Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 8

‘Socialism and China’

China’s New Economic Policy 1977 - today

In the post-Mao era, the Chinese Communist Party leadership was to learn from both the
mistakes of Mao and from the experience of the Soviet Union.

The new accepted leader of the Party, Deng Xaioping, was determined not to return to Mao's ultraleft
policies of war communism, purges and ideological purity. ​For a detailed account of these go to the
Background section of this Topic​.
To begin with Deng simply proposed that the Party adopt the basic position of ‘Boluan Fanzheng’ -
"​eliminating chaos and returning to normal​”.
Deng then went on to challenge the slavishly pro-Mao philosophy of the Party encapsulated by the
‘Two Whatevers’ approach: "​Whatever Chairman Mao said, we will say and whatever Chairman Mao did,
we will do"​ . This had even been incorporated into China's constitution. Deng famously counterposed to
this a very different approach based on two simple principles: “​seek truth from facts​” and ​"​practice is the
sole criterion for testing truth​".
A first step in the post-Mao healing process was to restore the rights and reputation of the victims of
the purges of the previous 20 years - over three million cases were reviewed and rehabilitated.
Deng’s next step was to approach the economic management of the Peoples Republic in a pragmatic,
open-minded way. One that was aimed at achieving prosperity. That was willing to try out new things and
then to implement what worked.
To this end, Deng and the team of economists who soon surrounded him, began by surveying the
various experiences of socialist economy in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. It was during this
process that they identified the continuing relevance to China of Lenin’s New Economic Policy (NEP), the
economic policy that had operated in the USSR for much of the 1920s. And of its chief theoretician,
Nicolai Bukharin.
In Moscow, Deng himself had personally studied the NEP in 1926 and Bukharin’s interpretation of it.
As one of his biographers put it: “​The theory of reform and opening that Deng developed several years
after Mao’s death, in the late 1970s and early 1980s, did not originate with him. It was rooted in…
Bukharin’s interpretation of Lenin’s New Economic Policy aimed at developing a market economy under
the control of the Communist Party. Deng studied this concept in the mid-1920s in Moscow during his
sojourn as a student at a Comintern school… The evident superiority of NEP-style socialism was
confirmed by his reading of Marxist-Leninist books and articles as well as contemporary speeches by
Stalin and Bukharin, which made a deep impression on Deng’s worldview ​ ."
Deng’s direct experience in the Soviet Union confirmed the effectiveness of the NEP. The economy
was booming. Markets were increasingly filled with goods produced by state and private enterprises. New
stores, restaurants, and cafes were opening all the time. “​We were never short of chicken, duck, fish, and
meat​,” recalled one of Deng’s classmates.
Deng Xiaoping drew on the ideas from NEP when he spoke of his own reforms in China. In 1985, he
openly acknowledged that “​'perhaps' the most correct model of socialism was the New Economic Policy
of the USSR.​"

Bukharin’s Influence On China’s New Economic Policy


In July 1979 at the behest of Deng and Hu Yaobang, Party General Secretary​, ​a special Institute on
Marxism-Leninism and Mao Zedong Thought was established to begin a serious study of the Yugoslav
and Hungarian experiences in building socialism. But their main attention was devoted to the Bolsheviks’
NEP and the works of Nikolai Bukharin, its main theoretician.
The fact that Bukharin had been repressed and executed by Stalin actually increased their interest in
his works and in his person. Having lived through the Cultural Revolution, the intelligentsia hated any kind
of terror. Interest in Bukharin was particularly stimulated by an international conference on him organized
by the communist movement in Italy. In September 1980 an academic forum on Bukharin was held near
Beijing: “​About sixty social scientists gathered and over many weeks discussed the theory of NEP, trying
to understand why it was not fully implemented in the USSR and how applicable it is to China​.” The
conference agreed to translate and seriously study Bukharin’s works. To this end, Hu Yaobang allotted
the entire upper floor of the Beijing Party School to the task. Thirty seven of Bukharin’s works were
published in Chinese including his biography. Several Chinese Bukharin specialists began to give
lectures at the newly established Department of Foreign Socialist Studies at the Higher Party School, and
a national tour on the subject was organised. Within intellectual circles, there was enormous interest:
“​The halls were jam packed. People sat on the window sills, and everybody wanted to hear something
new​.”
In 1981 Chinese scholars began publishing their own articles on Bukharin. They noted “​his insistence
that the growth of industry directly depended on the growth of agriculture. And his support of the
harmonious combination of planned and market regulations"​ .

How To Move Forward


Armed with a general economy strategy, Deng Xaioping and the increasingly collective leadership had to
work out how to move forward. Despite being the fourth largest country in the world, and having by far the
biggest population at 956 million, China’s output in 1978 was only ranked at 34th place. Its population
was hard put to even feed itself with extreme poverty levels above 60%. How was the party to tackle such
massive problems and unleash the system’s potential?
In the face of what seemed insurmountable problems, Socialist China had some major advantages
over its capitalist rivals:
● A political system geared to public benefit for all not private profit for the rich
● A willingness to consciously develop the economy through planning and experimentation
● The necessary tools for implementation of economic policy through public ownership of the banks
and key industries
● A stable and powerful government able to collect taxes and implement long term policies
But how were such advantages to be best put to use?
After the almost constant upheavals of the Maoist era with its artificial political ideology of class
struggle from above, the party leadership recognised that future change would have to be gradual and
experimental. Thus Deng’s famous expression “Crossing the river by feeling the stones” became China’s
approach, implementing reforms in a trial-by-error manner.
Often such reforms would start in a few regions, and if successful then be extended throughout China:
“​This gradual strategy reinforced the credibility of reform over time. By making reforms one step at a time,
and starting with those most likely to deliver results, the government built up its reputation for delivering
on reform. With every successful reform, the likelihood that the next one would be a success as well
undoubtedly increased. It also gradually built up the experience and skills for the design and
implementation of reforms.”​

Countryside the First Priority


Change had to come first in the countryside where the overwhelming majority of Chinese people lived.
And it had to end the problem of food shortages and malnutrition. This was a major change from the
Soviet economy which prioritised industry over agriculture. A model that China had followed in the first
three decades of its revolution.
The first step in the new strategy was to recognise that Mao’s experiment in collective agriculture had
failed. In 1979, in response to local demand, elements of individual private farm production and sale
through a ‘Household Responsibility System’ were allowed in a few areas. Facing ideological resistance
from conservative members in the Party, the leadership held back from making such changes official.
However, just as Lenin had experienced when introducing the NEP in Soviet Russia, the peasants in
China took matters into their own hands. The new system started to rapidly spread across the
countryside. Within three years, approximately 73% of rural farms had been de-collectivised and the
Household Responsibility System became the official policy for all of China.
The results were astounding. By 1984, annual agricultural output increased more than ​tenfold
from what it had been in the years of the Cultural Revolution. For the farmers this translated into
an increase in their average income of 166%.
Rural Industrialisation
The big increase in rural income for the peasants naturally led to an increased demand for agricultural
equipment for the farms, as well as consumer goods for the home and the individual peasant. In a natural
way, rural enterprises nearby began to develop to meet the demand. In most cases these were owned by
the old communes and in time became the property of the succeeding local authority bodies. They came
to be officially known as Township and Village Enterprises (TVEs) producing a wide range of items. The
state banks helped the formation of these enterprises with cheap loans. Already b​y 1985 there existed 12
million TVEs.
Fortunately, the fast growth of productivity in the agricultural sector was releasing large amounts of
labour which was taken up by these rural enterprises. In this way the total number of employees in the
Town and Village Enterprises rose rapidly from 28 million in 1978 to 94 million in just a decade. This was
soon reflected in China’s national income which by 1996 saw the share from non-agricultural activities
jumping to over 30%.
Just as Bukharin had predicted for the Soviet Union’s New Economic Policy if it had been allowed to
develop, China saw a natural process of industrialization in the countryside. A process that expanded
organically from the field to the city rather than the other way round. And this process didn’t just stop at
the borders of the Chinese domestic market but with provincial and national encouragement began to
expand into production for export. The TVEs even managed to become major international brands such
as Haier supplying half of the US home refrigerator market. In their heyday, the TVEs came to account for
40% of China’s industrial production and 27% of the country’s exports.
As one commentator put it: “​Agriculture in China grew steadily with favourable tax policies and other
encouragements from the state and advances in processes of mechanization and productive
specialization leading to record harvests. In contrast to the continuing weakness of Soviet agriculture, the
Chinese farming sector while declining as a relative factor in the economy became a success story that
helped the country's development rather than hindering it.​”

Opening up a Closed Economy


Another side to the economic reforms in China was the policy of opening up the economy to outside
investment and foreign technology. In line with its cautious and experimental approach to reform, the
Party leadership thought it best to test out the new open policy in a few limited areas. To this end,
between 1980 and 1984 China established what came to be known as Special Economic Zones in
Guangdong and Fujian Provinces, and the island of Hainan. Such zones allowed foreign companies to
come and set up jointly-owned operations with Chinese companies. The results were effective with many
overseas wealthy Chinese investing in the new Zones to take advantage of China’s huge supply of cheap
labour. Soon after, capital from the advanced capitalist countries began to take an interest. Having proven
the concept, the government decided to increase the number of zones. In 1984, China opened 14 other
coastal cities to overseas investment including Shanghai. Then in 1985, the central government
established a series of such economic zones further inland including the Beijing area.

Tiananmen Square Protests


The success of the big economic reforms in the countryside and the special zones during the 1980s had
its downside. The transition from an almost completely state-owned, centrally controlled, closed economic
system to a more decentralised and hybrid economy was bound to create transitional stresses and
distortions. The massive growth of rural and special zone business and trading made it possible for
individuals to make fortunes. And created all sorts of opportunities for corruption for Party and state
officials.
Equality which had been a hallmark of the maoist years began to be replaced by new wealth and
ostentatious consumption. This wealth was unequally distributed with uneven results between the
countryside and the cities. And with the growing wealth of the Eastern coastal areas leaving behind many
other regions.
Worse still was the lifting of some price controls that had kept prices stable and low for decades. For
example, between 1987 and 1988 prices rose by 30% in Beijing leading to panic among salaried workers
that they could no longer afford staple goods.
Moreover, unprofitable state-owned enterprises were being pressured to cut costs and lay off staff.
This threatened many urban workers who relied on the ‘iron rice bowl’ - the wide range of housing,
medical and other benefits that usually came with state employment.
Another discontented group were students and academics. Facing a dismal job market and limited
chances of going abroad, intellectuals and students began to voice their criticisms. Avenues for such
expression had significantly grown in the previous decade. A large number of private publications had
emerged which supported the reform process. For Deng and the leadership team around him, this was
useful in their ongoing struggles with the anti-reformist conservatives in the Party.
There was widespread public scepticism over the country's future. The communist certainties of the
old Maoist era were fast disappearing. People wanted change, yet exclusive power to shape events still
only remained in the hands of the top Party officials. And these officials were themselves divided over the
direction, scope and speed of the reforms:
“​The reformers ("the right," led by Hu Yaobang) favoured political liberalization and a plurality of ideas as
a channel to voice popular discontent, and pressed for further reforms. The conservatives ("the left," led
by Chen Yun) said that the reforms had gone too far, and advocated a return to greater state control to
ensure social stability and to better align with the party's socialist ideology. However, both sides needed
the backing of paramount leader Deng Xiaoping to carry out important policy decisions.​"
The divisions at the top of the Party were reflected in the media which had become more numerous
and diverse. Inevitably, the wider citizenry became drawn into these debates on the problems facing the
country. And began to surface openly. Public manifestations of discontent arose in the form of student
demonstrations in the capital in April and May 1989. These were sparked by the death of pro-reform
former Party General Secretary Hu Yaobang.
A protest encampment was organised in Tiananmen Square which then turned into a popular hunger
strike by some of the students on the 13 May in a demonstration attended by 300,000 people. This was
only two days before a welcoming ceremony was scheduled in the Square for the highly publicized state
visit of Soviet leader Mikhail Gorbachev. The students were hoping to use this to force the Party
leadership to negotiate with them, a demand supported by some of the more liberal Party leaders.
However, Deng joined forces with the Conservatives and decided to crush the protests which they
thought threatened to unravel the Party’s control of society.
Actually, the students themselves were divided over their aims. Those who actually wanted to move
China in the direction of capitalism and an American-style democratic system appeared to have been
very much in the minority. The large majority restricted themselves to demands for an end to corruption,
more democratic freedoms etc.
Nevertheless, the majority of Party leaders feared that the protest movement could escalate in the
direction of capitalist restoration, a fear that now seems justified in retrospect with the fall of the Berlin
Wall some five months later. The event that sparked off the rapid collapse of the state socialist regimes in
Eastern Europe and later the Soviet Union itself.
On the 3-4th of June the Party sent in the army to reach Tiananmen Square and clear it of the
protestors. In the approaches to the Square there were violent clashes between the army and Beijing
residents who supported the students. Then after repeated appeals from the soldiers, the students left
Tiananmen Square and the protest movement was suppressed.
On June 9, Deng Xiaoping, declared that “​the goal of the movement was to overthrow the party and
the state. "Their goal is to establish a totally Western-dependent bourgeois republic," Deng argued that
protesters had complained about corruption to cover their real motive, which was to replace the socialist
system… "the entire imperialist Western world plans to make all socialist countries discard the socialist
road and then bring them under the monopoly of international capital and onto the capitalist road.​"
Deng’s action in suppressing the protests turned out to be highly unpopular at the time. And he ended
up taking much of the blame for it. As a result he was forced to withdraw from his various state and Party
positions. However, behind the scenes he was still accepted as the final arbiter between the factions.
The 1990s
The crushing of the Tiananmen Square protest movement represented a victory for the conservatives in
the Party leadership. These conservatives felt that the economic reforms had introduced elements of
capitalism which were to blame for the outbreak of dissent and threatened the future of socialist China.
The collapse of Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union which soon followed only seemed to confirm their
fears. Unsurprisingly, the economic reform process stalled.
While Deng Xaioping no longer held any official positions in the party and the state, he was still
regarded as the ‘paramount leader’. His conclusions from the fate of the Soviet Bloc was not to halt the
reforms but the exact opposite: to accelerate the process. For this purpose, Deng embarked on a highly
publicised tour of the southern Special Economic Zones in 1992 ending up in Shanghai. In the tour Deng
commented on the various debates about socialist or capitalist ownership with what became one of his
famous catchphrases: "​I don't care if the cat is black or white, so long as it catches mice"​ . He urged the
provincial governments to “​be bolder in carrying out the Reforms and Opening-up, dare to make
experiments and should not act as women with bound feet​". The public reaction was very enthusiastic.
Taking advantage of this Deng bluntly threatened that "​those who do not promote reform should be
brought down from their leadership positions"​ .
The official Party leadership bowed to the pressure and resumed the reform process. This was
supported later in the year at the Party Congress which officially accepted that China must create a
‘socialist market economy’. Continuity in the political system but bolder reform in the economic system
were set as the goals of the 10-year development plan for the 1990s.
Meanwhile, from 1995 onwards inflation dropped sharply as the government tightened monetary
policies and food price controls. The following year, the state banking system was modernised.
Another major problem facing the Chinese economy was the large number of state owned enterprises,
many of which were inefficient and loss making. In September 1997 plans were announced to merge,
close or sell off many of them. Over the next three years up to 28 million SOE workers lost their jobs as
the government strove to make large state-owned enterprises profitable.
As such, the 1990s turned out to be a period of major economic change in China. It became the
second biggest recipient of foreign investment after the US and national output really took off.
As we can see from the graph below, the results speak for themselves.

If we just compare China to India, a country with a similarly sized population and level of GDP back in
1990. Now, three decades later, national output in China has reached nearly five times that of India.

The Power of Planning


A key to China’s amazing economic achievements has been its five-year planning process. The ability of
the government to consciously assess the country’s performance and direct its resources where they are
most needed has given China a massive advantage over its capitalist rivals. Part of this has been China’s
willingness to incorporate foreign capital as part of its plan.
A good example can be seen in the auto production sector. China was once famous for its bicycles which
were the main mode of transport in the maoist era. Then in the 1980s the new wealth that began to flow
from the reforms led to increasing purchase of car imports mainly from Japan. By 1985 the country was
spending some $3 billion a year to import more than 350,000 vehicles. This was beginning to create a
severe trade deficit. To overcome this, Chinese authorities decided to include an ambitious auto
production sector in its plan. The problem was that China did not have the technology to produce modern
motor engines and auto bodies. So, it had no choice but to invite foreign capitalist manufacturers to come
and produce in China. However, the result of these efforts was dramatic. The number of vehicles
produced in China rose from only 5200 in 1985 to 26 million in 2019, 28% of the world’s total and more
than the output of the US, Japan and the European Union combined!
Within this total local Chinese brands have a major share of the Chinese market made possible by the
joint ownership arrangements that were an original condition for the foreign companies to produce in
China. This trend is likely to rise as the government has taken major steps to encourage local
manufacturers to produce electric cars and establish Chinese brands as world leaders in this new
technology sector.

A New Planning Process


In the Soviet Union, planning was essential in helping to build up its economic strength. But it ultimately
failed because of its rigidity, centralisation and lack of innovation. In the maoist era, the soviet planning
model was used in China demonstrating many of the same limitations but made much worse by political
upheavals which often rendered the plans ineffective.
After Mao’s death, the Chinese planning process slowly evolved into a much more open, effective and
flexible system. As with his approach to the NEP, the Chinese leaders took on board Bukharin’s approach
to planning which was to​: “​establish the conditions for dynamic economic equilibrium. Essentially the task
of working out a national economic plan, more and more resembling a balance-sheet of the whole
economy… a consciously outlined plan, which will at one and the same time be a forecast and a
directive.​”
In particular, from 1993 onwards central planning in China was relaxed, with competition among
regions and their enterprises becoming possible. This decentralisation turned China into a laboratory for
experimentation. And vitally, room for experiments and trials became integrated into the planning
process. This provided vital feedback during the period of the Plan, allowing for changes and fine-tuning
to be made as the plan progressed, rather than having to wait for the plans to finish. “​This distinctive
Chinese approach to bottom-up program adjustment is very different from both Soviet-style command
economies and Western legislation-driven policy making. The decentralized generation of policy options
represents a crucial asset for innovation that had never been realized in top-heavy, centralized
Soviet-type party-states.”​
Moreover, the Chinese planning process has become increasingly sophisticated, involving experts in
China and internationally to identify and advise on developing technologies and rising sectors. Now, the
world’s fastest supercomputers are used to put the plan together.
The Plan is not just of use to the state sector but also of great benefit for the private sector too. It
removes much of the uncertainty typical of capitalist economies, and allows business to focus on meeting
the needs of the plan rather than having to work on its own forecasting.
Last but not least, there is a direct link between China’s Plan priorities and the party’s control over the
leaders of major institutions and state-owned enterprises. This is known as the ‘plan-cadre nexus’. The
ability of officials to achieve Plan targets is an essential part of their cadre evaluation and their prospects
for promotion. Criteria for this is largely based on achieving growth, creation of employment, attraction of
Foreign Direct Investment (FDI), and control of social unrest.
This ties the bureaucracy directly into the content and outcomes of the Plan.

The Advantages of Public Ownership


Although Deng Xaioping’s reforms introduced private ownership and business into China’s economic mix,
it retained a central role for public ownership. Through the state owned enterprises and state banks the
government maintains direct control over a majority of the economy. This gives China major advantages
in its economic development.
For one thing, it provides the government at national and local level mechanisms through which to
invest at scale and for the long-term, both areas that risk averse and short-termist private investors avoid
like the plague. In this way, the Chinese public sector has been able to develop infrastructure on a level
unseen in human history. The same with public housing and education. And so too in mobilising
investment in new technology.
Secondly, the large-scale nature of public ownership in China - in 2020 mainland China overtook
America in the Fortune Global 500, with its state-owned enterprises now being 124 out of the largest
companies in the world (the US coming second at 121). Among these, China now has three of the top five
most highly valued companies in the world. Such massive state companies gain great economies of scale
being able to buy resources more cheaply, carry out more research, employ more specialists, and
influence the market, than many of its multinational capitalist rivals. These advantages will become more
apparent in the coming years.
Thirdly, the government sees the state-owned enterprises as a necessary way to maintain social
stability, without which the economy cannot function properly. By providing secure employment and good
employee social benefits, periods of dislocation in the private sector and transitions between various
technologies can be smoothed out more easily.
Finally, the government uses the state sector to maintain control over the ‘commanding heights’ of the
economy. Through this instrument, the government can ensure its planning decisions are implemented
and not just ignored as is so often the case in the capitalist economies.

Effects of the 2008-9 Capitalist Great Economic Recession


The entry of China into the World Trade Organisation in 2001 ushered in high hopes among capitalist
leaders that China would evolve into a western-style capitalist economy with liberal multiparty institutions
to match. Such hopes found their echoes in China itself. Indeed, some in the private sector, academia
and inside the Communist Party itself began to argue for China to take its reforms to what they saw as
their logical conclusion. They wanted to close down the state-owned enterprises, privatise the state banks
and create a full blooded capitalist economy. Among other things, they drew inspiration from the formal
inclusion of the ​right to private property that was written into the country’s constitution in 2004 and carried
into law in 2007.
However, events were soon to dash such hopes and expose them as the delusions they really were.
Specifically, the financial crisis which sparked off the Great Recession of 2008-9 in America and Europe
dramatically highlighted the weaknesses of the capitalist model. And confirmed the strengths of China’s
dominant public sector / supportive private sector model.
In China, the initial impact of the capitalist crisis was to threaten the crash of China’s export-oriented
industries and create mass unemployment within them. To avoid this, the government launched the
Economic Stimulus Plan, a package of massive infrastructure projects. These included new airports,
motorways, major water projects, high speed rail lines and so on. Plus, a large house building programme
which extended even to whole new cities.
Secondly, the central government loosened credit for local government and private projects. These
anti-crisis measures not only boosted the Chinese economy but delivered facilities that were very
valuable in themselves, generating future revenue and efficiencies for the country. But in the capitalist
countries such state investment is usually blocked as it creates impossible competition for the private
sector. And the private sector is their main concern not the benefit of society as a whole.
In the US fixed investment in the Great Recession fell by over twenty five per cent, while in China
urban fixed investment rose by over thirty per cent. No wonder that China’s economy sailed through the
crisis virtually unscathed, while the USA has not been able to fully recover even by 2020. Even in the
previously developmental states of South Korea, Taiwan etc. no significant positive response to the Great
Recession was enacted.
The Great Recession turned out to be a historic turning point for the world economy: China surpassed
Japan as the second biggest economy of the world; it passed Germany as the greatest trading nation;
and the US as the largest manufacturer. In the latter case, China has become known as the "world's
factory" which obviously evokes memories of Britain’s ‘workshop of the world’ label in the 19th century.
The Great Recession also represented a reversal of fortunes for the previously growing private sector
in China. Many private Chinese companies went bankrupt or were bought up by their state rivals. The
phrase: ‘Guo jin min tui’ ‘the state advances, the private sector retreats’ summed up the process that
took place as a result of the crisis.

Living Standards
Over the last four decades, the miracle that is China’s economy, has translated into a massive increase in
living standards for the people, albeit from a very low level. While there has been a large increase in
inequality, unlike the capitalist countries the growth in the economy has also been shared by the rest of
the population. Annual personal disposable income, the amount of money that households have available
after income taxes, rose from only $263 per person in 1986 to $4462 in 2019. Given the size of China’s
population this is an incredible achievement. Yet, it also underscores how far China still needs to go to
catch up with and overtake living standards in the advanced capitalist countries. This is not planned to
happen until around the hundredth anniversary of the Chinese Revolution in 2049.
Another way of measuring living standards is to look at increases in household consumption – China's
rapidly growing numbers of smartphones, cars, internet users, those taking foreign holidays and so on
clearly reflect its improving living standards which in 2019 were currently rising at three times the rate of
the USA. Living standards are also reflected in rising life expectancy. Starting at only 36 years in 1949, by
2020 China had reached 77.3 years, just behind the USA at 78.54. Indeed, Chinese people will likely be
living longer than their US counterparts by 2025, if not sooner.
Perhaps the most amazing achievement in modern China has been the huge fall in poverty among its
population. Above all, this reflects the priorities of China’s socialistic policies. In late 1978 when the
reforms began, the number of extremely poor rural residents was nearly 770 million. By 2019 this had
been reduced to only 5.51 million or 1.7% of the population. Nonetheless, President Xi Jinping
announced a serious goal of completely eradicating extreme poverty in time for the centenary of the
Communist Party in July 2021. To achieve this, every person and family affected was visited, assessed
and assisted on a continuous basis. And it appears that the goal was already met by 2020.

Conclusions
The last four decades of China’s economic development and the dramatic impact it has had on the well
being of the Chinese people, has forcefully confirmed the effectiveness of Deng Xaioping’s reforms and
his wisdom in adopting the strategy of Lenin and Bukharin’s New Economic Policy. By recognising that
agriculture was the first priority in a rural country and accepting the need for private initiative to move it
forward, Deng and his circle of advisers opened up the way for the farmers and the socialist state to work
together to solve its problems. Through this, China was able to create a solid foundation on which to build
industry, first in the countryside and then in the urban areas. Moreover, the combination of state planning
and public ownership with foreign capital and technology, as well as local private enterprise, has allowed
China to achieve incredible growth rates for the economy and living standards. As such, China’s
experience of socialist economic reform represents a new way forward for poorer, largely rural economies
across the globe.
The mix of dominant socialist and subordinate capitalist forms that has evolved in China has secured
stunning achievements and moved China into the front rank of nations. To such an extent that the
advanced capitalist countries fear its continuing growth and innovation. And see it as a serious threat to
their system.
However, nothing stands still. And China faces many challenges ahead. We will address these
challenges later in this Manifesto and suggest some possible positive and far-reaching solutions to them -
see ‘​The Challenges Facing China​’.

You might also like