification of why a division of labour is the way it is.[37]

This claim, however, is often disputed by various sources, particularly:

Marxists[38] claim hierarchy is created to support the power structures in capitalist societies which
maintain the capitalist class as the owner of the labour of workers, in order to exploit it. Anarchists[39]
often add to this analysis by defending that the presence of coercive hierarchy in any form is contrary to
the values of liberty and equality.

Anti-imperialists see the globalised labour hierarchy between first world and third world countries
necessitated by companies (through unequal exchange) that create a labor aristocracy by exploiting the
poverty of workers in the developing world, where wages are much lower. These increased profits enable
these companies to pay higher wages and taxes in the developed world (which fund welfare in first world
countries), thus creating a working class satisfied with their standard of living and not inclined to
revolution.[40] This concept is further explored in dependency theory, notably by Samir Amin[31] and Zak
Cope.[30]

Limitations

Adam Smith famously said in The Wealth of Nations that the division of labour is limited by the extent of the
market. This is because it is by the exchange that each person can be specialised in their work and yet still
have access to a wide range of goods and services. Hence, reductions in barriers to exchange lead to
increases in the division of labour and so help to drive economic growth. Limitations to the division of labour
have also been related to coordination and transportation costs.[41]

There can be motivational advantages to a reduced division of labour (which has been termed ‘job
enlargement’ and 'job enrichment').[42] Jobs that are too specialised in a narrow range of tasks are said to
result in demotivation due to boredom and alienation. Hence, a Taylorist approach to work design
contributed to worsened industrial relations.

There are also limitations to the division of labour (and the division of work) that result from workflow
variations and uncertainties.[43][44] These help to explain issues in modern work organisation, such as task
consolidations in business process re-engineering and the use of multi-skilled work teams. For instance,
one stage of a production process may temporarily work at a slower pace, forcing other stages to slow
down. One answer to this is to make some portion of resources mobile between stages so that those
resources must be capable of undertaking a wider range of tasks. Another is to consolidate tasks so that
they are undertaken one after another by the same workers and other resources. Stocks between stages
can also help to reduce the problem to some extent but are costly and can hamper quality control. Modern
flexible manufacturing systems require both flexible machines and flexible workers.

In project-based work, the coordination of resources is a difficult issue for the project manager as project
schedules and resulting resource bookings are based on estimates of task durations and so are subject to
subsequent revisions. Again, consolidating tasks so that they are undertaken consecutively by the same
resources and having resources available that can be called on at short-notice from other tasks can help to
reduce such problems, though at the cost of reduced specialisation.

There are also advantages in a reduced division of labour where knowledge would otherwise have to be
transferred between stages.[45] For example, having a single person deal with a customer query means that
only that one person has to be familiar with the customer's details. It is also likely to result in the query
being handled faster due to the elimination of delays in passing the query between different people.

Gendered division of labour

Main articles: Gender role, Women's work, Sexual division of labour, and Occupational segregation

This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding
citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (July
2020) (Learn how and when to remove this template message)

The clearest exposition of the principles of sexual division of labour across the full range of human
societies can be summarised by a large number of logically complementary implicational constraints of the
following form: if women of childbearing ages in a given community tend to do X (e.g., preparing soil for
planting) they will also do Y (e.g., the planting); while for men the logical reversal in this example would be
that if men plant, they will prepare the soil.

White, Brudner, and Burton's (1977) "Entailment Theory and Method: A Cross-Cultural Analysis of the
Sexual Division of Labor",[46] using statistical entailment analysis, shows that tasks more frequently chosen
by women in these order relations are those more convenient in relation to child rearing. This type of finding
has been replicated in a variety of studies, including those on modern industrial economies. These
entailments do not restrict how much work for any given task could be done by men (e.g., in cooking) or by
women (e.g., in clearing forests), but are only least-effort or role-consistent tendencies. To the extent that
women clear forests for agriculture, for example, they tend to do the entire agricultural sequence of tasks
on those clearings. In theory, these types of constraints could be removed by provisions of child care, but
ethnographic examples are lacking.

Industrial organisational psychology

Job satisfaction has been shown to improve as an employee is given the task of a specific job. Students
who have received PhDs in a chosen field later report increased satisfaction compared to their previous
jobs. This can be attributed to their high levels of specialisation.[47] The higher the training needed for the
specialised job position, the higher is the level of job satisfaction as well, although many highly specialised
jobs can be monotonous and produce high rates of burnout periodically.[48]

Division of work

This section does not cite any sources. Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable
sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (July 2020) (Learn how and when to
remove this template message)

In contrast to the division of labour, a division of work refers to the division of a large task, contract, or
project into smaller tasks—each with a separate schedule within the overall project schedule.

Division of labour, instead, refers to the allocation of tasks to individuals or organisations according to the
skills and/or equipment those people or organisations possess. Often division of labour and division of work
are both part of the economic activity within an industrial nation or organisation.

Disaggregated work

Main article: Disaggregated work

This section does not cite any sources. Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable
sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (July 2020) (Learn how and when to
remove this template message)

A job divided into elemental parts is sometimes called "disaggregated work". Workers specialising in
particular parts of the job are called professionals. The workers doing a portion of a non-recurring work may
be called contractors, freelancers, or temporary workers. Modern communication technologies, particularly
the Internet, gave rise to the sharing economy, which is orchestrated by online marketplaces for various
kinds of disaggregated work.

See also

Economies of scale

Complex society

Economic sector

Family economy

Fordism

New international division of labour

Productive and unproductive labour

Price system

Surplus product

Temporary work

Urbanisation

Industrialisation

Mechanization

Newly industrialized country

References

1. ^ Rosenberg, Nathan (1993). Exploring the Black Box: Technology, economics and history . Cambridge
University Press. pp. 25 , 27–32, 37–8. ISBN 0-521-459559.

2. ^ a b Silvermintz, Daniel (2010). "Plato's Supposed Defense of the Division of Labor: A Reexamination of the Role
of Job Specialisation in the Republic". History of Political Economy. 42 (4): 747–72. doi:10.1215/00182702-2010-
036 .

3. ^ Book VIII, ch, ii, 4[]-6 , cited in The Ancient Economy by M. I. Finley. Penguin books 1992, p. 135.

4. ^ Burns, Anthony (16 July 2020). Social Institutions and the Politics of Recognition: From the Ancient Greeks to
the Reformation . Rowman & Littlefield. p. 127. ISBN 978-1-78348-880-3.

5. ^ Hosseini, Hamid (1998). "Seeking the Roots of Adam Smith's Division of Labor in Medieval Persia". History of
Political Economy. 30 (4): 667-673. doi:10.1215/00182702-30-4-653 .

6. ^ a b du Monceau, Henri-Louis Duhamel. 1761. "Introduction." In Art de l'Épinglier, by R. Réaumur, and A. de


Ferchault. Paris: Saillant et Nyon.

7. ^ Smith, Adam (1976) [1904]. Cannan, Edwin (ed.). An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of
Nations . Chicago: University of Chicago Press. pp. ii.302–303. ISBN 978-0-226-76374-3. "In the progress of
the division of labour, the employment of the far greater part of those who live by labour, that is, of the great
body of people, comes to be confined to a few very simple operations, frequently one or two. But the
understandings of the greater part of men are necessarily formed by their ordinary employments. The man whose
whole life is spent in performing a few simple operations, of which the effects too are, perhaps, always the same,
or very nearly the same, has no occasion to exert his understanding, or to exercise his invention in finding out
expedients for removing difficulties which never occur. He naturally loses, therefore, the habit of such exertion,
and generally becomes as stupid and ignorant as it is possible for a human creature to become." Curiously,
this edition's Index carries no reference to this instance of usage of the phrase 'division of labour.'

8. ^ Rothbard, Murray. "The Celebrated Adam Smith" . An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic
Thought. Mises Institute. Archived from the original on 12 June 2012. Retrieved 5 May 2012.

9. ^ Tocqueville, Alexis de (1841). Democracy in America: Volume I. New York, NY: J. & H. G. Langley. p. 460 .

10. ^ Hill, Lisa (2004). "Adam Smith, Adam Ferguson and the Division of Labor" (PDF). Archived from the original
(PDF) on 28 July 2013. Retrieved 1 July 2012. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)

11. ^ O'Rourke, P.J. (2008). On the Wealth of Nations . London: Atlantic Books. ISBN 9781843543893.

12. ^ "An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, by Adam Smith" . www.gutenberg.org.
Retrieved 22 April 2020.

13. ^ Rosenberg, Nathan. "Babbage: pioneer economist by Nathan Rosenberg" . Archived from the original on 4
March 2016. Retrieved 28 March 2014.

14. ^ Fundamental Principles of the Metaphysic of Morals by Immanuel Kant - Free Ebook . Retrieved 25 April 2019
– via Project Gutenberg.

15. ^ Marx, Karl. [1844] 1963. "Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts of 1844." In Karl Marx Early Writings, edited
by T. B. Bottomore. London: C.A. Watts and Co. § First Manuscript, p. 72.

16. ^ Marx, Karl. 1849. "Wage Labor & Capital."

17. ^ Marx, Karl. [1867] 1977. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume 1. New York: Vintage Books. pp. 781–
94.

18. ^ Rattansi, Ali (1982). Marx and the Division of Labour . London: Macmillan Education UK. doi:10.1007/978-1-
349-16829-3 . ISBN 978-0-333-28556-5.

19. ^ a b Khurana, A. (2009). Scientific management : a management idea to reach a mass audience. New Delhi:
Global India Pub. ISBN 978-93-80228-01-3. OCLC 495418951 .

20. ^ Alpert, Harry (1959). "Emile Durkheim: A Perspective and Appreciation". American Sociological Review. 24 (4):
462–65. doi:10.2307/2089532 . JSTOR 2089532 . A founding father of sociology, Émile Durkheim, best
known for his 1893 seminal work, De La Division Du Travail Social [The Division of Labor in Society], "dedicated
himself to the establishment of sociology as a legitimate and respected science and as an instrument of rational
social action."

21. ^ Smith, Adam (23 January 2012). The Wealth of Nations. Simon & Brown. ISBN 978-1-61382-931-8.

22. ^ a b c d Jones, Robert Alun (1992). Emile Durkheim: an introduction to four major works. Masters of social theory
(4 ed.). Newbury Park, Califoria: Sage Publ. ISBN 978-0-8039-2333-1.

23. ^ a b Durkheim, Emile. [1893] 1997. The Division of Labor in Society. New York: The Free Press. Print.

24. ^ Anderson, Margaret L. and Howard F. Taylor. 2008. Sociology: Understanding a Diverse Society. Belmont, CA:
Thomson Wadsworth. Print.

25. ^ Moody, James. n.d. Sociology 138: Theory and Society. Duke University, Department of Sociology. Web.
Retrieved 16 November 2012.

26. ^ a b Merton, Robert K (1994). "Durkheim's Division of Labor in Society". Sociological Forum. 9 (1): 17–25.
doi:10.1007/bf01507702 . S2CID 144951894 .

27. ^ Alpert, Harry (1959). "Emile Durkheim: A Perspective and Appreciation". American Sociological Review. 24 (4):
462–65. doi:10.2307/2089532 . JSTOR 2089532 .

28. ^ Mises, Ludwig (1949). Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. p. 164.

29. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. 1945. "The Use of Knowledge in Society." American Economic Review 35(4):519–30.

30. ^ a b Cope, Zak (2015). Divided world, divided class : global political economy and the stratification of labour
under capitalism . Kersplebedeb. ISBN 978-1-894946-68-1. OCLC 905638389 .

31. ^ a b Amin, Samir (1976). Unequal development : an essay on the social formations of peripheral capitalism .
Monthly Review Press. OCLC 1151842795 .

32. ^ Khurana, A. (2009). Scientific management : a management idea to reach a mass audience . New Delhi:
Global India Pub. p. 136. ISBN 978-93-80228-01-3. OCLC 495418951 .

33. ^ a b "ILO releases Global Employment Trends 2007" . BANGKOK: ILO News. 25 January 2007. Archived from
:

You might also like