Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 34

16/10/2023

Vector Autoregressive Models (VAR)

Macroeconometrics

Prof. Freddy Espino

Macroeconometrics VAR 1

Readings

• Enders, Ch. 5

• Sims (1980) “Macroeconomics and Reality”, Econometrica, Vol. 48, No.

1., pp. 1-48.

• Stock and Watson (2001) “Vector Autoregressions”, Journal of

Economic Perspectives, Vol. 15, Number 4, Pages 101–115.

Macroeconometrics VAR 2

1
16/10/2023

1. Introduction

Macroeconometrics VAR 3

1. Introduction

• According to Sims (1980), if there is true simultaneity among a set of

variables, they should all be treated on an equal footing; there should

not be any a priori distinction between endogenous and exogenous

variables.

• In the two variables case, we can let the time path 𝑦 , be affected by

current and past realizations of 𝑦 , sequence and vice versa.

Macroeconometrics VAR 4

2
16/10/2023

2. Vector Autoregressive (VAR)

Macroeconometrics VAR 5

2.1 VAR

• Consider the simple bivariate model

1. 𝑦 , =𝛾 +𝑏 𝑦 +𝛾 𝑦 , +𝛾 𝑦 , +𝜀 ,

2. 𝑦 , =𝛾 +𝑏 𝑦 , +𝛾 𝑦 , +𝛾 𝑦 , +𝜀 ,

• Where it is assumed that

• (i) both 𝑦 , and 𝑦 , are stationary,

• (ii) 𝜀 s are white-noise disturbances with variance 𝜎 and 𝜎 ; and

• (iii) 𝜀 , and 𝜀 , are uncorrelated.

Macroeconometrics VAR 6

3
16/10/2023

2.1 VAR

• Equations (1) and (2) constitute a first-order vector autoregression

VAR(1), because it has 1 lag.

• Note that 𝜀 𝑠 are pure innovations (or shocks) in 𝑦 , and 𝑦 , .

• If 𝑏 (𝑏 ) is not equal to zero, 𝜀 , (𝜀 , ) has an indirect

contemporaneous effect on 𝑦 , (𝑦 , ).

Macroeconometrics VAR 7

2.1 VAR

• Using matrix algebra, we can write the system in the compact form:

1 𝑏 𝑦 , 𝛾 𝛾 𝛾 𝑦 , 𝜀 ,
3. 𝑦 = 𝛾 + 𝛾 𝛾 𝑦 + 𝜀
𝑏 1 , , ,

4. 𝐵𝑦 = Γ + Γ 𝑦 +𝜀

5. 𝑦 = 𝐴 + 𝐴 𝑦 +𝑢

• Notice 𝑢 = 𝐵 𝜀 ⇒ 𝜀 = 𝐵𝑢

Macroeconometrics VAR 8

4
16/10/2023

2.1 VAR

• Using the new notation, we can rewrite in the equivalent form:

6. 𝑦 , =𝑎 +𝑎 𝑦 , +𝑎 𝑦 , +𝑢 ,

7. 𝑦 , =𝑎 +𝑎 𝑦 , +𝑎 𝑦 , +𝑢 ,

• System (1) and (2) is called a structural VAR or the primitive system

and the system (7) and (6) is called a reduced VAR or in standard

form.

Macroeconometrics VAR 9

2.1 VAR

• Structural VAR:

1 𝑏 𝑦 , 𝛾 𝛾 𝛾 𝑦 , 𝜀 ,
𝑦 = 𝛾 + 𝛾 𝛾 𝑦 + 𝜀
𝑏 1 , , ,

𝜀 ,
𝜀 = 𝜀 ~𝑖𝑖𝑑 0, Σ
,

𝜎 0
Σ =
0 𝜎

Macroeconometrics VAR 10

10

5
16/10/2023

2.1 VAR

• Reduced or Standard VAR:

𝑦 , 𝑎 𝑎 𝑎 𝑦 , 𝑢 ,
𝑦 = 𝑎 + 𝑎 𝑎 𝑦 + 𝑢
, , ,

𝑢 ,
𝑢 = 𝑢 ~𝑖𝑖𝑑 0, Ω
,

𝜔 𝜔
Ω =
𝜔 𝜔

Macroeconometrics VAR 11

11

2.1 VAR

• In general, consider a VAR in the standard form with p lags, VAR (p):

𝑦 =𝐴 +𝐴 𝑦 + ⋯+ 𝐴 𝑦 +𝑢

𝑦 = 𝐴 + 𝐴(𝐿) 𝑦 + 𝑢

𝜔 𝜔
𝑢 ~𝑖𝑖𝑑 0, Ω ; Ω =
𝜔 𝜔

Macroeconometrics VAR 12

12

6
16/10/2023

2.1 VAR

• 𝑢 , = (𝜀 , − 𝑏 𝜀 , )/(1 − 𝑏 𝑏 )

• 𝑢 , = (𝜀 , − 𝑏 𝜀 , )/(1 − 𝑏 𝑏 )

• 𝐸𝑢 , =𝐸 𝑢 , =0

• Var 𝑢 , 𝑎𝑛𝑑 Var 𝑢 , 𝑎𝑟𝑒 𝑐𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑡

• 𝐶𝑜𝑣 𝑢 , , 𝑢 , = 𝐶𝑜𝑣 𝑢 , , 𝑢 , = 0 for 𝑖 ≠ 0

Macroeconometrics VAR 13

13

2.1 VAR

• The covariance of the two terms is not zero:

•𝐸𝑢,𝑢 , = −𝑏 𝜎 + 𝑏 𝜎 ⁄ 1− 𝑏 𝑏 =𝜎 =𝜎

• In the case that 𝑏 =𝑏 = 0 the shocks will be uncorrelated.

Macroeconometrics VAR 14

14

7
16/10/2023

3. Lag Selection

Macroeconometrics VAR 15

15

3.1 Lag Selection

• In a VAR, long lengths quickly consume degrees of freedom.

• If lag length is 𝑝, each of the 𝐾 equations contains 𝐾 × 𝑝 coefficients

plus the intercept term: 𝑁 = 𝐾 + 𝐾 𝑝

• Appropriate lag-length selection can be critical.

• If p is to small, the model is misspecified;

• if p is too large, degrees of freedom are wasted.

Macroeconometrics VAR 16

16

8
16/10/2023

3.1 Lag Selection

• There are basically three methods that have been employed to

determine what p should be:

1. By using some theoretical model.

2. By using a rule of thumb.

3. By using statistical criteria that trade off fit against the number of

parameters fitted.

Macroeconometrics VAR 17

17

3.1 Lag Selection

1. By using some theoretical model.

• For example, if one has a DSGE model of an economy in mind, one

would know what the potential set of variables to appear in a VAR

would be, as well as the likely order of it.

• Generally, if data is quarterly a VAR(2) would probably suffice.

Macroeconometrics VAR 18

18

9
16/10/2023

3.1 Lag Selection

2. By using a rule of thumb.

• Initially in practice one used to see people choosing p = 4 when

working with quarterly data and p = 6 with monthly data.

• Provided T is small these are probably upper limits to the likely

order.

Macroeconometrics VAR 19

19

3.1 Lag Selection

3. By using statistical criteria:

• The idea of imposing a penalty for adding regressors to the model

has been carried further in the Akaike Information Criterion

(AIC) and Schwarz Information Criterion (SIC):

𝐴𝐼𝐶 = −2𝑙 ⁄𝑇 + 2𝑛⁄𝑇

𝑆𝐼𝐶 = −2𝑙 ⁄𝑇 + 𝑛 × 𝑙𝑜𝑔(𝑇)⁄𝑇

Macroeconometrics VAR 20

20

10
16/10/2023

3.2 Lag Selection: Lag Exclusion Tests

• Suppose we want to test ℓ against ℓ − 1 lags in a VAR system.

• The proper test for this cross-equation restriction is a Likelihood Ratio (LR):

• 𝐿𝑅 = (𝑇 − 𝑚) 𝑙𝑜𝑔 𝛴ℓ − log( 𝛴ℓ ) ~𝜒 (𝑞)

• 𝑇 is the number of usable observations

• 𝑚 is the number of parameters estimated in each equation of the unrestricted

model, in this case ℓ.

• 𝑞 = (#𝑈𝑛𝑟𝑒𝑠𝑡𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑡𝑒𝑑 − #𝑅𝑒𝑠𝑡𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑡𝑒𝑑) in terms of parameters.

Macroeconometrics VAR 21

21

3.2 Lag Selection: Lag Exclusion Tests

• Under the Null that H0: 𝑝 = ℓ − 1 lags are appropriate, reestimate

the VAR over the same sample period using ℓ − 1 lags and obtain the

variance/covariance matrix of the residuals: 𝛴ℓ

• If the calculated value of the statistic is less than 𝜒 (𝑞) at a perspective

significance level (5%), we would not be able to reject H0.

Macroeconometrics VAR 22

22

11
16/10/2023

4. Stability and stationarity

Macroeconometrics VAR 23

23

4. Stability and stationarity

• The VAR

𝑦 = 𝐴 + 𝐴(𝐿) 𝑦 + 𝑢

• Can be written as:

[𝐼 − 𝐴 𝐿 ]𝑦 = 𝐴 + 𝑢

• Like in the ARIMA model, stability requires that the roots of 𝐼 − 𝐴 𝐿

lie outside the unit circle.

Macroeconometrics VAR 24

24

12
16/10/2023

4. Stability and stationarity

• If we can abstract from an initial condition, the 𝑦 sequences will be

jointly covariance stationarity if the stability condition holds.

• Each sequence 𝑦 has a finite and time-invariant mean, and a finite

and time-invariant variance.

Macroeconometrics VAR 25

25

5. Identification

Macroeconometrics VAR 26

26

13
16/10/2023

5. Identification

• Suppose that you want to recover the structural VAR from your

estimate of the model in standard form.

• Return to the two-variable/first-order VAR. Due to the feedback

inherent in the system, these equations cannot be estimated directly.

• The reason is that 𝑦 , is correlated with the error term 𝜀 , and 𝑦 ,

with the error term 𝜀 , .

Macroeconometrics VAR 27

27

5. Identification

• Standard estimation techniques require that the regressors be

uncorrelated with the error term.

• Note there is no such problem in estimating the VAR system in the

standard form [i.e., in the form 6 and 7]

• OLS can provide estimates of the two elements of A’s.

Macroeconometrics VAR 28

28

14
16/10/2023

5. Identification

• The issue is whether it is possible to recover all the information present

in the primitive system from the estimated system.

• Is the primitive form identifiable given the OLS estimates of the VAR

model in the form of 6 and 7?

Macroeconometrics VAR 29

29

5. Identification

• The answer to this question is “No, unless we are willing to

appropriately restrict the primitive system”

• The reason is clear if we compare the number of parameters in the

structural VAR with the number of parameters recovered from the

standard form VAR model.

Macroeconometrics VAR 30

30

15
16/10/2023

5. Identification

• The primitive form has 10 parameters: 2𝑏, 6𝛾, 𝜎 and 𝜎 .

• The standard form calculates 9 parameters: 6𝑎, 𝜔 , 𝜔 and 𝜔 =𝜔

• Thus, unless one is willing to restrict one of the parameters, it is not

possible to identify the primitive system.

• One way to identify the model is to use the type of recursive system

proposed by Sims (1980).

Macroeconometrics VAR 31

31

5. Identification

• Suppose that you are willing to impose a restriction on the primitive system

such that the coefficient 𝑏 equals zero:

1. 𝑦 , =𝑏 +𝑏 𝑦 +𝛾 𝑦 , +𝛾 𝑦 , +𝜀 ,

2. 𝑦 , =𝑏 + (0)𝑦 , +𝛾 𝑦 , +𝛾 𝑦 , +𝜀 ,

• Imposing the restriction 𝑏 = 0 means that B-1:

1 𝑏 1 −𝑏
• 𝐵= ⇒𝐵 =
0 1 0 1

Macroeconometrics VAR 32

32

16
16/10/2023

5. Identification

• Which will produce:

1 𝑏 𝑦 , 𝑏 𝛾 𝛾 𝑦 , 𝜀 ,
𝑦 = + 𝛾 𝛾 𝑦 + 𝜀
0 1 , 𝑏 , ,

• Pre multiplying by B-1:

𝑢 =𝐵 𝜀

𝑢 1 −𝑏 𝜀
𝑢 = 𝜀
0 1

Macroeconometrics VAR 33

33

5. Identification

• Decomposing the residuals in this triangular fashion is called a Choleski

Decomposition.

• Note that structural shocks (not observed) can now be identified from the

residuals of the standard VAR (observed):

𝑢 =𝐵 𝜀 ⟹ 𝜀 = 𝐵𝑢

𝜀 1 𝑏 𝑢
𝜀 = 𝑢
0 1

Macroeconometrics VAR 34

34

17
16/10/2023

Cholesky Decomposition

• In linear algebra, the Cholesky Decomposition or Cholesky Factorization is a

decomposition of a Hermitian, positive-definite matrix into the product of a

lower triangular matrix and its conjugate transpose:

• 𝑀 = 𝐿𝐿′

• Where L is a lower triangular matrix with real and positive diagonal

entries, and 𝐿′ denotes the conjugate transpose of L.

Macroeconometrics VAR 35

35

Cholesky Decomposition

• It was discovered by André-Louis Cholesky for real matrices, and

posthumously published in 1924.

Macroeconometrics VAR 36

36

18
16/10/2023

6. Impulse Response Function (IRF)

Macroeconometrics VAR 37

37

6.1 IRF

• Their main purpose is to describe the evolution of a model’s variables in

reaction to a shock in one or more variables.

• This feature allows to trace the transmission of a single shock within

an otherwise noisy system of equations and, thus, makes them very

useful tools in the assessment of economic policies.

Macroeconometrics VAR 38

38

19
16/10/2023

6.1 IRF

• The VAR

𝑦 = 𝐴 + 𝐴(𝐿) 𝑦 + 𝑢

• Can be written as:

[𝐼 − 𝐴 𝐿 ]𝑦 = 𝐴 + 𝑢

Macroeconometrics VAR 39

39

6.1 IRF

• Pre multiplying by Ψ 𝐿 = [𝐼 − 𝐴 𝐿 ] we get the Vector Moving

Average (VMA) representation:

𝑦 = 𝜇 + Ψ(𝐿)𝑢

Macroeconometrics VAR 40

40

20
16/10/2023

6.1 IRF

• As we know, the VMA representation can be written in terms of u’s shocks:

𝑦 𝜇 𝜓 (𝑖) 𝜓 (𝑖) 𝑢 ( )
= 𝜇 +
𝑦 𝜓 (𝑖) 𝜓 (𝑖) 𝑢 ( )

𝑦 = 𝜇 +𝜓 0 𝑢 +𝜓 0 𝑢 + ⋯∞

𝑦 =𝜇 +𝜓 0 𝑢 +𝜓 0 𝑢 +⋯∞

Macroeconometrics VAR 41

41

6.1 IRF

• The coefficients of 𝜑 cannot be used to generate the effects of 𝑢 on

the entire path of the 𝑦 sequences.

𝜕𝑦 𝜕𝑦
= =𝜑
𝜕𝑢 𝜕𝑢

• As we know, shocks in the reduced form are correlated.

• We cannot interpret as a casual-effect.

Macroeconometrics VAR 42

42

21
16/10/2023

6.1 IRF

• However, if we know the matrix 𝐵 we can identify shocks as structural,

i.e., not correlated.

• We know that 𝑢 = 𝐵 𝜀 ⇒ 𝜀 = 𝐵𝑢

𝑦 = 𝜇 + Ψ(𝐿)𝑢

𝑦 = 𝜇 + Ψ(𝐿)𝐵 𝐵𝑢

𝑦 = 𝜇 + Θ(𝐿)𝜀

Macroeconometrics VAR 43

43

6. IRF

• Notice that the results of the IRF depends on the identification of the

VAR.

• For example, Cholesky decomposition.

Macroeconometrics VAR 44

44

22
16/10/2023

6.1 IRF

• Thus, the VMA representation can be written in terms of 𝜀’s shocks:

𝑦 𝜇 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜀 ( )
= 𝜇 +
𝑦 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜀 ( )

𝑦 = 𝜇 +𝜃 0 𝜀 +𝜃 0 𝜀 + ⋯∞

𝑦 =𝜇 +𝜃 0 𝜀 +𝜃 0 𝜀 + ⋯∞

Macroeconometrics VAR 45

45

6.1 IRF

• The coefficients of 𝜃(𝑖) can be used to generate the effects of 𝜀 on the

entire path of the 𝑦 sequences.

𝜕𝑦 𝜕𝑦
= = 𝜃(𝑖)
𝜕𝜀 𝜕𝜀

Macroeconometrics VAR 46

46

23
16/10/2023

6.1 IRF

• Each element of 𝜃(𝑖) are impact multiplier.

• For example, the coefficient 𝜃 (0) is the instantaneous impact of a one-

unit change in 𝜀 on 𝑦 .

Macroeconometrics VAR 47

47

6.1 IRF

• In the case of a stable VAR(1):

𝑦 , 𝑎 𝑎 𝑎 𝑦 , 𝑢 ,
𝑦 = 𝑎 + 𝑎 𝑎 𝑦 + 𝑢
, , ,

• The VMA representation is:

𝑦 , 𝜇 𝑎 𝑎 𝑢 ,
𝑦 = 𝜇 + 𝑎 𝑎 𝑢
, ,

Macroeconometrics VAR 48

48

24
16/10/2023

6.2 Accumulated IRF

• The accumulated effects of unit impulses in 𝜀 and / or 𝜀 can be

obtained by the appropriate summation of the coefficient of the impulse

response functions.

• Letting n approach to infinity yields the long-run multiplier

𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜃 (𝑖)
= Θ(1)
𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜃 (𝑖)

Macroeconometrics VAR 49

49

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

Macroeconometrics VAR 50

50

25
16/10/2023

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• Is used to aid in the interpretation of a VAR model once it has been

fitted.

• The variance decomposition indicates the amount of information each

variable contributes to the other variables in the autoregression.

• It determines how much of the forecast error variance of each of

the variables can be explained by exogenous shocks to the

other variables.
Macroeconometrics VAR 51

51

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• We want to forecast one period ahead and we have information until period 𝒕:

• The conditional expectation of 𝑦 is:

• 𝐸𝑦 =𝐴 +𝐴 𝑦

• The observed 𝑦 is:

• 𝑦 =𝐴 +𝐴 𝑦 +𝑢

• Thus, the forecast error is:

• 𝑦 −𝐸 𝑦 =𝑢

Macroeconometrics VAR 52

52

26
16/10/2023

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• Then, we want to forecast two periods ahead.

•𝐸𝑦 =𝐴 +𝐴 𝐸 𝑦

•𝐸𝑦 = 𝐴 + 𝐴 (𝐴 + 𝐴 𝑦 )

•𝐸𝑦 = (𝐼 + 𝐴 )𝐴 + 𝐴 𝑦

• The observed 𝑦 is:

•𝑦 =𝐴 +𝐴 𝑦 +𝑢

Macroeconometrics VAR 53

53

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• And the forecast error is:

•𝑦 −𝐸 𝑦 =𝐴 +𝐴 𝑦 +𝑢 −𝐴 −𝐴 𝐸 𝑦

•𝑦 −𝐸 𝑦 =𝑢 +𝐴 𝑦 −𝐸 𝑦 =𝑢 +𝐴 𝑢

Macroeconometrics VAR 54

54

27
16/10/2023

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• The n-step-ahead forecast:

𝐸𝑦 = (𝐼 + 𝐴 + 𝐴 + ⋯ + 𝐴 )𝐴 + 𝐴 𝑦

• And the associated n-step-ahead forecast error:

𝑢 +𝐴 𝑢 +𝐴 𝑢 + ⋯+𝐴 𝑢

Macroeconometrics VAR 55

55

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• From the VMA representation, the n-step-ahead forecast is:

𝑦 ( ) 𝜇 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜀 ( )
𝑦 = 𝜇 +
( ) 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜀 ( )

Macroeconometrics VAR 56

56

28
16/10/2023

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• The conditional expectation of 𝑦 is:

𝑦 ( ) 𝜇 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜀 ( )
𝐸 𝑦 = 𝜇 +
( ) 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜀 ( )

Macroeconometrics VAR 57

57

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• Thus, the n-period forecast error is:

𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜀 ( )
𝑦 −𝐸 𝑦 =
𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜃 (𝑖) 𝜀 ( )

Macroeconometrics VAR 58

58

29
16/10/2023

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• Focusing solely on the 𝑦 , sequence, we see that the n-step-ahead

forecast error is:

𝑦 , −𝐸 𝑦 , =𝜃 0 𝜀 , +𝜃 1 𝜀 , + ⋯+ 𝜃 𝑛−1 𝜀 , +⋯

+𝜃 0 𝜀 , +𝜃 1 𝜀 , + ⋯+ 𝜃 𝑛−1 𝜀 ,

Macroeconometrics VAR 59

59

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• Denote the n-step-ahead forecast error variance of 𝑦 , as 𝜎 (𝑛)

𝜎 (𝑛) = 𝜎 𝜃 (0) +𝜃 (1) + ⋯ + 𝜃 (𝑛 − 1) +⋯

𝜎 𝜃 (0) +𝜃 (1) + ⋯ + 𝜃 (𝑛 − 1)

• Because all values of 𝜃 (𝑖) are necessarily nonnegative, the variance

of the forecast error increases as the forecast horizon n increases.

Macroeconometrics VAR 60

60

30
16/10/2023

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• Note that it is possible to decompose the n-step-ahead forecast error

variance into the proportions due to each shock.

• The proportions of 𝜎 (𝑛) due to shocks in the 𝜀 and 𝜀 sequences

are:

𝜎 𝜃 (0) +𝜃 (1) + ⋯ + 𝜃 (𝑛 − 1)
𝜎 (𝑛)

Macroeconometrics VAR 61

61

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• And

𝜎 𝜃 (0) +𝜃 (1) + ⋯ + 𝜃 (𝑛 − 1)
𝜎 (𝑛)

• Respectively

Macroeconometrics VAR 62

62

31
16/10/2023

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• If 𝜀 shocks explain none of the forecast error variance of 𝑦 , at all forecast

horizons, we can say that the 𝑦 , sequence is exogenous.

• At the other extreme, 𝜀 could explain all the forecast error variance in the

𝑦 at all forecast horizons, so that 𝑦 would be entirely endogenous.

• It is typical for a variable to explain almost all its forecast error variance at

short horizons and smaller proportions at longer horizons.

Macroeconometrics VAR 63

63

7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition (FEVD)

• Note that the Choleski decomposition used necessitates that all the

one-period forecast error variance of 𝑦 , is due to 𝜀 .

• The dramatic effects of this alternative assumption are reduced at

longer forecasting horizons.

Macroeconometrics VAR 64

64

32
16/10/2023

8. Granger Causality Test

Macroeconometrics VAR 65

65

8. Granger Causality Test

• This definition of causality was developed by Granger (1969) and Sims

(1972).

• A test of causality is whether the lags of one variable enter the

equation for another variable.

• In a two-equation model with 1 lag, 𝑦 , does not Granger cause 𝑦 , if

only if 𝑎 is equal to zero.

Macroeconometrics VAR 66

66

33
16/10/2023

8. Granger Causality Test

• Thus, if 𝑦 , does not improve the forecasting performance of 𝑦 , , then

𝑦 , does not Granger cause 𝑦 , .

6. 𝑦 , =𝑎 +𝑎 𝑦 , +𝑎 𝑦 , +𝑢 ,

7. 𝑦 , =𝑎 +𝑎 𝑦 , +𝑎 𝑦 , +𝑢 ,

Macroeconometrics VAR 67

67

8. Granger Causality Test

• The direct way to determine Granger causality is to use a standard

F-test to test that restriction.

• 𝐻 :𝑎 =0

• If 𝑦 , is some sort of forecast of the future, such as a future price, then

𝑦 , may help to forecast 𝑦 , even though it does not cause a la Granger

𝑦,.

Macroeconometrics VAR 68

68

34

You might also like